This is a modern-English version of Up To Date Business: Including Lessons in Banking, Exchange, Business Geography, Finance, Transportation and Commercial Law, originally written by unknown author(s). It has been thoroughly updated, including changes to sentence structure, words, spelling, and grammar—to ensure clarity for contemporary readers, while preserving the original spirit and nuance. If you click on a paragraph, you will see the original text that we modified, and you can toggle between the two versions.

Scroll to the bottom of this page and you will find a free ePUB download link for this book.


UP-TO-DATE
BUSINESS

HOME STUDY CIRCLE LIBRARY

EDITED BY

SEYMOUR EATON

UP TO DATE
BUSINESS

INCLUDING

LESSONS IN BANKING, EXCHANGE,
BUSINESS GEOGRAPHY, FINANCE,
TRANSPORTATION AND
COMMERCIAL LAW

FROM THE CHICAGO RECORD

NEW YORK
THE DOUBLEDAY & McCLURE CO.
1900

Copyright, 1897, 1898, 1899, by the Chicago Tribune
Copyright, 1899, by Seymour Eaton
Copyright, 1899, 1900, by Victor F. Lawson

[v]CONTENTS

I

GENERAL BUSINESS INFORMATION

Page
I. Commercial Terms and Usages 3
II. Commercial Terms and Usages (Continued) 4
III. Bank Cheques 6
IV. Bank Cheques (Continued) 8
V. Bank Cheques (Continued) 12
VI. Bank Drafts 15
VII. Promissory Notes 18
VIII. The Clearing-house System 21
IX. Commercial Drafts 26
X. Foreign Exchange 31
XI. Letters of Credit 37
XII. Joint-stock Companies 41
XIII. Protested Paper 46
XIV. Paper Offered for Discount 49
XV. Corporations 51
XVI. Bonds 54
XVII. Transportation 57
XVIII. Transportation Papers 59
  Examination Paper 64

II

BUSINESS GEOGRAPHY

Trade Characteristics

I. The Trade Features of the British Isles 69
[vi]II. """"France 94
III. """Germany 102
IV. """"Spain and Italy 111
V. ""Russia 120
VI. ""India 129
VII. """"China 139
VIII. """"Japan 148
IX. """"Africa 157
X. """"Australia and Australasia 166
XI. """"South America 177
XII. """"Canada 187
XIII. """"The United States 194
  Examination Paper 210

III

FINANCE, TRADE, AND TRANSPORTATION

I. National and State Banks 215
II. Savings Banks and Trust Companies 221
III. Corporations and Stock Companies 225
IV. Borrowing and Loaning Money 228
V. Collaterals and Securities 233
VI. Cheques, Drafts, and Bills of Exchange 240
VII. The Clearing-house System 248
VIII. Commercial Credits and Mercantile Agencies 254
IX. Bonds 263
X. Transportation by Rail 267
XI. Freight Transportation 274
XII. Railroad Rates 281
XIII. Stock and Produce Exchanges 288
XIV. Storage and Warehousing 294
  Examination Paper 301

[vii]IV

COMMERCIAL LAW

I. The Different Kinds of Contracts 309
II. The Parties to a Contract 312
III. The Parties to a Contract (Continued) 315
IV. The Consideration in Contracts 318
V. The Essentials of a Contract 321
VI. Contracts by Correspondence 326
VII. What Contracts Must Be in Writing 332
VIII. Contracts for the Sale of Merchandise 336
IX. The Warranties of Merchandise 340
X. Common Carriers 344
XI. The Carrying of Passengers 347
XII. On the Keeping of Things 350
XIII. Concerning Agents 353
XIV. The Law Relating to Bank Cheques 358
XV. The Law Relating to Leases 363
XVI. Liability of Employers to Employés 369
XVII. Liability of Employers to Employés 373
  Examination Paper 377

V

PREPARING COPY FOR THE PRESS
AND PROOF-READING

I. Preparing Copy 381
II. On the Names and Sizes of Type 382
III. The Terms Used in Printing 384
IV. Marks Used in Proof-reading 387

[ix]ILLUSTRATIONS

I

GENERAL BUSINESS INFORMATION

Page
A Poorly Drawn Cheque 7
A Carefully Drawn Cheque 8
A Cheque Drawn so as to Insure Payment to Proper Party 9
A Cheque Payable to Order 11
A Blank Indorsement 11
A Cheque Made to Obtain Money for Immediate Use 13
A Certified Cheque 14
A Cheque for the Purchase of a Draft 16
A Bank Draft 17
Ordinary Form of Promissory Note 18
A Promissory Note Filled Out in an Engraved Blank 19
A Special Form for a Promissory Note 20
The Advantages of the Clearing-house System 22
The Route of a Cheque 24
Backs of Two Paid Cheques 25
A Sight Draft Developed from Letter 27
A Sight Draft 28
An Accepted Ten-day Sight Draft 28
An Accepted Sight Draft 29
A Time Draft 29
Foreign Exchange 32
A Bill of Exchange (Private) 35
A Bill of Exchange (Banker's) 36
First Page of a Letter of Credit 38
Second Page of a Letter of Credit 40
A Certificate of Stock in a National Bank 42
[x]A Certificate of Stock in a Manufacturing Company 43
A Protest 48
A Private Bond 55
A Shipping Receipt ("Original") 60
A Steamship Bill of Lading 61
A Local Waybill 62

II

BUSINESS GEOGRAPHY

London the Natural Centre of the World's Trade 72
British Mercantile Marine 74
London Bridge 76
The Coal-fields of England 80
The Manchester Ship Canal 84
The Great Manufacturing Districts of England 88
France Compared in Size with the States of Illinois and Texas 95
Street Scene in Paris, Showing the Bourse 97
Approximate Size of the German Empire 104
North Central Germany, Showing the Ship Canal and the Leading Commercial Centres 109
Spain Compared in Size with California 113
Italy and its Chief Commercial Centres 117
Russia, the British Empire, and the United States Compared 121
Moscow 127
Comparative Sizes of India and the United States 133
China and its Chief Trade Centres 145
Japan's Relation to Eastern Asia 155
The Partition of Africa 159
Australia 171
The Most Prosperous Part of South America 183
Trade Centres of Canada and Trunk Railway Lines 192
Export Trade of United States and Great Britain Compared 198
[xi]United States Manufactures and Internal Trade Compared with the Manufactures and Internal Trade of all Other Countries 199
Principal Articles of Domestic Exports of the United States 205

III

FINANCE, TRADE, AND TRANSPORTATION

The Bank of England 216
Showing Cheque Raised from $7.50 to $70.50 241
A Certified Cheque 244
A Bank Draft 245
A Bill of Exchange 246
Illustrating Cheque Collections 252
A Mercantile Agency Inquiry Form 259
Specimens of Interest Coupons 266
Judge Thomas M. Cooley, First Chairman of the Interstate Commerce Commission 287
The Paris Bourse 289
Interior View of New York Stock Exchange 290

V

PREPARING COPY FOR THE PRESS
AND PROOF-READING

A Printer's Proof 390
A Printer's Corrected Proof 391

[3]GENERAL BUSINESS INFORMATION

I. COMMERCIAL TERMS AND USAGES

Decorative T

HERE is a distinction between the usage of the names commerce and business. The interchange of products and manufactured articles between countries, or even between different sections of the same country, is usually referred to as commerce. The term business refers more particularly to our dealings at home—that is, in our own town or city. Sometimes this name is used in connection with a particular product, as the coal business or the lumber business, or in connection with a particular class, as the dry-goods business or the grocery business. The name commerce, however, seldom admits of a limited application. In the United States trade is synonymous with business. The word traffic applies more especially to the conveyance than to the exchange of products; thus we refer to railroad traffic or lake traffic. Products, when considered articles of trade, are called merchandise, goods, wares. The term merchandise has the widest meaning, and includes all kinds of movable articles bought or sold. Goods is applied more particularly to the supplies of a merchant. Wares is commonly applied to utensils, as glassware, hardware, etc.

HERE is a distinction between the use of the names business and business. The exchange of products and manufactured goods between countries, or even between different areas of the same country, is usually called commerce. The term business specifically refers to our activities at home—that is, in our own town or city. Sometimes this term is associated with a specific product, like the coal business or the lumber business, or with a specific category, like the dry-goods business or the grocery business. The term commerce, however, is rarely used in a limited sense. In the United States, trade is synonymous with business. The word traffic specifically relates more to the movement than to the exchange of products; for example, we refer to railroad traffic or lake traffic. Items, when considered as items for sale, are called merchandise, goods, wares. The term merch has the broadest meaning and includes all kinds of movable items that are bought or sold. Products is used more specifically for the supplies of a merchant. Goods typically refers to items like utensils, such as glassware, hardware, etc.

Gross commonly means coarse or bulky. In trade it is used with reference to both money and goods. The gross weight of a package includes the weight of the case or[4] wrappings. The larger sum in an account or bill—that is, the sum of money before any allowance or deductions are made—is the gross amount of the bill. The word net is derived from a Latin word meaning neat, clean, unadulterated, and indicates the amount of goods or money after all the deductions have been made. To say that a price is net is to indicate that no further discount will be made.

Disgusting usually means large or heavy. In business, it refers to both money and products. The gross weight of a package includes the weight of the container or[4] packaging. The total amount in an invoice or account—that is, the total amount of money before any subtractions or deductions—is called the gross amount. The term net comes from a Latin word meaning tidy, clear, and pure, and it represents the amount of goods or money after all deductions have been made. When a price is labeled as net, it means that no additional discount will be offered.

The word firm relates to solidity, establishment, strength, and in a business sense signifies two or more persons united in partnership for the purpose of trading. The word house is very frequently used in the same sense. In mercantile usage house does not mean the building in which the business is conducted, but the men who own the business, including, perhaps, the building, stock, plant, and business reputation. The name concern is often used in a very similar way.

The word strong refers to stability, establishment, strength, and in a business context, it means two or more people joined together in a partnership for the purpose of trading. The word home is often used in the same way. In business terminology, house doesn’t refer to the physical building where the business operates, but rather the people who own the business, which may include the building, inventory, equipment, and the business’s reputation. The term worry is commonly used in a similar manner.

The name market expresses a locality for the sale of goods, and in commerce is often used to denote cities or even countries. We say that Boston is a leather market, meaning that a large number of Boston merchants buy and sell leather. In the same sense we call Chicago a grain market, or New Orleans a cotton market. In its more restricted sense the name market signifies a building or place where meat or produce is bought and sold. We say that the market is flooded with a particular article when dealers are carrying more of that article than they can find sale for. There is no market for any product when there is no demand. The money market is tight or close when it is difficult to borrow money from banks and money-lenders.

The term marketplace refers to a place where goods are sold, and in business, it often describes cities or even countries. For example, we say Boston is a leather market, which means many merchants in Boston buy and sell leather. Similarly, we refer to Chicago as a grain market and New Orleans as a cotton market. In a more specific sense, the word market means a building or area where meat or produce is bought and sold. We say that the market is flooded with a certain product when sellers have more of that product than they can sell. There is no market for a product when there is no demand for it. The money market is tight or close when it's hard to borrow money from banks and lenders.

II. COMMERCIAL TERMS AND USAGES (Continued)

The natural resources of a country are mainly the mineral commodities and agricultural produce that it[5] yields. The lumber and fish produced in a country are also among its natural resources. The positions and industries of cities are usually fixed by natural conditions, but the most powerful agent is the personal energy of enterprising and persevering men, who, by superior education, or scientific knowledge, or practical foresight, have often been able to found industrial centres in situations which no geographical considerations would suggest or explain.

Natural resources of a country are mainly the mineral products and agricultural goods that it[5] produces. The timber and fish available in a country are also part of its natural resources. The locations and industries of cities are generally determined by natural conditions, but the strongest influence comes from the personal drive of ambitious and determined individuals, who, through better education, scientific knowledge, or practical foresight, have often been able to establish industrial hubs in places that geographical factors alone wouldn't suggest or justify.

Commission merchants receive and sell goods belonging to others for a compensation called a commission. A selling agent is a person who represents a manufacturing establishment in its dealings with the trade. The factory may be located in a small town, while the selling agent has his office and samples in the heart of a great city. As regards the quantity of goods bought or sold in a single transaction, trade is divided into wholesale and retail. The wholesale dealer sells to other dealers, while the retail dealer sells to the consumer—that is, the person who consumes, or uses, the goods. A jobber is one who buys from importers and manufacturers and sells to retailers. He is constantly in the market for bargains. The names jobber and wholesaler are often used in the same sense, but a jobber sometimes sells to wholesalers. Wholesale has reference to the quantity the dealer sells, and not to the source from which he buys, or the person to whom he sells. The wholesaler, as a rule, deals in staples—that is, goods which are used season after season—though of course there are wholesalers in practically all businesses.

Brokerage firms receive and sell goods owned by others for a fee called a commission. A sales agent is someone who represents a manufacturing company in its transactions with the market. The factory might be based in a small town, while the selling agent operates from an office with samples in a bustling city. In terms of the volume of goods bought or sold in a single transaction, trade is split into bulk and shopping. The wholesale dealer sells to other dealers, while the retail dealer sells directly to consumers—that is, the individuals who consume or use the goods. A freelancer is someone who purchases from importers and manufacturers and sells to retailers. They are always looking for good deals. The terms freelancer and distributor are often used interchangeably, but a jobber can sometimes sell to wholesalers. Wholesale refers to the quantity the dealer sells, not the source from where they buy or the person to whom they sell. Generally, wholesalers deal in staples—goods that are used season after season—though there are wholesalers in nearly every industry.

Wholesale dealers send out travellers or drummers, who carry samples of the goods. Frequently the traveller starts out with his samples from six months to a year in advance of the time of delivery. It is quite a common thing for the retailer to order from samples[6] merchandise which at the time of placing the order may not even be manufactured.

Wholesale dealers send out travelers or sales representatives, who carry samples of the products. Often, the traveler sets off with their samples six months to a year before the delivery date. It's pretty common for retailers to order merchandise from samples[6] that might not even be made yet when they place the order.

By the price of a commodity is meant its value estimated in money, or the amount of money for which it will exchange. The exchangeable value of commodities depends at any given period partly upon the expense of production and partly upon the relation of supply and demand. Prices are affected by the creation of monopolies, by the opening of new markets, by the obstructing of the ordinary channels of commercial intercourse, and by the anticipation of these and other causes. It is the business of the merchant to acquaint himself with every circumstance affecting the prices of the goods in which he deals.

By the cost of a product, we mean its value measured in money, or how much money it can be exchanged for. The exchangeable value of products at any given time depends partly on the cost of production and partly on the dynamics of supply and demand. Prices can be influenced by the creation of monopolies, the emergence of new markets, the disruption of normal trading channels, and expectations about these and other factors. It is the merchant's job to stay informed about every situation that affects the prices of the goods he trades in.

The entire world is the field of the modern merchant. He buys raw and manufactured products wherever he can buy cheapest, and he ships to whatever market pays him the highest price. Our corner grocer or produce-dealer may furnish us with beef from Texas, potatoes from Egypt, celery from Michigan, onions from Jamaica, coffee from Java, oranges from Spain, and a hundred other things from as many different points; and yet, so complete is the interlocking of the world's commercial interests, and so great is the speed of transportation, that he can supply us with these necessaries under existing conditions more easily and readily than if they were all grown on an adjoining farm.

The whole world is now the playground of today’s merchant. They buy raw and manufactured goods wherever they’re the cheapest, and ship them to the markets that offer the highest prices. Our local grocery store might provide us with beef from Texas, potatoes from Egypt, celery from Michigan, onions from Jamaica, coffee from Java, oranges from Spain, and countless other items from many different places; and yet, the interconnectedness of global commercial interests, along with the fast pace of transportation, allows them to supply these essentials to us much more easily and quickly than if everything were produced on a nearby farm.

III. BANK CHEQUES

A cheque is an order for money, drawn by one who has funds in the bank. It is payable on demand. In reality, it is a sight draft on the bank. Banks provide blank cheques for their customers, and it is a very simple matter to fill them out properly. In writing in the amount begin at the extreme left of the line.

A check is an instruction for money, issued by someone who has money in the bank. It can be cashed immediately. Essentially, it's a sight draft on the bank. Banks give their customers blank checks, and it's quite easy to fill them out correctly. When writing the amount, start at the far left of the line.

[7]The illustration given below shows a poorly written cheque and one which could be very easily raised. A fraudulent receiver could, for instance write, "ninety" before the "six" and "9" before the figure "6," and in this way raise the cheque from $6 to $96. If this were done and the cheque cashed, the maker, and not the bank, would become responsible for the loss. You cannot hold other people responsible for your own carelessness. A cheque has been raised from $100 to $190 by writing the words "and ninety" after the words "one hundred." One of the ciphers in the figures was changed to a "9" by adding a tail to it. It is wise to draw a running line, thus ~~~~~~, after the amount in words, thus preventing any additional writing.

[7]The illustration below shows a poorly written check and one that could be easily altered. A dishonest person could write "ninety" before the "six" and "9" before the number "6," thus changing the check from $6 to $96. If this happens and the check is cashed, the person who wrote it, not the bank, would be responsible for the loss. You can't expect others to take the blame for your own mistakes. A check was changed from $100 to $190 by adding the words "and ninety" after "one hundred." One of the numbers was altered by modifying a digit to a "9" by adding a small line to it. It's a good idea to draw a line through the space after the amount in words, like this Sure, please provide the text you would like me to modernize., to prevent any extra writing.

A poorly drawn cheque. A badly drawn check.

The illustration on page 8 shows a cheque carefully and correctly drawn. The signature should be in your usual style, familiar to the paying teller. Sign your name the same way all the time. Have a characteristic signature, as familiar to your friends as is your face.

The illustration on page 8 shows a check carefully and accurately written. The signature should be in your regular style, known to the paying teller. Sign your name the same way every time. Have a distinct signature, as recognizable to your friends as your face.

A cheque is a draft or order upon your bank, and it need not necessarily be written in the prescribed form. Such an order written on a sheet of note-paper with[8] a lead-pencil might be in every way a legally good cheque.

A check is an order to your bank, and it doesn't have to be in a specific format. An order written on a piece of note paper with [8] a pencil could still be a legally valid check.

A carefully drawn cheque. A carefully written check.

Usually cheques should be drawn "to order." The words "Pay to the order of John Brown" mean that the money is to be paid to John Brown, or to any person that he orders it paid to. If a cheque is drawn "Pay to John Brown or Bearer" or simply "Pay to Bearer," any person that is the bearer can collect it. The paying teller may ask the person presenting the cheque to write his name on the back, simply to have it for reference.

Usually, checks should be made out "to order." The phrase "Pay to the order of John Brown" means that the money is to be paid to John Brown or to anyone he designates to receive it. If a check is written "Pay to John Brown or Bearer" or just "Pay to Bearer," anyone who has the check can cash it. The teller may ask the person cashing the check to write their name on the back, just to keep it for reference.

In writing and signing cheques use good black ink and let the copy dry a little before a blotter is used.

In writing and signing checks, use good black ink and let the copy dry a bit before using a blotter.

The subject of indorsements will be treated in a subsequent lesson.

We'll cover the topic of endorsements in a later lesson.

IV. BANK CHEQUES (Continued)

The banks of this country make it a rule not to cash a cheque that is drawn payable to order, unless the person presenting the cheque is known at the bank, or unless he satisfies the paying teller that he is really the person to whom the money should be paid. It must be remembered[9] however, that a cheque drawn to order and then indorsed in blank by the payee is really payable to bearer, and if the paying teller is satisfied that the payee's signature is genuine he will not likely hesitate to cash the cheque. In England all cheques apparently properly indorsed are paid without identification.

The banks in this country have a rule against cashing a check made out to order unless the person presenting it is known by the bank or can convince the teller that they are the correct person to receive the money. It’s important to remember[9] that a check made to order and then endorsed in blank by the payee is essentially payable to whoever holds it, and if the teller believes the payee's signature is authentic, they are unlikely to refuse to cash the check. In England, all checks that are properly endorsed seem to be cashed without the need for identification.

A cheque drawn so as to insure payment to proper party, A check written to ensure payment to the correct party.

In drawing a cheque in favour of a person not likely to be well known in banking circles, write his address or his business after his name on the face of the cheque. For instance, if you should send a cheque to John Brown, St. Louis, it might possibly fall into the hands of the wrong John Brown; but if you write the cheque in favour of "John Brown, 246 West Avenue, St. Louis," it is more than likely that the right person will collect it.

When writing a check to someone who isn’t well-known in banking, include their address or business after their name on the front of the check. For example, if you send a check to John Brown in St. Louis, it could easily end up with the wrong John Brown. However, if you write the check to "John Brown, 246 West Avenue, St. Louis," it’s much more likely that the right person will receive it.

If you wish to get a cheque cashed where you are unknown, and it is not convenient for a friend who has an account at the bank to go with you for the purpose of identification, ask him to place his signature on the back of your cheque, and you will not likely have trouble in getting it cashed at the bank where your friend keeps his account. By placing his signature upon the back of the cheque he guarantees the bank against loss. A bank[10] is responsible for the signatures of its depositors, but it cannot be supposed to know the signatures of indorsers. The reliable identifier is in reality the person who is responsible.

If you want to cash a check where you’re not known, and it’s not convenient for a friend with a bank account to go with you for identification, ask them to sign the back of your check. This way, you’re less likely to have issues cashing it at your friend’s bank. By signing the back, they’re guaranteeing the bank against any loss. A bank[10] is responsible for the signatures of its account holders, but it can’t be expected to recognize the signatures of endorsers. The true identifier is actually the person who takes responsibility.

INDORSING CHEQUES

  1. In indorsing cheques note the following points:
  2. Write across the back—not lengthwise.
  3. If your indorsement is the first, write it about two inches from the top of the back; if it is not the first indorsement, write immediately under the last indorsement.
  4. Do not indorse wrong end up; the top of the back is the left end of the face.
  5. Write your name as you are accustomed to write it, no matter how it is written on the face. If you are depositing the cheque write or stamp "For Deposit" or "Pay to ______Bank______," as may be the custom, over your signature. This is hardly necessary if you are taking the cheque yourself to the bank. A cheque with a simple or blank indorsement on the back is payable to bearer, and if lost the finder might succeed in collecting it; but if the words "For Deposit" appear over the name the bank officials understand that the cheque is intended to be deposited, and they will not cash it.
  6. If you wish to make the cheque payable to some particular person by indorsing, write "Pay now ______(name)______ or order," and under this write your own name as you are accustomed to sign it.
  7. Do not carry around indorsed cheques loosely. Such cheques are payable to bearer and may be collected by any one.
  8. [11]If you receive a cheque which has been transferred to you by a blank indorsement (name of indorser only), and you wish to hold it a day or two, write over the indorsement the words "Pay to the order of (yourself—writing your own name)." This is allowable legally. The cheque cannot then be collected until you indorse it.
    Cheque payable to order and a blank indorsement. A check made out to someone and signed over without specifying a particular person.
  9. [12]An authorised stamped indorsement is as good as a written one. Whether such indorsements are accepted or not depends upon the regulations of the clearing-house in the particular city in which they are offered for deposit. The written indorsement is considered safer for transmission of out-of-town collections.
  10. If you are indorsing for a company, or society, or corporation, write first the name of the company (this may be stamped on) and then your own name, followed by the word "Treasurer."
  11. If you have power of attorney to indorse for some particular person, write his name, followed by your own, followed by the word "Lawyer" or "Attorney.," as it is usually written.
  12. It is sometimes permissible to indorse the payee's name thus, "By ______(your own name)." This may be done by a junior member of a concern when the person authorised to indorse cheques is absent and the cheques are deposited and not cashed.
  13. Do not write any unnecessary information on the back of your cheque. A story is told of a woman who received a cheque from her husband, and when cashing it wrote "Your loving wife" above her name on the back.

V. BANK CHEQUES (Continued)

If you wish to draw money from your own account, the most approved form of cheque is written "Pay to the order of Cash." This differs from a cheque drawn to "Bearer." The paying teller expects to see yourself, or some one well known to him as your representative, when you write "Cash." If you write "Pay to the order of[13] (your own name)" you will be required to indorse your cheque before you can get it cashed.

If you want to withdraw money from your own account, the best way to write a check is "Pay to the order of Cash." This is different from a check made out to "Bearer." The teller will expect to see you, or someone he knows as your representative, when you write "Cash." If you write "Pay to the order of[13] (your own name)" you’ll need to sign your check before you can cash it.

If your note is due at your own bank and you wish to draw a cheque in payment, write "Pay to the order of Bills Payable." If you wish to write a cheque to draw money for wages, write "Pay to the order of Pay-roll." If you wish to write a cheque to pay for a draft which you are buying, write "Pay to the order of N. Y. Draft and Exchange," or whatever the circumstances may call for.

If your note is due at your bank and you want to write a check to pay it, write "Pay to the order of Bills Payable." If you want to write a check to get cash for wages, write "Pay to the order of Pay-roll." If you want to write a check to pay for a draft you're purchasing, write "Pay to the order of N. Y. Draft and Exchange," or whatever fits the situation.

A cheque made to obtain money for immediate use. A check written to get cash for immediate use.

If you wish to stop the payment of a cheque which you have issued you should notify the bank at once, giving full particulars.

If you want to stop the payment on a check you've written, you should immediately notify the bank with all the details.

Banks have a custom, after paying and charging cheques, of cancelling them by punching or making some cut through their face. These cancelled cheques are returned to the makers at the end of each month.

Banks have a practice of canceling checks after processing them by punching a hole or making a cut through the front. These canceled checks are sent back to the issuers at the end of each month.

If you have deposited a cheque and it is returned through your bank marked "No Funds," it signifies that the cheque is worthless and that the person upon whose account it was drawn has no funds to meet it. Your bank will charge the amount to your account. The best thing to[14] do in such a case is to hold the cheque as evidence of the debt, and write the person who sent it to you, giving particulars and asking for an explanation.

If you deposit a check and it gets returned by your bank marked "No Funds," it means that the check has no value and that the person who wrote it doesn't have enough money in their account to cover it. Your bank will deduct the amount from your account. The best thing to[14] do in this situation is to keep the check as proof of the debt, and write to the person who sent it to you, providing details and asking for an explanation.

If you wish to use your cheque to pay a note due at some other bank, or in buying real estate, or stocks, or bonds, you may find it necessary to get the cheque certified. This is done by an officer of the bank, who writes or stamps across the face of the cheque the words "Certified" or "Good When Properly Indorsed," and signs his name. (See illustration.) The amount will immediately be deducted from your account, and the bank, by guaranteeing your cheque, becomes responsible for its payment. Banks will usually certify any cheque drawn upon them if the depositor has the amount called for to his credit, no matter who presents the cheque, and this certifying makes it feasible for a man to carry in his pocket any amount of actual cash. If you should get a cheque certified and then not use it, deposit it in your bank, otherwise your account will be short the amount for which the cheque is drawn. In Canada all cheques are presented to the "ledger-keeper" for certification before being presented to the paying teller.

If you want to use your check to pay a bill at another bank, or for purchasing real estate, stocks, or bonds, you might need to have the check certified. This is done by a bank officer, who writes or stamps the words "Certified" or "Good When Properly Indorsed" across the front of the check and signs their name. (See illustration.) The amount will be immediately deducted from your account, and by guaranteeing your check, the bank takes responsibility for its payment. Banks typically certify any check drawn on them if the depositor has enough funds available, regardless of who presents the check, and this certification allows a person to carry around the equivalent of cash. If you have a check certified but then don't use it, deposit it in your bank; otherwise, your account will be short the amount of the check. In Canada, all checks are presented to the "ledger-keeper" for certification before being brought to the paying teller.

A certified cheque. __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__.

[15]THE USEFULNESS OF BANKS

Banks are absolutely necessary to the success of modern commercial enterprises. They provide a place for the safe-keeping of money and securities, and they make the payment of bills much more convenient than if currency instead of cheques were the more largely used. But the great advantage of a banking institution to a business man is the opportunity it affords him of borrowing money, of securing cash for the carrying on of his business while his own capital is locked up in merchandise or in the hands of his debtors. Another important advantage is to be found in the facilities afforded by banks for the collection of cheques, notes, and drafts.

Banks are essential for the success of modern businesses. They offer a secure place to keep money and investments, and they make paying bills much more convenient than relying solely on cash. However, the major benefit of a bank for a business owner is the ability to borrow money, allowing them to access cash to run their business while their own funds are tied up in inventory or owed by customers. Another significant advantage is the convenience banks provide in collecting checks, promissory notes, and drafts.

VI. BANK DRAFTS

A draft is a formal demand for the payment of money. Your bank cheque is your sight draft on your bank. It is not so stated, but it is so understood. A cheque differs from an ordinary commercial draft, both in its wording and in its purpose. The bank is obliged to pay your cheque if it holds funds of yours sufficient to meet it, while the person upon whom your draft is drawn may or may not honour it at his pleasure. A cheque is used for paying money to a creditor, while a draft is used as a means of collecting money from a debtor.

A draft is a formal request for payment. Your bank check acts as a sight draft on your bank. It might not be explicitly stated, but it's understood that way. A check is different from a regular commercial draft, both in its wording and intention. The bank must pay your check if it has enough of your funds to cover it, whereas the person who receives your draft can choose whether or not to honor it. A check is used to pay money to a creditor, while a draft is used to collect money from a debtor.

Nearly all large banks keep money on deposit with one or more of the banks located in the great commercial centres. They call these centrally located banks their correspondents. The larger banks have correspondents in New York, Chicago, Boston, and other large cities.[16] As business men keep money on deposit with banks to meet their cheques, so banks keep money on deposit with other banks to meet their drafts.

Nearly all large banks have funds deposited with one or more banks situated in major commercial centers. They refer to these centrally located banks as their correspondents. The bigger banks have correspondents in New York, Chicago, Boston, and other major cities.[16] Just as businesspeople maintain deposits with banks to cover their checks, banks keep deposits with other banks to cover their drafts.

A bank draft is simply the bank's cheque, drawn upon its deposit with some other bank. Banks sell these cheques to their customers, and merchants make large use of them in paying bills in distant cities. These drafts, or cashiers' cheques, as they are sometimes called, pass as cash anywhere within a reasonable distance of the money centre upon which they are drawn. Bankers' drafts on New York would, under ordinary financial conditions, be considered cash anywhere in the United States. A draft on a foreign bank is usually called a bill of exchange.

A bank transfer is basically a cheque from the bank, taken from its deposits with another bank. Banks sell these cheques to their customers, and merchants often use them to pay bills in different cities. These drafts, or cashier's checks, as they're sometimes referred to, are treated like cash anywhere within a reasonable distance of the money center they are drawn on. Bank drafts from New York would generally be considered cash anywhere in the United States under normal financial conditions. A draft from a foreign bank is usually called a bill of exchange.

A cheque for the purchase of a draft. A check for buying a draft.

Cheques have come to be quite generally used for the payment of bills even at long distances. If a business man desires to close an important contract requiring cash in advance he sends a bank draft, if at a distance, or a certified cheque, if in the same city. If he desires simply to pay a debt he sends his own personal cheque. Bank drafts are quite generally used by merchants in the West to pay bills in the East. A draft on New York[17] bought in San Francisco is cash when it reaches New York, while a San Francisco cheque is not cash until it returns and is cashed by the bank upon which it is drawn. In the ordinary course of business cheques are considered cash no matter upon what bank drawn. The bank receiving them on deposit gives the depositor credit at once, even though it may take a week before the value represented by the cheque is in the possession of the bank.

Checks are now widely used for paying bills, even over long distances. If a businessman wants to finalize an important contract that needs cash upfront, he’ll send a bank draft if he’s far away, or a certified check if he’s in the same city. If he just needs to pay a debt, he sends his personal check. Bank drafts are commonly used by merchants in the West to settle bills in the East. A draft on New York[17] purchased in San Francisco is considered cash when it arrives in New York, while a San Francisco check isn’t cash until it comes back and is cashed by the bank it’s drawn on. In regular business practice, checks are treated as cash no matter which bank they're from. The bank receiving them for deposit gives the depositor credit immediately, even though it might take a week for the funds represented by the check to actually reach the bank.

A bank draft. A bank check.

All wholesale transactions and a large proportion of retail transactions are completed by the passing of instruments of credit—notes, cheques, drafts, etc.; a part only of the retail trade is conducted by actual currency-bills and "change." Banks handle the bulk of these transferable titles and deal to a very small extent—that is, proportionally—in actual money. The notes, drafts, bills of exchange, and bank cheques are representative of the property passing by title in money from the producers to the consumers. A small proportion—perhaps six or eight per cent.—of these transactions is conducted by the use of actual bank or legal-tender notes. This trade in[18] instruments of credit amounts in the United States to fifty billions of dollars yearly.

All wholesale transactions and a large portion of retail transactions are handled through credit instruments—such as notes, checks, drafts, etc. Only a small part of retail trade is carried out using physical currency bills and "change." Banks manage the majority of these transferable instruments and only deal minimally—in relative terms—in actual cash. The notes, drafts, bills of exchange, and bank checks represent the property being transferred in money from producers to consumers. A small percentage—about six to eight percent—of these transactions occur using actual banknotes or legal tender. This trade in [18] credit instruments amounts to fifty billion dollars annually in the United States.

VII. PROMISSORY NOTES

Ordinary form of promissory note. Standard promissory note.

A promissory note is a written promise to pay a specified sum of money. At the time of the note's issue—that is, when signed and delivered—two parties are connected with it, the maker and the payee. The maker is the person who signs or promises to pay the note; the payee is the person to whom or to whose order the note is made payable. Negotiable in a commercial sense means transferable, and a negotiable note is a note which can be transferred from one person to another. A note to be made negotiable must contain the word bearer or the word order—that is, it must be payable either to bearer, or to the order of the payee. A non-negotiable note is payable to a particular person only. A note may be written on any[19] kind of paper, in ink or pencil. It is wise, however, to use ink to prevent changes. All stationers sell blank forms for notes which are easily filled in.

A IOU is a written promise to pay a specific amount of money. When the note is issued—meaning when it’s signed and handed over—there are two parties involved: the maker and the payee. The maker is the person who signs or promises to pay the note; the payee is the person to whom the note is payable. Open to negotiation, in a business context, means transferable, and a negotiable note is one that can be transferred from one person to another. For a note to be negotiable, it must include the word bearer or order—meaning it must be payable either to bearer or to the order of the payee. A non-negotiable note is payable to a specific person only. A note can be written on any[19] type of paper, in ink or pencil. However, it’s best to use ink to avoid changes. All stationery stores sell blank forms for notes that are easy to fill out.

The samples of notes which appear in this lesson are selected simply to illustrate to students the fact that there are a great many special forms of notes in common use. The wording differs slightly in different States.

The notes provided in this lesson are chosen just to show students that there are many special types of notes commonly used. The wording varies a bit from one state to another.

The date of a note is a matter of the first importance. Some bankers and business men consider it better to draw notes payable at a certain fixed time, as, "I promise to pay on the 10th of March, 1897." The common custom is to make notes payable a certain number of days or months after date. A note made or issued on Sunday is void. The day of maturity is the day upon which a note becomes legally due. In several of the States a note is not legally due until three days, called days of grace, after the expiration of the time specified in the note.

The date on a note is extremely important. Some bankers and business people believe it's better to create notes that are payable at a specific date, like, "I promise to pay on March 10, 1897." The usual practice is to make notes payable a certain number of days or months after the date. A note created or issued on a Sunday is invalid. The maturity day is the day when a note is legally due. In several States, a note isn't considered legally due until three days later, known as grace period, after the time specified in the note.

A promissory note filled out on an engraved blank. A promissory note completed on a printed blank form.

The words value received, which usually appear upon notes, are not necessary legally. Thousands of good notes made without any value consideration are handled daily.

The phrase value received, which typically appears on notes, isn't legally required. Every day, thousands of valid notes are processed without any consideration of value.

[20]The promise to pay of a negotiable note must be unconditional. It cannot be made to depend upon any contingency whatever.

[20]The pay promise of a negotiable note has to be unconditional. It can't be tied to any kind of condition.

Notes that are made in settlement of genuine business transactions come under the head of regular, legitimate business paper. An accommodation note is one which is signed, or indorsed, simply as an accommodation, and not in settlement of an account or in payment of an indebtedness. With banks accommodation paper has a deservedly hard reputation. However, there are all grades and shades of accommodation paper, though it represents no actual business transaction between the parties to it, and rests upon no other foundation than that of mutual agreement. No contract is good without a consideration, but this is only true between the original parties to a note. The third party or innocent receiver or holder of a note has a good title, and can recover its value, even though it was originally given without a valuable consideration. An innocent holder of a note which had been originally lost or stolen has a good title to it if he received it for value.

Notes made in the settlement of genuine business transactions fall under the category of regular, legitimate business instruments. An housing note is one that is signed or endorsed simply as a favor, and not as a means to settle an account or pay off a debt. In the banking world, accommodation paper has a deservedly bad reputation. However, there are various types of accommodation paper, even though it does not reflect any actual business transaction between the parties involved and is based solely on mutual agreement. No contract is valid without consideration, but this only applies to the original parties to a note. A third party or innocent holder of a note has a legal right to it and can claim its value, even if it was initially issued without valuable consideration. An innocent holder of a note that was originally lost or stolen has a valid title to it if they received it for value.

A special form for a promissory note. A specific format for a promissory note.

[21]A note does not draw interest until after maturity, unless the words with interest appear on the face. Notes draw interest after maturity and until paid, at the legal rate.

[21]A note doesn’t earn interest until after it matures, unless it says with interest on the front. Notes earn interest after maturity and until they’re paid, at the legal rate.

A note should be presented for payment upon the exact day of maturity. Notes made payable at a bank, or at any other place, must be presented for payment at the place named. When no place is specified the note is payable at the maker's place of business or at his residence.

A note should be presented for payment on the exact due date. Notes that are payable at a bank or any other location must be presented for payment at the specified place. If no place is mentioned, the note is payable at the maker's business address or at their home.

In finding the date of maturity it is important to remember that when a note is drawn days after date the actual days must be counted, and when drawn months after date the time is reckoned by months.

In determining the date of maturity, it's important to remember that when a note is written days after date, the actual days must be counted, and when written months after date, the time is calculated by months.

To discount a note is to sell it at a discount. The rates of discount vary according to the security offered, or the character of the loan, or the state of the money market. For ordinary commercial paper the rates run from four to eight per cent. Notes received and given by commercial houses and discounted by banks are not usually for a longer period than four months.

To sale a note means to sell it for less than its face value. The discount rates depend on the security provided, the nature of the loan, or the current conditions of the money market. For typical commercial paper, the rates range from four to eight percent. Notes that commercial businesses issue and receive, which are then discounted by banks, usually have a duration of no more than four months.

VIII. THE CLEARING-HOUSE SYSTEM

In large cities cheques representing millions of dollars are deposited in the banks every day. The separate collection of these would be almost impossible were it not for the clearing-house system. Each large city has its clearing-house. It is an establishment formed by the banks themselves, and for their own convenience. The leading banks of a city connect themselves with the clearing-house of that city, and through other banks with the clearing-houses of other cities, particularly New York. Country banks connect themselves with one or more clearing-houses through city banks, which do their[22] business for them. The New York banks, largely through private bankers, branches of foreign banking houses, connect themselves with London, so that each bank in the world is connected indirectly with every other bank in the world, and in London is the final clearing-house of the world.

In big cities, millions of dollars in checks are deposited in banks every day. Collecting these individually would be nearly impossible without the clearing-house system. Each major city has its own clearing-house, set up by the banks for their convenience. The leading banks in a city connect with that city's clearing-house and, through other banks, with the clearing-houses of other cities, especially New York. Rural banks connect to one or more clearing-houses through city banks that handle their[22] business. The New York banks, mainly through private bankers and branches of foreign banks, connect with London, making it so that each bank in the world is indirectly linked to every other bank, with London serving as the ultimate clearing-house globally.

The advantages of the clearing-house system. The benefits of the clearing-house system.

Suppose that the above diagram represents the banks and clearing-house of a city, and also the two business houses of Brown and Smith. Brown keeps his money on deposit in Bank E, and Smith in Bank B. Brown sends (by mail) a cheque to Smith in payment of a bill. Now, Smith can come all the way to Bank E, and, if he is properly identified, can collect the cheque. He does not do this, however, but deposits Brown's cheque in[23] Bank B, the bank where he does his banking business. Now, B cannot send to E to get the money. It could do this, perhaps, if it had only one cheque, but it has taken in hundreds of cheques, some, perhaps, on every bank in town, and on many banks out of town. It would take a hundred messengers to collect them. So, instead of B's going to E, they meet half-way, or at a central point called a clearing-house, and there collect their cheques. B may have $5000 in cheques on E, and E may have $4000 in cheques on B, so that the exchange can be made—that is, the cheques can be paid by E paying the difference of $1000, which is done, not direct, but through the officers of the clearing-house. Now Bank E's messenger carries Brown's cheque back with him and enters it up against Brown's account. This in simple language is the primary idea of the clearing-house.

Suppose the diagram above represents the banks and clearinghouse of a city, as well as the two businesses of Brown and Smith. Brown has his money deposited in Bank E, and Smith in Bank B. Brown sends a check to Smith by mail to pay a bill. Instead of traveling all the way to Bank E to cash the check—if he can prove his identity—Smith decides to deposit Brown's check at Bank B, where he usually banks. Bank B can't just send someone to Bank E to collect the money. It might manage this if it only had one check, but it's taken in hundreds of checks, some from every bank in town and even from many banks outside of it. It would take a hundred messengers to collect them all. So, instead of Bank B going to Bank E, they meet halfway, at a central location called a clearinghouse, to settle their checks. Bank B might have $5,000 in checks from Bank E, and Bank E could have $4,000 in checks from Bank B, allowing for an exchange. This means Bank E can clear the checks by simply paying the $1,000 difference, done indirectly through the clearinghouse officers. Then, the messenger from Bank E takes Brown's check back with him and credits it to Brown's account. This is basically the main idea of the clearinghouse.

The clearings in New York in one day amount to from one to two hundred millions of dollars. By clearings we mean the value of the cheques which are cleared—that is, which change hands through the clearing-house. Usually once a week (in some cities oftener) the banks of a city make to their clearing-house a report, based on daily balances, of their condition.

The clearings in New York in one day total between one and two hundred million dollars. By clearings, we mean the value of the checks that are cleared—that is, those that are processed through the clearing-house. Typically, once a week (and sometimes more often in certain cities), the banks in a city submit a report to their clearing-house, based on daily balances, regarding their status.

The route of a cheque. The process of a cheque.

To illustrate the connection between banks at distant points let us suppose that B of Media, Pennsylvania, who keeps his money on deposit in the First National Bank of Media, sends a cheque in payment of a bill to K of South Evanston, Illinois. K deposits the cheque in the Citizens Bank of his town and receives immediate credit for it upon his bank-book, just the same as though the cheque were drawn upon the same or a near-by bank. The Citizens Bank simply sends the cheque, with other distant cheques, to its correspondent, the National Bank of the Republic, Chicago, on deposit, in many instances in about the same sense that K deposited the cheque in the Citizens Bank. The National Bank of the Republic sends the cheque, with other cheques, to its New York correspondent, the National Park Bank. It may possibly send to Philadelphia direct, or even to Media; but this is very unlikely. The National Park Bank sends the cheque to its Philadelphia correspondent, say the Penn National Bank. Now the clearing-house clerk of the Penn National carries the cheque to the Philadelphia clearing-house and enters it, with other cheques, on the First National of Media. Custom, however, differs very greatly in this particular. Many near-by country banks clear through city banks; others clear less directly. If the First National Bank of Philadelphia is known at the clearing-house as the representative of the First National Bank of Media it likely has money belonging to this Media bank on deposit. In that case the cheque is charged up against the account of the First National of Philadelphia. This bank then sends the cheque to the First National of Media, by which it is charged up against B. This system of collection of cheques is about as perfect as is the post-office system of carrying registered mail.

To show how banks at different locations are connected, let’s imagine that B from Media, Pennsylvania, who has his money deposited at the First National Bank of Media, sends a check to K in South Evanston, Illinois, to pay a bill. K deposits the check at his local Citizens Bank and gets immediate credit in his bank account, just like if the check was drawn from the same bank or one nearby. The Citizens Bank then forwards the check, along with other checks from far away, to its partner, the National Bank of the Republic in Chicago, essentially in the same way K deposited it at his bank. The National Bank of the Republic sends the check, along with others, to its New York partner, the National Park Bank. It might send it directly to Philadelphia or even back to Media, but that's not very likely. The National Park Bank then sends the check to its Philadelphia partner, like the Penn National Bank. The clerk at the Penn National takes the check to the Philadelphia clearinghouse and processes it with other checks for the First National Bank of Media. However, practices in this area can vary widely. Some nearby rural banks clear transactions through city banks, while others take a more indirect approach. If the First National Bank of Philadelphia is recognized at the clearinghouse as the representative bank for the First National Bank of Media, it likely has funds from Media's bank on deposit. In that case, the check is deducted from the account of the First National Bank of Philadelphia. Then, this bank sends the check to the First National Bank of Media, which charges it to B’s account. This system for collecting checks is nearly as efficient as the post office's method for handling registered mail.

Backs of two paid cheques. Backs of two paid checks.

[26]Now, the banks and clearing-houses through which the cheque passes on its way home stamp their indorsements and other information upon the back. Our illustration shows the backs of two cheques which have "travelled." Millions of dollars are collected by banks daily in this way, and all without expense to their customers. It is estimated that these collections cost the New York City banks more than two million dollars a year in loss of interest while the cheques are en route. Ten thousand collection letters are sent out daily by the banks of New York City alone.

[26]Now, the banks and clearinghouses that process the cheque on its way home stamp their endorsements and other details on the back. Our illustration shows the backs of two cheques that have "travelled." Millions of dollars are collected by banks every day this way, all at no cost to their customers. It's estimated that these collections cost New York City banks over two million dollars a year in lost interest while the cheques are in transit. Ten thousand collection letters are sent out daily by the banks in New York City alone.

IX. COMMERCIAL DRAFTS

A commercial draft bears a close resemblance to a letter from one person to another requesting that a certain sum of money be paid to the person who calls, or to the bank or firm for whom he is acting. For instance, the draft shown in the first illustration might be worded something like this:[27]

A commercial invoice looks a lot like a letter from one person to another asking for a specific amount of money to be paid to the person making the request or to the bank or company they represent. For example, the draft displayed in the first illustration could be written like this:[27]

St. Louis, Mo., Feb. 22, 1899.

St. Louis, MO, Feb. 22, 1899.

Mr. Robert Elsmere,

Mr. Robert Elsmere,

Jefferson City, Mo.

Jefferson City, MO

My dear Sir:

Dear Sir:

Will you kindly pay to the messenger from the —— Bank who will call to-morrow the sum of three hundred and ninety-seven dollars and charge to my account?

Could you please pay the messenger from the Sure, please provide the text you'd like me to modernize. Bank who will come tomorrow the amount of three hundred and ninety-seven dollars and charge it to my account?

Yours, very truly,

Best regards,

David Grieve.

David Grieve.

A sight draft developed from the above letter. A sight draft created from the letter above.

Commercial usage, however, recognises a particular form in which this letter is to be written, and the address of the person for whom it is intended is usually written at the lower left-hand corner instead of on an envelope. Commercial drafts usually reach the persons upon whom they are drawn through the medium of the banks rather than directly by mail. Let us illustrate. Suppose that A of Chicago owes B of Buffalo $200, and B desires to collect the amount by means of a draft. He fills in a blank draft, signs it, and addresses it on the[28] lower left-hand corner to A. Instead of sending it by mail he takes it to his bank—that is, deposits it for collection. It will reach a Chicago bank in about the same way that cheques for collection go from one place to another. A messenger from the Chicago bank will carry the draft to A's office and present it for payment or for acceptance. If it is a sight draft—that is, a draft payable when A sees it—he may give cash for it at once and take the draft as his receipt. If he has not the money convenient he may write across the face "Accepted, payable at (his) Bank," as in the illustration. It will then reach his bank and be paid as his personal cheque would be, and should be entered in his cheque-book. Banks usually give one day upon sight drafts. The draft will not be presented a second time, but will be held at the bank until the close of the banking hours the next day, where A can call to pay if he chooses. Leniency in the matter of time will depend largely upon B's instructions and the bank's attitude toward A. If the draft is a time draft—that is, if B gives A time, a certain number of days, in which to pay it—A, if he wishes to pay the draft, accepts it. He does this by writing the word accepted with the date and his signature across the face of the draft. He may make it payable at his bank as he would a note, if he so desires. He then returns the draft to the messenger, and if the time is long the draft is returned to B; if only a few days, the bank holds it for collection.

Commercial usage, however, specifies a particular format for this letter, and the address of the person it’s intended for is usually written in the lower left-hand corner instead of on an envelope. Commercial drafts typically reach the parties they’re drawn on through banks rather than directly by mail. Let’s illustrate. Suppose A in Chicago owes B in Buffalo $200, and B wants to collect that amount via a draft. He fills out a blank draft, signs it, and addresses it in the[28] lower left-hand corner to A. Instead of mailing it, he takes it to his bank—meaning he deposits it for collection. It will get to a Chicago bank in a similar way that cheques for collection travel from one place to another. A messenger from the Chicago bank will carry the draft to A's office and present it for payment or acceptance. If it’s a sight draft—that is, a draft payable when A sees it—he might pay cash for it right away and take the draft as his receipt. If he doesn’t have the cash on hand, he might write across the face "Accepted, payable at (his) Bank," like in the illustration. It will then go to his bank and be paid just like his personal cheque would be, and he should record it in his cheque book. Banks usually allow one day for sight drafts. The draft won’t be presented a second time but will be kept at the bank until the end of banking hours the next day, where A can go to pay if he wants. Any leniency regarding time will largely depend on B's instructions and the bank's view of A. If the draft is a time draft—that is, if B gives A a certain number of days to pay—it means A needs to accept it if he wants to pay. He does this by writing the word accepted with the date and his signature across the front of the draft. He can make it payable at his bank as he would a note if he wishes. He then gives the draft back to the messenger, and if the time frame is long, the draft is sent back to B; if it’s only a few days, the bank holds it for collection.

No. 1. A sight draft. A sight draft.
No. 2. An accepted ten-day sight draft. No. 2. A ten-day sight draft that has been accepted.
No. 3. An accepted sight draft. No. 3. An accepted sight draft.
No. 4. A time draft. No. 4. A time draft.

[30]An accepted draft is really a promissory note, though it is more often called an acceptance. When a man pays or accepts a draft he is said to honour it. In the foregoing illustration A is not obliged either to pay or to accept the draft. It is not binding upon him any more than a letter would be. He can refuse payment just as easily and as readily as he could decline to pay a collector who calls for payment of a bill. Of course, if a man habitually refuses to honour legitimate drafts it may injure his credit with banks and business houses.

[30]An accepted draft is basically a promissory note, although it's more commonly referred to as an acceptance. When someone pays or accepts a draft, it's said that they honour it. In the previous example, A is not required to pay or accept the draft. It's not binding on him any more than a letter would be. He can refuse to pay just as easily as he could turn down a collector asking for payment of a bill. However, if someone consistently refuses to honour legitimate drafts, it could hurt their credit with banks and businesses.

It is a very common thing to collect distant accounts by means of commercial drafts. A debtor is more likely to meet—that is, to pay—a draft than he is to reply to a letter and inclose his cheque. It is really more convenient, and safer, too, for there is some risk in sending personal cheques through the mail. There are some houses that make all their payments by cheques, while there are others which prefer to have their creditors at a distance draw on them for the amounts due.

It’s quite common to collect payments from far away using commercial drafts. A debtor is more likely to pay a draft than to respond to a letter and include a check. It’s actually more convenient and safer, as sending personal checks through the mail carries some risk. Some companies handle all their payments by checks, while others prefer to let their creditors draw on them for what’s owed.

If a business man who has been accustomed to honour drafts continues for a period to dishonour them, the banks through which the drafts pass naturally conclude that he is unable to meet his liabilities.

If a businessman who is used to honoring drafts suddenly starts dishonoring them for a while, the banks handling those drafts will naturally assume he can't meet his obligations.

Some houses deposit their drafts for collection in their[31] home banks, while others have a custom of sending them direct to some bank in or near the place where the debtor resides. If the place is a very small one the collection is sometimes made through one of the express companies.

Some companies send their drafts for collection to their[31] home banks, while others prefer to send them directly to a bank in or near where the debtor lives. In very small towns, collection is sometimes handled by one of the express companies.

When goods are sold for distinct periods of credit, and it is generally understood that maturing accounts are subject to sight drafts, there should be no need of notifying the debtor in advance. Some houses, however, make a general custom of sending notices ten days in advance, stating that a draft will be drawn if cheque is not received in the meantime.

When items are sold on credit for specific time periods, and it's commonly understood that due accounts are subject to sight drafts, there shouldn't be a need to notify the debtor beforehand. Some businesses, however, have a standard practice of sending notices ten days in advance, indicating that a draft will be issued if payment isn't received in the meantime.

Notice the illustrations. The protest notice at the left of Nos. 1, 2, and 4 is intended for the bank presenting the draft for payment. The reason for this will be fully explained in our lesson on protested paper. (See Lesson XIII.) No. 2 shows an accepted draft payable to the order of a bank in the city upon which it is drawn. No. 1 is payable to the order of a bank in the city of the drawer. No. 3 is a sight draft payable to the order of a bank and accepted payable at a bank. No. 4 is a time draft payable to "ourselves"—that is, the Pennsylvania Steel Company.

Notice the illustrations. The protest notice on the left of Nos. 1, 2, and 4 is meant for the bank presenting the draft for payment. The reason for this will be fully explained in our lesson on protested paper. (See Lesson 13.) No. 2 shows an accepted draft payable to the order of a bank in the city where it is drawn. No. 1 is payable to the order of a bank in the drawer’s city. No. 3 is a sight draft payable to the order of a bank and accepted for payment at a bank. No. 4 is a time draft payable to "ourselves"—that is, the Pennsylvania Steel Company.

Drafts are often discounted at banks before acceptance where the credit of the drawer is good. In such cases the drafts which are dishonoured are charged up against the drawer's account.

Drafts are often ignored at banks before they’re accepted if the drawer's credit is solid. In these situations, the drafts that are rejected are charged to the drawer's account.

X. FOREIGN EXCHANGE

It is quite in order that we should follow lessons on the clearing-house and commercial drafts with a lesson on foreign exchange.

It makes sense for us to follow lessons on the clearinghouse and business drafts with a lesson on foreign exchange.

We learned in the last lesson that commercial drafts are made use of to facilitate the collection of accounts.[32] They are simply formal demands for the payment of legitimate debts. When these formal demands are made upon foreign debtors they are called bills of exchange; and the process of buying and selling these drafts, the drafts themselves, and the fluctuations in price, all are included in the general name exchange.

We learned in the last lesson that commercial drafts are used to help collect accounts.[32] They are basically formal requests for the payment of valid debts. When these formal requests are made to foreign debtors, they are called bills of exchange; and the process of buying and selling these drafts, the drafts themselves, and the price changes, are all included under the general term exchange.

Foreign exchange. Currency exchange.

To illustrate the principles of exchange let us suppose that the following transactions have occurred:

To show how the principles of exchange work, let's say that these transactions have taken place:

  1. C of Boston has sold goods, £2000, to H of Hamburg.
  2. D of Chicago has sold goods, £5000, to F of Glasgow.
  3. M of Chicago has sold goods, £3000, to K of London.
  4. E of Philadelphia has sold goods, £6000, to R of Paris.
  5. P of New York has sold goods, £1000, to G of Paris.

C draws on H for £2000, sells the draft to a banking-house in Boston; they send to Bank A of New York, and[33] the New York bank to their London correspondent, say Bank B, with instructions to collect from Hamburg.

C takes a loan from H for £2000, sells the draft to a bank in Boston; they send it to Bank A in New York, and[33] the New York bank to their London correspondent, let's say Bank B, with orders to collect from Hamburg.

D draws in a similar way on F. E draws on R, and P on G. Suppose that M instead of drawing on K receives a draft drawn by Bank B of London on Bank A of New York, payable to M's order.

D draws in a similar way on F. E draws on R, and P on G. Suppose that M, instead of drawing on K, receives a draft drawn by Bank B of London on Bank A of New York, payable to M's order.

America has sold goods worth £17,000 to Europe.

U.S. has sold products valued at £17,000 to Europe.

Europe . . . . . . owes £17,000 to . . . . . America

Europe . . . . . . owes £17,000 to . . . . . USA

But B has paid A £3000.

But B has paid A £3,000.

____________

____________

B . . . . . . therefore owes £14,000 to . . . . . . A

B . . . . . . therefore owes £14,000 to . . . . . . A

Now it will cost B a considerable sum of money to ship £14,000 in gold to A, for all exchanges between Europe and America are payable in gold. Suppose that S of New York owes T of London £14,000, and T draws on S and takes the draft to Bank B in London and offers it for sale. Will B offer more or less than £14,000 for the bill of exchange or draft? He will offer more. It will be cheaper for him to pay a premium for the draft than to ship gold, for he can send this draft to Bank A to pay his indebtedness, and A can collect from S.

Now it will cost B a significant amount of money to ship £14,000 in gold to A, since all transactions between Europe and America are done in gold. Let’s say S in New York owes T in London £14,000. If T draws a draft on S and takes it to Bank B in London to sell it, will B offer more or less than £14,000 for that draft? He will offer more. It will be cheaper for him to pay a premium for the draft than to ship gold, because he can send this draft to Bank A to settle his debt, and A can collect from S.

In the money market in New York there is a constant supply of exchanges (drafts) on London, and in London a constant supply of exchanges on New York.

In the New York money market, there's a steady supply of exchanges (drafts) on London, and in London, there's a steady supply of exchanges on New York.

Experience has shown that at all times the number of persons in Europe indebted to American business houses is about (though of course not actually) the same as the number of persons in America indebted to European houses. Hence when A of New York wishes to make a payment to B of London he does not send the actual money, but goes into the market—that is, to a banker doing a foreign business—and buys a draft, called a bill of exchange, which is in reality the banker's order on his London correspondent, asking the latter to pay the money to the person named. It may be that[34] about the same time some London merchant who owes money in New York goes to the very same London banker and buys a draft on the New York bank. In this way the one draft cancels the other, and when there is a difference at the end of the week or month the actual gold is sent across to balance the account.

Experience has shown that at any given time, the number of people in Europe who owe money to American businesses is roughly (though not precisely) the same as the number of people in America who owe money to European businesses. So, when A from New York wants to pay B in London, he doesn’t send actual cash; instead, he goes to the market—specifically, a banker that deals in foreign transactions—and buys a draft, known as a bill of exchange. This is essentially the banker's request to his London counterpart to pay the specified amount to the named individual. Meanwhile, it’s possible that around the same time, some merchant in London who owes money in New York heads to that same London banker and purchases a draft for the New York bank. In this way, one draft offsets the other, and any difference at the end of the week or month is settled by sending gold across to balance the account.

These exchanges have a sort of commodity value, and like all commodities, depend upon the law of supply and demand. When gold is being shipped abroad we say that the balance of trade is against us—that is, we are buying more from Europe than Europe is buying from us, and the gold is shipped to pay the balance or difference.

These exchanges have a kind of commodity value, and like all commodities, they rely on the law of supply and demand. When gold is being sent overseas, we say that the balance of trade is unfavorable for us—that is, we’re buying more from Europe than Europe is buying from us, and the gold is sent to settle the balance or difference.

The par of the currency of any two countries means, among merchants, the equivalency of a certain amount of the (coin) currency of the one in the (coin) currency of the other, supposing the currencies of both to be of the precise weight and purity fixed by the respective mints. The par of exchange between Great Britain and the United States is 4.8623; that is, £1 sterling is worth $4.8623. Exchange is quoted daily in New York and other city papers at 4.87, 4.88, 4.88½, etc., for sight bills and at a higher rate for sixty-day bills. Business men who are accustomed to watching fluctuations in exchange rates use the quotations as a sort of barometer to foretell trade conditions. The imports and exports of bullion (uncoined gold) are the real test of exchange. If bullion is stationary, flowing neither into nor out of a country, its exchanges may be truly said to be at par; and on the other hand, if bullion is being exported from a country, it is a proof that the exchange is against it; and conversely if there be large importations.

The par of the currency of any two countries refers to, among traders, the equivalency of a certain amount of one country's currency in the currency of the other, assuming both currencies are of the exact weight and purity set by their respective mints. The par of exchange between Great Britain and the United States is 4.8623; that is, £1 sterling is worth $4.8623. Exchange rates are quoted daily in New York and various city papers at 4.87, 4.88, 4.88½, etc., for sight bills, and at a higher rate for sixty-day bills. Businesspeople who keep an eye on changes in exchange rates use these quotes as a way to predict trade conditions. The imports and exports of bullion (uncoined gold) are the real indicators of exchange. If bullion remains steady, not flowing into or out of a country, its exchanges can be said to be at par; on the other hand, if bullion is being exported from a country, it indicates that the exchange is unfavorable for that country; similarly, large imports suggest the opposite.

The cost of conveying bullion from one country to another forms the limit within which the rise and fall of the real exchange between them must be confined. If, for illustration, a New York merchant owes a debt in[35] London and exchange costs him, say, two per cent., and the cost of shipping the gold is only one per cent., it will be to his advantage to pay the debt by sending the actual coin across. A favourable real exchange operates as a duty on exportation and as a bounty on importation.

The cost of sending gold from one country to another sets the boundaries for how much the actual exchange rate between them can change. For example, if a merchant in New York owes a debt in[35] London and the exchange rate costs him about two percent, while shipping the gold only costs one percent, it would be better for him to pay the debt by actually sending the gold. A favorable actual exchange acts like a tax on exports and a bonus on imports.

A bill of exchange (private). A bill of exchange (private). A private bill of exchange.

It is to the interest of merchants or bankers who deal[36] in foreign bills to buy them where they are the cheapest and to sell them where they are the dearest. For this reason it might often be an advantage for a New York merchant to buy a bill on London to pay a debt in Paris.

It benefits merchants or bankers who deal[36] in foreign bills to buy them where they are the cheapest and sell them where they are the most expensive. For this reason, it can often be advantageous for a New York merchant to buy a bill on London to settle a debt in Paris.

A bill of exchange (banker's). A bill of exchange (banker's). A banker's bill of exchange.

Two illustrations of bills of exchange are given in this lesson. Each is drawn in duplicate. The original is sold[37] or sent abroad, while the duplicate is preserved as a safeguard against the loss of the original. When one is paid the other is of no value. Notice the similarity between bills of exchange as shown here and commercial drafts as shown in our last lesson.

Two examples of bills of exchange are provided in this lesson. Each one comes in two copies. The original is sold[37] or sent overseas, while the duplicate is kept as a backup in case the original is lost. When one is paid, the other holds no value. Notice the similarity between the bills of exchange shown here and the commercial drafts we discussed in our last lesson.

The first form shows a draft made by a coal company upon a steamship company to pay for coal supplied to a particular steamer. Suppose that the steamship company has a contract with Robert Hare Powel & Co. of Philadelphia to supply coal to their steamers. The steamer Cardiff, when in port at Philadelphia, is supplied; the bill is certified to by the engineer; the master (captain) of the vessel signs Powel & Co.'s draft (and in doing this really makes it the captain's draft); the bill is receipted. Now Powel & Co. sell this exchange (draft) on London to a broker or banker doing a foreign business. It is forwarded to London and presented in due time at the office of the Wales Navigation Company for payment.

The first form shows a draft created by a coal company for a steamship company to cover the cost of coal provided to a specific steamer. Let's say the steamship company has an agreement with Robert Hare Powel & Co. of Philadelphia to supply coal for their steamers. The steamer Cardiff, while docked in Philadelphia, is refueled; the engineer certifies the bill; the master (captain) of the ship signs Powel & Co.'s draft (which essentially makes it the captain's draft); and the bill is receipted. Now, Powel & Co. sells this draft in London to a broker or banker involved in foreign trade. It is sent to London and presented at the office of the Wales Navigation Company for payment at the appropriate time.

The second form shows a bill of exchange drawn by a Philadelphia banking house upon a London banking house and payable to the order of the firm buying the draft. C. H. Bannerman & Co. will send this bill (the original) to pay an account in Europe. The first form bears the same relation to a commercial draft that the second does to a cashier's cheque.

The second form displays a bill of exchange issued by a Philadelphia bank to a London bank, made payable to the firm purchasing the draft. C. H. Bannerman & Co. will send this bill (the original) to settle an account in Europe. The first form is related to a commercial draft in the same way that the second form relates to a cashier's check.

First page of a letter of credit. First page of a letter of credit.

XI. LETTERS OF CREDIT

The usual instruments of credit by means of which travellers abroad draw upon their deposits at home are known as circular letters of credit. These forms of credit are of such common use that every one should be familiar with their form. We reproduce here a facsimile[39] of the first and second pages of a circular letter for £1000, copied with slight change of names from an actual instrument. The first page shows the credit proper authorising the various correspondents of the bank issuing it to pay the holder, whose signature is given on its face, money to the extent of £1000. The names of the banks who are authorised to advance money upon the letter are usually printed upon the third and fourth pages, though letters issued by well-known banking houses are usually recognised by any banking house to which they are presented.

The common types of credit that travelers use abroad to access their funds at home are called circular letters of credit. These credit forms are so widely used that everyone should know what they look like. We include a facsimile[39] of the first and second pages of a circular letter for £1000, slightly altered from an actual document. The first page displays the credit itself, authorizing the various correspondents of the issuing bank to pay the holder, whose signature appears on it, up to £1000. The names of the banks authorized to disburse funds based on the letter are typically printed on the third and fourth pages, although letters issued by reputable banking institutions are usually accepted by any bank they are presented to.

The second illustration shows how the holder of a particular letter availed himself of its advantages. It gives the names of the banks to which he presented his letter, and the amounts paid by each.

The second illustration shows how the holder of a particular letter took advantage of it. It lists the names of the banks where he presented his letter and the amounts paid by each.

With such a letter a traveller could make a trip around the world and not have in his pocket at any one time more gold or silver or bills than would be necessary to meet immediate expenses.

With such a letter, a traveler could take a trip around the world and not carry more gold, silver, or cash than what was needed for immediate expenses.

Suppose that A. B. is about to make a European trip. He goes to a bank doing a foreign business, say Brown Bros. & Co. of New York City, and asks for a circular letter for £1000, for which he is obliged to pay about $4880. Copies of A. B.'s signature are left with Brown Bros. & Co., and may perhaps be forwarded to their foreign banking houses. When A. B. presents himself at a Glasgow or Paris bank with his letter of credit, and asks for a payment upon it, the banker asks him to sign a draft on Brown Bros. & Co., New York, or more likely on their London bank, for the amount required, which amount is immediately indorsed on the second page of the letter of credit, so that when the indorsements equal the face the letter is fully paid. A. B. is simply drawing upon his own account—that is, upon the money he deposited to secure the letter of credit.

Suppose A. B. is about to take a trip to Europe. He goes to a bank that handles foreign business, like Brown Bros. & Co. in New York City, and requests a circular letter for £1000, for which he has to pay around $4880. A. B. leaves copies of his signature with Brown Bros. & Co., which may be sent to their foreign banking branches. When A. B. goes to a bank in Glasgow or Paris with his letter of credit and requests a payment, the banker asks him to sign a draft on Brown Bros. & Co., New York, or more likely on their London branch, for the amount he needs. That amount is then recorded on the second page of the letter of credit, so once the endorsements reach the total amount, the letter is fully paid. A. B. is simply withdrawing from his own account—that is, the money he deposited to secure the letter of credit.

[40]Payment is usually made upon the simple identification or comparison of signatures. If a traveller should lose his letter of credit he should notify at once the bank issuing it and, if possible, the banks upon which drawn.

[40]Payment is typically made upon just identifying or matching signatures. If a traveler loses their letter of credit, they should immediately inform the bank that issued it and, if possible, the banks it’s drawn on.

Second page of a letter of credit (used). Second page of a letter of credit (used).

There are several other forms of travellers' credits in use. The Cheque Bank, an English institution with a branch in New York City, issues to travellers a book of cheques, each of which can be filled up only to a limited[41] amount, as shown by printed and perforated notices appearing on the face. For instance, for £100 one can buy a cheque-book containing fifty blank cheques, each good, when properly filled up, for £2. Each of these cheques is really a certified cheque, only it is certified in advance of issue. Any of the thousand or more foreign banks which are agents for the Cheque Bank sell these cheque-books, and cash the cheques when presented. The amounts that may be short drawn go toward the cost of a new cheque-book, or may be returned in cash. The American and other express companies have forms of travellers' cheque-books very similar to those issued by the Cheque Bank.

There are several other types of travelers' checks available. The Cheque Bank, a British institution with a branch in New York City, provides travelers with a checkbook, where each check can only be filled out for a limited[41] amount, as indicated by printed and perforated notices on the front. For example, for £100, you can buy a checkbook that contains fifty blank checks, each valid for £2 when filled out correctly. Each of these checks is essentially a certified check, except it’s certified before it is issued. Any of the thousand or more foreign banks that are agents for the Cheque Bank sell these checkbooks and cash the checks when presented. The amounts that aren’t fully used contribute to the cost of a new checkbook or can be refunded in cash. American and other express companies offer traveler checkbooks that are very similar to those from the Cheque Bank.

XII. JOINT-STOCK COMPANIES

To organise a stock company it is necessary for a number of persons to come together and make a certificate to the effect that they propose to form a company to bear a certain name, for the purpose of transacting a certain kind of business at a certain place. The certificate states that they propose to issue a certain number of shares of stock at a certain price per share, that the capital stock is to be a certain amount, and that the company is to continue to exist for a definite period of time. Blank forms for such certificate are supplied by the Secretary of the State where the company is being organised, and when such certificate is properly filled out, signed, and delivered to him, he issues a license, or charter, to the persons making such certificate, giving them permission to open books, sell stock, and carry on the enterprise outlined.

To set up a stock company, a group of people needs to come together and create a certificate stating their intention to form a company under a specific name, for the purpose of conducting a particular type of business in a designated location. The certificate outlines their plan to issue a certain number of shares at a specific price per share, that the total capital stock will be a defined amount, and that the company will operate for a set period of time. The Secretary of State for the area where the company is being established provides blank forms for this certificate. Once the certificate is filled out correctly, signed, and submitted, the Secretary issues a license or charter to the individuals who created the certificate, allowing them to open books, sell stock, and pursue the business venture described.

State laws regarding stock companies differ very largely. Students of this course who desire to know the law in any particular State can easily secure the information by writing to the secretary of that State.

State laws about stock companies vary significantly. Students in this course who want to know the law in a specific State can easily get the information by contacting the secretary of that State.

[42]The usual par value of a share of stock is $100. That is, if a company organises with a capital of $200,000, there will be 2000 shares to sell. Each person who buys or subscribes for the stock—that is, who joins the company—receives a certificate of stock. Our illustrations show two examples; one of a national bank, and the other of a manufacturing company. These certificates are transferable at the pleasure of the owners. The transfer is made usually by a form of indorsement on the back of the certificate, but to be legal the transfer must be recorded on the books of the company.

[42]The standard value of a share of stock is $100. So, if a company starts with a capital of $200,000, there will be 2,000 shares available for sale. Each person who buys or subscribes to the stock—that is, who becomes a part of the company—gets a stock certificate. Our examples illustrate two scenarios: one from a national bank and the other from a manufacturing company. These certificates can be transferred at the owner's discretion. The transfer is usually done by signing on the back of the certificate, but to be legal, the transfer must also be recorded in the company's books.

A certificate of stock in a national bank. A stock certificate from a national bank.

The men subscribing in this way become responsible[43] for the good management of the business and are obliged to act according to the laws of the State in which the company is organised. Usually they are not responsible individually for the liabilities of the concern beyond the amounts of their individual subscriptions.

The men who sign up in this way become responsible[43] for managing the business well and must follow the laws of the state where the company is set up. Typically, they aren't individually liable for the company's debts beyond the amounts they subscribed.

A certificate of stock in a manufacturing company. A stock certificate for a manufacturing company.

Every person who subscribes for stock owns a part of the business and is called a shareholder. All the shareholders meet together, and out of their number they choose a certain number of directors. The directors choose a president and other necessary officers, and in a general way direct the policy of the company. As a rule directors have no salaries attached to their positions.[44] General meetings of shareholders are held once a year to elect the directors and to hear the reports of the officers.

Every person who buys stock owns a part of the business and is called a stockholder. All the shareholders gather together, and from their group, they elect a certain number of management team. The directors then appoint a president and other necessary officers, and generally oversee the company's policies. Typically, directors do not receive salaries for their roles.[44] Annual meetings of shareholders are held to elect the directors and to hear reports from the officers.

The student should be familiar in a general way with the different classes of stock and with the technical terms familiar to stock companies. The more important of these matters are as follows:

The student should have a general understanding of the different types of stock and the technical terms common to stock companies. The key points to know are as follows:

Directors. All the shareholders meet together and out of their number choose a certain number of directors. The directors choose a president and other necessary officers and fix the amount of salary which shall be paid such officers for their work.

Leadership Team. All the shareholders come together and select a specific number of directors from among themselves. The directors then choose a president and other essential officers and determine the salary that will be paid to these officers for their work.

Capital Stock. This name is given to the gross capital for which the company is organised, without any reference to its value or to whether it has been fully paid in or not. The paid-in capital is the amount received from the stockholders on the shares for which they have subscribed.

Equity Capital. This term refers to the total capital for which the company is established, regardless of its value or whether it has been fully paid up. The paid-in capital is the amount collected from shareholders for the shares they have subscribed to.

Dividends. The directors of the company, after paying the expenses and laying by a certain amount for contingencies, divide the profits among the shareholders. These profits are called dividends, and in successful concerns such dividends as are declared quarterly, semiannually, or annually usually amount to good interest on the shareholders' investments.

Payouts. The company's directors, after covering expenses and setting aside some money for unexpected events, share the profits with the shareholders. These profits are known as dividends, and in successful businesses, the dividends declared quarterly, semiannually, or annually typically provide a solid return on the shareholders' investments.

Treasury Stock. It often occurs that a new company finds it necessary to set aside a certain number of shares to be sold from time to time to secure working capital. Such stock is held in the treasury until it is needed, and is called treasury stock.

Treasury Shares. It's common for a new company to need to set aside a certain number of shares to sell occasionally to raise working capital. This stock is kept in the treasury until required, and it's referred to as treasury stock.

Preferred Stock. Preferred stock is stock which is guaranteed certain advantages over ordinary stock. It is usually given to secure some obligation of the company, and upon it dividends are declared in preference to common stock. That is to say, if a man holds a share of preferred stock he will receive interest thereon out[45] of the profits of the business before such profits are given in the form of dividends to shareholders generally. Preferred stock can be issued only when authorised by the charter of the company. The interest on the investment in the case of preferred stock is more sure, but the security itself is not any more secure than in the case of common stock.

Preferred Shares. Preferred stock is a type of stock that comes with certain advantages over ordinary stock. It's typically issued to meet some obligation of the company, and dividends are paid on it before any are paid out to common stockholders. In other words, if someone owns a share of preferred stock, they will receive dividends from the company's profits before those profits are distributed to all shareholders. Preferred stock can only be issued if the company's charter allows it. While the returns on preferred stock are generally more reliable, the actual investment isn’t any safer than common stock.

Guaranteed Stock. Guaranteed stock differs from preferred stock in this—that it is entitled to the guaranteed dividend (interest) before all other classes of stock, whether the company earns the necessary amount in any one year or not. This right is carried over from year to year, thus rendering the shares absolutely secured as to interest.

Guaranteed Inventory. Guaranteed stock is different from preferred stock in that it has the right to receive a guaranteed dividend (interest) before any other class of stock, regardless of whether the company makes enough money in a given year or not. This right carries over from year to year, making the shares completely secure in terms of interest.

Watered Stock. When stock is issued to the shareholders without increase of actual capital the stock is said to have been watered. A company may organise for, say, $10,000, and may want to increase to $50,000 without adding to the number of its shareholders. Each holder of one share will, in this instance, receive four new shares, and in future instead of receiving a dividend on one share will receive a dividend on five shares. The object of this is, quite commonly, to avoid State laws requiring certain corporations to pay excess of profit over a stated rate per cent. into the State treasury.

Diluted stock. When stock is given to shareholders without actually increasing the capital, the stock is referred to as watered. A company might start with, say, $10,000, and then want to grow to $50,000 without bringing in more shareholders. In this case, each holder of one share will receive four new shares, so instead of getting a dividend on one share, they will get a dividend on five shares. The usual goal here is to sidestep state laws that require certain corporations to pay any profits above a specified percentage into the state treasury.

Forfeited Stock. Stock is usually sold on certain explicit conditions, such as the paying of ten per cent. down and the balance in installments at stated intervals. If the conditions which are agreed to by the shareholder are not met his stock is declared forfeited, or he can be sued in the same manner as upon any other contract.

Lost Stock. Stock is typically sold under specific conditions, like paying ten percent upfront and the rest in installments at regular intervals. If the shareholder fails to meet the agreed-upon conditions, their stock is declared forfeited, or they can be sued just like with any other contract.

Assessments. Some companies organise with the understanding that a certain percentage of the nominal value of the shares is to be paid at the time of subscribing, and that future payments are to be made at such times and[46] in such amounts as the company may require. Under these conditions the stockholders are assessed whenever money is needed. Such assessments are uniform on all stockholders.

Evaluations. Some companies operate with the understanding that a certain percentage of the nominal value of the shares must be paid when subscribing, with future payments to be made at times and[46] in amounts determined by the company as needed. Under these conditions, stockholders are assessed whenever funds are required. These assessments are the same for all stockholders.

Surplus Fund. It is not customary to pay a larger dividend than good interest. The profits remaining after the expenses and dividends are paid are credited to what is called a surplus fund. This fund is the property of the shareholders and is usually invested in good securities.

Excess Fund. It's not typical to pay a greater dividend than what's considered fair interest. The profits left after covering expenses and dividends are added to what's known as a surplus fund. This fund belongs to the shareholders and is generally invested in reliable securities.

Franchise. A franchise is a right granted by the State to individuals or to corporations. The franchise of a railroad company is the right to operate its road. Such franchise has a value entirely distinct from the value of the plant or of the ordinary property of the corporation.

Franchise. A franchise is a right given by the State to individuals or corporations. The franchise of a railroad company is the right to run its services. This franchise has a value completely separate from the value of the infrastructure or the usual property of the corporation.

Sinking Fund. A sinking fund is a fund set aside yearly for the purpose at some future time of sinking—that is, paying a debt.

Savings Fund. A sinking fund is a fund set aside each year to eventually pay off a debt.

XIII. PROTESTED PAPER

When a note is presented for payment at maturity and is not paid it is usually protested; that is, a notary public makes a formal statement that the note was presented for payment and payment was refused. Notice of such protest is sent to the maker of the note and to each indorser.

When a note is presented for payment at maturity and isn't paid, it is typically protested; meaning a notary public makes a formal declaration that the note was presented for payment and payment was denied. A notice of this protest is sent to the maker of the note and to each endorser.

The bank should never hand to its notary any paper for protest until it has made sure that its non-payment has not been brought about by some error or misunderstanding. Quite often, even though the paper has been made payable at a bank, the notary sends a messenger with the note to the maker to make a formal demand for payment.

The bank should never give any document for protest to its notary until it has confirmed that the non-payment wasn't caused by any mistake or misunderstanding. Often, even if the document is made payable at a bank, the notary sends a messenger with the note to the issuer to formally request payment.

In taking in collection paper, banks should obtain clear instructions from its owners as to whether or not it should[47] be protested in case of non-payment. It by no means follows that a formal protest is not desired because the paper bears no indorsements. Many banks make it a rule to protest all unpaid paper unless otherwise ordered.

In accepting collection paper, banks should get clear instructions from the owners about whether it should[47] be protested if there's a non-payment. Just because the paper has no endorsements doesn’t automatically mean a formal protest isn’t wanted. Many banks follow a policy of protesting all unpaid paper unless instructed otherwise.

We often see attached to the end of a draft a little slip with the words: "No protest; tear this off before protesting." This is simply private advice to the banker informing him that the drawer does not wish to have the draft protested. It may be that he does not wish to wrong or injure the credit of or add to the expense of his debtor; or it may be that he considers the account doubtful and does not wish to add to his own loss the cost of protest fees.

We often see a small note attached to the end of a draft that says: "No protest; tear this off before protesting." This is just private advice to the banker letting him know that the drawer doesn't want the draft protested. It could be that he doesn't want to harm the credit of his debtor or increase their expenses; or it might be that he thinks the account is uncertain and doesn't want to add the cost of protest fees to his own loss.

To hold an indorser, he must be properly notified of the non-payment of the note; and whether this has been done is a question of fact. If he was not properly notified this defence will avail whenever it is clearly proved. A great variety of defences may be successfully made by an indorser. A few of these defences are here briefly noticed: One is usury; another is the maker's discharge by the holder; nor can he be held when he has paid the note; nor when its issue was unlawful, nor when the note was non-negotiable, nor when his indorsement was procured by fraud. Finally, an indorser may avail himself of any defence existing between the holder and the maker or principal debtor. This is evidently a just principle, for the holder should have no more rights against an indorser than he has against the maker. If, therefore, the maker can interpose some just claim as a partial or complete defence the indorser should be permitted to avail himself of this claim.

To hold an indorser accountable, they must be properly notified about the note’s non-payment; whether this notification has occurred is a matter of fact. If they were not properly notified, this defense will be valid whenever it is clearly proven. An indorser can successfully raise a variety of defenses. A few of these defenses are briefly mentioned here: one is usury; another is if the holder discharged the maker; also, they cannot be held liable if they have already paid the note; nor if its issuance was illegal, nor if the note was non-negotiable, nor if their endorsement was obtained through fraud. Lastly, an indorser can make use of any defense that exists between the holder and the maker or principal debtor. This is clearly a fair principle, as the holder should have no more rights against an indorser than they have against the maker. Therefore, if the maker can present a valid claim as a partial or complete defense, the indorser should be allowed to use this claim.

In order to recover from an indorser it must be proven that a formal and proper demand for payment was made upon the maker. The formal protest is usually undisputed evidence of this. The maker is liable in any event.

To recover from an indorser, it's necessary to show that a proper demand for payment was made to the maker. A formal protest typically serves as unquestionable proof of this. The maker is responsible in any case.

A protest. A demonstration.

[49]To make the indorser's liability absolute it is necessary to demand payment at the specified place on the last day of the period for which the note was given, and to give due notice of non-payment to the indorser. For, as the contract requires the maker to pay at maturity, the indorser may presume, unless he has received a notice to the contrary, that the maker has paid the obligation.

[49]To make the endorser's liability absolute, it is essential to request payment at the designated place on the last day of the period for which the note was issued, and to provide timely notice of non-payment to the endorser. Since the contract requires the borrower to pay at maturity, the endorser can assume, unless they have received a contrary notice, that the borrower has fulfilled the obligation.

Ordinarily a notice of an indorsement by a partnership need not be sent to each member. Even after the partnership has been dissolved a notice to one partner is sufficient to bind the other members. If the note is owned jointly (that is, by parties who are not business partners) the indorsers are not liable as partners but as individuals. In such a case the notice of non-payment should be sent to each.

Ordinarily, a notice of an endorsement by a partnership doesn't need to be sent to every member. Even after the partnership is dissolved, notifying one partner is enough to bind the other members. If the note is owned jointly (meaning by parties who aren't business partners), the endorsers are liable as individuals, not as partners. In this case, the notice of non-payment should be sent to each endorsing party.

Our illustration shows a facsimile of a protest notice.

Our illustration displays a duplicate of a protest notice.

XIV. PAPER OFFERED FOR DISCOUNT

One of the most valuable parts of a banker's education is to learn whom to trust. Every bank should have a well-organised and thoroughly equipped credit department, in charge of some one who can be relied upon to investigate carefully all names referred to him by the officers. A banker has the right to expect the fullest confidence on the part of the borrower, and the borrower should furnish him with a complete and detailed statement of the condition of his affairs. It is safe to conclude that when a borrower refuses absolutely to give any information as to his financial condition his credit is not in the most favourable shape.

One of the most valuable parts of a banker's education is learning whom to trust. Every bank should have a well-organized and fully equipped credit department, led by someone dependable who can thoroughly investigate all names referred to them by the officers. A banker has the right to expect complete honesty from the borrower, and the borrower should provide a full and detailed statement of their financial situation. It’s safe to conclude that when a borrower outright refuses to share any information about their financial status, their credit is probably not in the most favourable shape.

Many of the banks have blank forms which they, from time to time, ask borrowers to fill out. These statements show in detail the assets and liabilities of the firm in[50] question; they show the notes which are outstanding, the mortgages on real estate, and many other particulars, including the personal or individual credit of members of the firm, if a partnership.

Many banks have blank forms that they occasionally ask borrowers to fill out. These statements provide detailed information about the firm’s assets and liabilities in[50] question; they list any outstanding notes, mortgages on real estate, and various other details, including the individual credit of the firm's members if it's a partnership.

In estimating the value of paper offered for discount the following points should be considered:

In evaluating the value of paper submitted for discount, the following points should be taken into account:

  1. The total net worth of the borrower.
  2. The character of his business; whether it is speculative or staple.
  3. The borrower's record and standing in the community and his business habits.
  4. Whether he is in enterprise abreast with modern ideas and methods.
  5. The character of the merchandise owned by the borrower. What would it bring under the hammer? Groceries and raw material can usually be turned into cash at a forced sale at very small discount from current prices. Not so with hardware, glass, dry goods, boots and shoes, books, etc. Machinery and fixtures are not a bankable asset upon which to base credit.

The banker should note his borrower's bills payable. Why did he give notes? Are they met promptly? Many houses prefer to sell their own paper in the open market, and keep their banks open for accommodations when they are unable to secure outside credit. The insurance carried should be considered; also the volume of business done. A large business on moderate capital, with long credits, will naturally have large liabilities, while a small business with a liberal capital and short credits should have small liabilities.

The banker should keep track of his borrower's bills payable. Why did he issue notes? Are they being paid on time? Many companies choose to sell their own notes in the open market and keep their banks available for support when they can't get outside credit. The insurance coverage should be taken into account, as well as the amount of business conducted. A large business with moderate capital and long credit terms will naturally have significant liabilities, while a small business with ample capital and short credit terms should have minimal liabilities.

Paper offered for discount is of a variety of kinds. The larger proportion of it is from customers of the borrower who have extended their credit by paying their accounts in notes instead of in cash. Such paper is really, though having two names, very little better than[51] single-name paper, for it is not the maker's credit, but the payee's, which the bank usually considers. Many very small notes offered for discount usually indicate a very needy condition.

Paper submitted for discount comes in various types. Most of it is from the borrower's customers who have chosen to pay their bills with notes instead of cash. This type of paper, even though it has two names, is not much better than a single-name note, because the bank usually evaluates the credit of the payee rather than the maker. Many small notes submitted for discount often suggest a very desperate situation.

There are many firms which carry two or more bank accounts, and others who sell their paper to out-of-town banks. In buying paper it is important to ascertain whether the firm is in the habit of taking up paper at one bank by floating a loan at another.

There are many companies that have two or more bank accounts, and others that sell their notes to banks in other towns. When purchasing notes, it’s important to find out if the company usually pays off notes at one bank by taking out a loan at another.

Paper may be classified for purposes of discount as follows:

Paper can be categorized for discount purposes as follows:

  1. Bills drawn by shippers on the houses to which the goods are shipped.
  2. Bills drawn by importers against commodities placed in brokers' hands for sale.
  3. Bills arising out of our manifold trades and industries.
  4. Drafts with bills of lading attached.
  5. Paper having personal indorsements.
  6. Paper secured by collateral.
  7. One-name paper.

XV. CORPORATIONS

Stock companies are in a sense corporations, but the name corporation has in its common application a broader meaning. Public corporations are those which are created exclusively for the public interest, as cities, towns, counties, colleges, etc. Private corporations are created wholly or in part for the pecuniary benefit of the members, as railroad companies, banks, etc. Corporate bodies whose members at discretion fill by appointment all vacancies occurring in their membership are sometimes called close corporations. In this country[52] the power to be a corporation is a franchise which can only exist through the legislature.

Stock companies are essentially corporations, but the term company has a wider meaning in common usage. Public companies are created solely for the public good, like cities, towns, counties, and colleges. Private companies are formed either entirely or partly for the financial benefit of the members, such as railroad companies and banks. Corporate entities whose members can fill any vacancies by appointment are sometimes called close corporations. In this country[52], the ability to be a corporation is a privilege that can only be granted by the legislature.

In municipal corporations the members are the citizens; the number is indefinite; one ceases to be a member when he moves from the town or city, while every new resident becomes a member when by law he becomes entitled to the privileges of local citizenship.

In municipal corporations, the members are the citizens; the number is unlimited; a person stops being a member when they move out of the town or city, while every new resident becomes a member when they are legally entitled to the privileges of local citizenship.

The laws which corporations may make for their own government are made under the several heads of by-laws, ordinances, rules, and regulations. These laws may be made by the governing body for any object not foreign to the corporate purposes. A municipal corporation, for example, makes ordinances for the cleaning and lighting of its streets, for the government of its police force, for the supply of water to its citizens, and for the punishment of all breaches of its regulations. A railway corporation establishes regulations for signals, for the running of trains, for freight connections, for the conduct of its passengers, and for hundreds of other things. But such by-laws and regulations must be in harmony with the charter of the corporation and with the general law of the land. For instance, a municipal corporation could not enforce a by-law forbidding the use of its streets by others than its own citizens, because by general law all highways are open to the common use of all the people. Again, a railway corporation could not make a rule that it would carry goods for one class of persons only, because as a common carrier the law requires that it carry impartially for all.

The laws that corporations create for their own management are known as by-laws, ordinances, rules, and regulations. These laws can be made by the governing body for any purpose that aligns with the corporation’s objectives. For instance, a municipal corporation creates ordinances for street cleaning and lighting, manages its police force, supplies water to its residents, and punishes any violations of its regulations. A railway corporation sets regulations for signals, train operations, freight connections, passenger behavior, and many other areas. However, these by-laws and regulations must align with the corporation's charter and the overall law of the land. For example, a municipal corporation cannot enforce a by-law that prohibits non-residents from using its streets because under general law, all highways must be accessible to everyone. Similarly, a railway corporation cannot impose a rule that restricts service to only one class of people, as the law requires it to provide impartial service as a common carrier.

As a general rule private corporations organised under the laws of one State are permitted to do business in other States. It is quite often to the advantage of a company to organise under the laws of one State for the purpose of doing business in another. For instance, there are many companies chartered under the laws of[53] Maine with headquarters in Boston. The Massachusetts laws require that a large proportion of the capital be actually paid in at the time of organising, while the Maine law has no such provision. For similar reasons many large companies doing business in New York or Philadelphia are organised under the laws of New Jersey.

As a general rule, private companies organized under the laws of one state can operate in other states. It’s often beneficial for a company to set up under the laws of one state to conduct business in another. For example, many companies are chartered under Maine's laws but have their headquarters in Boston. Massachusetts law requires that a significant portion of the capital be paid in at the time of organization, while Maine law doesn’t have that requirement. For similar reasons, many large companies operating in New York or Philadelphia are organized under New Jersey law.

A corporation may make an assignment just as may an individual. If all the members die the property interests pass to the rightful heirs, and under ordinary conditions the corporation still exists.

A corporation can make an assignment just like an individual can. If all the members die, the property interests go to the rightful heirs, and under normal conditions, the corporation continues to exist.

A franchise is a right granted by the State or by a municipal corporation to individuals or to a private corporation. The franchise of a railroad company is the right to operate its road. Such franchise has a value entirely distinct from the value of the plant or the ordinary property of the corporation.

A franchise is a privilege given by the State or a local government to individuals or a private company. The franchise of a railroad company is the permission to run its railway. This franchise has a value that is completely separate from the value of the infrastructure or the regular assets of the company.

An unlimited liability corporation is one in which the stockholders are liable as partners, each for the full indebtedness.

An unlimited liability corporation is one where the shareholders are personally responsible as partners, each for the entire amount of the company’s debts.

A limited liability corporation is one in which the stockholders, in case of the failure of the corporation, are liable for the amount of their subscriptions. The name limited is required by law to appear after the name of the company. If a subscription is entirely paid up there is no further liability—that is to say, the property of a shareholder cannot be attached for any debts of the company. Understand clearly that the name limited printed after the name of a company does not indicate in any way that the capital or credit of the company is limited, only that the liability of the shareholders of the company is limited to the amounts of their shares.

A limited liability corporation is a type of company where shareholders are only responsible for the amount they invested if the corporation fails. The term limited must legally be included after the company's name. Once a subscription is fully paid, there is no additional liability—meaning a shareholder's assets cannot be seized for the company's debts. It’s important to note that the term limited at the end of a company's name does not mean that the company's capital or credit is restricted; it only signifies that the shareholders' liability is limited to the value of their shares.

A double liability corporation is one in which, in case of failure, the stockholders are further liable for amounts equal to their subscriptions. All national banks are double liability companies. If A owns $5000 stock in a[54] national bank, and the bank fails, he loses his stock; and if the liabilities of the bank are large he may be obliged to pay a part or the whole of an additional $5000.

A double responsibility corporation is one where, if it goes under, shareholders are also responsible for paying amounts equal to their investments. All national banks are double liability companies. If A holds $5000 in stock in a [54] national bank and the bank fails, he loses his stock; and if the bank has significant debts, he might have to pay some or all of an extra $5000.

XVI. BONDS

When a railroad company, or a city or any other corporation desires to borrow money it is a common practice to issue instruments of credit called bonds. A bond means something that binds. Bonds bear the same relation to the resources of a corporation that mortgages do to real estate.

When a railroad company, a city, or any other corporation wants to borrow money, it's typical to issue credit instruments known as bonds. A bond represents something that ties. Bonds have the same relationship to a corporation's resources that mortgages have to real estate.

Corporation bonds are issued for a period of years. They usually have coupons attached which are cut off and presented at regular intervals for the payment of interest. A bondholder of a corporation runs less risk than a stockholder, first, as to interest: the corporation is obliged to pay interest on its bonds, but may at its own pleasure pass its dividends; secondly, the bondholder is a creditor, while the stockholder of the corporation is the debtor. On the other hand, if a concern is very successful, a shareholder may receive large dividends, while the bondholder receives only the stipulated interest. A bond is evidence of debt, specifying the interest, and stating when the principal shall be paid; a certificate of stock is evidence that the owner is a part-owner in the corporation or company, not a creditor, and he has no right to regain his money except by the sale of his stock, or through the winding up of the company's business.

Corporation bonds are issued for a set number of years. They usually come with coupons that are clipped off and submitted at regular intervals for interest payments. A bondholder in a corporation takes on less risk than a stockholder. First, regarding interest: the corporation must pay interest on its bonds, but can choose to skip dividends. Second, the bondholder is a creditor, while the stockholder in the corporation is a debtor. However, if a company is very successful, a shareholder might get large dividends, while the bondholder only receives the agreed-upon interest. A bond serves as proof of debt, indicating the interest and specifying when the principal will be repaid; a certificate of stock proves that the owner is a part-owner of the corporation or company and not a creditor, and they can't get their money back unless they sell their stock or the company's business is liquidated.

The name debentures is given to a form of municipal bond in common use. Nearly all the large sums of money used by States and cities for the building of State or municipal buildings, bridges, canals, water-works, etc.,[55] are raised through the issue of bonds (debentures), which are sold, usually at a price a little below par, to large financial institutions, banks, and insurance companies. Generally speaking, such bonds are good securities, and are marketable anywhere.

The term bonds refers to a type of municipal bond that is commonly used. Almost all the significant amounts of money that states and cities use to build state or municipal buildings, bridges, canals, water systems, etc.,[55] are raised by issuing bonds (debentures), which are typically sold at a slightly lower price than their face value to large financial institutions, banks, and insurance companies. Generally, these bonds are considered good securities and can be sold in any market.

A private bond. A private connection.

[56]At different times the United States government has issued bonds to relieve the treasury. These bonds are absolutely safe and are always marketable. Registered bonds have the name of the buyer registered; unregistered bonds are payable to bearer. Municipal bonds are issued by cities and other municipalities to raise money for local improvements. If proper precautions are taken by buyers, municipal securities may be considered among the safest and most remunerative investments.

[56]At various points, the U.S. government has issued bonds to support the treasury. These bonds are completely safe and always sellable. Registered bonds have the buyer's name registered; unregistered bonds are payable to bearer. Municipal bonds are issued by cities and other local governments to raise funds for community projects. If buyers take the right precautions, municipal securities can be seen as some of the safest and most profitable investments.

When a new railroad enterprise is undertaken its promoters often expect to make the road not only supply the money for its construction but also give working capital in addition. This is done by the issue of mortgage bonds. Default in the payment of interest throws the road into the hands of a receiver. The securities immediately fall in value and are perhaps bought up by a syndicate of crafty speculators who are permitted to reorganise the road and its management. This is the history of many of our roads. There are exceptional cases, of course, but the investor should be familiar with the facts before buying railroad mortgages.

When a new railroad project is started, the promoters often expect it to not only generate funds for its construction but also provide working capital. This is achieved by issuing mortgage bonds. If the interest payments are missed, the railroad falls into the hands of a receiver. The value of the securities drops immediately and may be purchased by a group of savvy speculators who are allowed to reorganize the railroad and its management. This has been the story for many of our railroads. There are, of course, exceptions, but investors should understand the facts before purchasing railroad mortgages.

A bottomry bond is a kind of mortgage peculiar to shipping. It is a conveyance of the ship as security for advances made to the owner. If the ship is lost the creditor loses his money and has no claim against the owner personally. It is allowable for a loan made upon such a bond to bear any rate of interest in excess of the legal rate. A vessel arriving in a foreign port may require repairs and supplies before she can proceed farther on her voyage, and in occasions of this kind a bottomry[57] bond is given. The owner or master pledges the keel or bottom of the ship—a part, in fact, for the whole—as security.

A bottomry loan is a type of mortgage specific to shipping. It involves using the ship as collateral for loans given to the owner. If the ship is lost, the lender loses their money and cannot make any claims against the owner personally. It's allowed for loans secured by such a bond to charge any interest rate above the legal limit. When a vessel arrives in a foreign port and needs repairs or supplies before continuing its journey, a bottomry[57] bond is issued. The owner or captain pledges the keel or bottom of the ship—essentially part of the ship for the whole—as collateral.

We have now upon the market stocks and bonds representing all conceivable kinds of property. Not only are properties of many kinds used to issue bonds upon, but many kinds of bonds are often issued upon the same property. Thus we find among our railroads not only first, second, and third mortgage bonds, but income bonds, dividend bonds, convertible bonds, consolidated bonds, redemption bonds, renewal bonds, sinking-fund bonds, collateral trust bonds, equipment bonds, etc., until they lap and overlap in seemingly endless confusion.

We now have stocks and bonds available on the market that represent every conceivable type of property. Not only are various properties used to issue bonds, but many different types of bonds are often issued against the same property. For example, within our railroads, we see not just first, second, and third mortgage bonds, but also income bonds, dividend bonds, convertible bonds, consolidated bonds, redemption bonds, renewal bonds, sinking-fund bonds, collateral trust bonds, equipment bonds, and more, creating a seemingly endless and confusing overlap.

Receiver's certificates are issued by receivers of corporations, companies, etc., in financial difficulties, to secure operating capital; they are granted first rights upon the property and are placed above prior lien and first mortgage bonds.

Receiver certificates are issued by receivers of corporations, companies, etc., facing financial difficulties to secure operating capital; they have first rights on the property and take priority over prior lien and first mortgage bonds.

XVII. TRANSPORTATION

The most common effect of cheapened transportation is to increase the distance at which it is possible for producer and consumer to deal with each other. To the producer it offers a wider market and to the consumer a more varied source of supply. On the whole, cheapened transportation is more uniformly beneficial to the consumer; its temporary advantage to the producer very often leads to overproduction. It has the effect also of bringing about nearly uniform prices the world over.

The most common effect of cheaper transportation is to extend the distance over which producers and consumers can interact. For producers, it provides a broader market, and for consumers, a wider range of options. Overall, cheaper transportation tends to be more beneficial for consumers; its short-term gains for producers often lead to overproduction. It also results in almost uniform prices around the world.

The time was when nearness to market was of the greatest possible advantage. At the present time a farmer can raise his celery in Michigan or his beets in Dakota and market them in New York City about as[58] easily as though he lived on Long Island. It is no longer location which determines the business to be carried on in a particular place, but natural advantages more or less independent of location. But the railroad or the steamboat very often determines where a new business shall be developed. It is this quickening and cheapening of transportation that has given such stimulus in the present day to the growth of large cities. It enables them to draw cheap food from a far larger territory, and it causes business to locate where the widest selling connection is to be had, rather than where the goods or raw materials are most easily procured. It is the quick and comfortable transportation facilities which our large cities possess that have given strength to the great shopping centres. Shoppers for thirty or forty miles around can easily reach these centres, and the result is that trade gathers in centres rather than at local points. A city of a million population in the most productive agricultural section of country could not be fed if the food had to reach the city by teaming. With this growth of trade centres comes the increased gain of large dealers at the expense of the small; with it comes organised speculation and its attendant results, good and evil.

There was a time when being close to the market was a huge advantage. Nowadays, a farmer can grow his celery in Michigan or his beets in Dakota and sell them in New York City just as easily as if he lived on Long Island. It’s no longer the location that decides what business operates in a specific area, but rather natural benefits that are somewhat independent of location. However, railroads and steamboats often determine where new businesses will develop. This improvement and reduction in transportation costs have significantly contributed to the growth of large cities today. It allows them to source cheap food from a much larger area and leads businesses to establish themselves where they can reach the biggest customer base, rather than where goods or raw materials are easiest to obtain. The efficient and convenient transportation options available in our large cities have strengthened major shopping districts. Shoppers from thirty or forty miles away can easily access these areas, resulting in trade consolidating in these centers rather than at local spots. A city with a million residents in a highly productive agricultural region couldn't be sustained if the food had to arrive by horse and wagon. With the rise of trade centers comes the increased profits of big dealers at the expense of smaller ones, along with organized speculation and its mixed consequences, both positive and negative.

Prior to the completion of the organisation of trunk or through lines, freight was compelled to break bulk and suffer trans-shipment at the end of each line, where a new corporation took up the traffic and carried it beyond. To prevent this breaking of bulk and to expedite the carriage of freight, fast freight lines on separate capitalisation were organised. The purpose of the interstate-commerce law is largely to prevent discrimination and corruption in freight charges, to secure for every person and place just and equal treatment at the hands of the transportation companies. The freight rates are arranged and regulated by the traffic associations, and the various[59] conditions and compromises necessary have made both classifications and rates about as complicated as anything possibly could be.

Before the trunk or main lines were fully organized, freight had to be unloaded and transferred at the end of each line, where another company would take over and transport it further. To avoid this unloading and to speed up freight delivery, separate fast freight lines were established. The main goal of the interstate commerce law is to prevent unfairness and corruption in freight pricing, ensuring that everyone and every location receives fair and equal treatment from transportation companies. Freight rates are set and controlled by traffic associations, and the various[59] conditions and compromises needed have made classification and rates as complicated as they could possibly be.

The name differential as applied to freight rates refers to the differences which are made by railroad companies. Certain roads are by agreement allowed to charge a lower rate than others running to the same points. To and from each of the eastern cities there are two classes of roads—the standard lines and the differential lines. The standard lines have the advantage of more direct connections; the differential lines reach the freight destinations by circuitous routes, in some instances by almost double the mileage. With a view to equalising these conditions the general traffic associations allow the differential lines to carry freight at a lower rate per mile than the rate charged by the standard lines.

The term difference when it comes to freight rates refers to the variations made by railroad companies. Some routes are permitted to charge lower rates than others that serve the same destinations. For each of the eastern cities, there are two types of routes—the standard lines and the differential lines. The standard lines have the benefit of more direct connections, while the differential lines reach their freight destinations through longer, often nearly double the mileage routes. To balance these differences, the general traffic associations permit the differential lines to transport freight at a lower rate per mile than what the standard lines charge.

The transportation business of the United States is so varied and complicated that a proper study of its freight tariffs and classifications would require much more space than can be given the subject in these lessons.

The transportation industry in the United States is so diverse and complex that an adequate examination of its freight tariffs and classifications would need far more space than can be allotted to the topic in these lessons.

XVIII. TRANSPORTATION PAPERS

The common transportation papers, familiar to all shippers, are the (1) shipping receipt, (2) bill of lading, (3) waybill.

The standard shipping documents that all senders recognize are the (1) shipping receipt, (2) bill of lading, (3) waybill.

Original receipts, stating marks and quantities of goods, go with each separate lot of merchandise to the freight sheds or vessels, and these are summed up in a formal bill of lading, for which they are exchanged when all the cases or bundles belonging to the particular shipment have been delivered. The duplicate receipt, or the part commonly marked invoice, is kept by the receiver of the freight, and the other end, commonly marked original,[60] is given to the drayman. In making ordinary shipments it is not usual or necessary to make out a formal bill of lading. Of course, when no bill of lading is made out, the receipt should be preserved by the shipper. The full contract is usually printed on the receipt, but it must be remembered that a receipt is not a negotiable instrument and cannot be used as security for money.

Original receipts, showing the marks and quantities of goods, accompany each separate lot of merchandise to the freight sheds or vessels. These are summarized in a formal bill of lading, which is exchanged once all the cases or bundles for that specific shipment have been delivered. The duplicate receipt, often labeled invoice, is kept by the freight receiver, while the other part, typically marked original, [60] is given to the drayman. For regular shipments, it’s not standard or necessary to create a formal bill of lading. However, if no bill of lading is issued, the shipper should keep the receipt. The full contract is usually printed on the receipt, but it's important to remember that a receipt is not a negotiable instrument and can't be used as collateral for money.

A shipping receipt (original). An original shipping receipt.

A bill of lading is an acknowledgment by a transportation company of the receipt of goods specified, and contracts for their delivery at a certain place, under conditions stated thereon, upon payment of freight and expenses. Bills of lading are negotiable and maybe transferred by indorsement, but are of no value apart from the goods to which they give title. A bill of lading goes with certain named goods and cannot be transferred to other goods, even though of precisely the same kind and price. Marine bills of lading are usually made in tripli[61]cate; one is kept by the shipper, another by the vessel, and the third is sent by mail to the person to receive the goods.

A shipping document is a document from a shipping company confirming that it has received the specified goods and agrees to deliver them to a specific location under the stated conditions, for payment of freight and expenses. Bills of lading are negotiable and can be transferred through endorsement, but they have no value on their own, separate from the goods they represent. A bill of lading is associated with specific named goods and cannot be applied to different items, even if they are exactly the same type and price. Marine bills of lading are typically created in triplicate; one stays with the shipper, another remains with the vessel, and the third is mailed to the person who will receive the goods.

A steamship bill of lading. A steamship bill of lading.

The parties to a bill of lading are three—the shipper, the consignee, and the transportation company. The declaration of having received the goods in good order and condition, and the consequent obligation, subsequently expressed, of delivering them in like good order and condition, is sensibly lessened in its importance by the additional clause now adopted by almost all transportation companies—namely: "Contents and condition of contents[62] of packages unknown." Should the goods or part of them be shipped in a damaged condition, or in a bad condition of packing, a note to that effect should be made by the transportation company on the bill of lading, which ceases then to be a clean bill of lading.

The parties involved in a bill of lading are three: the shipper, the consignee, and the transportation company. The statement that the goods were received in good order and condition, along with the obligation to deliver them in the same condition, is significantly lessened in importance by the additional clause that nearly all transportation companies now use: "Contents and condition of contents[62] of packages unknown." If the goods or part of them are shipped in damaged condition or poorly packed, the transportation company should note this on the bill of lading, which then stops being a clean bill of lading.

A local waybill. A local shipping slip.

Like any other instrument of credit, a bill of lading may be deposited with a creditor as security for money advanced (or it may be transferred to a buyer) by means of indorsement, and the property or goods will be thereby either mortgaged or assigned. Acting upon this principle, the shipper declares in the bill of lading that the goods shall be delivered unto the consignee or his assigns. When a shipper is unable to insert the name of the consignee at the time the bill of lading is made out, a bill to order is drawn up wherein the consignee's name is superseded by the words shipper's order, or simply order; it being thus understood that the goods shall be delivered to whomsoever presents, at point of destination, the bill of lading duly indorsed by the shipper. By such a simple arrangement as a bill to order the merchant is enabled to sell the goods while they are at sea, or in transit, and a consignment of merchandise may change hands several times before arriving at its destination.

Like any other form of credit, a bill of lading can be given to a creditor as collateral for money borrowed (or it can be transferred to a buyer) through endorsement, which means the property or goods are either mortgaged or assigned. Following this principle, the shipper states in the bill of lading that the goods will be delivered to the consignee or their designated representative. When a shipper can't write down the consignee's name when the bill of lading is created, a bill to order is prepared where the consignee's name is replaced with the words shipper's order, or simply order; this indicates that the goods will be delivered to whoever presents the duly endorsed bill of lading at the destination. With a simple arrangement like a bill to order, the merchant can sell the goods while they're still at sea or in transit, allowing a shipment of merchandise to change ownership several times before reaching its final destination.

When a case of merchandise to be shipped has been properly entered and weighed it is then ready to be man[63]ifested or waybilled, as no shipment is allowed to go forward without a waybill. The waybill is simply a memorandum of the consignment, together with full and complete shipping directions, giving also the number of the car into which the case has been loaded, and the point to which the car is "carded." The freight conductor has waybills for all goods which he carries. They are turned over with the merchandise to the agent of the railroad at the point of destination.

When a shipment of goods has been properly recorded and weighed, it's then ready to be man[63]ifested or waybilled, since no shipment can proceed without a waybill. The shipping label is simply a record of the shipment, including detailed shipping instructions, the car number where the shipment is loaded, and the destination of the car. The freight conductor has waybills for all the goods he transports. These are handed over with the goods to the railroad agent at the destination point.

Our illustrations show (1) a shipping receipt—the half marked "original"; (2) a steamship bill of lading; (3) a local waybill.

Our illustrations show (1) a shipping receipt—the half marked "original"; (2) a steamship bill of lading; (3) a local waybill.

[64]EXAMINATION PAPER

Note.—The following questions are set as an indication of the sort of knowledge a student should possess who has carefully read the several papers of this course. The paper covers only about the first half of the course. The student is recommended to write out the answers carefully. Only such answers need be attempted as can be made from a study of the lessons.

Note.—The questions below indicate the type of knowledge a student should have after thoroughly reading the different papers in this course. This paper only addresses about the first half of the course. Students are encouraged to write out their answers carefully. Only attempt answers that can be derived from studying the lessons.

  1. What in a general sense is meant when we speak of the currency of a country?
  2. Enumerate some of the advantages afforded to the community and to commerce in general by banking institutions.
  3. A bank cheque is a demand order for money, drawn by one who has funds in the bank. How does a cheque differ from an order on John Smith to pay bearer a certain sum of money?
  4. Why is it important that cheques should be very carefully drawn?
  5. (a)  A cheque has no date. Does this make it void? (b)  How about a cheque dated months ago? (c)  Is a cheque dated on Sunday good? (d)  Why are cheques sometimes dated ahead? (e)  Are you at liberty to print your own form of cheque? (f)  Is it necessary that your cheque be written on the prescribed blank form? (g)  How would you write a cheque for 75 cents?
  6. How would you word a cheque to give to a person[65] who is unknown at your bank, but who wishes to draw the money over the counter?
  7. You are sending a cheque through the mails to John Brown, Philadelphia. How will you prevent the cheque from falling into the hands of the wrong John Brown?
  8. You identify A. B. at your bank. The cheque A. B. presented turns out to be a forgery. Are you responsible?
  9. A. B. transfers a cheque to you by a blank indorsement. It is then payable to bearer. How can you legally make it payable to your own order?
  10. What is meant by power-of-attorney? How should an attorney indorse cheques for any person for whom he is acting?
  11. If a note were about to be transferred to you by indorsement and delivery in payment of a debt, would it make any difference to you whether or not it was overdue? Explain in full.
  12. Tell how you would receipt for a payment of a note. Why is not an ordinary separate receipt sufficient?
  13. Why are notes protested? Why is a formal protest sometimes desired even though the paper bears no indorsements?
  14. If an indorser is compelled to pay a note, against whom has he a good claim?

NOTE TO THE FOREGOING EXAMINATION PAPER

It is a mistake to answer questions for a student if he is able of himself to find the answers. A question which sets a student thinking, even though he cannot immediately find a satisfactory answer, affords educational training of considerable value. A few of the answers to the foregoing questions are as follows:

It’s a mistake to answer questions for a student if he can find the answers on his own. A question that gets a student thinking, even if he can't immediately come up with a good answer, provides valuable educational training. Here are some answers to the previous questions:

5. (a)  Not necessarily so. (b)  Such a cheque would under ordinary conditions be all right. Cheques should be presented as soon[66] after date as convenient. (c)  Cheques dated on Sunday are very commonly paid. Cheques or notes delivered on Sunday are void. The delivery makes the contract, not the dating. (d)  That the maker may have a few days in which to deposit sufficient money to meet them. (e)  You are at liberty to print your own form of cheque or to write it out in full if you wish. (g)  Write the words "Seventy-five cents" plainly along the money line.

5. (a) Not necessarily. (b) A check like that would usually be fine. Checks should be presented as soon[66] after the date as convenient. (c) Checks dated on Sunday are commonly paid. Checks or notes given on Sunday are void. The delivery creates the contract, not the date. (d) So that the issuer has a few days to deposit enough money to cover them. (e) You can create your own check format or write it out in full if you want. (g) Clearly write the words "Seventy-five cents" along the money line.

8. Yes.

Yes.


[69]BUSINESS GEOGRAPHY

THE TRADE FEATURES OF THE GREAT COMMERCIAL NATIONS

I. THE TRADE FEATURES OF THE BRITISH ISLES

LONDON AS A FOOD CONSUMER

London is the greatest seat of trade and commerce in the world. Its commercial greatness is evidenced by its greatness of population. Its inhabitants number over 6,000,000. The houses in which this vast population lives, would, if placed end to end, make a continuous street that would stretch across all Europe and Asia. The mere effort of providing food for this vast population necessitates an enormous commerce. Half a million of beeves are required every year to supply its meat market; also 2,000,000 sheep and 8,000,000 fowls. To supply its fish market 400,000,000 pounds of fish are required, and 500,000,000 oysters. Grain, flour, fruit, butter, eggs, cheese, sugar, tea, and coffee, are brought to London daily in such quantities that the prices of these commodities all the world over are based upon what they will fetch in London. Whole nations and provinces and districts get their subsistence from industries that have for their end the supplying of some of this enormous food demand. Denmark, for example, owes its entire prosperity of re[70]cent years to its profitable manufacture of butter for the London market. Brittany and Normandy, in France, are almost wholly occupied in supplying that market with poultry and eggs. The islands of Jersey and Guernsey derive their principal wealth, not, as might be supposed, from the sale of milk and butter, but from the supplying of London with potatoes. Canada during the last six or eight years has built up with London an immense trade in cheese, a trade that exceeds in importance any other that Canada has, while even our own home States—Illinois, Iowa, and Wisconsin, for example—have found new sources of wealth in catering to the London dairy trade. "Elgin" and "Ames" creamery butters are products well known to the London consumer.

London is the biggest hub of trade and commerce in the world. Its commercial significance is reflected in its large population, which exceeds 6,000,000. If you lined up all the houses that this massive population lives in, they would create a continuous street stretching across all of Europe and Asia. Just the effort of providing food for this huge population requires a massive trade network. Every year, half a million cattle are needed to supply the meat market, along with 2,000,000 sheep and 8,000,000 chickens. To keep the fish market stocked, 400,000,000 pounds of fish and 500,000,000 oysters are required. Grain, flour, fruit, butter, eggs, cheese, sugar, tea, and coffee are brought to London daily in such large quantities that the prices of these goods around the world depend on what they can sell for in London. Entire nations and regions depend on industries that focus on meeting this vast food demand. For instance, Denmark's recent prosperity has come from its successful butter production for the London market. Brittany and Normandy in France mainly produce poultry and eggs for that same market. The islands of Jersey and Guernsey gain most of their wealth not, as one might think, from selling milk and butter, but from supplying London with potatoes. Over the last six to eight years, Canada has established a massive cheese trade with London, which is more significant than any other trade Canada has, while even our own states—like Illinois, Iowa, and Wisconsin—have found new opportunities in supplying the London dairy market. "Elgin" and "Ames" creamery butters are well-known to London consumers.

LONDON THE COMMERCIAL CENTRE OF THE WORLD

What is the reason of London's wonderful prosperity? Already its population is one fifth the entire population of England and Wales, and it is increasing at the rate of about 20 per cent. per decade. Three hundred people are added to the number every day in the year, a rate of 110,000 inhabitants in the course of the year. It is now one half greater than the total population of all Ireland. London's Scotch population is almost as numerous as that of Edinburgh, while its Irish population is quite as numerous as that of Dublin. Every civilised country is represented among its people, and every civilised tongue is spoken among them. A sea of brick and mortar, even now fifteen miles long and ten miles broad, it is growing at the rate of a new house every hour of its existence. Its streets are already 28,000 miles in length, and these are spreading out so rapidly that every year many whole villages and townships are enmeshed by them. Every day 1,000,000 people enter London by railway, and at[71] least 500,000 people have occupations in it in the daytime who reside beyond its limits at night. Fifty thousand people have occupations in it in the night-time who reside beyond its limits during the day. It is the largest importing centre in Great Britain, and the largest in the world, and its exports are exceeded only by Liverpool, and not always by Liverpool. It is also the centre of the world's financial business. For example, traders in the East Indies who ship cargoes of spices and other Eastern produce to America, draw in settlement on London rather than on New York, while traders in America who ship cargoes of cotton to Marseilles or Riga, draw in settlement on London rather than on Paris or St. Petersburg. What is it that thus makes London the chief seat of population in the world, the commercial metropolis of the world, the great financial clearing-house of the world?

What’s behind London’s amazing prosperity? Its population is already one-fifth of the entire population of England and Wales, growing at a rate of about 20 percent per decade. Three hundred new residents are added every day, totaling around 110,000 people each year. It’s now one and a half times larger than the total population of all of Ireland. The Scottish population in London is almost as large as that of Edinburgh, while the Irish population is nearly equal to that of Dublin. People from every civilized country live there, and every civilized language is spoken. A massive expanse of brick and mortar, now stretching fifteen miles long and ten miles wide, London is growing at the astonishing pace of a new house being built every hour. Its streets already extend for 28,000 miles, and they’re spreading so quickly that entire villages and townships are being enveloped each year. Each day, a million people arrive in London by train, and at least 500,000 people work in the city during the day but live outside it at night. Another 50,000 work there at night while living elsewhere during the day. It’s the largest importing hub in Great Britain and also the biggest in the world, with exports only surpassed by Liverpool, and sometimes not even by Liverpool. Additionally, it’s the center of global financial business. For instance, traders in the East Indies who ship spices and other products to America choose London for settlement instead of New York, while American traders sending cotton to Marseilles or Riga opt for London over Paris or St. Petersburg. What makes London the world’s main population hub, its commercial capital, and its leading financial clearinghouse?

LONDON THE CENTRE OF THE LAND SURFACE OF THE GLOBE

London the natural centre of the world's trade. London is the natural center of global trade.

London stands as nearly as possible in the centre of the land surface of the globe. Its situation, therefore, eminently adapts it to be the great centre of the world's trade—the great distributing centre of the world's products. Its ships can go to the farthest parts of the earth, and, loading themselves with the natural products of these parts, can bring them to its docks without breaking bulk, deposit them there for assortment, and then take them away again to other parts of the earth, and do this more economically than the ships of almost any other port in the world. But a greater reason is to be found in the fact that for centuries the British people have pursued a definite policy of manufacture, trade, and commerce, and have had the good fortune to have had that policy interfered with in a less degree than any other nation in the world by commerce-destroying war, whether internal or external. And whenever Britain has been in external wars her navy has been able to protect her commercial interests. London, being the capital of the kingdom and its chief seat of trade, has naturally derived the principal benefit from these many[73] years of peaceful industry and commerce. Then, again, London is favourably adapted to trade in respect to its own country. It is a seaport, sixty miles inland, and is connected by navigable canals with all the other chief manufacturing and commercial centres of the country. Its railway facilities, too, are so complete that there is not a manufacturing town in the whole island that is not within fifteen hours of freightage from it. Then, too, the peculiar configuration of the coast-line of Great Britain makes every point on the island within an hour or two of carriage from a seaport. Finally, all British seaports are in trade connection with London by a coasting service unequalled in the world for cheapness, completeness, and efficiency. In a word, London stands not only in the centre of the land surface of the globe, but also at the commercial centre of its own home territory—that is to say, within easy reach both by water and by land of all the trading and producing interests of a people that for centuries have been leaders in commercial and manufacturing industry and enterprise.

London is located as close to the center of the Earth’s land surface as possible. This central position makes it ideally suited to be the main hub for global trade and the primary distribution center for the world’s products. Its ships can reach the farthest corners of the globe, collecting natural products from these areas and bringing them back to its docks without unloading, where they can be sorted and then sent off to other locations around the world, all done more cost-effectively than from almost any other port. A bigger reason for this is that for centuries, the British people have followed a clear strategy of manufacturing, trade, and commerce, and they've been fortunate that this approach has faced less disruption from trade-harming wars, both internal and external, than any other nation. Whenever Britain has faced external conflicts, its navy has been able to safeguard its commercial interests. London, as the capital and main trading center of the kingdom, has naturally benefited the most from these many years of stable industry and commerce. Additionally, London is well-situated for trade within the country itself. It is a seaport located sixty miles inland and is linked by navigable canals to all the other major manufacturing and commercial centers across the nation. Its railway connections are so comprehensive that there isn't a manufacturing town on the entire island that's more than fifteen hours away by freight. Moreover, the unique layout of Great Britain's coastline means every part of the island is only an hour or two from a seaport. Lastly, all British seaports are connected to London by a coastal service unmatched in the world for its affordability, thoroughness, and effectiveness. In summary, London is not only at the center of the world's land surface but also at the commercial center of its own territory, easily accessible by both water and land to all trading and production interests of a people who have been leaders in commerce and manufacturing for centuries.

GREAT BRITAIN'S COMMERCIAL POLICY

But that which more than anything else has made London the great trade centre of the world has been the policy, now for many years adopted by the British people, of allowing the goods and products of all other nations to enter their ports untaxed. Every port in Britain is a free port of entry for all imported merchandise except spirits, tobacco, wine, tea, coffee, cocoa, and chicory; and ships of all nations are allowed to trade at British ports upon terms exactly the same as those laid down for British ships. The result is that Britain has become the entrepôt or distributing mart for the produce of the world. Ships of all nations are found at[74] her wharves, and commodities from all parts of the world brought in those ships are found in her warehouses. Her mercantile navy numbers 21,000 vessels, and 8000 of these are steamships. The tonnage of these vessels amounts to over 8,750,000 tons, and of this nearly 8,000,000 is engaged in the foreign trade alone. Her mercantile sailors number over 250,000 men, and over 150,000 of these are engaged in the foreign trade. London is, of course, the chief gainer from this perfect unrestriction of trade. Twenty-seven per cent. of the whole trade of the country is in its hands. Its merchants do business in every seaport on the globe, and the trade of Great Britain with ports in Europe, the Levant, Egypt, India, the East Indies, China, Japan, and Australasia, is almost wholly controlled by them. Its shipping embraces the finest trading fleets known to commerce. Its docks and wharves extend on either side of the Thames for twenty-four miles from London Bridge down to Gravesend, and are the largest and finest in the world.

But what has really made London the biggest trade center in the world is the British people's long-standing policy of letting goods and products from all other nations enter their ports without taxes. Every port in Britain is a free entry point for all imported goods except for spirits, tobacco, wine, tea, coffee, cocoa, and chicory; ships from all nations can trade at British ports on the same terms as British ships. As a result, Britain has become the hub or distribution center for the world's products. Ships from every nation can be seen at[74] its docks, and goods from around the world that arrive on those ships are stored in its warehouses. The commercial navy has 21,000 vessels, with 8,000 of them being steamships. The total tonnage of these vessels exceeds 8,750,000 tons, with nearly 8,000,000 tons dedicated to foreign trade alone. There are over 250,000 merchant sailors, with more than 150,000 involved in foreign trade. Naturally, London is the main beneficiary of this complete freedom of trade. Twenty-seven percent of the country’s total trade is handled here. Its merchants operate in every seaport across the globe, and the trades between Great Britain and ports in Europe, the Levant, Egypt, India, the East Indies, China, Japan, and Australasia are almost entirely managed by them. Its shipping includes the finest trading fleets known in commerce. Its docks and wharves stretch for twenty-four miles on either side of the Thames from London Bridge to Gravesend, making them the largest and best in the world.

British mercantile marine. Compared with that of other countries. British merchant navy. Compared to that of other countries.

[75]LONDON THE CLEARING-HOUSE OF THE WORLD

A similar explanation is to be given of the fact that London is the great financial centre of the world. The same policy which has made Britain a great trading country has also made her a great manufacturing country. The food products of all the world pour in upon her shores, and Britain has become a cheap place to live in. Her artisans are supplied with the best food that the world can produce, and this at prices that are practically what the British demand makes them to be. The British artisan is therefore both well fed and cheaply fed. As a consequence of this, British manufactures are produced more efficiently and more cheaply than those of most other nations, and they are therefore exported enormously to every quarter of the globe. London, from its accessibility with respect to the great manufacturing centres at home, and from its trade connections and facilities for trade abroad, is the great distributing centre of this enormous manufacture. London exporters have accounts for goods sold by them all the world over. There is,[76] therefore, no quarter of the world where money is not constantly owing to London; or, if not to London, then to Manchester, Birmingham, Sheffield, Leeds, Glasgow, or some other manufacturing centre in close financial touch with London. In this, then, lies the explanation of the financial supremacy of London. No matter in what quarter of the world money is owed by any place, the final destination of that money is London; for in almost all cases it will be found that the locality to which the money is owed, if it be not London, will itself be a debtor to London. London, therefore, from necessity, and as a matter of custom and convenience, has become the great clearing-house of the world. The final adjustments of the indebtedness of all the commercial centres of the world are made there.

A similar explanation applies to why London is the leading financial center in the world. The same policies that have made Britain a major trading nation have also turned it into a significant manufacturing hub. Food products from around the globe flood its shores, and Britain has become an affordable place to live. Workers have access to the best food available, and they pay prices shaped by their demands. As a result, British workers are both well-fed and able to eat cheaply. This leads to British goods being produced more efficiently and at lower costs than many other countries, causing exports to surge globally. London, due to its proximity to key manufacturing centers and its strong trade connections, serves as the primary distribution hub for this vast production. London exporters have accounts for goods sold worldwide. There is, [76] therefore, no part of the world where money isn’t regularly owed to London; if not to London, then to cities like Manchester, Birmingham, Sheffield, Leeds, Glasgow, or other manufacturing centers closely linked to London. This explains London's financial dominance. No matter where in the world money is owed, its ultimate destination is London; typically, the place that owes the money will end up owing London as well. Thus, London has naturally become the major clearing-house of the world. Final settlements of debts among all the commercial centers occur there.

London bridge. London Bridge.

[77]GREAT BRITAIN THE CREDITOR NATION OF THE WORLD

One other reason for the financial supremacy of London lies in the enormous wealth of Britain. For now almost half a century Britain has been importing far more than she has been exporting, and the total volume of her import and export trade is more than quadruple what it was in 1850. The consequence is that not only has Britain been accumulating wealth, but she has been accumulating it enormously. Her accumulated savings, therefore, have been at the world's disposal, and she has had so much money to invest that she has become the creditor nation of the world. The total investments of British capital in foreign countries (in loans, railways, manufacturing syndicates, etc.) is estimated to be the enormous sum of over $10,500,000,000. London, of course, is the investing, controlling, and supervising counting-house for all this capital. And as so much British capital finds in London its place of investment, it naturally follows that nearly all the remaining unemployed capital of the world, that seeks investment, either is sent to London as a market, or else assumes a price for investment elsewhere which the current price of capital in London warrants it to assume. The London market rate of capital, therefore, determines its market rate in every other commercial centre of the world.

One more reason for London’s financial dominance is the immense wealth of Britain. For almost fifty years now, Britain has been importing far more than it has been exporting, and the total volume of its import and export trade is more than four times what it was in 1850. As a result, not only has Britain been building up its wealth, but it has been doing so at an incredible rate. The savings it has accumulated are available for use worldwide, and it has so much money to invest that it has become the world’s creditor nation. The total investments of British capital in foreign countries (in loans, railways, manufacturing partnerships, etc.) is estimated to exceed $10.5 billion. London, of course, is the hub for investing, managing, and overseeing all this capital. Since so much British capital is invested in London, it follows that nearly all the remaining unused capital from around the world that seeks investment is either sent to London or adjusts its investment pricing elsewhere based on the current capital prices in London. Thus, the market rate for capital in London sets the standard for market rates in every other commercial center around the globe.

GREAT BRITAIN A BEEHIVE OF MERCANTILE AND MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY

Britain like all other civilised countries, was originally an agricultural country. Although for some centuries she has been one of the chief manufacturing and mercantile countries of the world, it has been only during the past[78] one hundred years, and especially during the past fifty years, that her development in manufactures and in commerce has been remarkable. Britain is still, in respect of quality, the foremost agricultural country on the globe. Her breeds of horses, cattle, sheep, and swine are the standard breeds from which almost all other breeds derive their origin, and by which from time to time they are improved. And nowhere is the raising of grains and roots for food of man and beast pursued with more skill and success than in Britain. But agriculture is fast ceasing to be an important industry of Britain. Two million acres less are under cultivation now than were cultivated fifty years ago. The total amount of wheat raised is sufficient only for three months' consumption of the people; the remaining quantity needed must be supplied by importation. Three fifths of the total population of the island live in towns, and only a small proportion of the population that live in the country is actually supported by agriculture. Agriculture, in fact, supports only fifteen per cent. of the population in all Britain, and in England only ten per cent. Three and a half times as many people are personally engaged in manufactures as in rural pursuits. For three quarters of a century the population in towns and cities has been growing four times faster than the population of the rural parts. At the same time the working power of the urban population has been constantly growing more effective. In fifty years, by the general adoption of machinery, the effective working power of the British workman has been increased sixfold. In England eighty-six per cent. of the total work of the country is done by steam, and in Scotland ninety per cent. Great Britain, therefore, has become practically one great beehive of mercantile and manufacturing industry. Agriculture as a general occupation of the people, except in the production of the finer food products,[79] such as choice beef and mutton and high-grade dairy products, is no longer profitable. Indeed, during the last fifteen years the plant (including land) employed in agricultural industries has been depreciating in value at the rate of $150,000,000 yearly; that is, in these fifteen years the enormous sum of $2,250,000,000 of capital employed in agriculture has been obliterated. But the gain to capital employed in profitable mercantile and manufacturing pursuits has much more than compensated for this enormous loss in agriculture.

Britain, like all other civilized countries, was originally an agricultural nation. Although it has been one of the leading manufacturing and trading nations in the world for centuries, it is only in the last[78] hundred years, especially the past fifty, that its growth in manufacturing and commerce has been remarkable. In terms of quality, Britain remains the top agricultural country worldwide. Its breeds of horses, cattle, sheep, and pigs are the standard from which almost all other breeds originate and are periodically improved. Nowhere are grains and root crops for human and animal consumption farmed with more skill and success than in Britain. However, agriculture is rapidly becoming a less significant industry in Britain. Two million acres less are currently in cultivation compared to fifty years ago. The total amount of wheat produced is enough for only three months of the population's consumption; the rest must be imported. Three-fifths of the island's total population resides in towns, and only a small percentage of those living in rural areas rely on agriculture for their livelihoods. In fact, agriculture supports only fifteen percent of the total population in Britain, and just ten percent in England. There are three and a half times more people engaged in manufacturing than in agricultural work. For the past seventy-five years, urban populations have been growing four times faster than rural populations. Meanwhile, the productivity of the urban workforce has continually increased. Over fifty years, the widespread use of machinery has increased the effective productivity of British workers sixfold. Currently, eighty-six percent of England's total work is done by steam, and in Scotland, it’s ninety percent. Thus, Great Britain has essentially become one massive hub of trade and manufacturing. Agriculture as a general occupation for the populace, except for producing higher-quality food products,[79] such as premium beef, lamb, and high-quality dairy products, is no longer financially viable. In fact, over the past fifteen years, the value of assets (including land) used in agricultural industries has depreciated at a rate of $150 million each year; over these fifteen years, an impressive total of $2.25 billion of capital tied up in agriculture has been lost. However, the profits from capital invested in prosperous commercial and manufacturing ventures have significantly outweighed this immense loss in agriculture.

GREAT BRITAIN'S COAL-FIELDS AND IRON DEPOSITS

One reason for the great development which Britain has made as a manufacturing and trading nation lies in the fact that Britain was the first nation to utilise on a large scale the power of steam as a help to manufacture and trade. The steam-engine was a British invention. The first railways were built in Britain. The first steamship to cross the Atlantic was a British enterprise. A second reason lies in the fact that when Britain began to use steam as a motive power she found her supplies of coal so near her iron mines, and so near her clays and earths needed for her potteries, that from the very first she was able to manufacture cheaply and undersell most of her competitors. Her coal-fields have an area of over 12,000 square miles, and wherever her coal-beds are other natural products have been found near by, so that her manufacturing areas and her coal areas are almost identical. Taking Liverpool, Manchester, Birmingham, Wolverhampton, Sheffield, Leeds, Newcastle, Durham, Bristol, Stoke, Carlisle, Cardiff, Swansea, Glasgow, Paisley, and Dundee as centres, around each of these lies a coal area of such richness as amply sustains it in its commercial and manufacturing pre-eminence. London is almost the only great commercial centre of Britain that does not lie in the midst of or quite adjacent to a rich coal and other mineral region. But London is within easy distance, not only by rail, but also by canal and by coastwise sailing, of every coal-field and mineral deposit of Britain. London, however, is an importing and exporting centre rather than a manufacturing centre.

One reason for Britain's significant growth as a manufacturing and trading nation is that it was the first country to widely use steam power to boost production and trade. The steam engine was invented in Britain. The first railways were established there. The first steamship to sail across the Atlantic was also a British venture. A second reason is that when Britain started using steam as a power source, it discovered its coal supplies were located close to its iron mines and near the clays and soils needed for pottery. This proximity allowed Britain to manufacture products cheaply and outshine most competitors from the very beginning. Its coalfields cover over 12,000 square miles, and wherever coal deposits are found, other natural resources are typically nearby. This means that Britain’s manufacturing regions are almost the same as its coal fields. Cities like Liverpool, Manchester, Birmingham, Wolverhampton, Sheffield, Leeds, Newcastle, Durham, Bristol, Stoke, Carlisle, Cardiff, Swansea, Glasgow, Paisley, and Dundee serve as hubs, each surrounded by rich coal areas that support their commercial and manufacturing success. London is almost the only major commercial center in Britain not located within or very close to a valuable coal or mineral region. However, London is easily accessible by rail, canal, and coastal routes to every coalfield and mineral deposit in the country. Still, London functions more as an importing and exporting center than a manufacturing one.

The coal-fields of England. The coalfields of England.

[81]LONDON'S SPECIAL TRADE FEATURES

The commercial supremacy attained by many of the large cities of Britain is not wholly due to natural causes, or even to ordinary causes. Much of it is due to extraordinary enterprise and forethought on the part of their citizens. London, for example, is the centre of the wool trade of Britain. The woollen manufacturers of Britain use about 250,000 tons of wool annually, and three fourths of this is imported. Other cities that lie near the seats of the great woollen manufactures—Liverpool, for example—have tried to secure a share of this vast importation of wool, but London, because of the special attention it gives to this trade, manages to keep almost the whole of the trade in its own hands. Similarly, London almost wholly monopolises the trade of England with Arabia, India, the East Indies, China, and Japan. It is therefore the great emporium for tea, coffee, sugar, spices, indigo, and raw silk. It also enjoys the bulk of Britain's trade in fruits (oranges, lemons, currants, raisins, figs, dates, etc.) and in wines, olive oil, and madder, with the countries that lie about the Mediterranean. By virtue partly of its situation, but largely because of the enterprise of its merchants, it absorbs nearly the whole of Britain's French trade, and of England's trade with Germany, Belgium, Holland, and Denmark. This includes principally wines (from France), and butter,[82] eggs, and vegetables. Another great branch of its trade is that with the ports of the Baltic, including those of Russia, the imports comprising, besides wheat and wool, tallow, timber, hemp, and linseed. The tobacco imported from Virginia into England goes almost wholly to London; so does almost the whole of the Central American and South American trade in fine woods, dye-stuffs, drugs, sugar, hides, india-rubber, coffee, and diamonds. Quite a large share of the trade of Britain with Canada is concentrated in London; also, more than one half of the trade of England with the West Indies, the imports from the latter country comprising principally sugar, molasses, fruit, rum, coffee, cocoa, fine woods, and ginger.

The commercial dominance achieved by many large cities in Britain isn't just because of natural factors or usual circumstances. A lot of it comes from the exceptional initiative and foresight of their residents. London, for instance, is the hub of Britain’s wool trade. Wool manufacturers in Britain use about 250,000 tons of wool each year, with three-quarters of that being imported. Other cities close to major wool production, like Liverpool, have attempted to grab a share of this enormous wool import, but London, due to its dedicated focus on this industry, manages to retain almost all of it. Likewise, London virtually monopolizes England’s trade with Arabia, India, the East Indies, China, and Japan. It stands as the primary marketplace for tea, coffee, sugar, spices, indigo, and raw silk. It also handles most of Britain’s fruit trade (oranges, lemons, currants, raisins, figs, dates, etc.) as well as wines, olive oil, and madder from Mediterranean countries. Thanks in part to its location, but largely because of its merchants' initiative, it captures nearly all of Britain’s trade with France and England's trade with Germany, Belgium, Holland, and Denmark, primarily including wines (from France), along with butter, eggs, and vegetables. Another significant part of its trade is with the Baltic ports, including those in Russia, with imports consisting mainly of wheat and wool, tallow, timber, hemp, and linseed. The tobacco imported from Virginia to England goes almost entirely to London, as does the majority of the trade in fine woods, dye-stuffs, drugs, sugar, hides, rubber, coffee, and diamonds from Central and South America. A substantial portion of Britain’s trade with Canada is centered in London, as well as over half of England's trade with the West Indies, with imports from that region mainly comprising sugar, molasses, fruit, rum, coffee, cocoa, fine woods, and ginger.

THE SPECIAL TRADE FEATURES OF GLASGOW, LIVERPOOL, AND MANCHESTER

The great commercial centres of Britain after London are Glasgow (800,000), Liverpool (700,000) and Manchester (640,000, including Salford). All these cities have derived the greater portion of their size from the progress they have made during the present century. All, of course, owe their progress and their prosperity largely to their natural advantages of situation, etc. Liverpool stands on the margin of the Atlantic, "the Mediterranean of the modern world," and thus enjoys the principal share of the trade with America, especially that with the United States. Great Britain's imports from the United States amount to over $500,000,000 per annum, and her exports to the United States (exclusive of bullion, etc.) to over $100,000,000. (Formerly the exports to the United States were twice this amount.) Of this vast trade, amounting to one fifth of Britain's total trade with the world, Liverpool enjoys the lion's share. Nearly all the cotton, not merely of the United States but of the[83] world, that is used in Europe is sent to Liverpool for distribution. Similarly, Glasgow, situated with its aspect directed toward the same maritime routes, enjoys also an immense transatlantic trade both north and south. And Manchester, situated in the very heart of the richest coal districts of the kingdom, and within easy reach of the great cotton port, Liverpool, has built up a cotton-manufacturing industry surpassing that of all the rest of the world.

The major commercial centers of Britain after London are Glasgow (800,000), Liverpool (700,000), and Manchester (640,000, including Salford). These cities have mostly grown due to their advancements in the current century. Their growth and success are largely thanks to their natural advantages and locations. Liverpool is located on the edge of the Atlantic, "the Mediterranean of the modern world," which allows it to handle most of the trade with America, particularly the United States. Great Britain imports over $500,000,000 worth of goods from the United States every year, while exports to the United States (excluding bullion and such) exceed $100,000,000. (In the past, the exports to the United States were double this amount.) Liverpool receives the largest share of this immense trade, which makes up one-fifth of Britain’s total trade with the world. Nearly all the cotton used in Europe, not just from the United States but from the [83] world, is sent to Liverpool for distribution. Likewise, Glasgow, positioned facing the same shipping routes, has a vast transatlantic trade both to the north and south. Manchester, located in the heart of the richest coal regions in the kingdom and close to the major cotton port, Liverpool, has developed a cotton-manufacturing industry that surpasses all the others worldwide.

THE BUSINESS ENTERPRISE OF GLASGOW, LIVERPOOL, AND MANCHESTER

But the natural advantages of situation possessed by these great cities have been grandly supplemented by the enterprise of their inhabitants. Glasgow is only a river port. For twenty miles below its site the Clyde is naturally narrow, shallow, and shoal-encumbered. In places it is naturally not more than fifteen inches deep. By the expenditure of no less a sum than $60,000,000 this shallow stream has been converted into a continuous harbour, lined on either side for miles with wharves and docks, and easily capable of accommodating the largest and finest merchant ships afloat. As a consequence of this enterprise Glasgow has become the greatest ship-building port in the world. No less than twenty shipyards—in efficiency and magnitude of the very highest class—are to be found along the banks of the once shallow, impassable Clyde, between Glasgow proper and the river's mouth.

But the natural advantages of location that these great cities have are significantly enhanced by the efforts of their residents. Glasgow is just a river port. For twenty miles downstream, the Clyde is naturally narrow, shallow, and filled with obstacles. In some areas, it's only about fifteen inches deep. By investing a whopping $60 million, this shallow river has been transformed into a continuous harbor, with miles of wharves and docks on both sides, capable of accommodating the largest and finest merchant ships in existence. As a result of this initiative, Glasgow has become the largest shipbuilding port in the world. There are at least twenty shipyards—among the most efficient and largest—to be found along the banks of the once shallow, impassable Clyde, stretching from Glasgow itself to the river's mouth.

Similarly, the enterprise of the ship merchants of Liverpool has converted a port, that high tides and impassable bars would naturally render unfit for modern ships, into the greatest shipping port in the world. One hundred million dollars were spent in making the im[84]provement, but $5,000,000 is the annual revenue derived therefrom in dock dues alone. And because of this enterprise Liverpool can now boast of controlling one fourth of all the imports of the kingdom, and two fifths of all the exports, and of handling three fourths of all the grain and provision trade of the kingdom, and of having the largest grain warehouses in the world.

Similarly, the efforts of the ship merchants of Liverpool have turned a port that high tides and impassable bars would make unsuitable for modern ships into the largest shipping port in the world. One hundred million dollars were invested in the [84] improvement, but the annual revenue from dock fees alone is $5,000,000. Because of this initiative, Liverpool can now proudly claim to control one-fourth of all the kingdom's imports, two-fifths of all its exports, and to handle three-fourths of all the grain and provision trade, as well as having the largest grain warehouses in the world.

The Manchester ship canal. The Manchester Ship Canal.

But Manchester, a wholly inland city, forty miles distant from Liverpool, its nearest port, has outdone even Glasgow and Liverpool in its endeavour to bring the sea to its own doors. It also has spent $100,000,000—not, however, in amounts spread over a number of years, and as occasion seemed to demand, but all at once, in one lump sum, in one huge enterprise. It has built a canal to the Mersey where it is navigable, thirty-five and one half miles in length, and sufficiently deep and wide, so that the whole of its vast importation of cotton, and the whole of its vast manufacture of cotton and other[85] textile fabrics, and as much else as may be desired, may be brought in from the sea or taken to the sea in merchant vessels of the very largest size now afloat. And it has done this in the face of engineering difficulties, and of obstacles raised against it by jealous competing interests that were almost insurmountable.

But Manchester, a completely inland city, forty miles away from Liverpool, its closest port, has surpassed even Glasgow and Liverpool in its efforts to bring the sea to its own doorstep. It has invested $100,000,000—not spread out over several years or as needed, but all at once, in one large project. It has constructed a canal to the Mersey where it's navigable, stretching thirty-five and a half miles and deep and wide enough for its entire massive import of cotton, and for all its extensive production of cotton and other[85] textile goods, as well as whatever else may be needed, to be brought in from the sea or shipped out to the sea in the largest merchant vessels currently afloat. And it has accomplished this despite significant engineering challenges and obstacles created by jealous competing interests that were nearly impossible to overcome.

GREAT BRITAIN'S SPECIALISATION OF HER INDUSTRIES IN DEFINITE CENTRES

In no part of the world are manufacture and trade carried on with such strict regard to the conditions of economic production and the economic handling of goods as in the British Isles. The free-trade policy of the empire permits everywhere within its borders not merely national but world-wide competition; and yet it is but truth to say that wherever Great Britain attempts to sell her goods abroad every nation and every community in the world rises against her. Even her colonies are against her. Her markets are open to every one's trade, and yet in almost every market in the world which she does not absolutely control barriers are raised against her trade. She is able to sell goods in foreign markets only because, despite these barriers, she is able to undersell all competitors in them, or to give better value for the same money than they. Even when she obtains the control of new markets, as she has in India, China, Egypt, West Africa, etc., she allows every nation to trade in these markets on precisely the same terms as she herself trades in them. In the face of this world-wide competition, therefore, the industries of Britain would cease to exist if every condition conducive to economy of production—climatic suitability, availability of cheap motive power, accessibility to cheap raw material, and accessibility to natural and cheap means of transportation[86]—were not taken advantage of to the utmost. But this is just what Britain does. She does take advantage to the utmost of conditions conducive to economy of production; and this is why, to a degree nowhere else attempted in the world, she has specialised her industries in definite favouring localities.

In no part of the world are manufacturing and trade conducted with such strict attention to the conditions of economic production and the efficient handling of goods as in the British Isles. The empire's free-trade policy allows for not just national but global competition within its borders; however, it’s true that wherever Great Britain tries to sell its products internationally, every nation and community rises against it. Even its colonies are not in favor. Its markets are open to everyone’s trade, yet in almost every market globally that it doesn’t fully control, barriers are erected against its commerce. Great Britain can sell goods in foreign markets only because, despite these barriers, it can sell for less than all its competitors or provide better value for the same price. Even when it secures control of new markets, as it has in India, China, Egypt, West Africa, etc., it allows every nation to trade in those markets under the same terms as it does. Thus, facing this global competition, Britain's industries would not survive if every factor benefiting economic production—suitable climate, availability of inexpensive power sources, access to cheap raw materials, and convenient and affordable transportation—weren’t fully utilized. But this is exactly what Britain does. It fully leverages these conditions for economic production, which is why, to an extent not attempted anywhere else in the world, it has specialized its industries in specific advantageous locations.[86]

THE NATURAL APTITUDES OF COMMUNITIES IN GREAT BRITAIN FOR SPECIAL INDUSTRIES

A result of this specialisation of industries in definite centres is that a natural aptitude for the industry specialised in a locality is developed among the inhabitants of the locality, and this, being stimulated by association, is transmitted from generation to generation with ever-increasing efficiency. Again, this inherited aptitude of the community for the industry historically associated with it is a prime element in the economic prosecution of the industry. Also, in turn, it acts as an important influence in continuing the industry in the locality where once it has been successfully specialised. In no country in the world, outside of Asia, have great industries had such long-continued successful existence in definite localities as in Britain. And therefore in no country in the world do the natural aptitudes of communities for special industries constitute such an important element of economic industrial production. A community of efficient "smiths," for example, has existed in and about Birmingham since the fifteenth century. As a consequence of this the Birmingham country has for several centuries been the greatest seat of the metal or hardware industries in the world. Again, the manufacture of woollen cloths has been an industry successfully specialised in West Yorkshire from the fourteenth century. It results that nowhere in the world is the woollen manufacture car[87]ried on more prosperously than in West Yorkshire to-day. The potteries of Staffordshire have been in existence time out of mind, and in the eighteenth century they took a pre-eminent place among the industries of the world. They hold that place of pre-eminence now, even though since then the methods of manufacture have been several times revolutionised.

A result of this specialization of industries in specific areas is that the local residents develop a natural talent for the industry that is prominent there, and this talent, fueled by interaction, gets passed down through generations with growing effectiveness. Moreover, this inherited skill of the community for the industry tied to its history is a key factor in the economic pursuit of that industry. This, in turn, plays a significant role in keeping the industry thriving in the area where it has once been successfully established. In no other country in the world, outside of Asia, have major industries maintained such long-lasting success in specific locations as they have in Britain. Consequently, in no other country do the innate skills of communities in specialized industries represent such a crucial element of economic industrial production. For instance, a community of skilled "smiths" has existed in and around Birmingham since the fifteenth century. As a result, Birmingham has been the leading center for metal or hardware industries globally for several centuries. Similarly, the production of woolen cloth has been a successfully specialized industry in West Yorkshire since the fourteenth century. This means that nowhere else in the world is woolen manufacturing as successful as it is in West Yorkshire today. The potteries in Staffordshire have been around for ages, and in the eighteenth century, they became a leading player in global industries. They still hold that prominent position now, even though the manufacturing methods have undergone several revolutions since then.

THE COTTON MANUFACTURES OF GREAT BRITAIN

But the influence which more than anything else has determined the specialisation of industries in certain places in Britain rather than in others has been the presence of coal-fields. In only a very few instances have great industries been maintained in districts that are not coal-producing. The busiest industrial centre in all Britain is, perhaps, South Lancashire, the great seat of the cotton manufacture. South Lancashire is one great coal-field. Liverpool, the great cotton port of the world, is at one edge of this field. Manchester, the cotton metropolis of the world, is at the other edge. Between and near these two chief towns is a whole nest of large towns and cities—Preston, Burnley, Blackburn, Rochdale, Bolton, Bury, Ashton, Stockport, Oldham, etc.—every one of which is wholly devoted to the cotton interest. From their position all these towns obtain both their motive power and their raw material at the lowest possible cost. But, in addition to its advantages of cheap coal and cheap raw material, South Lancashire has one other great advantage in favour of its special industry—its climate is eminently suited to the industry. Its atmosphere is moist, and not too moist, and its temperature is not too cold. Cotton thread can be spun and woven in Lancashire which elsewhere would break. In scarcely any other place in England has cotton-weaving [88]or cotton-spinning ever proved a success. The cotton industry of Scotland is not so localised as it is in England, but Paisley (65,000) is famous all the world over for its identification with the manufacture of cotton thread. Ireland has no important cotton manufactures except in Belfast. One third of the cotton manufactured in the world is manufactured in the United Kingdom. The total product is about 14,000 miles of cloth daily. The number of separate mills is over 2500. The annual product is $500,000,000, which is one hundred times what it was one hundred years ago. The quantity of raw cotton imported annually to sustain this immense production is 1,750,000 pounds.

But the main factor that has influenced the specialization of industries in certain areas of Britain rather than others has been the presence of coalfields. In only a few cases have large industries thrived in regions that don’t produce coal. The busiest industrial center in all of Britain is probably South Lancashire, the major hub of the cotton production. South Lancashire is one massive coalfield. Liverpool, the world’s leading cotton port, sits at one edge of this field. Manchester, the cotton capital of the world, is at the other edge. Nestled between and near these two main cities are many large towns and cities—Preston, Burnley, Blackburn, Rochdale, Bolton, Bury, Ashton, Stockport, Oldham, and others—each fully dedicated to the cotton industry. Their location allows these towns to access both their power sources and their raw materials at the lowest possible costs. Additionally, beyond the benefits of cheap coal and raw materials, South Lancashire has another significant advantage for its specialized industry—its climate is particularly well-suited for it. The atmosphere is adequately moist, but not excessively so, and the temperature is not too cold. Cotton thread can be spun and woven in Lancashire that would break in other locations. Rarely has cotton weaving [88] or cotton spinning achieved success elsewhere in England. The cotton industry in Scotland is less localized than in England, but Paisley pattern (65,000) is renowned worldwide for its association with cotton thread manufacturing. Ireland has no significant cotton manufacturing except in Belfast. One-third of the world’s cotton is produced in the United Kingdom. The total output is about 14,000 miles of cloth every day. The number of individual mills exceeds 2,500. The annual production value is $500,000,000, which is one hundred times what it was a century ago. The amount of raw cotton imported each year to support this vast production is 1,750,000 pounds.

The great manufacturing districts of England. The major manufacturing areas of England.

[89]THE WOOLLEN MANUFACTURES OF GREAT BRITAIN

A second great industry of Great Britain is its woollen manufacture. This industry is specialised in England, principally in West Yorkshire, a district which is as well supplied with coal as is South Lancashire. Leeds (410,000) and Bradford (232,000) are the two principal seats of the industry, but Huddersfield and Halifax are also important "cloth towns," and many other communities are identified with the manufacture of woollens. The noted "West of England" cloths are made principally in Gloucestershire, where their manufacture in the town of Stroud is a survival of an ancient industry once general throughout the whole county. In Scotland there are two centres of the woollen industry. The first and most important is in southeast Scotland, where, in the valley of the Tweed (in Galashiels, Hawick, Jedburgh, etc.), the celebrated "Scotch tweeds" are manufactured. The second is in the valley of the Teith (Stirling, Bannockburn, etc.). At one time the sheep that were pastured on the wolds of Yorkshire were the chief supply of the raw material for this industry in the whole of Britain, but that time is now long past. The total annual import of wool into the United Kingdom is about 750,000 pounds, of which about one half is retained for home manufacture. Two thirds of this import comes from[90] Australia. The number of wool and worsted factories in the kingdom aggregates over 2750. The value of the woollen goods produced annually is about $250,000,000, which is about one fourth of the total product of the world.

A second major industry in Great Britain is its wool production. This industry is concentrated in England, primarily in West Yorkshire, a region that has an abundant supply of coal, similar to South Lancashire. Leeds (410,000) and Bradford (232,000) are the main hubs of this industry, but Huddersfield and Halifax are also significant "cloth towns," with many other communities involved in woolen production. The well-known "West of England" cloths are mainly produced in Gloucestershire, where their manufacturing in the town of Stroud is a remnant of an ancient industry that once thrived throughout the entire county. In Scotland, there are two main centers for the woolen industry. The first and most significant is in southeast Scotland, where celebrated "Scotch tweeds" are made in the valley of the Tweed (in Galashiels, Hawick, Jedburgh, etc.). The second is in the valley of the Teith (Stirling, Bannockburn, etc.). Once, the sheep that grazed on the wolds of Yorkshire were the primary source of raw material for this industry throughout Britain, but that era has long passed. The total annual wool import into the United Kingdom is about 750,000 pounds, with roughly half of it allocated for domestic manufacturing. Two-thirds of this import comes from [90] Australia. The number of wool and worsted factories in the UK exceeds 2,750. The annual value of woolen goods produced is around $250,000,000, which accounts for about a quarter of the world's total production.

THE LINEN MANUFACTURES OF GREAT BRITAIN

The third great textile manufacture of the United Kingdom is that of linens. This is the one manufacture in which Ireland surpasses her sister kingdoms, England and Scotland. The cultivation of flax and the spinning of linen yarn have been domestic industries throughout all Ireland from time immemorial. But at the present time the linen-manufacturing industry of Ireland is almost wholly concentrated in Belfast. In Scotland, which now almost rivals Ireland in the extent and perfection of her linen manufactures, the industry is principally located in Fifeshire and Forfarshire, especially in the towns of Dundee and Dunfermline, the latter town being greatly famed for its napery and table linens. Linen, like cotton, requires a peculiar atmospheric condition of temperature and moisture for its manufacture, and only in few localities has the linen industry been successfully established. The total value of the annual linen manufacture of the United Kingdom is $100,000,000.

The third major textile industry in the United Kingdom is that of bedding. This is the one area where Ireland outshines England and Scotland. The growing of flax and the spinning of linen yarn have been household activities across Ireland for ages. However, today, Ireland's linen manufacturing is almost entirely based in Belfast. In Scotland, which has nearly caught up to Ireland in terms of the scale and quality of its linen production, the industry is mainly found in Fifeshire and Forfarshire, especially in the towns of Dundee and Dunfermline, the latter being well-known for its napery and table linens. Like cotton, linen needs specific temperature and moisture conditions for production, and only a few areas have managed to successfully establish the linen industry. The total annual value of linen manufacturing in the United Kingdom is $100,000,000.

OTHER TEXTILE MANUFACTURES OF GREAT BRITAIN

The annual value of the total manufacture of textile fabrics in the British Isles is about $1,000,000,000—not far short, indeed, of one fourth of the total manufacture of textile fabrics in all the world. Great Britain has over $1,000,000,000 invested in her textile industry, and one half of her total exports consists of[91] textile manufactures. Cotton, woollen, and linen cloths are the chief staples of this industry, but there are many other branches of it and many other localities in which it is specialised besides the ones already mentioned. Leicester (204,000), which, like so many other manufacturing cities of England, lies at the centre of a coal-field, is the chief seat of the wollen hosiery manufacture. Dumfries is the chief seat of the woollen hosiery manufacture in Scotland. Kidderminster, in Worcestershire, is the chief seat of the "Brussels" carpet industry; Wilton, in Wiltshire, of the Wilton carpet industry. Kilmarnock, in Ayrshire, is the chief seat of the carpet manufacture in Scotland. Nottingham (233,000) is the metropolis of the cotton hosiery and lace manufacture of England. Norwich (110,000), in eastern England, has a noted manufacture of muslins and fine dress-goods. The Norwich textile manufacture is an instance of the continuance of an industry in a community historically associated with it, although its seat is far removed from a coal-field. The silk manufacture of Great Britain is almost entirely confined to the county of Derby and adjacent districts in England. Macclesfield, in Cheshire, is the chief centre. Coventry is noted for its silk ribbons and gauzes. But the manufacture of silk in Britain is not prospering like that of her other textile fabrics. In fact, in forty years it has depreciated three fourths. British silk manufacturers are not as adept in weighting their products with dyes as their French competitors are, and in consequence English silks, though intrinsically better than French silks, look inferior and therefore cannot be sold at profitable prices. But, on the other hand, the jute manufacture of Great Britain is increasing by leaps and bounds. Established only sixty years ago, the value of its annual output is now twice that of the whole manufacture of silk, and in[92] twenty-five years has tripled. The chief seat of this industry is Dundee (160,000), in Scotland.

The annual value of all textile fabric production in the British Isles is around $1 billion—not far off from a quarter of the total textile production in the entire world. Great Britain has over $1 billion invested in its textile industry, and half of its total exports are made up of[91] textile products. Cotton, wool, and linen fabrics are the main staples of this industry, but there are many other branches and areas where it specializes beyond those mentioned. Leicester (204,000), like many other manufacturing cities in England, is located at the center of a coal field and is the main hub for wool socks production. Dumfries is the primary center for woolen hosiery in Scotland. Kidderminster, in Worcestershire, is the main area for the "Brussels" carpet industry, while Wilton, in Wiltshire, leads in the Wilton carpet industry. Kilmarnock, in Ayrshire, is the central location for carpet manufacturing in Scotland. Nottingham (233,000) is the capital of cotton hosiery and lace production in England. Norwich (110,000), in eastern England, is known for its muslins and fine dress goods. The textile manufacturing in Norwich is an example of an industry persisting in a community historically linked to it, even though it's far from a coal field. The silk industry in Great Britain is almost entirely concentrated in Derbyshire and nearby regions in England. Macclesfield, in Cheshire, is the leading center for silk production. Coventry is recognized for its silk ribbons and gauzes. However, the silk industry in Britain isn't thriving like its other textile sectors. In fact, over the past forty years, it has declined by three-quarters. British silk manufacturers struggle to match the skill of French competitors in dyeing their fabrics; as a result, English silks, despite being of higher quality than French ones, appear inferior and cannot be sold at profitable rates. Conversely, the jute industry in Great Britain is rapidly growing. Established only sixty years ago, its annual output is now worth twice that of the entire silk industry, and it has tripled in the last[92] twenty-five years. The main hub of this industry is Dundee (160,000), in Scotland.

THE HARDWARE MANUFACTURES OF GREAT BRITAIN

The textile manufactures of Great Britain are in the aggregate first in importance, but the hardware manufactures come a close second. The total amount of Great Britain's hardware products is about $750,000,000, or one fourth of the total product of the world, and of this about one third is exported. Even more than her textile fabrics, the hardware manufactures of Great Britain are associated with her coal-fields. The most distinctive "hardware centre" is that one which is identified with the great coal-field in the middle of England known as the "Black Country." Birmingham (506,000), the chief place in this centre, is unrivalled in the world for the multifariousness and extent of its metal manufactures. It is literally true that everything from a "needle to an anchor" is made within its limits. But though its industries comprise principally those of iron and steel, its manufactures in gold, silver, copper, zinc, lead, and aluminium are also very important. Birmingham, too, is unrivalled in the world in the application of art to metal work. Its manufacture of jewellery, and gold and silver ornaments, is enormous. Its manufacture of small wares is also enormous. For example, it turns out 15,000,000 pens weekly. Its manufacture of buttons runs into the hundreds of thousands of millions. Wolverhampton (88,000), also in the Black Country, is noted for its manufacture of heavy hardware and machinery. So also in Oldham, in the Lancashire district. So also in Leeds, in the West Yorkshire district. Sheffield (352,000), also in Yorkshire, is historically identified with its celebrated cutlery manufacture, an industry that first began there because of the quality and[93] abundance of the grindstones found near by. With the coal-beds of Durham and Cumberland are identified the great ship-building and locomotive-building industries of Newcastle (218,000), Sunderland (142,000), and Darlington, on the northeast side of England, and the great steel manufactures (the largest in the kingdom) and ship-building industries of Barrow-on-Furness, on the northwest side. With the coal-fields of South Wales (noted for its smokeless coal) are identified the smelting industries of Swansea (70,000). Ores of copper especially, but also of silver, zinc, and lead, are brought from all over the world to Swansea to be smelted. These South Wales coal-fields also account for the fact that in respect to amount of tonnage Cardiff (160,000) is one of the chief ports for exports in the world, ranking in this respect next after New York. The exports of coal from Cardiff are now 12,000,000 tons annually.

The textile industry in Great Britain is the most significant overall, but the hardware industry is a close second. Great Britain's total hardware production is about $750,000,000, which is one-fourth of the world's total, with roughly one-third of that being exported. More than its textile products, Great Britain's hardware industry is tied to its coal fields. The main "hardware hub" is linked to the major coal field in central England known as the "Black Country." Birmingham (506,000), the leading area in this hub, is unmatched globally for the variety and scale of its metal manufacturing. It’s true that everything from a "needle to an anchor" is produced within the city. While its industries mainly focus on iron and steel, it also has significant production in gold, silver, copper, zinc, lead, and aluminum. Birmingham excels in incorporating art into metalwork. Its production of jewelry and gold and silver items is immense, and it also produces a massive quantity of small goods, like 15,000,000 pens weekly. Its button production numbers in the hundreds of billions. Wolves (88,000), also in the Black Country, is known for heavy hardware and machinery manufacturing. The same goes for Oldham in Lancashire and Leeds in West Yorkshire. Sheffield (352,000), in Yorkshire, is historically recognized for its famous cutlery manufacturing, which started due to the quality and abundance of local grindstones. The coalfields of Durham and Cumberland are linked to the major shipbuilding and locomotive-building industries in Newcastle (218,000), Sunderland (142,000), and Darlington to Barrow-in-Furness in the northwest. The coal fields of South Wales, known for its smokeless coal, are associated with the smelting industries in Swansea (70,000). Copper ores, in particular, along with silver, zinc, and lead, are sourced from around the globe to be smelted in Swansea. These coalfields in South Wales also explain why Cardiff (160,000) is one of the leading export ports in the world, ranking just behind New York. Cardiff now exports 12,000,000 tons of coal each year.

[94]II. THE TRADE FEATURES OF FRANCE

FRANCE A RICHLY FAVOURED COUNTRY

France by nature is one of the most highly favoured countries in the world. Its climate is genial. Its temperature is so varied that almost every vegetable, grain or fruit needed for the sustenance of man may be raised within its borders. Its soil, though not surprisingly fertile, yet yields abundantly such products as are suited to it. Its mineral resources, especially in coal, iron, lead, marble, and salt, are very considerable. Its area is compact. Its facilities for foreign commerce are unsurpassed. It lies between the two bodies of water—the Atlantic and the Mediterranean—of greatest commercial importance in the world. And its people, especially those in rural parts, are exceptionally frugal and industrious. But France as a nation has not made the progress in the world that its natural advantages call for. It has been cursed with expensive and unstable governments and sanguinary wars. Its upper classes, the natural leaders of its peoples, are excessively fond of pleasure and military glory, and the energies of the nation have been much misdirected. As a consequence, despite its natural advantages, France is losing ground[95] among the nations of the world. Its national debt amounts to nearly $7,000,000,000, the largest national debt known in history, being per head of population seventeen and one half times as great as that of Germany, six times as great as that of the United States, and much more than one and one half times as great as that of Great Britain. But, what is of more serious consequence, the vitality of its people seems debilitated. For years the annual number of births in France has been steadily decreasing, while the annual number of deaths has been more or less increasing. Over a great part of the country the number of deaths annually exceeds the number of births. In numerous years this is so for the whole country. The birth rate is the lowest in Europe. The death rate, while not the highest, is yet higher than in many other countries. As a consequence of all this the population of France is almost stationary. During the last seventy years it has increased only 18 per cent., while that of Great Britain has increased 63 per cent., Germany 75 per cent., Russia 92 per cent., and Europe as a whole 62 per cent. And even this increase, small as it is, is largely due to immigration from other countries. Nor is the emigration of Frenchmen to their colonies or to other countries to be set down as a sufficient explanation. The French are averse to emigration. At the present time the number of Frenchmen residing abroad is only a little more than half a million, while of foreigners residing in France the number is not far short of a million and a quarter.

France is naturally one of the most fortunate countries in the world. Its climate is mild, and its temperature is so varied that almost every vegetable, grain, or fruit needed for people's sustenance can be grown within its borders. While its soil may not be incredibly fertile, it still produces abundantly products that are suitable for it. Its mineral resources, especially coal, iron, lead, marble, and salt, are quite significant. Its area is compact, and its facilities for foreign trade are unmatched. It sits between the two most commercially important bodies of water in the world—the Atlantic and the Mediterranean. Plus, its people, especially those in rural areas, are particularly frugal and hard-working. However, as a nation, France has not made the progress in the world that its natural advantages suggest it should. It has been plagued by costly and unstable governments and bloody wars. Its upper classes, who should naturally lead its people, are overly focused on pleasure and military glory, resulting in much misdirection of the nation’s energies. Consequently, despite its natural advantages, France is losing ground among the nations of the world. Its national debt is nearly $7,000,000,000, the largest national debt in history, amounting to per capita debts seventeen and a half times greater than Germany's, six times greater than the United States', and more than one and a half times greater than Great Britain's. More seriously, the vitality of its people seems weakened. For years, the annual number of births in France has steadily declined while the annual number of deaths has gradually increased. In many regions of the country, fatalities exceed births annually. In numerous years, this has been true for the entire country. The birth rate is the lowest in Europe. The death rate, though not the highest, is still greater than in many other countries. As a result, France's population is almost stagnant. Over the last seventy years, it has increased by only 18 percent, while Great Britain's has grown by 63 percent, Germany’s by 75 percent, Russia's by 92 percent, and Europe as a whole by 62 percent. Even this small increase can be largely attributed to immigration from other countries. The emigration of French citizens to their colonies or to other countries cannot fully explain this situation, as the French tend to be resistant to emigration. Currently, the number of French citizens living abroad is just a little over half a million, while the number of foreigners living in France is close to one and a quarter million.[95]

France, compared in size with the States of Illinois and Texas. France is similar in size to the states of Illinois and Texas.

[96]THE FRENCH A THRIFTY, FRUGAL PEOPLE

When France is compared with other countries in respect of commercial development and progress, the results will in almost every particular turn out unfavourable to France. For example, since the close of the Napoleonic wars eighty-three years ago the national trade of Great Britain has quadrupled, while that of France has only trebled. At the close of the Franco-German war France was eighteen per cent. ahead of Germany in the carrying power of her shipping. Now Germany is seventy[97] per cent. ahead of France in that respect. But it must be remembered that the Franco-German war cost France in army expenses and in indemnity no less a sum than $3,250,000,000. The effect of that tremendous expenditure upon the prosperity of the nation can be estimated by one comparison. Since that war the annual average savings per inhabitant in France have been $17. For the same period the annual average savings per inhabitant in Great Britain have been $19.50. Had that war not occurred the average annual savings per inhabitant in France would have been $21.50. In short, no people in Europe are comparable with the working classes of the French people in frugality and thrift, and because of this characteristic, if France were well governed, its prosperity would be equal to that of any country in the world, and this would be so in spite of the fact that France's interest bill imposes a tax of $6.50 a year on every inhabitant of the country.

When you compare France to other countries regarding commercial development and progress, the results are generally unfavorable for France. For instance, since the end of the Napoleonic wars eighty-three years ago, Britain's national trade has quadrupled, whereas France's has only tripled. At the end of the Franco-German war, France was eighteen percent ahead of Germany in shipping capacity. Now, Germany is seventy[97] percent ahead of France in that regard. It’s important to note that the Franco-German war cost France around $3.25 billion in military expenses and reparations. The impact of this massive expenditure on the country's prosperity can be shown by one comparison. Since that war, the average annual savings per person in France have been $17, while in Great Britain, it's been $19.50. If the war hadn’t happened, the average annual savings per person in France would have been $21.50. In short, no other people in Europe are as frugal and thrifty as the French working class, and because of this trait, if France were better governed, its prosperity could match that of any country in the world, despite the fact that France's interest payments impose a tax of $6.50 a year on every resident.

Street scene in Paris, showing the Bourse. Street scene in Paris featuring the Bourse.

[98]THE IMPORTANCE OF AGRICULTURE IN FRANCE

France has one element of stability, one characteristic inducive of thriftiness, that most other countries of Europe lack. In most other European countries the land is held by few proprietors. In France it is held by many. In Great Britain and Ireland, for example, the land that is devoted to agriculture is held by only 19,000 proprietors. In France it is held by 3,500,000 proprietors. There are also 3,500,000 district farms in France, though only sixty per cent. of the farm land of the country is cultivated by the owners. It follows from this that agriculture has in France a hold upon the affections and self-interest of the people that it has in no other country in the world. About forty-two per cent. of the total population of the country able to work are employed in agricultural pursuits. Agriculture, therefore, is one of the most important industries of France. One fifth of the total earnings of her people are made in agriculture. It cannot be said, however, that agriculture in France is pursued as successfully as it is in some other countries—in Great Britain, for example. France, with sometimes the exception of Russia, is the largest wheat-grower of all the nations of Europe, but its production of grain per acre is not more than four sevenths that of Great Britain, while its production of grain per farming hand is only two thirds that of Great Britain. But so much of the agricultural effort of France is devoted to such industries as can be carried on in small farms or holdings—potato-raising, for example, and fruit-raising and poultry-raising—that the total money product per acre in France[99] is not far short of what it is in Great Britain. That is to say, while agriculture is more profitably carried on in Great Britain than in France, it proportionately supports a larger number of people in France than in Great Britain.

France has one stable feature, one trait that encourages thriftiness, which most other European countries lack. In many other European nations, land is owned by a small number of proprietors. In France, however, it is owned by many. For instance, in Great Britain and Ireland, only 19,000 owners control the land used for agriculture, while in France, there are 3,500,000 owners. France also has 3,500,000 small farms, although only sixty percent of the agricultural land is cultivated by its owners. This leads to agriculture in France holding a special place in the hearts and interests of its people, unlike in any other country in the world. About forty-two percent of those able to work in France are employed in agriculture, making it one of the most significant industries. One fifth of the total earnings of the population comes from agriculture. However, it's worth noting that agriculture in France doesn't reach the same level of success as in some other countries, such as Great Britain. France, sometimes alongside Russia, is the largest wheat producer in Europe, but its grain production per acre is only about four-sevenths of that in Great Britain, and its grain production per worker is just two-thirds of Great Britain's. Nonetheless, a large portion of France's agricultural efforts goes towards industries suited for small farms, like potato, fruit, and poultry farming, so the total monetary output per acre in France[99] is not far off from that in Great Britain. In other words, while agriculture is more profitable in Great Britain than in France, it supports a larger number of people in France proportionately compared to Great Britain.

FRANCE'S WATERWAYS AND RAILWAYS

France, like Germany, is well supplied with navigable rivers, and these, with its canals, constitute a complete network of navigable waterways that cover all the country and greatly promote the internal commerce of the nation. These navigable rivers aggregate 5500 miles, and the navigable canals over 3100 miles. The tonnage of goods carried on these waterways compares quite favourably with that carried by the railways. The railways aggregate 25,000 miles.

France, just like Germany, has plenty of navigable rivers, and together with its canals, they create a comprehensive network of navigable waterways that spans the entire country and greatly enhances internal trade. These navigable rivers total 5,500 miles, while the navigable canals cover over 3,100 miles. The amount of goods transported on these waterways compares very favorably to what the railways carry. The railways cover a total of 25,000 miles.

THE DISTINCTIVE AND IMPORTANT MANUFACTURES OF FRANCE

The most distinctive manufacture of France, the one in which she surpasses all other countries of the world, is the silk manufacture. France's total production of silk is not far short of one third of the total production of the world. Lyons (466,000), on the Rhone, is the chief seat of the industry, having had this pre-eminence ever since the Jacquard loom was invented there at the beginning of this century. Its production is not far short of three fourths of the total production of the country. The most important manufacture of France, however, is her manufacture of woollens. In this manufacture she comes next after Great Britain, her total production being a little ahead of that of both Germany and the United States. Her woollen mills number over 2000. Her consumption of wool for this industry is about three[100] fourths that of Great Britain, but the value of her production is only two thirds that of Britain. Lille (216,000) and Rheims (108,000) are the chief seats of the woollen industry. Of about equal value with the woollen manufacture of France is its hardware manufacture, but the importance of France's hardware manufacture is national rather than international. Of next importance is the manufacture of cottons and linens. The chief seats of these industries are, for cottons, Rouen (113,000), the "Manchester of France," and for linens, Lille. Near Lille is Cambrai, the chief place of manufacture for that finer class of linens known as cambrics. A second distinctive manufacture of France is that of glass and porcelain. In this manufacture France quite equals Great Britain in respect of value, and surpasses her in respect of the artistic character of the wares. Limoges (77,000) and St. Cloud (near Paris) are the chief seats of the French porcelain manufacture. It is at St. Cloud that the celebrated "Sèvres" porcelain is made.

The most notable industry in France, where it outpaces all other countries in the world, is the silk production. France's total silk production is almost one-third of the world's total. Lyons (466,000), located on the Rhone, is the main hub for this industry, maintaining this position since the Jacquard loom was invented there at the start of this century. Its production is nearly three-fourths of the country's total. However, the most significant industry in France is the production of knitwear. In this regard, France ranks just behind Great Britain, with its total production slightly exceeding that of both Germany and the United States. The country has over 2,000 woolen mills. Its wool consumption for this industry is approximately three[100] fourths of that of Great Britain, but the value of its production is only two-thirds that of Britain. Lille (216,000) and Reims (108,000) are the primary centers for the woolen industry. The value of France's tech production is on par with its woolen manufacture, but its hardware industry is more important nationally than internationally. Next in significance is the production of cotton and bedding. The main centers for these industries are Rouen (113,000), known as the "Manchester of France," for cottons, and Lille for linens. Nearby Lille is Cambrai, which is the primary location for producing finer linens, known as cambrics. Another notable industry in France is glass and ceramic. In terms of value, France is nearly equal to Great Britain and surpasses it in the artistic quality of its products. The main centers for French porcelain production are Limoges (77,000) and St. Cloud (near Paris). It is at St. Cloud where the famous "Sèvres" porcelain is produced.

PARIS AND THE GREAT SEAPORTS OF FRANCE

Paris (2,536,834) is, of course, the chief trade centre of all France, but the trade interests of Paris are general rather than special. The manufactures that are most localised in Paris are those of articles of luxury, such as jewellery, perfumery, gloves, fancy wares, novelties, and fashionable boots and shoes. Paris is also a great financial centre. Marseilles (442,000), one of the oldest cities in Europe, is the great seaport of France. Its trade amounts to over $350,000,000 annually, and it ranks next after Hamburg among the great seaports of central Europe. Its specialty is its great trade with the Mediterranean and the East. The opening of the Suez Canal has been of incalculable advantage to Marseilles. Next[101] as shipping port comes Havre (119,000), at the mouth of the Seine, with a total trade not far short of that of Marseilles. Havre is in reality the port or "haven" of Paris. It is the great depot for French imports from North and South America. These comprise principally cotton, tobacco, wheat, animal produce, and wool. Its import of South American wool is enormous, for three fourths of the wool used in France now comes from the region of the La Plata. Recently the Seine has been deepened and now both Rouen and Paris may be considered seaports. By this means Paris has direct water communication with London, and is, indeed, the third seaport in the country. Next comes Bordeaux (257,000), the chief place of export for French wines and brandies. About twenty years ago the wine industry of France suffered tremendous loss from the ravages of the insect phylloxera. Over 4,000,000 acres of vineyard, representing a value of $1,000,000,000, were wholly or partially ruined by this terrible pest. The plague, however, has now been stamped out, but nearly 2,000,000 acres of vineyards have been permanently destroyed and have been devoted to potatoes and the sugar-beet root. The result is that the production of wine in France is now less than what is needed for home consumption, and over fifty per cent. more wine is imported than is exported. The remaining great shipping ports are Dunkerque (40,000) and Boulogne (37,500). Calais (57,000) has a great passenger trade with England.

Paris (2,536,834) is, of course, the main trade hub of France, but the trade interests of Paris are broad rather than specific. The industries most concentrated in Paris are luxury items, such as jewelry, perfume, gloves, decorative goods, novelties, and trendy boots and shoes. Paris is also a major financial center. Marseille (442,000), one of the oldest cities in Europe, is France's main seaport. Its trade amounts to over $350,000,000 annually, making it the second largest seaport in Central Europe after Hamburg. Its specialty is its extensive trade with the Mediterranean and the East. The opening of the Suez Canal has greatly benefited Marseilles. Next[101] in shipping ports is Havre (119,000), located at the mouth of the Seine, with trade levels close to those of Marseilles. Havre essentially serves as the "haven" for Paris. It is the primary hub for French imports from North and South America, mainly consisting of cotton, tobacco, wheat, livestock products, and wool. Its import of South American wool is massive, as three-quarters of the wool used in France now comes from the La Plata region. Recently, the Seine has been deepened, so both Rouen and Paris can now be considered seaports. This provides Paris with direct water access to London and makes it the third largest seaport in the country. Following is Bordeaux wine (257,000), the main point of export for French wines and brandies. About twenty years ago, the French wine industry faced significant losses due to the insect phylloxera. Over 4,000,000 acres of vineyards, valued at $1,000,000,000, were completely or partially destroyed by this devastating pest. Although the plague has now been eradicated, nearly 2,000,000 acres of vineyards have been permanently lost and are now used for potatoes and sugar beet. Consequently, wine production in France now falls short of local consumption needs, with more than fifty percent more wine imported than exported. The other major shipping ports are Dunkirk (40,000) and Boulogne-sur-Mer (37,500). Calais (57,000) has a significant passenger trade with England.

[102]III. THE TRADE FEATURES OF GERMANY

GERMANY THE MOST PROSPEROUS NATION IN CONTINENTAL EUROPE

The greatest and most prosperous commercial nation in the old world after Great Britain is Germany. Its population is 52,000,000, as against France's 38,500,000; and while France's population is scarcely increasing at all, Germany's population is increasing the most rapidly of any in Europe. Since the Franco-Prussian war France has gained in population only a little over 2,000,000, while Germany in the same time has gained 12,000,000. In the middle of the present century the populations of Germany and France were equal, being each about 35,000,000. Since that date Germany's population has increased by about fifty per cent. and France's by only about ten per cent. Similarly, the commerce of Germany not only greatly exceeds that of France, but is growing much faster than that of France. The total exports and imports of Germany, exclusive of bullion, now foot up to nearly $2,000,000,000 a year. The total exports and imports of France, exclusive of bullion, foot up to only $1,500,000,000 a year. The total commerce of Germany is[103] therefore about one third more than that of France. At the close of the Franco-Prussian war the total commerce of France considerably exceeded that of Germany.

The largest and most successful commercial nation in the old world after Great Britain is Germany. Its population is 52 million, compared to France's 38.5 million; and while France's population is barely increasing, Germany's population is growing the fastest in Europe. Since the Franco-Prussian war, France has gained just over 2 million people, whereas Germany has gained 12 million in the same time. In the middle of this century, the populations of Germany and France were equal, each around 35 million. Since then, Germany's population has increased by about fifty percent, while France's has only risen by about ten percent. Likewise, Germany's commerce not only greatly surpasses that of France, but it is also growing much quicker than France's. The total exports and imports of Germany, excluding bullion, now total nearly $2 billion a year. The total exports and imports of France, excluding bullion, amount to only $1.5 billion a year. Thus, Germany's total commerce is [103] about one third more than that of France. At the end of the Franco-Prussian war, France's total commerce significantly exceeded that of Germany.

THE CHARACTER OF GERMANY'S INDUSTRIES CHANGING

Germany, like England, is rapidly changing the character of her industries and becoming a manufacturing and commercial nation instead of an agricultural nation. This is the cause of her well-known anxiety to secure control of territories in Africa, Asia, etc., as exclusive markets for her manufactures, for, unlike England, Germany is at present a believer in exclusion in trade, both at home and in her colonies. Fifty years ago about four sevenths of the people of Germany were engaged in agriculture; now only about one third of the people are so employed. The growth of the great cities of Germany is eight times faster than that of the rural districts, and in fifty years the aggregate population of the six largest cities of the empire—Berlin, Hamburg, Leipzig, Munich, Breslau, and Dresden—has grown sixfold, namely, from 600,000 to 3,600,000. In fifty years, too, the manufactures of Germany have nearly doubled, the commerce nearly trebled, the shipping increased more than fivefold, and the mining output more than sixfold. While all this is true, it nevertheless is also true that the area of cultivated soil in Germany is double what it was fifty years ago. But this is because much land, formerly waste or in pasture, has been brought under cultivation. Yet even now only one half of the land of Germany is cultivated, and thirty-three per cent. of the total food consumption of the people has to be imported. Fifty years ago only five per cent. of the total food consumption was imported, and this small fraction consisted almost wholly of luxuries.

Germany, like England, is quickly changing the nature of its industries and transforming into a manufacturing and commercial powerhouse instead of just an agricultural nation. This shift drives its well-known desire to secure control of territories in Africa, Asia, and other areas as exclusive markets for its products. Unlike England, Germany currently believes in trade exclusivity, both domestically and in its colonies. Fifty years ago, about four-sevenths of the German population was involved in agriculture; now, only about one-third of the population works in that field. The growth of Germany's major cities is eight times faster than that of rural areas, and over the past fifty years, the total population of the six largest cities in the empire—Berlin, Hamburg, Leipzig, Munich, Breslau, and Dresden—has increased sixfold, from 600,000 to 3,600,000. In the same fifty-year span, Germany's manufacturing industry has nearly doubled, commerce has nearly tripled, shipping has increased more than five times, and mining output has gone up more than six times. While all of this is true, it's also worth noting that the area of cultivated land in Germany is now double what it was fifty years ago. This is mainly because much land that was previously waste or used for pasture has been converted to farming. Still, even now, only half of Germany's land is cultivated, and one-third of the total food consumed by the population has to be imported. Fifty years ago, only five percent of the total food consumption was imported, and this small amount was almost entirely made up of luxury items.

[104]GERMANY'S SUCCESS IN TECHNICAL EDUCATION

Approximate size of the German Empire. Approximate size of the German Empire.

Note.—The population of that part of the United States included within the circle is about 10,000,000. The population of the German Empire is about 52,000,000.

Note.—The population of that area of the United States indicated by the circle is around 10,000,000. The population of Germany is about 52,000,000.

Germany's prosperity and progress cannot wholly be measured by statistics. No one can predict what it will be, for it is partly based upon elements that unfortunately other countries have not taken much account of.[105] Germany pays greater attention to the practical education of her people than any other nation in the world. Her system of technical education extends over the whole empire, and provides technical instruction for every class of the people and for every occupation of the people—night schools for those already engaged in life's work, agricultural schools, forestry schools, commercial schools, mining schools, naval schools, and schools in every branch of manufacturing industry, besides, of course, schools for the education of those intending to follow the learned professions. As a consequence of this very general provision of technical education, there is engaged in German manufacturing pursuits a class of workmen not found in the workshops of any other country—men of industrial skill and experience, and at the same time of the highest scientific technical attainments in the branches of science that bear particularly upon their work. These men work at salaries that in other countries would be considered absurdly low. In almost all other countries the possession of a sound scientific education is a passport to social distinction, and every profession is open to him who is deserving to enter it. In Germany, however, the learned professions, and especially the official positions of the army and navy, are almost the exclusive preserves of those who are born to social rank. The educated commoner, therefore, has to betake himself to manufacture, trade, or commerce. It follows that scientific skill and intelligence are more generally diffused in German commercial industries than in those of all other nations. So far, however, the German artisan has not been the equal in special technical skill of his more rigidly specialised English competitor, and as a consequence of this more than one sixth of Germany's total imports consist of goods brought from England—principally the finer sort of textile fabrics[106] and articles of iron and steel. This inferiority in specialisation in the German workmen cannot continue long, and the successful rivalry of Germany with the manufacturing pre-eminence of Great Britain may soon be a startling fact.

Germany's prosperity and progress can't be fully measured by statistics. No one can predict what it will become, as it's partly based on factors that unfortunately many other countries haven't considered.[105] Germany focuses more on the hands-on education of its people than any other country in the world. Its technical education system spans the entire nation and offers technical training for every class of people and occupation—night schools for those already in the workforce, agricultural schools, forestry schools, commercial schools, mining schools, naval schools, and schools in every manufacturing field, as well as schools for those aiming for the learned professions. As a result of this widespread technical education, there is a group of workers in German manufacturing that isn't found in the workshops of any other country—individuals with industrial skills and experience, and at the same time, the highest scientific technical qualifications relevant to their work. These workers earn salaries that would be considered ridiculously low in other countries. In almost every other country, having a solid scientific education is a ticket to social status, and every profession is open to anyone deserving of entry. However, in Germany, the learned professions, especially official positions in the army and navy, are mostly reserved for those born into social rank. Thus, educated commoners often turn to manufacturing, trade, or commerce. This leads to a broader distribution of scientific skill and intelligence in German commercial industries than in those of other nations. However, so far, the German artisan hasn't matched the specialized technical skill of his more narrowly focused English competitor, and as a result, over one-sixth of Germany's total imports come from England—mainly high-quality textile fabrics[106] and iron and steel products. This disadvantage in specialization among German workers can’t last long, and Germany's successful competition with the manufacturing dominance of Great Britain may soon become a surprising reality.

GERMANY'S MINES AND HARDWARE MANUFACTURES

It is in the development of her mines and of manufactures in which minerals are employed that Germany has made most noticeable progress. She produces four times as much coal as France, and she has over 1000 separate iron-mines. Her production of iron has increased tenfold in fifty years. She employs over 400,000 men in her mines, and by the use of labour-saving machinery one man can now produce as much as three men could produce fifty years ago. Her hardware manufactures are one sixth of her total manufactures, and in the past half century they have increased sixfold. They are now double those of France, and are only one fourth less than those of Great Britain. She has 750 factories devoted to the making of machinery alone. Two of these—Krupp's at Essen, and Borsig's at Berlin—are among the largest in the world. Krupp's employs 20,000 men, has 310 steam-engines, and covers an area of 1000 acres. Borsig's employs 10,000 men, and in fifty years, starting from nothing, has turned out nearly 4000 locomotives. One of Krupp's hammers (a fifty-ton hammer) cost $500,000.

Germany has made significant progress in developing her mines and industries that useminerals. She produces four times as much coal as France and has over 1,000 separate iron mines. Her iron production has increased tenfold in the past fifty years. She employs more than 400,000 workers in her mines, and thanks to labor-saving machinery, one person can now produce as much as three could fifty years ago. Hertech manufacturing makes up one-sixth of her total manufacturing, and it has increased sixfold over the last fifty years. Her output is now double that of France and only one-fourth less than Great Britain's. She has 750 factories dedicated to machinery alone. Two of these—Krupp's in Essen and Borsig's in Berlin—are among the largest in the world. Krupp's employs 20,000 workers, has 310 steam engines, and spans an area of 1,000 acres. Borsig's employs 10,000 workers and has produced nearly 4,000 locomotives in fifty years, starting from scratch. One of Krupp's hammers (a fifty-ton hammer) cost $500,000.

GERMANY'S INTERNAL TRADE

Germany's commercial energies up to the present have been mainly concentrated on her internal trade. The total amount of this trade foots up to $7,000,000,000, against France's $6,000,000,000, and in fifty years it has[107] trebled, while that of France has scarcely doubled. Germany has more miles of railway than any other country in the world except the United States, her mileage being nearly 30,000, against France's 25,000 and Great Britain's 21,000. Her natural and artificial waterways are also the best in Europe, and her vast production of mineral wealth is transported from mine to foundry and factory, and her vast production of lumber and grain is transported from forest and field to seaport, largely by means of water carriage. The Rhine, the Elbe, the Oder, and the Vistula are all navigable throughout their whole courses through German territory, while the Weser and the Danube are also navigable throughout great parts of their courses. All these navigable rivers are interconnected by canals. The total length of possible river navigation is nearly 6000 miles, while the total length of canals and canalised rivers is 2700 miles. Besides, in 1895 there was completed the Kaiser Wilhelm Canal, a lockless sea-going vessel canal, twenty-nine feet six inches deep and sixty-one miles long, connecting the North Sea and the Baltic, and constructed at a cost of nearly $40,000,000. This canal effects a saving of almost one whole day for commercial steamers, and of three days for all sailing-vessels, engaged in the Baltic and North Sea trade.

Germany's commercial activity has mainly focused on its internal trade, which totals around $7 billion, compared to France's $6 billion. Over the past fifty years, Germany's trade has tripled, while France's has barely doubled. Germany has more railway miles than any country in the world except the United States, with nearly 30,000 miles compared to France's 25,000 and Great Britain's 21,000. The country's natural and artificial waterways are also the best in Europe, effectively transporting its vast amounts of minerals from mines to foundries and factories, as well as lumber and grain from forests and fields to seaports, largely via waterways. The Rhine, Elbe, Oder, and Vistula rivers are navigable throughout their entire lengths within German territory, while the Weser and Danube are navigable in significant parts. All these navigable rivers are connected by canals. The total length of navigable rivers is nearly 6,000 miles, and the total length of canals and canalized rivers is 2,700 miles. Additionally, in 1895, the Kaiser Wilhelm Canal was completed. This lockless canal for sea-going vessels is 29 feet 6 inches deep and 61 miles long, connecting the North Sea and the Baltic, built at a cost of nearly $40 million. This canal saves commercial steamers almost a whole day and sailing vessels three days in Baltic and North Sea trade.

GERMANY'S FOREIGN TRADE

But while it is true that Germany's internal trade is her most important trade, it is also true that her foreign trade has during the last half century made more progress than that of any other European country, and during the last three or four decades more progress than even that of the United States. Since 1840 it has increased six and two third times, while that of Great Britain has increased six times, and France only four and[108] one fifth times. It is now second in the world, being more than half of that of Great Britain, ahead of that of the United States,[1] and very considerably ahead of that of France, while in 1860 it was much less than half of that of Great Britain, less than that of the United States, and considerably less than that of France. Germany, however, is not well favoured with respect to seaports, for in its transmarine trade it is largely dependent on foreign seaports—namely, ports in Belgium, Holland, France, Italy, and Austria. Rotterdam in Holland and Antwerp in Belgium are much more favourably situated with respect to the commerce of its chief mining and manufacturing regions than any of its own ports. There are only two German seaports with water of depth sufficient to accommodate the deep-drawing vessels in which foreign commerce is now mainly carried on—namely, Cuxhaven, the outport of Hamburg, sixty-five miles from Hamburg, and Bremerhaven, the outport of Bremen, thirty-five miles from Bremen, though recent improvements in the navigation of the Elbe allow vessels of even twenty-six feet draught to ascend the Elbe wholly to Hamburg. But Hamburg (625,000), for the reason that for centuries it was a free port of entry, has built up a very large foreign trade, being the fifth in the world in this respect, London, New York, Liverpool, and Rotterdam, alone being ahead of it. Hamburg's foreign trade is almost one half greater than the whole foreign trade of all other German ports put together, while the foreign trade of Bremen is about one fourth that of Hamburg. Bremen, like Hamburg, was[109] for centuries a free port of entry, but in 1888 both Hamburg and Bremen gave up in great part their free port privileges and entered the general customs union of the empire. Both cities were extremely loath to give up their ancient unique commercial privileges, for they feared an immense loss of trade in doing so, but it was hoped that what they lost in foreign commerce would be made up to them in increased commerce with other parts of the empire. One reason for the great development of Germany's foreign trade in late years is found in the facilities that it possesses for rapid transit to and from Italy by means of tunnels through the Alps.

But while it’s true that Germany's internal trade is her most important trade, it's also true that her global trade has made more progress in the last fifty years than any other European country, and in the last three or four decades, even more than that of the United States. Since 1840, it has increased by six and two-thirds times, while Great Britain's increased six times, and France's only increased four and[108] one-fifth times. It's now second in the world, being more than half of Great Britain's trade, ahead of the United States,[1] and significantly ahead of France, while in 1860 it was much less than half of Great Britain's, less than that of the United States, and considerably less than that of France. Germany, however, isn’t well-equipped with seaports, relying heavily on foreign ports for its trade—specifically, the ports in Belgium, Holland, France, Italy, and Austria. Rotterdam in Holland and Antwerp in Belgium are situated much better for the commerce of Germany's main mining and manufacturing regions than any of its own ports. There are only two German seaports with deep enough water to accommodate the large cargo ships used in foreign trade—specifically, Cuxhaven, the outport of Hamburg, which is sixty-five miles from Hamburg, and Bremerhaven, the outport of Bremen, thirty-five miles from Bremen, although recent improvements in the Elbe River’s navigation now allow vessels with a draft of up to twenty-six feet to reach Hamburg completely via the Elbe. However, Hamburg (625,000), due to being a free port for centuries, has developed a very large foreign trade, ranking fifth in the world, only behind London, New York, Liverpool, and Rotterdam. Hamburg's foreign trade is almost one and a half times greater than the combined foreign trade of all other German ports, while Bremen's foreign trade is about one-fourth that of Hamburg. Bremen, like Hamburg, was[109] a free port for centuries, but in 1888, both Hamburg and Bremen largely gave up their free port privileges to join the general customs union of the empire. Both cities were very reluctant to lose their historical unique commercial privileges, fearing a significant loss in trade, but it was hoped that any losses in foreign commerce would be compensated by increased trade with other parts of the empire. One reason for the significant growth of Germany's foreign trade in recent years is the efficient transit options available to and from Italy through tunnels in the Alps.

North central Germany, showing the ship canal and the leading commercial arteries. North Central Germany, highlighting the ship canal and the main commercial routes.

FOOTNOTE:

[1]During the last two or three years the foreign trade of the United States has greatly expanded and has exceeded that of Germany, and is making a close push upon that of Great Britain. The above statement was intended to represent the situation as existing during a period of some years.

[1]In the past two or three years, the United States' foreign trade has significantly grown, surpassing Germany's and is closely approaching that of Great Britain. This statement reflects the situation over a period of several years.

THE SPECIAL TRADE CENTRES OF GERMANY

Berlin (1,700,000), the capital of the empire, is a chief seat of machinery manufacture. For many years Frank[110]fort-on-the-Main enjoyed the pre-eminence of being next to London the greatest money market in the world; but since the establishment of the German Empire Frankfort's financial business has been absorbed by Berlin. Leipzig (400,000) has the distinction of being the seat of a book-publishing trade that turns out over 60,000,000 volumes in a year, amounting in value to $30,000,000. Leipzig has also the honour of being the greatest fur market in the world. Dantzig (120,000) is Germany's chief port on the Baltic, and the chief seat of its great export trade in timber, grain, flax, hemp, and potatoes. Its harbour, however, is closed in winter because of ice. Dresden (330,000) is noted for its porcelain manufacture, but the porcelain is not manufactured chiefly in Dresden, but in Meissen, fifteen miles from Dresden. Munich (407,000) manufactures largely the national beverage, beer. Finally, Nuremberg (162,000), in southern Germany, is remarkable for its continuance into modern days of manufactures for centuries carried on domestically. Of these the most noted are watches, clocks, pencils, and toys.

Berlin (1,700,000), the capital of the empire, is a major center for machinery manufacturing. For many years, Frank[110]fort-on-the-Main was recognized as the second biggest money market in the world after London. However, since the formation of the German Empire, Berlin has taken over Frankfort's financial activities. Leipzig (400,000) is known for its book-publishing industry, producing over 60,000,000 volumes each year, valued at around $30,000,000. Leipzig is also home to the world's largest fur market. Dantzig (120,000) is Germany's main port on the Baltic Sea and a key hub for exporting timber, grain, flax, hemp, and potatoes. However, its harbor is closed during winter due to ice. Dresden (330,000) is famous for its porcelain, though most of the porcelain is actually produced in Meissen, which is fifteen miles away. Munich (407,000) is well-known for producing beer, the country's national drink. Finally, Nuremberg (162,000), in southern Germany, stands out for its long-lasting tradition of domestic manufacturing. Notable products include watches, clocks, pencils, and toys.

[111]IV. TRADE FEATURES OF SPAIN AND ITALY

ITALY, TURKEY, AND SPAIN, THE THREE DECADENT NATIONS OF EUROPE

The Mediterranean from the very earliest epochs of civilisation has been a chief highway of trade, and along its shores every sort of commercial activity has been prosecuted. For centuries and centuries the nations upon the borders, especially those upon its northern borders, were the leading nations of the world, and their empire, indeed, comprised the empire of the world. But during the last two or three centuries, and especially during the nineteenth century, commercial pre-eminence and pre-eminence in empire have departed from the Mediterranean. Italy, the ruler of the whole ancient world, and even in modern times a ruler of almost equal potency; Turkey, during the middle ages a chief power both in Europe and in Asia; Spain, for two centuries at the beginning of our modern epoch a chief power in Europe and the mistress of almost the whole Western world as well,—these countries have all sunk to positions of comparative insignificance, and Italy alone shows signs of effectual regeneration. And yet on the whole earth's surface there are no lands more richly endowed by nature as abodes for man than Italy, Turkey, and Spain.

The Mediterranean has been a major trade route since the earliest days of civilization, and its shores have hosted all kinds of commercial activities. For centuries, the nations along its coasts, especially those to the north, were the dominant powers in the world, with empires that truly encompassed the globe. However, over the last two or three centuries, particularly in the nineteenth century, commercial and imperial dominance has shifted away from the Mediterranean. Italy, which once ruled the entire ancient world and still held significant power in modern times; Turkey, a leading force in both Europe and Asia during the Middle Ages; and Spain, the major power in Europe and the master of much of the Western world for two centuries at the start of our modern era—these countries have all diminished in significance, with only Italy showing real signs of recovery. Yet, overall, there are no places on Earth that are more naturally equipped to support human life than Italy, Turkey, and Spain.

[112]SPAIN: ITS TRADE AND ITS SPECIAL TRADE CENTRES

Spain, because of the varied climate of her several parts, is capable of producing almost all the edible fruits and grains known to both temperate and tropical regions. Though there are some desert areas, a great portion of the soil is abundantly productive, and were agriculture pursued with the same skill as it is in other countries—in England and Scotland, for example—Spain would be one of the richest agricultural regions on the globe. But not only is agriculture very inefficiently pursued, but the country is also sparsely inhabited (only 90 to the square mile, as compared with 270 to the square mile in Italy) and only one fourth of it is cultivated. As a consequence only those products are raised in Spain in which, because of her advantages of climate, etc., she has least competition. The principal commercial agricultural product is wine, the vine being cultivated in every province in the kingdom. Six hundred million gallons of wine are raised annually, which is more in value than the total quantity of grain raised. Only one fifth of this, however, is exported (principally to France), and even of this the greater portion is wine of inferior grade, used for mixing. The remaining agricultural products of Spain exported are chiefly oranges, lemons, grapes, raisins, nuts, olives, and onions. Of these over $15,000,000 worth go to England annually. England and France, indeed, enjoy the great bulk of Spain's foreign trade, but of late years Germany and the United States are taking a small share of it. The mineral wealth of Spain is enormous, and as the mines are often controlled by foreign capital they are worked with energy. The iron ore of the Basque provinces of the north and the copper ore of the district about Cadiz[113] have been renowned for ages. Thirty-five million dollars' worth of copper, iron, lead, silver, and quicksilver are exported to Great Britain annually. There are manufactures of cottons, woollens, linens, and silks, but none of these can be said to be very prosperous, although during the last twenty-five years, owing to a high protective tariff, the quantity of raw material used in textile manufacture in Spain has doubled. Spain produces excellent wool, but her woollen manufacture is unable to use it all and one fourth is exported. Similarly, although Spain is especially rich in iron-fields, she gets about one third of the hardware she needs for her own consumption from England. The total area of Spain's coal-fields is estimated at 5500 miles, but hitherto little coal has been mined, partly because it is somewhat inaccessible. Four million dollars' worth of coal is annually imported from England. Whole mountains of rock salt exist, but little is mined and none is exported, although bay salt obtained in the south is exported to the fishermen of Cornwall. Another important export is esparto grass, which is sent to England to be used in paper-making. And still another is cork, although Portugal, which adjoins Spain, is the chief seat of the cork-producing industry. Madrid (470,000) is the capital and largest city. Barcelona (250,000) is the chief seaport of Spain and the chief manufacturing centre. Valencia (145,000), in the southeast, and Seville (135,000) and Malaga (115,000), in the south, are the principal seats of the fruit export trade of the country. Cadiz (65,000), Spain's principal naval seaport, has a famous export trade in sherry wines. The total population of Spain is 17,500,000.

Spain, due to the diverse climates in its different regions, is capable of producing almost all the edible fruits and grains found in both temperate and tropical areas. Although there are some desert regions, much of the land is highly productive, and if agriculture were practiced with the same expertise as in other countries—like England and Scotland, for instance—Spain could be one of the richest agricultural areas in the world. However, agriculture is not only poorly managed, but the country also has a low population density (only 90 people per square mile, compared to 270 in Italy), and only a quarter of the land is cultivated. As a result, Spain primarily grows those products where it faces the least competition due to its climate advantages. The main agricultural product for trade is wine, with vineyards found in every province. Annually, six hundred million gallons of wine are produced, which has a higher value than the total grain output. However, only one-fifth of this wine is exported (mainly to France), and most of that is lower-grade wine used for blending. Other agricultural exports from Spain include primarily oranges, lemons, grapes, raisins, nuts, olives, and onions, with over $15,000,000 worth going to England each year. England and France account for the majority of Spain's foreign trade, but in recent years Germany and the United States have started taking a small share. The mineral resources of Spain is vast, and since many mines are operated with foreign investment, they are worked vigorously. The iron ore from the Basque provinces in the north and the copper ore around Cadiz[113] have been famous for centuries. Every year, $35 million worth of copper, iron, lead, silver, and quicksilver are exported to Great Britain. Spain produces cottons, wools, linens, and silks, but none of these industries can be described as particularly successful. However, in the last twenty-five years, the amount of raw materials used in textile manufacturing in Spain has doubled due to a high protective tariff. Spain produces quality wool, but its wool industry cannot process all of it, leading to one-fourth being exported. Although Spain is rich in iron fields, about one-third of the hardware it requires is imported from England. The total area of Spain's coal mines is around 5,500 miles, but little coal has been mined so far, partly because it's somewhat difficult to access. Spain imports four million dollars' worth of coal from England each year. There are entire mountains of sea salt, but very little is mined and none is exported, although bay salt produced in the south is exported to fishermen in Cornwall. Another significant export is esparto, which is sent to England for paper production. Cork is also an important export, although Portugal, which borders Spain, dominates the cork industry. The capital and largest city is Madrid (470,000). Barcelona (250,000) is the main seaport and manufacturing center. Valencia (145,000), located in the southeast, along with Seville (135,000) and Malaga (115,000) in the south, are the main hubs for the country’s fruit export trade. Cadiz (65,000), Spain's key naval port, has a renowned export business for sherry wines. The total population of Spain is 17,500,000.

Spain compared in size with California. Spain is about the same size as California.

[114]ITALY'S LAMENTABLE CONDITION

Italy's condition is in some respects better than that of Spain, but in others worse. Its population is 30,500,000, being three times more to the square mile than that of Spain, and fifty per cent. more to the square mile than that of France. Since 1830 the population has increased forty-five per cent., and this notwithstanding the fact that the loss by emigration is equal to one half of the natural increase from the surplus of births over deaths. Two million people of Italian birth are to-day residing in foreign countries. Again, the Italians, except those[115] in the southern parts (the Italians of Naples and vicinity, for example), are the most industrious people in Europe, with a special aptitude for gardening and tillage. In fifty years they have reclaimed 20,000,000 acres from forest, and increased the area of land under cultivation by one hundred per cent. In fifty years, too, they have trebled the amount of capital invested in agriculture. Since 1860 they have increased the amount of material which they use in their textile manufactures (cotton, wool, silk, and linen) nearly fivefold. Since 1850 they have increased their external commerce two and one half times. Finally, since 1830, they have increased their internal trade two and one quarter times. But all these signs of prosperity in Italy are negatived by the constantly increasing magnitude of her national debt. This now amounts to more than $2,500,000,000, or more than two and one half times the total net national debt of the United States, and about one fourth more than the total national, state, county, municipal, and school-district debts of the United States. And this vast debt for a people of 30,500,000 is exclusive of the provincial and communal debts, which amount to $275,000,000 additional. Italy since her reorganisation as a kingdom in 1870 has set out to be a first-class military and naval power, and the cost is more than she can stand. She has a permanent army of nearly 800,000 men, 250,000 of whom she keeps under arms constantly. She has a fleet of seventeen battleships, two coast-defence ships, eighteen cruisers, and 272 torpedo craft, most of these being of modern type and first-class rating. She spends on her army nearly $50,000,000 annually, and on her navy nearly $20,000,000 annually. This, with an annual interest payment of $115,000,000, all unproductive expenditure, makes a demand upon her revenue that is draining her people of their life's blood. Every sort of taxation is resorted to—direct and indirect; land,[116] house, and income; succession duties, registration charges, and stamps for commercial papers; customs, excise and octroi; besides government monopolies; and all this exclusive of communal taxation. And yet since 1891 there has been an annual deficit of national revenue under national expenditure averaging $2,250,000. As a consequence of these taxes, and of the repressive effect they have upon industrial enterprise, the net earnings of the country per inhabitant are lower in Italy than in any other European state except Turkey, Russia, and Greece—lower, even, than in the Danubian states and Portugal and Spain.

Italy's situation is somewhat better than Spain's in some ways, but worse in others. Its population is 30,500,000, which is three times denser than Spain's and fifty percent denser than France's. Since 1830, the population has grown by forty-five percent, despite the fact that emigration has cut the natural increase from births outpacing deaths in half. Two million Italians currently live abroad. Moreover, except for those in the southern regions (like the Italians from Naples and nearby areas), Italians are the most hardworking people in Europe, especially skilled in gardening and farming. Over the last fifty years, they have reclaimed 20 million acres from forests and doubled the amount of land cultivated. They've also tripled the investment in agriculture during this time. Since 1860, the materials used in their textile manufacturing (cotton, wool, silk, and linen) have increased nearly fivefold. Since 1850, their external trade has more than doubled. Finally, since 1830, their internal trade has grown by more than two times. However, all these signs of prosperity are offset by the constantly rising national debt. This has now reached over $2,500,000,000, which is more than two and a half times the total net national debt of the United States and about a quarter more than all debts combined at the national, state, county, municipal, and school district levels in the U.S. This enormous debt burden for a population of 30,500,000 does not include the provincial and communal debts, which add another $275,000,000. Since becoming a kingdom in 1870, Italy has aimed to be a leading military and naval power, and the costs are more than it can bear. It maintains a standing army of nearly 800,000, with 250,000 on active duty at all times. Its navy includes seventeen battleships, two coastal defense ships, eighteen cruisers, and 272 torpedo vessels, most of which are modern and top-rated. The annual expenditure for the army is nearly $50,000,000, with around $20,000,000 for the navy. With an annual interest payment of $115,000,000, all of which is unproductive spending, this puts an immense strain on its revenues, draining the people's resources. Various types of taxes are imposed—both direct and indirect; on land, houses, and income; estate duties, registration fees, and stamps for commercial papers; customs, excise, and local taxes; along with government monopolies; all excluding local taxation. Yet since 1891, there has been an annual deficit averaging $2,250,000, where national expenditures exceed revenues. As a result of these taxes and their stifling effect on industry, the net earnings per person in Italy are lower than in any other European country except Turkey, Russia, and Greece— even below those in the Danubian states, Portugal, and Spain.

ITALY'S TRADE AND SPECIAL TRADE CENTRES

The most distinctive natural product of Italy is silk, and the amount of raw and thrown silk exported is about $57,500,000 annually. Silk culture is carried on all over the kingdom, though the industry flourishes most extensively in Piedmont and Lombardy, in the north. Over 550,000 people are engaged in rearing silkworms, and the annual cocoon harvest approximates 100,000,000 pounds. Silk-"throwing," or-spinning, is the principal manufacturing industry, and the amount of silk spun and exported is about 45,000 tons, most of which goes to France. After silk the products of the country that constitute the principal exports are olive oil, fruit (oranges, lemons, grapes, almonds, figs, dates, and pistachio nuts), and wine (in casks). The olive-oil export and the fruit export are each about a fifth of the export of silk, and the wine export about a sixth. Other important and characteristic exports are raw hemp and flax, sulphur, eggs, manufactured coral, woods and roots used for dyeing and tanning, rice, marble, and straw-plaiting. The principal import is wheat, for agricul[117]ture, though generally pursued, is still in a backward state of efficiency, and the average grain crop is only one third what it is in Great Britain. One eighth the total amount of wheat needed to support the people has to be imported. In fact, the total amount of food-stuffs raised in the kingdom is much less than the amount required, being, for example, per inhabitant, not more than one half of what is raised in France. In particular, there is a deficiency of meat, and the amount of meat raised per inhabitant is the lowest in Europe. As a consequence the Italians are poorly fed, and it is estimated that four per cent. of the annual death loss is occasioned by impoverishment of blood due to insufficiency of wholesome food. After wheat and raw cotton, the next principal import is coal, for Italy has no workable coal-fields. As far as possible water power is used as a motive power instead of coal, especially in the iron industries. [118]An important import also is fish, for, owing to the great number of fast days which the Italian people observe, and to the dearness and scarcity of meat, fish is a very general article of consumption. Six million dollars' worth is imported annually, and perhaps an equal amount is obtained from local fisheries, for there are over 22,000 vessels and boats and over 70,000 men engaged in this industry. After silk-throwing, the most characteristic Italian manufacturing industries are those which are of an artistic or semi-artistic nature, such as the making of fine earthenware, porcelain, glassware, mosaics, and lace. Venice (154,000) and Genoa (225,000) are still the principal seaports and trade centres of Italy, but in commercial importance these famous cities are only the mere shadows of what they once were. Naples (529,000), the largest city, is a place of little enterprise, for its imports, principally cereals, are three or four times the value of its exports, which are mainly cheap country produce. Milan (457,000) and Turin (348,000) are the great trade centres of the north interior, and the most prosperous places in the kingdom, being the chief seats of the silk-throwing industry. Milan is also the chief seat of the Italian cutlery manufacture. Palermo (284,000) and Messina (150,000), in[119] Sicily, are the chief ports for the export of Italian fruits, and also of Italian fish (anchovies, tunnies, etc.). Rome (474,000) and Florence (207,000) owe their chief importance to their art interest and to their historic associations, but Florence has an important manufacture of fine earthenware and mosaics. Rome is the chief seat of government. Catania (127,000), in Sicily, is the chief seat of the Italian sulphur export trade. Leghorn (104,000), the port of Florence, is the chief seat of the export straw-plaiting trade. It should be noted that notwithstanding Italy's extent of coast-line a large part of her foreign commerce is transacted northward by means of the railways that tunnel the Alps.

The most distinctive natural product of Italy is silk, and the annual export of raw and processed silk is about $57,500,000. Silk farming occurs throughout the country, but the industry is most prominent in Piedmont and Lombardy in the north. Over 550,000 people are involved in raising silkworms, and the yearly cocoon harvest is around 100,000,000 pounds. The main manufacturing industry is silk processing, and approximately 45,000 tons of silk are spun and exported, with most of it going to France. After silk, the main exports of the country include olive oil, fruit (oranges, lemons, grapes, almonds, figs, dates, and pistachio nuts), and wine (in barrels). The exports of olive oil and fruit are each about one-fifth of the silk export, and the wine export is around one-sixth. Other significant and characteristic exports include raw hemp and flax, sulfur, eggs, manufactured coral, woods and roots used for dyeing and tanning, rice, marble, and straw-plaiting. The main import is wheat, as agriculture, while generally practiced, is still quite inefficient, with the average grain crop only one-third of what it is in Great Britain. One-eighth of the total wheat needed to feed the population must be imported. In fact, the total amount of food raised in the country is much less than what is required, being about half of what is produced in France per person. There is a particular shortage of meat, with the amount raised per person being the lowest in Europe. As a result, Italians often eat poorly, and it’s estimated that four percent of the annual death rate is due to blood impoverishment from inadequate nutrition. After wheat and raw cotton, the next major import is coal, since Italy has no viable coal fields. Water power is used wherever possible instead of coal, especially in the iron industries. [118]An essential import is fish, as the many fast days observed by Italians, combined with the high cost and scarcity of meat, make fish a common food source. Six million dollars' worth is imported annually, and perhaps an equal amount comes from local fisheries, with over 22,000 vessels and boats and more than 70,000 men involved in this industry. After silk processing, the most characteristic Italian manufacturing sectors include artistic or semi-artistic products like fine pottery, porcelain, glassware, mosaics, and lace. Venice (154,000) and Genoa (225,000) remain the main seaports and trade centers of Italy, but in terms of commercial significance, these famous cities are mere shadows of their former glory. Napoli (529,000), the largest city, lacks enterprise, as its imports, primarily cereals, are three to four times more valuable than its exports, which mainly consist of low-cost rural products. Milan (457,000) and Turin (348,000) are the main trade centers in the northern interior, being the most prosperous locations in the country and the leading hubs of the silk processing industry. Milan is also the top center for Italian cutlery production. Palermo (284,000) and Messina (150,000) in [119] Sicily are the primary ports for exporting Italian fruits and fish (like anchovies and tunas). Rome (474,000) and Florence (207,000) are mainly significant for their artistic value and historical significance, although Florence also has a notable industry in fine pottery and mosaics. Rome serves as the primary seat of government. Catania (127,000) in Sicily is the main hub for the Italian sulfur export trade. Leghorn (104,000), the port of Florence, is the leading center for the export of straw-plaiting. It’s important to note that despite Italy’s long coastline, a large portion of its foreign trade is conducted northward through railways that traverse the Alps.

Italy and its chief commercial centres. Italy and its major commercial centers.

[120]V. THE TRADE FEATURES OF RUSSIA

RUSSIA, A COUNTRY WHOSE FUTURE IS A PROBLEM

The position of Russia in the world is a sort of problem. Its area is immense. More than one seventh of the land surface of the globe is included within its compact borders. Of this vast territory the area of European Russia alone is only a fourth; but even so it is larger than the area of all other European states put together. The population of Russia is over 129,000,000, of which over 106,000,000 belong to European Russia. But taking even European Russia this is a population of only fifty-four to the square mile, the lowest proportion in Europe, except in Sweden and Norway. And the population is increasing. The birth rate is the highest in the world. And though the death rate is very heavy, being fifty per cent. more than it is in England, the increase from births is so great that the population doubles in forty-six years. There is thus apparently a prospect that Russia will, in the near future, play an important part in the drama of nations, her capacities and capabilities for growth seem so prodigious. And yet there is a reverse side to the picture. Of the 106,000,000 inhabitants of European Russia 10,000,000 belong to a cultured, progressive class,[121] quite the equal of any people in Europe. But the remainder are principally a low grade of peasantry, not long removed from slavery. The principal occupation of these peasantry is farming. But their farms are small, not more than ten acres apiece, and the total revenue they get from them does not average more than $65 a year per farm. The food of these peasantry is the poorest in Europe. In the main it consists of rye bread and mushroom soup, worth about four cents a day. The houses are often mere huts, not more than five feet square. Women as well as men work in the fields, and yet the total amount of food raised is not more per head of population than one tenth of what is raised by the peasantry of France. The value of food raised per acre, too, is but little more than one third of the average per acre for all Europe.

The position of Russia in the world presents a sort of dilemma. Its land area is massive—over one-seventh of the Earth's total land is within its borders. Of this vast territory, European Russia makes up only a quarter, yet it's still larger than all other European countries combined. Russia's population exceeds 129 million, with more than 106 million in European Russia alone. However, even in European Russia, this equals just fifty-four people per square mile, the lowest density in Europe aside from Sweden and Norway. The population is growing, with the highest birth rate in the world. Although the death rate is significantly higher—fifty percent more than in England—the high birth rate means the population doubles every forty-six years. Thus, it seems likely that Russia will play a significant role in world affairs soon, given its tremendous potential for growth. Yet, there's a contrasting aspect. Of the 106 million people in European Russia, 10 million belong to a cultured, progressive class that rivals any in Europe. The rest are mostly a low-income peasantry, not far removed from a life of servitude. Their main occupation is farming, but their plots are small—no more than ten acres each—with an average income of only $65 per farm per year. The peasant's diet is the poorest in Europe, mainly consisting of rye bread and mushroom soup, worth about four cents a day. Their dwellings are often tiny huts, about five feet square. Both men and women work in the fields, yet the total food produced per person is only one-tenth of what the French peasantry produces. Additionally, the value of food produced per acre is just over a third of the European average.

Russia, the British Empire, the United States compared. Russia, the British Empire, and the United States compared.

[122]RUSSIA A COUNTRY OF SOCIAL EXTREMES

The degradation of the peasantry of Russia is not simply material. It is also moral. In the language of a recent traveller, "they are the drunkenest people in Europe." The principal intoxicant is a sort of whisky called "vodka." With drunkenness exist also dirtiness, idleness, dishonesty, and untruthfulness. And as yet little has been done to ameliorate this degradation. Ignorance prevails everywhere. Even of the young people of the peasant class more than eighty per cent. can neither read nor write. There is no middle class. The gulf between the upper class and the lower is so wide as to be absolutely impassable. And for the most part the upper class is quite content to have this state of affairs continue.

The decline of the peasantry in Russia isn't just about their material conditions; it also reflects a moral crisis. As a recent traveler put it, "they are the most drunken people in Europe." The main alcoholic drink is a type of whisky called "vodka." With alcoholism comes dirtiness, laziness, dishonesty, and a lack of truthfulness. So far, not much has been done to improve this situation. Ignorance is widespread. Over eighty percent of young people in the peasant class can neither read nor write. There is no middle class. The divide between the upper and lower classes is so vast that it's completely unbridgeable. And for the most part, the upper class is quite happy to maintain this status quo.

THE "ARTELS" OF THE RUSSIAN PEASANTS

There is, however, some hope for the lower classes of Russia. This is because of the prevalence among them, especially in villages, towns, and cities, of a communal custom in which self-restraint and self-government are necessary conditions of existence. In every branch of common industry "artels" are found; that is, communistic organisations, where all labour for a common purse in accordance with rules and regulations determined by the members of the organisations. These "artels" have done much toward increasing the industry, the honesty, the truthfulness, the thrift, and also the sobriety of their members. They exist throughout all Russia, but in some parts more prevalently than in others. As yet, however, they scarcely affect the character and[123] condition of the rural peasantry, and it is these who are most in need of elevation. It should be said, too, that the government is doing something to lessen the evil of drunkenness.

There is, however, some hope for the lower classes in Russia. This is due to the widespread communal custom among them, especially in villages, towns, and cities, where self-restraint and self-governance are essential for survival. In every area of common industry, you can find "artels," which are communal organizations where everyone works for a shared goal according to rules set by the members. These "artels" have significantly improved the industry, honesty, trustworthiness, thrift, and sobriety of their members. They exist all over Russia, but some areas have them more than others. However, they barely impact the character and[123] conditions of the rural peasantry, who are the ones in most need of improvement. It's also worth mentioning that the government is taking steps to reduce the problem of alcoholism.

RUSSIA PRINCIPALLY AN AGRICULTURAL COUNTRY

Russia's principal business is agriculture. More than one half her whole internal trade is agricultural. Her agricultural products are one and one half times greater than the products of her manufactures and ten times greater than her mining products or her imports. And though her production of grain per acre is the lowest in all Europe except Italy, Spain, and Portugal, and her total production of all food products per acre by far the lowest in Europe (not more than one third that of Spain, which is next lowest), yet she manages to export a larger quantity of grain than any other country in Europe, France only sometimes excepted. Russia's export of grain for some years past has averaged 266,000,000 bushels a year. Her export of wheat alone has averaged 94,000,000 bushels a year, or considerably more than a fifth of the total wheat export of the world. The explanation of this enormous export of wheat from so poor a country is that three fourths of the people live on rye. Among the peasants wheat bread is practically unknown, and nothing could be more pathetic than the hard rye lumps which passed as bread during the last famine. Other agricultural exports (besides grain) are flax, hemp, oil-seed cake, linseed and grass seed, butter, eggs, wool, hides, and hogs' bristles. Wood, lumber, and timber are also extensively exported. England is Russia's best customer. The amount of England's annual importation of the above products (including grain) exceeds $112,000,000.

Russia's main industry is farming. More than half of its total internal trade is agricultural. Its agricultural output is one and a half times greater than its manufacturing products and ten times greater than its mining products or imports. Although its grain production per acre is the lowest in all of Europe except for Italy, Spain, and Portugal, and its overall food production per acre is significantly the lowest in Europe (not exceeding one third of Spain’s, which is the next lowest), it still manages to export more grains than any other European country, with France being a rare exception. In recent years, Russia’s average grain export has been 266 million bushels annually. Its wheat exports alone have averaged 94 million bushels a year, which is considerably more than a fifth of total wheat exports worldwide. The reason for this huge wheat export from such a seemingly poor country is that three fourths of the population eats rye. Among the peasants, wheat bread is almost unheard of, and nothing is more disheartening than the hard rye lumps that passed as bread during the last famine. Other agricultural exports (besides grain) include flax, hemp, oil-seed cake, linseed and grass seed, butter, eggs, wool, hides, and hog bristles. Wood, lumber, and timber are also exported in large amounts. England is Russia's biggest customer, with annual imports of the mentioned products (including grain) exceeding $112 million.

[124]RUSSIA'S MINERAL WEALTH

In minerals Russia is enormously wealthy, but the mining lands are not diffused throughout the empire but confined to definite areas. Nor can they be said to be energetically worked. The great gold-fields of the Ural mountains would not pay expenses as worked at present were they not supplied with convict labour. Owing to the heavy import duty which is imposed on pig-iron nearly all the iron now needed for the iron manufactures of the empire is obtained at home, but this amounts to only 46 pounds per inhabitant, as against 810 pounds per inhabitant used in Britain. Coal is very abundant, especially in the valley of the Donetz, but fire-wood is so plentiful for domestic purposes, and water power so plentiful for heavy manufactures, that the amount of coal mined in all Russia is only one twelfth that mined in Germany, and only one twenty-fourth that mined in Britain. Over 2,250,000 tons of coal are imported despite very heavy protective duties. There is one mineral product, however, in which Russia excels all other European countries. This is petroleum. The oil-springs on the Caspian Sea produce an annual yield of crude petroleum of an average value of $15,000,000. The value of the petroleum and petroleum products exported in 1896 was over $22,000,000.

In minerals, Russia is extremely rich, but the mining areas are not spread out across the country; they are limited to specific regions. They also aren’t being worked very actively. The vast gold fields in the Ural Mountains wouldn’t cover costs under current operations if they weren’t supported by convict labor. Due to the high import duty on pig iron, almost all the iron required for the iron industries in the country comes from domestic sources, but this only amounts to 46 pounds per person, compared to 810 pounds per person used in Britain. Coal is very abundant, especially in the Donetz Valley, but since firewood is so readily available for home use and there is so much water power for heavy industries, the total amount of coal mined in Russia is just one-twelfth of what is mined in Germany and one-twenty-fourth of what is mined in Britain. Over 2,250,000 tons of coal are imported despite significant protective tariffs. However, there is one mineral product in which Russia outshines all other European countries: oil. The oil springs near the Caspian Sea produce an annual output of crude petroleum valued at approximately $15,000,000. In 1896, the value of exported petroleum and petroleum products was over $22,000,000.

RUSSIA'S TRADE AND MANUFACTURES

Despite Russia's resources in farm products and in minerals, yet, owing to the ignorance and degradation of her people, she is a poor country, and her exports are always more than her imports. Her total wealth per inhabitant is only $305, as against $780 per inhabitant for[125] Germany, $1260 for France, and $1510 for Great Britain and Ireland. Her total foreign trade is only $5 per inhabitant, whereas the foreign trade of her neighbour, Germany, is $35 per inhabitant. Her total internal trade is only $50 per inhabitant, whereas even in Greece the internal trade is $65 per inhabitant, while in Germany it is $130 per inhabitant, and in the United States $215 per inhabitant. The reason of all this is the lack of energy and industry in the people. Their earnings per inhabitant average only 12 cents a day. Another reason is the lack of modern labour-saving devices. Comparing inhabitant with inhabitant, Russia has only one sixth of the steam power which Germany has. One half of all the manufactures of the country are produced domestically—that is, without motive power or machinery. No industry in Russia is fully up to the needs of the people when judged by the standards of other countries. For example, notwithstanding the severity of the climate, only two pounds of raw wool per inhabitant are consumed in Russia's woollen manufactures, as against seven pounds consumed in Germany, and the total annual value of all manufactures is only $20 per inhabitant, as against $56 in Germany, and $88 in Britain. Notwithstanding these unfavourable comparisons, the factory industries of Russia are making progress. In seventy years the textile factories have increased fivefold and in thirty years twofold. In sixty years the cotton-manufacturing industry has increased sevenfold, and in fifteen years twofold. Until recently Russia exported wool. Now she imports more wool than she exports. Ninety years ago in Russia iron was dearer than bread, and the peasants used wooden plough-shares and left their horses unshod. Now the consumption of hardware, though still per inhabitant the smallest in Europe, is yet in the aggregate the fourth in Europe, although even so it is only two ninths what it is in Britain.[126] Beet-root sugar-making is also a new industry, and 500,000 tons are made annually, the number of sugar works being 235. The beet-root crop of the country amounts to nearly 6,000,000 tons annually. But the consumption of sugar per inhabitant is only seven pounds annually, as against eighteen pounds per inhabitant in Germany. A universal industry throughout Russia is tanning, and Russia leather, with its fragrant birch-oil odour, is a highly prized commodity the world over. But the amount manufactured is only 114,000 tons yearly, and the quantity exported is inconsiderable.

Despite Russia's resources in agricultural products and minerals, it remains a poor country due to the ignorance and hardship of its people. Its exports consistently exceed its imports. The total wealth per person is just $305, compared to $780 in [125] Germany, $1260 in France, and $1510 in Great Britain and Ireland. Russia's total foreign trade is only $5 per person, while Germany’s foreign trade is $35 per person. The total internal trade in Russia is merely $50 per person, whereas even Greece has $65 per person, Germany has $130 per person, and the United States has $215 per person. This situation arises from a lack of energy and industry among the people, which leads to an average income of only 12 cents a day per person. Another issue is the absence of modern labor-saving technologies. For each person, Russia has only one-sixth the steam power that Germany has. Half of all manufacturing in the country is done without any machinery or power. No industry in Russia meets the needs of its people when compared to standards in other countries. For instance, despite the harsh climate, only two pounds of raw wool per person are used in Russia’s woolen industry, compared to seven pounds in Germany. The total annual value of all manufacturing is just $20 per person, compared to $56 in Germany and $88 in Britain. Despite these unfavorable comparisons, Russia's factory-based industries are advancing. In the past seventy years, textile factories have increased fivefold, and in the last thirty years, they have doubled. The cotton manufacturing industry has grown sevenfold in sixty years and doubled in fifteen years. Until recently, Russia exported wool, but now it imports more wool than it exports. Ninety years ago, iron was more expensive than bread in Russia, and peasants used wooden plowshares and left their horses unshod. Nowadays, while hardware consumption per person is still the lowest in Europe, Russia's total consumption ranks fourth in Europe, even though it is only two-ninths of what it is in Britain.[126] Sugar production from beetroot is a new industry, yielding 500,000 tons annually from 235 sugar factories. The beetroot crop totals nearly 6,000,000 tons each year. However, sugar consumption per person is only seven pounds annually, compared to eighteen pounds per person in Germany. Tanning is a widespread industry in Russia, and Russian leather, known for its fragrant birch-oil scent, is a highly valued product globally. Yet, the amount produced is only 114,000 tons a year, with negligible exports.

RUSSIA'S RAILWAYS AND NAVIGABLE RIVERS

The most characteristic physical feature of European Russia is its flatness. In consequence its rivers are almost all navigable, and, as the most important of them are interconnected by canals, the facilities for transportation which they afford are very considerable. Altogether the length of inland navigation thus afforded amounts to nearly 47,000 miles. This abundance of navigation facilities has retarded the growth of railways, but there are already 25,756 miles of finished railway in European Russia alone. The total length of railway in all Russia built and in building is 34,849 miles. The most important railway enterprise in the empire is the Trans-Siberian Railway, which will afford through communication from the Baltic to the Pacific. The shortest possible distance between these two bodies of water is 4500 miles. The length of the railway will be 4950 miles, and its cost, it is supposed, will be $120,000,000. It is to be completed by 1905.

The most noticeable physical feature of European Russia is its flatness. Because of this, nearly all of its rivers are navigable, and since the main rivers are linked by canals, they provide significant transportation opportunities. In total, the length of navigable waterways is almost 47,000 miles. This abundance of navigable routes has slowed the development of railways; however, there are already 25,756 miles of completed railway in European Russia alone. The overall length of railways in all of Russia, both completed and under construction, is 34,849 miles. The biggest railway project in the empire is the Trans-Siberian Railway, which will connect the Baltic to the Pacific. The shortest distance between these two bodies of water is 4,500 miles. The railway will be 4,950 miles long and is expected to cost $120,000,000. It is scheduled to be finished by 1905.

RUSSIA'S CITIES AND TOWNS

Moscow. Moscow.

St. Petersburg (with suburbs 1,267,000), the capital of Russia, is, like most European capitals, an important[127] trade centre as well as the seat of government. Its manufactures are general and numerous, but the chief ones are those concerned in making munitions of war. Until 1885 St. Petersburg was not a seaport, but in that year a canal was built which now permits vessels drawing twenty-two feet of water to enter its docks. Its harbour, however, is closed with ice from November to May. Near St. Petersburg is Reval, the chief cotton port of Russia. The raw cotton importation of Russia averages about $60,000,000 annually, most of which comes direct from the United States. Moscow (988,000), the ancient capital of Russia, is also a great manufacturing city, but its principal importance is derived from the fact that it is the great centre of the internal trade of Russia. Warsaw (615,000), the capital of Polish Russia, is a great railway centre, and the principal entrepôt of railway traffic between Russia and the rest of Europe. Lódz (315,000), also in Polish Russia, is the great cotton-manufacturing centre of the empire. Odessa (405,000) is the chief seaport of Russia. It has an immense export trade in grain, tallow, iron, linseed,[128] wood, hides, cordage, sailcloth, tar, and beef. Riga (283,000), the chief port of Russia on the Baltic, has a large export trade with England in characteristic Russian produce. Kieff (249,000) is the centre of the Russian sugar-refining industry. Astrakhan (113,000), on the Volga delta, is noted for its sturgeon fisheries, and its export of caviare, amounting, it is said, to $1,500,000 yearly. Tula (111,000) is the Sheffield of Russia. Even in 1828 there were 600 cutlery establishments in Tula, but the manufacture was then principally domestic. It is now a city of factories, for it stands on a large coal and iron field. Nijni-Novgorod (99,000) is noted for its fair, an Asiatic institution which modern civilisation will no doubt soon disestablish. Once a year merchants to the number of 200,000 come to Nijni-Novgorod from all over Russia, and even from India and China, to exchange their wares. The value of the exchange sometimes amounts to $100,000,000. Orenburg (73,000), on the Ural, is the terminal depot of the caravan trade of Asiatic Russia. Archangel (25,000), on the White Sea, is the chief emporium of trade in the north, with exports of characteristic northern produce. Baku, on the Caspian Sea, is the chief seat of the petroleum industry of Russia. All the towns and cities above named have grown enormously during the last twenty years.

Saint Petersburg (with suburbs 1,267,000), the capital of Russia, is, like most European capitals, an important[127] trade center and the seat of government. Its manufacturing is diverse and plentiful, but the main focus is on producing weapons. Until 1885, St. Petersburg wasn’t a seaport, but that year a canal was built that now allows vessels drawing twenty-two feet of water to access its docks. However, its harbor is frozen shut from November to May. Close to St. Petersburg is Reval, the main cotton port of Russia. The country imports about $60,000,000 worth of raw cotton each year, most of it coming directly from the United States. Moscow (988,000), the historic capital of Russia, is also a major manufacturing city, but its primary significance comes from being the main hub for internal trade in Russia. Warszawa (615,000), the capital of Polish Russia, is a major railway hub and the key point of railway traffic between Russia and the rest of Europe. Łódź (315,000), also in Polish Russia, is the main cotton manufacturing center of the empire. Odesa (405,000) is Russia's principal seaport, with a massive export trade in grain, tallow, iron, linseed,[128] wood, hides, cordage, sailcloth, tar, and beef. Riga (283,000), the leading port of Russia on the Baltic, has a significant export trade with England featuring typical Russian products. Kiev (249,000) is the center of Russia's sugar-refining industry. Astrakhan (113,000), located on the Volga delta, is famous for its sturgeon fisheries and exports of caviar, which reportedly amount to $1,500,000 per year. Tula (111,000) is often called the Sheffield of Russia. Even in 1828, there were 600 cutlery businesses in Tula, but then most production was for home use. Now, it's a city filled with factories, built on a large coal and iron field. Nizhny Novgorod (99,000) is famous for its fair, an Asian tradition that modern civilization will likely soon replace. Once a year, about 200,000 merchants from all over Russia, and even from India and China, come to Nijni-Novgorod to trade their goods. The total value of exchanges can reach $100,000,000. Orenburg (73,000), located on the Ural, is the final stop for the caravan trade from Asian Russia. Angel (25,000), on the White Sea, is the main trade center in the north, exporting typical northern products. Baku, by the Caspian Sea, is the leading center for the petroleum industry in Russia. All the cities and towns mentioned above have seen tremendous growth in the last twenty years.

[129]VI. THE TRADE FEATURES OF INDIA

INDIA'S PAST AND PRESENT COMPARED

To the student of civilisation India is one of the most interesting countries in the world. It has always been one of the most fertile and populous regions of the globe. For centuries it was thought to be one of the richest. In consequence it has, time and time again, been the scene of invasion, conquest, and spoliation. But its riches never consisted so much in natural treasure as in the savings of an industrious and frugal people. Since the year 1600 European nations have had much to do with India, especially England, France, Portugal, and Holland. During the last 140 years, however, England has been the dominant power there. Whatever may be said as to the motive of England's interference in India's affairs in the first place, it can only be said that the present influence of England in India is immensely beneficial to the country. India's prosperity on the whole is now comparable with that of any civilised nation on the globe. And a people that once, because of repeated conquest and spoliation, had lost all sense of honour and self-respect, are now, under the benign influence of peace, law, order, and security, rapidly becoming honourable, self[130]-reliant, and enterprising, and ambitious to possess all the rights and privileges of modern civilisation.

To anyone studying civilization, India is one of the most fascinating countries in the world. It has always been one of the most fertile and densely populated areas on the planet. For centuries, it was considered one of the richest. As a result, it has repeatedly experienced invasion, conquest, and plunder. However, its wealth was never just in natural resources but in the savings of a hardworking and frugal population. Since 1600, European nations, particularly England, France, Portugal, and Holland, have been heavily involved with India. Over the last 140 years, though, England has been the dominant power there. Regardless of the reasons behind England's initial involvement in Indian affairs, it's clear that England's current influence is extremely beneficial for the country. Overall, India's prosperity is now on par with that of any civilized nation in the world. A population that once lost all sense of honor and self-respect due to constant conquest and destruction is now, thanks to the positive effects of peace, law, order, and security, quickly becoming honorable, self-reliant, enterprising, and eager to obtain all the rights and privileges of modern civilization.

INDIA'S SIZE AND POPULATION

India is a much larger and more populous country than most people think it to be. In shape it is somewhat like a huge kite, each of whose diameters is over 2000 miles long, or more than the distance across the Atlantic from Ireland to Newfoundland. Its territory is about 1,700,000 square miles. Of this area, over 1,000,000 square miles, a territory considerably greater than the territory of all the states of Europe (including the British Isles) except Russia, is directly under British control. The remainder is indirectly under British control. The population is 308,000,000, of which 236,000,000 are directly under British control and 72,000,000 indirectly so. This population is made up of people who speak seventy-eight different languages, of which twenty languages are spoken by not less than 1,000,000 persons each.

India is a much larger and more populous country than most people realize. Its shape is somewhat like a giant kite, with each side measuring over 2000 miles long, which is more than the distance across the Atlantic from Ireland to Newfoundland. Its area is about 1,700,000 square miles. Within this area, over 1,000,000 square miles, which is significantly larger than the combined area of all the European countries (including the British Isles) except Russia, is directly controlled by the British. The rest is under indirect British control. The population is 308,000,000, out of which 236,000,000 live under direct British control, and 72,000,000 are indirectly controlled. This population comprises people who speak seventy-eight different languages, with twenty of those languages spoken by at least 1,000,000 people each.

INDIA'S GREAT FERTILITY

India owes much of its fertility to the fact that its soil is constantly being replenished by alluvium brought down from its high mountains by its immense rivers. The valleys of the Indus (1800 miles long), the Ganges (1600 miles long), and the Brahmapootra (1500 miles long) include an area of 1,125,000 square miles, a part of which, the Indus-Ganges plain, consists of a great stretch of alluvial soil whose fertility is as rich as that of any portion of the globe. One hundred and eighty millions of people live in this plain. So finely pulverised is its soil that for a distance of almost 2000 miles not even a pebble can be found in it. And so fertile is it[131] that there are some agricultural districts in the plain where the population exceeds 900 to the square mile. In that part of the plain which the Ganges waters, 60,000,000 of people find support on the soil by agriculture, at a density of over 700 persons to the square mile, which is 140 persons more to the square mile than the density of Belgium, the most thickly populated country in Europe.

India owes much of its fertility to the fact that its soil is constantly being replenished by alluvium brought down from its high mountains by its immense rivers. The valleys of the Indus (1,800 miles long), the Ganges (1,600 miles long), and the Brahmaputra (1,500 miles long) cover an area of 1,125,000 square miles, part of which, the Indus-Ganges plain, consists of a vast stretch of alluvial soil as fertile as any area in the world. One hundred eighty million people live in this plain. The soil is so finely crushed that for almost 2,000 miles, not even a pebble can be found. And it is so fertile that there are some agricultural regions in the plain where the population density exceeds 900 people per square mile. In the part of the plain irrigated by the Ganges, 60 million people rely on agriculture for their livelihoods, with a density of over 700 people per square mile, which is 140 people more per square mile than Belgium, the most densely populated country in Europe.[131]

INDIA'S IRRIGATION CANALS AND RIVER EMBANKMENTS

But, fertile as is the soil of India, and propitious to agricultural industry as is its climate generally, its climate is not always favourable. It suffers periodically from excess of drought. As a consequence artificial irrigation has to be resorted to, or much of this fertile country would oftentimes be a desert. In British India alone 28,000 miles of irrigation canals are under the control of the government, 14,000 of which have been constructed by the present (British) government—works of vast dimensions and the highest engineering skill. Altogether 28,000,000 acres in British India are dependent for their necessary supply of moisture upon general irrigation, and 8,000,000 upon irrigation canals. Were it not for these irrigation canals, 2,000,000 acres in Scinde (northwestern India) would be a perpetual desert, for Scinde is almost wholly rainless. On the other hand, in a great part of India the rainfall is excessive. Some districts indeed are the wettest on the globe. In Assam, for example (which is also one of the hottest places in India), the rainfall is 600 inches yearly, and it has been 650. As a consequence rivers in India often overflow their banks. Therefore to protect the country on the lower river reaches from floods the British government has built over 1500 miles of embankments.

But, while the soil of India is very fertile and its climate is generally good for agriculture, it’s not always favorable. It periodically experiences severe droughts. As a result, artificial irrigation is necessary, or much of this fertile land would often turn into desert. In British India alone, the government manages 28,000 miles of irrigation canals, 14,000 of which have been built by the current (British) government—major projects that showcase top-notch engineering skills. In total, 28 million acres in British India rely on general irrigation for adequate moisture, and 8 million depend on irrigation canals. Without these canals, 2 million acres in Scinde (northwestern India) would remain constantly desert since Scinde receives almost no rain. Conversely, many areas in India experience excessive rainfall. Some districts are indeed among the wettest on Earth. For instance, in Assam (which is also one of the hottest places in India), the annual rainfall reaches 600 inches, and has even been recorded at 650 inches. As a result, rivers in India frequently overflow their banks. To protect lower regions from flooding, the British government has constructed over 1,500 miles of embankments.

[132]INDIA'S MINERAL RESOURCES

At one time India was famed for its wealth in precious minerals and precious stones. Poets often celebrated its golden resources. But its wealth in this respect was always fabulous rather than real. India is in reality poor in minerals. It has a good deal of iron—iron of the choicest quality. It has also a good deal of coal, but its coal is poor, owing to its superabundance of ash. It has also a little copper and tin. It has gold-mines that are worked. Diamonds, too, are found in southern India, and numerously so. The celebrated Koh-i-nur (280 carats) was an Indian product. But neither diamond-hunting nor gold-mining is any longer a profitable industry in India. The principal mineral industry of India is salt-mining, pursued in the Punjaub, where there are solid cliffs of pure salt. Owing to the fact that the people of India are mostly vegetarians (250,000,000 of Hindoos would rather die than eat flesh), salt is a necessary article of diet and a universal commodity. Its production, therefore, is controlled by the government as a means of raising revenue.

At one point, India was well-known for its wealth in precious minerals and gemstones. Poets often sang the praises of its abundant resources. However, this wealth was more of a myth than a reality. In truth, India lacks many minerals. It does have a fair amount of high-quality iron and a significant amount of coal, although the coal is of poor quality due to a high ash content. There's also a small amount of copper and tin available. India has operational gold mines, and diamonds are found in large quantities in southern India. The famous Koh-i-nur diamond (280 carats) originated in India. Nonetheless, diamond mining and gold mining are no longer profitable industries there. The main mineral industry in India is salt mining, which takes place in Punjab, where there are solid cliffs of pure salt. Because most people in India are vegetarians (250 million Hindus would rather die than eat meat), salt is a crucial part of their diet and a widely used commodity. As a result, its production is regulated by the government to generate revenue.

[133]INDIA'S WONDERFUL AGRICULTURAL RESOURCES

Comparative sizes of India and the United States. Comparing the sizes of India and the United States.

The real wealth of India lies in the luxuriance and economic value of its vegetation. As a consequence the principal industry is agriculture. Only one tenth of the people live in towns. Two thirds of the adult males in the country are engaged wholly in tilling the soil. Every sort of agricultural product known to commerce is raised in India; for from the high levels on the mountain sides to the low levels on the coasts the vegetation of the whole world is produced within its borders. Even in wheat India competes in the world's markets with countries like Russia and Argentina. In 1896 British India had 19,000,000 acres of wheat under cultivation, and (though a dearth year) an exportation of $4,000,000. In 1892 the exportation was $25,000,000. The district known as the Central Provinces of India has become one of the most important wheat areas in the world. But the principal agricultural product of India is rice. British India alone has 70,000,000 acres of rice under cultivation, and an annual exportation of $60,000,000. In all the coast regions rice is grown universally, and also in the lower parts of the river plains, especially in the[134] Ganges valley. It is the staple food of the people everywhere except on the higher levels. On the higher levels millet and maize (corn) are the staple foods. The next important agricultural product of India is cotton, of which $47,000,000 worth in the raw state is exported annually, besides what is used at home. The American civil war was the great cause of the starting of the cotton-growing industry in India. The next important agricultural product is jute, of which the export in the raw state is about $35,000,000. No country in the world can compete with India in the production of this fibre, for jute is very exhaustive of the soil, and in the Ganges valley, where it is principally raised, the soil is annually replenished by alluvium. A fifth great agricultural product is tea, in which India now leads the world. England uses twice as much India tea as China tea, the reason being that India teas are produced with all the economic care of a high-class English or American manufactured product. The value of the tea export of India is about $27,000,000. Other chief agricultural products are opium (which is a government monopoly), oil seeds, hides, and skins, indigo (in which India excels the world, the value of the export being $14,000,000), coffee (the best grown anywhere—except perhaps that of Arabia and Java—though the bean is sometimes injured in transit), raw wool, lac (for dyeing), cinchona or Peruvian bark (which since it has been raised in India, has greatly reduced the price of quinine), raw silk, raw sugar, tobacco, and spices. Spices are produced abundantly in India, but their quality is not equal to East Indian spices. Also the cotton, rice, sugar, and tobacco of India, though produced plentifully, are inferior in quality to those of the United States. Nor are the wheat and corn of India so good as the wheat and corn of the United States and Canada. Improved cultivation will, however, in time improve the quality of all these[135] products. Of exports of natural products not agricultural the principal are wood (chiefly teak, the most valuable timber known for ship-building, and sal, a most valuable wood for carpentry) and saltpetre.

The real wealth of India lies in the abundance and economic value of its plants. As a result, the main industry is farming. Only one-tenth of the population lives in cities. Two-thirds of adult men are fully engaged in farming. Every type of agricultural product available in commerce is grown in India; from the high altitudes of the mountains to the lowlands of the coasts, the vegetation of the entire world is produced within its borders. Even in wheat, India competes in the global market with countries like Russia and Argentina. In 1896, British India had 19,000,000 acres of wheat under cultivation, and despite it being a drought year, they exported $4,000,000. In 1892, exports reached $25,000,000. The region known as the Central Provinces of India has become one of the most significant wheat-producing areas in the world. However, the main agricultural product of India is rice. British India alone cultivates 70,000,000 acres of rice, generating an annual export of $60,000,000. Rice is universally grown in all coastal regions and also in the lower river plains, especially in the[134] Ganges valley. It's the staple food for people everywhere except in the higher elevations, where millet and maize (corn) are the staples. The next important agricultural product is cotton, with $47,000,000 worth of raw cotton exported annually, in addition to domestic use. The American Civil War sparked the growth of cotton cultivation in India. Following cotton, jute fiber is another significant agricultural product, with an export value of around $35,000,000 in its raw form. No other country can compete with India in jute production, as it heavily depletes the soil, but in the Ganges valley, where it's primarily grown, the soil is annually refreshed by alluvial deposits. A fifth major agricultural product is tea, where India now leads globally. England consumes twice as much Indian tea as Chinese tea because Indian teas are produced with the same economic care as high-quality English or American manufactured goods. The value of India's tea exports is about $27,000,000. Other significant agricultural products include opioid (which is a government monopoly), oil seeds, hides and skins, indigo (where India excels globally, exporting $14,000,000), coffee (considered the best cultivated anywhere, except perhaps for that of Arabia and Java, although the beans can sometimes be damaged in transport), raw wool, lac (used for dyeing), cinchona or Peruvian bark (which has significantly lowered the price of quinine since being cultivated in India), raw silk, raw sugar, tobacco, and spices. While India produces spices abundantly, their quality does not match that of East Indian spices. Additionally, India's cotton, rice, sugar, and tobacco, although produced in large quantities, are of lower quality compared to those of the United States. The wheat and corn from India are also inferior to those from the United States and Canada. However, improved cultivation practices will, in time, enhance the quality of all these[135] products. Among non-agricultural natural product exports, the primary ones are wood (mainly teak wood, the most valuable timber for shipbuilding, and sal, a highly valued wood for carpentry) and saltpeter.

INDIA'S GROWING MANUFACTURES

Though India is now chiefly an agricultural country her people from time immemorial have been adepts in manufacturing. The domestic textile manufactures and the domestic metal manufactures of India were for ages among the most beautiful and ingenious in the world. These domestic manufactures are principally pursued in small villages, of which there are over half a million in India. But under the influences of modern civilisation introduced by British rule, the domestic industries of the country are now giving way to factory industries. These have already become well established, and are rapidly increasing in number and importance. The stability of India as a nation is now so well assured that capital can be had there as cheaply as in England or the United States. Besides, co-operative or joint-stock enterprises are becoming common. The Indian people, with their natural aptitude for weaving, make the best of textile operatives, and India bids fair soon to become a formidable rival of Western nations in textile manufactures. In twenty years the cotton spindles have increased sixfold. In ten years the cotton output has increased twofold. Bombay has become one of the greatest cotton centres in the world, a sort of Liverpool and Manchester combined. It has practically shut the doors of India to English manufactured cottons of the cheaper grades. Bombay manufactured cotton is even sent to England in immense quantities, but the principal export is to China. The total export of Indian manufac[136]tured cotton is $23,000,000. Another important modern manufacture is that of jute. The jute factories of Bengal are now competing with those of Scotland, and the total export is $17,500,000. A similar development is expected in iron manufactures, for already iron-smelting has begun. But, notwithstanding these developments, India still remains a tremendous market for the manufactured goods of England, especially in cottons and hardware and machinery. The value of the annual cotton importation from England is $100,000,000, equal to the total of England's exportation of goods of every sort to the United States. The value of the annual hardware and machinery importation from England is $35,000,000.

Although India is primarily an agricultural country today, its people have been skilled in manufacturing for centuries. The domestic textile and metal goods of India have long been recognized as some of the most beautiful and innovative worldwide. These domestic industries mainly operate in small villages, of which there are over half a million in India. However, under the influence of modern civilization brought by British rule, traditional domestic industries are now being replaced by factory-based industries. These factory industries are becoming well established and are quickly growing in number and significance. India's stability as a nation is now so assured that capital is available there as affordably as in England or the United States. Additionally, co-operative or joint-stock ventures are becoming increasingly common. The Indian people, with their natural talent for weaving, make excellent textile workers, and India is likely to soon become a major competitor to Western nations in textile manufacturing. Over the past twenty years, the number of cotton spindles has increased sixfold. In the last ten years, the cotton output has doubled. Bombay has emerged as one of the largest cotton centers in the world, similar to a combination of Liverpool and Manchester. It has practically closed the doors of India to cheaper grades of English manufactured cotton. Cotton manufactured in Bombay is even shipped to England in huge quantities, but the main export is to China. The total export value of Indian manufactured cotton is $23,000,000. Another significant modern manufacturing sector is jute. The jute factories in Bengal are now competing with those in Scotland, with a total export value of $17,500,000. A similar growth is anticipated in iron manufacturing, as iron-smelting has already started. Nevertheless, despite these developments, India still represents a significant market for manufactured goods from England, particularly in cotton, hardware, and machinery. The annual value of cotton imports from England is $100,000,000, which is equivalent to the total value of England's export of all goods to the United States. The annual value of hardware and machinery imports from England is $35,000,000.

INDIA'S EXTERNAL AND INTERNAL TRADE

The total yearly value of the exports of India amounts to the enormous sum of $350,000,000, more than a third of the total exportation of the United States for the banner year 1897.[2] Of this England receives about one half. The total yearly value of the imports of India (exclusive of bullion) amounts to $255,000,000, which is considerably more than a third of the total importation of the United States. Of this England sends out about two thirds. (India is therefore England's best customer, although from the United States England purchases vastly more.) Of the internal trade of India no statistics are available, but with the rapid advances in modern conveniences for doing business which the country is adopting, the internal trade is also enormously increasing. Already 20,290 miles of railway are built and opened, and 13,000 miles of canals and canalised river navigation.[137] Railways are rapidly being constructed in every part of the country. Over 31,000 miles of metalled roads for highways and 106,000 of unmetalled roads are now maintained by the government as public works. There are 38,000 miles of telegraph routes. The government highways and canals as well as the railways are all splendidly engineered and solidly built works. The greatness of India is only just beginning.

The total annual value of India’s downloads is an impressive $350,000,000, which is more than a third of the total exports of the United States in the record year of 1897.[2] Out of this, England receives about half. The total annual value of India’s imports (excluding bullion) is $255,000,000, which is significantly more than a third of the total imports of the United States. Of this, England supplies about two-thirds. (India is therefore England's best customer, although England buys much more from the United States.) There are no statistics available for India’s internal trade, but with the rapid advancements in modern business practices that the country is adopting, internal trade is also growing tremendously. Currently, there are 20,290 miles of railway completed and operational, along with 13,000 miles of canals and navigable rivers.[137] Railways are being rapidly constructed throughout the country. The government maintains over 31,000 miles of paved highways and 106,000 miles of unpaved roads as public works. There are also 38,000 miles of telegraph routes. The government’s highways and canals, as well as the railways, are all excellently engineered and solidly constructed. The greatness of India is just beginning to unfold.

FOOTNOTE:

[2]The total exports of the United States for the years 1898 and 1899 have exceeded $1,200,000,000, each year. In the year 1897 they were about $1,050,000,000.

[2]The total exports of the United States for the years 1898 and 1899 were over $1.2 billion each year. In 1897, they were around $1.05 billion.

INDIA'S CITIES AND TOWNS

Calcutta (862,000) is the capital of the empire of India and the second city in the British Empire. Although situated on an arm of the delta of the Ganges, eighty miles inland, Calcutta is an immense seaport, but its sea-going privileges can be maintained only by great engineering works, because of the silt which the Ganges is constantly bringing down and depositing in its seaward channels. Calcutta enjoys almost a monopoly of the whole trade of the Ganges and Brahmapootra valleys, and until the building of the Suez Canal it had almost a monopoly of the outward trade of the whole Hindustan peninsula. Its total trade is even yet very large, aggregating for outward and inward business together about $700,000,000 per annum, a sum which can be appreciated from the fact that it is about equal to the total import trade of the whole of the United States. Bombay (822,000), the second city of the Indian Empire, owes its eminence to three things: (1) the opening of the Suez Canal, which has made it the port of India nearest England; (2) the starting of the cotton-growing industry in India, owing to the American civil war (the cotton-growing district of India is adjacent to Bombay); and (3) the development of the railway system of India, which is making Bombay rather than Calcutta the natural ocean outlet for the trade of[138] the country. Madras (453,000), the third city of India, is also the third seaport. But it has no natural harbour, and its shore is surf-beaten and for months together exposed to the full fury of the northeast monsoons. An artificial harbour, however, has recently been built. Besides the cities above mentioned there is one (Hyderabad) with a population of over 400,000; there are two (Lucknow and Benares) with a population of over 150,000 each, and eleven more with a population of over 100,000 each. There are besides forty-seven towns with a population more than 50,000 each, and over a thousand towns with a population of about 10,000 each.

Kolkata (862,000) is the capital of the Indian empire and the second-largest city in the British Empire. Even though it’s located eighty miles inland on an arm of the Ganges delta, Calcutta is a massive seaport. However, maintaining its sea access requires significant engineering efforts because the Ganges constantly brings in silt and deposits it along its seaward channels. Calcutta almost monopolizes the entire trade of the Ganges and Brahmaputra valleys, and before the Suez Canal was built, it had nearly complete control over the outward trade of the entire Hindustan peninsula. Its total trade is still quite substantial, amounting to around $700,000,000 annually, which is comparable to the total import trade of the entire United States. Mumbai (822,000), the second-largest city in the Indian Empire, owes its prominence to three factors: (1) the opening of the Suez Canal, which has made it the closest port in India to England; (2) the rise of the cotton-growing industry in India due to the American Civil War (the cotton-growing region is near Bombay); and (3) the development of India’s railway system, which is making Bombay a more natural ocean outlet for the country’s trade instead of Calcutta. Chennai (453,000), the third city in India, is also the third-largest seaport. Yet, it lacks a natural harbor, and its coastline is battered by waves and exposed to the full force of the northeast monsoons for months. However, a man-made harbor has been built recently. Besides the cities mentioned, there is one (Hyderabad) with a population over 400,000; two (Lucknow and Varanasi) with populations exceeding 150,000 each, and eleven more with over 100,000 each. Additionally, there are forty-seven towns with populations over 50,000 each, and over a thousand towns with populations around 10,000 each.

[139]VII. THE TRADE FEATURES OF CHINA

THE VASTNESS OF CHINA'S AREA AND POPULATION

China, to the student of commerce, is the most interesting country on the globe. The reason for this is that its area is so large, its population so vast, and its chances for development so magnificent. The total area of the empire, according to late estimates, is 4,218,401 square miles. Other estimates make it 4,468,470 square miles. The greatness of this area may be understood from a few comparisons. It is about one twelfth of the total land surface of the globe. It is two and one fourth times the size of European Russia. It is almost one and one half times the total area of the United States, exclusive of Alaska. But all of this territory is not of equal commercial interest. The Chinese Empire consists of six parts: China Proper, Manchuria, Mongolia, Tibet, Jungaria, and Eastern Turkestan. Because of recent treaties, which give to Russia the right to build and "control" railways in Manchuria—ostensibly for the purpose of securing for the great Russian Trans-Siberian Railway a shorter route to Vladivostok, its Pacific terminus—Manchuria becomes practically a Russian possession. Turkestan, Jungaria, Tibet, and Mongolia are thinly inhabited coun[140]tries, scarcely semi-civilised. But the part which remains when these "dependencies" are left out of consideration—China Proper—is at once one of the largest, most thickly populated, and most fertile countries on the face of the globe, and one also of the most richly endowed in mineral products. Its area is 1,336,841 square miles. Its population is 386,000,000. Its population per square mile is not far short of 300. That is to say, its area is more than eleven times that of Great Britain and Ireland, and almost one half that of the United States, exclusive of Alaska; its population is ten times that of Great Britain and Ireland, and more than six times that of the United States; while its population per square mile is greater than that of any European or American country except Great Britain (which, however, it nearly equals), Holland, and Belgium. In fact, more than one fourth of the total population of the globe is concentrated within the boundaries of China Proper.

China, for business students, is the most fascinating country in the world. This is because its land area is incredibly large, its population is massive, and its potential for growth is extraordinary. Recent estimates put the total area of the empire at 4,218,401 square miles, with other estimates suggesting it could be 4,468,470 square miles. To grasp the size of this area, a few comparisons help. It represents about one twelfth of the Earth's total land surface, is two and a fourth times larger than European Russia, and is nearly one and a half times the size of the United States, without counting Alaska. However, not all of this area has the same commercial value. The Chinese Empire is divided into six regions: China Proper, Manchuria, Mongolia, Tibet, Jungaria, and Eastern Turkestan. Recent treaties have granted Russia the right to build and “control” railways in Manchuria—allegedly to create a shorter route for the Russian Trans-Siberian Railway to reach Vladivostok, its Pacific terminus—so Manchuria effectively becomes a Russian possession. Turkestan, Jungaria, Tibet, and Mongolia are sparsely populated regions, hardly semi-civilized. But what remains after excluding these “dependencies”—China Proper—is one of the largest, most densely populated, and most fertile regions in the world, and it's also richly endowed with mineral resources. Its area measures 1,336,841 square miles, and it has a population of 386,000,000. The population density is close to 300 people per square mile. This means its area is more than eleven times that of Great Britain and Ireland, and almost half of the United States' size, excluding Alaska. Its population is ten times greater than that of Great Britain and Ireland and more than six times that of the United States, while its population density is higher than any other European or American country except Great Britain (which it almost matches), the Netherlands, and Belgium. In fact, more than a quarter of the entire world’s population is concentrated within the borders of China Proper.

CHINA A COUNTRY OF GREAT TRADE POSSIBILITIES

The great commercial nations of the world are now all trying to get shares of the trade of this vast and populous country. For not only is China (Proper) large and populous, but it is also wealthy, for its inhabitants are both industrious and frugal, and, besides, as compared with the people of European countries they have been greatly spared the disastrous commerce-destroying effects of war, both foreign and internecine. Centuries ago the Chinese had made great progress toward civilisation. Their skill in the manufacturing arts, and in agriculture and horticulture, was for ages superior to that of Western nations. But, unfortunately for their advancement, they are conservative, self-conceited, and averse to improvement, especially if they have to learn improvement of others. As[141] yet they have almost wholly ignored the ideas and methods of modern Western civilisation. They have scarcely any railways, but few steamships, almost no steam-power manufactories, and no telephones. The only modern improvement which they have made much use of is the telegraph. Some years ago (in 1876) a European company secured the privilege of building a short railway from Shanghai, but it was scarcely built before the government got fearful of its influence and bought it up and stopped its running. But the Chinese people are not averse to foreign trade; on the contrary, they are rather fond of it. If only the thing could happen in China that happened in Japan—that is to say, if only the government could fall into the hands of rulers who were open-minded to improvement and inclined to be progressive—the rush that China would make toward civilisation and the adoption of modern trade methods and modern processes of manufacture would be startling.

The major commercial nations of the world are all trying to get a piece of the trade in this large and crowded country. Not only is China (Proper) large and populated, but it’s also wealthy, since its people are both hardworking and thrifty. Additionally, compared to people in European countries, they have largely been spared the devastating effects of war, both foreign and civil. Centuries ago, the Chinese made significant strides toward civilization. Their skills in manufacturing, agriculture, and horticulture were superior to those of Western nations for a long time. Unfortunately, their progress has been hindered because they tend to be conservative, self-satisfied, and resistant to change, especially if it means learning from others. As[141] yet, they have almost completely ignored the ideas and methods of modern Western civilization. They have very few railways, a limited number of steamships, almost no steam-powered factories, and no telephones. The only modern advancement they have widely adopted is the telegraph. A few years ago (in 1876), a European company was given permission to build a short railway from Shanghai, but it was barely constructed when the government grew concerned about its influence, bought it out, and shut it down. However, the Chinese people are not opposed to foreign trade; in fact, they quite enjoy it. If only China could experience what happened in Japan—if the government could fall into the hands of leaders who are open to change and inclined to progress—the surge toward civilization and the embrace of modern trade practices and manufacturing techniques would be remarkable.

CHINA'S FOREIGN TRADE

At present the foreign trade of China is largely in the hands of the English. In the year 1896 the foreign export trade of China amounted to $167,000,000. Of this amount $132,500,000 was with Great Britain and her dependencies; $10,000,000 with the United States; something over $8,000,000 with the continent of Europe exclusive of Russia, and less than $2,000,000 with Russia. In the same year the foreign import trade of China was $102,500,000, of which $56,000,000 was with Great Britain and her dependencies; a little over $9,000,000 with the United States; $15,000,000 with the continent of Europe exclusive of Russia, and $12,500,000 with Russia. (The rest of her trade was principally with Japan.) The policy of the government of China has always been to prevent or[142] restrict foreign trade; and even to-day foreign trade can be carried on in only twenty-six Chinese ports—the so-called "treaty ports." The policy of Great Britain has been to secure by treaty as large a privilege of trading with China as possible; then to throw open the privilege to the world, but to follow it up with such commercial activity on her own part as would secure to her the lion's share of the resulting trade. Of the twenty-six ports now by treaty open to the world for trade, twenty-three have been secured by Great Britain and three by Japan.

Right now, foreign trade in China is mainly controlled by the British. In 1896, China's foreign export trade totaled $167,000,000. Out of this, $132,500,000 was with Great Britain and its colonies; $10,000,000 with the United States; just over $8,000,000 with continental Europe, excluding Russia; and less than $2,000,000 with Russia. In the same year, China's foreign import trade reached $102,500,000, with $56,000,000 from Great Britain and its colonies; a little over $9,000,000 from the United States; $15,000,000 from continental Europe, excluding Russia; and $12,500,000 from Russia. (Most of the rest of its trade was mainly with Japan.) The Chinese government has always aimed to prevent or[142] limit foreign trade; even today, foreign trade can only happen in twenty-six Chinese ports—the so-called "open ports." Britain's approach has been to secure as many trading privileges in China as possible through treaties, then open these privileges to everyone while ensuring that their own commercial activities would capture the majority of the resulting trade. Out of the twenty-six ports currently open to international trade, twenty-three have been secured by Great Britain and three by Japan.

CHINA'S EXPORTS, IMPORTS, AND RESOURCES

China's principal exports are tea and silk, tea constituting about one third and silk (principally raw silk) fully one half of her total export trade. Other principal exports are sugar, straw braid (one twentieth of her total exportation), hides, paper, chinaware, and pottery. Her principal imports are opium and cotton goods, opium constituting a fifth, and cotton goods considerably more than a half, of her total import trade. Other principal imports are woollen goods, metal goods and machinery, coal, and kerosene oil. A considerable importation is also made of raw cotton. But if China only had the blessing of an enlightened and progressive government this disposition of exports and imports would not long continue. China's resources of coal are among the finest and certainly among the largest in the whole world. Her coal-fields, indeed, are estimated to be twenty times as great as those of all Europe combined. Much of this coal, too, is of the purest quality, and much of it very accessible to the miner. And near her coal-fields are vast deposits of some of the richest iron ores in the world. Again, a great portion of the soil of China is extremely fertile. There are indeed two regions, one of "red soil" and another, much[143] vaster, of "yellow soil," that are among the most fertile in the world. It is because of the extent and fertility of the yellow soil of China that "yellow" is the imperial colour, and the emperor called the "yellow lord." The climate, too, of China permits almost the whole range of useful vegetable products to be raised. The growth of cotton is already very great, because for seven centuries cotton has been the staple cloth for the clothing of the people. And already it is being manufactured by modern machinery. But both the growth of cotton and its manufacture by modern methods would be enormously increased if only facilities for internal transportation existed, and freedom from unjust taxation could be secured. If, in short, China only had railways and a good and enlightened system of government her progress and prosperity would soon make the Western world envious. But her government is not only stupidly unprogressive, it is also disastrously wasteful. About seventy per cent. of the whole revenue of the country is lost to the public use through the malfeasance of officials. And only about 85 miles of railway have as yet been opened, although it must be said that 200 or 250 miles more are under construction.

China's main exports are tea and silk, with tea making up about one third and silk (mainly raw silk) accounting for about half of her total export trade. Other key exports include sugar, straw braid (which is one twentieth of her total exports), hides, paper, chinaware, and pottery. Her main imports are opioid and cotton products, with opium constituting a fifth and cotton goods making up more than half of her total imports. Other significant imports are woolen goods, metal goods and machinery, coal, and kerosene oil. A considerable amount of raw cotton is also imported. If China had the advantage of a progressive and enlightened government, this trade imbalance wouldn't last long. China's coal resources are among the best and largest in the world, with coalfields estimated to be twenty times larger than all of Europe combined. Much of this coal is of very high quality and easily accessible to miners. Additionally, there are vast deposits of some of the richest iron ore near the coalfields. A large portion of China's soil is incredibly fertile, particularly two regions: one of "red dirt" and another, much[143] larger, of "yellow dirt," which are among the most fertile globally. This extensive and fertile yellow soil is why "yellow" is the imperial color and the emperor is referred to as the "yellow lord." The climate in China also allows for a wide variety of useful crops to be grown. The cultivation of cotton has been significant since cotton has been the main fabric for people's clothing for seven centuries, and it is already being produced using modern machinery. However, the growth of cotton and its manufacturing using modern techniques would vastly increase if there were better transportation facilities within the country and relief from unjust taxes could be achieved. In short, if China had railways and a good, enlightened government system, its progress and prosperity would soon make the Western world envious. However, the current government is not only dreadfully un-progressive but also incredibly wasteful. About seventy percent of the total revenue of the country is lost to public use due to official misconduct. Currently, only about 85 miles of railway are operational, although it should be noted that an additional 200 to 250 miles are under construction.

POSSIBILITIES OF INCREASED FOREIGN TRADE WITH CHINA

There are, however, even now several ways in which foreign trade with China may be increased. Two of these are the supplying her people with woollen goods, and the supplying them with wheat and flour. The winters of a great part of China are so cool that warm garments are necessary. At present these are made principally of padded cotton. Owing to the density of the population pasturage is scarce, and sheep are almost unknown. For[144] an indefinite time, therefore, there will be a demand for woollen goods in China, a demand that will constantly increase as the superior convenience of woollen garments over garments of padded cotton becomes more and more known to the people. And though rice is now the staple food of the people even of all classes, the wealthy classes are fond of wheat bread and obtain it when possible. But the agriculture of the country does not permit of the profitable growth of wheat and flour, and wheat if used must be imported.

There are, however, still several ways to boost foreign trade with China. Two of these are providing the people with wool products and supplying them with wheat and flour. Many parts of China have cool winters, making warm clothing necessary. Right now, these are mostly made from padded cotton. Due to the high population density, grazing land is limited, and sheep are nearly nonexistent. For[144] an indefinite period, there will thus be a demand for woolen goods in China, a demand that will keep growing as people become more aware of the advantages of woolen clothing over padded cotton garments. Although rice is currently the main food for people of all classes, the wealthy enjoy wheat bread and seek it when they can. However, the country's agriculture doesn't support the profitable cultivation of wheat and flour, so wheat must be imported if it's to be used.

THE PRINCIPAL TRADING CITIES OF CHINA

The cities of China are large and numerous. Peking (1,500,000?), the capital, is not open to foreign trade. In fact, it has no trade of any sort, and derives its whole importance from being the seat of government. But Tientsin (750,000), the port of Peking, and an important "treaty port," has a large trade, both foreign and local. Tientsin and Peking are connected by rail, and since the Russian government has obtained the right of connecting Peking with the Trans-Siberian Railway, it is more than likely that in time Tientsin will become a terminus of that railway. Of "treaty ports" other than Tientsin the principal are Shanghai, Hankow, Foochow, Hangchow, Amoy, and Canton. Shanghai (405,000) exceeds all other ports of China put together in the amount of its foreign trade. Its foreign trade is, indeed, almost three fifths of that of the whole empire. And of the total number of foreigners residing in China (in 1896 said to be 10,855, of whom 4362 were British subjects and 1439 Americans) about one half reside in Shanghai. Shanghai is, indeed, the New York of China, and if railways were only built from it (as has been proposed) to the capital, Peking, and up the Yang-tse-kiang to Hankow, and by way of[145] the coast cities to Canton, China would begin a new era in her career. Hankow (800,000), on the Yang-tse-kiang, about 700 miles from its mouth, is the chief emporium of the tea-producing area of China. Ocean-going steamships ascend the river to Hankow for their cargoes. Foochow (650,900) also has a great tea export trade. Hangchow (700,000), one of the most beautiful cities in China, is also the chief city for the manufacture of silks, and of gold and silver ware, lacquered ware, and fans. Amoy (100,000) has the best harbour in China and an immense import trade, ranking in that respect next after Shanghai. Canton (2,000,000?) is the largest city in the Chinese Empire. A considerable portion of its inhabitants live in boats. Of these "house-boats" there are said to be 40,000. The foreign trade of Canton is next to that of Shanghai. Once it was superior, now it is much inferior. Its manufactures, however, are still important and include silk, cotton, glass, porcelain, paper, sugar, lacquered ware, and ivory goods and metal goods. Nanking (150,000), once the capital of China and once the largest city in the world, is now comparatively a small city. Although a treaty port, its commerce is not important. It was once famous for its beautiful tower of porcelain, 200 feet high, but that is now destroyed. There are many other large cities in China.

The cities of China are big and numerous. Beijing (1,500,000?), the capital, is not open to foreign trade. In fact, it has no trade of any kind and gets its entire importance from being the seat of government. But Tianjin (750,000), the port for Beijing and an important "treaty port," has a large amount of both foreign and local trade. Tianjin and Beijing are connected by rail, and since the Russian government has secured the right to connect Beijing with the Trans-Siberian Railway, it’s likely that over time Tianjin will become a terminus for that railway. Other significant "treaty ports" besides Tianjin include Shanghai, Hankou, Fuzhou, Hangzhou, Xiamen, and Guangzhou. Shanghai (405,000) has a foreign trade volume that exceeds all other ports in China combined, making up nearly three-fifths of the entire empire's foreign trade. Of the total number of foreigners living in China (which was said to be 10,855 in 1896, including 4,362 British subjects and 1,439 Americans), about half reside in Shanghai. Shanghai is often called the New York of China, and if railways were built from there (as has been proposed) to the capital, Beijing, and up the Yangtze River to Hankou, and along the coast to Guangzhou, China would enter a new era. Hankou (800,000), located on the Yangtze River about 700 miles from its mouth, is the main hub for the tea-producing region of China. Ocean-going steamships travel up the river to Hankou for their cargoes. Fuzhou (650,900) also has a significant tea export trade. Hangzhou (700,000), one of the most beautiful cities in China, is also the primary city for silk production, as well as gold and silver ware, lacquered goods, and fans. Xiamen (100,000) features the best harbor in China and a massive import trade, ranking second only to Shanghai in this regard. Guangzhou (2,000,000?) is the largest city in the Chinese Empire, with a substantial number of its residents living on boats. There are said to be around 40,000 of these "house-boats." The foreign trade of Guangzhou comes after that of Shanghai. It was once more significant, but now it has decreased considerably. However, its manufacturing sector remains important and produces silk, cotton, glass, porcelain, paper, sugar, lacquered goods, ivory, and metal products. Nanjing (150,000), which was once the capital of China and the largest city in the world, is now relatively small. Despite being a treaty port, its commerce isn't significant. It was once renowned for its stunning porcelain tower, which stood 200 feet high, but that has now been destroyed. There are many other large cities in China.

China and its chief trade centres. China and its main trading hubs.

[146]HONGKONG

Hongkong (245,000) is a small island belonging to Great Britain situated in the mouth of the Canton River, seventy-five miles from the city of Canton. Its population is made up principally of Chinese, who have been attracted there by its trade privileges. The British population is only 13,000, even including the garrison of 2800. Almost the whole population reside in the capital,[147] Victoria, for the island itself is a barren rock. Forty-four per cent. of the total foreign trade of China passes through Hongkong. Its harbour is one of the finest in the world. It has magnificent docks. Its port is entirely free, and there is even no custom-house. It is calculated that the foreign trade transacted by its merchants amounts to $100,000,000 a year, exclusive of what passes through its port without breaking bulk. The whole of the vast export trade of China in silk and tea is largely handled by Hongkong firms. Other commodities of which Hongkong is the chief trade centre for China are opium, flour, salt, earthenware, oil, cotton, and cotton goods and woollen goods, which it imports from other countries and exports to China; and sugar, rice, amber, sandal-wood, ivory, and betel, which it imports from China and exports to other countries. Its trade is not confined to Great Britain, but includes France, Germany, the United States, and all other trading nations. But of course Great Britain has the greatest share.

Hong Kong (245,000) is a small island that belongs to Great Britain, located at the mouth of the Canton River, seventy-five miles from the city of Canton. The population is mainly Chinese, drawn there by trade opportunities. The British community is only 13,000, including a garrison of 2,800. Nearly the entire population lives in the capital, [147] Victoria, since the island itself is mostly a barren rock. Forty-four percent of China's total foreign trade goes through Hongkong. Its harbor is one of the best in the world, featuring magnificent docks. The port is completely free, and there isn’t even a custom-house. It's estimated that the foreign trade handled by its merchants amounts to $100,000,000 a year, not counting what passes through the port without being unloaded. The enormous export trade of China in silk and tea is primarily managed by Hongkong companies. Other key commodities for which Hongkong serves as the main trade hub for China include opium, flour, salt, earthenware, oil, cotton, and cotton goods, along with woolen goods imported from other countries and exported to China; as well as sugar, rice, amber, sandalwood, ivory, and betel, imported from China and sent to other countries. Its trade isn't limited to Great Britain but includes France, Germany, the United States, and other trading nations. However, Great Britain still holds the largest share.

[148]VIII. THE TRADE FEATURES OF JAPAN

JAPAN THE GREAT BRITAIN OF ASIA

Japan consists of a group of islands situated to the east of the continent of Asia, somewhat as the British Isles are situated to the west of the continent of Europe. But the Japan islands are of volcanic origin and are very numerous. There are said to be 4223 of them. However, there are only four that are of important size, and it is these that are usually thought of when Japan is spoken of. The area of these four islands is 147,655 miles, which is almost a fourth more than that of Great Britain and Ireland. The population (census of 1895) is 42,270,620, which is 4,000,000 more than that of Great Britain and Ireland. The population per square mile is 286, which, though large, is not quite so large as that of Great Britain. If, however, we do not take into consideration the northern island (Yezo), which is still partly inhabited by uncivilised aborigines, the population per square mile is 375, which is considerably in excess of that of both China and Great Britain and Ireland, though still considerably less than that of England alone. The above statistics do not include the island of Formosa (area 13,500 miles, population almost 2,000,000), which was transferred from[149] China to Japan in 1895, at the close of the late Chino-Japanese war.

Japan is an island nation located to the east of Asia, similar to how the British Isles are positioned to the west of Europe. However, the islands of Japan are volcanic in origin and quite numerous, totaling around 4,223. Yet, only four of these islands are significant in size, and they are the ones people typically think of when discussing Japan. The total area of these four main islands is 147,655 square miles, which is nearly a quarter more than that of Great Britain and Ireland. According to the 1895 census, the population is 42,270,620, which is 4 million more than that of Great Britain and Ireland. The population density is 286 people per square mile, which, while high, is not quite as dense as Great Britain's. However, if we exclude the northern island of Yezo, which is still partly inhabited by uncivilized aborigines, the population density rises to 375 per square mile, significantly exceeding that of both China and Great Britain and Ireland, though still less than that of England alone. These statistics do not include the island of Formosa (area 13,500 square miles, population nearly 2,000,000), which was ceded from[149] China to Japan in 1895, following the recent Sino-Japanese war.

JAPAN'S WONDERFUL TRANSFORMATION

The significant thing about Japan is the rapidity with which it has become transformed from a semi-civilised nation into one of the great nations of the modern world. Until the year 1868 Japan was an unprogressive, unenlightened country of the usual Asiatic type, scarcely differing in any way from an inland province of China of to-day. In that year a revolution took place which put the whole power of the empire into the hands of the present Mikado, or Emperor. Immediately Japan began to assimilate Western ideas of civilisation and to adopt Western methods of trade, commerce, manufacture, government, and education. Until 1889 the government remained an absolute monarchy. In that year the Mikado voluntarily promulgated a constitution by which a legislative Parliament, or "Imperial Diet," and an executive Cabinet of State Ministers were instituted, so that the government of Japan is now as "constitutional" as that of Germany or Great Britain. The government is in other ways thoroughly modern. Education, for example, is almost as well looked after as in Germany or New England. There are 220 kindergartens established, 97 technical schools, and 49 normal schools for the training of teachers (one being for the training of high-school teachers), besides elementary schools, middle schools, high schools, special schools (1263 of these), and universities. The University of Tokio is an imperial institution, supported entirely by the government, with colleges in law, science, medicine, literature, engineering, and agriculture. Education, between the ages of six and fourteen, is compulsory. The army, too, is wholly a[150] modern affair. It consists of 285,000 men, and an idea of its modernness may be gathered from the fact that an important part of its organisation is its training schools and colleges. Even the non-commissioned officers are specially trained and educated. Altogether the students in the military schools and colleges of Japan number 2400. The navy, too, as is well known, is both modern and efficient. It consists of 5 battleships and 15 high-class cruisers, besides 46 other vessels,—torpedo craft, gunboats, convoy ships, etc.,—and it is intended to build an immense fleet of 19 battleships and cruisers, and 100 torpedo craft in addition.

The important thing about Japan is how quickly it has transformed from a semi-civilized nation into one of the great nations of the modern world. Until 1868, Japan was an unprogressive, unenlightened country typical of Asia, hardly differing from an inland province of China today. In that year, a revolution occurred that placed all the power of the empire in the hands of the current Mikado, or Emperor. Immediately, Japan started to adopt Western ideas of civilization and integrate Western methods of trade, commerce, manufacturing, government, and education. Until 1889, the government was an absolute monarchy. In that year, the Mikado voluntarily issued a constitution that established a legislative Parliament, or "Imperial Diet," and an executive Cabinet of State Ministers, making Japan's government as "constitutional" as that of Germany or Great Britain. The government is also thoroughly modern in other ways. Education, for example, is almost as well-managed as it is in Germany or New England. There are 220 kindergartens, 97 technical schools, and 49 normal schools for training teachers (including one for high school teacher training), in addition to elementary schools, middle schools, high schools, special schools (1263 of these), and universities. The University of Tokyo is a national institution fully supported by the government, with colleges in law, science, medicine, literature, engineering, and agriculture. Education is compulsory for children between the ages of six and fourteen. The army is also a completely modern entity. It consists of 285,000 men, and its modernity can be seen in the importance placed on its training schools and colleges. Even non-commissioned officers receive specialized training and education. In total, there are 2,400 students in Japan's military schools and colleges. The navy, as is widely known, is both modern and efficient. It includes 5 battleships and 15 high-class cruisers, along with 46 other vessels—such as torpedo craft, gunboats, convoy ships, etc.—and plans are in place to build a massive fleet of 19 battleships and cruisers, as well as 100 torpedo craft.

JAPAN'S AGRICULTURE

Japan being of volcanic origin, much of its soil is unfit for cultivation. The total productive area amounts to less than thirty per cent., and even of this only a small portion is capable of being tilled by modern methods. At present only twelve per cent. of the whole surface of the country is devoted to agriculture, even including pasturing. There is, however, but little pasturing, and the principal implement of cultivation is the spade. The modern plough is unknown. But manure (principally domestic manure and fish refuse) is very generously used, and by this means the returns are abundant. The principal food crop is rice. Other food crops are wheat, barley, and the soya bean, but these not numerously so. The principal cultivated products for purposes of commerce are the mulberry tree (for supporting the silkworm), the tea plant, the lacquer tree, and the camphor tree. Rice also is grown for export as well as for home consumption, and cotton is very largely grown for home manufacture. No milk, butter, or cheese is produced, scarcely any meat, no wood, and scarcely any leather. (For boots and shoes[151] paper is used instead of leather.) Of cattle there are only 1,000,000, as compared with 10,000,000 in the British Isles, although the population of Japan is considerably the greater. Of horses there are 1,500,000, and the raising of horses is much encouraged by the government, but principally for military purposes. Horses, indeed, are but little employed. In cities, for purposes of carriage and cartage, men are used instead of horses. Even in rural districts horses are unknown for farming purposes, and not even the hand-cart or wheelbarrow is used. Everything is carried. Fruit is much raised,—oranges, apples, walnuts, plums, peaches, and grapes,—but Japanese fruits are of very inferior quality. Flowers are raised everywhere in great variety and in great abundance, and the chrysanthemum is the emblem of the country and is used on postage stamps.

Japan's volcanic origins mean that a lot of its soil isn't suitable for farming. The total agricultural area is less than thirty percent, and even within that, only a small part can be cultivated with modern techniques. Right now, only twelve percent of the entire country is used for agriculture, including grazing. However, there's very little grazing, and the main tool for farming is a spade. The modern plow isn't used at all. Manure, mainly from households and fish waste, is used generously, which leads to good harvests. The primary food crop is rice. Other food crops include wheat, barley, and soybeans, but they are not grown in large quantities. The main commercial crops are the mulberry tree (for raising silkworms), the tea plant, the lacquer tree, and the camphor tree. Rice is cultivated for both export and local consumption, and cotton is widely grown for local manufacturing. There is no production of milk, butter, or cheese; very little meat, no timber, and hardly any leather. (For boots and shoes[151], paper is used instead of leather.) There are only 1,000,000 cattle compared to 10,000,000 in the British Isles, despite Japan having a significantly larger population. There are 1,500,000 horses, and the government encourages horse breeding mostly for military use, but horses are rarely used otherwise. In cities, people are employed for transportation instead of horses. Even in rural areas, horses aren’t used for farming, and hand carts or wheelbarrows aren't utilized. Everything is carried by hand. Fruits such as oranges, apples, walnuts, plums, peaches, and grapes are grown, but Japanese fruits tend to be of lower quality. Flowers are cultivated everywhere in great variety and abundance, with the chrysanthemum serving as the country's symbol and appearing on postage stamps.

JAPAN'S MANUFACTURES: THEIR FUTURE POSSIBILITIES

The future of Japan depends upon its manufactures, but these also are not without their difficulties. The mineral wealth of the country is very great, principally in coal and iron. On the northern island alone (Yezo) the coal deposits are two thirds those of all Great Britain. Unfortunately, however, owing to the mountainous character of the country, railways in Japan are difficult to construct, and the transportation of coal or of ore is difficult and expensive. As the coal deposits and iron deposits are not near together charcoal has been used for smelting purposes. Iron, therefore, so far, has not been produced profitably, and its production has decreased. But silver is mined abundantly, and also kaolin, or the raw material used in the manufacture of the beautiful porcelain of the country. Copper and antimony are also large articles of export. The principal manufactures of[152] Japan as yet are the textiles, especially silk and cotton. In these modern methods are used, although so far the productions of the native domestic looms are superior to those of the factory looms. The production of textiles by machinery has increased fourfold in ten years, and now amounts to about $40,000,000 annually. This, however, is not a large amount, being less than the textile production of any important state in Europe, even Switzerland, or Sweden and Norway, and is only one twentieth that of the United States. Until recently the factory owner in Japan has had the advantage of cheap labour. But the Japanese artisan is also becoming "modernised," and is now demanding higher wages, and enforcing his demand by "strikes." And for all their deftness in domestic manufacture Japanese workmen are not yet as skilful in machine labour as British or American workmen. It follows, therefore, that textile manufacturing in Japan, especially the manufacture of cotton and wool, is not yet out of its tentative or probationary stage. But Japan, having the advantage of an extensive home market for cotton goods (like the Chinese, the Japanese common people wear cotton garments all the year round, in winter padding them for warmth), and having the raw material at her own door (she already grows a large proportion of all the raw cotton she needs), and having, too, an abundance of coal at hand, must needs become a great cotton-manufacturing country. The same conditions hold with regard to the possibilities of Japan's silk manufactures.

The future of Japan relies on its production, but this sector faces its challenges as well. The country has significant mineral resources, mainly in coal and iron. The northern island (Hokkaido) alone has coal deposits that are two-thirds the size of those in all of Great Britain. Unfortunately, due to the mountainous terrain, building railways in Japan is tough, making the transportation of coal and ore both challenging and costly. Since the coal and iron deposits are not located close to each other, charcoal has been used for smelting instead. Consequently, iron production has not been profitable and has declined. However, silver is mined in large quantities, along with kaolin clay, the raw material for Japan's beautiful porcelain. Copper and antimony are also significant exports. The main [152] manufactured goods in Japan are textiles, particularly silk and cotton. Modern methods are employed in these areas, although traditional domestic looms still produce higher quality items than factory looms. Textile production by machinery has quadrupled in ten years, now reaching about $40 million annually. However, this is still a small amount, less than the textile production of any major European country, including Switzerland or Sweden and Norway, and only one-twentieth that of the United States. Until recently, factory owners in Japan enjoyed the benefit of cheap labor. But Japanese workers are also becoming "modernized," demanding higher wages and resorting to "strikes" to enforce their demands. Despite their skill in domestic manufacturing, Japanese workers still lack the machine labor expertise of their British or American counterparts. Therefore, textile manufacturing in Japan, especially for cotton and wool, is still in a developmental phase. However, with a large home market for cotton goods (like the Chinese, the Japanese working class wears cotton all year round, layering for warmth in winter) and access to raw materials (Japan grows a significant portion of the cotton it needs), along with abundant coal resources, it must become a major cotton manufacturing nation. The same conditions apply to the potential of Japan's silk manufacturing.

POSSIBILITIES OF INCREASED FOREIGN TRADE WITH JAPAN

As in the case of China, the possibilities of increased trade with Japan lie principally in woollen manufactures and in breadstuffs. In addition there is a fair[153] chance of increased trade in metal manufactures. The use of woollen garments in Japan in winter is extending even to the middle and working classes. And inasmuch as the country does not raise sheep, and is, indeed, not well able to raise sheep, such woollen clothing, woollen cloth, or raw wool as is used must be imported. Hitherto the woollen manufactures which have been established in the country have not been very successful, and the probability is that Japan's import trade in woollen clothing and woollen cloths will increase year by year. Similarly, from the fact that the agriculture of the country is not adapted to the growth of wheat, nor seems ever likely to be so adapted, and also from the fact that both the higher and the middle classes of Japan are rapidly adopting European and American habits of living, it is very probable that the importation of wheat and wheat flour into Japan will also continue to increase year by year. And from the difficulty there is of smelting iron cheaply it is probable that the importation of iron and iron goods (which in raw iron, iron and steel rails, iron small wares and nails, spinning and other machinery, and steel ships, already amounts to $8,000,000 a year) is likewise likely to increase greatly year by year also.

As with China, the potential for increased trade with Japan mainly lies in wool products and baked goods. Additionally, there is a good[153] chance of increased trade in metal products. The use of woolen garments during winter is becoming more common among the middle and working classes in Japan. Since the country doesn't raise sheep and isn't well-suited for it, any woolen clothing, woolen fabric, or raw wool used must be imported. Until now, the woolen manufacturing established in the country hasn't been very successful, and it's likely that Japan's import trade in woolen clothing and fabrics will continue to grow each year. Similarly, given that the agriculture in the country is not suitable for growing wheat and likely won't ever be, combined with the fact that both the upper and middle classes in Japan are quickly adopting European and American lifestyles, it's very probable that the import of wheat and wheat flour into Japan will also keep increasing yearly. Furthermore, due to the challenges of smelting iron cost-effectively, it's likely that the import of iron and iron products (which, including raw iron, iron and steel rails, small iron goods, nails, spinning machinery, and steel ships, already totals $8,000,000 per year) will also see significant growth year after year.

JAPAN'S MODERN TRADE FACILITIES

Owing to the irregular conformation of the surface of the country, good roads in Japan can scarcely be said to exist. But 20,000 miles of roads have been built, of which the state maintains about one fourth. There are also 2505 miles of railway, of which the state owns and maintains about one fourth also. There are 11,720 miles of telegraph routes, with 37,000 miles of wire; 520 miles of telephone routes, with 6347 miles of wire; and 387 miles of submarine cable routes, with 1481 miles of wire.[154] The country also has a merchant navy of 827 steam vessels of modern type and 702 sailing-vessels of modern type, besides 668 native craft. Owing to the irregular and rocky nature of the coast-line and the great number of small islands which exist, numerous lighthouses are needed; but Japan's lighthouse system is one of the best in the world.

Due to the uneven landscape of the country, it's hard to say that Japan has good roads. Nevertheless, 20,000 miles of roads have been constructed, with the government maintaining about a quarter of them. There are also 2,505 miles of railways, of which the government owns and maintains roughly a quarter as well. Additionally, there are 11,720 miles of telegraph lines with 37,000 miles of wire; 520 miles of telephone lines with 6,347 miles of wire; and 387 miles of submarine cable routes with 1,481 miles of wire.[154] The country has a merchant navy comprising 827 modern steam vessels and 702 modern sailing vessels, along with 668 native boats. Because of the rugged and rocky coastline, as well as the many small islands, numerous lighthouses are necessary, and Japan's lighthouse system is considered one of the best in the world.

JAPAN'S FOREIGN TRADE

Japan has a foreign trade of $60,000,000 annually in exports and $86,000,000 annually in imports. Of the export trade the principal part, running from a fourth to a third, is with the United States. The next largest part is with France, the next with Hongkong, the next with China, and the next with Great Britain. But Great Britain's direct share is not more than a twelfth. Of the import trade the principal part, almost one third, is with Great Britain. The United States' share is about a twelfth, and that of France about one twenty-fifth. The principal exports are raw silk (about one third of the whole), silk goods (about one tenth of the whole), tea, coal, copper, rice, and matches. The export of matches amounts to $2,500,000 annually. Characteristic exports, though they do not figure largely in the total amount, are floor rugs, lacquered ware, porcelain ware, fans, umbrellas, bronze ware, repoussé work, paper ware and papier-mâché, fibre carpets, and camphor. There is also a large export of fish, shellfish, cuttlefish, edible seaweed, and mushrooms to China and other Asiatic countries. The chief import is raw cotton (almost one fifth of the whole). Other important imports are sugar (although she raises almost 100,000,000 pounds of sugar herself annually), cotton yarn, cotton goods, woollen cloths, flannels and blankets, kerosene oil, watches, and articles of iron and steel as above enumerated. The fishing industry is a very important one and over 2,500,000 people are engaged in it. The number of fishing-boats is about 400,000. The fish trade, which includes seaweed, is (when not for home consumption) principally with China.

Japan has an annual foreign trade of $60,000,000 in exports and $86,000,000 in imports. The majority of the export trade, about a fourth to a third, is with the United States. The next largest partner is France, followed by Hong Kong, China, and Great Britain, although Great Britain's direct share is only about a twelfth. For imports, almost a third comes from Great Britain, while the United States contributes about a twelfth and France around one twenty-fifth. The main exports include silk (approximately one third of the total), silk products (roughly one tenth), tea, coal, copper, rice, and matches. The export of matches is valued at $2,500,000 annually. Other notable exports, while not large in total value, consist of floor rugs, lacquerware, porcelain, fans, umbrellas, bronze items, repoussé work, paper products, papier-mâché, fiber carpets, and camphor. Additionally, there is a significant export of fish, shellfish, cuttlefish, edible seaweed, and mushrooms to China and other Asian countries. The primary import is uncooked cotton (nearly one fifth of the total), alongside other key imports like sugar (despite producing almost 100,000,000 pounds of sugar per year), cotton yarn, cotton goods, woolen fabrics, flannels, blankets, kerosene oil, watches, and various iron and steel products. The fishing industry is extremely important, employing over 2,500,000 people, with about 400,000 fishing boats in operation. The fish trade, which includes seaweed, primarily targets China when it’s not for local use.

Japan's relation to eastern Asia. Japan's relationship with East Asia.

[156]JAPAN'S SPECIAL TRADE CENTRES

The foreign commerce of Japan, like that of China, is allowed to be carried on only at certain ports, called "treaty ports," of which there are nineteen, the principal being Yokohama, Osaka, Nagasaki, Hakodate, Niigata, and Kobe. The two principal cities, not treaty ports, are Tokio and Kioto. Tokio (1,300,000) is the capital and chief centre of the political, commercial, and literary activity of the empire. In many respects Tokio is a "modern" city. Its educational features are excellent. Its sanitation also is good. Kioto (340,000) was formerly the capital, but after the revolution of 1868 it was superseded in this respect by Tokio. Yokohama (170,000), distant from Tokio eighteen miles, is the chief place of the empire for foreign trade. Its foreign trade, indeed, is more than half that of the whole empire, being about $75,000,000 annually. Osaka (487,000) is in respect to population the second city of the empire, but its foreign trade is not large and is carried on principally at Hiogo, a port near it. Niigata (50,000) is the only treaty port on the west side of Japan, the surf caused by the winter monsoon making the flat west coast of the country very dangerous for shipping for half the year. Other important ports are Kobe (161,000) and Nagasaki (72,000). Nagoya (215,000) is an important inland town.

The foreign trade of Japan, like that of China, can only take place at specific ports known as "treaty ports." There are nineteen of these, with the main ones being Yokohama, Osaka, Nagasaki, Hakodate, Niigata, and Kobe. The two main cities that are not treaty ports are Tokyo and Kyoto. Tokyo (1,300,000) is the capital and the central hub for politics, commerce, and culture in the empire. In many ways, Tokyo is a "modern" city. It has excellent educational facilities and good sanitation. Kyoto (340,000) was the former capital but was replaced by Tokyo following the revolution of 1868. Yokohama (170,000), located eighteen miles from Tokyo, is the primary center for foreign trade in the empire. In fact, its foreign trade accounts for over half of the entire country's trade, totaling about $75,000,000 each year. Osaka (487,000) is the second largest city by population in the empire, but its foreign trade is not significant and primarily takes place at Hiogo, a nearby port. Niigata (50,000) is the only treaty port on Japan's west side, where the winter monsoon creates dangerous surf conditions for shipping along the flat western coast for half the year. Other key ports include Kobe Bryant (161,000) and Nagasaki (72,000). Nagoya (215,000) is an important inland city.

[157]IX. THE TRADE FEATURES OF AFRICA

AFRICA FIFTEEN YEARS AGO

Within a period of about fifteen years the continent of Africa has been the scene of a vast partition. At the beginning of that period the amount of African territory that was subject to European control was comparatively small. The British were firmly established in South Africa, and had possessions along the coasts elsewhere principally in the west. The French were firmly established in Algeria and in Senegal. The Portuguese had their ancient settlements in Mozambique and Lower Guinea. Morocco on the northwest and Abyssinia in the northeast were more or less well-established governments that were independent. Egypt in the extreme northeast, with tributary possessions extending along the Nile into the far interior of the continent, was also a more or less well-established government that possessed a quasi-independence, though it was nominally dependent upon Turkey. But elsewhere, except in a few other places controlled by European authority, the whole continent may be described as having been in its original state of savagery or semi-savagery. No government existed anywhere that was either beneficent or stable. The slave-traffic abounded everywhere.

Within about fifteen years, Africa underwent a massive partition. At the beginning of that time, the amount of African land under European control was relatively small. The British had a strong presence in South Africa and held coastal territories, mainly in the west. The French had established themselves in Algeria and Senegal. The Portuguese maintained their historic settlements in Mozambique and Lower Guinea. Morocco in the northwest and Abyssinia in the northeast had relatively stable governments that were independent. Egypt in the far northeast had tributary territories extending along the Nile deep into the continent; it was a somewhat stable government that had a form of quasi-independence, although it was nominally under Turkish rule. However, in most other areas, aside from a few other places under European control, the entire continent could be described as largely untouched and in a state of savagery or semi-savagery. There was no government anywhere that was either beneficial or stable, and the slave trade was rampant everywhere.

[158]EUROPEAN SPHERES OF INFLUENCE IN AFRICA

The European governments that had possessions in Africa were all doing their best to suppress the slave-traffic. But they could not take very salutary steps in this direction without exercising authority beyond the territorial limits they were supposed to occupy. Gradually, for these reasons, and also for the reason that they were all anxious to extend their commercial dealings in Africa, they began to exercise authority beyond their old-time territorial limits. In this way began the establishment on the part of European nations of what are known as "spheres of influence" in Africa. At first England and France were the only nations that were at all active in establishing these spheres of influence. Later on Germany and Italy and other nations began to establish them also. Beginning, therefore, with the years 1883 and 1884 there has been a general establishment and gradual extension of these spheres until now the whole continent has been practically parcelled out among a few European powers.

The European governments that had colonies in Africa were all trying their best to stop the slave trade. However, they could not take significant actions in this area without extending their authority beyond the regions they were meant to control. Gradually, for these reasons, and also because they all wanted to expand their trade in Africa, they started to exert authority beyond their traditional territorial limits. This led to the establishment of what are known as "spheres of influence" by European nations in Africa. Initially, England and France were the only countries actively setting up these spheres of influence. Eventually, Germany, Italy, and other nations began to do the same. Starting around 1883 and 1884, there has been a widespread establishment and gradual expansion of these spheres until now the entire continent has been almost completely divided among a few European powers.

[159]THE GREAT PARTITION OF AFRICA

The partition of Africa. The division of Africa.

The ancient empire of Morocco still exists in an independent state. Abyssinia, though Italy attempted to subjugate it, is again also independent. The little republic of Liberia is nominally independent. Some territory in the very heart of the Sahara or Great Desert is yet in its aboriginal independence. But elsewhere, throughout the whole continent, Africa is either British, or French, or German, or Belgian, or Portuguese, or Italian. Spain's holding is not worth mentioning. Italy's holding also is scarcely worth mentioning. Portugal's holding has not been increased in the recent "scramble"—only made more definite. France's holding, however, has been enormously increased, and is now the largest (3,300,000 square miles), although much of the French area is barren desert,[160] and much of the rest of it uninhabitable by white people. Great Britain's holding also has been greatly increased, but not nearly so much so as it would have been if in the earlier years of the scramble the British government had not been singularly blind to the actions of other governments in the matter. Germany, too, has got a substantial holding (925,000 square miles). The Kongo Free State, which, though nominally independent, is practically under the suzerainty of Belgium, and must look to Belgium for the funds with which to promote its development, is also a substantial possession, being a little less than Germany's holding—900,000 square miles.

The ancient empire of Morocco still exists as an independent state. Abyssinia, despite Italy's attempts to control it, is also independent again. The small republic of Liberia is officially independent. Some land in the heart of the Sahara or Great Desert is still in its original independent state. However, across the entire continent, Africa is mostly under British, French, German, Belgian, Portuguese, or Italian rule. Spain's territories aren't worth mentioning. Italy's holdings are also hardly significant. Portugal's claims haven't grown during the recent "scramble"—they've just become clearer. France's territories, on the other hand, have expanded enormously and are now the largest (3,300,000 square miles), although much of it is barren desert, and much of the rest is uninhabitable by white people. Great Britain's territories have also increased significantly, but not nearly as much as they could have if, in the earlier phases of the scramble, the British government hadn't been so oblivious to the actions of other countries. Germany has also acquired a substantial area (925,000 square miles). The Kongo Free State, which, while officially independent, is effectively under Belgian control and relies on Belgium for the funds needed to support its development, is also a significant possession, being just under Germany's holdings at 900,000 square miles.[160]

GREAT BRITAIN IN AFRICA

Great Britain's holding, however, in the partitioned continent comprises its best portions. Much of Africa is uninhabitable by white men. Wherever, however, white men can live—except in northern Africa—there Great Britain has managed to get control. Excluding the shore of the Mediterranean, the best part of Africa, considered from the view points of colonisation and commerce, is what is now known as "British South Africa." This is an immense area—an area of almost 1,000,000 square miles. It comprises (1) that whole southern portion of the continent known as Cape Colony, and (2) that portion of the great central plateau of the continent which extends from Cape Colony northward to Lakes Nyassa and Tanganyika—all except the two Boer republics, the Orange Free State and the South African Republic. British East Africa (800,000 square miles) includes the territory of Uganda, north of Lake Victoria, a territory which from the character of its native population and its possibilities of trade has been called the "pearl of Africa." British West Africa (500,000 square[161] miles) includes the basin of the lower Niger, the most densely peopled area in all Africa, the seat of the great Fula-Hausa empire of Sokoto-Gandu, the wealthiest and greatest trading nation in the continent. Furthermore, in the northeast, Great Britain exercises "protectorate control" over Egypt—a control that is likely to be instrumental in reclaiming for Egypt, and thus for civilisation and commerce under British authority, the whole of Egypt's ancient possessions along the Nile as far at least as Uganda. The total area of the British possessions in Africa, exclusive of the two Boer republics and Egypt, is over 2,300,000 square miles.

Great Britain's holdings in the divided continent consist of its most valuable parts. Much of Africa is uninhabitable for white people. However, wherever white people can live—except in northern Africa—Great Britain has managed to gain control. Excluding the Mediterranean coast, the best part of Africa, in terms of colonization and commerce, is what we now refer to as "British South Africa." This is a vast area—almost 1,000,000 square miles. It includes (1) the entire southern section of the continent known as Cape Colony, and (2) the part of the great central plateau that stretches from Cape Colony north to Lakes Nyassa and Tanganyika—all except the two Boer republics, the Orange Free State and the South African Republic. British East Africa (800,000 square miles) includes the territory of Uganda, located north of Lake Victoria, which has been called the "pearl of Africa" due to its native population and trade potential. British West Africa (500,000 square miles) includes the lower Niger basin, the most densely populated area in Africa, home to the great Fula-Hausa empire of Sokoto-Gandu, the wealthiest and largest trading nation on the continent. Furthermore, in the northeast, Great Britain has "protectorate control" over Egypt—a control that is likely to help reclaim all of Egypt's ancient lands along the Nile, at least as far as Uganda, for Egypt and, therefore, for civilization and commerce under British authority. The total area of British possessions in Africa, excluding the two Boer republics and Egypt, is over 2,300,000 square miles.

THE "DOMINION OF SOUTH AFRICA"

"South Africa" is practically "British South Africa." The German portion is either largely barren or else inaccessible. The Portuguese portion is only a narrow strip along the east coast, much of which is too unhealthy for habitation other than by natives. The two Boer republics are rapidly filling up with British people, are being developed by British capital, and must in time become confederated with the states that environ them. One of them, too, is already under British suzerainty. British South Africa, however, is as yet only a name. It has no real existence except in hope. The aspiration of statesmen in southern Africa is that all the territories of southern Africa under British control shall form one confederation, and that in this confederation the Orange Free State and the South African Republic shall join. The territories entering into this confederation would therefore be as follows: The self-governing colonies of Cape Colony and Natal, the crown colony of Basutoland, the protectorates of Bechuanaland and Zululand, the territory now administered by the British South Africa[162] Company, popularly known as "Rhodesia," and the British Central Africa protectorate, with in addition the two Boer republics previously mentioned. The length of this proposed South African dominion would be 1800 miles. Its width would be from 600 to 800 miles. And, as said above, its area would be about 1,000,000 square miles. Mr. Stanley predicts that in a hundred years the "Dominion of South Africa" will have a white population of 8,000,000, and a coloured population of 16,000,000.

"South Africa" is essentially "British South Africa." The German part is mostly barren or difficult to access. The Portuguese section is just a narrow strip along the east coast, much of which is too unhealthy for anyone to live there except for locals. The two Boer republics are quickly filling up with British settlers, are being developed with British investment, and will eventually have to unite with the surrounding states. One of them is already under British control. However, British South Africa is still just a name. It only exists as a hope. Southern African leaders aspire for all territories under British control to form one confederation, which would include the Orange Free State and the South African Republic. The territories that would make up this confederation are: the self-governing colonies of Cape Colony and Natal, the crown colony of Basutoland, the protectorates of Bechuanaland and Zululand, the area currently managed by the British South Africa[162] Company, commonly known as "Rhodesia," and the British Central Africa protectorate, along with the two previously mentioned Boer republics. The length of this proposed South African dominion would be 1,800 miles, and its width would range from 600 to 800 miles. As mentioned earlier, its total area would be around 1,000,000 square miles. Mr. Stanley predicts that in a hundred years, the "Dominion of South Africa" will have a white population of 8,000,000 and a colored population of 16,000,000.

SOUTH AFRICA'S AGRICULTURAL POSSIBILITIES

Of South Africa as above defined Cape Colony and Natal are at present the most important portions. Their climate is in some respects the finest in the world. Their soil is of remarkable richness. The number of distinct species of indigenous plants found upon it is greater than for any other equal area on the globe. The same remark was once true of the animals found in South Africa, which again is testimony to the great fertility of the soil. But a serious drawback is the insufficiency and uncertainty of the rain supply. Irrigation, however, is practised, and wherever irrigation is possible the land may be made to blossom like the rose. Agriculture, however, is only indifferently pursued. The vine in Cape Colony produces more abundantly, very much more abundantly than anywhere else in the world, and yet neither grape-raising nor wine-making can be said to be successful. Pasturing is the principal occupation of the people in rural districts. There are 17,000,000 sheep in Cape Colony, and 6,000,000 goats. Natal, which is warmer, has 500,000 sheep. Another principal occupation is ostrich-farming. The ostrich, once wild in South Africa, is now bred domestically. Cape Colony has 230,000 ostriches.[163] Ostrich feathers fetch from $150 to $300 a pound. The raising of cattle is another principal occupation, and draught cattle are much used for transport purposes. Cape Colony has 2,000,000 cattle; Natal, 1,000,000. The principal food crops are wheat and maize, but little is raised for export. In Natal, sugar is an important product, and also tea. Many magnificent timber woods are found, but the trees are stunted and little timber is exported. Much has been wasted by fires. The great agricultural possibilities of South Africa are wool, mohair (the hair of the Angora goat), fruit, wine, and skins. The breadstuffs of South Africa will probably all be needed for home consumption.

Of the regions defined as South Africa, Cape Colony and Natal are currently the most significant parts. Their climate is among the best in the world in several ways. The soil is exceptionally rich, and the variety of native plant species found there is greater than in any other comparable area on Earth. This was also true for the animals in South Africa, further proving the soil's remarkable fertility. However, a major issue is the inadequate and unpredictable rainfall. Irrigation is practiced, and wherever irrigation is feasible, the land can flourish beautifully. Agriculture is pursued, but not with much enthusiasm. The grapevines in Cape Colony produce significantly more than anywhere else in the world, yet neither grape cultivation nor winemaking can be considered successful. Grazing is the main activity for people in rural areas, with 17 million sheep and 6 million goats in Cape Colony. Natal, which is warmer, has 500,000 sheep. Another key activity is ostrich farming. The ostrich, once a wild animal in South Africa, is now raised domestically, with Cape Colony hosting 230,000 ostriches. Ostrich feathers sell for between $150 and $300 per pound. Raising cattle is another primary occupation, and draught animals are heavily utilized for transportation. Cape Colony has 2 million cattle, while Natal has 1 million. The main food crops are wheat and maize, though little is grown for export. In Natal, sugar and tea are significant products. While there are many magnificent timber species, the trees are often stunted and not much timber is exported. A lot has been lost to fires. The vast agricultural potential of South Africa is found in wool, mohair (from the Angora goat), fruit, wine, and animal hides. The food production in South Africa will likely be needed primarily for local consumption.

SOUTH AFRICA'S GREAT MINERAL WEALTH

All the world over South Africa is famous for its diamond mines and its gold-mines. The diamonds are found principally in Griqualand, north of the Orange River, now a part of Cape Colony, but they are also found in the Orange Free State. The diamond areas are very circumscribed, the diamond-bearing "pipes" being supposed to be craters of extinct volcanoes. The principal "pipes" are at Kimberley (28,718), in Griqualand. These constitute the richest diamond-fields in the world. It is estimated that over $350,000,000 worth of diamonds have been taken out of Kimberley since their first discovery there in 1867. The largest South African diamond yet found was worth $300,000, but many other large ones have been found. The annual diamond export now is about $20,000,000. For 1896 the export was $23,200,000; for 1897 a little less. The production and export are strictly limited, so that prices may not depreciate. Next in interest to the diamond-fields are the gold-mines. These so far have been found principally in the South[164] African Republic, or "Transvaal" as it is popularly called, in the "rand," or "reef," near the far-famed town of Johannesburg (102,078). Since gold was first discovered in the rand (1871) $250,000,000 worth has been taken out. The annual output now is nearly $50,000,000, but it is estimated that before the rand can be exhausted $2,250,000,000 worth of gold must be taken out—an amount much greater than the total public debt of the United States, national, state, and municipal. But north of the Transvaal, in Rhodesia, especially in Mashonaland, is a territory popularly called the "Land of Ophir," where mining operations are only just begun, but where gold is supposed to be even more richly stored than in the Transvaal. Of this district the newly built town of Salisbury is the centre. Other mineral products of South Africa are coal in Natal, mined at Newcastle, and copper in the northwest of Cape Colony, shipped at Port Nolloth.

All around the world, South Africa is known for its diamond mines and gold mines. The diamonds are mainly found in Griqualand, north of the Orange River, which is now part of Cape Colony, but they can also be located in the Orange Free State. The diamond regions are quite limited, with the diamond-bearing "pipes" believed to be craters of extinct volcanoes. The main "pipes" are in Kimberley (28,718), in Griqualand. These represent the richest diamond fields in the world. It’s estimated that over $350,000,000 worth of diamonds have been extracted from Kimberley since their discovery in 1867. The largest diamond found in South Africa was valued at $300,000, but many other large diamonds have also been discovered. The annual diamond export now amounts to about $20,000,000. In 1896, the export was $23,200,000; it was slightly less in 1897. The production and export are tightly controlled to prevent price drops. Next in importance to the diamond fields are the gold mines. So far, these have mostly been found in the South[164] African Republic, or "Transvaal," as it’s commonly called, in the "rand" or "reef," near the well-known town of Joburg (102,078). Since gold was first discovered in the rand (1871), $250,000,000 worth has been mined. The current annual output is nearly $50,000,000, but it’s estimated that before the rand is exhausted, $2,250,000,000 worth of gold must be extracted—an amount much larger than the total public debt of the United States, including national, state, and municipal debts. However, north of the Transvaal, in Rhodesia, particularly in Mashonaland, there's an area often referred to as the "Land of Ophir," where mining operations have just started, but where gold is believed to be even more abundantly available than in the Transvaal. The newly established town of Salisbury serves as the center of this district. Other mineral resources in South Africa include coal in Natal, mined at Newcastle, and copper in the northwest of Cape Colony, exported through Port Nolloth.

SOUTH AFRICA'S FOREIGN TRADE

The import trade of South Africa so far consists of almost everything needed by the inhabitants except meat, flour, vegetables, and fruit, for there are as yet almost no manufactures. The principal exports are: (1) gold, $60,000,000 per annum, including that from the Transvaal; (2) diamonds, $22,500,000; (3) wool, $12,500,000; (4) mohair, the hair of the Angora goat, $3,000,000; (5) ostrich feathers, over $2,500,000; (6) hides and skins, $2,200,000; and (7) copper ore, $1,250,000. The export of wine and fruit, for the production of which the country is so well suited, and also of grain, is inconsiderable.

The import trade of South Africa currently includes almost everything needed by the people except for meat, flour, vegetables, and fruit, as there are still very few manufactures. The main exports are: (1) gold, $60,000,000 per year, including that from the Transvaal; (2) diamonds, $22,500,000; (3) wool, $12,500,000; (4) mohair, from the Angora goat, $3,000,000; (5) ostrich feathers, over $2,500,000; (6) hides and skins, $2,200,000; and (7) copper ore, $1,250,000. The export of wine and fruit, for which the country is well suited, as well as grain, is minimal.

SHIPPING PORTS AND RAILWAYS OF SOUTH AFRICA

British South Africa, like all of Africa, is wanting in seaports. In fact, it has but few. However, it has one,[165] Walfish Bay, which territorially does not belong to it, inasmuch as it is in the middle of the coast of German Southwest Africa—the only port in that coast. The principal port in British South Africa is Cape Town (83,718), which is also the capital and principal place. The next principal ports are, for Cape Colony, Port Elizabeth (23,266) and East London, and for Natal, Durban. Lorenzo Marquez, on Delagoa Bay, and Beira, at the mouth of the Pungwe, both in Portuguese East Africa, are natural ports for northern British South Africa, and are used as such, railways being constructed from them into the interior. Railroad-making, indeed, is now the all-important matter in South Africa. Lines are already built from Cape Town, Port Elizabeth, East London, Durban, and Lorenzo Marquez to the diamond-fields of Kimberley and the gold-mines of Johannesburg. These also give to the pastoral and agricultural parts of the interior facilities of access to the sea. But the line from Cape Town to Kimberley is being rapidly extended northward to Salisbury, the central point of the gold-fields of Rhodesia, and already has reached Bulawayo, 1600 miles from Cape Town. The line from Beira is also to end at Salisbury. Already a telegraph line extending from Salisbury northward has reached the west shore of Lake Nyassa, and by the close of this year (1898) it will reach the south end of Lake Tanganyika. It is proposed that the railroad from Bulawayo shall follow this same route, and it is the dream (or shall we say the hope?) of the empire-builders of South Africa that this railway shall before many years be so far advanced northward that it will meet the railway that is now being built from Cairo southward through the continent along the Nile. Mr. Stanley predicts that the "Cape to Cairo" railway will be an accomplished fact before 1925. The white population of South Africa, even including the Boer republics, is still less than 750,000.

British South Africa, like the rest of Africa, lacks seaports. In fact, it has very few. However, it does have one, [165] Walfish Bay, which technically doesn't belong to it since it's located in the middle of the coast of German Southwest Africa—the only port on that coast. The main port in British South Africa is Cape Town (83,718), which is also the capital and the primary hub. The next important ports are Gqeberha (23,266) and East London in Cape Colony, and Durban in Natal. Lorenzo Marquez, on Delagoa Bay, and Beira, at the mouth of the Pungwe, both in Portuguese East Africa, serve as natural ports for northern British South Africa and are utilized as such, with railways being built from these ports into the interior. Building railroads is currently the top priority in South Africa. Lines have already been constructed from Cape Town, Port Elizabeth, East London, Durban, and Lorenzo Marquez to the diamond fields of Kimberley and the gold mines of Johannesburg. These routes also provide access to the pastoral and agricultural regions of the interior, linking them to the sea. The line from Cape Town to Kimberley is being quickly extended northward to Salisbury, the central point of the gold fields of Rhodesia, and it has already reached Bulawayo, 1,600 miles from Cape Town. The railway from Beira is also set to terminate at Salisbury. A telegraph line extending from Salisbury northward has reached the west shore of Lake Nyassa, and by the end of this year (1898), it will reach the southern end of Lake Tanganyika. There are plans for the railroad from Bulawayo to follow this same path, and it is the aspiration (or shall we say the hope?) of the empire builders of South Africa that this railway will advance far enough north in a few years to connect with the railway being constructed from Cairo southward through the continent along the Nile. Mr. Stanley predicts that the "Cape to Cairo" railway will be completed by 1925. The white population of South Africa, including the Boer republics, is still under 750,000.

[166]X. THE TRADE FEATURES OF AUSTRALIA

AUSTRALIA AND AUSTRALASIA

The term Australasia, as now generally used, comprises Australia (including Tasmania) and New Zealand, and a number of small neighbouring islands. So used it practically denotes a British possession; for such islands as are comprised by the term and yet do not belong to Great Britain are comparatively unimportant. But when we speak of Australasia, we are generally thinking of Australia, for Australia is so large and important that it seems to overshadow the other parts of Australasia. But in respect to politics or commerce Australia is not one country; it is divided into several self-governing colonies. These are, in order of importance, Victoria, New South Wales, South Australia, Queensland, and West Australia. But a movement is now being made to unite all these colonies, and Tasmania as well, into one "Australian Confederation," just as the several provinces of Canada, which were once independent colonies, have been united into one "Dominion of Canada." This confederation scheme, however, has not yet been accomplished.[167][3] New Zealand, because of its distance (1200 miles) from Australia, has so far shown no desire to enter into this confederation.

The term Oceania, as it’s commonly used today, includes Australia (which also covers Tasmania), New Zealand, and a number of smaller nearby islands. In this context, it essentially refers to a British territory; the islands included that don’t belong to Great Britain are relatively insignificant. However, when we talk about Australasia, we're usually focusing on Australia, since it is so large and significant that it tends to overshadow the other regions of Australasia. Politically and economically, Australia isn't a single nation; it consists of several self-governing colonies. These, in order of significance, are Victoria, New South Wales, South Australia, Queensland, and Western Australia. There's currently a push to unite all these colonies, along with Tasmania, into one "Australian Confederation," similar to how the separate provinces of Canada, which were once independent colonies, have come together as one "Dominion of Canada." However, this confederation plan hasn’t been realized yet.[167][3] New Zealand, due to its distance (1200 miles) from Australia, has not expressed any interest in joining this confederation so far.

FOOTNOTE:

[3]Since the above was written the scheme has been developed a very considerable way toward completion. The name of the confederation is to be "The Commonwealth of Australia."

[3]Since this was written, the plan has progressed significantly towards completion. The confederation will be called "The Commonwealth of Australia."

THE AREA AND CLIMATE OF AUSTRALIA

Australia is a continent not only in name but in fact. Its area, including Tasmania, is almost 3,000,000 square miles, which is about the area of the United States exclusive of Alaska, and only about one fourth less than the area of the continent of Europe. Fully two fifths of this area lie within the torrid zone, and of the rest, even in Victoria, the part farthest from the equator, the climate is so warm that it corresponds with that of Spain, southern France, and Italy. But over so vast a territory great differences of climate must occur, and consequently of products also. A general description of the climate and products of Australia is therefore impossible. Yet there are several characteristics which appertain to the whole continent. The chief of these are (1) the great dryness of the atmosphere—not merely its lack of rain, but its absolute freedom from moisture; (2) the remarkable inequality, or want of regularity, in the rainfall. Occasionally the rainfall is excessive, but a more frequent and serious cause of trouble is excessive drought. The continent on every side has a low coast region, where the rainfall is heavier and the temperature generally hotter than in the corresponding table-land interior to it. But the vast table-land of the interior has comparatively little rain, and indeed in some parts of it, especially in the centre and west, the rainfall is so slight that the country is practically a desert.

Australia is a continent not just in name but also in reality. Its area, including Tasmania, is nearly 3,000,000 square miles, which is about the size of the United States excluding Alaska, and only about a quarter less than the area of Europe. Two-fifths of this area is located within the tropics, and even in Victoria, the furthest part from the equator, the climate is so warm that it resembles that of Spain, southern France, and Italy. However, with such a vast territory, there are significant differences in climate and, consequently, in the products available. Therefore, a general overview of Australia’s climate and products is impossible. Yet, there are several characteristics that apply to the entire continent. The main ones are (1) the extreme dryness of the atmosphere—not just its lack of rain, but its complete absence of moisture; (2) the unusual inequality, or lack of consistency, in rainfall. Sometimes the rainfall is excessive, but more often, the bigger issue is severe drought. The continent has a low coastal region on every side, where the rainfall is heavier and the temperature generally hotter than in the corresponding table-land further inland. However, the vast interior table-land receives relatively little rain, and indeed in some areas, especially in the center and west, the rainfall is so minimal that the land is essentially a desert.

But even when all the desert areas of Australia are excluded from calculation there still remains in the interior plateau, toward the east and south, an immense area[168] of country of great fertility and productiveness. The Murray River alone drains an area of 500,000 square miles, one sixth of the whole continent, a great part of which is of exceeding richness. In these fertile parts irrigation by artesian wells has been tried, and always with great success. And it is thought that almost the whole continent can be regained for agriculture, or at least for sheep-pasturing, by similar means; for even in the arid and so-called desert parts of the interior, there is very little soil that is not really fertile, for all of it is covered with thick brushwood. Moisture alone is needed to make it bear crops abundantly. And this dryness of the atmosphere which prevails throughout the whole continent is not without its compensations. It renders the climate exceedingly healthful.

But even when all the desert areas of Australia are left out of the calculation, there’s still a huge area in the interior plateau, toward the east and south, that is incredibly fertile and productive. The Murray River alone drains 500,000 square miles, which is one-sixth of the entire continent, much of which is extremely rich. In these fertile regions, irrigation through artesian wells has been tested and has always been very successful. It’s believed that nearly the entire continent can be made suitable for farming or at least for sheep grazing using similar methods; because even in the dry and so-called desert areas of the interior, there isn’t much soil that isn’t actually fertile, as it’s all covered in thick brush. All it needs is moisture to produce abundant crops. Moreover, the dryness of the atmosphere that exists throughout the whole continent isn't without its benefits. It makes the climate very healthy.

AUSTRALIA A CONTINENT OF PECULIARITIES

Australia has many peculiarities. It has only one large river, and even that in summer becomes a series of isolated pools. It has no high mountain range, its principal mountains being only a series of ramparts marking off the lower coast lands from the interior plateau. Again, its native quadrupeds are entirely different from those of other continents, being almost all, whether little or big, "marsupials," or "pouch-bearers," like the kangaroo. Its birds are mostly songless. Its flowers, for the most part, have no scent. Its trees are leaved vertically and cast no shade. Its indigenous inhabitants have made no progress toward civilisation. When Europeans first came to the country they found no native animal that could be put to any use, nor any native fruit, vegetable, or grain that could be utilised for food. Still, all European domestic animals thrive abundantly in the country, and so do all European fruits, grasses, grains, and vege[169]tables. The English rabbits, indeed, have become a terrible pest. As many as 25,000,000 of them have been killed in a year without any apparent diminution in their numbers. Over $1,000,000 a year has at times been spent to exterminate them, all to no effect.

Australia has many idiosyncrasies. It has only one major river, and even that turns into a series of isolated pools during the summer. There are no high mountain ranges; its main mountains are just a series of barriers separating the lower coastal areas from the interior plateau. Moreover, its native mammals are completely different from those on other continents, with almost all of them being "marsupials" or "pouch-bearers," like the kangaroo. Most of its birds don’t sing. Most of its flowers lack fragrance. Its trees have vertical leaves and provide no shade. The indigenous people have made little progress toward civilization. When Europeans first arrived, they found no native animals that could be used, and no native fruit, vegetables, or grains that were edible. Nevertheless, all European domestic animals thrive in the country, as do all European fruits, grasses, grains, and vege[169]tables. English rabbits have actually become a huge problem. Up to 25,000,000 of them have been killed in a year, yet there seems to be no noticeable decrease in their population. More than $1,000,000 a year has sometimes been spent trying to eradicate them, and it’s had no impact.

VICTORIA

Victoria, the smallest of the Australian colonies, had until recently the largest population (June, 1897, 1,177,304) and also the largest trade. In both respects, however, it is at present surpassed by New South Wales. Victoria has owed its past pre-eminence to its gold production. Gold was discovered in the colony in 1851, and for years the output of the precious mineral was not less than $50,000,000 per annum. The present output of gold in Victoria, however, is only $10,000,000 per annum. Richer, however, than the gold-mines of Victoria is the fertility of its soil. A large part of the soil is exceedingly fertile—with irrigation one of the finest fruit-bearing soils in the world. The arboreal vegetation of the country is magnificent. Trees thirty feet in diameter rise to the height of 200 feet without a single lateral branch, and then 100 feet to 200 feet higher still. Pear-trees grow to the height of eighty feet, with trunks three feet in diameter. But as yet wool-growing, wheat-raising, and vine-growing are the principal agricultural occupations of the people. The principal agricultural export is wool—$25,000,000 worth per annum. But a considerable portion of this comes from New South Wales. The sheep kept number 15,000,000, the cattle 2,000,000. But the colony still remains principally a mining community. Five ninths of the population live in towns. Yet there are few towns, and two fifths of the whole population live in Melbourne—a city almost exactly as large as Boston.

Victoria, the smallest of the Australian colonies, recently had the largest population (June 1897, 1,177,304) and the highest trade volume. However, it is currently outpaced by New South Wales in both areas. Victoria's past prominence largely came from its gold output. Gold was discovered in the colony in 1851, and for many years, the annual output of the precious metal reached at least $50,000,000. Today, the gold output in Victoria is only $10,000,000 per year. Despite this decline, the rich soil of the region is even more valuable than its gold mines. Much of the land is incredibly fertile—especially with irrigation—making it some of the finest fruit-bearing soil in the world. The natural tree growth in the area is stunning, with trees that can grow up to thirty feet in diameter and soar to heights of 200 feet, often extending another 100 to 200 feet higher without any lateral branches. Pear trees can grow as tall as eighty feet, with trunks three feet in diameter. Currently, the main agricultural activities for the people involve wool-growing, wheat-raising, and vine-growing. The leading agricultural export is wool, valued at $25,000,000 per year, with a significant part coming from New South Wales. The number of sheep reaches 15,000,000, while there are 2,000,000 cattle. Nevertheless, the colony remains primarily a mining community, with five-ninths of the population residing in towns. However, there are few towns, and two-fifths of the total population live in Melbourne, a city almost the same size as Boston.

[170]MELBOURNE

Melbourne (451,110; with suburbs, 500,000), the capital city of Victoria and the chief city in Australia, is also one of the most beautiful cities in the world. Its parliament buildings, town hall, post-office, treasury, mint, law courts, public libraries, picture galleries, theatres, churches, and clubs are all edifices of architectural magnificence and beauty, while its boulevards, parks and gardens are equally splendid. At one time money flowed freely and great commercial recklessness prevailed. But though Melbourne has sustained several severe depressions its present condition is prosperous and its future is assured. It is, however, a pleasure-loving city, and it is as much on this account as on account of its great beauty that it is called "the Paris of the southern hemisphere." Nowhere else in the world, perhaps, are indoor amusements—the theatre, concerts, etc.—or outdoor amusements—cricket, football, horse-racing, etc.—more devotedly patronised than in Melbourne. Other important places in Victoria are Ballarat (40,000) and Sandhurst (37,000), both mining towns, and Geelong (25,000) locally noted for its manufacture of "tweeds."

Melbourne (451,110; with suburbs, 500,000), the capital of Victoria and the main city in Australia, is also one of the most beautiful cities in the world. Its parliament buildings, town hall, post office, treasury, mint, law courts, public libraries, art galleries, theaters, churches, and clubs are all remarkable examples of architectural beauty, while its boulevards, parks, and gardens are just as impressive. At one time, money flowed freely and there was great commercial risk-taking. However, even after going through several severe downturns, Melbourne is currently thriving and has a bright future ahead. It is, however, a city that loves pleasure, and it is for this reason as much as its great beauty that it is known as "the Paris of the southern hemisphere." Nowhere else in the world, perhaps, are indoor entertainment—like theater and concerts—or outdoor activities—such as cricket, football, horse racing, etc.—more passionately supported than in Melbourne. Other significant places in Victoria include Ballarat (40,000) and Sandhurst (37,000), both mining towns, and Geelong (25,000), which is locally famous for its “tweeds.”

[171]NEW SOUTH WALES

Australia. Shaded portions show where the rainfall is sufficiently abundant. Australia. The shaded areas indicate where the rainfall is adequately plentiful.

New South Wales (population 1,311,440) is the oldest colony of Australia and the parent of both Victoria and Queensland. Of all the colonies, it has, perhaps, the greatest range of productions. On the low coast lands its soil is of extraordinary fertility, and even in the dry interior, when irrigation is employed, the fertility is still extraordinary. As yet, however, but one acre out of every two hundred is under cultivation, the chief agricultural occupation being pasturing. Over 50,000,000 sheep are kept, principally the merino. Grass grows everywhere, and even the summits of the mountains are covered. Drought, however, is a terrible drawback, and sometimes tremendous losses occur. In 1877 over 8,000,000 sheep perished, and in 1884 over 12,000,000. The total wool production is very large, averaging $50,000,000 a year. The export of hides, skins, leather, and chilled meat, principally mutton, amounts to $10,000,000 annually.[172] Chilled mutton and beef are sent direct to London, though the passage takes five or six weeks by steamer and twelve to sixteen weeks by sailing-vessel. Scarcely less important than its agricultural products are the mineral products of New South Wales. Its coal-mines are the finest on the continent, and $4,500,000 worth of coal is exported annually, besides what is consumed locally. Its gold production, though not very large, is general throughout the whole colony. Its silver-mines in Silverton and Broken Hill are among the most famous in the world, and its tin-bearing lands comprise over 5,500,000 acres. The foregoing comprise the staple products—the production of industries already well established. But fruit-growing, including all fruits, from apples, pears, and peaches, to olives and oranges, is a rapidly developing industry, no country in the world being better suited to it. Wine-making, too, is quickly coming forward, the New South Wales wines equalling in flavour those of France and Spain. Wheat-growing, cotton-growing, and even rice-growing are also in their several districts rapidly extending and prosperous pursuits. The development of New South Wales has only just begun. Sydney (including suburbs 410,000) is the capital and by far the largest city. Sydney, like Melbourne, is a beautiful city, but its beauty is natural rather than artificial, and it is well entitled to its name, "Queen of the South." It is situated on Port Jackson, one of the finest and most beautiful harbours on the globe. Sydney is the headquarters of all the various lines of steamships—British, American, French, Italian, etc.—that trade with Australia, and is indeed one of the great seaports of the world.

New South Wales (population 1,311,440) is the oldest colony in Australia and the birthplace of both Victoria and Queensland. Among all the colonies, it likely has the widest variety of products. The coastal lowlands have incredibly fertile soil, and even in the dry interior, irrigation allows for remarkable fertility. However, only one acre out of every two hundred is currently cultivated, with the main agricultural activity being pasturing. Over 50,000,000 sheep are raised, primarily merino wool. Grass grows everywhere, even on top of the mountains. Drought is a significant challenge, sometimes leading to devastating losses. In 1877, over 8,000,000 sheep died, and in 1884, more than 12,000,000. The total sheep farming is substantial, averaging $50,000,000 a year. The export of hides, skins, leather, and chilled meat, mainly mutton, totals about $10,000,000 annually.[172] Chilled mutton and beef are sent directly to London, though the journey takes five to six weeks by steamer and twelve to sixteen weeks by sailing vessel. Equally important are New South Wales' mineral products. Its coal mines are the best on the continent, exporting $4,500,000 worth of coal each year, in addition to what is used locally. Although its gold production isn't vast, it is widespread throughout the entire colony. The silver mines in Silverton and Broken Hill are among the most renowned globally, and the region has more than 5,500,000 acres of tin-bearing land. These are the main products—industries that are already well established. However, fruit-growing, including all kinds from apples, pears, and peaches to olives and oranges, is a fast-growing industry, with no country better suited for it. Wine-making is also on the rise, with New South Wales wines comparable in flavor to those from France and Spain. Wheat, cotton, and even rice farming are rapidly growing and successful in their specific regions. The development of New South Wales has only just begun. Sydney (including suburbs 410,000) is the capital and by far the largest city. Like Melbourne, Sydney is a beautiful city, though its beauty is natural rather than artificial, truly deserving of its title, "Queen of the South." It is located on Port Jackson, one of the finest and most picturesque harbors in the world. Sydney serves as the headquarters for various steamship lines—British, American, French, Italian, etc.—that operate in Australia, making it one of the major seaports worldwide.

SOUTH AUSTRALIA

South Australia (358,224 in 1897) occupies the whole central part of the continent from north to south. But[173] as only a very small portion of this vast area is settled—the southeast corner—it may be described as in characteristics resembling Victoria. Its principal industry is wheat-growing. South Australia is indeed the great granary of the continent, and is destined to be one of the great granaries of the world. Like the other divisions of Australia, South Australia, when once drought has been overcome by irrigation, is destined to become a great fruit country, its warm, moistureless climate being peculiarly well suited to the ripening of fruits of exquisite flavours. Already its olives are pronounced the finest in the world. The principal city and chief port is Adelaide (with suburbs 144,352). Like other Australian ports, Adelaide possesses excellent steamboat shipping facilities. In the north, on the Timor Sea, is Port Darwin, likely to be an important trade centre.

South Australia (358,224 in 1897) covers the entire central part of the continent from north to south. But[173] since only a small part of this vast area is settled—the southeast corner—it can be described as being similar to Victoria in its traits. Its main industry is growing wheat. South Australia is truly the great granary of the continent and is on track to become one of the major granaries of the world. Like other regions in Australia, once drought is managed through irrigation, South Australia is set to be a significant fruit-producing area, with its warm, dry climate being particularly well-suited for ripening fruits with exceptional flavors. Its olives are already regarded as the finest in the world. The main city and leading port is Adelaide (with suburbs totaling 144,352). Like other Australian ports, Adelaide has excellent steamboat shipping facilities. In the north, on the Timor Sea, is Darwin Port, which is expected to become an important trade center.

QUEENSLAND

The most interesting of all the Australian colonies is Queensland (population 472,179), for it is a tropical country with a climate so salubrious that white people can live in it and be comfortable and healthy. The heat, instead of being enervating, is stimulating and bracing. A great portion of its soil is of unsurpassed fertility. The only drawback is the unequal distribution throughout the year of the rainfall. But wherever irrigation wells are sunk the climate becomes highly suitable for sheep-raising, and also for the growing of many kinds of fruit. There are already 15,000,000 sheep and 5,000,000 cattle in the colony, and wool is exported to the amount of $15,000,000 annually. Other agricultural exports are frozen beef and mutton, and hides and skins. Wool is the chief export. The second export in importance is gold, which reaches $10,000,000 per annum. Tin is also exported,[174] and coal, though little worked, is abundant. Developing exports are sugar ($2,500,000 per annum), arrowroot, cotton, tobacco, rice, and coffee. A difficulty, however, in the development of these products is the labour question. White men cannot work in the plantations. Chinese prefer to work in the mines. The natives won't work anywhere. No negroes are obtainable. As a consequence Polynesians have to be imported. Brisbane (100,913) is the capital and chief city and port.

The most interesting of all the Australian colonies is Queensland (population 472,179) because it's a tropical region with such a pleasant climate that white people can live there comfortably and stay healthy. The heat is invigorating rather than exhausting. Much of its soil is incredibly fertile. The only downside is the uneven distribution of rainfall throughout the year. However, where irrigation wells are drilled, the climate becomes excellent for sheep farming and for growing various types of fruit. There are already 15 million sheep and 5 million cattle in the colony, with wool exports reaching $15 million annually. Other agricultural exports include frozen beef, mutton, and hides and skins. Wool is the main export. The second most important export is gold, which amounts to $10 million a year. Tin is also exported, [174] and while coal is abundant, it is not mined much. Emerging exports include sugar ($2.5 million a year), arrowroot, cotton, tobacco, rice, and coffee. However, a challenge in developing these products is the labor situation. White people cannot work on the plantations. Chinese workers prefer mining jobs. The local Indigenous people won't work anywhere. No Black workers are available. As a result, Polynesians have to be brought in. Brissy (100,913) is the capital, main city, and port.

WEST AUSTRALIA

West Australia (population 162,394), the largest of all the Australian colonies, has only been recently settled, and its constitution as a self-governing colony dates only from 1890. A large part of its area has never been explored, and a large part is known to be scrub desert. But there is scarcely any part of it, even of its "scrub" areas, but that will support sheep when once artesian wells have been sunk, and large portions of the colony, especially along the coasts, are as fertile as need be. And the climate, though very dry, is exceedingly healthful. Perth (43,000) is the capital. Albany is the principal port.

West Australia (population 162,394), the largest of all the Australian colonies, has only been settled recently, and its constitution as a self-governing colony dates back to 1890. A significant part of its area has never been explored, and much of it is known to be scrub desert. However, there’s hardly any part of it, even the "scrub" areas, that won't support sheep once artesian wells have been installed, and large sections of the colony, especially along the coasts, are very fertile. The climate, while quite dry, is extremely healthy. Perth (43,000) is the capital. Albany is the main port.

THE IMMENSE RESOURCES OF AUSTRALIA. ITS PROBABLE FUTURE

Australia is undoubtedly on the eve of a period of great development. Its resources are known to be immense. Its climate has been found most favourable to human health, and the objectionable feature of the climate, the smallness and irregularity of the rainfall, has been studied and become understood and found remediable. Once the confederation that is now in process of formation[175] takes place, there is no doubt that Australia will enter upon a new and prosperous commercial era. Owing to the fact that its chief opportunities for wealth lie in the development of its natural resources, it is probable that for some time to come almost all the manufactured goods Australia needs will have to be imported. Already its importation amounts to $275,000,000, of which, of course, Great Britain supplies the principal share. This importation is principally clothing and materials for clothing, but it also comprises hardware and machinery, and in fact everything required by a highly civilised and money-spending people, except breadstuffs and provisions. The magnitude of this importation may be comprehended from the fact that it is more than one third of the total exportation of the United States for any year save one up to 1896, including our immense export of breadstuffs, provisions, and cotton. And besides the articles of export already mentioned—wool, meats, hides, skins, minerals, fruits, etc.—there is one other Australian resource that is capable of almost indefinite development. This is its timber. The eucalyptus or gum-tree prevails almost universally in Australia, and some of its commonest varieties, being both strong and indestructible by insects, are of almost unequalled value for ship-building, railway ties, and dock and harbour construction. That the Australians are fully alive to the importance of developing their foreign trade is seen in the efforts they have made to provide facilities for bringing their products to ocean ports. There are 11,980 miles of railway, almost every mile of which has been built by the governments. This is one mile of railway for every 300 inhabitants, as against one mile for every 400 inhabitants in the United States. These railways run wholly to and from the seaboard. There are no manufacturing towns to be catered to. Australian trade consists wholly in[176] exchanging home-raised natural products for imported manufactures. Equally remarkable with the railroad enterprise of the Australians is their enterprise in telegraphic construction and the establishment of cable communications. For example, a telegraph line 2000 miles long, running across the continent from Adelaide to Port Darwin, has been built by the province of South Australia so as to connect with a cable from Port Darwin to Java, Singapore, etc., and thus with Europe and America. For at least 1500 miles this telegraph line runs through one of the most desolate and inaccessible regions in the world.

Australia is clearly on the brink of a significant period of growth. Its resources are known to be vast. The climate is very favorable for human health, and the previously concerning aspects, like limited and irregular rainfall, have been studied and understood, with solutions identified. Once the confederation currently being formed[175] is completed, there’s no doubt that Australia will enter a new and thriving commercial era. Since its main opportunities for wealth come from harnessing its natural resources, it’s likely that, for the foreseeable future, most of the manufactured goods Australia needs will have to be imported. Right now, imports total $275,000,000, mainly from Great Britain. These imports primarily consist of clothing and fabrics, but also include hardware, machinery, and pretty much everything else a wealthy, developed society needs, except for grains and basic foods. The scale of these imports is significant, amounting to more than one-third of the total exports from the United States for all but one year up to 1896, including our vast exports of grains, food, and cotton. In addition to the aforementioned exports—wool, meats, hiding, skins, minerals, fruits, etc.—there's another Australian resource that can be developed extensively: its lumber. The eucalyptus or gum tree is nearly universal in Australia, and some of its most common types are both strong and resistant to insects, making them extremely valuable for shipbuilding, railway ties, and dock and harbor construction. Australians are keenly aware of the importance of expanding their foreign trade, as evidenced by their efforts to create facilities to transport their products to ocean ports. There are 11,980 miles of railway, almost all built by the government. This means there is one mile of railway for every 300 residents, compared to one mile for every 400 residents in the United States. These railways connect exclusively to the coastline, without any focus on manufacturing towns. Australian trade relies entirely on[176] exchanging locally produced natural goods for imported manufactured products. Equally significant as the railway efforts is Australia’s initiative in telecommunication, particularly in building telegraph lines and establishing cable connections. For instance, there’s a 2000-mile-long telegraph line spanning the continent from Adelaide to Port Darwin, set up by the province of South Australia, linking to a cable from Port Darwin to Java, Singapore, and further on to Europe and America. This telegraph line stretches for at least 1500 miles across one of the most barren and remote areas in the world.

[177]XI. THE TRADE FEATURES OF SOUTH AMERICA

SOUTH AMERICA, A FERTILE CONTINENT WITH DRAWBACKS

South America is an immense but very fertile continent, whose natural resources are as yet scarcely begun to be utilised. Though not so large as North America, it has a far greater area of productive soil—and, indeed, much of its soil is quite unsurpassed in fertility. It suffers, however, from two great drawbacks. 1. A great portion of its area (four fifths) lies within the torrid zone. In the low coast regions of this torrid area, and also in the low forest regions watered by the great flat rivers of the interior, the climate is for the most part unendurable to white men. 2. South America has been unfortunate in its settlement and colonisation. Until in recent years colonisation as understood in Anglo-Saxon communities has scarcely been attempted in South America at all. All the earlier immigrations from the Old World were prompted by the thought of getting gold and silver and precious stones—if need were by the spoliation and enslavery of the natives. Only a small proportion of the population—not more than a quarter of the whole—consists of whites, and these are principally from Spain and[178] Portugal. These conquerors of the continent have not in the main succeeded in establishing either stable forms of government or high types of civilisation. Furthermore, the mixed races—the mestizos or metis, as they are called, the descendants of the earlier Europeans and the natives—instead of advancing in civilisation have for some time past been retrograding. Then, again, there is a large negro element, the descendants of Africans once imported as slaves, to still further complicate the race question; and there is a considerable element partly negro and partly Indian. In only one state, Argentina, can affairs be said to be really prosperous, and even in Argentina the civilisation developed by its prosperity is gross and material rather than refined and intellectual. The next most prosperous and important states are Brazil and Chile. Perhaps Uruguay, though the smallest of all the states, should be placed after Argentina. The remaining independent states of the continent—Venezuela, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Bolivia, and Paraguay—are all states of the prevailing South American type. Their governments are more or less unstable. They are terribly burdened with debt, and their credit is such that they must pay high rates of interest. The civilisation once introduced among their native races by the zeal of Spanish missionaries is deteriorating if not vanishing. And even among their leading classes there is much to be desired in the observance of the ordinary principles of right and wrong.

South America is a vast but highly fertile continent, whose natural resources have barely begun to be tapped. Although it's not as large as North America, it has a much larger area of productive soil—and much of this soil is truly unparalleled in fertility. However, it faces two significant challenges. 1. A large part of its land (four-fifths) is located within the tropics. In the low coastal regions of this tropical area, as well as in the low forest areas fed by the vast flat rivers of the interior, the climate is mostly unbearable for white people. 2. South America has had an unfortunate history of settlement and colonization. Until recently, colonization, as understood in Anglo-Saxon societies, has hardly been attempted in South America. All earlier migrations from the Old World were motivated by a desire for gold, silver, and precious stones—often through the exploitation and enslavement of the natives. Only a small percentage of the population—not more than a quarter—consists of white people, mainly from Spain and[178] Portugal. These conquerors have mostly failed to establish stable governments or advanced civilizations. Moreover, the mixed-race population—the mixed-race individuals or Métis, descendants of earlier Europeans and natives—have been regressing rather than advancing in civilization for some time. Additionally, there is a significant Black population, the descendants of Africans brought in as slaves, which complicates the racial dynamics; there is also a sizable group that is partly Black and partly Indigenous. Only one country, Argentina, can be considered truly prosperous, and even in Argentina, the civilization that arises from its wealth is more coarse and material than refined and intellectual. The next most prosperous countries are Brazil and Chile. Perhaps Uruguay, although the smallest of all, should follow Argentina in this ranking. The other independent countries on the continent—Venezuela, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Bolivia, and Paraguay—are all of the typical South American kind. Their governments are generally unstable. They are heavily burdened with debt, which forces them to pay high interest rates. The civilization that Spanish missionaries once introduced to the native populations is declining, if not disappearing entirely. Even among their elite, there is much lacking in the adherence to basic principles of right and wrong.

EUROPEAN IMMIGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA

All the South American states enumerated above, with the exception of Brazil, were first taken possession of and "settled" by the Spanish, and the Spanish language still remains in them the language of government, education,[179] and society. Brazil was first taken possession of and "settled" by the Portuguese, and in Brazil the Portuguese language prevails, just as elsewhere in the continent the Spanish language prevails. Among the natives many different languages are found, but in Brazil a "common language" is used, one introduced by the original Portuguese missionaries, and understood by nearly all the tribes. Between Brazil and Venezuela is a triangular piece of country called Guiana, which, unlike the rest of South America, is still under the control of European powers. It consists of three parts—French Guiana, Dutch Guiana, and British Guiana—colonies of France, Holland, and Great Britain, respectively. Leaving out Guiana, South America has received its entire civilisation from Spain and Portugal, and, with the exception of Argentina, Uruguay, and Brazil, there has been little or no emigration to any South American country except from these two European countries. To Argentina, however, there has been a large emigration from Italy especially, but also from France, Great Britain (mainly from Ireland and Wales), Germany, and Sweden. A similar emigration has taken place to Uruguay, though the foreigners in Uruguay are principally Basques, a people that live on the border-land between Spain and France, but are neither Spanish nor French. In Brazil the immigration, where it has not been Portuguese, has been chiefly Italian and German, and in the temperate region of the extreme south of Brazil a large German population exists. Everywhere in South America the parts most prosperous are the parts that have come most directly under the influence of recent European emigration.

All the South American countries mentioned above, except for Brazil, were initially taken over and "settled" by the Spanish, and Spanish is still the language of government, education, [179] and society in those countries. Brazil, on the other hand, was first claimed and "settled" by the Portuguese, and Portuguese is the dominant language there, just as Spanish is in the rest of the continent. Various languages are spoken among the native people, but in Brazil a "common language" was introduced by the original Portuguese missionaries, which is understood by nearly all indigenous groups. Between Brazil and Venezuela lies a triangular region known as Guiana, which, unlike the rest of South America, is still under European control. It is made up of three areas—French Guiana, Dutch Guiana, and British Guiana—colonies of France, the Netherlands, and Great Britain, respectively. Excluding Guiana, South America owes its entire civilization to Spain and Portugal, and aside from Argentina, Uruguay, and Brazil, there has been little to no immigration to any South American country from sources other than these two European nations. However, Argentina has seen significant immigration from Italy, as well as from France, Great Britain (mainly from Ireland and Wales), Germany, and Sweden. A similar trend has occurred in Uruguay, though the majority of immigrants there are Basques, a group that resides on the border between Spain and France, yet identifies as neither. In Brazil, aside from the Portuguese arrivals, the main immigrant groups have been Italian and German, with a large German community located in the temperate southern region of Brazil. Overall, the most prosperous areas in South America are those that have been most influenced by recent European immigration.

THE ARGENTINE REPUBLIC

The Argentine Republic, or "Argentina," as it is popularly called, is the most prosperous and most important of[180] all the South American states. Its area (1,319,247 square miles) is equal to the total area of the States of the United States east of the Mississippi and Missouri, including the Dakotas, Missouri, Arkansas, and Louisiana. Although a portion of this vast area is not of much value for agricultural purposes, especially in Patagonia, a very large portion of it does consist of soil of great fertility, while the climate, which for the most part is a temperate one, is such as is well suited to Europeans and white people generally. The population May 10, 1895, was 4,094,911. Of this population it is estimated that over 850,000 are Italians, 183,000 French, 161,000 recently emigrated Spaniards, 60,000 English, and 54,000 Germans and Swedes. The language of the government and of the schools is Spanish. At one time in Argentina there was a disposition to take the United States as a model in everything, but of late years there has been a tendency toward taking France as a model in manners and customs. This disposition to imitate European peoples is particularly true of the wealthy classes.

The Argentine Republic, or "Argentina," as it's commonly known, is the most prosperous and significant of[180] all the South American countries. Its area (1,319,247 square miles) is comparable to the total area of the States in the United States east of the Mississippi and Missouri, including the Dakotas, Missouri, Arkansas, and Louisiana. While some parts of this vast land aren't very useful for agriculture, especially in Patagonia, a large portion is made up of highly fertile soil, and the climate, which is mostly temperate, is well-suited for Europeans and white people in general. As of May 10, 1895, the population was 4,094,911. It's estimated that over 850,000 of these residents are Italians, 183,000 are French, 161,000 are recently immigrated Spaniards, 60,000 are English, and 54,000 are Germans and Swedes. The language used in government and schools is Spanish. There was once a tendency in Argentina to model itself after the United States in all respects, but in recent years, there has been a shift toward looking to France as a model for manners and customs. This desire to emulate European cultures is particularly evident among the wealthy classes.

ARGENTINA'S RAPID PROGRESS

The pride and boast of Argentina has been its rapid progress. In the thirty years ending 1886 the immigration was over a million. From 1886 to 1889 it was from 100,000 a year to 200,000 a year. In 1890, owing to the financial crisis of that year, it fell away almost to nothing. Since 1890 it has gradually increased until now it is about 100,000 a year again. In 1869 the population was only 1,837,000. Now it is over 4,000,000. Similarly the capital city, Buenos Ayres, has made an increase not easily paralleled. In 1869 its population was only 187,126. In 1887 it was 423,996. By the census of 1895 it was 663,854. To-day it is said to be[181] 750,000. Of this number about one half are foreigners. The high protective tariff established by Argentina in 1878 had the effect of instituting many small industries in Buenos Ayres, and to this cause the exceedingly rapid growth of its population is partly attributable.

The pride and highlight of Argentina has been its rapid progress. In the thirty years leading up to 1886, immigration exceeded a million. From 1886 to 1889, it fluctuated between 100,000 and 200,000 immigrants per year. However, in 1890, due to that year’s financial crisis, it dropped almost to zero. Since 1890, it has gradually picked up again, reaching about 100,000 a year. In 1869, the population was only 1,837,000. Now, it exceeds 4,000,000. Likewise, the capital city, Buenos Aires, has experienced growth that's hard to match. In 1869, its population was only 187,126. By 1887, it had risen to 423,996. According to the 1895 census, it was 663,854. Today, it’s estimated to be[181] 750,000. About half of this number consists of foreigners. The high protective tariff implemented by Argentina in 1878 helped establish numerous small industries in Buenos Aires, contributing to the city's exceptionally rapid population growth.

ARGENTINA'S AGRICULTURE AND MANUFACTURES

The great prosperity of Argentina has been due to the extent and immediate availability of its agricultural resources, for its forest wealth remains undeveloped, and its mineral resources are comparatively scanty. Its vast treeless and stoneless plains have needed no "improvements" to make them fit for settlement, and the soil which covers them being of virgin richness bears crop after crop without fertilising and with very little cultivation. Immigrants arrive in the country without a dollar and in twenty years are owners of estates of 5000 acres each. In no country in the world has agricultural extension been more rapid. In twenty years the acreage under cultivation increased 1400 per cent. The amount under cultivation in wheat alone increased 2600 per cent. The wheat production averages 40,000,000 bushels, which is not far short of one fourth of the total wheat export of the United States. The production for 1897 was 60,000,000 bushels, although the amount exported was much less than that. The wheat product is indeed very variable, owing to droughts and locusts, for, like Australia, Argentina is uncertain in its rainfall. The corn crop is steadier, and in 1896 amounted (for export alone) to 60,000,000 bushels. More important in the aggregate than the direct products of the soil are the indirect products. There are 22,000,000 cattle kept in Argentina, 75,000,000 sheep, and 4,500,000 horses. The total exportation of animals and animal products amounts to $70,-[182]000,000. Of this exportation the principal item is wool, the wool-clip of Argentina being, in weight, one seventh of the total wool-clip of the world. Unfortunately, however, Argentina wool is very dirty, and when washed reduces to one third, while Australian wool reduces only to two thirds or three fifths and is free from seeds. The profit accruing to the Argentina wool-grower is thereby lessened. But, nevertheless, wool-growing in Argentina is a very profitable industry, and many farmers (principally Irish settlers) have from 50,000 to 100,000 sheep each. Cattle-farming is carried on mostly by native Argentines, and many cattle farms are stocked with as many as 10,000 cattle and 2000 horses each. The great exports of Argentina, therefore, after wheat and corn and wool, are hides and skins, tallow, chilled beef, and mutton and bones. There are five factories in Buenos Ayres engaged wholly in chilling mutton, and the export of chilled mutton to Great Britain alone is $5,000,000 a year. Another growing agricultural product is wine, the yearly production being 1,500,000 gallons. Notwithstanding Argentina's magnificent forest areas, but little timber is exported or even manufactured for home consumption. The other principal manufacturing industries are carriage-, cart-, and harness-making, cigarette- and match-making, preserving and tinning meat, brewing, flour- and corn-milling, and the making of macaroni.

The significant prosperity of Argentina comes from the abundance and immediate availability of its agricultural resources, as its forest wealth is still untapped, and its mineral resources are fairly limited. Its vast plains, lacking trees and stones, didn’t require any "improvements" to become suitable for settlement, and the rich soil can produce crop after crop without fertilization and minimal cultivation. Immigrants arrive in the country without any money and within twenty years become owners of estates averaging 5,000 acres each. No other country in the world has seen such rapid agricultural expansion. In just twenty years, the land under cultivation increased by 1,400 percent. The area planted with wheat alone grew by 2,600 percent. The wheat farming averages 40 million bushels, which is nearly one-fourth of the total wheat export of the United States. In 1897, production reached 60 million bushels, although the amount exported was much less. Wheat production can be very unpredictable due to droughts and locusts, similar to Australia, as Argentina's rainfall is inconsistent. The corn harvest is more reliable, reaching 60 million bushels for export in 1896. More significant than the direct products of the soil are the indirect products. Argentina has 22 million livestock, 75 million sheep, and 4.5 million horses. The total export of animals and animal products amounts to $70,000,000. The main export item is wool, which makes up one-seventh of the world's total wool production by weight. Unfortunately, Argentine wool is heavily contaminated, and after washing, it reduces to one-third of its original weight, while Australian wool only reduces to two-thirds or three-fifths and is free of seeds. This diminishes the profits for Argentine wool growers. Nevertheless, wool production in Argentina is still a lucrative industry, with many farmers (mostly Irish settlers) owning between 50,000 and 100,000 sheep each. Cattle farming is primarily done by native Argentines, and some cattle farms have as many as 10,000 cattle and 2,000 horses each. Thus, after wheat, corn, and wool, Argentina’s major exports include hides, skins, rendered animal fat, cold beef, and lamb and bones. There are five factories in Buenos Aires dedicated entirely to chilling mutton, and the export of chilled mutton to Great Britain alone is $5 million each year. Another growing agricultural product is vino, with an annual production of 1.5 million gallons. Despite Argentina's impressive forest resources, very little timber is exported or even produced for domestic consumption. The other main manufacturing industries include carriage, cart, and harness-making, cigarette and match production, meat preserving and canning, brewing, flour and corn milling, and pasta production.

[183]BUENOS AYRES

The most prosperous part of South America. The wealthiest region of South America.

Buenos Ayres, the capital of Argentina, is the largest city not only in South America but in the whole southern hemisphere. The La Plata, at whose mouth it stands, affords navigation into all the northern parts of the republic, as well as into the neighbouring states of Uruguay, Paraguay, Brazil, and Bolivia. The riverside at Buenos Ayres is at all times of the year a perfect forest of masts and smoke-stacks belonging to the shipping that supplies this navigation. Recently, at a cost of $25,000,000, the river, which here is shallow, has been deepened and new wharves and docks have been built, and ocean-going vessels of the deepest draught (which formerly used to be lightened fourteen miles away) can now unload or be loaded right in the very heart of the city. The total commerce of the republic amounts to $200,000,000 or $225,000,000 a year, and of this trade Buenos Ayres transacts seven eighths in imports and three fifths in exports. The amount of this trade secured by the United States is[184] about a tenth, running from $12,000,000 to $24,000,000. In 1896 it was only $12,500,000. The principal export trade is with France ($24,000,000), Great Britain ($14,000,000), Germany ($13,000,000), and Belgium. Great Britain does not buy Argentina wool. The principal import trade is with Great Britain ($45,000,000), Germany ($14,000,000), France ($12,000,000), and Italy. The Buenos Ayreans are fond of display and of dress and of ornamentation, and the importations from France and Italy are principally of goods to gratify this fondness. There is a considerable exportation of wheat, flour, tobacco, and maté (Paraguay tea) to Brazil and other South American states. Buenos Ayres is the centre of the Argentina railway system, which consists of about 9000 miles of road. There are 25,500 miles of telegraph routes. The national debt amounts to $430,000,000. The provincial debts amount to about $140,000,000. The taxation amounts to nearly ten per cent. of the earnings of the people, as against four and one half per cent. in Canada and five per cent. in Australia.

BA, the capital of Argentina, is the largest city not just in South America but in the entire southern hemisphere. The La Plata River, where it sits, provides navigation to all the northern regions of the country, as well as to the neighboring countries of Uruguay, Paraguay, Brazil, and Bolivia. The waterfront in Buenos Aires is always bustling with a mix of masts and smoke stacks from the ships that support this navigation. Recently, $25 million was spent to deepen the river, which was shallow in this area, and new docks and wharves have been constructed. Large ocean-going vessels, which used to have to lighten their loads fourteen miles away, can now load and unload right in the city's center. The total trade of the country is around $200 million to $225 million a year, with Buenos Aires handling seven-eighths of imports and three-fifths of exports. The amount of trade from the United States is[184] about ten percent, ranging from $12 million to $24 million. In 1896, it was only $12.5 million. The primary export markets are France ($24 million), Great Britain ($14 million), Germany ($13 million), and Belgium. Great Britain does not import Argentine wool. The main sources for imports are Great Britain ($45 million), Germany ($14 million), France ($12 million), and Italy. The people of Buenos Aires enjoy showing off their style, fashion, and decor, and the goods imported from France and Italy primarily cater to this taste. There is significant exportation of wheat, flour, tobacco, and maté (Paraguayan tea) to Brazil and other South American countries. Buenos Aires is the hub of Argentina's railway system, which spans about 9,000 miles. There are 25,500 miles of telegraph lines. The national debt stands at $430 million, while the provincial debts total around $140 million. Taxation amounts to nearly ten percent of the people's earnings, compared to four and a half percent in Canada and five percent in Australia.

BRAZIL

Brazil is a much larger and more populous country than Argentina. Its area (3,209,878 square miles) is as large as that of all the United States, less half of Alaska. A great portion of this area is of superlatively tropical richness of production. But, unfortunately, the most fertile parts of Brazil are the parts least fit for settlement by white men. The population by the last census is approximately 14,500,000, but less than 4,000,000 of this population are pure whites. The negroes that were lately slaves number over 2,000,000, and there are supposed to be about 1,000,000 Indians. Intermediate between the Indians and negroes and the white population are the numerous mixed races or half-breeds. Agriculture is the[185] chief industry, but is of two kinds: the tropical agriculture of the central and south central seaboard, which is carried on principally by negro and mulatto labour, and the agriculture of the temperate region of the extreme south, which is carried on mainly by colonists from Europe, the recent European emigration being almost wholly directed toward that region. Almost the whole of the interior of Brazil still remains unsettled and untilled. The coffee yield of Brazil is enormous and is its principal product. The production amounts to 8,000,000 bags or over 1,000,000,000 pounds annually, which is more than two thirds of the total amount of coffee used in the world. Labour for coffee cultivation is scarce and dear, and in the earlier stages of the production of the berry the Brazilian coffee gets badly treated. But machinery is used wherever possible, and in the later stages of the production the Brazilian coffee gets the best attention that skill can devise. As a consequence the coffee product of Brazil is rising in the estimation of coffee-users. The shrubs are cultivated under palm-trees so as to keep them from the intense heat of the sun. Three or four harvests of berries are obtained in a year. Rio Janeiro and Santos are the two chief centres of the coffee industry. Next to coffee the chief tropical product is sugar, the export of which is about 250,000 tons annually, principally from Pernambuco. Other products of the tropical area of Brazil are cocoa and cotton, from the cultivated coast regions, and rubber and Brazil-nuts, from the dense forests of the lower Amazon; also dyewoods and cabinet woods, drugs, and diamonds. For many years Brazil was celebrated for its diamonds—obtained chiefly from a town in the interior named Diamantina. The present diamond production is not large. From the temperate agricultural region of the south, dried beef, hides, and tallow are the chief exports. The greatest customer of Brazilian produce is the United[186] States, which takes $70,000,000 worth. Great Britain is next, with $35,000,000 worth (in rubber alone in 1896 $15,000,000). Brazil gets her goods principally from Great Britain, the United States, France, and Germany—from Great Britain $20,000,000, from the United States $13,000,000. The imports include almost all articles needed for domestic and manufacturing purposes—particularly cottons and woollens, ironware, machinery, lumber, flour, rice, dried meats, kerosene, butter, and fish. There are, however, 155 cotton factories established in Brazil, with capital to the value of $50,000,000, and cotton manufacturing is protected by very heavy duties. But agricultural machinery and such like manufactures are very lightly taxed. The principal food of the people is manioc flour (tapioca).

Brazil is a much larger and more populated country than Argentina. Its land area (3,209,878 square miles) is about the size of the entire United States, minus half of Alaska. A large part of this area has incredibly rich tropical production. Unfortunately, the most fertile regions of Brazil are the least suitable for settlement by white people. According to the last census, the population is around 14,500,000, but less than 4,000,000 of this population are pure whites. The formerly enslaved Black population exceeds 2,000,000, and there are estimated to be about 1,000,000 Indigenous people. Between the Indigenous and Black populations and the white population are many mixed-race individuals. Agriculture is the[185] main industry, which comes in two forms: the tropical agriculture of the central and south-central coastline, primarily carried out by Black and mixed-race workers, and the agriculture of the temperate region in the far south, mainly run by immigrants from Europe, as recent European migration has mostly focused on that area. Almost the entire interior of Brazil is still uninhabited and uncultivated. The coffee output of Brazil is massive and is its primary product. Production reaches 8,000,000 bags or over 1,000,000,000 pounds each year, accounting for more than two-thirds of the total coffee consumed worldwide. Labor for coffee cultivation is scarce and costly, and during the early stages of coffee production, Brazilian coffee can be poorly treated. However, machinery is used wherever possible, and in the later stages of production, Brazilian coffee receives the best attention that expertise can provide. As a result, the quality of Brazilian coffee is improving in the eyes of coffee drinkers. The plants are grown under palm trees to protect them from the intense sunlight. Three or four harvests of beans are collected each year. Rio de Janeiro and Santos are the two main hubs of the coffee industry. After coffee, the primary tropical product is sugar, with exports around 250,000 tons per year, mostly from Pernambuco. Other tropical products from Brazil include chocolate and cotton, from the cultivated coastal areas, and rubber and Brazil nuts from the dense forests of the lower Amazon, as well as dyes, hardwood flooring, medicines, and diamonds. For many years, Brazil was known for its diamonds—mainly sourced from a town in the interior called Diamantina. Currently, diamond production is not significant. From the temperate agricultural region of the south, dried beef, hides, and tallow are the primary exports. The main customer for Brazilian products is the United[186] States, which imports $70,000,000 worth. Great Britain is next, with $35,000,000 worth (including $15,000,000 in rubber alone in 1896). Brazil mainly gets its goods from Great Britain, the United States, France, and Germany—$20,000,000 from Great Britain and $13,000,000 from the United States. Imports consist of nearly all items needed for domestic and manufacturing purposes—especially cottons and woolens, iron goods, machinery, lumber, flour, rice, dried meats, kerosene, butter, and fish. However, there are 155 cotton factories in Brazil, with a total investment of $50,000,000 and cotton manufacturing is supported by very high tariffs. But agricultural machinery and similar products are taxed very lightly. The primary food for the population is manioc flour (tapioca).

RIO JANEIRO

Rio Janeiro (674,972), the capital and principal city, though a poor-looking place, is situated on a magnificent harbour—one of the very finest in the world. About 1500 vessels, with tonnage amounting to 2,500,000 tons, enter Rio Janeiro with foreign trade annually. Nine thousand miles of railway have been built in Brazil and 3500 more are in course of construction, and 12,000 miles of telegraph routes have been built. Rio Janeiro is the chief railway centre, but other centres are Rio Grande do Sul, in the temperate regions of the south, and Bahia and Pernambuco, in the tropical regions. The public (national) debt of Brazil is not far short of $1,000,000,000, bearing interest (a great part of it) at from four to six per cent. per annum.

Rio de Janeiro (674,972), the capital and main city, might look a bit run-down, but it's located on a stunning harbor—one of the best in the world. Every year, about 1,500 ships, with a total tonnage of 2,500,000 tons, come into Rio Janeiro for foreign trade. Brazil has built 9,000 miles of railways, and another 3,500 miles are currently under construction, along with 12,000 miles of telegraph lines. Rio Janeiro is the main railway hub, but there are also important centers in Rio Grande do Sul in the cooler southern regions, and Bahia and Pernambuco in the tropical areas. Brazil's public (national) debt is close to $1,000,000,000, with a large portion of it earning interest at rates between four and six percent per year.

[187]XII. THE TRADE FEATURES OF CANADA

CANADA, PRACTICALLY AN INDEPENDENT FEDERAL REPUBLIC

The dominion of Canada comprises all that portion of the continent of North America north of the United States—except Alaska and Newfoundland and the coast of Labrador. (Newfoundland and the Labrador coast is a colony in direct relationship to Great Britain.) Canada is entirely self-governing and self-maintaining, and its connection with Great Britain is almost wholly a matter of loyalty and affection. It consists (1) of seven Provinces: Ontario, Quebec, Nova Scotia, New Brunswick, Prince Edward Island, Manitoba, and British Columbia, which, in their self-governing powers and their relation to the general government, correspond very closely to our States; (2) of four Territories—Assiniboia, Alberta, Saskatchewan, and Athabasca, which correspond somewhat to our Territories; (3) of four other Territories—Ungava, Franklin, Mackenzie, and Yukon, which are administered by the general government; and (4) the District of Keewatin, which is under the jurisdiction of the lieutenant-governor of Manitoba. The capital of the whole dominion is Ottawa. Each province has its own capital.

The dominion of Canada includes everything in North America that's north of the United States—except for Alaska, Newfoundland, and the coast of Labrador. (Newfoundland and the Labrador coast are a colony that directly relates to Great Britain.) Canada is fully self-governing and self-supporting, and its connection with Great Britain is mostly based on loyalty and affection. It consists of (1) seven Provinces: Ontario, Quebec, Nova Scotia, New Brunswick, Prince Edward Island, Manitoba, and British Columbia, which have self-governing powers and a relationship to the general government that is quite similar to our States; (2) four Territories—Assiniboia, Alberta, Saskatchewan, and Athabasca, which are somewhat like our Territories; (3) four other Territories—Ungava, Franklin, Mackenzie, and Yukon, which are managed by the general government; and (4) the District of Keewatin, which is under the control of the lieutenant-governor of Manitoba. The capital of the entire dominion is Ottawa. Each province has its own capital.

[188]SIZE, SOIL, CLIMATE, AND POPULATION OF CANADA

The area of Canada is immense. It figures up to 3,456,383 square miles, which is almost 500,000 square miles more than the total area of the United States exclusive of Alaska, and not far short of being equal to the area of all Europe. But almost 150,000 square miles of this area are taken up by lakes and rivers; and a much greater portion than this, under present conditions of civilisation, is wholly uninhabitable, being either too cold or too barren. Yet when all the necessary allowances have been made there still remains in Canada an immense area with soil fertile enough and climate favourable enough for all the purposes of a highly civilised population. Over 900,000 square miles are already occupied, and of the occupied area fully one half has been "improved." The older provinces are, acre for acre, as suitable for agricultural pursuits as the adjoining States of the Union. Manitoba, the "Prairie Province," is almost one vast wheat field, with a productivity for wheat unequalled anywhere except in the Red River valley of Minnesota and Dakota. The Manitoba grain harvest foots up to 50,000,000 bushels. British Columbia is a land of almost infinite possibilities, not only because of its mineral and timber resources, but also because of its capabilities for agriculture and fruit-growing. The Territories are so vast an area that no general description of them is possible, but it may be said that the great wheat valley of the Saskatchewan, the sheltered grazing country of Alberta, and the great wheat plains of the Peace River valley in Athabasca, are regions adapted in soil and climate to sustain a hardy and vigorous people. The population of Canada is comparatively small. It is estimated at 5,250,000. Over 1,000,000 people of Canadian birth reside in the United[189] States, and the number of Americans residing in Canada is only 80,000. Out of the 2,425,000 persons who came to Canada as immigrants in a period of forty years, no fewer than 1,310,000, or fifty four per cent., came over into the United States. It is stated that this exodus has ceased, and that if any great movement of population now exists it is toward Canada.

The area of Canada is huge. It measures up to 3,456,383 square miles, which is almost 500,000 square miles more than the total area of the United States, excluding Alaska, and nearly equal to the area of all of Europe. However, almost 150,000 square miles of this area is covered by lakes and rivers, and a much larger portion is completely uninhabitable due to being too cold or too barren under current civil conditions. Yet, when factoring in all the necessary considerations, Canada still has a vast area with fertile soil and a favorable climate suitable for a highly civilized population. Over 900,000 square miles are already occupied, and half of that area has been "improved." The older provinces are just as suitable for farming as the neighboring states in the Union. Manitoba, known as the "Prairie Province," is nearly one big wheat field, with wheat yields unmatched anywhere except in Minnesota and Dakota's Red River Valley. The Manitoba grain harvest totals up to 50,000,000 bushels. British Columbia offers almost endless possibilities, thanks not only to its mineral and timber resources but also its capabilities for agriculture and fruit-growing. The Territories are so vast that a general description is difficult, but it can be said that the rich wheat valley of Saskatchewan, the protected grazing lands of Alberta, and the expansive wheat plains of the Peace River Valley in Athabasca are areas with soil and climate suitable for supporting a strong and resilient population. Canada's population is relatively small, estimated at 5,250,000. Over 1,000,000 people born in Canada live in the United States, while only 80,000 Americans reside in Canada. Of the 2,425,000 people who immigrated to Canada over a span of forty years, no fewer than 1,310,000, or fifty-four percent, moved on to the United States. It is said that this exodus has stopped and, if any significant population movement exists now, it is towards Canada.

CANADA'S FOREST WEALTH

Canada, like all new countries, depends for her prosperity upon the development and exportation of her natural products. These are of four great classes: (1), the products of her forests; (2), the products of her mines; (3), the products of her fisheries; (4), her agricultural products. Canada's forest resources, when both extent and quality are considered, are the finest in the world. The forest area uncut was in 1891 nearly 1,250,000 square miles, or more than one third of the area of the whole country. The annual value of the timber and lumber produced is about $82,500,000. The annual value of the timber and lumber exported is about $32,000,000. Two thirds of this goes to Great Britain, and over $9,000,000 in lumber and logs goes to the United States. Quebec and Ontario have unlimited supplies of spruce for wood-pulp manufacture, the annual output of which reaches 200,000 tons. The uncut lumber of British Columbia, which includes Douglas pine, Menzies fir, spruce, red and yellow cedar, and hemlock, is estimated to be 100,000,000,000 cubic feet.

Canada, like all new countries, relies on the development and export of its natural resources for prosperity. These resources fall into four main categories: (1) forest products; (2) mineral products; (3) fishery products; (4) agricultural products. Canada's forest resources, in terms of both size and quality, are among the best in the world. The uncut forest area was nearly 1,250,000 square miles in 1891, which is more than one-third of the entire country. The annual value of the timber and lumber produced is around $82,500,000. The annual value of the timber and lumber exported is about $32,000,000. Two-thirds of this goes to Great Britain, and over $9,000,000 in lumber and logs is sent to the United States. Quebec and Ontario have unlimited supplies of spruce for wood pulp production, with an annual output reaching 200,000 tons. The uncut lumber in British Columbia, which includes Douglas pine, Menzies fir, spruce, red and yellow cedar, and hemlock, is estimated at 100,000,000,000 cubic feet.

CANADA'S MINERAL RESOURCES

Canada is just beginning to realise the largeness of her mineral resources. The most talked of gold-mines are[190] those of the Klondike district, the extent of which is still uncertain. Much more definitely known and almost as productive are the gold-mines of British Columbia and the newly discovered gold-fields of the Rainy River district in northern Ontario. More important than the gold-mines of Canada are its coal-fields. These are principally in Nova Scotia and British Columbia. The latter province is destined to be the coal-supplying region for the whole Pacific coast of North America. The yearly output at present is about 1,000,000 tons; the yearly output of Nova Scotia is about 2,000,000 tons, principally produced by American capital. In Alberta there are said to be coal-fields having an area of 65,000 square miles. Iron is found in abundance in both British Columbia and Ontario. Ontario has in its nickel-mines of Sudbury a mineral treasure not found elsewhere in equal abundance in the world. Experts have estimated that 650,000,000 tons of this ore are actually in sight. Ontario produces petroleum and salt. Silver, copper, lead, asbestos, plumbago, mica, etc., are found in varying quantities. Canada imports annually from the United States nearly $10,000,000 worth of coal and coke.

Canada is just starting to realize the vastness of its mineral resources. The most discussed gold mines are[190] those in the Klondike district, whose size is still uncertain. Much more clearly defined and nearly as productive are the gold mines in British Columbia and the newly discovered gold fields in the Rainy River district in northern Ontario. More significant than Canada's gold mines are its coal fields. These are mainly located in Nova Scotia and British Columbia. The latter province is set to be the coal supplier for the entire Pacific coast of North America. Currently, the annual output is about 1,000,000 tons; Nova Scotia produces around 2,000,000 tons, largely generated by American investment. Alberta is said to have coal fields that cover an area of 65,000 square miles. Iron is plentiful in both British Columbia and Ontario. Ontario boasts nickel mines in Sudbury, which contain a type of mineral treasure not found elsewhere in such abundance globally. Experts estimate that 650,000,000 tons of this ore are readily available. Ontario also produces petroleum and salt. Silver, copper, lead, asbestos, plumbago, mica, and other minerals are found in varying amounts. Canada imports nearly $10,000,000 worth of coal and coke from the United States each year.

CANADA'S FISHERIES

The fisheries of the Gulf of St. Lawrence and of the shallow waters bordering on Nova Scotia and Newfoundland have for centuries been the most productive in the world. The Canadian fishing interest in these waters is very great. Cod, mackerel, haddock, halibut, herring, smelts, and salmon, are the principal fish, and the annual "take" is about $15,000,000. About $2,500,000 worth of whitefish, salmon-trout, herring, pickerel, and sturgeon are produced annually from the Canadian lakes. The salmon-fishing of the rivers and great sea-inlets of British[191] Columbia brings about $4,500,000 annually. About one half of the total product is exported to Great Britain and the United States.

The fisheries of the Gulf of St. Lawrence and the shallow waters around Nova Scotia and Newfoundland have been among the most productive in the world for centuries. The Canadian fishing industry in these areas is significant. The main fish caught are cod, mackerel, haddock, halibut, herring, smelts, and salmon, generating an annual revenue of about $15,000,000. Additionally, around $2,500,000 worth of whitefish, salmon-trout, herring, pickerel, and sturgeon are produced each year from Canadian lakes. Salmon fishing in the rivers and large sea-inlets of British[191] Columbia brings in about $4,500,000 annually. About half of the total catch is exported to Great Britain and the United States.

CANADA'S AGRICULTURAL PRODUCE

Agriculture, including stock-raising, dairying and fruit-growing, is Canada's greatest industry. Over 23,000,000 acres are under crop and about 20,000,000 under pasture. Over 3,000,000 acres are under wheat cultivation. Ontario exports more than twice as much cheese as the whole of the United States, and her cheese product is recognised as the finest in the world. Canada exports to Great Britain alone $15,000,000 worth of cheese annually. In 1896, in Ontario alone, 170 creameries turned out over 6,000,000 pounds of butter at an average net receipt of 18¼ cents a pound. By the cold-storage facilities provided by the government Canadian butter can be sent even from far inland points to Liverpool or London without the slightest deterioration. England buys $6,000,000 worth of Canadian bacon and hams annually, and Canadian beef is already famous on the London market. American corn for stock-feeding is admitted to Canada free of duty and about $10,000,000 worth is imported annually. A great deal of eastern and southern Canada is well adapted to fruit-raising. The Niagara-St. Clair peninsula of Ontario is especially famous for its peaches and grapes.

Agriculture, which includes livestock farming, dairy production, and fruit growing, is Canada's biggest industry. Over 23 million acres are cultivated, with about 20 million used for pasture. More than 3 million acres are dedicated to wheat farming. Ontario exports more cheese than the entire United States combined, and its cheese is recognized as the best in the world. Canada sells $15 million worth of cheese to Great Britain each year. In 1896, Ontario alone had 170 creameries that produced over 6 million pounds of butter, earning an average of 18¼ cents per pound. Thanks to government-provided cold storage facilities, Canadian butter can be transported from far inland to Liverpool or London without losing quality. England buys $6 million worth of Canadian bacon and hams each year, and Canadian beef is already well-known in the London market. American corn for livestock feed is imported into Canada duty-free, amounting to about $10 million annually. Much of eastern and southern Canada is great for fruit cultivation. The Niagara-St. Clair peninsula in Ontario is especially famous for its peaches and grapes.

CANADA'S TRADE WITH THE UNITED STATES

Canada has made a great effort in the direction of encouraging home manufactures, but her most progressive and most staple industries are those concerned in the conversion of the raw products of the country into articles[192] of common merchandise. Her steam horse-power in proportion to population is the largest in the world. The capital invested in factories as a whole amounts to over $400,000,000, with an annual output of over $500,000,000. Her total annual importation is now over $130,000,000. More than half of this is from the United States. Canada's total annual exportation is about $160,000,000. Of this over one third goes to the United States. Canada's total trade with the United States is about forty one per cent. of her total trade with all countries, and almost equal to her total trade with Great Britain. Canada's total trade with the United States is exceeded only by that of Great Britain, Germany, and France, and her import trade with the United States is exceeded only by that of Great Britain and Germany.

Canada has worked hard to promote domestic manufacturing, but its most advanced and reliable industries focus on turning the country’s raw materials into everyday products[192]. Its steam power per person is the highest in the world. The total investment in factories exceeds $400,000,000, with an annual production surpassing $500,000,000. The country’s total annual imports are now over $130,000,000, with more than half coming from the United States. Canada’s total annual exports are around $160,000,000, with over a third going to the United States. Trade with the U.S. accounts for about forty-one percent of Canada’s total trade with all nations, which is nearly equal to its total trade with Great Britain. The total trade with the United States ranks just behind trade with Great Britain, Germany, and France, and its import trade from the U.S. is only surpassed by that from Great Britain and Germany.

Trade centres of Canada and trunk railway lines. Trade centers in Canada and main railway lines.

CANADIAN CITIES

Montreal (250,000) is the commercial metropolis of Canada. It is situated on an island in the St. Lawrence River, and, though 1000 miles from the open ocean, the largest sea-going vessels reach its wharves with ease. It is the headquarters of Canada's two great railways—the[193] Canadian Pacific system, with its 8000 miles of road, and the Grand Trunk system, with its 5000 miles of road. Through passenger-trains run from Montreal to Vancouver on the Pacific coast, a distance of nearly 3000 miles. Montreal is the centre also of the great inland navigation system of Canada.

Montreal (250,000) is the commercial hub of Canada. It’s located on an island in the St. Lawrence River, and even though it's 1000 miles from the open ocean, the largest sea-going vessels can easily reach its docks. It serves as the headquarters for Canada's two major railways—the[193] Canadian Pacific system, which has 8000 miles of track, and the Grand Trunk system, with 5000 miles of track. Passenger trains travel from Montreal to Vancouver on the Pacific coast, covering nearly 3000 miles. Montreal is also the center of Canada’s extensive inland navigation system.

Toronto (200,000), the capital of the province of Ontario, is the second city of Canada. While Toronto has a great local trade and many important manufactures, it is specially noted as an educational centre. Quebec (80,000) is the oldest city of Canada and one of the oldest upon the continent. Halifax (50,000), the eastern terminus of the Canadian railway system, has one of the finest harbours in the world. Winnipeg (35,000) is destined to be the centre of the great inland trade of Canada.

Toronto (200,000), the capital of Ontario, is Canada’s second-largest city. While Toronto has a strong local economy and many key industries, it’s particularly recognized as an educational hub. Quebec (80,000) is the oldest city in Canada and one of the oldest on the continent. Halifax (50,000), the eastern endpoint of the Canadian railway system, boasts one of the best harbors in the world. Winnipeg (35,000) is set to become the center of Canada’s extensive inland trade.

[194]XIII. THE TRADE FEATURES OF THE UNITED STATES

THE CHARACTER OF OUR EXPORT TRADE

Having reviewed the industrial and trading conditions of the other great commercial nations of the world, it should now remain for us to review these conditions in the United States. But the United States is so large a country, and its trading and industrial interests are so diversified and extensive, that it would be impossible for us in the limits of our space even barely to touch upon all these interests. So that with respect to the "Trade Features of the United States" we shall simply confine ourselves to one part of the subject—namely, the character, extent, and importance of our foreign trade. And we shall, further, have to restrict ourselves in the main to our exports. These will be found to be principally not manufactures, but the products of our great agricultural, mining, and forest industries. The total value of the manufactures of the United States amounts in round numbers to the immense sum of $10,000,000,000 annually, a sum considerably more than a third (it is thirty five per cent.) of the total value of the annual manufactures of the world. But only a very small portion of this vast output is exported.[195] The greater portion of it is used to sustain the still vaster internal trade of our country, a trade which amounts to more than $15,500,000,000 annually, an amount not far short of being one third of the total internal trade of the world, and not far short of being twice the internal trade of Great Britain and Ireland, the country whose internal trade comes next to ours. Our exports, therefore, are not in the main manufactured goods, but breadstuffs, provisions, and raw materials, the production of our farms, our plantations, our forests, and our mines. But principally they are the products of our farms and our plantations, for with the exception of cotton we do not export much raw material. Nearly all the raw material we produce (other than cotton) we use in our own manufactures. And even this is not enough, for in addition we have to import considerable quantities of raw material for our manufactures from other countries, the principal items being raw sugar, raw silk, raw wool, chemicals of various kinds including dye-stuffs, hides and skins, lumber, tin, nickel, and paper stock.

After looking at the industrial and trading conditions of other major commercial nations, it's time to examine these conditions in the United States. However, the U.S. is such a vast country with highly diverse and extensive trading and industrial interests that it's impossible for us to cover everything in the limited space we have. Therefore, when discussing the "Trade Features of the United States," we will focus on one aspect: the nature, scope, and significance of our foreign trade. Additionally, we will mainly concentrate on our exports. These are primarily not manufactured goods, but rather the products from our vast agricultural, mining, and forestry sectors. The total value of U.S. manufacturing is around $10 billion per year, which is over a third (specifically, 35%) of the total value of global manufacturing. However, only a tiny fraction of this massive output is exported. Most of it is used to support our even larger internal trade, which totals more than $15.5 billion annually—close to one third of the total internal trade in the world and almost double that of Great Britain and Ireland, the country with the next largest internal trade. Consequently, our exports mainly consist of food products and raw materials from our farms, plantations, forests, and mines. Specifically, the majority comes from our farms and plantations, since we do not export much raw material other than cotton. Nearly all the raw materials we produce (besides cotton) are used in our own manufacturing. Even this isn't sufficient, as we also need to import significant amounts of raw materials for our manufacturing from other countries, including raw sugar, raw silk, raw wool, various chemicals like dyes, hides and skins, lumber, tin, nickel, and paper stock.[195]

OUR EXPORT TRADE IN DETAIL

Our total exportation for the twelve months ended June 30, 1898, amounted to the unprecedented sum of nearly $1,250,000,000 ($1,231,329,950).[4] This is an amount almost a quarter of a billion dollars greater than ever before, the only years when the export even approximated this amount being 1897 and 1892, when the exportation was slightly over a billion dollars in each case. Of this exportation the sum of $855,000,000, or seventy one per cent. of the whole, was for the products of agriculture, the principal items being (1) "breadstuffs,"[196] including wheat and wheat flour, corn and cornmeal, oats and oatmeal, rye and rye flour, $335,000,000; (2) cotton, $231,000,000; (3) "provisions," including beef and tallow, bacon and hams, pork and lard, oleomargarine, and butter and cheese, $166,000,000; (4) animals, including cattle, horses, sheep, and hogs, $47,000,000; (5) raw tobacco, $23,000,000; (6) oil-cake, $12,500,000, and (7) fruits and nuts, $9,000,000. The exports of the products of our mines amounted to only 1.6 per cent. of the total export, or scarcely $20,000,000, the principal items being (1) coal and coke, $12,500,000; (2) crude petroleum, $4,000,000, and (3) copper ore. The exports of the products of the forest amounted to only three per cent. of the total export, or $38,000,000, the principal items being (1) sawed and hewn timber, logs, lumber, shingles, and staves, $28,500,000, and (2) naval stores, including resin, tar, turpentine, and pitch, $9,000,000. The exports of the products of our fisheries amounted to only $4,500,000, or less than one half of one per cent. of the total exports. The exports of the products of our manufactures, according to the official returns, amounted to $289,000,000, or twenty four per cent. of the total export. But this sum included many items which represent raw natural products converted merely into material for subsequent manufacture, as, for example, pig- and bar-iron, planed boards, sole leather, ingot- and bar-copper, cotton-seed oil, and pig- and bar-zinc. The principal items in the true "manufactures" list are (1) machinery, including metal-working machinery, steam-engines and locomotives, electrical machinery, pumping machinery, sewing-machines, typewriting-machines and printing-presses, and railway rails, hardware, and nails, $65,000,000; (2) refined petroleum, $50,000,000; (3) manufactures of cotton, $17,000,000; (4) vegetable oils and essences, $12,000,000; (5) agricultural implements, $7,000,000; (6) cycles, $7,000,000; (7) paper and[197] stationery, $5,500,000; (8) furniture and other manufactures of wood, $5,000,000; (9) tobacco and cigarettes, $5,000,000; (10) fertilisers, $4,500,000; (11) boots and shoes, harness, and rubber shoes, $3,500,000; (12) telegraph, telephone, and other instruments, $3,000,000; (13) bags, cordage, and twine, $2,500,000; (14) books and pamphlets, $2,500,000; (15) sugar, syrup, molasses, candy, and confectionery, $2,000,000; (16) spirits, including brandy and whisky, $2,000,000; and (17) clocks and watches, $2,000,000.

Our total exports for the twelve months ending June 30, 1898, reached an unprecedented total of nearly $1,250,000,000 ($1,231,329,950).[4] This amount is almost a quarter of a billion dollars more than ever before, with the only other years coming close being 1897 and 1892, when exports were just over a billion dollars in each case. Of this total, $855,000,000, or seventy-one percent, was from farm products, with the main items being (1) "breadstuffs,"[196] which include wheat and wheat flour, corn and cornmeal, oats and oatmeal, rye and rye flour, totaling $335,000,000; (2) cotton, $231,000,000; (3) "provisions," which consist of beef and tallow, bacon and hams, pork and lard, oleomargarine, and butter and cheese, $166,000,000; (4) animals like cattle, horses, sheep, and hogs, $47,000,000; (5) raw tobacco, $23,000,000; (6) oil-cake, $12,500,000; and (7) fruits and nuts, $9,000,000. The mining exports accounted for only 1.6 percent of total exports, barely $20,000,000, with the main items being (1) coal and coke, $12,500,000; (2) crude petroleum, $4,000,000; and (3) copper ore. Exports from forestry made up only three percent of the total, or $38,000,000, with the primary items being (1) sawn and hewn timber, logs, lumber, shingles, and staves, $28,500,000, and (2) naval stores, including resin, tar, turpentine, and pitch, $9,000,000. Fishery products exported amounted to just $4,500,000, or less than half a percent of total exports. The exports from manufacturing, according to official records, reached $289,000,000, or twenty-four percent of the total exports. However, this figure included many items that represent raw natural products minimally processed into material for further manufacturing, such as pig- and bar-iron, planed boards, sole leather, ingot- and bar-copper, cotton-seed oil, and pig- and bar-zinc. The main items in the true "manufacturing" category are (1) machinery, which includes metal-working machinery, steam engines and locomotives, electrical machinery, pumping machinery, sewing machines, typewriters, and printing presses, as well as railway rails, hardware, and nails, totaling $65,000,000; (2) refined petroleum, $50,000,000; (3) cotton products, $17,000,000; (4) vegetable oils and essences, $12,000,000; (5) agricultural machinery, $7,000,000; (6) bicycles, $7,000,000; (7) paper and[197] stationery, $5,500,000; (8) furniture and other wooden products, $5,000,000; (9) tobacco and cigarettes, $5,000,000; (10) fertilizers, $4,500,000; (11) boots and shoes, harnesses, and rubber footwear, $3,500,000; (12) telecommunication equipment and other instruments, $3,000,000; (13) bags, rope, and twine, $2,500,000; (14) books and pamphlets, $2,500,000; (15) sugar, syrup, molasses, candy, and confections, $2,000,000; (16) alcoholic beverages, including brandy and whiskey, $2,000,000; and (17) clocks and watches, $2,000,000.

FOOTNOTE:

[4]For the year ending June 30, 1899, the total exportation amounted to $1,204,123,134.

[4]For the year ending June 30, 1899, the total exports reached $1,204,123,134.

OUR EXPORTS AND THOSE OF GREAT BRITAIN COMPARED

The significance of these figures descriptive of our export trade will be better understood from a few comparisons. Our total exportation for the year 1897-8 was, as said before, in round numbers, $1,250,000,000. For the year previous it was over $1,000,000,000. The exportation of Great Britain for the year 1896 was $1,500,000,000. For the year 1897 it was almost the same amount. For the year 1895 it was $1,450,000,000. But whereas our exportation of breadstuffs, provisions, animals, fruit, etc., and of raw materials, such as cotton, lumber, ores, etc., amounts to probably 77 or 78 per cent. of our total exportation, while our exportation of manufactured goods amounts to not more than 22 or 23 per cent., the exportation of breadstuffs, provisions, raw material, etc., which Great Britain makes is not more than one sixth, or 17 per cent., of her total exportation, while her exportation of manufactured goods is five sixths, or 83 per cent., of her total exportation. For example, Great Britain's export of textiles alone amounts to over $500,000,000 a year (for 1896 $526,647,525), while our total export of textiles, including cottons, woollens, silks, and fibres, is[198] not more than $19,000,000 a year. Great Britain's total export of hardware and machinery amounts to over $250,000,000 a year; our total export of these articles does not amount to more than a third of this sum. On the other hand, Great Britain's total export of raw materials of all sorts is not more than $100,000,000 a year, while ours of cotton alone is almost two and one-third times that sum. And while Great Britain exports no breadstuffs or provisions to speak of, our exportation of these articles (including animals) amounts to the enormous sum of $855,000,000 a year.

The importance of these figures representing our export trade will become clearer through some comparisons. Our total exports for the year 1897-98 were, as mentioned earlier, around $1,250,000,000. The year before, it was over $1,000,000,000. Great Britain's exports for 1896 were $1,500,000,000, and for 1897, it was about the same. In 1895, it was $1,450,000,000. While our export of grains, provisions, livestock, fruits, and raw materials like cotton, lumber, and ores makes up about 77 or 78 percent of our total exports, our export of manufactured goods is only 22 or 23 percent. In contrast, only about one-sixth, or 17 percent, of Great Britain's exports consist of grains, provisions, and raw materials, whereas manufactured goods account for five-sixths, or 83 percent, of their total exports. For instance, Great Britain’s textile exports alone exceed $500,000,000 a year (specifically $526,647,525 in 1896), while our total textile exports, which include cottons, woolens, silks, and fibers, are not more than $19,000,000 a year. Great Britain's total export of hardware and machinery is over $250,000,000 a year, whereas our total export of these items is less than a third of that amount. On the flip side, Great Britain’s total export of all kinds of raw materials doesn't exceed $100,000,000 a year, while our cotton exports alone are almost two and a third times that figure. Furthermore, while Great Britain doesn't export significant amounts of grains or provisions, our exports of these products (including livestock) reach the impressive total of $855,000,000 a year.

OUR IMPORTS AND THOSE OF GREAT BRITAIN COMPARED

Export trade of the United States and Great Britain compared. Comparison of Export Trade Between the United States and Great Britain.

Similar differences with respect to our import trade and that of Great Britain are observable. Our imports do not amount to more than from $600,000,000 to $800,000,000 a year. For the year ended June 30, 1897, they were[199] $765,000,000. For the year ended June 30, 1898, they were $616,000,000. The imports of Great Britain, on the other hand, amount to over $2,000,000,000 a year. For the year 1896 they were $2,210,000,000. For the year 1897 they were $2,225,000,000. But, while our imports, with the exception of coffee, sugar, tea, fruits, and fish, consist chiefly of manufactured articles, such as woollen goods, cotton goods, silk goods, and iron and steel goods, with only moderate amounts of raw material (for example, hides, skins, and furs, $41,000,000; raw silk, $32,000,000; raw wool, $17,000,000), Great Britain, besides importing coffee, sugar, tea, fruits, and fish, the same as we do, and manufactured goods to a far greater amount than we do (not less than $500,000,000 annually), imports likewise an enormous quantity of raw material for her manufactures, all duty free, and a still more enormous quantity of breadstuffs, provisions, etc., also all duty free. For example, for the year 1897 her imports of raw materials for her manufactures were not less than $750,-[200]000,000, while her imports of duty-free food products were not less than $825,000,000. The difference between the two countries, therefore, so far as their foreign trades are concerned is simply this: The United States is an immense exporter of food-stuffs, and also of raw materials for foreign manufacture; but for the raw materials for her own manufacture she depends principally upon her own products. In comparison she is only a moderate exporter of manufactured goods. Great Britain, on the other hand, is an enormous importer and consumer of food-stuffs and also of raw materials for her manufactures. She, in fact, depends very largely upon other countries for her food products and her raw materials, and obtains them wherever she can, very largely from the United States. She is also an enormous exporter of manufactures.

Similar differences in our import trade compared to Great Britain's are noticeable. Our imports are no more than $600 million to $800 million a year. For the year ending June 30, 1897, they were[199] $765 million. For the year ending June 30, 1898, they were $616 million. In contrast, Great Britain's imports exceed $2 billion annually. In 1896, they were $2.21 billion. In 1897, they reached $2.225 billion. While our imports, except for coffee, sugar, tea, fruits, and fish, mainly consist of manufactured goods like woolen items, cotton products, silk articles, and iron and steel, with only moderate amounts of raw materials (for instance, hides, skins, and furs at $41 million; raw silk at $32 million; raw wool at $17 million), Great Britain, besides importing coffee, sugar, tea, fruits, and fish like we do, also imports manufactured goods in much larger quantities (at least $500 million per year), and a vast amount of raw materials for her manufacturing, all duty-free, along with an even larger quantity of food products, also duty-free. For instance, in 1897, her imports of raw materials for manufacturing were at least $750 million,[200] while her duty-free food product imports were not less than $825 million. The key difference between the two countries regarding their foreign trade is this: The United States is a massive exporter of food and raw materials for foreign manufacturing, but relies mainly on its own products for the raw materials needed for its own manufacturing. Compared to this, it only moderately exports manufactured goods. Great Britain, on the other hand, is a huge importer and consumer of food and raw materials for her manufacturing. She largely depends on other countries for her food products and raw materials, obtaining them wherever possible, predominantly from the United States. She is also a significant exporter of manufactured goods.

The United States manufactures and internal trade compared with the manufactures and internal trade of all other countries. The United States' manufacturing and domestic trade are compared to the manufacturing and domestic trade of all other countries.

OUR COTTON PRODUCTION AND COTTON EXPORT

The one article of export that is of greatest importance in our commerce is cotton. The production of cotton in the United States is enormous. It is not far short of 5,000,000,000 pounds per annum. This is probably four times the amount produced upon the whole globe elsewhere. Our export amounts annually to about 4,000,000,000 pounds, with a total value of about $240,000,000. Our greatest competitors in the world's cotton markets are Egypt and India. The export of cotton from Egypt amounts to $50,000,000 annually. The export of cotton from India amounts to $45,000,000 annually. At least one half of our export of cotton goes to Great Britain. Our next greatest customers are (in order) Germany, France, Italy, Spain, and Russia. We send about $7,500,000 worth annually to Japan, and $4,000,000 worth annually to Canada. All our southeastern States produce[201] cotton, but the States that produce it most plentifully are (in order) Texas (about one third of the whole), Georgia, Mississippi, and Alabama. The area under cultivation in the whole country is about 21,000,000 acres, which is about one sixth of the area devoted to corn, wheat, and oats, or one half the area devoted to hay. The areas of greatest cotton production are (1) the "Yazoo bottom," a strip on the left bank of the Mississippi extending from Memphis to Vicksburg, and (2) the upper part of the right bank of the Tombigbee. The productivity of cotton is much higher in the United States than it is in India, averaging not far short of 200 pounds per acre, as against less than 100 pounds in India. In India, however, the cotton crop has been grown on the same soil for ages, whereas in the United States the practice is to substitute new soils for old ones as soon as crops begin to fail. On the other hand, the United States cotton crop is much less per acre than the crop in Egypt. There the yield per acre is from 300 pounds to 500 pounds. The remedy for this defect of productivity in our cotton crop as compared with that of Egypt is manuring. Where the manuring is properly attended to our cotton crop is comparable with Egypt's. But the cotton of Egypt is of better quality than the great mass of the cotton crop of the United States (the "upland" cotton crop). On the other hand in the low, flat islands off the coast of Georgia and South Carolina a species of cotton grows ("sea-island" cotton) which is the finest in the world, its fibres being the longest, finest, and straightest, of all cotton fibres produced anywhere, and the most beautiful in appearance in the mass. Of this "sea-island" cotton about three to four million dollars' worth is exported annually at a price averaging from two and one fourth to two and three fourth times the value per pound of the "upland" cotton. The great cotton ports of our country are (in order of[202] amount of exportation) New Orleans, Galveston, Savannah, New York, Charleston, Mobile, and Wilmington. New Orleans' export is about a third of the whole, and Galveston's about a fifth.

The most important export in our trade is cotton. The United States produces a huge amount of cotton, almost 5,000,000,000 pounds each year. This is likely four times what the rest of the world produces combined. We export around 4,000,000,000 pounds annually, worth about $240,000,000. Our biggest competitors in the global cotton market are Egypt and India. Egypt's cotton exports total about $50,000,000 each year, while India exports about $45,000,000. At least half of our cotton exports go to Great Britain. Our next biggest customers are (in order) Germany, France, Italy, Spain, and Russia. We send around $7,500,000 worth of cotton yearly to Japan and $4,000,000 to Canada. All our southeastern states grow[201] cotton, but the states that produce it the most are (in order) Texas (which accounts for about one third of the total), Georgia, Mississippi, and Alabama. The total area cultivated in the country is about 21,000,000 acres, which is about one sixth of the land used for corn, wheat, and oats, or half the area used for hay. The top areas for cotton production are (1) the "Yazoo bottom," a strip along the left bank of the Mississippi from Memphis to Vicksburg, and (2) the upper part of the right bank of the Tombigbee. The yield per acre in the U.S. is significantly higher than in India, averaging close to 200 pounds compared to under 100 pounds in India. However, in India, the cotton has been grown on the same land for ages, while in the U.S., farmers switch to new soils as soon as the old ones start to lose productivity. On the flip side, the cotton yield in the U.S. is lower than in Egypt, where the yield ranges from 300 pounds to 500 pounds per acre. The solution to our lower productivity, compared to Egypt's, is proper manuring. When done correctly, the U.S. cotton yield can match Egypt's. Nevertheless, Egyptian cotton is of better quality than the majority of U.S. cotton (the "upland" cotton). Conversely, in the low, flat islands off the coast of Georgia and South Carolina, a type of cotton known as "sea-island" cotton grows, which is the finest in the world, with the longest, finest, and straightest fibers, and it looks beautiful in bulk. About three to four million dollars' worth of "sea-island" cotton is exported each year at prices that are two and a fourth to two and three fourths times the value per pound of "upland" cotton. The major cotton ports in our country, ranked by export volume, are NOLA, Galveston, TX, Savannah, NYC, Charleston, Mobile, and Wilmington. New Orleans accounts for about a third of total exports, and Galveston about a fifth.

OUR PRODUCTION AND EXPORT OF BREADSTUFFS

The item in the official returns that figures largest for exports is that which is set down as breadstuffs. This term includes wheat, corn, oats, rye, and other grains, and the flours or meals made from these. For the year ending June 30, 1898, our total export of breadstuffs was $334,000,000. This is an enormous increase over the year before, when the amount was not quite $200,000,000.[5] A large part of this increase was due to the high prices for breadstuffs which prevailed in the European markets during the past autumn and winter, but a part of the increase was due to an increased acreage and to good crops. The main products that composed this vast exportation were: wheat, $146,000,000; wheat flour, $70,000,000; corn, $75,000,000; cornmeal, $2,000,000; oats and oatmeal, $22,500,000; rye and rye flour, $9,000,000, and barley, $5,500,000. The magnitude of our breadstuffs exportation can be judged from the magnitude and importance of our exports of wheat and flour as compared with those of other countries. Our average wheat export is two and one half times that of Russia, four and one third times that of Argentina, five and one half times that of India, and almost twenty-five times that of Canada, while it is also four and one half times that of all other countries in the world combined. Our flour export ($70,000,000) is without a rival. The export from Canada is now not much more than $1,500,000 a year, and the export from Hungary not more than $2,500,000 a year,[203] and these are the only countries with which we have to compete in the western European markets. Still it must be remembered that Hungarian flour, owing to the dryness of the climate in which it is made, is the best in the world, while the flour of Canada made from Manitoba hard wheat is alike unsurpassed. As a rule much more than one half of our total exports of breadstuffs goes to Great Britain. Germany is our next best customer, but her imports of our breadstuffs are not more that a fifth to a tenth of those of Great Britain. France comes next, but her importation of our breadstuffs is still more uncertain, ranging from a half to a hundredth of that of Great Britain. Our other principal customers for our breadstuffs are (1) the other states of Europe, (2) Canada, (3) the countries of South America, (4) the West Indies, (5) Hongkong, (6) the islands of the Pacific, and (7) British Africa. Our exportation of breadstuffs to Japan and China (direct)[6] is still inconsiderable. Since the close of the War of the Rebellion our exportation of wheat has increased thirtyfold and our exportation of flour fifteenfold. Our chief wheat-growing States are Minnesota and California, each with about 50,000,000 bushels a year; then Kansas, North Dakota, Illinois, and South Dakota, each with about 30,000,000 bushels a year; and then Ohio, Indiana, Nebraska, Pennsylvania, Missouri, and Michigan. The best wheat is grown in the deep black soil, rich in organic matter, of the Red River valley of Minnesota, and in the dry, sunny climate of California. The total yield for 1897 was 530,000,000 bushels, which was about 70,000,000 bushels more than recent averages. The estimate for this year (1898) is over 600,000,000 bushels, which was also the yield for 1891. The total area sown to wheat was for several years about 35,000,000 acres, but[204] the average is now increased to about 40,000,000 acres. Large as is the gross production of our wheat, however, the yield per acre is somewhat small, being only from 12 to 13 bushels as against 18 bushels in Ontario, 20 in Manitoba, 26½ in New Zealand, and 30 in Great Britain. In fact, the wheat yield per acre is lowest in the United States of all the great wheat-producing countries of the world, except Australia (7 to 11½), Italy (10½), Germany (10¼), India (9¼), and Russia (8). But far greater than our production of wheat is our production of corn. Of corn we have nearly 85,000,000 acres under cultivation and a production of nearly 2,500,000,000 bushels. Our export of corn, however, is proportionately not large, and figures only to about 210,000,000 bushels a year, with a value (including cornmeal) of about $76,000,000. As is well known, Chicago is the great commercial centre of the continent for breadstuffs. New York is the great port of export for the Atlantic seaboard, San Francisco for the Pacific seaboard. Duluth is the great receiving point for the wheat of the Red River valley and the northern Mississippi. Buffalo is the great point where the wheat brought down from Chicago, Duluth, etc., in barges, "whale-backs," and immense propellers, is trans-shipped to the small boats of the Erie Canal for carriage to New York. Minneapolis is the great milling point of the continent, its mills being the largest and most capacious in the world.

The main item listed in the official reports for exports is what’s categorized as bread products. This term covers wheat, corn, oats, rye, and other grains, along with the flours or meals made from them. For the year ending June 30, 1898, our total export of breadstuffs was $334,000,000. This marks a huge increase from the previous year when the amount was just below $200,000,000.[5] A large part of this increase resulted from the high prices for breadstuffs in European markets during the past autumn and winter, but part of the increase also came from more acreage and good crop yields. The main products that made up this vast export were: wheat, $146,000,000; wheat flour, $70,000,000; corn, $75,000,000; cornmeal, $2,000,000; oats and oatmeal, $22,500,000; rye and rye flour, $9,000,000; and barley, $5,500,000. The scale of our breadstuffs exports can be appreciated when compared to those of other countries. Our average wheat exports is two and a half times larger than Russia's, four and a third times larger than Argentina's, five and a half times more than India's, and almost twenty-five times that of Canada. Additionally, it is four and a half times larger than the combined exports of all other countries globally. Our flour shipment ($70,000,000) has no rival. Canada's export is now just over $1,500,000 annually, and Hungary’s is about $2,500,000 each year,[203] making these the only countries we compete with in western European markets. However, it should be noted that Hungarian flour, due to its dry climate, is considered the best in the world, while Canadian flour made from Manitoba hard wheat is also exceptional. Generally, more than half of our total breadstuffs exports go to Great Britain. Germany is our next best customer, but her imports of our breadstuffs are only about a fifth to a tenth of those of Great Britain. France comes next, but her imports of our breadstuffs are even more unpredictable, varying from half to one-hundredth of Great Britain's imports. Our other main customers for breadstuffs include (1) other European countries, (2) Canada, (3) South American countries, (4) the West Indies, (5) Hong Kong, (6) Pacific islands, and (7) British Africa. Our direct exports of breadstuffs to Japan and China[6] are still quite small. Since the end of the Civil War, our wheat exports have increased thirtyfold, and flour exports have increased fifteenfold. Our top wheat-producing states are Minnesota and California, each with about 50,000,000 bushels per year, followed by Kansas, North Dakota, Illinois, and South Dakota, which produce around 30,000,000 bushels each year, and then Ohio, Indiana, Nebraska, Pennsylvania, Missouri, and Michigan. The best wheat comes from the rich, black soil of the Red River valley in Minnesota and the dry, sunny climate of California. The total yield for 1897 was 530,000,000 bushels, about 70,000,000 more than recent averages. The estimate for this year (1898) is over 600,000,000 bushels, which matches the yield for 1891. The area sown to wheat has been around 35,000,000 acres for several years, but[204] the average has now risen to about 40,000,000 acres. Although our wheat production is large, the yield per acre is relatively low, at only 12 to 13 bushels compared to 18 bushels in Ontario, 20 in Manitoba, 26½ in New Zealand, and 30 in Great Britain. In fact, the yield per acre is the lowest in the United States among major wheat-producing countries, except for Australia (7 to 11½), Italy (10½), Germany (10¼), India (9¼), and Russia (8). However, our production of corn far exceeds that of wheat. We cultivate nearly 85,000,000 acres of corn, producing nearly 2,500,000,000 bushels. Our corn exports, though, are not large in proportion, totaling about 210,000,000 bushels per year, with a value (including cornmeal) of around $76,000,000. As is well known, Chicago is the primary commercial center for breadstuffs on the continent. NYC serves as the main export port for the Atlantic coast, while SF serves the Pacific coast. Duluth acts as the primary receiving hub for wheat from the Red River valley and the northern Mississippi. Buffalo (the animal/city context not specified) is a key point where wheat transported from Chicago, Duluth, etc., via barges, "whale-backs," and large propeller boats is transferred to smaller boats for transport through the Erie Canal to New York. Minneapolis is the leading milling hub in the continent, boasting the largest and most capacity-efficient mills in the world.

FOOTNOTES:

[5]For the year ending June 30, 1899, the amount was $274,000,000.

[5]For the year ending June 30, 1899, the total was $274,000,000.

[6]A portion of the exportation of breadstuffs made to Hongkong is no doubt intended for consumption in China and Japan.

[6]Some of the exported grain to Hong Kong is definitely meant for people in China and Japan.

[205]OUR EXPORT OF PROVISIONS AND ANIMALS

Principal articles of domestic exports of the United States. Main items of exports from the United States.[7]

FOOTNOTE:

[7]For the year ended June 30, 1898.

[7]For the year ended June 30, 1898.

The next most important item in our list of exports is provisions. But, like "breadstuffs," "provisions" also is a composite term, including two main divisions, "meat products" and "dairy products." Practically there are three main divisions, "beef products," "hog products," and "dairy products." We have in these great products of our country an export trade of $165,500,000 per annum, and if we add "animals," a similar item, we have $46,500,000 more, or a total of $212,000,000 per annum. Our export of fresh beef is nearly 300,000,000 pounds a year. Almost the[206] whole of this goes to Great Britain. Our export of canned beef runs from 40,000,000 to 60,000,000 pounds a year. About three fifths of this goes to Great Britain, the remainder going principally to Germany and other parts of Europe and to British Africa. We have about 50,000,000 cattle upon our farms and ranches, and our production of beef is estimated to be the enormous amount of 5,400,000,000 pounds a year, which is between a third and a fourth of the total quantity produced throughout the world. Of course the greater portion of this is retained for our own home consumption, for we eat more meat per inhabitant than any other people in the world except the English. In addition to our beef we export about 400,000 cattle annually, more than seven eighths of which are taken by Great Britain, our other principal customers being the West Indies and Canada. The principal export, however, among our "provisions" is our hog products. We export annually of these products 100,000,000 pounds of pork, 850,000,000 pounds of bacon and hams, and 700,000,000 pounds of lard, with a value greater than $110,000,000. As with our beef products, so with our hog products—by far the greatest share goes to Great Britain. Great Britain, however, does not import largely of our pork or of our lard. And though she purchases from us over four fifths of our total export of bacon and hams, she does not pay for them so much as she does for the bacon and hams of Ireland, Denmark, and Canada. The reason for this is that as a rule our corn-fed bacon and hams are too fat—a fault that could be easily remedied. After Great Britain our next best customers for our hog products are Germany (principally in lard), the Netherlands, Sweden, and the West Indies (the latter principally in pork). We keep on our farms from 40,000,000 to 50,000,000 hogs, and our production reaches nearly to 4,600,000,000 pounds of pork, bacon, hams, lard, etc., per annum. A great draw[207]back to our swine-raising industry is the terrible swine plague which so frequently devastates our swine herds. Were this plague stamped out by thorough preventive measures our swine industry would soon become very much larger and more profitable. The third principal item in our provisions export trade is "dairy produce." Our export of butter now amounts to 30,000,000 pounds a year. Our cheese export, once much greater, is now about 50,000,000 pounds a year. As in our beef products and in our hog products so again in our dairy products Great Britain is our chief customer. But our butter export to Great Britain is only one twelfth of her total importation of butter, and our cheese export to Great Britain is only about one eighth of her total importation of cheese. Our cheese has lost its hold on the English market because of its relative deterioration of quality, and its export is not more than a half or a third of what it once was. Much of our butter also is not suited to the English taste. But both our cheese and our butter are now improving in quality. Our great competitor in the cheese export trade is Canada. Canada's export of cheese to Great Britain is $15,000,000 annually, while ours is only a fifth of that amount. Our great competitor in butter is Denmark. Denmark's export of butter to Great Britain is $32,000,000 while ours is not more than a fourteenth of that sum. Our competitors in the markets of Britain for cattle are Canada and Argentina, but their exports together, however, are less than a third of ours. Our competitors in the British markets for the sale of meats are principally the Australasian colonies and Argentina, but their principal exportation so far is chilled mutton, which they send to Britain to the amount of many million dollars annually (Argentina alone $5,000,000 a year, New Zealand alone $10,000,000 a year), while our exportation of mutton is practically nil. We do, however, export $1,000,000[208] worth of sheep a year, but in this item we are frequently far exceeded by Canada. Chicago is, of course, the great commercial centre of the continent for "provisions" and "live stock," and New York the great shipping port. Of the entire export trade of the whole country New York does two fifths. Baltimore comes next with about one ninth. Then (in order) come Philadelphia, Boston, and New Orleans. The chief centres of our great provision and live-stock trade, other than Chicago, are Cincinnati, Kansas City, Indianapolis, Buffalo, and Omaha.

The next important item on our list of exports is supplies. But, like "breadstuffs," "provisions" is also a broad term that includes two main categories: "meat products" and "dairy products." Practically, there are three main categories: "beef products," "pork products," and "dairy products." In these major products of our country, we have an export trade worth $165,500,000 per year, and if we include "animals," another related item, we add $46,500,000 more, totaling $212,000,000 per year. Our export of fresh beef is nearly 300,000,000 pounds annually, and almost the[206] entire amount goes to Great Britain. We export between 40,000,000 and 60,000,000 pounds of canned beef each year, with about three-fifths of that going to Great Britain, and the rest going mainly to Germany and other parts of Europe and British Africa. We have around 50,000,000 cattle on our farms and ranches, and our beef production is estimated at an impressive 5,400,000,000 pounds annually, which is between a third and a fourth of the total quantity produced worldwide. Most of this is kept for our own consumption since we eat more meat per person than almost any other nation, except the English. In addition to our beef, we also export about 400,000 cattle each year, more than seven-eighths of which go to Great Britain, with our other main customers being the West Indies and Canada. However, the top export among our "provisions" is our pork products. Annually, we export 100,000,000 pounds of pork, 850,000,000 pounds of bacon and hams, and 700,000,000 pounds of lard, with a combined value of over $110,000,000. Just like our beef products, the majority of our hog products go to Great Britain. However, Great Britain does not import as much of our pork or lard. While they buy over four-fifths of our total bacon and ham exports, they don't pay as much for them compared to bacon and hams from Ireland, Denmark, and Canada. This is because, generally speaking, our corn-fed bacon and hams are too fatty, a flaw that could be easily corrected. After Great Britain, our next best customers for hog products are Germany (mainly for lard), the Netherlands, Sweden, and the West Indies (mostly for pork). We raise between 40,000,000 to 50,000,000 hogs on our farms, producing nearly 4,600,000,000 pounds of pork, bacon, hams, lard, etc., each year. A major drawback to our swine-raising industry is the severe swine plague that frequently devastates our herds. If this plague were eliminated through effective preventive measures, our swine industry could quickly expand and become much more profitable. The third main category in our provisions export trade is "dairy produce." Currently, our butter exports amount to 30,000,000 pounds a year. Our cheese exports, once much greater, are now around 50,000,000 pounds annually. As with our beef and hog products, Great Britain remains our primary customer for dairy products. However, our butter exports to Great Britain account for only one-twelfth of their total butter imports, while our cheese exports make up about one-eighth of their total cheese imports. Our cheese has lost its appeal in the English market due to a drop in quality, with exports now at only half to a third of what they used to be. Much of our butter also does not meet English taste preferences. Nonetheless, both our cheese and butter are improving in quality. Canada is our main competitor in the cheese export market, exporting $15,000,000 worth of cheese to Great Britain annually, while we export only a fifth of that amount. Denmark is our foremost competitor in butter, exporting $32,000,000 worth to Great Britain, whereas we export only about a fourteenth of that total. Our competitors for cattle in the British market include Canada and Argentina, but their combined exports are less than a third of ours. The main competitors in the British meat market are primarily the Australasian colonies and Argentina, but their primary exports so far are chilled mutton, which they sell to Britain for several million dollars each year (with Argentina exporting $5,000,000 and New Zealand exporting $10,000,000 annually), while our mutton exports are practically negligible. We do export sheep worth $1,000,000[208] each year, but Canada often surpasses us in this area. Chicago is, of course, the main commercial hub of the continent for "provisions" and "live stock," while NYC is the leading shipping port. New York handles two-fifths of the nation's total export trade. Baltimore follows with about one-ninth. Next in line are Philly, Boston, and NOLA. Other than Chicago, the major centers of our extensive provision and live-stock trade are Cincy, Kansas City, Indy, Buffalo, and Omaha.

OUR FOREIGN CARRYING TRADE

One aspect of our foreign trade is not so well understood as it ought to be. Our foreign commerce is carried on largely in foreign ships. The reason is that no vessel is allowed to be registered as belonging to a United States owner unless she is built in the United States, and it therefore seems as if our ship-builders could not compete (in price) in the building of steel and iron ships with those of Great Britain and Germany. Formerly, when wooden ships were used, our foreign trade was carried on in our own vessels, and our "clipper" sailing vessels beat the world. In 1859 seventy per cent. in value of our foreign trade was carried in American vessels. Since that date the proportion has decreased steadily until in 1896-97 it was only eleven per cent., and for 1897-98 it was even less than this. During the five years 1881-85 it averaged barely twenty per cent. Taking into consideration tonnage only the proportion at present varies from twenty five to thirty per cent., showing that the American vessels are used for carrying the cheaper sorts of goods. The aggregate tonnage burden of vessels belonging to the United States registered as engaged in the foreign trade 1896 was for 792,870 tons. For the same year the aggre[209]gate tonnage burden of vessels belonging to Great Britain engaged in the foreign trade was considerably more than ten times that amount. Of our export trade to Europe United States vessels carry only five and one half per cent., and of our export trade to Africa only four and one half per cent. But of our export trade to Asia and Oceanica our own vessels carry twenty six and one half per cent., while of our export trade to other countries on the American continent our own vessels carry nearly forty per cent. But as our Atlantic trade is seventy six per cent. of the whole, and as our trade elsewhere than on the Atlantic is more than one third carried by sailing-vessels, it is evident how largely our steamship ocean carrying trade has been allowed to fall into the hands of foreigners. Seven tenths of our total export trade, and nearly two thirds of our total foreign trade, both export and import, are carried in British vessels. The next greatest carriers of our foreign trade are, first, the Germans, then ourselves, then the Norwegians, then the Dutch, then the French, then the Belgians.

One aspect of our foreign trade is not as well understood as it should be. A significant portion of our foreign commerce is conducted using foreign ships. The reason for this is that no vessel can be registered as owned by a United States owner unless it is built in the United States. This means our shipbuilders struggle to compete (in price) with those in Great Britain and Germany when it comes to building steel and iron ships. In the past, when wooden ships were the norm, we conducted our foreign trade using our own vessels, and our "clipper" sailing ships were the best in the world. In 1859, seventy percent of the value of our foreign trade was carried in American vessels. Since then, this proportion has steadily decreased, dropping to only eleven percent in 1896-97, and even lower for 1897-98. During the five years from 1881 to 1885, the average was barely twenty percent. If we consider tonnage alone, the proportion now varies from twenty-five to thirty percent, indicating that American vessels are mainly used for transporting cheaper goods. In 1896, the total tonnage of vessels registered in the United States engaged in foreign trade was 792,870 tons. In that same year, the total tonnage of vessels from Great Britain involved in foreign trade was more than ten times that amount. For our export trade to Europe, United States vessels only carry five and a half percent, and for Africa, it’s just four and a half percent. However, for our export trade to Asia and Oceania, our vessels carry twenty-six and a half percent, and for other countries in the Americas, nearly forty percent. Given that our Atlantic trade accounts for seventy-six percent of the total, and that more than one-third of trade outside the Atlantic is handled by sailing vessels, it’s clear how much of our steamship ocean trade has ended up in foreign hands. Seven-tenths of our total export trade and nearly two-thirds of our total foreign trade, both exports and imports, are carried by British vessels. The next largest carriers of our foreign trade are, in order, the Germans, then ourselves, followed by the Norwegians, the Dutch, the French, and then the Belgians.

[210]EXAMINATION PAPERS

Note.The following questions are given for the purpose of indicating to the student the sort of knowledge he ought to be possessed of after he has made a careful study of the papers of the course. The student is recommended to write out carefully the answers to the questions asked. Only such answers need be attempted as can be made from a careful study of the papers.

Note.The following questions are provided to help you understand the kind of knowledge you should have after thoroughly studying the course materials. You are encouraged to write out your answers to these questions carefully. Only answer the questions that can be addressed based on a detailed study of the materials.

PART I

  1. UK. Give as full an account as you can of the causes which have made London the great commercial centre of the world.
  2. UK. England is said to be "a beehive of mercantile and manufacturing industry." Give reasons for this statement and also show how England has become such.
  3. UK. (a) Describe the foreign trade of Great Britain. (b) Describe the steps taken by Liverpool, Manchester, and Glasgow to improve their natural facilities for external trade.
  4. France. (a) Describe the conditions which (1) conduce toward, and (2) militate against, France's being a[211] great commercial nation. (b) Give an account of the distinctive manufactures of France.
  5. Germany. (a) Give an account of what Germany has accomplished in technical education. (b) Compare Germany and France as commercial nations. (c) Give a brief account of Germany's foreign trade.
  6. Spain and Italy. (a) Why are Spain, Italy, and Turkey sometimes called "the three decadent nations of Europe"? (b) Give some account of Spain's foreign trade. (c) Give an account of the conditions that militate against Italy's prosperity as a trading nation.
  7. Russia. (a) Describe the social condition of the Russian people. (b) What are the "artels" of Russia? (c) Describe Russia's export trade.
  8. India. (a) Describe the present condition of the manufactures of India. (b) Give a brief account of India's trade—(1) external, (2) internal.
  9. China. (a) Give an account of China's size, population, and trade resources. (b) Give an account of China's present foreign trade. (c) Give an account of the trade possibilities of China, and show in what manner an increase of the foreign trade of China is most likely first to occur.
  10. Japan. (a) Describe the transformation which in recent times has been witnessed in the Japanese nation. (b) Describe Japan's manufactures. (c) Show in what respects an increase in the foreign trade of Japan is presently possible.

PART II

  1. Africa. (a) Describe the "partition of Africa." (b) Describe more particularly Great Britain's possessions in Africa. (c) Describe South Africa's mineral wealth.
  2. Australia. (a) Describe Australia's "peculiarities."[212] (b)  Enumerate the political divisions of Australia, and for each describe briefly (1) its climate, (2) its resources and trade.
  3. South America. (a) Describe the social and political condition of the various peoples of South America. (b) Describe the agricultural resources and export trade of Argentina. (c) Describe (1) the resources, and (2) the export and import trade, of Brazil.
  4. Canada. (a) Describe Canada's resources (1) in forest wealth, (2) in minerals, (3) in fisheries. (b) Describe Canada's agricultural trade. (c) Describe Canada's trade with the United States.
  5. The U.S. (a) Describe the export trade of the United States. (b) Compare our export trade with that of Great Britain. (c) Compare our import trade with that of Great Britain.
  6. USA. (a) Describe our cotton production and our cotton export trade. (b) Describe briefly our export trade in "breadstuffs." (c) Describe briefly our export trade in "provisions" and "animals."

[215]FINANCE, TRADE, AND TRANSPORTATION[8]

I. NATIONAL AND STATE BANKS

ORIGIN OF BANKING INSTITUTIONS

The Bank of England, showing the Threadneedle Street entrance. The Bank of England, featuring the entrance on Threadneedle Street.

The world has had its bankers and money-changers for thousands of years. Babylonian tablets have been found which record banking transactions which took place in the reign of Nebuchadnezzar. Modern banking institutions, however, had their origin in the twelfth century. The first institution of this character in Europe was the Bank of Venice, founded a. d. 1171. It was based upon a forced loan of the republic. Funds deposited in it could not be withdrawn, but were transferable on the books at the pleasure of the owners. The Bank of Genoa was[216] founded in 1407, and for many years was one of the principal banks of Europe. It was the first to issue circulating notes; these were negotiable only by indorsement—that is to say, they were not made payable to bearer. This was a long step in advance of the earlier system of deposit transfers which was also employed by this bank. The Bank of Amsterdam, established in 1607, was the earliest considerable institution of the kind which looked to the promotion of commerce. The Bank of Hamburg, established in 1619, was a bank of deposit and circulation based upon fine silver bars. The deposits were confined to silver. The Bank of England is more than 200 years old and is to-day acknowledged to be the greatest financial institution in the world. Nearly all the paper money of England is issued by this bank. This currency is[217] based partly upon securities and partly upon deposits of coin. There are three or four banks in the United States more than one hundred years old. In 1781 Robert Morris, then superintendent of finance, submitted to Congress a plan for the establishment of the Bank of North America at Philadelphia. In 1784 the State of Massachusetts incorporated the Massachusetts Bank. The Bank of New York was chartered in 1791.

The world has had bankers and money-changers for thousands of years. Babylonian tablets have been found that document banking transactions from the reign of Nebuchadnezzar. However, modern banking institutions originated in the twelfth century. The first of these in Europe was the Bank of Venice, founded a. d. 1171. It was based on a mandatory loan from the republic. Funds deposited there couldn’t be withdrawn but could be transferred in the books at the owners' discretion. The Bank of Genoa was[216] founded in 1407 and for many years was one of the major banks in Europe. It was the first to issue circulating notes, which were negotiable only by endorsement—that is, they were not payable to the bearer. This was a significant advancement over the earlier system of deposit transfers used by this bank. The Bank of Amsterdam, established in 1607, was the first substantial institution focused on promoting commerce. The Bank of Hamburg, set up in 1619, was a bank for deposits and circulation based on fine silver bars, with deposits limited to silver. The Bank of England is over 200 years old and today is recognized as the largest financial institution in the world. Almost all the paper money in England is issued by this bank. This currency is[217] based partially on securities and partially on coin deposits. There are three or four banks in the United States that are over one hundred years old. In 1781, Robert Morris, then superintendent of finance, presented a plan to Congress for the establishment of the Bank of North America in Philadelphia. In 1784, the State of Massachusetts incorporated the Massachusetts Bank. The Bank of New York was chartered in 1791.

FOOTNOTE:

[8]SUGGESTIONS AS TO METHOD OF STUDY

__A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__STUDY METHOD SUGGESTIONS

1. Read the lessons as printed very carefully. The aim will be to give fundamental knowledge as to the organisation and conduct of modern business.

1. Read the lessons as printed very carefully. The goal is to provide a fundamental understanding of how modern business is organized and run.

2. Books will not be necessary. The student, however, who wishes to make a more thorough study of the national banking system will find excellent chapters on the subject in "Carroll's Principles and Practice of Finance" (New York: Putnams) and "White's Money and Banking" (Boston: Ginn & Co.).

2. Books won't be necessary. However, the student who wants to dive deeper into the national banking system will find great chapters on the topic in "Carroll's Principles and Practice of Finance" (New York: Putnams) and "White's Money and Banking" (Boston: Ginn & Co.).

3. Take up the papers of the course paragraph by paragraph and ask yourself the reason why each is introduced. Discuss with your friends the advantages or disadvantages of particular requirements.

3. Go through the course materials section by section and ask yourself why each part is included. Talk with your friends about the pros and cons of specific requirements.

OUR NATIONAL BANKING SYSTEM

The national banking system of the United States was established by an act of Congress in 1863, revised in 1864, and amended by later legislation. The great advantage of the system, it is said, is the feature of uniformity, the fact that it brings the banking business of the whole United States under one authority and under the supervision of one set of administrative officers. The note-issuing department is subordinate in its public usefulness to the facilities afforded by banks and clearing-houses for the interchange of credits. The essential features of national banks are briefly set forth as follows:

The national banking system of the United States was created by an act of Congress in 1863, updated in 1864, and changed by subsequent legislation. The main benefit of the system is its uniformity, meaning it brings the banking operations across the entire United States under one authority and overseen by a single group of administrative officers. The note-issuing department is less important for public use than the services provided by banks and clearinghouses for exchanging credits. The key characteristics of national banks are summarized as follows:

  1. There is a bureau of the Treasury Department having charge of all matters relating to national banks, the chief officer of which is the comptroller of the currency.
  2. Any number of persons, not less than five, may form an association for banking purposes, to continue not more than twenty years, but renewable for twenty years with the approval of the comptroller.
  3. The powers of the bank are limited to the discounting of promissory notes, drafts, bills of exchange, and other evidences of debt; receiving deposits, dealing in exchange, coin, and bullion, loaning money on personal security, and issuing circulating notes. It cannot hold[218] real estate except such as may be necessary for the transaction of its business, or such as may have been taken as security for debts previously contracted in good faith.
  4. There can be no national banks anywhere of less capital than $50,000, and these small ones are restricted to places of not more than 6000 inhabitants. In cities of more than 6000 and less than 50,000 inhabitants there can be no bank of less than $100,000 capital, and in cities of 50,000 inhabitants or more none of less than $200,000. One half of the capital must be paid in before the bank can begin business and the remainder must be paid in monthly instalments of at least ten per cent. each.
  5. Shareholders are liable for the debts of the bank to an amount equal to the par value of their shares in addition to the amount invested therein.
  6. Each bank having a capital exceeding $150,000 must deposit in the treasury of the United States registered interest-bearing bonds to an amount not less than $50,000. Those having a capital of $150,000 or less must deposit bonds equal to one fourth of their capital stock. Each bank may issue circulating notes to the amount of ninety per cent. of the market value of the bonds deposited by it, but not exceeding ninety per cent. of the par value of the same, and not exceeding ninety per cent. of the paid-in capital of the bank; but no bank is compelled to issue circulating notes. No bank-notes shall be issued smaller than $5. The notes are receivable at par for all dues to the United States except duties on imports, and are payable for all debts owing by the United States within the United States except interest on the public debt and in redemption of the national currency.
  7. Every bank in certain designated cities, called reserve cities, must keep a reserve of lawful money equal to twenty five per cent. of its deposits. All other banks must keep a like reserve of fifteen per cent., but three fifths of the[219] said fifteen per cent. may consist of balances on deposit in banks approved by the comptroller in the reserve cities.
  8. Each bank must keep on deposit in the treasury of the United States lawful money equal to five per cent. of its circulation as a fund for redeeming the same. This five per cent. may be counted as part of its lawful reserve. This does not relieve banks from the duty of redeeming their notes at their own counters on demand.
  9. One tenth of the net profits must be carried to the surplus fund until it is equal to twenty per cent. of the capital.
  10. A bank must not lend more than one tenth of its capital to one person, corporation or firm, directly or indirectly, nor lend money on the security of its own shares, nor be the purchaser or holder of its own shares unless taken as security for a debt previously contracted in good faith, and if so taken they must be sold within six months under penalty of being put in liquidation.
  11. Each bank must make to the comptroller not less than five reports each year, showing its condition at times to be designated by him, and he may call for special reports from any particular bank whenever he chooses to do so.
  12. Each bank must pay to the treasurer of the United States a tax equal to one per cent. per annum on the average amount of its notes in circulation. The shares are liable to taxation by the States in which they are situated at the same rate as other moneyed capital owned by the citizens of such States.
  13. Any gain arising from lost and destroyed notes inures to the benefit of the United States.
  14. The comptroller has the absolute appointment of all receivers and fixes their compensation. All moneys realised from the assets are paid into the treasury to the credit of the comptroller, and all dividends are paid out by him.
  15. [220]Over-certification of cheques is strictly prohibited, rendering officers or clerks liable to imprisonment.
  16. National bank directors are by law individually liable for the full amount of losses resulting from violations of the national banking laws.

STATE BANKS

Upon the establishment of the national banking system the greater number of the banks incorporated under the laws of the several States were organised as national banks. With others, however, the rights of issue did not outweigh some inconveniences of the national system, and as a result there is now an important class of banks, and loan and trust companies, organised under State legislation and carrying on a deposit and loan business. The regulations under which they work are necessarily diverse, and the amount of public supervision over them varies in different states. The State banks in existence when the national banking system was organised were obliged to retire their note circulation, owing to the fact that the government imposed a tax of ten per cent. on their circulation. The object of the tax was to secure the retirement of the State bank-notes to make room for the circulation of the national banks. The internal mechanism of State banks differs but slightly from that of national banks.

When the national banking system was established, most banks formed under state laws became national banks. However, some banks found that the benefits of issuing money didn’t outweigh the drawbacks of the national system. As a result, there is now a significant number of banks, as well as loan and trust companies, organized under state laws that operate deposit and loan businesses. The rules they follow vary widely, and the level of public oversight differs from state to state. State banks that existed when the national banking system was set up had to stop issuing their own notes because the government imposed a 10% tax on their circulation. The purpose of this tax was to eliminate state banknotes and make way for the national banks' circulation. The way state banks operate is quite similar to how national banks function.

[221]II. SAVINGS BANKS AND TRUST COMPANIES

SAVINGS BANKS

Nearly $2,000,000,000 is deposited in the savings banks of the United States. This large sum represents the savings of about 5,000,000 people. The primary idea of a savings bank and of the post-office and other forms of saving institutions in foreign countries is to encourage thrift among the masses of the people.

Nearly $2,000,000,000 is deposited in the savings banks of the United States. This large sum represents the savings of about 5,000,000 people. The main idea of a savings bank, as well as post offices and other types of savings institutions in other countries, is to promote savings habits among the general population.

The older savings banks, especially those in the eastern States, have no capital stock. That is to say, they are mutual in their form of organisation. Their capital is the accumulated deposits of a large number of people. The depositors are the owners. When taxes and other expenses are paid and a proper reserve set aside, the remaining profits go in the form of interest to the depositors. Many of the savings banks in the western States are capitalised as are other financial institutions, and on the Pacific coast they have capital stock or its equivalent in the form of a reserve fund in which the majority of the depositors are not interested otherwise than so far as it affords security for their deposits.

The older savings banks, especially in the eastern states, have no capital stock. In other words, they are set up as mutual organizations. Their capital comes from the accumulated deposits of many people. The depositors are the owners. After paying taxes and other expenses and setting aside an appropriate reserve, the remaining profits are distributed as interest to the depositors. Many of the savings banks in the western states are capitalized like other financial institutions, and on the Pacific coast, they have capital stock or a similar reserve fund, in which most depositors are only interested because it provides security for their deposits.

As these banks are the custodians of the surplus savings of large numbers of people the laws of the several States have hedged them about with many safeguards,[222] not only for the protection of the depositors but of the institutions themselves. It is eminently right and proper that the State, through its bank commissioners or otherwise, should so far supervise the operations of savings banks as to see that they perform their part of their contract with depositors.

As these banks hold the extra savings of many people, the laws of different states have surrounded them with various safeguards,[222] not just for the protection of the depositors but also for the institutions themselves. It's absolutely fair and appropriate for the state, through its bank commissioners or other means, to supervise the operations of savings banks to ensure they fulfill their obligations to depositors.

Safety, at best, is relative only; there is no absolute safety for the twenty-dollar piece a man has in his pocket, whether he is on the street, at his office, or by his own fireside. We are reminded that 'riches take to themselves wings' and that 'thieves break through and steal.' No savings bank can keep money on hand or deposit it or loan it with absolute safety. All is comparative. It is a peculiarity of money that each dollar requires watching; general supervision is insufficient; hence it is that the safety of moneyed institutions depends upon the capacity and honesty of those in control, and not upon adherence to arbitrary rules. No set of rules can be adopted that will bind dishonest men nor that will compensate for want of experience and ability of honest ones.

Safety, at best, is only relative; there’s no absolute safety for the twenty-dollar bill a person has in their pocket, whether they’re on the street, at work, or by their own fireplace. We’re reminded that 'riches take to themselves wings' and that 'thieves break through and steal.' No bank can keep money on hand, deposit it, or lend it with absolute safety. Everything is comparative. It’s a unique feature of money that each dollar needs to be watched; general oversight isn’t enough. That’s why the safety of financial institutions relies on the competence and integrity of those in charge, not just on following strict rules. No set of rules can prevent dishonest people from acting without integrity, nor can they make up for the lack of experience and ability among honest ones.

There is really no conflict between commercial and savings banks. In fact, a large number of the commercial banks of a country allow interest upon average balances and standing deposits in the same manner as savings banks. Primarily the savings bank creates wealth, while the commercial bank handles it; the savings banks are creative, while the commercial banks are administrative. The aim of the savings bank is to gather money and invest it safely and thus bring profit to the depositor; the aim of the commercial bank is to lend money at fixed charges and thus bring profit to the institution. The former opens its doors to savers, the latter to borrowers. One serves by receiving and keeping and the other by lending. The savings bank aims at making men savers as well as producers. It offers the aid of the strong, who can manage well, to the weak and inexperienced. If the 5,000,000 depositors of savings in the[223] United States were to hide away their own savings nearly $2,000,000,000 would be withdrawn from circulation. The savings bank invests its money. Its managers are as a rule intelligent men, competent to make safe investments in solid securities. The best savings banks are conservative and do not encourage speculation.

There’s really no conflict between commercial and savings banks. In fact, many commercial banks in a country offer interest on average balances and deposits just like savings banks do. Essentially, savings banks create wealth while commercial banks manage it; savings banks are about creativity, while commercial banks focus on administration. The goal of a savings bank is to collect money and invest it safely to provide returns to the depositor, while the goal of a commercial bank is to lend money for a fee to generate profit for the institution. One serves savers, while the other serves borrowers. One bank focuses on receiving and holding funds, and the other on lending. The savings bank encourages people to become savers as well as producers. It provides support from those who are financially strong to those who are weaker or less experienced. If the 5,000,000 depositors in savings in the[223] United States were to stash their savings away, almost $2,000,000,000 would be taken out of circulation. The savings bank invests its money. Its managers are typically knowledgeable individuals capable of making secure investments in solid assets. The best savings banks are conservative and do not promote speculation.

The rules and regulations of savings banks differ largely. In some institutions deposits of a dime at a time are accepted; in others a dollar is the limit. Deposits usually begin to draw interest on the first day of each quarter, but they are entitled to it only if they remain until the end of the half-year. Thus money deposited on the 1st of January is entitled to six months' interest on the 1st of July, though it is not entitled to any interest if withdrawn in June. Some few banks allow interest to begin on the 1st of each month. Most savings banks do not permit money to be withdrawn short of thirty days' notice. Students of this course who are interested in securing definite information upon this subject regarding any particular bank should apply to that bank for a set of its rules and regulations for the information of depositors.

The rules and regulations of savings banks vary significantly. In some institutions, you can deposit as little as a dime at a time; in others, the minimum is a dollar. Deposits typically start earning interest on the first day of each quarter, but you only qualify for that interest if you keep the money in for the entire half-year. So, money deposited on January 1st will earn six months' interest by July 1st, but if you withdraw it in June, you won’t earn any interest. A few banks do allow interest to start on the first of each month. Most savings banks require a notice of at least thirty days before you can withdraw any money. Students in this course who want specific information about this topic for a particular bank should reach out to that bank to get a copy of its rules and regulations for depositors.

TRUST COMPANIES

There has grown up in this country a class of financial institutions which take a sort of middle ground between the commercial bank and the savings bank, so far as their service to the public is concerned. These are what are known as trust companies. National banks are prohibited by law from making loans on real estate, and though State banks are not hedged in this way, as a matter of good banking they usually avoid loans of this character. The policy of commercial banks is to make a great many comparatively small loans on short-time paper, while that of the trust company is to make large loans on long-time[224] securities. The deposits of trust companies consist largely of undisturbed sums such as might be set aside by administrators, executors, trustees, committees, societies, or from private estates. They are such as are not likely to fluctuate greatly in amount. From the very nature of their deposits trust companies find it convenient and profitable to make larger loans and at longer periods than do ordinary banks. Trust companies not only receive moneys upon deposit subject to cheque and for savings, and loan money on commercial paper and other securities, as do commercial banks; but they also act as agents, trustees, executors, administrators, assignees, receivers for individual properties, and corporations. They frequently assist as promoters or reorganisers of corporations and in the sale of stocks, bonds, and securities. They act also as agents for the payment of obligations maturing at future dates, such as the premiums on insurance, interest on mortgages and bonds, etc. Trust companies are organised under the laws of the State in which they exist and are usually subject to all the supervision required in the case of State banks.

There has emerged in this country a type of financial institution that stands between commercial banks and savings banks in terms of their public services. These are known as trust companies. National banks are legally restricted from making loans on real estate, and although state banks don't have this limitation, they generally avoid such loans as a good banking practice. Commercial banks typically focus on making a large number of relatively small loans on short-term paper, while trust companies make large loans on long-term securities. The deposits at trust companies mainly come from stable amounts set aside by administrators, executors, trustees, committees, societies, or private estates. These deposits are not likely to vary significantly in amount. Due to the nature of their deposits, trust companies find it both convenient and profitable to make larger loans for longer periods than regular banks. Trust companies not only accept deposits that can be withdrawn through checks and for savings but also loan money on commercial paper and other securities like commercial banks. Additionally, they serve as agents, trustees, executors, administrators, assignees, and receivers for individual properties and corporations. They often help promote or reorganize corporations and assist in the sale of stocks, bonds, and securities. Trust companies also act as agents for paying obligations that come due in the future, such as insurance premiums, interest on mortgages, and bonds. Trust companies are organized under the laws of the state where they operate and are typically subject to the same level of supervision required for state banks.

[225]III. CORPORATIONS AND STOCK COMPANIES[9]

CORPORATIONS

Stock companies are usually referred to as corporations, though all corporations are not stock companies. A corporation is a body consisting usually of several persons empowered by law to act as one individual. There are two principal classes—(1) public corporations and (2) private corporations. Public corporations are not stock companies; private corporations usually are. Public corporations are created for the public interest, such as cities, towns, universities, hospitals, etc.; private corporations, such as railways, banks, manufacturing companies, etc., are created usually for the profit of the members. Corporate bodies whose members at discretion fill by appointment all vacancies occurring in their membership are sometimes called close corporations.

Stock companies are generally known as corporations, but not all corporations are stock companies. A corporation is a group, typically made up of several individuals, legally authorized to act as a single entity. There are two main types: (1) public corporations and (2) private corporations. Public corporations are not stock companies; private corporations usually are. Public corporations are established for the public good, like cities, towns, universities, and hospitals; private corporations, such as railroads, banks, and manufacturing firms, are generally formed for the profit of their members. Corporate entities that allow members to selectively appoint individuals to fill any openings are sometimes referred to as close corporations.

POWER TO BE A CORPORATION IS A FRANCHISE

In the United States the power to be a corporation is a franchise which can only exist through the legislature.[226] There are two distinct methods in which corporations may be called into being: First, by a specific grant of the franchise to the members, and, second, by a general grant which becomes operative in favour of particular persons when they organise for the purpose of availing themselves of its provisions. When the specific grant is made it is called a charter. In the case of private corporations the charter must be accepted by the members, since corporate powers cannot be forced upon them against their will; but the charter is sufficiently accepted by their acting under it. When special charters are not granted individuals may voluntarily associate, and by complying with the provisions of certain State laws may take to themselves corporate powers. In some of the States private corporations are not suffered to be created otherwise than under general laws, and in others public corporations are created in the same way.

In the United States, the ability to operate as a corporation is a privilege that can only exist through legislation.[226] There are two ways in which corporations can be formed: First, through a specific grant of the franchise to its members, and second, through a general grant that becomes effective for certain individuals when they come together to utilize its provisions. When a specific grant is given, it's referred to as a charter. For private corporations, the charter must be accepted by the members, as corporate powers can't be imposed on them against their will; however, the charter is considered accepted when they act under it. When specific charters aren't provided, individuals can voluntarily join together and, by following certain State laws, can gain corporate powers. In some states, private corporations can only be formed under general laws, while in others, public corporations are established in the same way.

FOOTNOTE:

[9]For a preliminary treatment of the subject of this lesson the student is referred to Part I. of this book, entitled "General Business Information," especially Lessons XII. and XV.

[9]For an initial overview of the topic covered in this lesson, the student should look at Part I of this book, called "General Business Information," particularly Lessons XII and XV.

A CORPORATION MUST HAVE A NAME

A corporation must have a name by which it shall be known in law and in the transaction of its business. The name is given to it in its charter or articles of association and must be adhered to. The necessity for the use of the corporate name in the transaction of business follows from the fact that in corporate affairs the law knows the corporation as an individual and takes no notice of the constituent members.

A corporation must have a name that it will be recognized by in legal terms and in its business dealings. This name is established in its charter or articles of association and must be followed. The requirement to use the corporate name in business transactions comes from the fact that, in corporate matters, the law treats the corporation as an individual and does not consider the individual members.

CORPORATE INTERESTS

In municipal corporations in the United States the members are the citizens; the number is indefinite; one ceases to be a member when he moves from the town or city, while every new resident becomes a member when[227] by law he becomes entitled to the privileges of local citizenship. In corporations created for the emolument of their members interests are represented by shares, which may be transferred by their owners, and the assignee becomes entitled to the rights of membership when the transfer is recorded; and if the owner dies his personal representative becomes a member for the time being. In such corporations also shares may be sold in satisfaction of debts against their owners.

In municipal corporations in the United States, the members are the citizens; the number is unlimited. A person stops being a member when they move away from the town or city, while every new resident becomes a member when[227] they are legally entitled to the benefits of local citizenship. In corporations created for the benefit of their members, interests are represented by shares, which can be transferred by their owners, and the new owner gains the rights of membership once the transfer is recorded. If the owner passes away, their personal representative becomes a member temporarily. In these corporations, shares can also be sold to settle debts owed by their owners.

ADVANTAGES OF CORPORATIONS AND JOINT-STOCK COMPANIES OVER PARTNERSHIPS

The following are given as a few of the advantages which are claimed for corporations and joint-stock companies over partnerships:

The following are some of the advantages that are said to be offered by corporations and joint-stock companies compared to partnerships:

  1. Union of capital without the active service of the investors.
  2. Better facilities for borrowing. It is a common thing for a partnership to be changed to a stock company for the express purpose of raising money by the issue of bonds or stock.
  3. Limited agency of directors. A partner may pledge and sell the partnership property, may buy goods on account of the partnership, may borrow money and contract debts in the name and on the account of the partnership. Directors of a joint-stock company must act in accordance with the provisions of the by-laws of the company.
  4. The continuous existence of a company.
  5. New shareholders are admitted more easily than new partners.
  6. A retiring partner is still liable for existing debts. A shareholder may retire absolutely by selling his stock and having it legally transferred.

[228]IV. BORROWING AND LOANING MONEY[10]

THE MONEY MARKET

Money, like other articles of commerce, has for hundreds of years had its fields for the production of the raw products, its manufacturing establishments, its markets and exchange centres, its sellers and buyers, its wholesale and retail dealers, and its brokers and commission merchants. Out of this trade in actual coin has grown a trade in paper notes, which are really only promises to pay coin, and out of this latter trade has grown up during recent years a still further enormous trade in securities representing all kinds of property. Very often these securities are based solely upon the credit of the names attached to them, so that our modern system of borrowing and loaning money is really a system of borrowing and loaning credit. When our government borrows $100,000,000, as it did a few years ago, it gives "its bond" that the money will be paid. When States, or cities, or railroads, or other corporations borrow money they issue bonds guaranteeing payment at a particular time. When an individual borrows money he gives his "bond" in the form of a promissory note. These bonds pass from hand to hand[229] and have a fairly constant value in the money market. They really represent the money trade to a much larger extent than does actual coin, so that the borrowing or loaning of money really means, to a very large extent, simply the borrowing or loaning of credit. If we borrow a $10 gold piece we borrow money; if we borrow a $10 bill or an indorser's name for the back of our note we simply borrow credit—in the one instance the credit of the United States and in the other the credit of the man who indorses our paper.

Money, like other goods, has had its own production fields, manufacturing plants, markets and trading hubs, sellers and buyers, and both wholesale and retail dealers for hundreds of years. From the trade in actual coins, a system of trading in paper notes has emerged, which are essentially just promises to pay in coins. Recently, this has led to a massive trade in securities representing various kinds of property. Often, these securities rely entirely on the credit of the names attached to them, so our modern borrowing and lending system really revolves around borrowing and lending credit. When our government borrows $100,000,000, as it did a few years back, it issues "its bond" as a promise to repay the money. When states, cities, railroads, or other corporations take out loans, they issue bonds that guarantee repayment at a specific time. When an individual borrows money, they give their "bond" in the form of a promissory note. These bonds are traded among people[229] and generally maintain a stable value in the money market. They actually represent the money trade to a much greater extent than physical coins do, meaning that borrowing or lending money largely consists of borrowing or lending credit. If we borrow a $10 gold coin, we’re borrowing money; if we borrow a $10 bill or a guarantor’s name on our note, we’re just borrowing credit—in one case, the credit of the United States, and in the other, the credit of the person who backs our paper.

FOOTNOTE:

[10]The student is also referred to Part I. ("General Business Information"), Lesson IX.

[10]The student is also directed to Part I. ("General Business Information"), Lesson IX.

BORROWING FROM BANKS

It is the business of a bank to loan money to responsible persons within reasonable limits. The regular customer of the bank is entitled to and will receive the first consideration if the demand is larger than the bank can safely meet. A business man should not hesitate, when occasion requires, to offer his bank any paper he may want discounted, if in his opinion it is good, nor should he be offended if his banker refuses to take it even without giving reasons. A portion of the loans of many banks consists of investments in solid bonds, but the bulk of the loans of banks is made on commercial paper. Time and demand loans are made upon collaterals of many descriptions. The larger banks loan on an average from $50,000 to $100,000 a day. Banks discount paper for their depositors—and simply term the operation discounting; but when they go outside of their line of depositors in making investments in time paper they call it buying paper. They generally buy from private bankers and note brokers. National banks are prohibited from loaning over ten per cent. of their capital to any one individual or corporation except upon paper representing actually existing merchandise.

It’s the job of a bank to lend money to responsible people within reasonable limits. Regular customers of the bank are prioritized if demand exceeds what the bank can safely accommodate. Business owners shouldn’t hesitate to present any documents they want discounted, as long as they believe they’re good, nor should they be offended if their banker declines without explanation. Many banks invest a portion of their loans in solid bonds, but most of their loans are based on commercial paper. Time and demand loans are secured by various types of collateral. Larger banks typically lend between $50,000 and $100,000 a day. Banks discount paper for their depositors—and call this operation discounting; however, when they invest in time paper for non-depositors, they refer to it as buying paper. They usually purchase from private bankers and note brokers. National banks are not allowed to lend more than ten percent of their capital to any one individual or corporation, except for loans backed by actual merchandise.

[230]WHAT ARE COLLATERALS?

If a business man borrow $1000 from a bank on his note and give ten shares of stock to the bank, to be held by it simply as security, the stock thus given would be termed collateral. These collaterals are not the bank's property and the bank is responsible for their safe keeping. If coupons mature while bonds are being held as collateral, the owners are usually allowed to collect the amount for which they sell. Sometimes one note is given as collateral security for another which is discounted.

If a businessman borrows $1,000 from a bank with a promissory note and gives ten shares of stock to the bank as security, the stock provided is referred to as collateral. This collateral remains the property of the owner, and the bank is accountable for its safe custody. If coupons mature while bonds are being held as collateral, the owners are typically allowed to collect the amounts they sell. Sometimes, one note is used as collateral security for another note that has been discounted.

ACCOMMODATION PAPER

Notes and acceptances that are made in settlement of genuine business transactions come under the head of regular, legitimate business paper. An accommodation note or acceptance is one which is signed or indorsed or accepted simply as an accommodation and not in settlement of an account or in payment of an indebtedness. With banks accommodation paper has a deservedly hard reputation. However, there are all grades and shades of accommodation paper, though it represents no actual business transaction between the parties to it and rests upon no other foundation than that of mutual agreement. No contract is good without a consideration, but this is only true between the original parties to a note. The third party, or innocent receiver or holder of a note, has a good title and can recover its value even though it was originally given without a valuable consideration. An innocent holder of a note which had been originally lost or stolen has a good title to it if he received it for value, the law justly protecting such a holder against the fault or carelessness of others.

Notes and acceptances created to settle legitimate business transactions are considered standard business documents. An accommodation note or acceptance is one that is signed, endorsed, or accepted simply as a favor and not to settle a debt or pay an obligation. In the banking world, accommodation paper has a deservedly tough reputation. However, there are various types and nuances of accommodation paper, even though it doesn't represent an actual business transaction between the involved parties and is based solely on mutual agreement. No contract is valid without consideration, but this only applies between the original parties to a note. A third party, or an innocent receiver or holder of a note, has a valid title and can recover its value even if it was initially issued without valuable consideration. An innocent holder of a note that was originally lost or stolen has a valid title to it if they received it for value, with the law justly protecting such holders against the mistakes or negligence of others.

[231]NOTE BROKERS

Merchants sell a great many of their notes in the open market—that is, to note brokers. The banks buy these notes from the note brokers. The assistance of the broker who handles commercial paper is a necessary and valuable aid to the purchasing bank. Fully three fourths of all the paper purchased by banks in large cities is purchased upon the simple recommendation of the note brokers. As a rule these brokers simply transfer the paper without guaranteeing by indorsement its payment. Notes bought by banks from note brokers without their indorsement are held to be guaranteed by them to be all right in all points except that which covers the question of whether they will be paid or not. The bank uses its best judgment in taking the risk. If the note dealer in selling notes to a bank makes what he believes to be fair and honest representations regarding any particular paper—statements of such a straightforward type that upon them no charge of false pretenses can be made to rest—he simply guarantees the note genuine as to names, date, amount, etc., and that in selling it he conveys a good title to the paper. As business men, however, they are very cautious and are exceedingly anxious that the paper they sell shall be paid, and as a rule they make good any losses which grow out of apparent misrepresentations on their part.

Merchants sell many of their notes in the open market—that is, to note brokers. The banks buy these notes from the note brokers. The help of the broker who deals with commercial paper is a necessary and valuable resource for the purchasing bank. About three-quarters of all the paper bought by banks in large cities is acquired based solely on the recommendation of the note brokers. Typically, these brokers just transfer the paper without guaranteeing its payment through endorsement. Notes purchased by banks from note brokers without their endorsement are considered guaranteed by them to be good in every way except for the question of whether they will be paid. The bank uses its best judgment when taking the risk. If the note dealer, when selling notes to a bank, makes what he believes to be fair and honest claims about any particular paper—statements that are clear enough to not be considered false pretenses—he simply guarantees that the note is genuine in terms of names, date, amount, etc., and that in selling it, he conveys a legitimate title to the paper. As business people, however, they are very cautious and genuinely want the paper they sell to be paid, and typically, they cover any losses that arise from apparent misrepresentations on their part.

BANKERS' RATES FOR LOANS

In loaning money on demand, when it is strictly understood between bank and borrower that the money so advanced is positively minute money—money returnable at any minute when the bank calls for it—banks usually charge low rates of interest. When interest rates are high[232] bankers prefer to deal in long-time paper. This general rule is reversed when the situation is reversed. Bankers aim also to scatter and locate their maturities so that as the seasons roll around they will not have very large amounts maturing at one time and very small amounts at another. They plan also to be "in funds" at those seasons when there is always a large and profitable demand for money. For instance, in the centres of the cotton-manufacturing interest the banks count on a large demand for money between October and January, when the bulk of the purchases to supply the mills are made. Again, among those who operate and deal in wool there is an active demand for money in the wool-clip in the spring months. The wheat and corn crops are autumn consumers of money. Midwinter and midsummer in the north are usually periods of comparative stagnation in the money market. All these things affect rates, and the successful banker is he who from observation and large experience shows the most skill in timing his money supply.

In providing loans on demand, when it is clearly understood between the bank and the borrower that the money loaned is definitely short-term—money that must be paid back anytime the bank requests it—banks typically charge low interest rates. When interest rates are high[232], bankers prefer to deal with long-term loans. This general rule flips when the situation changes. Bankers also aim to spread out and manage their loan maturities so that as the seasons change, they won’t have large sums maturing all at once and small amounts at another time. They also plan to have enough funds during times when there’s always a high and profitable demand for money. For example, in areas where cotton is manufactured, banks expect a high demand for money from October to January when most of the purchases to supply the mills occur. Similarly, those who work with wool see a strong demand for money during the spring months when the wool is clipped. The wheat and corn harvests are significant consumers of money in the autumn. Midwinter and midsummer in the north are usually times of relative stagnation in the money market. All these factors influence rates, and the successful banker is one who, based on careful observation and extensive experience, shows the greatest skill in timing their money supply.

[233]V. COLLATERALS AND SECURITIES

TWO DISTINCT CLASSES OF SECURITIES

There are two distinct classes of mortgage securities—one class based upon the actual value and the other upon the earning value of the property. When a man lends money upon a dwelling-house he bases his estimate of security upon (1) the cost of the property, (2) its location, (3) the average value of adjoining properties, and (4) the general character of the locality; that is to say, the value of the property is the basis of the security. On the other hand, the lender of money upon railway mortgages, for instance (that is, the buyer of securities known as railway mortgages), considers the general earnings of the road rather than the cost of building and equipping the road as the correct basis upon which to estimate the value of the security. These two classes of securities differ in other particulars. The value of the mortgage upon ordinary real estate is constant and the security itself is not so likely to change ownership, while the value of the railway mortgage may vary with the success or failure of the road, and the security itself is in the market constantly as a speculative property. The whole property of a railroad company, considered simply as real estate and equipment, is usually worth but a small[234] fraction of the amount for which it is mortgaged. The creditors, as a rule, depend for the security of their money upon the business of the company.

There are two distinct types of mortgage securities—one based on the actual value and the other on the earning potential of the property. When someone lends money on a house, they estimate the security based on (1) the property's cost, (2) its location, (3) the average value of nearby properties, and (4) the overall character of the area; in other words, the property's value serves as the security foundation. Conversely, a lender dealing with railway mortgages, for example (that is, someone buying securities known as railway mortgages), focuses on the overall earnings of the railroad rather than its construction and equipping costs as the proper basis for estimating the security's value. These two types of securities also differ in other aspects. The value of a mortgage on typical real estate is stable, and it’s less likely to change hands, while the value of railway mortgages can fluctuate with the railroad's success or failure, and these securities are constantly traded as speculative investments. The entire property of a railroad company, viewed merely as real estate and equipment, is usually worth only a small[234] fraction of its mortgage amount. Generally, creditors rely on the company's business performance for the security of their investments.

We have already learned that collaterals are mortgages, stocks, bonds, etc., placed temporarily in the hands of lenders as additional security for money borrowed. The student will note, further, that the borrowing value of such securities depends very largely upon the character of the property represented.

We have already learned that collaterals are mortgages, stocks, bonds, etc., temporarily handed over to lenders as extra security for money borrowed. The student will also notice that the borrowing value of these securities mainly depends on the quality of the property represented.

MORTGAGES AS SECURITIES

A mortgage is a conveyance of property for the purpose of securing debt, with the condition that if the debt is paid the conveyance is to become void. A mortgage in form is really a deed of the land, with a special clause stating that the grant is not absolute but only for the security of the debt. It is usual for the debtor at the time of executing the mortgage to execute also a bond or promissory note in favour of the creditor for the amount of the debt. This is called a mortgage note. Mortgages are frequently given in cases where there is a debt existing to secure or indemnify the mortgagee against some liability which he may possibly incur on behalf or for the benefit of the mortgagor. For instance, when a man has indorsed another's note for the latter's accommodation or gone on his bond as surety the latter may execute to the former a mortgage of indemnity. The power of a corporation to mortgage its property is usually regulated by its character or by the general law under which it is organised. All mortgages must be recorded in the office of the register of deeds for the county in which the property is located. The object of recording is to give notice of the existence of the mortgage to any one who might wish to purchase the land or[235] to take a mortgage upon it. There may be several mortgages upon the same property. The first mortgagee is entitled to be paid in full first, then the second, and so on. The mortgagee may use his mortgage as security for loans or he may assign it as he pleases. When the requirements of a mortgage are not met the holder has under certain conditions the right to foreclose—that is, to advertise the property for sale and, within a time fixed by law, to sell it to satisfy the mortgage. It is usual for the mortgagor to insure the property for the benefit of the mortgagee.

A home loan is a transfer of property to secure a loan, with the understanding that if the loan is paid off, the transfer becomes void. Essentially, a mortgage is a deed of the property, with a specific clause stating that the transfer is not absolute but only for securing the debt. Typically, when the borrower signs the mortgage, they also sign a bond or promissory note in favor of the lender for the loan amount. This is known as a loan agreement. Mortgages are often created to secure existing debt or to protect the lender against liabilities they might incur for the borrower’s benefit. For example, if someone has co-signed a loan for another person, the latter might grant the former a mortgage for protection. The ability of a corporation to mortgage its assets is usually governed by its charter or by the law under which it operates. All mortgages must be recorded in the register of deeds office for the county where the property is located. The purpose of recording is to notify anyone interested in buying the land or [235] taking out a mortgage on it. There can be multiple mortgages on the same property. The first mortgagee has the right to be paid in full before the second, and so on. The mortgagee can use their mortgage as collateral for loans or transfer it as they wish. If the terms of the mortgage are not met, the holder can, under certain conditions, foreclosure—which means to advertise the property for sale and, within a legally defined period, sell it to pay off the mortgage. It is common for the borrower to insure the property for the benefit of the lender.

Although the terms of corporation mortgages are similar to those on real estate such as is represented by dwelling-houses, the commercial conditions make it inconvenient or impossible to foreclose and sell such properties. To stop all business of a railway or to shut down the work of a manufacturing concern would not only result in injury to the public but would reduce largely the earning value of the property. To overcome this difficulty where an active concern is financially embarrassed, the court appoints a receiver, who is responsible for the proper conduct of the business until a satisfactory reorganisation or sale is accomplished.

Although the terms of corporate mortgages are similar to those on real estate like residential homes, the commercial circumstances make it difficult or impossible to foreclose and sell those properties. Stopping all operations of a railway or shutting down a manufacturing business would not only harm the public but also significantly decrease the property’s earning potential. To address this issue when a business is financially struggling, the court appoints a receiver, who is in charge of managing the business properly until a satisfactory reorganization or sale takes place.

Mortgages upon improved property, if properly graduated in amount, should be safe and profitable investments. The buyer, however, must exercise great care and good judgment. Should there be collusion between the loaning agent and the land-owner, the money advanced may be largely in excess of the actual property value. Villages with less than a dozen houses are often the sites of investment companies doing business under pretentious names and offering mortgage investments at interest rates which by the local conditions are impossible. One of the devices of these enterprising companies is to offer their own guarantees as to both principal and[236] interest of all mortgages negotiated by them. The investor should be sure of two things: (1) The safety of the principal, and (2) regularity in the payment of the interest. There is great danger of default from causes not anticipated by the mortgagor and over which he has no control.

Mortgages on improved properties, if properly structured, can be safe and profitable investments. However, buyers need to be very careful and use good judgment. If there is any collusion between the loan agent and the property owner, the amount of money loaned could far exceed the actual property value. Small villages with fewer than a dozen houses often host investment companies that operate under flashy names and offer mortgage investments with interest rates that are unrealistic for the area. One tactic these companies use is to provide their own guarantees regarding both the principal and[236] interest for all mortgages they handle. Investors should ensure two things: (1) the safety of their principal, and (2) consistent payment of interest. There is a significant risk of default due to unforeseen circumstances beyond the control of the mortgagor.

STOCKS AS SECURITIES

To make a profitable investment in stocks the buyer must anticipate the future. A mill that may be working day and night this year may be obliged to shut down entirely next year. A business which is open to public competition must take its chances on its future success. The greater the earnings, the more certain the competition. Many corporations owning monopolies by virtue of patent rights have made large fortunes, but there is always the possibility of new discovery. Electricity has succeeded gas; the telephone is competing with the telegraph; the trolley is cutting into the profits of railways. A good thing in stocks to-day does not necessarily mean a good thing next year. Railroad stocks are of such varied character that it is impossible here to make more than general statements. Many of our railroad stocks bring prices far above par and pay liberal interest on investments. Some of them are so profitable that they are really not on the market and cannot easily be bought. Others represent roads loaded down with mortgages and other obligations so heavy as to make the stock really a liability rather than a resource to its owner. The stock quotations represent in a general way the comparative value of these securities. Of recent stock electric-railway stock is the most popular and in many instances the most profitable. The introduction of electric power has reduced the working expense one half and in most instances has doubled the traffic without any reduction in[237] fares. The buyer should make sure that the road is in a busy community able to sustain it, that its franchise will protect it from dangerous competition, and that the securities have been legally issued.

To make a successful investment in stocks, buyers need to predict the future. A mill that might be running around the clock this year could be forced to shut down completely next year. A business facing public competition must take risks regarding its future success. The higher the profits, the more intense the competition. Many companies that hold monopolies thanks to patent rights have made substantial fortunes, but there’s always a chance of new discoveries. Electricity has replaced gas; the telephone is taking the place of the telegraph; and trolleys are cutting into railway profits. A solid investment in stocks today doesn’t guarantee it will still be good next year. Railroad stocks are so varied that it’s impossible to make more than general comments here. Many railroad stocks sell for much higher than par value and offer generous returns on investments. Some are so lucrative that they’re not readily available on the market. Others are burdened with heavy mortgages and obligations, making the stock more of a liability than an asset for the owner. Stock prices generally reflect the comparative value of these securities. Recently, electric railway stocks have become the most sought-after and often the most profitable. The use of electric power has halved operational costs and, in many cases, doubled the traffic without lowering fares. Buyers should ensure that the railway operates in a busy community that can support it, that its franchise protects it from severe competition, and that the securities have been legally issued.

SUBSTITUTION SECURITIES

There have recently been formed several large companies whose business it is to issue bonds on the security of other bonds. The idea is similar to that of real-estate title insurance. Such companies are supposed to have superior facilities for investigating securities. They purchase those which they consider good and at the best prices possible. These they deposit with some trust company or banking institution. With these bonds which they buy as their original property they issue new bonds of their own, which they sell to the public and which they guarantee. The differences in prices and in interest make up their profits.

There have recently been several large companies that specialize in issuing bonds backed by other bonds. The concept is similar to real-estate title insurance. These companies are expected to have better resources for researching securities. They buy the ones they think are valuable and at the best prices available. They then deposit these with a trust company or bank. Using these bonds as their original assets, they issue new bonds of their own, which they sell to the public and guarantee. The differences in prices and interest rates create their profits.

LOANS AND INVESTMENTS

With the growth of wealth we find increasing numbers of persons who want to invest their means in good securities. To do this successfully and safely is a very difficult question. It is even more difficult to keep money profitably employed than to make it. Changes and innovations are of continual occurrence. Not only are new securities constantly coming upon the market, but new subjects as a basis of their production are industriously sought after. Every newly discovered force or process in mechanics means the appearance of another detachment of paper securities. The War of the Rebellion popularised the coupon bond, in consequence of its adoption by the government, and made it the favourite form of invest[238]ment paper. Railroads and other corporations soon availed themselves of the confidence which that species of paper inspired, and States, cities, and counties were soon flooding the country with obligations carrying long coupon attachments. Many persons have purchased and paid good prices for mortgage coupon bonds, giving them no control over their security, who would have rejected share certificates standing for an equal interest in the property pledged and giving them the right to participate in its management, with the possibility of a greater return for their money. Many of the States through careless legislation have permitted corporations to decide for themselves the amounts of obligations they might put out, and the privilege has been very much abused. We now have stocks and bonds upon the market representing nearly all conceivable kinds of property—telegraph and telephone companies, mining companies, cattle ranches, grain farms, water-works, canals, bridges, oil- and gas-wells, electric lighting, trolley companies, factories and mills, patent rights, steamboat lines, apartment-houses, etc. Not only are properties of many kinds used to issue bonds upon, but many kinds of bonds are often issued upon the same properties. One issue of bonds is sometimes made the basis of other issues. Some one has said that there never was a time in the history of the world when it was so easy to invest money—and to lose it. Of the securities that are offered with first-class recommendations it is probable that about one third are actually good, one third have some value, and one third are practically worthless. In making investments the first and main thing to be studied is safety. Never buy a security of any kind without having read it. Do not buy what are commonly known as cheap securities. Do not rely solely upon the advice of a broker; he may have personal interest to serve. By far the greater number of losses to investors have been in securities pur[239]chased exclusively on the recommendation of interested commission men. It is a mistake to give preference to listed securities—that is, those reported on the stock-exchange lists. Stocks are too often listed simply for speculative purposes, and the price represents not so much the value of the property as the pitch of the speculation at the time. Securities in the long run must stand upon their merits. As a rule the best time for an experienced investor to buy is when others are unloading.

With the growth of wealth, we see more people wanting to invest their money in solid securities. Successfully and safely doing this is a very challenging issue. It's even harder to keep money invested profitably than it is to earn it. Changes and innovations happen constantly. New securities are always entering the market, and new subjects for their creation are actively sought after. Every new force or process in mechanics leads to the emergence of another set of paper securities. The Civil War popularized the coupon bond, thanks to its adoption by the government, making it a favorite type of invest[238]ment paper. Railroads and other corporations quickly took advantage of the confidence that this type of paper inspired, and soon states, cities, and counties were flooding the country with obligations featuring long coupon attachments. Many people have bought and paid good prices for mortgage coupon bonds, giving them no control over their security, while they would have turned down share certificates representing an equal stake in the property pledged and giving them the right to take part in its management, possibly allowing for a greater return on their investment. Many states, through careless legislation, have allowed corporations to set their own amounts of obligations to issue, and this privilege has been abused significantly. We now have stocks and bonds in the market representing almost every imaginable type of property—telegraph and telephone companies, mining companies, cattle ranches, grain farms, waterworks, canals, bridges, oil and gas wells, electric lighting, trolley companies, factories and mills, patent rights, steamboat lines, apartment buildings, etc. Not only are various properties used to issue bonds, but many kinds of bonds can often be issued against the same properties. Sometimes one bond issue serves as the basis for other issues. Someone has said that there has never been a time in history when it was so easy to invest money—and to lose it. Of the securities offered with top-notch recommendations, it's likely that about a third are actually good, a third have some value, and a third are virtually worthless. When investing, the first and most important thing to focus on is safety. Never buy a security of any kind without having read it. Avoid what are commonly known as cheap securities. Don’t rely solely on a broker's advice; they might have personal interests to serve. The majority of losses for investors have occurred in securities pur[239]chased solely based on the recommendations of commission-driven individuals. It's a mistake to favor listed securities—those reported on the stock exchange lists. Stocks are often listed just for speculative reasons, and the price reflects not so much the property's value as the current speculation trend. Securities, in the long run, must stand on their own merits. Generally, the best time for an experienced investor to buy is when others are selling off.

[240]VI. CHEQUES, DRAFTS, AND BILLS OF EXCHANGE[11]

BANK CHEQUES

Showing cheque raised from $7.50 to $70.50. Showing cheque raised from $7.50 to $70.50. Showing the check increased from $7.50 to $70.50.

A cheque is an order for money, drawn by one who has funds in the bank, payable on demand. Banks provide blank cheques for their customers and it is a very simple matter to fill them out properly. In writing in the amount begin at the extreme left of the line. The illustrations given here show a poorly-written cheque and a copy of the same cheque after it has been "raised." The original cheque was for $7.50 and shows very careless arrangement. It was a very easy matter for the fraudulent receiver to change the "seven" to "seventy" and to add a cipher to the amount in figures. The running line was written in on the raised cheque to deceive the bank. In this case Mr. Carter and not the bank must suffer the loss. Mr. Carter cannot hold the bank responsible for his carelessness. Drawers of cheques should exercise the greatest care in writing in the amount to prevent changes or additions. Draw a running line, thus: ~~~Nine~~~ before and after the amount written in words. If the words are commenced close to the left margin the run[241]ning line will be necessary only at the right. The signature should be in your usual style familiar to the paying teller. The plain, freely written signature is the most difficult to forge. Usually cheques are drawn "to order." The words "Pay to the order of John Brown" mean that the money is to be paid to John Brown or to any person he "orders" it paid to. By indorsing the cheque in blank (see indorsements) he makes it payable to bearer. If a cheque is drawn "Pay to bearer" any person—that is, the bearer—can collect it. The paying teller may ask[242] the person cashing the cheque to write his name on the back, simply to have it for reference. Safety devices to prevent the fraudulent alteration of cheques are of almost endless variety, but there has not been a preventive against forgery and alterations yet invented, which has not been successfully overcome by swindlers. A machine for punching out the figures is in common use, but the swindler has successfully filled in the holes with paper-pulp and punched other figures to suit his purposes. The safest cheques are those carefully written upon what is known as safety paper.

A check is a request for money, written by someone who has funds in the bank, and is payable on demand. Banks provide blank checks for their customers, and it's very straightforward to fill them out correctly. When writing the amount, start from the far left of the line. The illustrations here show a poorly written check and a copy of that same check after it has been "raised." The original check was for $7.50 and shows a very careless arrangement. It was very easy for the fraudulent person to change "seven" to "seventy" and add a zero to the amount in figures. A line was drawn on the altered check to deceive the bank. In this case, Mr. Carter, not the bank, has to bear the loss. Mr. Carter can't hold the bank accountable for his carelessness. People writing checks should take great care when writing the amount to avoid changes or additions. Draw a line like this: Understood. Please provide the text you'd like me to modernize.NineUnderstood! Please provide the text for modernization. before and after the amount written in words. If the words start close to the left margin, the line will only be needed on the right. The signature should be in your usual style that the paying teller recognizes. A simple, clear signature is the hardest to forge. Generally, checks are written "to order." The phrase "Pay to the order of John Brown" means that the money is to be given to John Brown or anyone he instructs it to be paid to. By endorsing the check in blank (see indorsements) he makes it payable to whoever holds it. If a check says "Pay to bearer," then anyone—that is, the bearer—can cash it. The paying teller might ask the person cashing the check to write their name on the back, just to keep a record. There are countless safety features designed to prevent the fraudulent alteration of checks, but there hasn’t been a foolproof method against forgery or alterations that hasn't been successfully bypassed by scammers. A punch machine for creating holes in the figures is in common use, but scammers have successfully filled in those holes with paper pulp and punched other figures to suit their needs. The safest checks are those carefully written on what is known as safety paper.

FOOTNOTE:

[11]A part of the matter of this lesson has already appeared in Part I. of this book ("General Business Information"), but it is here repeated to preserve the connection.

[11]Some of the content of this lesson was already mentioned in Part I of this book ("General Business Information"), but it is included here again to maintain the flow.

IDENTIFICATION WHEN CHEQUES ARE PAID

The banks of this country make it a rule not to cash a cheque that is drawn payable to order unless the person presenting the cheque is known at the bank—or unless he satisfies the paying teller that he is really the person to whom the money is to be paid. It must be remembered, however, that a cheque drawn to order and then indorsed in blank by the payee is really payable to bearer, and if the paying teller is satisfied that the payee's signature is genuine he probably will not hesitate to cash the cheque. In England all cheques apparently properly indorsed are paid without identification. In drawing a cheque in favour of a person not likely to be well known in banking circles, write his address or his business after his name on the face of the cheque. For instance, if you should send a cheque to John Smith, Boston, it may possibly fall into the hands of the wrong John Smith; but if you write the cheque in favour of "John Smith, 849 Tremont Street, Boston," it is more than likely that the right person will collect it. If you wish to get a cheque cashed where you are unknown, and it is not convenient for a friend who has an account at the bank to go with you for[243] the purpose of identification, ask him to place his signature on the back of your cheque and it is likely you will not have trouble in getting it cashed. By placing his signature on the back of the cheque he guarantees the bank against loss. A bank is responsible for the signatures of its depositors, but it cannot be supposed to know the signatures of indorsers. The reliable identifier is in reality the person who is responsible.

The banks in this country have a rule that they won’t cash a check made out to order unless the person presenting it is known to the bank or can prove to the teller that they are indeed the intended recipient. However, it’s important to note that a check made out to order and then signed in blank by the payee is effectively payable to the bearer, and if the teller believes the payee's signature is genuine, they will likely cash the check without hesitation. In England, checks that are properly endorsed seem to be paid without requiring identification. When writing a check for someone who isn't likely to be familiar in banking circles, include their address or business after their name on the front of the check. For example, if you send a check to John Smith in Boston, it might end up with the wrong John Smith. But if you write it out to "John Smith, 849 Tremont Street, Boston," it’s much more likely the right person will collect it. If you need to cash a check where you’re not recognized, and it’s not convenient for a friend with a bank account to accompany you for identification, ask them to sign the back of your check, and you should have no problem getting it cashed. By signing the back, they guarantee the bank against loss. A bank is responsible for its depositors' signatures but can’t be expected to recognize the signatures of endorsers. The reliable identifier is effectively the person who takes responsibility.

CHEQUES FOR SPECIAL PURPOSES

If you wish to draw money from your own account the most approved form of cheque is written "Pay to the order of cash." This differs from a cheque drawn to "bearer." The paying teller expects to see you yourself or some one well known to him as your representative when you write "cash." If you write "Pay to the order of (your own name)" you will be required to indorse your own cheque before you can get it cashed. If you wish to draw a cheque to pay a note write "Pay to the order of bills payable." If you wish to write a cheque to draw money for wages write "Pay to the order of pay-roll." If you wish to write a cheque to pay for a draft which you are buying write "Pay to the order of N. Y. draft and exchange," or whatever the circumstances may call for.

If you want to withdraw cash from your account, the most common way to write a check is "Pay to the order of cash." This is different from a check made out to "bearer." The teller expects to see you or someone he knows well as your representative when you write "cash." If you write "Pay to the order of (your own name)," you'll need to sign your own check before you can cash it. If you want to write a check to pay a loan, write "Pay to the order of bills payable." If you're writing a check to withdraw money for wages, write "Pay to the order of pay-roll." If you need a check to pay for a draft you are purchasing, write "Pay to the order of N. Y. draft and exchange," or whatever the situation requires.

CHEQUE INDORSEMENTS

In indorsing a cheque remember that the left end of the face is the top when you turn it over. Write your name as you are accustomed to write it. If you are depositing the cheque, a blank indorsement—that is, an indorsement with simply your name—will answer; or you can write or stamp "Pay to the order of (the bank in which you deposit)" and follow with your signature. Either[244] indorsement makes the cheque the absolute property of the bank. If you wish to transfer the cheque by indorsement to some particular person write "Pay to the order of (naming the person)" and follow with your own signature; or you may simply write your name on the back. The latter form would be considered unwise if you were sending the cheque through the mail, for the reason that a blank indorsement makes the cheque payable to bearer. An authorised stamped indorsement is as good as a written one. Whether such indorsements are accepted or not depends upon the regulations of the clearing-house in the particular city in which they are offered for deposit.

When endorsing a check, remember that the left side of the front is the top when you flip it over. Write your name just as you usually do. If you're depositing the check, a blank endorsement—that is, just your name—will work; or you can write or stamp "Pay to the order of (the bank where you deposit)" and then sign your name. Either endorsement makes the check the bank's absolute property. If you want to transfer the check to a specific person, write "Pay to the order of (name the person)" and sign your name; or you can simply write your name on the back. The latter method isn't smart if you're mailing the check because a blank endorsement makes it payable to anyone who has it. An authorized stamped endorsement is just as valid as a written one. Whether these endorsements are accepted or not depends on the clearinghouse rules in the city where they’re being deposited.

THE NUMBERING OF CHEQUES

A certified cheque. __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__.

Cheques should be numbered, so that each can be accounted for. The numbers are for your convenience and not for the convenience of the bank. It is important that your cheque-book be correctly kept, so that you can tell at any time how much money you have in the bank.[245] At the end of each month your small bank-book should be left at the bank, so that the bookkeeper may balance it. It may happen that your bank-book will show a larger balance than your cheque-book. You will understand by this, if both have been correctly kept, that there are cheques outstanding which have not yet been presented at your bank for payment. You can find out which these are by checking over the paid cheques that have been returned to you with your bank-book. The unpaid cheques may be presented at any time, so that your actual balance is that shown by your cheque-book. Cheques should be presented for payment as soon after date as possible.

Checks should be numbered so that each one can be tracked. The numbers are for your convenience, not the bank's. It's important to keep your checkbook organized so you can always see how much money you have in the bank.[245] At the end of each month, you should leave your small bankbook at the bank for the bookkeeper to balance it. Occasionally, your bankbook may show a higher balance than your checkbook. If both have been managed correctly, this means there are checks that haven't been cashed yet. You can figure out which checks those are by going over the paid checks that have been returned to you with your bankbook. Uncashed checks can be presented for payment at any time, so your actual balance is what your checkbook indicates. Checks should be cashed as soon as possible after the date on them.

CERTIFIED CHEQUES

A bank draft. __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__.

If you wish to use your cheque to pay a note due at some other bank than your own, or in buying real estate or stocks or bonds you may find it necessary to get your cheque certified. This is done by an officer of the bank,[246] who writes or stamps across the face of the cheque the words "Certified" or "Good when properly indorsed" and signs his name. (See illustration, p. 244.) The amount will immediately be deducted from your account, and the bank by guaranteeing your cheque becomes responsible for its payment. If you should get a cheque certified and then not use it deposit it in your bank, otherwise your account will be short the amount for which it is drawn.

If you want to use your check to pay a note at a different bank or to buy real estate, stocks, or bonds, you may need to get your check certified. This is done by a bank officer, who will write or stamp the words "Certified" or "Good when properly endorsed" on the front of the check and sign their name. [246] (See illustration, p. 244.) The amount will be immediately subtracted from your account, and the bank takes responsibility for ensuring the check is paid. If you get a check certified but don’t use it, you should deposit it in your bank; otherwise, your account will be reduced by the amount of the check.

BANK DRAFTS

A bill of exchange. __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__.

Nearly all banks keep money on deposit in other banks in large commercial centres—for instance, in New York or Chicago. They call these banks their New York or Chicago correspondents. A bank draft is simply the bank's cheque drawing upon its deposit with some other bank. (See illustration, p. 245.) Banks sell these cheques to their customers, and merchants make large use of them in making remittances from one part of the country to another. These drafts or cashiers' cheques, as they are[247] sometimes called, pass as cash anywhere within a reasonable distance of the money centre upon which they are drawn.

Nearly all banks keep money deposited in other banks located in major commercial centers, like New York or Chicago. They refer to these banks as their New York or Chicago correspondents. A bank draft is basically the bank's check that draws upon its deposit in another bank. (See illustration, p. 245.) Banks sell these checks to their customers, and merchants often use them to send money from one part of the country to another. These drafts or cashier's checks, as they are[247] sometimes referred to, are accepted as cash anywhere within a reasonable distance of the money center they are drawn on.

BILLS OF EXCHANGE

A draft on a foreign bank is commonly called a bill of exchange. Bills of exchange are usually drawn in duplicate and sometimes in triplicate. (See illustration, p. 246.) Only one bill is collected, the others simply serving in the meantime as receipts. These bills are used to pay accounts in foreign countries, just as drafts on New York or Chicago are used to pay indebtedness at home.

A draft on a foreign bank is commonly referred to as a bill of exchange. Bills of exchange are typically created in duplicate and sometimes in triplicate. (See illustration, p. 246.) Only one bill is actually collected, while the others serve as receipts for now. These bills are used to settle accounts in foreign countries, just like drafts on New York or Chicago are used to pay debts domestically.

[248]VII. THE CLEARING-HOUSE SYSTEM[12]

THE CLEARING-HOUSE SYSTEM A MODERN INSTITUTION

The clearing-house is a comparatively modern institution, the Edinburgh bankers claiming the credit of establishing the first one. The earliest clearing-house of whose transactions we have any record is that of London, founded about 1775. For fully seventy-five years the London clearing-house and that of Edinburgh were the only organisations of the kind known to exist. The monetary systems of most European countries centring around one great national bank located at the capital of each, found in this a means of effecting mercantile settlements. The New York clearing-house was established in 1853, from which date the American clearing-house system has grown to enormous proportions. No country in the world has so large a need of clearing-houses, for in no country is the bank cheque so generally used in the payment of ordinary accounts.

The clearing-house is a relatively modern institution, with the Edinburgh bankers claiming credit for establishing the first one. The earliest clearing-house we have any record of is in London, founded around 1775. For seventy-five years, the London clearing-house and the Edinburgh one were the only organizations of their kind known to exist. The monetary systems of most European countries, centered around a major national bank in each capital, found this a way to facilitate commercial settlements. The New York clearing-house was set up in 1853, marking the beginning of the massive American clearing-house system. No country in the world has a greater need for clearing-houses, as no country uses bank checks as widely for paying everyday accounts.

TRANSFER OF CREDITS IN CLEARING-HOUSES

The purpose of the clearing-house is largely to facilitate the transfer of credits. This is explained by the fol[249]lowing illustration: Suppose that Brown and Smith keep their money on deposit in Bank A and that Brown gives Smith his cheque for $100 and Smith deposits it in the bank to his (Smith's) credit. The officers of the bank will subtract $100 from Brown's account and add the same amount to Smith's account. No actual money need be touched. It is simply a matter of arithmetic and bookkeeping. Credit has been transferred from Brown to Smith. If all the people of a city kept their money in one central bank there would be no need of a clearing-house. The bookkeepers of the bank would be kept busy transferring credits from one customer to another on the books of the bank. But if Brown keeps his money in Bank A and Smith keeps his money in Bank B it is necessary that Bank A and Bank B come together somewhere to conveniently make the credit transfer, and this is practically what they do in the clearing-house. Then, again, if Bank A should be located in San Francisco and Bank B in Boston, the difficulty of transfer of credit is greatly increased.

The clearing-house mainly exists to make it easier to transfer credits. This can be illustrated as follows: Imagine Brown and Smith both have their money deposited in Bank A. If Brown writes a $100 check to Smith and Smith deposits it to his (Smith's) account, the bank will deduct $100 from Brown's account and add the same amount to Smith's account. No actual cash needs to be exchanged; it's just a matter of numbers and record-keeping. Credit has been moved from Brown to Smith. If everyone in a city kept their money in a single central bank, a clearing-house wouldn't be necessary. The bank's record-keepers would just be busy moving credits from one customer's account to another's in the bank's books. However, if Brown has his money in Bank A and Smith has his in Bank B, then Bank A and Bank B need to meet somewhere to conveniently handle the credit transfer, which is essentially the role of the clearing-house. Additionally, if Bank A is in San Francisco and Bank B is in Boston, transferring credit becomes much more complicated.

Through the agency of clearing-houses located in money centres and of co-operation between banks at distant points, the transfer of credits between business men located anywhere in the United States, or for that matter in the world, has become a comparatively simple matter. If it were not for the agency of this system it would be utterly impossible for a great city to do the business of a single day. All the actual money in all the banks and stores and safes and pockets of New York City to-day would fall far short if used to pay to-day's transactions. It is estimated that the cash transactions of a single day are fifty times greater than the actual cash changing hands in one day. So that the great bulk of the business of the country, both cash and credit, is done on a system[250] of credit transfers made possible wholly through the agency of our banking system.

Thanks to clearinghouses in financial centers and cooperation between banks at different locations, transferring credits between businesspeople anywhere in the United States, or even around the world, has become quite straightforward. Without this system, it would be completely impossible for a major city to handle a single day's business. The actual amount of money in all the banks, stores, safes, and pockets in New York City today would be far from enough to cover today's transactions. It's estimated that the cash transactions in a single day are fifty times greater than the actual cash that changes hands on that day. Consequently, most of the business in the country, both cash and credit, relies on a system[250] of credit transfers that is entirely made possible through our banking system.

FOOTNOTE:

[12] See also Lesson VIII. of Part I. of this book ("General Business Information").

[12] See also Lesson VIII. of Part I. of this book ("General Business Information").

ORGANISATION OF CLEARING-HOUSES

Each large city has its clearing-house system. To establish a clearing-house a number of banks associate themselves together, under certain regulations, for the purpose of exchanging daily at one time and place the cheques and other commercial paper which they hold against each other. The usual officers are a president, a secretary, a treasurer, and manager, and a clearing-house committee. The cheques, etc., which the banks take to the clearing-house are called the clearing-house exchanges, and the total amount of paper exchanged is called the day's clearings. Those banks which bring a less amount than they take away are obliged to make the difference good in cash or its equivalent within a fixed time upon the same day. Suppose, for illustration, that a clearing-house association consists of five banks—A, B, C, D, and E—and that Bank A took to the clearing-house cheques against B, C, D, and E amounting to $20,000, and that B, C, D, and E took to the clearing-house cheques against A amounting to $21,000. Then A is on this particular day a debtor bank, and owes the clearing-house, or the other banks through the clearing-house, $1000. The payment of the balances by the debtor banks and the receipt of the balances by the creditor banks complete each day's transactions. As the total amount brought to the clearing-house is always the same as the amount taken away, so the balances due from the debtor banks must be exactly equal to the amounts due the creditor banks. The clearings in New York City in one day amount to from $100,000,000 to $200,000,000, and the actual cash handled, if any, need[251] only be for the actual debit balances. Usually once a week (in some cities oftener) the banks of a city make to their clearing-house a report, based on daily balances, of their condition. The clearing-house establishes a fellowship among banks that has already proved in times of money panics of the greatest service to themselves and the community.

Each large city has its clearing-house system. To set up a clearing house, several banks come together under certain rules to exchange checks and other commercial documents they hold against each other at a specific time and place each day. The typical officers include a president, a secretary, a treasurer, a manager, and a clearing-house committee. The checks and documents taken to the clearing house by the banks are called clearing-house exchanges, and the total amount exchanged is referred to as the day's clearings. Banks that bring in less than they take out must cover the difference in cash or its equivalent within a set time on the same day. For example, if a clearing-house association consists of five banks—A, B, C, D, and E—and Bank A brings in checks from B, C, D, and E totaling $20,000, while B, C, D, and E present checks from A amounting to $21,000, then A owes the clearing house, or the other banks through the clearing house, $1,000 that day. The payment of balances by the debtor banks and the receipt of balances by the creditor banks wrap up each day's transactions. Since the total amount brought to the clearing house always equals the amount taken away, the balances owed by the debtor banks must match the amounts due to the creditor banks. The clearings in New York City in a single day range from $100,000,000 to $200,000,000, and the actual cash handled, if any, only needs to cover the actual debit balances. Typically, once a week (or more frequently in some cities), the banks submit a report to their clearing house based on daily balances to show their financial condition. The clearing house creates a sense of community among banks that has already proven to be immensely helpful during times of financial panic for both the banks and the wider community.

PAYMENT OF BALANCES IN CLEARING-HOUSES

Clearing-house certificates are made use of in many cities for the payment of balances by debtor banks. These are issued against gold deposited with one of the associated banks. They are numbered, registered, and countersigned by the proper officer, and are used only in settlements between the banks. Various methods of making settlements are in use. In some of the cities the balances are paid by drafts on New York or other money centres. The debtor bank sells some creditor bank New York exchange, and receives in return a cheque or order on the clearing-house, which when presented makes the debits and credits balance. It is estimated that the actual cash employed in New York clearings is less than one half of one per cent. of the balances.

Clearing-house certificates are used in many cities for settling balances between debtor banks. These are issued against gold deposited with one of the member banks. They are numbered, registered, and signed off by the appropriate officer, and are only used for transactions between the banks. There are various ways to make these settlements. In some cities, balances are paid via drafts on New York or other financial hubs. The debtor bank sells New York exchange to a creditor bank and receives a check or order from the clearing house in return, which, when presented, balances the debits and credits. It's estimated that the actual cash used in New York clearings is less than half of one percent of the total balances.

[252]HOW DISTANT BANKS ARE CONNECTED BY THE CLEARING-HOUSE SYSTEM

Illustrating cheque collections. Cheque collection illustrations.

To illustrate the connection between banks at distant points let us suppose that B of Haverhill, Mass., who keeps his money on deposit in the First National Bank of that city, sends a cheque to S of Waconia, Wis., in payment of a bill. S deposits the cheque in the Farmers' Bank of Waconia and receives immediate credit for it in his bank-book, just the same as though the cheque were drawn upon the same or a near-by bank. The Farmers' Bank deposits the cheque, with other cheques, in, say, the First National Bank of Minneapolis, or it may send the cheque to its correspondent in New York—say the Ninth National—asking to be credited with the amount. For sake of illustration, suppose that the cheque is deposited with the First National of Minneapolis. Now, this bank has a correspondent in Chicago—the Commercial National—and a correspondent in New York—the National Bank of the Republic. If sent to the Commercial National, this bank has a correspondent in Boston—the Eliot Bank, where the cheque would be sent. Now, the First National of Haverhill has a correspondent in Boston—the National Revere Bank. The Eliot Bank would likely take this cheque to the Boston clearing-house as a charge against the Revere Bank. The Revere Bank would deduct the amount from the First National of[253] Haverhill's deposit and send the paid cheque to the Haverhill Bank, where at the close of the month it would be handed to B, showing on the back the indorsement of S, and stamping representing all the banks through whose hands it passed. If the Farmers' Bank of Waconia had sent direct to its New York correspondent, the Ninth National, this bank would have sent to its Boston correspondent, the North National, and the cheque would have been charged up through the clearing-house against the Revere Bank. If the First National of Minneapolis had sent direct to its New York correspondent, the National Bank of the Republic, this bank would have sent to its Boston correspondent, the Shawmut National, etc. As a rule, banks collect by whatever route seems most convenient or advantageous. It is estimated that millions of dollars are lost to the banks each year on account of the time consumed by cheques en route.

To show how banks connect at distant locations, let’s say that B from Haverhill, Mass., who has money deposited in the First National Bank of that city, sends a check to S in Waconia, Wis., to pay a bill. S deposits the check in the Farmers' Bank of Waconia and gets immediate credit in his bank book, just like if the check were drawn on the same or a nearby bank. The Farmers' Bank deposits the check, along with other checks, in the First National Bank of Minneapolis, or it might send the check to its correspondent in New York—let’s say the Ninth National—asking to be credited with the amount. For this example, let’s say the check is deposited with the First National of Minneapolis. This bank has a correspondent in Chicago—the Commercial National—and one in New York—the National Bank of the Republic. If it goes to the Commercial National, that bank has a correspondent in Boston—the Eliot Bank—and the check would be sent there. Now, the First National of Haverhill has a correspondent in Boston—the National Revere Bank. The Eliot Bank would likely take this check to the Boston clearinghouse to charge against the Revere Bank. The Revere Bank would deduct the amount from the First National of [253] Haverhill's deposit and send the paid check back to the Haverhill Bank, where at the end of the month it would be given to B, showing on the back the endorsement of S and stamps from all the banks that handled it. If the Farmers' Bank of Waconia had sent it directly to its New York correspondent, the Ninth National, this bank would have sent it to its Boston correspondent, the North National, and the check would have been charged through the clearinghouse against the Revere Bank. If the First National of Minneapolis had sent it directly to its New York correspondent, the National Bank of the Republic, this bank would have sent it to its Boston correspondent, the Shawmut National, etc. Generally, banks collect by the route that seems most convenient or beneficial. It's estimated that millions of dollars are lost by banks each year due to the time checks spend in transit.

[254] VIII. COMMERCIAL CREDITS AND MERCANTILE AGENCIES

HOW THE WORLD'S TRADE IS LARGELY TRANSACTED UPON CREDIT

It is estimated that about ninety per cent. of the world's trade is transacted upon credit. And in no country of the world are commercial credits so freely granted as in the United States. This is a land of seemingly unlimited faith in humanity, and yet a land in which hazardous speculation, extravagance, and bankruptcy have often prevailed. Statistics show that about ninety-five per cent. of our merchants "fail to succeed," and yet no other country can boast of such wealth, industrial energy, and generous confidence in business integrity. While credit is not money, in that it cannot settle a debt, it must be considered a very powerful agent in the creation of capital. Credit is another name for trust. The business world bases its confidence or trust in men upon their character and resources. And the extent of this trust becomes the only limitation of the business man's purchasing power. He who can show conclusively the ability and disposition to fulfil obligations, has it within his power to command[255] the capital or merchandise of others. Credit is one of the fruits of a higher civilisation and a settled condition of a country's business. It bespeaks a quality of government, too, that is not to be depreciated. The nations that are most successfully and equitably governed and show the most stable conditions of currency also show us the most extensive and efficient credit systems. It is abundantly true that these same nations have on many occasions passed through periods of great distress from failures widespread and panics severe, but it must also be borne in mind that these very bankruptcies are more often the abuse of prosperity than the product of adversity. Over-confidence in men and things has resulted in speculation and precipitated bankruptcy. And if it be urged that to the undue expansion of credit is traceable the greater number of our financial disasters, it may be said with still greater force that all our impetus to industrial achievement has been and still is dependent upon the generous exercise of credit. The construction of our railroads and canals, the operation of our mines, the improvement of our great farm areas, the building of our towns and cities, and the development of our extensive manufacturing interests are all the result of the trust reposed in men and the industrial interests they represent.

It’s estimated that about ninety percent of the world's trade happens on credit. And no country grants commercial credit as freely as the United States. This is a place with seemingly limitless faith in people, yet it's also where risky speculation, extravagance, and bankruptcy often thrive. Statistics indicate that around ninety-five percent of our merchants "fail to succeed," yet no other country can claim such wealth, industriousness, and strong confidence in business integrity. While credit isn’t money, since it can’t settle a debt, it should be seen as a powerful factor in creating capital. Credit is another term for trust. The business world’s confidence in individuals is based on their character and resources. The level of this trust becomes the only limit to a business person’s purchasing power. Those who can clearly demonstrate their ability and willingness to meet obligations can command[255] the capital or goods of others. Credit is one of the signs of a more advanced civilization and a stable business environment in a country. It also reflects a quality of governance that shouldn’t be underestimated. Countries that are governed effectively and equitably, and have stable currencies, also tend to have the most extensive and efficient credit systems. It’s certainly true that these same countries have often experienced significant distress from widespread failures and severe panics, but it’s important to remember that these bankruptcies are more often the result of mismanaged prosperity than of hardship. Overconfidence in people and things has led to speculation and triggered bankruptcies. And while it's argued that the excessive expansion of credit is responsible for many of our financial disasters, it's even more accurate to say that our drive for industrial success has always depended on the generous use of credit. The building of our railroads and canals, the operation of our mines, the improvement of our vast agricultural areas, the growth of our towns and cities, and the development of our extensive manufacturing sectors are all outcomes of the trust placed in individuals and the industries they represent.

THE IMPORTANCE OF A HIGH STANDARD OF CREDIT TO BUSINESS MEN

Reticence on the part of business men respecting their financial position may seriously impair their credit. It is universally regarded by the intelligent business man to be good policy to make known his condition. A refusal to do so throws a suspicion and doubt upon his financial[256] ability, and at some future time when confidence in his integrity may be essential to the very life of his business, he may find the necessary help unobtainable. An applicant for credit should be willing to prove himself worthy of it. But the keen competition among merchants eager for sales often enables the buyer to obtain credit without the necessity of giving very much evidence as to his commercial standing. Since some risks must be taken merchants frequently conclude to accept an account because of its possible acceptance by some competitor. If business is to be had risks must be taken, is the theory.

Holding back information about their financial situation can seriously damage business people's credit. Smart business owners know it's better to be open about their circumstances. If they refuse to share this information, it raises suspicion and doubt about their financial abilities. Later, when trust in their honesty is critical for their business’s survival, they might find it hard to get the help they need. Anyone seeking credit should be ready to show they deserve it. However, the intense competition among merchants wanting sales often allows buyers to get credit with little proof of their financial standing. Since some risks are unavoidable, merchants often decide to approve an account based on the chance that a competitor might accept it. The underlying belief is that if a business opportunity is available, some risks have to be taken.

When former customers apply for credit the merchant is guided by the record made in previous dealings. A business man's ledger is a very valuable history of credits. It is his compass in a sea of doubt. If upon the inspection of an old account it be discovered that in former years the customer paid cash and discounted his bills, and that later his method of payment was by promissory notes, and that on several occasions he asked for special favours, such as dating bills ahead or the privilege of renewal of notes, one is able to read a certain unmistakable sign of degeneracy in the customer's credit. New orders from such a customer will bear scrutiny; and a closer attention to the present condition of the account may save the firm from some bad debts.

When previous customers apply for credit, the merchant relies on their past interactions. A business person's ledger is a valuable account of credits. It serves as their guide in uncertain times. If an old account shows that in the past, the customer paid in cash and took discounts, but later switched to paying with promissory notes and frequently requested special favors like extending payment dates or renewing notes, it indicates a clear decline in the customer’s creditworthiness. New orders from such a customer should be examined closely, and a careful review of the current account status may help the business avoid potential bad debts.

While it is possible to-day to determine the average losses from bad debts in the various lines of business, individual risks cannot be accepted on that basis. Each requires special study. If an applying customer paints his financial condition in roseate colours, let him be willing to reduce his statement to writing, and when his signature is affixed his statement is much more reliable, because he knows of the impending liability of fraud if he has misrepresented. Men averse to transforming an oral[257] statement to writing have discredited themselves immediately. Men who mean to be honest may be optimistic in picturing prospects and be inclined to set an unreasonable value upon their property and extent of business. It may be easier to tell the absolute truth about one's liabilities, because they are such persistently real things; but assets have elastic qualities in many men's minds and seem capable of any extension in an emergency. Buyers who impress themselves most favourably upon the business house are frank in their statements. The explicit, candid man of few words will merit consideration. The cringing or pleading kind predisposes one unfavourably. Stephen Girard said of one who in tears asked for a loan: "The man who cries when he comes to borrow will cry when he comes to pay."

While today it’s possible to figure out the average losses from bad debts across different businesses, we can’t evaluate individual risks just based on that. Each one needs to be looked at closely. If a customer who wants to apply presents an overly positive picture of their financial situation, they should be willing to put their numbers in writing. Once they sign it, their statement becomes much more trustworthy because they know they could face serious consequences for fraud if they’ve misrepresented anything. People who hesitate to turn an oral[257] statement into writing immediately lose credibility. Those who intend to be honest might still be overly optimistic about their prospects and may assign too high a value to their assets and business. It’s often easier to be completely truthful about one’s debts since those are very real issues; however, assets can seem more flexible in many people's minds and may stretch beyond reality in times of crisis. Buyers who make a good impression on the business are straightforward in what they say. The clear, honest person who speaks minimally will earn respect. On the other hand, the timid or desperate type tends to leave a negative impression. Stephen Girard once remarked about someone who came to him in tears asking for a loan: "The man who cries when he comes to borrow will cry when he comes to pay."

To determine the right of a buyer to credit and the safe limit of credit to be extended to him is the seller's serious problem. It is customary to request references in order to discover how other firms regard the applicant's credit. But these references may be cautious of reply. A selfish desire to retain the customer for themselves, or the higher motive of a desire to be true to the interests of both the inquirer and the customer may produce dubious or very incomplete reports. If a bank be among the references one does not place too much stress upon a very favourable reply from it, because a merchant usually learns the lesson of expediency in making a friend of his banker. And, moreover, one endeavours to reveal only the best side of his business affairs to the bank. Favourable replies from several firms showing a uniform line of credit go a great way toward reaching a safe conclusion. But in these days of vast and multifarious interests there has developed, as a result of this desire for adequate knowledge respecting men's credit, an agency for the ex[258]clusive purpose of arriving at definite and reliable evidence upon financial matters; and after years of experience men have learned to depend upon these mercantile agencies as the most valuable and trustworthy assistants.

To figure out whether a buyer qualifies for credit and how much credit can be safely offered to them is a significant challenge for the seller. It's common to ask for references to find out how other companies view the applicant's creditworthiness. However, those references might hesitate to respond. A self-serving wish to keep the customer for themselves, or a genuine concern for both the inquirer's and the customer's interests, may lead to unclear or incomplete feedback. If a bank is among the references, one doesn’t put too much weight on a very positive reply from them, since a merchant tends to learn the importance of maintaining a good relationship with their banker. Additionally, one tries to present only the best aspects of their business dealings to the bank. Positive responses from multiple firms showing a consistent level of credit go a long way toward making a safe judgment. But today, with the complexity and variety of financial interests, an agency has emerged solely for the purpose of providing accurate and trustworthy information about financial matters; and after years of experience, people have come to rely on these mercantile agencies as some of the most valuable and dependable resources.

MERCANTILE AGENCIES

Mercantile agencies had their origin in the system adopted by several prominent firms of keeping on record all the information obtainable relating to their customers. In 1841 "The Mercantile Agency of New York City" began its history, and was the forerunner of the present great agencies whose record books of credits and ratings include the names of all the business houses and corporations in this country and Canada. The pioneer institution of this character in the United States was the one bearing at present the name of "R. G. Dun & Co.," an outgrowth of "The Mercantile Agency of New York City." Since 1860 it has borne the name of Mr. Dun, who was formerly a partner with Mr. Douglass when the agency was known as "B. Douglass & Co." Another popular and influential concern is the one known as "The Bradstreet Company," familiarly spoken of as "Bradstreet's." Besides these two leaders there are many others, whose reports on credits are limited to particular lines of trade. The larger agencies soon found it necessary to establish branches in all the business sections of the country. A particular field of investigation is allotted to each branch, and an interchange of information is in constant progress.

Mercantile agencies started from the practice of several leading firms keeping detailed records about their customers. In 1841, "The Mercantile Agency of New York City" was established, paving the way for today's major agencies whose credit and rating records include all business names and corporations in the U.S. and Canada. The first agency of this type in the United States is now known as "R. G. Dun & Co.," which evolved from "The Mercantile Agency of New York City." Since 1860, it has carried Mr. Dun’s name, who was previously a partner with Mr. Douglass when the agency was called "B. Douglass & Co." Another well-known and influential agency is "The Bradstreet Company," often referred to as "Bradstreet's." In addition to these two leaders, there are many others that provide credit reports focused on specific industries. The larger agencies quickly realized the need to set up branches in business hubs across the country. Each branch is assigned a specific area of research, and information sharing is continuously happening.

A mercantile agency inquiry form. A business agency inquiry form.

To be a recipient of the valuable information afforded by these agencies business men, by paying an annual fee, are enrolled as subscribers and furnished with books of ratings, as they are called. Besides this book special type-written reports with elaborate details respecting a[260] firm's credit are sent upon the request of the subscriber. The volume of information recorded in these agencies concerning any one's credit is obtained through the effort of officials of the agencies known as reporters. These men of experience, integrity, and discernment are seekers after truths. Usually each reporter has a distinct line of trade assigned him for research and investigation. This brings him into intimate acquaintanceship with every trader in his particular field. He is a constant solicitor of the banker and merchant for facts. His business is not merely to gather information respecting the resources of business men, but to investigate rumours that in themselves may be detrimental to one's credit, and to disprove them where possible and sustain and support the credit of a house. Too often it is supposed that the reporter is seeking evidences of weakness when in reality his business is most frequently that of discovering elements of strength. Information is freely given him as he interviews men whose businesses and experiences are the depositories for a wealth of credit information. He soon becomes a confidant of the merchant himself, who not only tells him all he knows about the customers and their accounts upon his books, but his own business affairs as well. Indeed, the relation becomes so very reciprocal that the reporter often furnishes information to the merchant in the interview on some matter of credit of pressing notice. In this way a corroboration of facts or the denial of a rumour may be effected. He inspects the books of the offices of public record to find the evidence of mortgages, judgments, and transfers of property, and have the same recorded on the agency's books. It is the reporter who finally has gathered the information that determines a firm's ability to have and to hold a line of credit.

To receive the valuable information provided by these agencies, businesspeople pay an annual fee to become subscribers and are given rating books, as they are called. In addition to this book, special type-written reports with detailed information about a[260] firm's credit are sent upon request from the subscriber. The extensive information recorded in these agencies about someone's credit is collected by officials known as reporters. These experienced, trustworthy, and perceptive individuals are truth-seekers. Typically, each reporter focuses on a specific line of trade for research and investigation, allowing them to become closely acquainted with every trader in that field. They consistently solicit information from bankers and merchants for details. Their job is not just to gather data about businesspeople's resources, but to look into rumors that could harm someone's credit, and to debunk these rumors when possible while supporting a company's credit. It's often assumed that the reporter is searching for signs of weakness when, in reality, their main task is usually to identify strengths. They receive plenty of information while interviewing individuals whose businesses and experiences hold valuable credit insights. They quickly become a confidant of merchants, who share not only what they know about their customers and accounts but also their personal business matters. The relationship often becomes so reciprocal that the reporter provides the merchant with information during the interview on some urgent credit issue. This way, facts can be confirmed or rumors can be denied. They examine the books of public record offices to find evidence of mortgages, judgments, and property transfers, and record this information in the agency's files. It is ultimately the reporter who compiles the information that determines a firm's ability to secure and maintain a line of credit.

It is essential to the life of the agency that its reports[261] be honest and free from any element of doubt. The public confidence in the reliability of the reports will determine the prosperity of the company. Perhaps at first glance it would seem as if the system of reporting financial information was a serious discrimination against the men of smaller capital and in favour of the wealthy. But mere capital is not the only element entering into an estimate of one's ability to pay. Character and reputation are powerful forces in assisting a merchant in determining credit. An agency discloses facts and not opinions. And it is within the range of possibility of any one to create and maintain his credit. Capital may grow gradually but credit is sometimes established or destroyed by a single act.

It’s crucial for the agency’s survival that its reports[261] are honest and completely free of doubt. Public trust in the accuracy of the reports will decide the company’s success. At first glance, it may seem like the system of reporting financial information unfairly favors wealthy individuals over those with smaller amounts of capital. However, wealth isn't the only factor in assessing someone's ability to pay. Character and reputation are significant influences in helping a merchant determine creditworthiness. An agency presents facts, not opinions. Anyone has the potential to build and maintain their credit. While capital may increase over time, credit can be established or ruined by a single action.

The facts obtained by mercantile agencies are not public property. They are given in confidence and for the sole purpose of aiding the business with respect to the propriety of granting credit. The private reports are for the eyes of the interested inquirer and not the curious. Whenever some particular item of interest finds its way to an agency that would affect one's credit seriously, such as the giving of chattel mortgage or the confession of a judgment or the sale and transfer of property, it is customary to send unsolicited a special report of these facts to all subscribers on the agency's books who have ever at any time made inquiry concerning the firm. One might expect that these agencies expose themselves to risk of prosecution for libel, but since no malice is ever intended in any report circulated, and since it rarely occurs that damaging reports are sent out by these institutions unless abundantly confirmed, there is little opportunity for litigation of this sort.

The information collected by business agencies isn't public knowledge. It's provided in confidence solely to help businesses decide whether to extend credit. The private reports are meant for interested parties, not the merely curious. Whenever a specific piece of information arises that could severely impact someone's credit—like the issuance of a chattel mortgage, a confession of judgment, or the sale and transfer of property—it's standard practice to send an unsolicited special report about these facts to all subscribers in the agency's records who have previously inquired about the business. One might think these agencies could face lawsuits for defamation, but because there’s never any malice intended in the reports shared, and because damaging reports are rarely distributed unless they are thoroughly verified, there’s not much risk of such litigation.

Another field of usefulness of the mercantile agency is in the exposure of the absconding debtor and his where[262]abouts, and also the dishonest trader who in arranging a fraudulent failure may be striving to open many new accounts. The unusual demands for reports respecting such a one lead to careful investigation. Instead of a restrictive tendency a mercantile agency promotes the expansion of credit and yet permits of proper conservatism. It opens to the trader as a market for his merchandise every new and trustworthy account. It curbs speculation, stimulates diligence in business, habituates punctuality, and develops character. When we remember that the present annual internal commerce of our country is estimated at about 800,000,000 tons of merchandise carried an average distance of 120 miles, and that this volume of trade is worth over $10,000,000,000, we are forced to admit that the unique system of these credit agencies has done much to further and make possible this commercial prosperity.

Another useful role of the mercantile agency is to expose the fleeing debtor and his whereabouts, as well as the dishonest trader who might be trying to set up multiple new accounts while falsely declaring bankruptcy. The unusual requests for reports about such individuals lead to thorough investigations. Instead of limiting opportunities, a mercantile agency fosters the growth of credit while still allowing for prudent caution. It provides the trader with every new and reliable account as a potential market for his goods. It curbs speculation, encourages hard work in business, promotes punctuality, and builds character. When we consider that the current annual internal commerce in our country is estimated at around 800,000,000 tons of merchandise transported an average of 120 miles, and that this trade volume is valued at over $10,000,000,000, we have to acknowledge that the unique system of these credit agencies has significantly contributed to this commercial success.

[263]IX. BONDS

UNITED STATES, STATE, AND MUNICIPAL BONDS

When a country borrows money it gives a guaranty that the money will be returned at a particular time and that interest will be paid at regular intervals at a fixed rate. This guaranty is called a bond. In actual practice, instead of borrowing the money required and then giving bonds for its return, countries usually issue the bonds first, and sell them to the highest bidder. For instance, if our government needed to borrow $1,000,000 it would issue bonds for this amount, stating definitely the rate of interest to be paid, and call for bids. If the rate of interest were four per cent. and a buyer paid more than $1000 for a $1000 bond he would, of course, make less than four per cent. upon his investment. Such bonds are absolutely safe and always marketable on account of our strong financial standing among the nations of the world. Similar bonds are issued by States, cities, towns, school districts, etc. They are not mortgages in the ordinary sense, and their worth consists entirely in the ability of the issuer through its taxing power to meet the obligations incurred. Municipal bonds are issued by cities and other municipalities to raise money for local improvements.

When a country borrows money, it guarantees that the funds will be repaid by a specific time and that interest will be paid regularly at a set rate. This guarantee is called a bond. In practice, instead of borrowing the necessary funds first and then issuing bonds for repayment, countries typically issue the bonds first and sell them to the highest bidder. For example, if our government needed to borrow $1,000,000, it would issue bonds for that amount, clearly stating the rate of interest to be paid and inviting bids. If the interest rate were four percent and a buyer paid more than $1,000 for a $1,000 bond, they would, of course, earn less than four percent on their investment. Such bonds are completely safe and always sellable due to our strong financial standing among the nations of the world. Similar bonds are issued by states, cities, towns, school districts, and so on. They aren't mortgages in the usual sense, and their value relies entirely on the issuer's ability, through its taxing authority, to meet the obligations it has taken on. Municipal bonds are issued by cities and other local governments to raise money for community improvements.

[264]BONDS AND CERTIFICATES OF STOCK

A bond is evidence of debt, specifying the interest and stating when the principal shall be paid; a certificate of stock is evidence that the owner is a part owner in the company, not a creditor of the company, and having no right to regain his money except by the sale of the stock or the winding up of the company's business. Bonds issued by stock companies and corporations are really mortgages upon their resources. Such a bond is usually secured by a mortgage upon the company's plant, franchises, and assets, or some part thereof. Corporate bonds can only be issued by the consent and direction of the shareholders of the company or corporation.

A bond is proof of a debt, detailing the interest and specifying when the principal will be paid back; a stock certificate shows that the owner is a part owner of the company, not a creditor, and they can only get their money back through selling the stock or if the company is dissolved. Bonds issued by stock companies and corporations essentially act as mortgages on their resources. Typically, such a bond is backed by a mortgage on the company's facilities, franchises, and assets, or some part of them. Corporate bonds can only be issued with the approval and direction of the company’s shareholders.

At the present time a mortgage securing the payment of corporate bonds is usually placed in the hands of a trustee—generally some trust company—which is supposed to act in behalf of the bondholders as a unit and which is empowered by the language of the bond, in the event of the failure of the corporation to perform the obligations it assumes in said bond, to foreclose the mortgage and divide the proceeds of sale among the bondholders.—Carroll.

Right now, a mortgage that secures corporate bonds is typically managed by a trustee—usually a trust company—that is meant to represent the bondholders as a group. This trustee is given the authority by the terms of the bond to foreclose the mortgage and distribute the sale proceeds among the bondholders if the corporation fails to meet its obligations outlined in the bond.—Carroll.

CLASSES OF CORPORATION BONDS

Corporation bonds are of many classes, differing widely in their value as securities. Only a few of the more important classes can be mentioned here. First mortgage bonds constitute, as the name implies, a first lien upon the property of the company issuing them. It is important in estimating the value of such securities to know whether they include only the property of the corporation at the time the bonds were issued or whether they are so worded as to include all property owned or acquired by the cor[265]poration. Second and third mortgage bonds are second and third liens. The interest upon second and third mortgage bonds is paid only after the interest upon first mortgage bonds is satisfied.

Corporation bonds come in many types, varying greatly in their value as investments. Only a few of the more significant types will be discussed here. First mortgage bonds represent, as the name indicates, a primary claim on the property of the company that issues them. When assessing the value of these securities, it’s crucial to understand whether they cover only the corporation's property at the time the bonds were issued or if they are phrased to include all property owned or acquired by the cor[265]poration. Second and third mortgage bonds are considered second and third claims. The interest on second and third mortgage bonds is paid only after the interest on first mortgage bonds has been covered.

When bonds are issued to take up and put into one fund all previously issued mortgage bonds, the new bonds are sometimes called consolidated mortgage bonds. Holders of previously issued bonds are not obliged to exchange them for any new securities.

When bonds are issued to combine all previously issued mortgage bonds into one fund, the new bonds are sometimes referred to as collateralized mortgage obligations. Holders of the previously issued bonds are not required to swap them for any new securities.

Income bonds are usually secured by a mortgage on the earnings of the corporation issuing them. Interest on such bonds must be paid before dividends are declared to stockholders. It is customary when such bonds are issued to set aside a percentage of the earnings as a sinking fund to meet the bonds at maturity.

Income bonds are typically backed by a mortgage on the corporate earnings of the company that issues them. Interest on these bonds has to be paid before any dividends are distributed to stockholders. It's standard practice when issuing these bonds to allocate a percentage of the earnings to a sinking fund to cover the bonds at maturity.

Bonds are issued against all conceivable kinds of securities. Not only are properties of many kinds used to issue bonds upon, but many kinds of bonds are often issued upon the same properties. This is especially true of railways, where mortgages of various kinds often lap and overlap in almost endless confusion.

Bonds are issued based on all sorts of securities. Not only are various types of properties used to issue bonds, but many different bonds are often issued against the same properties. This is especially common with railways, where different types of mortgages frequently overlap and create almost endless confusion.

SINKING FUNDS

Money set aside by a municipality or corporation to sink a debt at a certain future time is called a sinking fund. For instance, if a city should issue twenty-year bonds for $100,000 to secure money for street improvements the entire debt would fall due in twenty years, but to avoid having such a large amount fall due in one year, a proportional sum is set aside each year as a sinking fund—that is, to sink, or reduce, or wipe out the indebtedness when the bonds mature. Bonds are not paid in advance of maturity.

Money set aside by a municipality or corporation to pay off a debt at a certain future time is called a savings fund. For example, if a city issues twenty-year bonds for $100,000 to fund street improvements, the entire debt will be due in twenty years. To avoid having such a large amount due all at once, a proportional sum is set aside each year as a sinking fund—that is, to pay off, or reduce, or eliminate the debt when the bonds mature. Bonds are not paid off before they mature.

[266]INTEREST COUPONS

Specimens of interest coupons. Specimens of interest coupons. Interest coupon samples.

Most bonds have interest coupons attached. These are cut off and presented for payment as they mature. For instance, a four per cent. bond for $1000 would draw $40 interest yearly. This sum would be paid in two instalments of $20 each. If the bond were for twenty years there would be at the date of issue forty interest coupons, each calling for $20 and collectable at intervals of six months.

Most bonds come with interest coupons attached. These are clipped off and submitted for payment as they come due. For example, a 4% bond for $1,000 would earn $40 in interest every year. This amount would be paid in two installments of $20 each. If the bond was issued for twenty years, there would be a total of forty interest coupons at the issue date, each worth $20 and collectible every six months.

[267]X. TRANSPORTATION BY RAIL

THE GROWTH OF OUR RAILROAD SYSTEM

A railway map of the United States shows that most parts of our country have a thickly woven net of railroads. The mileage of our railroad lines is now 184,000 miles, the actual length of track on these roads being about 245,000 miles. The significance of these large figures becomes more manifest when a comparison is made between the length of our railroads and the length of those of Europe and those of the world. The railroads in the United States comprise over four ninths of the total railway mileage of the world, and are considerably longer than the railroads of all the countries of Europe combined. The facts are shown graphically by the following diagram:

A railway map of the United States shows that most areas of our country have a dense network of railroads. The total mileage of our railroad lines is now 184,000 miles, with the actual length of track on these roads being about 245,000 miles. The importance of these large figures becomes clearer when we compare the length of our railroads to that of Europe and the rest of the world. The railroads in the United States account for over four-ninths of the total railway mileage worldwide and are significantly longer than all the railroads in Europe combined. The facts are illustrated in the following diagram:

Mileage in Europe     155,000, Mileage in U. S. 184,000, Total for the World   434,000

The history of the construction of American railroads covers a period of seventy years. The greater part of[268] our mileage has been built since 1870. The following table and diagram illustrate the growth of our railway net during each decade:

The history of building American railroads spans seventy years. Most of[268] our mileage has been constructed since 1870. The table and diagram below show the expansion of our railway network over each decade:

Year 1830, 23 miles; 1840, 2,800; 1850, 9,000; 1860, 30,600; 1870, 53,000; 1880, 90,300; 1890, 163,600; 1898, 184,000.

It will be noted that the decades of most rapid railway development were the one from 1850 to 1860, following the discovery of gold in California, and the two between 1870 and 1890. We added 70,000 miles to our railway net between 1880 and 1890—a record that no other country has equalled. By 1892 we seem to have met the more urgent demands for new lines, and we are now annually building less than 2000 miles of new roads. The face value of the capital now invested in American railroads is $11,000,000,000. The number of persons employed in the railway service is 850,000.

It’s worth noting that the fastest growth of railways happened between 1850 and 1860, right after gold was found in California, and during the two decades from 1870 to 1890. We added 70,000 miles to our railway network between 1880 and 1890—a record that no other country has matched. By 1892, we had addressed the most pressing needs for new lines, and we are now building less than 2,000 miles of new tracks each year. The total amount of money now invested in American railroads is $11,000,000,000. The number of people working in the railway sector is 850,000.

THE RAILWAY CORPORATION

The agents that do the work of transportation by rail are the railway corporations. These "artificial persons"[269] are created by the several States and intrusted with the performance of services of a public nature. In all the German states and to a large degree in many other European states, the governments themselves provide the means of transportation by rail; but in the United States the ownership and management of the railroads is rightly regarded to be a task of greater magnitude than the administrative department of our government is as yet able to cope with.

The companies that handle transportation by rail are the railway corporations. These "artificial persons" [269] are established by the various states and entrusted with providing public services. In all the German states and to a large extent in many other European countries, the governments actually run the rail transportation; however, in the United States, the ownership and management of railroads is seen as a task too large for our government’s administrative department to handle effectively at this time.

The growth of the railway corporations of the United States has been typical of the evolution of industrial organisation in this country. The early railway corporations were small. The Philadelphia, Wilmington and Baltimore Railroad, for instance, comprised the lines of four companies. In 1850 the road connecting Albany and Buffalo included the lines of seven companies. During the last fifty years most of the small companies have united to form the corporations which now operate our large railway systems. Though the last statistical report of the Interstate Commerce Commission—the one for the year ended June 30, 1896—contains financial reports from 1985 companies, there were only 782 "independent operating roads," the remainder of the companies being subsidiary organisations. This report shows that forty-four of these operating companies have an aggregate mileage that equals nearly six tenths of the total railway mileage of the United States. Indeed, the statistician to the Interstate Commerce Commission declared in 1894 that "over 83 per cent. of the business of the railways and 82 per cent. of their earnings fall under the control of less than forty associations of business men."

The growth of railway companies in the United States has reflected the development of industrial organization in the country. The early railway companies were small. For example, the Philadelphia, Wilmington and Baltimore Railroad consisted of the lines of four companies. By 1850, the route connecting Albany and Buffalo included lines from seven companies. Over the past fifty years, most of the smaller companies have merged to form the corporations that now manage our large railway systems. Although the last statistical report from the Interstate Commerce Commission—the one for the year ending June 30, 1896—contains financial reports from 1985 companies, there were only 782 "independent operating roads," with the rest being subsidiary organizations. This report indicates that forty-four of these operating companies comprise nearly 60% of the total railway mileage in the United States. In fact, the statistician for the Interstate Commerce Commission stated in 1894 that "over 83 percent of the business of the railways and 82 percent of their earnings are controlled by fewer than forty business associations."

The Pennsylvania system affords a good concrete illustration of railway consolidation. That corporation, with its 9000 miles of road, was built up by the union of over 200 railroad companies, and it now comprises within its or[270]ganisation 177 corporations—most, though not all, of which are subsidiary railroad companies. This one railway system does one seventh of the entire freight business performed by all the railroads of the United States and handles one eighth of all the passenger traffic.

The Pennsylvania system provides a clear example of railway consolidation. This corporation, with its 9,000 miles of track, was formed by merging over 200 railroad companies, and it currently includes 177 corporations within its organization—most of which are subsidiary railroad companies. This single railway system accounts for one-seventh of the total freight business done by all the railroads in the United States and manages one-eighth of all passenger traffic.

THE FREIGHT SERVICE OF RAILROADS

The freight business of the railroads of the United States is much larger than their passenger service, the earnings from freight being nearly three times that from the passenger traffic. It is only in some of the New England States, the most densely populated parts of the United States, that the passenger receipts equal the freight earnings. The industrial conditions of the United States necessitate the movement of great quantities of bulky freight long distances. Our principal grain-fields are from 1000 to 1500 miles from the manufacturing districts and seaboard cities. Our richest iron deposits are in the States adjacent to Lake Superior hundreds of miles from the coal-beds of Illinois, Ohio, and Pennsylvania. Most of the cotton crop is moved long distances to reach the mills of New England and Great Britain. In fact, most of the products of our fields, forests, mines, and factories are marketed over wide areas. The average distance travelled by each ton of freight moved during the year ended June 30, 1896, was 124.47 miles; and, as the railroads carried 765,891,385 tons that year, the number of tons carried one mile was 95,328,360,278.

The freight business of the railroads in the United States is significantly larger than their passenger service, with freight earnings being nearly three times that of passenger traffic. It's only in some of the New England States, which are the most densely populated areas in the country, that passenger receipts match freight earnings. The economic situation in the United States requires the transportation of large amounts of bulky freight over long distances. Our main grain fields are located 1,000 to 1,500 miles away from manufacturing districts and coastal cities. Our richest iron deposits are in states near Lake Superior, which are hundreds of miles from the coal mines in Illinois, Ohio, and Pennsylvania. Most of the cotton crop is transported long distances to reach the mills in New England and Great Britain. In fact, most of the products from our fields, forests, mines, and factories are sold over wide areas. The average distance traveled by each ton of freight during the year ending June 30, 1896, was 124.47 miles; and since the railroads moved 765,891,385 tons that year, the total ton-miles was 95,328,360,278.

A comparison of the revenues received from the freight and passenger services by the American, German, French, and British railways is instructive. For each dollar received from the passenger traffic the American railroads earn $2.95 from their freight business, the German[271] roads $2.40, the French $1.31 and the British railways $1.17. The United Kingdom has the greatest volume of passenger traffic per population of any country in the world.

A comparison of the revenue generated by freight and passenger services among American, German, French, and British railways is enlightening. For every dollar earned from passenger traffic, American railroads make $2.95 from freight, German railways $2.40, French railways $1.31, and British railways $1.17. The United Kingdom has the highest volume of passenger traffic per capita of any country in the world.[271]

AMERICAN PASSENGER TRAFFIC ON RAILROADS RELATIVELY UNDEVELOPED

The long distances of the United States necessitate a large freight traffic but act as a hindrance to travel. It is a generally accepted but erroneous supposition that Americans travel more than any other people. A comparison of the passenger traffic in the United States with that in the United Kingdom, Germany, and France reveals some surprising facts. The figures are for 1896. The number of passengers carried one mile per mile of road upon the railroads of the United States was 71,705, in France the number was 273,315, in Germany 315,399, and in the United Kingdom 440,000. The average distance which the Briton travels per year by rail is 244 miles; for the American the distance is 209 miles, for the Frenchman 176 miles, and for the German 165 miles. The Englishman takes 24.4 trips per year on an average, the German 11.3, the Frenchman 9.6, and the American 8.2. Americans travel extensively, but it is evident from the foregoing comparisons that the possibility of developing the passenger service in this country has by no means reached its limit.

The vast distances in the United States require significant freight traffic but make travel more difficult. It's a common but incorrect belief that Americans travel more than anyone else. A comparison of passenger traffic in the United States with that of the United Kingdom, Germany, and France shows some surprising facts. The numbers are from 1896. The number of passengers carried one mile per mile of road on U.S. railroads was 71,705, while in France it was 273,315, in Germany 315,399, and in the United Kingdom 440,000. On average, a Brit travels 244 miles by rail each year; an American travels 209 miles, a Frenchman 176 miles, and a German 165 miles. The average Englishman makes 24.4 trips per year, the German 11.3, the Frenchman 9.6, and the American 8.2. While Americans do travel quite a bit, it's clear from these comparisons that there's still a lot of room to improve passenger service in this country.

RELATION OF TRANSPORTATION ON RAILROADS TO ECONOMIC ORGANISATION

The economic changes which have accompanied the great development of transportation that has taken place during the last fifty years have revolutionised our indus[272]trial and social life. Among the effects of developed transportation upon the economic organisation may be noted: First, that relations of producers and consumers have been fundamentally changed by placing a larger market at the service of both. Many classes of commodities are now bought and sold in a world market that were formerly restricted to local trade. Second, improved transportation has made the prices of commodities more uniform for different producers and consumers. The variations due to situation have been lessened. In a like manner there has been a decrease in those time variations in prices that result from changes in the supply of commodities. Improved transportation also makes prices lower—not only because it reduces the costs of moving the raw materials of manufacture and the finished products of industry, but also because it enables the merchant to turn his stock oftener and thus do business with less expenses for capital.

The economic changes that have come with the significant development of transportation over the last fifty years have transformed our industrial and social life. Among the effects of improved transportation on economic organization are the following: First, the relationships between producers and consumers have fundamentally changed by providing access to a larger market for both. Many types of goods that used to be sold only locally are now available in a global market. Second, better transportation has made prices for goods more uniform among different producers and consumers, reducing the impact of location on pricing. Additionally, there has been a decline in price fluctuations caused by changes in supply. Improved transportation also drives prices down—not only because it lowers the costs of moving raw materials and finished products, but also because it allows merchants to sell their inventory more frequently, reducing their capital expenses.

As a third effect of improved transportation may be mentioned the acceleration which it has given to the growth of cities. Cheap and efficient transportation has led manufacturers to locate their plants where they can command a large supply of labour and where they have the greatest advantages for the distribution of their products. The great manufacturing establishments are now located in Chicago, New York, Philadelphia, Pittsburg, and the other large cities. Conditions of transportation have become a stronger factor than even the location of the sources of raw materials in determining where an industry shall be established. The effect of the railroad upon the location of agriculture has been no less potent. The railroad has brought new agricultural regions into cultivation and destroyed the profits of cereal agriculture in many parts of the Eastern States.

As a third effect of better transportation, we can highlight the speed it has added to city growth. Affordable and efficient transportation has prompted manufacturers to set up their facilities in areas where they can access a large workforce and have the best advantages for distributing their products. Major manufacturing companies are now based in cities like Chicago, New York, Philadelphia, Pittsburg, and other large urban centers. The state of transportation has become a more significant factor than the proximity to raw materials in deciding where an industry should be established. The impact of the railroad on agriculture location has been equally strong. The railroad has opened up new agricultural regions and reduced the profits of cereal farming in many parts of the Eastern States.

Another important consequence of improved transpor[273]tation and communication has been that of bringing the nations of the world into closer economic and social relations. With the growing solidarity of the economic interests of the countries of the world, with the multiplication of the intellectual and other social ties that unite the nations, their political relations inevitably change, and for the better. Nothing is doing more to advance the attainments of the cherished ideal of international amity than is the development of transportation.

Another important outcome of better transportation and communication has been bringing the nations of the world into closer economic and social connections. With the increasing solidarity of the economic interests among countries, along with the rise of intellectual and other social ties that link nations, their political relations inevitably evolve, and for the better. Nothing is doing more to promote the goal of international friendship than the advancement of transportation.

[274]XI. FREIGHT TRANSPORTATION BY RAIL

THE ORIGIN OF RAILROAD TRAFFIC ASSOCIATIONS

The performance of the transportation services necessitates the co-operation of carriers. When the government owns and operates the railroads of a country they are managed by a single authority, and the different parts of the railway system are fully co-ordinated; but when the railroads are operated by a large number of independent corporations, co-operation can be secured only by means of traffic associations composed of representatives of the railway companies, and intrusted with the power of making arrangements affecting joint traffic, and settling questions involving the interests of two or more companies.

The effectiveness of transportation services relies on the cooperation of carriers. When the government owns and operates the country's railroads, they're managed by a single authority, ensuring that all parts of the railway system are fully coordinated. However, when railroads are run by numerous independent companies, cooperation can only be achieved through traffic associations made up of representatives from the railway companies. These associations are given the authority to make arrangements for joint traffic and address issues that involve the interests of two or more companies.

Two distinct causes brought about the establishment of railway traffic associations. The first cause was the necessity of co-operation to facilitate the joint business of connecting lines. Through tickets, joint fares and rates, through bills of lading, the interchange of cars between connecting roads, and the settlement of joint accounts led to the establishment of co-operative freight lines, car-service associations, claim associations, and various other general and local organisations for the promotion of the joint transportation business.

Two main reasons led to the creation of railway traffic associations. The first reason was the need for cooperation to streamline the shared business of connecting lines. Through tickets, joint fares and rates, bills of lading, the exchange of cars between connected roads, and the settlement of joint accounts resulted in the formation of cooperative freight lines, car-service associations, claim associations, and various other general and local organizations to promote joint transportation efforts.

[275]The other cause of co-operation among the railways was the necessity of regulating competition. This cause first became potent after the process of consolidation had brought about the formation of numerous large railway systems, and had inaugurated the violent competition which led to discriminations in transportation charges, rate wars, and the other evils which have combined to produce "the railway question." The competitive struggles of rival railway systems began to be violent shortly after 1867, and soon led to the formation of railway traffic associations, with enlarged powers. The classification of freight, the determination of rates on competitive traffic, and the apportionment of that traffic, or of the earnings from it, among the competitors became functions of the associations.

[275]The other reason for cooperation among the railways was the need to regulate competition. This need became significant after consolidation led to the creation of many large railway systems, which sparked intense competition resulting in unfair transportation charges, rate wars, and the various issues that together formed "the railway question." The competitive battles between rival railway systems became intense shortly after 1867, eventually leading to the establishment of railway traffic associations with expanded powers. These associations took on responsibilities like classifying freight, setting rates for competitive traffic, and distributing that traffic or the earnings from it among the competitors.

THE WORK OF ALBERT FINK

The man who did more than any other person to develop traffic associations and to promote the co-operation of competing railroads was the late Albert Fink. It was his master mind that organised and put into successful operation in 1876 the Southern Railway and Steamship Association. The following year Albert Fink succeeded in organising the great trunk lines connecting the North Atlantic seaboard and the States north of the Ohio River. Though smaller traffic associations similar to these two organisations had been previously established where but few obstacles had to be overcome, it was Fink who first organised traffic associations including all the competing railroads serving large sections of the country.

The man who did more than anyone else to develop traffic associations and encourage cooperation between competing railroads was the late Albert Fink. It was his brilliant mind that organized and successfully launched the Southern Railway and Steamship Association in 1876. The following year, Albert Fink managed to organize the major trunk lines connecting the North Atlantic coast and the states north of the Ohio River. While smaller traffic associations similar to these two had been set up before, where there were only a few challenges to tackle, it was Fink who first created traffic associations that included all the competing railroads serving large regions of the country.

In discussing the work of traffic associations, which are to-day concerns of really enormous magnitude, railway pooling and the classification of freight especially demand consideration.

In discussing the work of traffic associations, which are now matters of truly enormous scale, railway pooling and the classification of freight especially need attention.

[276]RAILROAD POOLING

Railroad pools are agreements entered into by competing carriers, by which the railroads provide for the division with each other of their competitive traffic, or of the earnings from that traffic in accordance with stipulated ratios. Thus there are traffic pools and money pools. During the decade preceding 1887, the year when the present interstate commerce law was enacted, most traffic associations had the pooling feature, and most of the competitive railway traffic was pooled, thus eliminating all competition in rates.

Railroad pools are agreements made by competing carriers, where the railroads agree to share their competitive traffic or the earnings from that traffic based on agreed-upon ratios. This results in both traffic pools and money pools. In the ten years leading up to 1887, the year the current interstate commerce law was established, most traffic associations included pooling, and a significant portion of competitive railway traffic was pooled, effectively removing competition in rates.

Pooling agreements have never been legal in this country. Being illegal by the common law, they could not be enforced in the courts. Section 4 of the interstate commerce law made it unlawful for the carriers subject to the act to pool their freights or the earnings from their freight traffic, and made it necessary for the traffic associations to reorganise without the pooling agreements. Until March 22, 1897, it was supposed that the associations, without pooling agreements, were legal; but, on that date, in the case of the United States vs. the Trans-Missouri Freight Association, the United States Supreme Court held that the law of July 2, 1890, popularly known as the Sherman anti-trust law, applied to railways, and made it illegal for railway companies to contract with each other to maintain rates. Thus at the present time traffic associations are permitted neither to contain a pooling feature nor to provide arrangements for the enforcement or maintenance of rates, although the charges may be reasonable and be sanctioned by all the carriers interested. The associations may now legally exercise those functions which are connected with the joint business of their members, and they may act as bureaus[277] of information regarding the competitive traffic. They have no power to make or to maintain rates.

Pooling agreements have never been legal in this country. Being illegal under common law, they couldn't be enforced in the courts. Section 4 of the interstate commerce law made it unlawful for the carriers covered by the act to pool their freights or the earnings from their freight traffic, and required traffic associations to reorganize without pooling agreements. Until March 22, 1897, it was thought that the associations, without pooling agreements, were legal; but on that date, in the case of the United States vs. the Trans-Missouri Freight Association, the United States Supreme Court ruled that the law of July 2, 1890, known as the Sherman antitrust law, applied to railways, and made it illegal for railway companies to contract with each other to keep rates. Thus, currently, traffic associations are not allowed to include a pooling feature or to create arrangements for enforcing or maintaining rates, even if the charges are reasonable and approved by all the involved carriers. The associations can now legally perform functions related to the joint business of their members, and they can act as bureaus[277] of information about competitive traffic. They have no authority to set or maintain rates.

TRAFFIC ASSOCIATIONS INCLUDING POOLING SHOULD BE LEGALISED

The best performance of the service of transportation by rail requires the fullest possible co-ordination of the different parts of our transportation system and the largest attainable measure of co-operation among the agents who perform the service. Section 4 of the act of 1887 and the law of July, 1890, as far as the latter relates to railways, are based on an unsound theory. Provision having been made for that kind and measure of governmental regulation of railway rates that will insure reasonable charges, the railways should be permitted to co-operate in rate-making and be given power to pool their competitive business.

The best performance of rail transportation services requires maximum coordination among the various parts of our transportation system and the highest level of cooperation among the people providing the service. Section 4 of the 1887 act and the law from July 1890, concerning railways, are grounded in flawed reasoning. Since there are already regulations in place to ensure reasonable railway rates, railways should be allowed to collaborate on rate-setting and have the authority to pool their competitive business.

CLASSIFICATION OF RAILROAD FREIGHT

There are thousands of varieties of freight offered to the railroads for transportation. If each class of commodities were charged the same freight rate per ton per mile, the charges upon many articles of prime necessity, such as coal, lumber, and grain, would be so high as to prevent their being moved, while the rates on goods of high value per bulk would be much lower than they could readily pay. Classification must precede the fixing of rate schedules. The railroads are interested in adjusting their charges to services performed in such a manner as to insure the greatest possible amount of traffic at rates that are properly remunerative. The public is interested in having the necessary revenues of the railroads so levied as to make the burdens as light as possible. To[278] accomplish this a careful grouping of commodities is necessary.

There are thousands of types of freight available for rail transportation. If every category of goods was charged the same freight rate per ton per mile, the costs for essential items like coal, lumber, and grain would be so high that it would prevent their shipment, while the rates for high-value but low-bulk goods would be much lower than they could easily afford. Classification must come before establishing rate schedules. Railroads want to adjust their charges based on the services provided to maximize traffic at rates that are fair. The public wants the railroads' revenue to be structured in a way that minimizes the financial burden. To[278] achieve this, a careful grouping of commodities is needed.

The goods are usually classified in five or six large divisions. The official classification referred to below has six classes. The first class consists of articles of high value, the sixth class of bulky commodities of low value, such as iron ore, lumber, grain in bulk, etc. In practice, however, the number of classes is at least doubled. Goods of especially high value are made to pay once and a half, double, treble or quadruple the regular first-class rate. A commodity is also frequently placed in more than one class, the rating of classification being lower for car-load lots than for less than car-load shipments. The classification is further extended by omitting certain articles from the list of those classified. Live stock and coal are illustrations of articles to which so-called "commodity," as distinct from "classification," rates are given. The individual shippers are constantly endeavouring to have their goods given commodity rates, and the effort of the railroad companies is to reduce the number of articles excepted from classification. Commodity tariffs have been a fruitful source of unjust discrimination.

The goods are typically grouped into five or six main categories. The official classification mentioned below has six classes. The first class includes high-value items, while the sixth class covers bulky low-value goods like iron ore, lumber, and bulk grain. In reality, though, there are at least double the number of classes. Items with particularly high value are charged one and a half times, two, three, or even four times the regular first-class rate. A product can also often fall into more than one class, with the classification rate being lower for full car-load shipments compared to smaller shipments. The classification is additionally expanded by excluding certain items from the list. Livestock and coal are examples of items that are given "commodity" rates, which differ from "classification" rates. Individual shippers are always trying to get their goods classified under commodity rates, while railroad companies aim to decrease the number of items excluded from classification. Commodity tariffs have often led to unfair discrimination.

From this description of freight classifications it will be perceived that the main basis upon which the grouping of commodities rests is the relative value of the goods. The gradations cannot, however, be made strictly according to value. The goods are frequently put into a lower class than their value would warrant in order to stimulate their production and shipment or to develop the industries depending upon those articles.

From this description of freight classifications, it’s clear that the primary basis for grouping goods is their relative value. However, the classifications can’t be made strictly based on value. Often, goods are placed in a lower class than their value would suggest to encourage their production and shipping or to support industries that rely on those items.

At first each railroad worked out a classification of its own, and there were practically as many classifications as there were railway systems. The disadvantages of this soon became apparent with the development of long-[279]distance traffic. The multiplicity of classifications made it difficult for shippers or purchasers to ascertain in advance what the charges on consignments would be; there was a constant tendency to increase the number of commodity tariffs, and unjust personal and local discriminations were in consequence made more numerous. It became evident that there would be great advantages in having one uniform classification for the whole United States. This ideal has not been reached yet, but the number of classifications has been practically reduced to three—the official, applying to the traffic north of the Potomac and Ohio and west of the Mississippi; the southern, in force among the railroads in the Southern States, and the western, which obtains in the territory west of the Mississippi River. This amalgamation of the classifications has been brought about chiefly by the traffic associations and as the result of the enactment of the interstate commerce law. In order to avoid the discriminations prohibited by that law it was necessary to abandon the system of a separate classification for each railway. It is to be hoped that the attainment of the ideal of uniform classification will not be long delayed.

At first, each railroad created its own classification system, and there were basically as many classifications as there were railway companies. The drawbacks of this quickly became obvious as long-distance traffic grew. The variety of classifications made it hard for shippers or buyers to know in advance what the charges for shipments would be; there was a constant push to increase the number of commodity tariffs, and unfair personal and local discriminations became more common as a result. It became clear that having one uniform classification for the entire United States would bring significant benefits. While this goal hasn't been achieved yet, the number of classifications has been reduced to practically three: the official one for traffic north of the Potomac and Ohio and west of the Mississippi; the southern one used by the railroads in the Southern States; and the western one that applies to the area west of the Mississippi River. This merging of classifications has mainly come about through traffic associations and as a result of the interstate commerce law being enacted. To avoid the discriminations prohibited by that law, it was necessary to drop the idea of having a separate classification for each railroad. We hope that achieving the ideal of uniform classification won't take much longer.

THE CONDUCT OF THE FREIGHT BUSINESS OF RAILROADS—TRANSPORTATION PAPERS

The manner in which the freight business is conducted affords a good illustration of the high degree of development to which modern business methods have attained. Freight is accepted by each railroad for shipment not only to all points on its own system, but also practically to every railway station in the country, and even to many foreign cities.

The way freight business is handled shows how advanced modern business methods have become. Each railroad accepts freight for shipment not just to all locations on its own network, but almost to every railway station in the country, and even to many cities abroad.

A waybill containing the initials of the number of the car used, the name of the consignor, the name and ad[280]dress of the consignee, the description and weight of the articles sent, the freight class and rate of the goods, and the total amount of freight charges, accompanies each shipment and is delivered to the agent at the place to which the goods are shipped.

A waybill that includes the car number, the consignor's name, the consignee's name and address, a description and weight of the items sent, the freight class and rate for the goods, and the total freight charges accompanies each shipment and is given to the agent at the destination where the goods are shipped.

For the goods thus accepted for transportation, manifests, or "bills of lading," are issued to the consignor, which, like other representatives of property, may be transferred by the owner or may be deposited in a bank subject to draft. Bills of lading are of two general kinds—"straight consignment bills" and "order bills." When a straight consignment bill of lading is issued the goods must be delivered to the consignee or to the person to whom he may order them delivered. An order bill of lading is one that may be transferred upon indorsement. The following concise description of an order bill of lading is taken from the "Book of General Instructions to Freight Agents," issued by the Pennsylvania Railroad Company:

For the goods accepted for transportation, manifests, or "bills of lading," are issued to the sender, which, like other proofs of ownership, can be transferred by the owner or deposited in a bank for withdrawal. Bills of lading come in two main types—"straight consignment bills" and "order bills." When a straight consignment bill of lading is issued, the goods must be delivered to the consignee or to whoever they designate. An order bill of lading can be transferred through endorsement. The following brief description of an order bill of lading is taken from the "Book of General Instructions to Freight Agents," issued by the Pennsylvania Railroad Company:

When freight is consigned to "Order" it is, as a rule, for the purpose of securing the payment at destination of a draft for the value of the property. The draft is usually attached to the bill of lading and sent through a bank for collection from the party at destination, who is to be notified of the arrival of the freight. The payment of the draft secures to the payer the possession of the bill of lading, which must be indorsed by the party to whose order the property is consigned.

When freight is sent to "Order," it’s usually to ensure that payment for a draft corresponding to the property’s value is collected at the destination. The draft is typically attached to the bill of lading and sent through a bank for collection from the recipient at the destination, who will be notified of the freight's arrival. By paying the draft, the payer gets possession of the bill of lading, which must be endorsed by the person to whom the property is consigned.

[281]XII. RAILROAD RATES

Transportation charges have such a general and vital relation to industrial and social welfare that the problem of the just and equitable distribution of their assessment is one of paramount economic and political consequence. A consideration of the main factors which influence the railway companies in fixing charges should precede a discussion of the regulation of transportation by the government.

Transportation costs have such a broad and essential impact on industrial and social well-being that figuring out a fair and balanced way to distribute these charges is critically important for our economy and politics. Before discussing how the government regulates transportation, we should look at the key factors that affect how railway companies set their prices.

GENERAL FACTORS WHICH DETERMINE RAILROAD RATES AND FARES

The factors which have most weight in fixing schedules of rates and fares are what it will cost to perform the several services, what the services are worth to those for whom they are to be rendered, and the extent to which there is competition among rival carriers to secure the traffic concerned. Though on the face of things it would seem that the railways should fix the charges for their various services in accordance with the costs of performing those services, it is neither practicable for them to do so nor is it desirable from the standpoint of public welfare[282] that such a criterion should be adopted. It is impracticable for the railroads to base their charges upon cost of service, because it is impossible to determine accurately the elements which enter into the cost of performing the particular transportation service. The modern railroad is a very complex mechanism, employed in the performance of a multitude of different services. No railroad official is able to say just how much of the company's total expenses are to be charged against any one particular freight or passenger service.

The main factors influencing the setting of rates and fares are the costs of providing various services, the value of those services to the people using them, and how much competition there is among different carriers for that business. While it might seem that railways should set their charges based on the costs of delivering those services, it's not practical or beneficial for public welfare to follow that approach. It's impractical for railroads to set prices according to service costs because it's impossible to accurately identify the components that make up the cost of a specific transportation service. Modern railroads are complex systems engaged in offering many different services. No railroad official can pinpoint exactly how much of the company's total expenses should be allocated to any single freight or passenger service.[282]

The cost of service would be an undesirable basis of rates, because the railroads would derive such a small part of their total necessary revenues from the carriage of goods having a high value in proportion to bulk and weight, that they would be obliged to charge much higher rates than they now do upon the cruder products of the farm, forest, and mine. These products are the basic materials of industry, and the lowest possible rate for their transportation is essential to social and economic progress.

The cost of service would be a bad basis for rates because the railroads would gain such a small portion of their total necessary revenue from transporting high-value goods in relation to their size and weight that they would have to charge much higher rates than they currently do for the more basic products from farms, forests, and mines. These products are the fundamental materials for industry, and having the lowest possible rate for transporting them is crucial for social and economic progress.

VALUE OF SERVICE AND VALUE OF COMMODITIES

Value of service is a more desirable basis for rates and fares than cost of service. By charging according to value of service is meant that the shippers of commodities and the passengers who travel shall contribute to the railroad's aggregate expenses in proportion to the value which they derive from the transportation service. The rates and fares may cover a part or all of the value of the service obtained. In either case they are fixed with reference to that value and not with regard to the cost involved in performing the work of transportation. The levy of rates and fares in accordance with this theory, which is usually called "charging what the traffic will bear," is considered by most people to distribute transpor[283]tation charges properly, because it is claimed that the true measure of a shipper's or a passenger's ability to pay for a desired service is the value which he will thereby derive. That this theory, nevertheless, does not afford an altogether satisfactory basis of charges, particularly in the freight traffic, may be readily shown.

The value of service is a better basis for rates and fares than the cost of service. Charging based on the value of service means that commodity shippers and travelers will contribute to the railroad's overall expenses in proportion to the value they receive from the transportation service. The rates and fares might cover part or all of the value of the service provided. In either case, they are set based on that value rather than the cost of providing the transportation. This method of setting rates and fares, often referred to as "charging what the traffic will bear," is widely seen as a fair way to distribute transportation costs because it is believed that the best measure of a shipper's or passenger's ability to pay for a service is the value they receive from it. However, it's clear that this theory does not provide a fully satisfactory basis for charges, especially in freight traffic.

While it is true that the amount of value added by transportation to goods of low value is less for each unit of weight or bulk than the amount of value which is acquired by an equal weight or bulk of high-priced commodities, yet the percentage increase in value is greater in the case of the goods of low cost. Expensive articles can be carried long distances without adding very much to their cost to the consumers. Measured in their percentages, then, the value of the service of transportation is relatively much lower in the case of the higher-priced commodities. The freight charges on wheat range from twenty to forty per cent. of its farm value, while the rate on shoes is possibly two per cent. of their factory price. That these charges are levied in accordance with the real ability of the articles to pay would be hard to establish.

While it's true that the value added by transportation for low-value goods is less per unit of weight or bulk compared to high-priced items, the percentage increase in value is greater for the low-cost goods. Expensive items can be transported over long distances without significantly increasing their cost to consumers. So, when looking at percentages, the value of transportation services is relatively much lower for higher-priced goods. Freight charges for wheat range from twenty to forty percent of its farm value, while the charges for shoes might be around two percent of their factory price. It would be difficult to prove that these charges are set based on the actual ability of the items to pay.

A PARTIAL THEORY OF RAILROAD FREIGHT RATES

Without attempting in this connection to formulate a complete theory of freight rates, it may be said that there are three factors to which weight should be given in fixing charges: First, the cost of service. The total costs of transportation, including a fair return on invested capital, must be covered by total receipts. Furthermore, the minimum rate charged any particular class of commodities ought to be sufficient to pay the operating expenses incurred in transporting the goods. Second, the value of the service. This fixes the maximum rate that may be charged. Were the railroads to charge more than the[284] service is worth to the shipper the service would not be desired. Third, the value of the commodities. Between the minimum rate fixed by the operating expenses and the maximum charge determined by the value of the service actual rates may vary through a wide possible range. In determining what rates within this range will be theoretically most just and least discriminatory, consideration should be given both to the value of the service and—more than is the case at present—to the value of the articles transported. By doing this rates will be paid by the various articles of freight more nearly in proportion to their ability to pay.

Without trying to create a complete theory of freight rates, it's clear that there are three factors to consider when setting charges: First, the cost of service. The total transportation costs, including a fair return on invested capital, need to be covered by total income. Additionally, the minimum rate charged for any specific category of goods should be enough to cover the operating expenses involved in transporting those goods. Second, the value of the service. This sets the maximum rate that can be charged. If railroads charged more than the[284] service is worth to the shipper, the service wouldn't be used. Third, the value of the commodities. Actual rates can vary widely within the range set between the minimum rate, based on operating expenses, and the maximum charge, determined by the value of the service. When figuring out what rates within this range would be the most fair and least discriminatory, there should be a focus on both the value of the service and—more than there is currently—on the value of the items being transported. By doing this, different types of freight will pay rates that are more in line with their ability to pay.

THE EFFECT OF COMPETITION ON RAILROAD RATES AND FARES

Whatever theory of rates may be accepted as ideally best, it cannot be strictly adhered to under the existing conditions of active competition obtaining in the United States. Actual charges have to be fixed and revised to meet the varying circumstances under which railway traffic is conducted. This competition takes several distinct forms. One is that between railways and waterways. A large part of the domestic traffic of the United States has the choice of transportation by rail or by water on the great lakes and the tributary canals, by the navigable rivers, or by one of the many ocean routes followed by our coastwise commerce. There is also the competition of rival railways connecting common termini or serving the same cities. These forms of competition are the ones most frequently noted; but they perhaps exercise a less potent influence over rates than what is known as competition through the markets or through the channels of trade. The competition between rival centres of commerce and industry—between the[285] Atlantic cities and the gulf ports, for instance, or between the manufactures of New York and Philadelphia and those of Chicago or Cincinnati for the markets of the Southern States, to cite another example—is a force that must be considered in making rates and fares. Even towns served by only one railway and by no waterway enjoy the benefits of this industrial competition. Unless the railroad can give the industries in these local towns rates that will enable them to market their products, the industries will decline and the railway will lose its traffic.

No matter which rate theory is considered ideal, it can't be strictly followed due to the active competition present in the United States. Actual charges need to be set and adjusted to accommodate the different situations in which railway traffic operates. This competition comes in several forms. One is between railways and waterways. A significant portion of domestic traffic in the U.S. can choose between transportation by rail or water on the Great Lakes and connected canals, along navigable rivers, or by various ocean routes used in our coastwise trade. There's also competition among rival railroads that connect the same destinations or serve the same cities. These types of competition are often mentioned, but they may have less impact on rates than what's known as competition through markets or trade channels. The competition between rival commercial and industrial centers—like between the Atlantic cities and Gulf ports, or between manufacturers in New York and Philadelphia versus those in Chicago or Cincinnati for the Southern States’ markets—is a factor that needs to be taken into account when setting rates and fares. Even towns that only have one railroad and no waterway benefit from this industrial competition. If a railroad can't offer rates that allow local industries to sell their products, those industries will struggle, and the railroad will ultimately lose its traffic.

An interesting result of the competition of roads connecting common termini or joining a common industrial region with seaboard points is that the road whose line is the longest and whose expenses of transportation are greatest is obliged to charge the lowest rate. The short lines can charge more because they compete for traffic under more favourable circumstances. The lower charge of the longer line is called a differential rate, and it is customary for the shorter or "standard" lines to agree to allow the "differential" line a stipulated differential rate. This is the concession which the standard lines are obliged to make to temper competition and to prevent rate wars. The Grand Trunk, running from Chicago to Boston by way of Montreal, is a good example of a differential line, and the New York Central is a good instance of a standard line.

An interesting result of the competition among roads that connect common destinations or link an industrial area to coastal points is that the road with the longest route and the highest transportation costs has to charge the lowest rates. Shorter routes can charge more because they compete for traffic under better conditions. The lower rates of the longer route are called a differential rate, and it's common for the shorter or "standard" routes to agree to give the "differential" route a set differential rate. This is the compromise that the standard routes have to make to ease competition and avoid rate wars. The Grand Trunk, which runs from Chicago to Boston via Montreal, is a good example of a differential route, while the New York Central serves as a solid example of a standard route.

GOVERNMENTAL REGULATION OF RAILROAD TRANSPORTATION

It is a maxim of common law that transportation charges must be reasonable, and the exaction of an unreasonable rate by a public carrier is a common-law misdemeanour punishable by the courts. But when, as the result of severe competition of railroads with waterways and with[286] each other, unjust discriminations between persons, between places, and as regards classes of traffic—the abuses which constitute the railway question—became prevalent, the common-law provisions applying to railway charges were given statutory form and were supplemented and extended by such legislation as the circumstances peculiar to the situation seemed to demand. The comprehensive railway- and canal-traffic act passed by Great Britain in 1854 has been the model adopted for much of the railway legislation in the United States.

It’s a principle of common law that transportation fees must be fair, and charging an unreasonable rate by a public carrier is a common-law offense that can be punished by the courts. However, due to intense competition between railroads and waterways, and among the railroads themselves, unfair discrimination against individuals, locations, and types of traffic—issues that define the railway problem—became widespread. As a result, the common-law regulations regarding railway charges were turned into statutory law and were expanded upon with additional legislation as needed for the specific circumstances. The comprehensive railway and canal traffic act passed by Great Britain in 1854 has served as the model for much of the railway legislation in the United States.

The Constitution of the United States gives Congress power to regulate commerce "among the several States," but the jurisdiction over intrastate traffic lies with the State governments. The States began to pass general laws for the regulation of railroads fully twenty years before Congress acted, and two thirds of the States have established commissions to administer those laws.

The Constitution of the United States empowers Congress to regulate commerce "among the several States," but the authority over intrastate traffic belongs to State governments. States started enacting general laws for railroad regulation a full twenty years before Congress took any action, and two-thirds of the States have set up commissions to oversee those laws.

THE INTERSTATE COMMERCE LAW

After fifteen years of agitation and investigation the existing interstate commerce law was enacted in 1887. The law prohibits unreasonable rates and unjust discriminations between persons, places, and classes of traffic, prohibits pooling agreements, provides penalties for the violation of the law, and establishes a commission of five men to administer and enforce the statute. Fortunately for the commission and for the country the first chairman of that body was the eminent jurist, Thomas M. Cooley, whose master mind did much to give vitality to the law.

After fifteen years of pressure and research, the current interstate commerce law was passed in 1887. The law bans unreasonable rates and unfair discrimination between individuals, locations, and types of traffic, prohibits pooling agreements, establishes penalties for violating the law, and creates a commission of five people to administer and enforce the statute. Luckily for the commission and for the nation, the first chairman of that group was the distinguished jurist, Thomas M. Cooley, whose brilliant mind contributed significantly to the law's effectiveness.

During the first five years after the law was passed it secured a fairly efficient regulation of interstate railway commerce, but recent decisions of the United States Supreme Court have so weakened the law that at present the commission has very little power. The commission[287] can investigate complaints and make reports, it can collect statistical information, it can and does informally adjust many differences between shippers and carriers; but, to quote from the last report of the commission, "it has ceased to be a body for the regulation of interstate carriers." Legislation to amend and strengthen the interstate commerce law is urgently needed.

During the first five years after the law was passed, it provided fairly effective regulation of interstate railway commerce, but recent rulings by the United States Supreme Court have weakened the law so much that the commission currently has very little power. The commission[287] can investigate complaints and make reports, collect statistical information, and informally resolve many issues between shippers and carriers; however, to quote from the commission's latest report, "it has ceased to be a body for the regulation of interstate carriers." There is an urgent need for legislation to amend and strengthen the interstate commerce law.

Judge Thomas M. Cooley. (First chairman of the interstate commerce commission.) Judge Thomas M. Cooley (the first chairman of the Interstate Commerce Commission).

[288]XIII. STOCK AND PRODUCE EXCHANGES

THE STOCK EXCHANGE

The stock exchanges of the world must not be considered simply as noisy congregations of brokers speculating in securities under the guise of legitimate business. They really play an important and necessary part in the financial mechanism of the country, and are instruments of enormous value in subdividing and distributing capital, and in directing its employment in great commercial and industrial enterprises.

The stock exchanges around the world shouldn’t just be seen as chaotic gatherings of brokers trading securities while pretending to engage in legitimate business. They actually play a vital and essential role in the country's financial system, serving as crucial tools for breaking down and distributing capital, and for guiding its use in major commercial and industrial projects.

The largest stock exchange of the world is that of London. It is not only the centre of the English market for stocks and securities but, like the Bank of England, it is linked internationally with nearly all the financial centres of the world. Almost every reputable security is marketable in London, either through the ordinary channels provided by arbitrage dealers, who buy in the cheaper and sell in the dearer markets, or through the agency of trusts and investment concerns. The magnitude and extent of the financial resources of the London Stock Exchange are enormous. Its advantages to the business public outweigh altogether the drawbacks imposed by the too-speculative spirit of mankind. It is a great business barometer, extremely sensitive to all con[289]ditions likely to disturb the world's finances. The London Stock Exchange has scarcely more than one hundred years of history. In the early part of the century the elder Rothschild was one of the giants "on 'change," and it was in this business that he amassed the great fortune which makes the name of his house a synonym for money power. The membership of the London exchange is not limited to a fixed number, as in Paris and New York. In the Paris Bourse all agents are strictly forbidden to trade on their own account.

The largest stock exchange in the world is located in London. It’s not only the center of the English market for stocks and securities, but like the Bank of England, it’s connected internationally with nearly all the financial hubs across the globe. Almost every reputable security can be traded in London, either through regular channels managed by arbitrage dealers, who buy in cheaper markets and sell in more expensive ones, or via trusts and investment firms. The scale and scope of the financial resources of the London Stock Exchange are massive. Its benefits to the business community far outweigh the downsides brought on by people's overly speculative nature. It serves as a critical business indicator, highly attuned to any conditions that could disrupt the world’s finances. The London Stock Exchange has only been around for just over a hundred years. In the early part of the century, the elder Rothschild was one of the key figures "on 'change," and it was in this business that he built the immense fortune that made his name synonymous with financial power. The membership of the London exchange isn't capped like it is in Paris and New York. In the Paris Bourse, all agents are strictly prohibited from trading on their own behalf.

The Paris Bourse. The Paris Stock Exchange.

The New York Stock Exchange was formed in 1792. There are 1100 members. Members are elected and must be nominated by two men who will say that they would accept the uncertified cheque of the nominee for $20,000.[290] The initiation fee is $20,000. Memberships have sold as high as $32,500, and the market value of a seat on the Exchange varies only slightly from year to year.

The New York Stock Exchange was established in 1792. It has 1,100 members. Members are elected and must be nominated by two people who will vouch for accepting the nominee's uncertified check for $20,000.[290] The initiation fee is $20,000. Memberships have sold for as much as $32,500, and the market value of a seat on the Exchange changes only slightly from year to year.

Interior view of New York Stock Exchange. Interior view of the New York Stock Exchange.

There are stock exchanges in all large cities, and scattered throughout the country in convenient centres are grain and produce exchanges, cotton exchanges, petroleum exchanges, etc. These exchanges are really the central markets for the commodities they represent. Commodity exchanges deal in actual products, even though the dealers handle nothing but warehouse receipts or promises to deliver. Stock exchanges deal in credits[291] and securities, which may or may not have a tangible value back of them.

There are stock exchanges in every major city, and you'll find grain and produce exchanges, cotton exchanges, petroleum exchanges, and more in various convenient locations across the country. These exchanges are basically the central markets for the commodities they represent. Commodity exchanges trade in real products, even if the dealers are only dealing with warehouse receipts or promises to deliver. Stock exchanges trade in credits[291] and securities, which may or may not have real value behind them.

There is no reason why bonds and shares should not be publicly dealt in—and in large quantities—as well as dry goods, corn or cotton; but, unfortunately, few stock exchanges confine their transactions wholly to legitimate business. You will look in vain in the quotations for the stock of dozens of corporations whose securities are among the choicest investments. It is upon fluctuations that stock speculations prosper, and it is often true that the largest profits are made on the poorest stocks.

There’s no reason why bonds and stocks shouldn’t be traded publicly—in large numbers—just like dry goods, corn, or cotton; but, unfortunately, few stock exchanges limit their transactions to legitimate business. You’ll search in vain among the quotes for the stock of many corporations whose securities are some of the best investments. Stock speculations thrive on fluctuations, and it’s often the case that the biggest profits come from the worst stocks.

Transactions are quickly collected and reported to the world. In hundreds of offices in New York, Chicago, and other American cities may be seen a little instrument called a ticker, which automatically prints abbreviated names of stocks, with their prices, on a narrow ribbon of paper. These tickers are rented to these offices by the telegraph companies, and as fast as the sales are made the quotations are ticked off in thousands of offices in all parts of the United States.

Transactions are quickly gathered and shared with the world. In hundreds of offices in New York, Chicago, and other American cities, you can find a small device called a ticker, which automatically prints shortened names of stocks along with their prices on a narrow strip of paper. These tickers are rented to these offices by the telegraph companies, and as soon as sales are made, the price updates are noted in thousands of offices across the United States.

TECHNICAL TERMS OF STOCK EXCHANGES

The term bull is applied to those who are purchasers of stock for long account, with the purpose of advancing prices, as the tendency of a bull is to elevate everything within his reach. The term bear is applied to those who sell short stock, with the purpose of depreciating values. The bear operates for a decline in prices. The broker's charge for his services is called a commission, which in the New York Stock Exchange is one eighth of one per cent. each way on a par value of the security purchased or sold. A point means one per cent. on the par value of a stock or bond. Stock privileges or puts and calls are extensively dealt in abroad and to some extent here. A put is an[292] agreement in the form of a written or printed contract filled out to suit the case, whereby the signer of it agrees to accept upon one day's notice, except on the day of expiration, a certain number of shares of a given stock at a stipulated price. A call is the reverse of a put, giving its owner the right to demand the stock under the same conditions. A put may serve as an insurance to an investor against a radical decline in the value of stocks he owns; a call may be purchased by a man whose property is not immediately available, but who may desire to be placed in a position to procure the shares at the call price, if they are not below that in the open market when he secures the necessary funds. The speculator usually trades on margins. If he has $500 to invest he buys $5000 worth of stock, his $500 being ten per cent. of the total amount. He expects to sell again before the remaining amount falls due. The margin is usually placed by the speculator in the hands of a broker as a guaranty against loss. Although these brokers are really agents for others, yet on 'change they stand in the mutual relationship of principals. A margin is merely a partial payment, but a broker buying stock for a client on margin is compelled to wholly pay for it. If he has not the necessary capital his usual custom is to borrow from banks or money-lenders, pledging the stock as collateral security. In foreign exchanges the element of credit enters more largely into the conduct of business. Where the credit of the client in London is established his broker does not, ordinarily, call on him for any cash until the next "settlement day." A wash sale is a fictitious transaction made by two members acting in collusion for the purpose of swelling the volume of apparent business in a security and thus giving a false impression of its value. Stocks sell dividend-on between the time the dividend is declared and the day the books of the company close for transfer; after that they sell[293] ex-dividend, in which case the dividend does not go to the buyer. When a company decides not to declare a dividend it is said to pass its dividend. To sell stock buyer 3 is to give the buyer the privilege of taking it on the day of purchase or on any of the three following days, without interest; and to sell stock seller 3 is to give the seller the privilege of delivering it on the day of purchase or on any one of the three following days without interest. Buyer 3 is a little lower and seller 3 a little higher than regular way when the market is in a normal condition. Bucket shops are establishments conducted nominally for the transaction of a stock-exchange business but really for the registration of bets or wagers, usually for small amounts, on the rise or fall of the prices of stocks, there being no transfer or delivery of the commodities nominally dealt in. There are thousands of these counterfeit concerns throughout the country conducted without any regard for legitimate commercial enterprises.

The term bull refers to people who buy stocks for the long term, aiming to drive up prices, since a bull's tendency is to elevate everything within reach. The term bear refers to those who sell stocks short, intending to lower values. A bear seeks a decline in prices. The broker's fee for their services is called a commission, which on the New York Stock Exchange is one-eighth of one percent for each transaction based on the security's par value. A point means one percent of a stock's or bond's par value. Stock privileges or puts and calls are commonly traded overseas and to some extent here. A put is an agreement, in the form of a written or printed contract tailored for the situation, in which the signer agrees to accept a certain number of shares of a specified stock at a set price, with one day's notice, except on the expiration day. A call is the opposite of a put, granting its owner the right to demand the stock under the same terms. A put can act as insurance for an investor against a major drop in the value of their stocks; a call can be bought by someone whose funds aren't immediately available but wants the option to acquire shares at the call price if they haven't dropped below that in the open market when they have the cash. Speculators typically trade on margins. If they have $500 to invest, they can purchase $5,000 worth of stock, with their $500 being ten percent of the total. They plan to sell before the remaining amount comes due. The margin is usually held by the broker as a guarantee against loss. Although brokers are essentially agents for others, on the trading floor, they act as principals to each other. A margin is just a partial payment, but a broker buying stocks for a client on margin must pay for it entirely. If they don't have the necessary capital, they generally borrow from banks or money-lenders, using the stock as collateral. In foreign exchanges, credit plays a larger role in business operations. If a client's credit in London is established, their broker usually won’t require cash until the next "settlement day." A wash sale is a fake transaction between two members colluding to inflate the appearance of business volume in a stock, creating a misleading impression of its value. Stocks trade dividend-on between the declaration of a dividend and when the company's books close for transfer; after that, they sell ex-dividend, meaning the buyer doesn't receive the dividend. When a company opts not to declare a dividend, it is referred to as passing its dividend. Selling stock buyer 3 allows the buyer to take it on the purchase day or within the next three days without interest, while selling stock seller 3 gives the seller the option to deliver it on the purchase day or within the following three days without interest. Buyer 3 is slightly lower and seller 3 is slightly higher than regular way when the market is stable. Bucket shops are businesses that are supposedly for stock exchange transactions but exist mainly for placing bets or wagers, usually for small amounts, on stock price movements, without any actual transfer or delivery of the traded commodities. Thousands of these fraudulent operations are spread across the country, operating without regard for legitimate business practices.

FUTURE DELIVERY

Grain is stored in warehouses until needed for milling or shipment. When we speak of December wheat we mean wheat that is to be delivered to the buyer in December. The carrying charges include storage, interest, and insurance, so that wheat sold for May delivery would necessarily bring a higher price than wheat sold for December delivery. Carrying charges are in favour of the short seller. When sold for immediate delivery it is known as cash grain.

Grain is kept in warehouses until it's needed for milling or shipping. When we talk about December wheat, we’re referring to wheat that will be delivered to the buyer in December. The carrying costs include storage, interest, and insurance, meaning that wheat sold for May delivery would generally have a higher price than wheat sold for December delivery. Carrying costs benefit the short seller. When sold for immediate delivery, it’s called cash grain.

[294]XIV. STORAGE AND WAREHOUSING

BONDED WAREHOUSES

There is a government regulation that an importer who does not wish to pay immediately the customs duties on his goods may have them stored in a warehouse, provided he furnish a bond with a surety that he will pay the duty within three years or export the goods to some other country. It is also a requisite that the goods be deposited in a bonded warehouse in the care and custody of its proprietor, who also must furnish the government with a bond of indemnity. The bond of the proprietor is a general bond and usually covers what might be considered a fair amount of total values due the government at any time. Officers of the United States are stationed at the bonded warehouse during business hours. These are there in evidence of the government's proprietary interest in the merchandise stored. When an importer makes entry at the custom house for bonding his goods, he at that time provides the security required.

There’s a government rule that allows an importer who doesn’t want to pay customs duties right away to store their goods in a warehouse, as long as they provide a bond with a guarantor that ensures they will pay the duty within three years or export the goods to another country. It’s also necessary for the goods to be kept in a bonded warehouse under the supervision of its owner, who must also provide the government with a bond for indemnity. The owner’s bond is a general bond that usually covers what would be considered a reasonable amount of total values owed to the government at any time. U.S. officers are present at the bonded warehouse during business hours. Their presence shows the government’s ownership interest in the stored merchandise. When an importer registers at the customs office to bond their goods, they provide the necessary security at that time.

By a recent decision of the Treasury Department at Washington goods in bond are in the joint custody of the United States government and the proprietor of the warehouse, and after the government has received its customs duties for the goods they are in the proprietor's[295] sole possession. The government cannot interfere to enforce delivery of the goods to the importer. The claim of the warehouse proprietor for storage charges becomes a first lien after the government's claim is satisfied. When the importer has paid both customs and storage charges he is privileged to remove his goods.

By a recent decision from the Treasury Department in Washington, goods in bond are jointly held by the United States government and the warehouse owner. Once the government has collected its customs duties for the goods, they are solely in the warehouse owner's[295] possession. The government cannot intervene to make the goods available to the importer. The warehouse owner's claim for storage fees takes priority after the government's claim is settled. When the importer has paid both the customs and storage fees, they are allowed to take their goods.

WAREHOUSE REGULATIONS

It is the duty of United States storekeepers to check off the goods as they are received at the warehouse and to report the same to the custom house; and when goods are to be withdrawn to see that delivery is not made until a custom house permit is presented. Upon payment of the import duty on goods in bond at the custom house at any time after importation, the customs officials issue a warehouse permit to the importer ordering the United States storekeeper in charge of the bonded warehouse to deliver the goods to the importer, and upon presentation of the permit the goods are released unless the proprietor holds them subject to storage charges.

It is the responsibility of United States storekeepers to check off goods as they arrive at the warehouse and report this to the customs office; and when goods are to be picked up, they must ensure that delivery is not made until a customs permit is presented. After paying the import duty on goods held in bond at the customs office anytime after importation, customs officials issue a warehouse permit to the importer, instructing the United States storekeeper in charge of the bonded warehouse to release the goods to the importer. Upon presenting the permit, the goods are released unless the owner holds them subject to storage fees.

Goods may be held in bond for three years with the duty unpaid, but after that time either the duty must be paid or the goods exported. If shipped to another country and afterward re-imported the goods would again be entitled to the three-year privilege. If goods are not exported and the customs charges are due and unpaid, the government may dispose of the goods at public sale to obtain its claim.

Goods can be held in bond for three years without paying the duty, but after that, either the duty needs to be paid or the goods must be exported. If they are shipped to another country and then brought back, they can again be held under the three-year rule. If the goods aren't exported and customs charges are due and unpaid, the government can sell the goods at a public auction to recover its claim.

Goods arriving by steamer and unclaimed lie at the wharf forty-eight hours. If the owner does not appear to make entry for them within that time, after the entry for the vessel has been made, the goods are sent to a bonded warehouse and remain there on what is known as a general order, and if they stand there unclaimed for[296] a year they may, at the expiration of that time, be sold by the government.

Goods that arrive by steamer and are unclaimed sit at the wharf for forty-eight hours. If the owner doesn't show up to claim them within that time, after the vessel's entry has been completed, the goods are sent to a bonded warehouse and stay there under a general order. If they remain unclaimed for[296] a year, the government may sell them after that period.

The capital of a warehouse is its storage space. The rates vary from ¼ to ¾ of a cent per cubic foot. The charges may be based on the amount of space consumed and the weight of the merchandise. The latter often determines the floor elevation to which the goods may be assigned. The more convenient of access the storage location is, the greater the cost. Warehouse receipts are issued as evidence of storage. All merchandise is conveniently bulked for numbering and marking, and these distinguishing marks appear on the receipts. Negotiable and non-negotiable receipts are issued as the needs of the owner may require. The former permit advances to be made by bankers upon the merchandise as collateral security.

The main asset of a warehouse is its storage space. The rates range from ¼ to ¾ of a cent per cubic foot. The charges might depend on the space used and the weight of the goods. The weight often determines which floor level the items can be stored on. The more accessible the storage area is, the higher the cost. Warehouse receipts are provided as proof of storage. All goods are efficiently grouped for numbering and labeling, and these labels are shown on the receipts. Negotiable and non-negotiable receipts are issued based on the owner's needs. The negotiable ones allow banks to give loans against the merchandise as collateral.

FREE WAREHOUSES

These differ from bonded warehouses only in the fact that the government has no control or interest in them. They are only for the storage of imported goods on which the customs duty has been paid or for goods imported free of duty or for merchandise of domestic production and manufacture. They are managed entirely by the proprietor, and the contracts for storage are, of course, between the proprietor of the warehouse and the owner of the goods. The storage rates in free warehouses are considerably lower than for goods stored in bonded warehouses—the latter being a much more expensive business to conduct. There is no time limit in free warehouses. Goods may remain indefinitely. When they remain from six months to a year the charges are collected usually at certain periods to avoid accumulation. Experience shows that goods in free warehouses do not stay so long as those in bond. The articles com[297]monly found in these houses are domestic and imported wools, cotton, canned goods, peanuts, yarns, cotton piece goods, mattings, dry goods, etc. Perishable goods, of course, do not find their way into bonded or free warehouses. These are placed in cold storage.

These differ from bonded warehouses in that the government has no control or interest in them. They are solely for storing imported goods on which customs duty has been paid, for goods imported duty-free, or for merchandise made domestically. They are entirely managed by the owner, and storage contracts are between the warehouse owner and the goods' owner. The storage rates in free warehouses are significantly lower than those for goods stored in bonded warehouses since the latter is a much more expensive operation. There’s no time limit in free warehouses; goods can stay indefinitely. When items remain for six months to a year, charges are usually collected at specific intervals to prevent accumulation. Experience shows that goods in free warehouses don’t stay as long as those in bonded warehouses. Common items found in these facilities include domestic and imported wools, cotton, canned goods, peanuts, yarn, cotton textiles, matting, dry goods, etc. Perishable goods, of course, don't go into bonded or free warehouses; they're put in cold storage.

BANKING FEATURES OF WAREHOUSING

Many of the warehouses find it advantageous to do a banking business in connection with the storage features. Very frequently, for the convenience of the importer, goods are consigned to the warehouse and sent subject to a sight draft for the amount of the invoice. The warehouse company will pay the draft with the exception of about twenty per cent., which the importer is expected to furnish. If the duty is paid then the value upon which a loan is estimated is based upon the market value of the goods in this country. After the draft has been satisfied the goods are placed in the stores of the warehouse company subject to the customs and storage charges. The amount advanced by the company bears interest at current money rates. In illustration let us suppose bonded goods to be shipped and invoiced at $10,000, customs duty $4000, and the goods consigned to a bonded warehouse. The draft ($10,000) is sent to the warehousing company, which advances $8000, and together with the $2000 received from the importer pays the draft. The $8000 loan made by the company is then charged to the importer at the usual interest rate, and when the borrower withdraws his merchandise from storage he will have to pay the government the $4000 customs duty and pay back his loan of $8000 to the warehouse company, together with interest and storage charges. If any portion of the goods stored is withdrawn for use in the business of the importer, the company will rebate a[298] proportionate amount of the interest. If goods decline in value as collateral in storage the company will demand additional margin for its protection. If goods appreciate in value the loan may be increased. The market value of the goods is ascertained by the appraisement of some expert, who receives a commission for his services.

Many warehouses find it beneficial to offer banking services along with their storage options. Often, for the importer’s convenience, goods are sent to the warehouse and released with a sight draft for the invoice amount. The warehouse company will pay the draft except for about twenty percent, which the importer needs to cover. If the duty is paid, the loan amount is based on the market value of the goods in this country. Once the draft is paid, the goods are stored in the warehouse, subject to customs and storage fees. The amount advanced by the company accrues interest at current market rates. For example, let's say bonded goods are shipped and invoiced at $10,000, with customs duty of $4,000, and the goods are sent to a bonded warehouse. The draft ($10,000) goes to the warehousing company, which advances $8,000, and along with the $2,000 from the importer, pays the draft. The $8,000 loan from the company is then charged to the importer at the usual interest rate. When the borrower takes their merchandise out of storage, they must pay the government the $4,000 customs duty and repay the $8,000 loan to the warehouse company, along with interest and storage fees. If any part of the stored goods is withdrawn for the importer’s business use, the company will rebate a[298] proportionate amount of the interest. If the value of the goods declines while in storage, the company will require additional margin for protection. If the goods increase in value, the loan may be raised. The market value of the goods is determined by an appraisal from an expert, who earns a commission for their services.

COLD STORAGE

The cold-storage warehouse is the natural result of the necessities of our great agricultural interests in the preservation of perishable products so sensitive to the deteriorating effects of temperature. The solution of the problem of the preservation of dairy products, meats, fish, poultry, fruits, and vegetables has developed a system that has eliminated the seasons and made possible the equalisation of prices of the finer class of edibles. The cornering of products and the creation of unreasonable prices are avoided. No article becomes a glut on the market as formerly. When there is a surplus of eggs and fruit, prices may be maintained by putting them in cold storage for a few days and offering them on the market when the conditions of trade warrant.

The cold-storage warehouse is a direct response to the needs of our major agricultural industries in maintaining perishable products that are so affected by temperature changes. The solution to preserving dairy products, meats, fish, poultry, fruits, and vegetables has led to a system that removes the restrictions of seasons and allows for price stabilization of high-quality foods. The monopolizing of products and the creation of inflated prices are prevented. No item ends up overstocked in the market like before. When there’s an excess of eggs and fruit, prices can be kept steady by storing them in cold storage for a few days and then selling them when market conditions are more favorable.

TEMPERATURE REQUIREMENTS FOR COLD STORAGE

Prior to the year 1890 cold storage was dependent upon the employment of ice, but in the evolution of the cold-storage warehouse ice is no longer a requisite. In fact, the temperature obtained by the employment of ice precluded a thermometric register much below the freezing point. The accepted temperature for butter and eggs was formerly 40° to 50°; but through the introduction of mechanical refrigeration, which has revolutionised the business economically as well as physically, eggs now[299] are held in storage at a temperature of 31° and butter from 10° to 18°. Under the former method of ice storage, goods that were offered on the market as "held goods"—that is, as coming from a cold storage—always brought several cents under the prices of fresh merchandise. But the remarkable modern methods of cold storage permit the carrying of dairy products for a number of months and their successful sale afterward in competition with fresh goods. Eggs stored in March are taken out in the following November and have commanded as high and often higher prices than the fresh commodity. Eggs have been kept two years and found perfectly sweet when used. In freezing poultry and fish the temperature now frequently given is zero and under. Poultry does not carry so well as other merchandise. Although it is possible to keep it for two years, yet it loses its flavour. Five or six months' storage is its usual average limit.

Before 1890, cold storage relied on ice, but now, ice isn't needed in cold-storage warehouses. Actually, the temperature from using ice couldn’t go much below freezing. The ideal temperature for butter and eggs used to be between 40° and 50°, but with mechanical refrigeration— which has changed the industry both economically and physically— eggs are now stored at 31° and butter at 10° to 18°. In the past, products labeled as "held goods" from cold storage were sold for several cents less than fresh products. However, today’s advanced cold storage methods allow dairy products to be stored for months and sold successfully alongside fresh goods. Eggs stored in March can be sold the following November, often fetching equal or higher prices than fresh ones. Eggs have been stored for two years and were still perfectly good when used. For freezing poultry and fish, temperatures are often at zero or lower. Poultry, however, does not store as well as other products. While it can be kept for two years, it tends to lose its flavor. Usually, its average storage limit is five or six months.

Certain temperatures are maintained in the various compartments of a cold-storage warehouse according to the requirements of the products, and these temperatures are made possible by forcing through pipes arranged around each compartment a brine composed of about ninety-five per cent. of pure salt whose temperature has been reduced by the action of the chemicals. When a shipper stores his goods there is an implied contract with the storage company that the temperature required for the product will be furnished and maintained. Failure to do this renders the company liable for any damage to property. So vital is this feature of the business, which is really the only liability assumed by the company, that the custom prevails of taking the temperature of each room as often as five times in every twenty-four hours, and keeping the record in temperature books open to the inspection of the shippers. A room filled with merchandise may not vary in temperature one degree in six months.

Certain temperatures are maintained in the different areas of a cold-storage warehouse based on the needs of the products, and these temperatures are achieved by circulating a brine made up of about ninety-five percent pure salt through pipes arranged around each area. This brine’s temperature is lowered through chemical processes. When a shipper stores their goods, there is an implied contract with the storage company that the necessary temperature for the product will be provided and kept stable. If the company fails to do this, they can be held responsible for any damage to the goods. This aspect of the business is so crucial—being the only liability the company takes on—that it’s common practice to check the temperature of each room up to five times every twenty-four hours and keep a log of these readings in temperature books that are accessible for shippers to review. A room filled with merchandise may not have a temperature variation of even one degree over six months.

[300]COLD-STORAGE CENTRES

Chicago very naturally is the leading cold-storage centre. Its situation in the heart of the productive area and its advantages as a distributing centre have given it its prestige. But in the last two or three years the Eastern cities, New York, Philadelphia, and Boston, have developed enormous cold-storage facilities, and Chicago no longer is absolute in her dictation to the markets of the world. When it is remembered that the dairy interests of our country during the last three years averaged an annual value of $650,000,000, and that the greater portion of this found its way into cold-storage warehouses, the importance of this new and very necessary business is readily appreciated.

Chicago is naturally the top cold-storage center. Its location in the heart of a productive area and its advantages as a distribution hub have earned it a strong reputation. However, in the past two or three years, Eastern cities like New York, Philadelphia, and Boston have built massive cold-storage facilities, and Chicago no longer has the final say in global markets. Considering that the dairy industry in our country has averaged an annual value of $650,000,000 over the last three years, with a large portion stored in cold-storage warehouses, the significance of this emerging and essential business is clear.

COLD-STORAGE CHARGES

The cold-storage charges for eggs in thirty-dozen cases would be about 15 cents per case for the first month and 9 cents for every additional month. Butter in sixty-pound tubs would be charged at the rate of 12 cents per tub for each month. Cheese would cost one tenth of a cent a pound per month. The rates of Eastern cities are usually higher than in the West. About ninety per cent. of the storage business of the East is in goods shipped from the West. The refrigerator car is a valuable adjunct to the business. The temperature of the cars is about 45°.

The cold-storage fees for eggs in thirty-dozen cases would be around 15 cents per case for the first month and 9 cents for each additional month. Butter in sixty-pound tubs would cost 12 cents per tub per month. Cheese would be priced at one-tenth of a cent per pound each month. Rates in Eastern cities are generally higher than those in the West. About ninety percent of the storage business in the East involves goods shipped from the West. The refrigerator car is a valuable addition to the business. The temperature in the cars is approximately 45°.

Although no ice is used in the modern cold-storage plant, yet the ice has become a very valuable by-product. Since all the facilities for its manufacture are at hand it has become a matter of commercial expediency to employ them to the company's profit in the production and sale of a commodity indispensable to modern life.

Although no ice is used in the modern cold-storage plant, it has become a very valuable by-product. Since all the facilities for its production are available, it has become a matter of business practicality to use them for the company's benefit in creating and selling a commodity essential to modern life.

[301]QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW

  1. Give some particulars in which the Bank of England differs from our larger national banks.
  2. A bank cheque is a demand order for money drawn by one who has funds in the bank. How does a cheque differ from an order on AI'm ready to help. Please provide the text you'd like me to modernize. BUnderstood! Please provide the text you'd like me to modernize. to pay bearer a certain sum of money?
  3. You are sending a cheque through the mails to John Brown, Chicago. How will you prevent the cheque from falling into the hands of the wrong Brown?
  4. You identify AUnderstood! Please provide the text you'd like me to modernize. BPlease provide the text you would like me to modernize. at your bank. The cheque AUnderstood! Please provide the text you would like me to modernize. BUnderstood. Please provide the text you would like modernized. presented turns out to be a forgery. Are you responsible?
  5. What is meant by power of attorney? How should an attorney indorse cheques for any person for whom he is acting?
  6. What is a certified cheque? Brown gives A an ordinary cheque for $1000, and B a certified cheque for $1000. He fails before either cheque is presented. Why is B's security for his claim considered better than A's?
  7. Show how all the banks of the United States are connected through the clearing-house system.
  8. How do State and national banks differ as to their organisation?
  9. A national bank has a capital of half a million. A[302] customer asks for a loan of $62,000 on indorsed paper. Can the bank legally grant the loan?
  10. Give some particulars of the liabilities of the officers and directors of national banks.
  11. What is meant by borrowing money on collaterals? How is this done?
  12. Tell how it is possible for a young man of good character, but without friends who have financial standing, to secure bonds for his faithful conduct in a responsible position.
  13. When rates are high bankers prefer to deal in long-time paper. Why?
  14. Account for the fact that London is the financial centre of the world.
  15. Explain in detail the business of a note broker, giving some particulars of his responsibility in connection with the paper handled.
  16. Enumerate the leading items of resource and liability in a national-bank statement.
  17. A bank receives from the comptroller of the treasury $100,000 in new bank-notes of its own issue. What ledger entry? A bank retires $10,000 of its own bank-notes. What entry?
  18. Discuss fully the points which should enter into a proper estimate of the value of paper offered for discount.
  19. Give the successive and necessary steps in the formation of a joint stock company.
  20. Why are companies which properly exist and belong in one State sometimes organised under the laws of another State?
  21. Explain very fully the difference as to resource and liability between a bondholder and a stockholder.
  22. How may a stock company be dissolved?
  23. What is the difference between a voluntary association, such as a society or club, and a stock company?
  24. [303]Explain very fully the meaning of Limited when it forms part of the legal title of a company.
  25. Is it legal to sell shares of stock and issue mortgage bonds upon the same property? What relationship do they bear one to the other?

[304]EXAMINATION PAPER

Note.The following questions are given as a means by which the student may test for himself whether he has attentively pursued the lessons of the course or not. It is recommended that each student as he finishes the course write out the answers to the questions in full. Only such answers need be attempted as the student can frame from a careful study of the course.

Note.The following questions are provided so that students can check if they have thoughtfully engaged with the course material. It’s suggested that each student write out complete answers to the questions after finishing the course. Only attempt to answer the questions that students can respond to based on their careful study of the course.

  1. (a)  Give some particulars in which the Bank of England differs from our larger national banks. (b)  Enumerate some of the advantages afforded to the community and to commerce in general by banking institutions. (c)  How do private banks and trust companies differ from national banks?
  2. (a)  What is a stock certificate? How does it differ from a mortgage bond? (b)  At what rate must United States 4 per cents be bought to net 3.2465 per cent.? (c)  Give the successive and necessary steps in the formation of a stock company. How can the stock of a company or corporation be increased?
  3. (a)  What provision is usually made for the redemption of municipal bonds which have a long period to run? (b)  What is meant when we say that a certain railway is in the hands of a receiver? (c)  Give some of the advantages which stock companies have over partnerships.
  4. (a)  Tell how you would receipt for a payment on a note. Why is not an ordinary separate receipt sufficient?[305] (b)  Discuss fully the points which should enter into a proper estimate of the value of paper offered for discount. (c)  Explain in detail the business of a note broker, giving some particulars of his responsibility in connection with the paper handled.
  5. (a)  What are the advantages to the banks of a city of their central clearing-house? (b)  Show by a diagram how collections are made between distant points. (c)  What is a certified check?
  6. (a)  Enumerate some of the abuses of rate discrimination in the United States and tell how they are met. (b)  What are the advantages to the public of freight organisations which arrange for through service? (c)  Explain in detail the methods adopted by leading and competing railway lines to regulate and adjust freight rates. (d)  What are differentials? How are (1)  through and (2)  local passenger rates regulated?
  7. (a)  Give the particulars in which a warehouse receipt resembles and differs from (1)  a promissory note, (2)  a bill of lading. (b)  What are the advantages to the importer of bonded warehouses? (c)  What are the duties of our foreign consuls with reference to the importation of goods?

[309]COMMERCIAL LAW

I. THE DIFFERENT KINDS OF CONTRACTS

Commercial law relates to contracts. These are made by almost every one. A person cannot ride in a street-car without making a contract with the company for carrying him. If he goes into a store and buys a cigar, a stick of candy, or a tin whistle, he has made a contract with the man behind the counter, who owns the store or is his salesman. Tramps and thieves are about the only persons who live without making contracts. In that respect they are like the birds of the air, getting whatever they desire whenever the chance is seen.

Commercial law is all about contracts. Almost everyone makes them. A person can't ride a streetcar without entering into a contract with the company that operates it. If someone walks into a store and buys a cigar, a candy bar, or a tin whistle, they've made a contract with the person behind the counter, whether that’s the store owner or a salesperson. The only people who really live without making contracts are vagrants and thieves. In that way, they're similar to birds, taking what they want whenever the opportunity arises.

A contract has been defined as an agreement to do or not to do some particular thing. These are the words used by one of the greatest of American judges. The reader may turn to his dictionary and find other definitions that contain more, if he pleases, but this will answer our purpose.

A contract is defined as an agreement to do something or not do something specific. These are the words from one of America's greatest judges. The reader can check their dictionary for other definitions that might be more detailed if they want, but this will serve our needs.

All contracts may be put into three classes, and each of these will be briefly explained. First, sealed and unsealed contracts. What do we mean by a contract that is sealed? It is one to which the person who signs it adds, after his name, a seal. But what is a seal? It may consist of sealing-wax, stamped in a peculiar manner, or a wafer made of sealing-wax, or a paper wafer. In the olden times when people could hunt and fight but[310] were not able to write their names, they put a seal at the end of a contract made by them; in other words, the seal supplied the place of a name. Each person's seal differed from the seal of every other. It had its origin really in the ignorance of the people. As they were unable to write their names these distinct signs or marks, called seals, were put on instead of their signatures.

All contracts can be classified into three categories, which I'll briefly explain. First, sealed and open contracts. What do we mean by a sealed contract? It's one where the signer adds a seal after their name. But what is a seal? It can be made of sealing wax, stamped in a unique way, or a wafer made of sealing wax, or a paper wafer. In ancient times, when people could hunt and fight but[310] couldn't write their names, they would put a seal at the end of a contract they made; in other words, the seal acted as a substitute for a name. Each person’s seal was different from everyone else's. It really originated from people’s inability to write. Since they couldn't sign their names, these unique signs or marks, known as seals, were used instead of signatures.

With the changes brought by time the form of this device or seal, required by law, is much simpler than it was centuries ago. Indeed, in every State persons use the letters "L. S.," with brackets around them, instead of a seal. They mean "the place of a seal," and are just as good in every way as any kind of seal that might be used. Here are two of the forms of seals in most common use:

With the changes brought by time, the form of this device or seal required by law is much simpler than it was centuries ago. In every state, people use the letters "L. S." within brackets instead of a seal. They stand for "the place of a seal" and are just as valid as any seal that might be used. Here are two of the most commonly used forms of seals:

Two seals in common use. Two commonly used seals.

Any contract that has a seal after the name of the signer is a sealed contract, and every other is called an unsealed, oral, or verbal contract. If a contract was written and a seal was added after the signer's name, and there was another exactly like it in form, but without a seal, this would be called an unsealed or verbal contract, and in law would differ in some important respects from the other. This is true in every State except California, where the difference between sealed and unsealed contracts is no longer known.

Any contract that has a seal next to the signer’s name is considered a sealed contract, while all others are referred to as unsealed, oral, or verbal contracts. If a contract is written and a seal is added after the signer’s name, but there’s another identical one without a seal, the latter would be classified as an unsealed or verbal contract, and it would have some significant legal differences from the sealed contract. This is the case in every state except California, where the distinction between sealed and unsealed contracts no longer exists.

The second class of contracts are called express and[311] implied contracts. By an express contract is meant one that is made either in writing or in words. But the reader may ask, Are not all contracts of this kind? By no means. Many contracts exist between people which have not been put into words. Suppose A should ask B for employment and it should be given to him, but no word should pass between them about the price to be paid. The law would imply that B must pay him whatever his work was reasonably worth. If A should come at the end of the week for his pay and B should say to him: "I never made any bargain with you concerning the price, and I am unwilling to pay you anything," A could, if he understood the law, say to B: "You told me to work, and the law implies that you must pay me whatever my work is worth." How much would the law give him for his work? Just what the employer was paying other men for the same kind of work.

The second class of contracts is called express and[311] implied agreements. An express agreement is one that is created either in writing or verbally. But you might wonder, aren’t all contracts like that? Not at all. Many contracts happen between people that haven’t been stated explicitly. For example, if A asks B for a job and B agrees, but they never discuss the pay, the law would imply that B has to pay A whatever his work is reasonably worth. If A comes at the end of the week to collect his payment and B says, "I never agreed on a price with you, and I'm not willing to pay you anything," A could respond, if he knows the law, "You asked me to work, and the law implies that you must pay me for my work." How much would the law require him to be paid? Exactly what B was paying other workers for the same type of work.

Another class of contracts are called executed and executory. An executed contract is one that is finished, done, completed. If I should go into a store and ask the price of a book and say to the salesman, "I will take it," and give him the money, and take the book with me, this would be an executed contract. An executory contract is one that is to be completed. Suppose the salesman did not have the book and I should say to him, "Please get it for me and I will come in next week and pay you for it," this would be an executory contract; and it would remain so until I came in and got the book, as I had promised to do, and paid the price.

Another category of contracts is known as executed and executory. An signed contract is one that is finished and complete. For example, if I walk into a store, ask the price of a book, say to the salesperson, "I'll take it," hand over the money, and leave with the book, this would be an executed contract. An executory contract is one that is still pending completion. If the salesperson didn’t have the book and I said, "Please order it for me, and I’ll come back next week to pay for it," this would be an executory contract; it would remain so until I returned and picked up the book, just as I agreed to do, and paid for it.

These are the three most general classes of contracts made by persons in daily life. Almost all persons make contracts of each kind during their lives. Sealed contracts are not as common as unsealed ones, yet they are frequently made. Every deed for the sale of land or lease for the use of it is a sealed contract.

These are the three main types of contracts that people enter into in their everyday lives. Almost everyone makes contracts of each type at some point. Sealed contracts are less common than unsealed ones, but they are still made often. Every deed for selling land or leasing it for use is a sealed contract.

[312]II. THE PARTIES TO A CONTRACT

To every contract there must be two or more persons or parties. When Robinson Crusoe was on his island all alone, eating breadfruit and entertaining himself by throwing stones at the monkeys, he perhaps had a good time, but he could not make any contracts. But as soon as Friday came along they could make contracts, trade, and cheat each other as much as they pleased. A contract, therefore, is one of the incidents of society. A person sailing in a balloon alone could not make a contract, but if two were in the basket they might amuse themselves by swapping jack-knives or neckties, and these exchanges would be completed or executed contracts and would possess, as we shall soon see, every element of a contract.

To make a contract, there need to be two or more people or events. When Robinson Crusoe was alone on his island, eating breadfruit and playing around by throwing stones at the monkeys, he might have had a good time, but he couldn't enter into any contracts. However, once Friday showed up, they could make contracts, trade, and even trick each other as much as they wanted. So, a contract is a key part of society. A person flying solo in a balloon can't make a contract, but if two people are in the basket, they could have fun trading jack-knives or neckties, and those trades would be valid contracts, containing, as we will soon discuss, all the necessary elements of a contract.

Again, persons must be able, or competent, to make contracts. What kind of ability or competency must a person have? Not every person can make a contract, even though he may wish to do so. A minor, or person less than twenty-one years of age, though he may be very wise and weigh perhaps two hundred and fifty pounds, can make very few contracts which the law regards as binding. In fact, the only contracts that a minor can make for which he is bound are for necessaries—clothing, food, and shelter. Nor can he make contracts even for these things in unlim[313]ited quantities. A minor could not go into a store and buy six overcoats and bind himself to pay for them. The storekeeper must have common sense in selling to him and keep within a reasonable limit. In one of the well-known cases a minor bought a dozen pairs of trousers, half a dozen hats, as many canes, besides a large supply of other things, and, refusing afterward to pay the bill, the merchant sued him, and the jury decided that he must pay. The case, however, was appealed to a higher court, which took a different view of his liability. The judge who wrote the opinion for the court said that the merchant must have known that the minor could not make any personal use of so many trousers, canes, and hats, and ought not to have sold him so many. In short, the court thought that the merchant himself was a young minor in intelligence and ought to have known better than to sell such a bill to a person under age.

Again, individuals must be able, or skilled, to make contracts. What kind of ability or competence must a person have? Not everyone can make a contract, even if they want to. A minor, or someone under twenty-one years old, even if they are very wise and weigh perhaps two hundred and fifty pounds, can make very few contracts that the law considers binding. In fact, the only contracts a minor can make that they are bound to are for necessities—clothing, food, and shelter. They also cannot make contracts for these things in unlimited quantities. A minor cannot walk into a store and buy six overcoats and commit to pay for them. The storekeeper needs to use common sense when selling to them and stick to a reasonable limit. In one well-known case, a minor bought a dozen pairs of trousers, half a dozen hats, several canes, and a large supply of other items. When he later refused to pay the bill, the merchant sued him, and the jury decided he must pay. However, the case was appealed to a higher court, which had a different opinion about his liability. The judge who wrote the court's opinion stated that the merchant must have known that the minor could not possibly use so many trousers, canes, and hats, and shouldn’t have sold him so many. In short, the court believed the merchant himself was lacking in judgment and should have known better than to sell such a large bill to someone underage.

Of course it is not always easy to answer this question, What are necessaries? Much depends on the condition of the person who buys. A merchant would be safe in selling more to a minor living in an affluent condition of life than to another living in a much humbler way. Quite recently the question has been considered whether a dentist's bill is a necessity, and the court decided that it was a proper thing for a minor to preserve his teeth and to this end use the arts of the dentist. Again, is a bicycle a necessity? If one is using it daily in going to and from his work, surely it is a necessity. But if one is using it merely for pleasure a different rule would apply, and a minor could not be compelled to pay for it. Cigars, liquors, theatre tickets are luxuries; so the courts have said on many occasions.

Of course, it’s not always easy to answer the question, What are necessities? Much depends on the situation of the person who is buying. A merchant would be safe selling more to a minor living an affluent lifestyle than to one living in a much more modest way. Recently, there has been discussion about whether a dentist's bill is a necessity, and the court decided that it is important for a minor to take care of their teeth and, therefore, to use a dentist's services. Then, is a bicycle a necessity? If someone uses it daily to commute to work, it definitely is a necessity. However, if someone is just using it for fun, a different rule would apply, and a minor couldn't be required to pay for it. Cigars, alcohol, and theater tickets are luxuries; that's what the courts have stated on many occasions.

The courts, in fact, regard a minor as hardly able to contract even for necessaries, and he is required to pay for them for the reason that as he needs them for his[314] comfort and health he ought to pay for them. In other words, his duty or obligation to pay rests rather on the ground of an implied contract (which has been already explained) than of an express one. The force of this reasoning we shall immediately see.

The courts actually view a minor as barely able to make contracts, even for essential items, and he is expected to pay for them because he needs them for his[314] comfort and health. In other words, his obligation to pay is based more on an implied contract (which has already been explained) than on an explicit one. We will soon see the strength of this reasoning.

Suppose a minor should say to a merchant who was unwilling to sell to minors,—having had, perhaps, sad experience in the way of not collecting bills of them,—"I am not a minor and so you can safely trust me. I wish to go into business and wish you would sell me some goods." Suppose that, relying on his statement, the merchant should sell him hats or other merchandise for which he would afterward decline to pay, on the ground that he was a minor. Suppose he proved that he really was one—could the merchant compel him to pay the bill? He could not compel him to fulfil his contract, because, as we have already said, the law does not permit a minor to make a contract except for necessaries. The court, then, would say to the merchant: "It is true that you sold the goods to this minor; he has indeed lied to you; still the court cannot regard a contract as existing between you and him." On the other hand, a court will not permit a person to defraud another, and the merchant could make the minor pay for the deceit or wrong that he had practised on him; and the measure of this wrong would be the value of the goods he had bought. Thus the court would render justice to the merchant without admitting that the minor could make a legal contract for the goods that he had actually bought and taken away.

Suppose a minor tells a merchant who refuses to sell to minors—maybe because he’s had bad experiences collecting debts from them—“I’m not a minor, so you can trust me. I want to start a business and I’d like to buy some goods.” If the merchant, believing this statement, sells him hats or other items and the minor later refuses to pay, claiming he is indeed a minor, could the merchant force him to pay the bill? He couldn’t, because, as we’ve mentioned before, the law doesn’t allow minors to enter into contracts except for necessary items. Therefore, the court would tell the merchant: “It’s true you sold the goods to this minor; he lied to you; however, the court can’t recognize a contract between you and him.” On the other hand, a court won’t allow someone to defraud another, so the merchant could make the minor pay for the deceit or wrong he committed. The value of the wrong would be assessed based on the worth of the goods he purchased. This way, the court would serve justice to the merchant while not acknowledging that the minor could legally contract for the goods he actually bought and took.

[315]III. THE PARTIES TO A CONTRACT (Continued)

In the former article we told our readers that there were some persons who could not make contracts, and among these were infants or minors. In most of the States a person, male or female, is a minor until he or she is twenty-one years old. In some of the States, among them Illinois, a female ceases to be a minor at eighteen years of age.

In the previous article, we informed our readers that there are certain individuals who cannot enter into contracts, including babies or underage individuals. In most states, a person, regardless of gender, is considered a minor until they turn twenty-one years old. In some states, including Illinois, a female is no longer considered a minor once she turns eighteen.

By the Roman law a minor did not reach his majority until the end of his twenty-fourth year, and this rule has been adopted in France, Spain, Holland, and some parts of Germany. The French law, though, has been changed, with one noteworthy exception. A woman cannot make a contract relating to her marriage without the consent of her parents until she is twenty-five. Among the Greeks and early Romans women never passed beyond the period of minority, but were always subject to the guardianship of their parents until they were married.

By Roman law, a minor didn't reach adulthood until the end of their twenty-fourth year, and this rule has been adopted in France, Spain, Holland, and some parts of Germany. However, French law has changed, with one important exception. A woman can't enter into a marriage-related contract without her parents' consent until she is twenty-five. Among the Greeks and early Romans, women never moved beyond childhood and were always under their parents' guardianship until they got married.

Married women are another class of persons who cannot make every kind of a contract like a man. Once a married woman had but very little power to make contracts. However great might have been her wealth before marriage, as soon as she entered into this blissful state the law kindly relieved her of all except her real estate, giving it to her husband. On the other hand, he[316] was obliged to pay her bills, which was one of his great pleasures, especially if she was a constant traveller to the silk and diamond stores. She could still keep her real estate in her own name, but that was about all. Her husband took everything else; he could claim her pocket-book, if he pleased, and was obliged to support her in sickness or health, in sweetness or in any other "ness."

Married women are another group of people who can't make every kind of contract like men can. In the past, married women had very little power to enter into contracts. No matter how wealthy they were before marriage, once they got married, the law took away most of their rights, except for their real estate, which was handed over to their husbands. On the other hand, he[316] had to pay her bills, which he often enjoyed, especially if she frequently shopped at silk and diamond stores. She could still keep her real estate in her name, but that was pretty much it. Her husband took everything else; he could claim her wallet if he wanted and was required to support her in sickness and health, in good times and bad.

The law has been greatly changed in all civilised countries in this regard, and to-day in most States she can make almost any kind of a contract. In some States, however, it is even now said that she cannot agree to pay the debt of another, but this is, perhaps, the only limit on her power to contract. She can engage in business, buy and sell, transfer notes, make contracts relating to the sale and leasing of her real estate, insure it, build houses, and do a thousand other things quite as freely as if there were no husband around. The most of these changes widening her authority to make contracts have come within the last fifty years. Of course, unmarried women can make contracts like men, and many of them know it.

The law has changed a lot in all civilized countries regarding this issue, and today in most states, women can enter into almost any kind of contract. In some states, however, it's still said that women can't agree to pay someone else's debt, but this might be the only limitation on their ability to contract. Women can start businesses, buy and sell goods, transfer promissory notes, make contracts for selling or leasing their property, insure it, build homes, and do a thousand other things just as freely as if there were no husband involved. Most of these changes that have expanded women's authority to make contracts have happened in the last fifty years. Of course, unmarried women can make contracts just like men, and many of them are aware of this.

Another class who cannot make contracts are drunken persons. Once the law regarded a drunken man as fully responsible for his acts, and if he made a contract he was obliged to execute or fulfil it. He could not shield himself by saying he did not know what he was doing at the time. The court sternly frowned on him and said: "No matter what was your condition at the time of making it, you must carry it out." This was the penalty for his misdeed. It may be the courts thought that by requiring him to fulfil his contracts he would be more careful and restrain his appetite. Whatever the courts may have thought, they have changed their opinions regarding his liability for his contracts made under such conditions. Now they hold that he need not carry them out if he desires to escape from them. There is, however,[317] one exception to this rule. If he has given a note in the ordinary form, and this has been taken by a third person in good faith who did not know of the maker's condition at the time of making it, he must pay. But, we repeat, the third person must act in good faith in taking it, for if he knew that the maker was drunk at that time he cannot require him to pay any more than the person to whom it was first given.

Another group that can't make contracts are intoxicated individuals. In the past, the law saw a drunken person as fully responsible for their actions, so if they made a contract, they had to follow through on it. They couldn't claim they didn't know what they were doing at the time. The court would sternly say, "No matter how you were at the time of making it, you must carry it out." This was the consequence of their behavior. Perhaps the courts believed that by making them honor their contracts, they'd be more cautious and control their drinking. Whatever the courts thought back then, they've changed their stance on liability for contracts made under such circumstances. Now, they hold that a person doesn't have to fulfill those contracts if they want to get out of them. However, there is, [317] one exception to this rule. If they've given a note in the regular form and a third person took it in good faith, not knowing about the maker's condition at the time, the maker has to pay. But again, the third person must act in good faith because if they knew the maker was drunk, they can't require them to pay any more than the original recipient could.

One other class may be briefly mentioned—the insane. They are regarded in the law quite the same as minors. For their own protection the law does not hold them liable on any contracts except those for necessaries. These are binding for the same reasons as the contracts of minors, in order that they may be able to get such things as they need for their health and comfort. For if the law were otherwise, then, of course, merchants would be afraid to sell to them. But as merchants can now safely sell to them whatever they truly need in the way of clothing, food, etc., to make themselves comfortable, so, on the other hand, the insane, like minors, must pay for these things, and it is right that they should.

One other group worth mentioning is the crazy. In the eyes of the law, they are treated similarly to minors. For their own protection, the law does not hold them responsible for any contracts except those for essential items. These contracts are enforceable for the same reasons as those made by minors, so they can obtain the necessities they need for their health and well-being. If the law were different, merchants would understandably hesitate to sell to them. However, since merchants can now confidently sell them whatever essential items they truly need, like clothing and food, the insane, just like minors, are required to pay for these things, which is only fair.

[318]IV. THE CONSIDERATION IN CONTRACTS

Having explained who can make contracts, we are now ready to take another step. Besides having parties, there must be a consideration for every contract. This is rather a long word, but no shorter can be found to put in its place. What do we mean by this term? We mean that there must be some actual gain or loss to one or both parties to a contract, otherwise it is not valid. If, for example, A should say to B, "I will give you $100 to-morrow," B, perhaps, might go away very happy, thinking that with this money he could buy a bicycle or some other fine thing; indeed, it was just the sum for which he was longing; so on the morrow he goes to A for his money. He promptly appears, but A says to him: "I have changed my mind, and will not give you the $100." B asks: "Did you not promise to give me this money?" "Certainly." "Well, why will you not fulfil your promise?" A replies: "I was a fool when I made that promise; you are not going to give me anything for it, so I am unwilling to give the money to you." Suppose B in his sorrow should go to a lawyer, thinking, perhaps, that he could compel A by some legal proceeding to pay over the money. What would the lawyer tell him? Why, he would say: "Did you promise to give A anything for the $100?" "No, sir." "Then the law will not help you[319] out. You cannot get the money from him by any legal method. Perhaps you can get $100 worth of fun in licking him for not giving you the money, but you cannot get the cash. But, mind, perhaps you had better not try to get your fun in that way, for this is contrary to law, and he might get much more than $100 out of you in the way of damages for licking him."

Having explained who can make contracts, we're now ready to move on. In addition to having parties, every contract must have a thoughtfulness. This is a long word, and there's no shorter term that can replace it. What do we mean by this term? We mean that there has to be some actual gain or loss for one or both parties involved in a contract; otherwise, it isn't valid. For example, if A says to B, "I'll give you $100 tomorrow," B might walk away feeling really happy, thinking he could buy a bicycle or something nice with that money; in fact, it’s exactly the amount he's been wanting. So the next day, he goes to A for his money. A shows up but says, "I've changed my mind and I won't give you the $100." B asks, "Did you promise to give me this money?" "Yes." "Then why won't you keep your promise?" A replies, "I was foolish to make that promise; you're not giving me anything for it, so I'm not willing to give you the money." Suppose B, feeling sad, goes to a lawyer, thinking that maybe he can force A through legal action to pay him. What would the lawyer say? He would say, "Did you promise to give A anything for the $100?" "No." "Then the law won't help you[319]. You can't get the money from him through any legal means. You might get $100 worth of satisfaction by hitting him for not giving you the money, but you won't get the cash. But remember, you might be better off not trying to get that satisfaction that way because it’s against the law, and he could end up getting a lot more than $100 from you in damages for hitting him."

In every case, therefore, there must be something for something. Now this something may be a thousand things. It may be money or merchandise or work. In short, there is no end of the things that may serve as a consideration of a contract. An example may be given to explain what is meant by this. A man had been speculating in stocks, and one of the rules of the stock board is that a margin or sum of money that is to be paid for stock must be paid in every case. It may be that an additional margin or sum must be paid under some circumstances. The speculator in this particular case was unwilling to pay this margin, and he said to the broker: "If you will do as I wish, and not put up this margin, I will save you from any loss that may result from such conduct." It was contrary to the rules of that stock exchange for the broker not to put up the margin, and the consequence was that he was put off the floor; in other words, the board would not permit him to act as a member. Of course, as he could not buy and sell any more stock, he lost money; and he went to his customer, the speculator, and told him that he was losing money in consequence of carrying out his order about the margin. The speculator said he was sorry, but he could not help it. The broker then insisted that the speculator must make good his daily loss in consequence of doing as he had promised. This the speculator would not do. The broker then sued him for the amount of his loss. The speculator defended on the ground that there was no consideration for the agreement he had made with[320] the broker about the margin. The court said that the loss which the broker had suffered in consequence of carrying out his contract with the speculator was a good consideration for the contract and must be made good.

In every case, therefore, there must be something for something. This something could be a variety of things, like money, goods, or services. In short, there are countless things that can act as consideration in a contract. For example, a man was trading stocks, and one of the rules of the stock exchange is that a margin or sum of money for purchasing stock must be paid every time. There may also be situations where an additional margin needs to be paid. In this case, the trader didn’t want to pay the margin and told the broker, "If you do what I want and don’t pay this margin, I’ll protect you from any loss that might come from that." It was against the rules of that stock exchange for the broker to skip paying the margin, and as a result, he was banned from the trading floor; in other words, he was not allowed to act as a member anymore. Since he could no longer buy or sell stock, he ended up losing money. He went to his client, the trader, and informed him that he was losing money because he followed the trader’s instructions regarding the margin. The trader expressed regret but said he couldn’t do anything about it. The broker then insisted that the trader must cover his daily losses due to honoring their agreement. The trader refused to do this. Consequently, the broker sued him for his losses. The trader defended himself by arguing that there was no consideration for the agreement with the broker concerning the margin. The court decided that the broker’s losses from fulfilling the contract with the trader constituted valid consideration for the contract and must be compensated.

When a contract is sealed the law implies that there is consideration, and there need not be an actual one consisting of money, labour, or any other thing. This seems like an exception to the rule requiring a consideration in all cases, but the reason is this: When a sealed contract is made, the law supposes or assumes that each party made it, clearly knowing its nature—made it carefully, slowly, and, consequently, that either a consideration had been or would be given. If, therefore, one of the parties should refuse to fulfil it the other could sue him in a court of law. The person who sought to have it carried out would not be obliged to show that he had given any consideration on his part for the undertaking, because the seal appended to his name would imply that a consideration had been given. A deed for a piece of land is a good illustration of a sealed instrument. The law assumes whenever such a deed is given that the seller received a consideration for his land. The money paid was a consideration received by the seller, and the land was the consideration received by the buyer. Each gives a consideration of some kind for the consideration received from the other; and this is true in all cases.

When a contract is sealed, the law assumes that there is consideration, and it doesn’t have to be something tangible like money, labor, or anything else. This appears to be an exception to the rule that requires consideration in all cases, but here's the reason: When a sealed contract is created, the law presumes that both parties made it, fully aware of what it means—they took their time and acted thoughtfully, and therefore, either a consideration has been or will be provided. So, if one party refuses to fulfill their part, the other can take them to court. The person wanting to enforce the contract won't have to show that they provided any consideration for the agreement, because the seal next to their name suggests that consideration was given. A deed for a piece of land is a good example of a sealed instrument. The law assumes that when such a deed is executed, the seller has received consideration for their land. The money paid is the consideration received by the seller, while the land is the consideration received by the buyer. Each party provides some form of consideration in exchange for what they receive from the other, and this applies in all cases.

[321]V. THE ESSENTIALS OF A CONTRACT

In our last paper we told our readers that there must be a consideration in every contract. Sometimes this is illegal, and when it is the effect is the same as would be the giving of no consideration.

In our last paper, we informed our readers that there must be a consideration in every contract. Sometimes this is illegal, and when it is, the effect is the same as giving no consideration.

Suppose a robber having stolen money from a bank should afterward offer to return a certain portion if he is assured that he will not be arrested and compelled to change the style of his clothing and his place of residence for a season. He cannot endure the thought of missing a game of football; and as for striped clothes, though very comfortable, perhaps, he is sure they would not be becoming. Suppose this agreement to return a part should be put in writing, and after fulfilling it he should be sued by the bank for the remainder, and also prosecuted by the State for committing the theft. Very naturally he would present the writing in court to show that he had been discharged from the crime and also from the payment of any more money. But this writing would not clear him either from prosecution for the criminal offence or from liability to return the rest of the money. The bank would say that although he had returned a part, this was not a proper consideration for its agreement not to sue him; it had no right to make such an agreement, and consequently it could sue the[322] robber for the remainder of the money just as though no agreement had ever been made.

Suppose a robber who stole money from a bank later offers to return a portion of it if he’s guaranteed he won’t be arrested and forced to change his clothes and his home for a while. He can’t stand the idea of missing a football game; and as for striped clothes, although they might be comfortable, he’s sure they wouldn’t look good on him. Now imagine this agreement to return part of the money is written down, but after he fulfills it, the bank sues him for the rest, and the State also prosecutes him for the theft. Naturally, he would present the written agreement in court to show that he has been freed from the crime and any further payment. However, this document wouldn’t absolve him from criminal prosecution or from returning the rest of the money. The bank would argue that even though he returned a part, that wasn’t a legitimate trade-off for the promise not to sue; they had no authority to make such an agreement, and therefore, they could sue the[322] robber for the rest of the money as if no agreement had ever existed.

Another illustration may be given. Suppose a person having made a bet and lost is unable to pay the money and gives his note for the amount. When the note becomes due the holder or owner sues him for the money. He defends, as he is unwilling to pay, by saying there was no legal consideration for the note. The money he promised to pay was only a wager, which the law regards as illegal. And this would be a good defence.

Another example can be given. Imagine someone who placed a bet and lost, then can't pay the amount and gives a promissory note instead. When the note is due, the holder or owner sues him for the money. He defends himself, unwilling to pay, by claiming there was no legal consideration for the note. The money he agreed to pay was just a wager, which the law sees as illegal. And this would be a valid defense.

If the consideration is partly legal and partly illegal and can be divided then there can be a recovery of the legal part. Suppose a man owed another $1000 for borrowed money and also a wager for the same amount, and had given his note for $2000. When it became due if the owner sued him he could recover only the $1000 of borrowed money; this much and no more, for the reason that the consideration could be divided, the legal part from the illegal part. If no separation was possible then the note would be void and the owner could get nothing.

If the consideration involves both legal and illegal elements and can be separated, then the legal part can be recovered. For instance, if someone owes another person $1000 for borrowed money and also has a bet for the same amount, and has signed a note for $2000, when the note is due and the owner sues, he can only recover the $1000 for the borrowed money; nothing more than that, because the consideration can be divided into the legal part and the illegal part. If separation isn't possible, then the note becomes void and the owner can't collect anything.

A person cannot recover for a voluntary service that he has rendered to another. A man would be very mean indeed who refused to pay another for any service rendered to him that was truly valuable; yet if he would not do so the man rendering the service could get nothing through the law. Suppose that a person when walking along a road should see some cattle astray in a corn-field having a good time with a farmer's corn. He knows they are in the field for business and in a short time, unless driven out, will get the best of nature and down her efforts in corn-raising. In the kindness of his heart he jumps over the fence and succeeds in driving them away. Suppose there happens to be among the number an unruly animal which is unwilling to leave such a tempt[323]ing field of plunder and turns on him and gores him, and he is taken to a hospital. The farmer finds out who drove out the animals, and of his injury, but declines to give him any reward whatever. Can the man recover anything? The law says not, because the service is purely voluntary.

A person can’t get paid for a voluntary service they provided to someone else. It would be pretty low for someone to refuse to pay for a service that was genuinely valuable; however, if they did, the person who provided the service wouldn't be able to seek any compensation through the law. Imagine someone walking down a road who sees cattle roaming in a cornfield, having a great time eating the farmer's corn. They know the cattle are there to cause trouble and if they aren’t driven away soon, they’ll ruin the farmer’s crop. Out of kindness, they jump over the fence and manage to chase the cattle off. Suppose one of the animals is difficult, doesn’t want to leave the tempting field of food, and charges at him, goring him, and he ends up in the hospital. The farmer learns that this person drove the animals away and hears about the injury but refuses to give him any reward. Can he get anything in return? The law says no, because the service was completely voluntary.

The question has often been asked whether a person who has made a contract to work for another and has broken it can recover for the worth of his service during the period he was employed. Some courts have said that a person thus breaking his contract cannot afterward recover anything, because he does not come into court with clean hands. Other courts have said that though he can recover nothing on the contract he has broken, he can nevertheless recover on a contract which the law implies in such a case for the worth of his service during the period of his employment. On the other hand, the employer can set off against his claim any injury that he may have sustained. Suppose he could show that the service was of no worth to him; that he was injured rather than benefited by what he did; then the employé could get nothing. The courts have been inclined of late years to uphold an employé in recovering whatever his service was worth—not, however, as done by virtue of an express or actual contract with the employer. He cannot sue on that; in other words, he cannot take advantage of his own wrong to recover anything from his employer, but he may recover on the contract which the law implies, as we have explained, as much as his service was worth to his employer, and no more.

The question has often been raised about whether someone who has entered into a contract to work for another and then broken it can still get paid for the value of their work during the time they were employed. Some courts have stated that a person who breaks their contract cannot recover anything afterward because they come to court with unclean hands. Other courts have said that although they can't recover anything from the broken contract, they can still recover on a contract that the law implies for the value of their service during the period of employment. On the flip side, the employer can counter the employee's claim with any harm they may have suffered. If the employer can show that the service was worthless to them, or that they were harmed rather than helped by what the employee did, then the employee might receive nothing. Recently, courts have generally leaned toward allowing an employee to recover whatever their service was worth—not as a result of an express or actual contract with the employer. They can't sue on that; in other words, they can't benefit from their own wrongdoing to recover anything from the employer, but they may recover based on the implied contract as we explained, up to the value of their service to the employer, and no more.

Another element in a contract is the meeting of minds of both parties. Both must understand the matter in the same sense. For example, a person offered to sell another "good barley" for a stated price, and the other offered to buy "fine barley" at the price mentioned.[324] There was no contract between these persons, because it was shown that "good barley" and "fine barley" were different things in the trade. This, therefore, is one of the essential elements of a contract—the meeting of the minds of the contracting parties. Whether they have assented or not is a question of fact, to be found out like any other question of fact.

Another element in a contract is the mutual understanding of both parties. Both must comprehend the matter in the same way. For instance, one person offered to sell another "good barley" for a specified price, and the other wanted to buy "fine barley" at that price.[324] There was no contract between these individuals because it was established that "good barley" and "fine barley" referred to different products in the trade. Thus, this is one of the essential elements of a contract—the mutual understanding of the contracting parties. Whether they have agreed or not is a matter of fact, to be determined just like any other factual question.

Sometimes offers are made on time, and when they are several interesting questions may arise. Suppose A and B are negotiating for the sale and purchase of a piece of land. A says to B: "I will give you a week to think the matter over." Soon after parting A meets C, to whom he mentions his offer to B. C says: "I will give you a great deal more for the land and pay you now." "Very well," says A; "the land is yours." And he at once writes a letter to B saying that he has withdrawn his offer, as another person has offered him more for the land and that he has sold it to him. Now B might be very much surprised by this letter. Very likely he would think A was a hard man and perhaps a dishonest one. Perhaps he would go to a lawyer and ask him if he could compel A to sell the land to him if he accepted his offer within the time mentioned and paid to him the money. The lawyer would tell him—if he understood his business—that A had a perfect right to withdraw his offer, even though it was made on time. This would probably be brand-new knowledge to B, but he would know what to do on the next occasion.

Sometimes offers are made on time, and when they are, several interesting questions can come up. Suppose A and B are negotiating for the sale and purchase of a piece of land. A says to B, "I'll give you a week to think it over." Soon after they part ways, A meets C, to whom he mentions his offer to B. C says, "I can give you a lot more for the land and pay you right now." "Alright," says A, "the land is yours." He then immediately writes a letter to B, saying that he has withdrawn his offer because someone else has offered him more for the land and that he has sold it to that person. B might be quite surprised by this letter. He would likely think A is a tough person and maybe even dishonest. He might go to a lawyer and ask if he could force A to sell the land to him if he accepted his offer within the stated time and paid him the money. The lawyer would tell him—if he knew his stuff—that A absolutely has the right to withdraw his offer, even if it was made on time. This would probably be new information for B, but he’d know what to do next time.

Is this true in all cases? It certainly is of all offers made in that manner. How, then, can a person who makes an offer to another on time be compelled to regard it? The way is simple enough. The person to whom the offer is made should give something—a consideration—to A, who makes the offer, for the delay. Then he would be bound by it. But the courts would say to B, if[325] nothing were given: "Why should A's offer bind him so long as he is to get no compensation or consideration for it?" And we shall see again and again in these papers this element of consideration is ever present, and must be to make transactions legal. So with respect to an offer on time—if the person to whom it is made is really desirous of having it continue, in order to find out whether he can raise the money to pay, or for some reason, he can make the offer binding by giving to the offerer a consideration for the specified time, whatever that may be.

Is this true in all cases? It definitely is for all offers made that way. So, how can someone who makes an offer to another within a timeframe be required to honor it? The answer is pretty straightforward. The person receiving the offer should give something—a consideration—to A, who made the offer, for the delay. Then A would be obligated by it. But the courts would tell B, if[325] nothing were given: "Why should A's offer be binding if he isn’t receiving any compensation or consideration for it?" And we will see time and again in these documents this element of consideration is always essential and must be present to make transactions valid. So regarding an offer made within a timeframe—if the person receiving it really wants it to stay valid, either to see if they can raise the funds to pay, or for some other reason, they can make the offer binding by giving the offerer a consideration for that specified time, whatever that may be.

[326]VI. CONTRACTS BY CORRESPONDENCE

A great many contracts are made by correspondence. A person writes a letter to another offering to sell him merchandise at a stated price. The other replies saying that he will accept the offer. Is a contract made at the time of writing his letter and putting it into the post-office, or not until it is received by the person who made the offer? The law in this country is that a contract is made between two persons in that way as soon as the answer is written and put into the post-office beyond the reach of the acceptor.

A lot of contracts are made through letters. A person sends a letter to someone else offering to sell them goods at a specified price. The other person responds, saying they accept the offer. Is a contract formed when they write their response and drop it in the mailbox, or does it only happen when the original offeror receives it? The law in this country states that a contract is formed between two people in this manner as soon as the reply is written and sent, out of the reach of the person who made the offer.

The post-office usually is the agent of the person who uses it, but when a person sends an offer to another by mail the post-office is regarded a little differently. It is the agent of the person who sends the offer and also his agent in bringing back the reply. Consequently, when this is put into the hands of the agent the law regards the offerer as bound by his offer. In like manner, if a creditor should send a letter to his debtor asking him to send a cheque for his debt and he should comply, the post-office would be the agent of the creditor in carrying that cheque, because he requested his debtor to use this means in sending his cheque to him. But when a request is not made and a debtor sends a cheque on his own account, the post-office is his agent for carrying it to his creditor.

The post office generally acts as the agent for the person using it, but when someone sends an offer to another person by mail, the role shifts a bit. The post office becomes the agent for the person sending the offer, as well as their agent for receiving the reply. So, once the offer is given to the post office, the law considers the offerer to be bound by that offer. Similarly, if a creditor sends a letter to their debtor asking for a check for their debt and the debtor sends it, the post office acts as the creditor's agent in delivering that check, since the creditor requested the debtor to use that method to send it. However, if there’s no request made and a debtor sends a check independently, the post office then serves as the debtor's agent in delivering it to the creditor.

[327]A person making an offer by letter can of course withdraw it through the telephone or telegraph if he likes at any time before the letter has been received by the other party. Suppose the price of things is rising and A, finding that his goods are also advancing, should, after making an offer of some of them by letter, send a telegram stating what he had written and withdrawing his offer. This would be a proper thing for him to do. If, on the other hand, A's offer had been received by B before his withdrawal and accepted, then A would be bound by it.

[327]A person can withdraw an offer made by letter via phone or telegram if they want, anytime before the letter is received by the other party. For example, if prices are rising and A notices that the value of their goods is also going up, after sending an offer by letter, A could send a telegram stating the details of that offer and withdrawing it. That would be completely acceptable. However, if B has received A's offer before the withdrawal and accepted it, then A would be bound by the offer.

Can B, after mailing his letter of acceptance and before it has been received by A, withdraw his acceptance? No, he cannot—for the reason above given, that the post-office is the agent of A, in carrying both his offer and B's reply. If this were not so, if the post-office were the agent of B in sending his reply, then of course it could be revoked or withdrawn at any time before it reached A.

Can B, after sending his acceptance letter and before A receives it, withdraw his acceptance? No, he cannot—because, as mentioned earlier, the post office is A's agent for delivering both his offer and B's response. If that weren't the case, and the post office were B's agent in sending his reply, then he could revoke or withdraw it at any time before it reached A.

Suppose A should send an offer and afterward a withdrawal and the withdrawal should be received first. Notwithstanding this, however, if the person to whom the offer was sent should accept the offer, could he not bind A? One can readily see that all the proof would be in the possession of B, the acceptor. If he were a man without regard for his honour and insisted that he received the offer first, A might be unable to offer any proof to the contrary and fail to win his case should B sue him. But the principle of law is plain enough; the only difficulty is in its application. Doubtless cases of this kind constantly happen in which the acceptor has taken advantage of the other to assent to an offer actually received after its withdrawal.

Imagine A sends an offer and later withdraws it, with the withdrawal being received first. Still, if the person who got the offer accepts it, can he not hold A to that offer? It's clear that all the evidence would be with B, the one who accepts. If B is someone who disregards his honor and claims he received the offer first, A might not have any way to prove otherwise and could lose his case if B decides to sue. The legal principle is straightforward; the challenge lies in applying it. Clearly, situations like this occur frequently where the acceptor exploits the situation by agreeing to an offer that was actually received after it was withdrawn.

Suppose B should in fact receive A's offer first in consequence of the neglect of the telegraph company to deliver A's message of withdrawal promptly, which if delivered as it should have been would have reached B[328] before the letter containing the offer, what then? A doubtless would be bound by his offer, but perhaps he could look to the telegraph company for any loss growing out of the affair. If he could show that he had been injured by fulfilling the contract the telegraph company might be obliged to pay this.

Suppose B actually receives A's offer first because the telegraph company failed to deliver A's message of withdrawal on time, which, if delivered properly, would have reached B[328] before the letter with the offer. What happens then? A would definitely be bound by his offer, but maybe he could hold the telegraph company responsible for any losses from this situation. If he can prove that he was harmed by going through with the contract, the telegraph company might have to compensate him.

Let us carry the inquiry a little further. Suppose the messenger on receiving the telegram took it to B's office and it was closed and he made diligent inquiry concerning B's whereabouts and was unable to find him. Suppose he had gone off to a horse race or to a football game, would it be the duty of the messenger boy to hunt him up at one of these places? By no means. If B was not at his place of business when he ought to have been, the company would not be bound to deliver the message to him elsewhere, except at his house, unless he had left a special direction with the company concerning its delivery. Generally a telegraph company states very clearly its mode of delivering messages and the time when it will do so, the place, etc., to which it will take them, and it is not obliged to hunt all over creation to find the person to whom a message is addressed. That would be a very unreasonable rule to apply. Therefore, if the company did its duty A could not recover anything from it. Would A, then, it may be asked, be obliged to fulfil his contract with B? He has sent his withdrawal, which if delivered in time would have been received by B before the letter containing the offer. B, however, is away from his place of business, and perhaps is where he ought not to be—perhaps he is playing poker or doing something worse—ought A under such circumstances to be held by his offer? This is a closer question and one that we will leave our readers to think over. Surely A would have a strong reason for claiming that he ought not to be held under such conditions.

Let’s take the inquiry a step further. Imagine the messenger, after receiving the telegram, goes to B's office and finds it closed. He searches diligently for B but can’t locate him. If B had gone to a horse race or a football game, would it be the messenger's responsibility to track him down at either of those places? Absolutely not. If B wasn’t at the office when he should have been, the company wouldn’t be obligated to deliver the message elsewhere, except to his home, unless he had given specific instructions to the company about the delivery. Typically, a telegraph company clearly outlines how it delivers messages, when it delivers them, and where it will take them. It's not required to search everywhere to find the intended recipient. That would be an unreasonable expectation. Therefore, if the company fulfilled its duty, A wouldn't be able to recover anything from them. So, the question arises: does A have to honor his contract with B? He has sent his withdrawal, which, if delivered on time, would have reached B before the letter containing the offer. However, B is away from his business and possibly where he shouldn’t be—maybe he’s playing poker or doing something worse—should A really be held to his offer in such a situation? This is a more complicated issue, and we’ll leave it for our readers to ponder. A would likely have a strong argument for saying he shouldn’t be held under these circumstances.

[329]A person who makes an offer cannot turn it into an acceptance. An old uncle offered by letter to buy his nephew's horse for $100, adding: "If I hear no more about the matter I consider the horse as mine." The uncle, not hearing from the nephew, proceeded to take the horse. At this stage of the proceedings, however, the nephew was not inclined to suffer his good old uncle to make the contract entirely himself, and refused to give up the horse. The court said that one person could not do all the contracting himself, and this is what he virtually undertook to do. If a person could, by correspondence or otherwise, make a contract in this manner, one can readily see the dangers that might follow. Some positive act must be put forth by the other party showing or indicating his assent before it will be regarded as given. A person, in truth, is not obliged to pay any attention to an offer of this kind.

[329]A person who makes an offer cannot turn it into an acceptance. An old uncle sent a letter offering to buy his nephew's horse for $100, adding: "If I don’t hear anything more about it, I consider the horse mine." When the uncle didn’t hear back from the nephew, he went ahead and took the horse. However, at this point, the nephew wasn’t willing to let his good old uncle make the contract all on his own and refused to give up the horse. The court stated that one person couldn’t handle all the contracting themselves, which is essentially what the uncle tried to do. If someone could form a contract this way through letters or otherwise, it’s easy to see the potential problems that could arise. The other party must take some positive action indicating their agreement before it will be considered as given. In reality, a person isn’t required to reply to an offer like this.

Rewards are often made. They are found almost every day among the newspaper advertisements. These are binding under various conditions. An interesting question has been raised in the case of a runaway horse whose owner has made an offer to any finder who returns him. Suppose a person at the time of catching the animal did not know of the reward but does know of it when returning the beast to his owner; can he claim the reward? This question has somewhat puzzled the judges, but the more recent opinion is that the catcher can claim the reward like a person who knew at the time of stopping the pleasure of the runaway. Of course, there is no question concerning these rewards when they are known at the time of acting on them.

Rewards are often offered and can be found almost daily in newspaper ads. These offers come with various conditions. An interesting question arose in a case involving a runaway horse, where the owner promised a reward to anyone who returned the horse. If someone caught the horse without knowing about the reward but learned about it when returning the horse to its owner, can they claim the reward? This question has puzzled judges, but the recent opinion is that the person who caught the horse can claim the reward, just like someone who knew about it when they acted to stop the runaway. Of course, there’s no question about these rewards when they are known at the time of taking action.

In one of the cases tried not long since, an old farmer offered a reward of $15 to any one who would find the person who had stolen his harness and also $100 to the man who would prosecute the thief. The harness, in truth,[330] was worth not even this small sum and the thief still less. Yet he was caught and prosecuted, and then the prosecutor and finder claimed the rewards. The farmer's excitement had cooled off by this time and he was not so loud and liberal as he was at the time of finding out his loss. He refused to pay, saying that he did not really mean to offer these sums as rewards, and the court decided in his favour, declaring that his offer of reward could not be regarded strictly as one, but rather "as an explosion of wrath." In another case a man's house was burning up and his wife was inside, and he offered any one $5000 who would go in and bring her out—"dead or alive." A brave fellow went in and rescued her. Then he claimed the reward. Was the man who made the offer obliged to pay, and could he not have escaped by insisting that this was simply "an explosion of affection" and not strictly an offer or promise of reward? He tried to hold on to his money, but the court held that this was an offer he must pay. Possibly after the recovery of his wife his valuation of her had changed somewhat from what it was while his house was burning up.

In a recent case, an old farmer posted a $15 reward for anyone who could find the person who had stolen his harness and an additional $100 for anyone who would prosecute the thief. The harness was hardly worth that amount, and the thief was worth even less. Yet he was caught and prosecuted, and then the prosecutor and the finder both wanted their rewards. By that time, the farmer's initial excitement had faded, and he wasn't as generous as he had been when he first discovered the theft. He refused to pay, claiming he didn't really mean to offer those amounts as rewards, and the court agreed with him, stating that his offer couldn't be seen as a genuine reward but rather "an explosion of wrath." In another case, a man's house was on fire with his wife trapped inside, and he offered $5000 to anyone who would go in and bring her out—"dead or alive." A courageous man went in and saved her. Later, when he claimed the reward, did the man who made the offer really have to pay? Could he have sidestepped it by saying it was just "an explosion of affection" and not a true offer or promise? He tried to keep his money, but the court ruled that it was indeed an offer he had to honor. Perhaps after rescuing his wife, his valuation of her changed from what it had been while his house was burning.

One or two more cases may be given. Some persons who prepared "carbolic-smoke balls" offered to pay £100 to any person who contracted influenza after having used one of the balls in the manner clearly set forth and for a stated period. This offer was in the form of a newspaper advertisement. A person bought one of them and followed carefully all the directions about its use. The influenza, though, did not disappear as advertised, so he sued to recover the offer; and, having proved clearly that he had complied faithfully with the directions and had not been cured, the court said that the owners must pay up and compelled them to give him the £100 offered.

One or two more examples can be given. Some people who made "carbolic-smoke balls" promised to pay £100 to anyone who got the flu after using one of the balls according to the clear instructions provided for a specific period. This offer was made through a newspaper ad. A person purchased one, carefully followed all the directions, but the flu didn’t go away as promised, so he sued to collect the offer. After clearly proving that he had faithfully followed the instructions and hadn’t been cured, the court ruled that the owners had to pay up and required them to give him the £100 they had promised.

Another case may be briefly mentioned. A offered to sell B his farm for $1000. B offered $950, which offer[331] was declined. Then B offered to pay $1000. By that time A had changed his mind and declined to accept B's offer. Then B sued to get the farm, offering to pay the money; but the court held that B had declined A's offer and consequently that, as A had not made any other offer, there was no contract.

Another case can be mentioned briefly. A offered to sell B his farm for $1000. B offered $950, but A declined that offer[331]. Then B offered to pay $1000. By that time, A had changed his mind and refused to accept B's offer. B then sued to acquire the farm, offering to pay the money; however, the court ruled that B had rejected A's offer, and since A hadn't made any other offer, there was no contract.

Finally, it may be added that the phrase "by return mail" does not always mean by the next mail, although the person to whom the offer is made cannot delay his answer long. On the other hand, the person to whom such a letter may be addressed can bind the other by an acceptance very quickly after the receipt of the offer, although not literally by the first mail going out.

Finally, it's important to note that the phrase "by return mail" doesn't always mean the very next mail, even though the person receiving the offer shouldn't take too long to respond. On the flip side, the person receiving such a letter can commit the other party by accepting it shortly after getting the offer, even if it’s not literally by the very first mail to go out.

[332]VII. WHAT CONTRACTS MUST BE IN WRITING

Some contracts must be in writing to be valid; for instance, contracts relating to the sale and leasing of lands. This writing must be signed by the person who is charged with having made it. Suppose that A has sold his farm to B for an agreed sum and refuses to give him a deed on his payment of the amount or offer to pay, and B wishes to compel A to carry out or execute his agreement. B must show a writing signed by A to that effect, otherwise the court will not pay any attention to the matter. On the other hand, if A claims that such an agreement has been made with B, who is unwilling to pay the money and receive the deed, he must show in court a writing signed by B that he has agreed to purchase the farm at a stated price and to receive a deed of the same. If such a writing is not forthcoming when required, he cannot recover anything from him. This is the meaning of the phrase, therefore, that a writing must be signed by the party charged with having made the agreement.

Some contracts need to be in writing to be valid; for example, contracts related to the sale and leasing of land. This writing must be signed by the person who is supposed to have made the agreement. Imagine that A sold his farm to B for an agreed amount but refuses to give him a deed after he pays or offers to pay. If B wants to force A to fulfill his agreement, he must show a written document signed by A to prove it; otherwise, the court won't consider the issue. On the flip side, if A argues that there was an agreement with B, who doesn't want to pay and get the deed, A must present a written document signed by B that confirms he agreed to buy the farm at a specific price and to receive the deed. If such a document isn't provided when needed, A can't recover anything from B. This is the meaning of the phrase that a writing must be signed by the party accused of making the agreement.

The writing need not be very formal. It need not specify the amount that is to be paid; in other words, it need not specify the consideration. Some courts say, however, that it must contain this fact or statement. It may be in pencil. I presume it would be sufficient if[333] written on a blackboard with chalk. But it must be a writing of some kind signed by the party to be charged; that is the essential thing. The courts have also said that this writing need not be on a single piece of paper. If the two parties have made an agreement by a series of letters, an offer on the one side and an acceptance on the other, and the agreement can be fully shown from the series of letters, this is sufficient writing.

The writing doesn't have to be very formal. It doesn't need to specify the amount that is to be paid; in other words, it doesn't have to state the consideration. Some courts, however, say that it must include this fact or statement. It can be in pencil. I suppose it would be enough if[333] written on a blackboard with chalk. But it has to be some kind of writing signed by the party being held accountable; that's the key point. The courts have also stated that this writing doesn't have to be on a single piece of paper. If the two parties have come to an agreement through a series of letters, one side making an offer and the other side accepting it, and the agreement can be clearly shown through those letters, then that counts as sufficient writing.

If a man buys a farm and pays a part of the price and goes away saying that he will pay the remainder within a week, expecting then to do so and receive a deed, the seller, if he chooses, can escape giving that deed and parting with his farm. The payment of a part of the money does not bind the bargain, nor will the courts, though knowing this, compel the seller to give such a deed. The reader may ask, if this is the law, cannot the farmer practise a fraud on the buyer by receiving his money and keeping it and the farm too? He cannot do both things. If he refuses to give the deed he must, on the other hand, return the money; if he refuses to do this the buyer can compel him by a proper legal proceeding to refund the amount. In this way the buyer gets his money back again, but not the farm that he bought.

If a man buys a farm and pays part of the price but then leaves saying he'll pay the rest within a week, expecting to do so and receive a deed, the seller, if he wants, can choose not to give that deed and keep his farm. Making a partial payment doesn’t finalize the deal, and even though the courts know this, they won’t force the seller to provide the deed. You might wonder, if that's the law, how can the farmer not scam the buyer by taking his money and keeping both it and the farm? He can't do both. If he refuses to give the deed, he has to return the money; if he doesn't want to do that, the buyer can legally force him to refund the amount. This way, the buyer can get his money back, but he won't get the farm he bought.

It is said that this statute is as often used as a shield to protect men in doing wrong as in preventing frauds. In numberless cases persons, just like the farmer imagined, have used this statute as a means to protect them in not carrying out their agreements. This happens every day.

It’s said that this law is just as frequently used as a shield to protect people when they do wrong as it is to prevent fraud. In countless cases, individuals, much like the farmer imagined, have used this law as a way to avoid fulfilling their agreements. This happens every day.

This statute also relates to other matters. One clause says that an executor or administrator cannot be required to pay anything at all out of his own pocket on any promise that he has made unless it be in writing. Every one knows about the duties of an executor or administrator. An executor is one who settles the estate of a person who[334] has died leaving a will directing what shall be done with his wealth. An administrator is a person who settles the estate of a deceased person leaving no will. He is appointed by the law, which fully states his duties. Let us suppose that an executor is employed to settle an estate, and that he employs a carpenter to make some repairs on a house belonging to the estate. The contract is fairly enough made between the carpenter and the executor. Let us also suppose that he has no lien on the house for the work that he has done, or that he has lost his lien by reason of not having filed it in time, as the law requires. Afterward he goes to the executor and demands payment for the repairs that he has made. Let us suppose that the estate is insolvent and cannot pay all of its debts in full. At the time of making this contract neither party supposed this would happen. But, unhappily, debts have come to light so large and numerous that there is not property enough to pay all the creditors everything that is due them. The executor says to the carpenter: "There is not property enough to pay all of the creditors and you, unfortunately, must fare like all of the rest, and you cannot be paid a larger percentage on your share than the others." To the carpenter this would be unwelcome news, and he would doubtless say to the executor: "I made this contract with you expecting that you would pay me, and if the property of the estate is not sufficient you ought to pay me this. I am a poor man and cannot afford to lose any of my hard-earned money." The executor might say to him: "I am as poor as you and I cannot afford to pay you out of my own pocket, and in law you cannot compel me to do this." And, in truth, the carpenter could not do this unless the executor had made a contract in writing, agreeing in any event to pay whether there was money enough belonging to the estate or not.

This law also covers other issues. One part states that an executor or administrator is not required to pay anything out of their own pocket for any promise they made unless it’s in writing. Everyone knows the responsibilities of an executor or administrator. An executor is someone who manages the estate of a person who[334] has passed away, leaving a will that specifies what should be done with their assets. An administrator is a person who manages the estate of someone who has died without a will. They are appointed by law, which clearly outlines their duties. Let's say an executor is tasked with settling an estate and hires a carpenter to make repairs on a house belonging to the estate. The contract is properly made between the carpenter and the executor. Now, let’s assume the carpenter has no lien on the house for the work he did, or he lost it because he didn’t file it on time, as required by law. Later, he approaches the executor and asks for payment for the repairs. Let’s suppose the estate is insolvent and cannot pay all of its debts in full. When this contract was made, neither party expected this outcome. Yet, unfortunately, debts have surfaced that are so large and numerous that there isn’t enough property to pay all the creditors what they are owed. The executor tells the carpenter: "There isn’t enough property to pay all the creditors, and unfortunately, you must take the same treatment as the rest, and you won’t be paid a larger percentage than the others." This would be disappointing news for the carpenter, who might respond: "I made this deal with you expecting to get paid, and if there isn't enough money in the estate, you should cover this. I'm a poor man and can’t afford to lose any of my hard-earned money." The executor might reply: "I’m as broke as you are, and I can’t afford to pay you out of my own funds, and legally, you can’t force me to do that." In reality, the carpenter could not compel this unless the executor had made a written agreement promising to pay, regardless of whether there was enough money in the estate.

Another clause says that a person cannot be required[335] to pay the debt of another unless the agreement is in writing. If A went into a store to buy goods and B should be a little afraid to trust him, and C, a friend of A's, should happen to be present and say to the merchant, "Let A have these goods and if he does not pay you I will," this would be the promise to pay the debt of another; and if A should not pay it C could shield himself behind this statute and escape without paying anything.

Another clause states that a person cannot be required[335] to pay someone else's debt unless there's a written agreement. If A goes into a store to buy something and B is a bit hesitant to trust him, and C, a friend of A's, happens to be there and tells the merchant, "Let A have these goods, and if he doesn't pay you, I will," this would be a promise to pay someone else's debt. If A fails to pay, C could use this statute to protect himself and get away without paying anything.

There is another clause relating to the sale of ordinary merchandise. The law says that contracts for ordinary merchandise must be in writing if the amount is over $50. In some States the amount is $35. Long ago it was decided that this statute did not relate to contracts for work, and they therefore must be carried out or fulfilled in the same manner as though no statute existed, for work is not merchandise.

There’s another clause about selling regular merchandise. The law states that contracts for regular merchandise must be written down if the amount exceeds $50. In some states, the limit is $35. A long time ago, it was determined that this rule doesn’t apply to contracts for services, so these must be executed in the same way as if the law didn’t exist, because services aren’t merchandise.

[336]VIII. CONTRACTS FOR THE SALE OF MERCHANDISE

To make a contract of sale there must be, as we have seen, two or more parties, and a consideration must also be given. The sale is complete when the property, or title, or ownership in the thing bought passes from the seller to the buyer. It is not necessary in order to make a valid sale to deliver the thing bought. If the title or ownership in the thing is not transferred, the sale still remains incomplete.

To create a sales contract, there must be at least two parties, and something of value needs to be exchanged. The sale is finalized when the property, or title, or ownership of the item purchased is transferred from the seller to the buyer. It's not required to actually deliver the item for the sale to be valid. However, if the title or ownership of the item isn't transferred, the sale is still considered incomplete.

The law supposes or assumes that a person will always pay for a thing purchased. If I should go into a store, inquire the price of a book, and, after learning the price, should say to the salesman, "I will take the book," and he should wrap it up and give it to me and I should then walk out with the book under my arm, he doubtless would come to me and say in his politest manner: "Why, sir, you have forgotten to pay me for it." Suppose I should say: "Oh, yes; but I will come in to-morrow and pay." But if I happened to be a stranger, and especially if there was a suspicious look about me, and he should say they did not give credit in that store, and I was still inclined to walk out with my book, he could insist that there had been no sale and that I must give the book to him. The law would protect him in taking it from me if he did not use undue force. The law assumes, unless[337] some different rule exists, that the buyer will always pay for the thing purchased, yet in law there is no sale unless the purchase money is actually paid.

The law assumes that a person will always pay for something they buy. If I go into a store, ask how much a book costs, and then say to the salesperson, "I'll take the book," and they wrap it up and hand it to me, and I walk out with the book under my arm, they would surely come after me and politely say, "Excuse me, sir, you forgot to pay for this." If I reply, "Oh, right; but I'll come back tomorrow to pay," and I'm a stranger, especially if I seem suspicious, the salesperson could say that they don't give credit in that store and insist that there hasn't been a sale, so I need to return the book. The law would allow them to take it back as long as they don’t use excessive force. The law assumes, unless[337] there is a different rule, that the buyer will always pay for what they bought, but in legal terms, there is no sale until the payment is actually made.

Of course, credit may be given in a store—that may be the practice; and if it is understood between buyer and seller that credit is to be given, then a sale is complete as soon as the bargain is struck. Indeed, so complete is the sale that if the buyer should say to the salesman, "I will leave this here and return and take it in a short time," and during his absence the store should be burned up and everything perish, the buyer would be obliged to pay for the book. In other words, after it had been sold, if still kept there the seller would be merely the keeper, or bailee, which is the legal term, and he would be obliged to use only ordinary care in keeping it. Suppose a thief should come in and take it away—would the seller be responsible for the loss? Not if he had used the same care in protecting it as in protecting his own property.

Of course, a store can offer credit—that might be standard practice; and if both the buyer and seller agree that credit will be provided, then the sale is finalized as soon as the deal is made. In fact, the sale is so final that if the buyer told the salesperson, "I’ll leave this here and come back to get it soon," and while they were away the store burned down and everything was lost, the buyer would still have to pay for the book. In other words, once the sale is made, if the item is still at the store, the seller is just holding onto it, or acting as a bailee, which is the legal term, and they only need to take reasonable care of it. If a thief came in and stole it—would the seller be liable for the loss? Not if they had taken the same precautions to protect it as they would for their own belongings.

Another illustration may be used to bring out the nature of a sale more clearly. Suppose I have bought a particular work in a store, either paying cash or buying it on credit, if that be the practice of the store, and I should say to the salesman: "I am going down street and on my return will call and take the book." During my absence I meet a friend and tell him of my purchase, and he should say to me: "I am very desirous to get that work; I am sure there is no other copy in town. Will you not sell it to me?" Suppose I gave him an order, directed to the seller, requesting him to deliver the work to the person to whom I have sold it. If he should take the order to the store he could claim the book as his own and the original seller would be obliged to give it to him.

Another example can help clarify the nature of a sale. Imagine I’ve bought a specific item at a store, either paying cash or on credit, depending on the store's policy, and I tell the salesperson, "I’m going down the street and will come back to pick up the book." While I’m gone, I run into a friend and mention my purchase, and he says, "I really want that book; I’m sure there isn't another copy in town. Will you sell it to me?" Let’s say I give him a note addressed to the seller, asking them to give the book to the person I sold it to. If he takes that note to the store, he could claim the book as his own, and the original seller would have to give it to him.

It is very important, however, in many cases to make a[338] delivery of the thing sold. As we have already stated, the title as between the buyer and seller is actually changed or transferred at the time of making the sale and it is therefore complete. But if a delivery of the thing sold is not actually made and another person should come along and wish to buy it, and the seller should prove to be, as he sometimes is, deceitfully wicked, and should sell and deliver it to him, the second buyer would get a good title and could hold it just as securely as though it had not been previously sold to another. Of course, the second buyer must be an innocent person, knowing nothing about the first or prior sale. If he did not know and pays the money for the thing he has bought and takes it away, he gets a perfectly good title as against the first buyer. If he was not innocent the first buyer could claim it and the second one would lose his money unless he was able to get it back again from the seller. Of course, such a transaction is a fraud on the part of the seller. Therefore it is safer in all ordinary transactions for the buyer to take the thing he has purchased unless he is sure that the seller is a perfectly honest man, who will not practise any such fraud upon him.

It’s very important, though, in many situations to actually make a[338] delivery of the item sold. As we've mentioned before, the ownership between the buyer and seller actually changes or transfers at the moment of sale, so it’s considered complete. However, if the item sold isn’t actually delivered and someone else comes along wishing to buy it, and if the seller turns out to be, as can sometimes happen, deceitfully dishonest, and sells and delivers it to that person, the second buyer would receive a valid title and could keep it just as securely as if it had never been sold to someone else first. Naturally, the second buyer must be an innocent person, unaware of the first or previous sale. If they don’t know and pay for the item and take it away, they get a completely good title against the first buyer. If they weren’t innocent, the first buyer could reclaim the item, and the second buyer would lose their money unless they could get it back from the seller. This situation is, of course, a fraud on the part of the seller. Therefore, it’s safer in most typical transactions for the buyer to take the item they've purchased unless they are sure that the seller is completely honest and won’t commit such fraud against them.

Suppose the seller had things in his keeping that had been sold but not taken away, and should fail in business, or that persons to whom he owed money should sue him and try to hold not only all of the goods still owned by him but even those which he had sold. Could they succeed as against a person who had bought them in perfectly good faith? It is said that the buyer in such cases can get his goods after clearly showing that he had bought them and paid for them; but the evidence of his purchase must be perfectly clear, otherwise the court will not permit him to take them away and he will lose them.

Suppose the seller had items that were sold but not picked up, and he goes out of business, or that people he owes money to sue him and try to claim not just all the goods he still owns, but also those he sold. Would they be able to succeed against someone who bought them in good faith? It’s said that the buyer in these situations can get his items back after clearly proving he bought and paid for them; however, his evidence of purchase must be completely clear; otherwise, the court won’t allow him to take them back, and he will lose them.

If a merchant is to deliver a thing as a part of the contract of sale, then, of course, he must do this; otherwise[339] he is liable for his failure to carry out his contract. This rule applies to most purchases that are made in stores. The merchant intends to deliver the thing sold, the buyer purchases expecting this will be done, and the price paid for them is enough to cover the cost of taking them to the buyer's house; in other words, the price of the goods, whatever it may be, is intended to be enough to pay the merchant for his cost in delivering them, and in such cases the contract is not complete until a delivery has actually taken place.

If a merchant agrees to deliver an item as part of a sale contract, they must follow through; otherwise[339] they are responsible for not fulfilling their contract. This rule applies to most purchases made in stores. The merchant plans to deliver the item sold, the buyer expects this will happen, and the price paid is meant to cover the cost of delivering it to the buyer's home; in other words, the price of the goods, whatever it is, is intended to compensate the merchant for their delivery costs, and in such cases, the contract isn’t complete until the delivery actually occurs.

Again, if the thing purchased is a part of a mass of goods, a separation must be made to complete the contract. If a man should buy 100 barrels of oil which were a part of 1000 barrels, a separation of some kind must be made of the particular ones sold. If one should buy trees in a nursery, to make the contract complete the particular trees must in some way be known, either by rows or every other tree—in short, in some way the trees must be clearly set apart. If part of a mass of timber is bought, the particular logs must be marked or in some way pointed out from the other part of the mass. This rule applies to all things bought that form a part of a large mass. The mode of pointing them out depends on the nature of the thing; a different kind of separation must be made in some cases from what is necessary in others.

Again, if what’s purchased is part of a larger bulk of goods, a separation must be made to finalize the contract. For example, if someone buys 100 barrels of oil that are part of 1,000 barrels, some type of separation needs to occur for the specific barrels sold. If someone buys trees in a nursery, the specific trees must be identifiable in some way, like by rows or every other tree; in short, the trees must be clearly distinguished. If part of a bulk of timber is bought, the specific logs must be marked or identified in some way from the rest of the bulk. This rule applies to all items purchased that are part of a larger mass. The method of identification depends on the nature of the item; different situations may require different types of separation.

[340]IX. THE WARRANTIES OF MERCHANDISE

The rule of law in buying is, the buyer must look out for himself; and if things are not what he supposed they were he has no rightful claim against the seller. The maxim of the law is, "Let the purchaser beware"—let him take care of himself. The rule of the Roman law was different. It was the duty of the seller to tell the buyer of all the defects known by him in the thing sold, and if he did not he was responsible for any loss caused by any defect or imperfection found after purchasing that was known by the seller before.

The rule of law in buying is, the buyer must look out for himself; and if things are not what he thought they were, he doesn’t have any legal claim against the seller. The legal principle is, "Let the purchaser beware"—the buyer needs to take care of himself. The rule in Roman law was different. It was the seller's responsibility to inform the buyer of any defects he knew about in the item being sold, and if he didn’t, he was liable for any losses caused by defects or issues that were known to him before the sale.

The modern principle may be looked at from two points of view. First, the seller need not make known any defects which the buyer can find out himself. Suppose a man is thinking of buying a horse that is (though he does not know it) blind in one eye. The law says that the buyer ought to be able to see such a defect quite as readily as the seller, and if he does not the fault is his own. Blindness in one eye is quite as easily seen as would be the lack of an ear or tail. And this principle applies very generally in all purchases. It covers all visible defects. Nor can any one find much fault with this rule, because the buyer generally has as good eyesight as the seller, and if he takes pains, as he should, he is able to discover all ordinary defects. Furthermore, the buyer doubtless often[341] knows quite as much about the things he purchases as the seller.

The modern principle can be viewed in two ways. First, the seller doesn't have to disclose any defects that the buyer can discover on their own. For instance, if a person is considering buying a horse that is (although he doesn't realize it) blind in one eye, the law states that the buyer should be able to notice such a defect just as easily as the seller can. If he doesn't, that’s his own fault. Blindness in one eye is as obvious as the absence of an ear or tail. This principle applies broadly to all purchases and covers all visible defects. Furthermore, there's not much to criticize about this rule, because typically the buyer has eyesight that is just as good as the seller's, and if he puts in the effort, as he should, he can spot all ordinary defects. Moreover, the buyer often [341] knows just as much about the items he buys as the seller.

But the courts also say that it applies to other defects. Suppose a horse has the heaves or the rheumatism, which is known to the seller but of which the buyer has no knowledge whatever. The seller is not obliged to make known this defect to the buyer, and if he is silly enough to purchase on his own wisdom he must abide by the consequences. If he does inquire and is deceived, that is another thing. But if he asks no questions, or the seller does not deceive him in any way, the seller is not responsible for defects known by him at the time of the sale. This also is a well-understood rule.

But the courts also say that it applies to other flaws. For example, if a horse has heaves or rheumatism, and the seller knows about it but the buyer has no clue, the seller doesn’t have to reveal this defect to the buyer. If the buyer is foolish enough to rely solely on their own judgment, they have to deal with the consequences. If the buyer asks questions and gets misled, that’s a different story. But if they don’t ask anything, or if the seller doesn’t deceive them in any way, the seller isn’t responsible for defects known to them at the time of sale. This is also a well-understood rule.

The seller, we repeat, must not deceive the buyer. In one of the well-known cases a man owned a ship that he was desirous of selling. She was unsound in several places and the seller put her in such a position that her defects could not be readily found out. He did this for the purpose of deceiving the buyer and succeeded. When the buyer learned how he had been tricked he began a legal proceeding to get back a part of the money that he had paid, and won his case. And rightfully, too, for the reason that the seller had deceived him, which he had no right to do.

The seller, we emphasize, must not mislead the buyer. In one of the famous cases, a man owned a ship that he wanted to sell. The ship had several defects, and the seller positioned it in such a way that the flaws couldn’t be easily discovered. He did this to trick the buyer, and he succeeded. When the buyer found out how he had been deceived, he began legal proceedings to recover part of the money he had paid and won his case. And rightly so, because the seller had misled him, which he had no right to do.

Another case may be stated of a man who was desirous of purchasing a picture, supposing that it was once in the collection of an eminent man. The seller knew perfectly well that the picture did not come from that collection and that the buyer was acting under a delusion. He did not say that the picture had belonged to the collection or had not; he was silent, although he knew that the buyer would not purchase it if he knew the truth about its former ownership. For some reason or other the buyer did not make any inquiry of the seller, or if he did was not told. But after purchasing the picture the[342] buyer learned that he was mistaken and that the seller knew this at the time of making the sale. He sought to recover the money he had paid and succeeded, the court saying that a fraud had been practised upon him; that it was the duty of the seller, knowing what was passing in the mind of the buyer, to have told him the truth about the former ownership of the picture.

Another case can be described involving a man who wanted to buy a painting, believing it had once belonged to a famous collection. The seller was fully aware that the painting had not come from that collection and that the buyer was mistaken. He didn’t clarify whether the painting was part of the collection or not; he remained silent, even though he knew the buyer wouldn't have made the purchase if he had known the truth about its past ownership. For some reason, the buyer didn’t ask the seller any questions, or if he did, he didn’t get an answer. But after buying the painting, the[342] buyer realized he was wrong and that the seller had known this at the time of the sale. He tried to get the money he had paid back and was successful, with the court stating that he had been defrauded; they determined that it was the seller’s responsibility, knowing what the buyer was thinking, to have disclosed the truth about the painting’s previous ownership.

It will be seen, therefore, that the seller must not deceive the buyer in any way or practise any fraud on him; if he does he will be responsible for the loss or injury befalling the other.

It’s clear that the seller must not mislead the buyer in any way or commit any fraud against them; if they do, they will be liable for any loss or harm that occurs to the buyer.

What, then, ought a buyer to do in purchasing a horse, for example, in order to guard himself against the unwelcome discovery of disease or other defect? Clearly, he ought to require the seller to give him a warranty. A proper way is, if the transaction be an important one, to have the warranty in writing and signed by the seller. It need not be very long; a few words usually are enough.

What should a buyer do when buying a horse, for instance, to protect himself from finding out about any diseases or other issues after the purchase? Clearly, he should ask the seller for a warranty. If the deal is significant, it’s best to have the warranty in writing and signed by the seller. It doesn't have to be long; just a few words are usually sufficient.

There is a very important difference that every one ought to understand between words that are spoken at a sale, which are mere representations, and words that form a warranty of the thing sold. If I should go into a store to buy a piece of flannel, and ask the salesman if it was all wool, and he should assure me that it was, and I, ignorant of the quality of the material, and desirous of buying a piece of all-wool flannel, should say to him: "I know nothing about it; I rely entirely on your statement," and he should say: "It is all right; all wool, and no cotton," his words would be a warranty, and if the flannel proved to be made partly of straw or cotton, or something besides wool, I could sue the seller on his warranty, and recover for the loss I had suffered, whatever that might be. But suppose I were a flannel manufacturer myself, and knew at the time he was saying this to me that the flannel was partly cotton; in short, knew a[343] great deal more about it than he did, and was not deceived in any way by what he said, his words would not be a warranty, because my action in buying the flannel would not be influenced by them.

There’s a crucial difference everyone should understand between statements made during a sale, which are just representations, and statements that serve as a warranty for the item being sold. If I walk into a store to buy a piece of flannel and ask the salesman if it's all wool, and he assures me it is, while I, not knowing the material's quality and wanting all-wool flannel, say to him, "I don't know anything about it; I completely trust your word," and he replies, "It's all good; all wool, no cotton," then his words would constitute a warranty. If the flannel turns out to be made partly of straw or cotton or anything other than wool, I could sue the seller based on his warranty and recover for my loss, whatever that may be. But if I were a flannel manufacturer and knew at that moment he was saying this that the flannel contained some cotton—essentially, I knew much more about it than he did and wasn’t misled by his words—then his statements wouldn’t be a warranty because my decision to buy the flannel wouldn’t be influenced by what he said.

What test, then, is to be applied? Evidently whether or not the buyer acts on the words spoken and is deceived by them. If, relying on them, he buys and is deceived or misled to his loss or injury, then the words will be taken as a warranty and protect the buyer. If, on the other hand, he is not deceived by what is told him, and he buys on his own knowledge and judgment, then the words are not a warranty.

What test should be used, then? Clearly, it's whether the buyer relies on what was said and is misled by it. If he buys based on that and ends up being deceived or suffers a loss because of it, then those words will be considered a warranty and will protect the buyer. However, if he isn’t deceived by what he was told and makes the purchase based on his own knowledge and judgment, then those words are not a warranty.

One or two other points may be briefly noticed. The law says that the seller always warrants the title to the thing sold—in other words, that he is the owner. He may not say one word about the matter, but the law implies that he is the owner and would not sell a thing that did not belong to him. If he should prove not to be the owner, the buyer could recover for his loss.

One or two other points can be mentioned briefly. The law states that the seller always guarantees the title to the item sold—in other words, that he is the owner. He might not say anything about it, but the law assumes that he is the owner and wouldn't sell something that doesn't belong to him. If he turns out not to be the owner, the buyer could claim compensation for his loss.

Another point about adulterations. The common law does not regard an article as adulterated, giving the buyer the right to claim something back, unless it has been materially changed by the foreign substance. All, or nearly all, of the States have made statutes within recent years, or re-enacted old ones, holding sellers strictly responsible for the quality, especially of provisions, sold. These statutes generally require the seller to sell absolutely pure articles, and he cannot shield himself by saying that he was ignorant and innocent of their nature if they proved to be other than pure articles. If a grocer should sell cotton-seed oil for olive oil, even though doing so ignorantly, without any intention to deceive, he would nevertheless be held liable under the statutes that now exist in most of the States; and public opinion strongly favours the strict execution of these statutes.

Another point about adulterations. The common law doesn't view an item as adulterated, giving the buyer the right to get something back, unless it has been significantly altered by foreign substances. Almost all states have enacted new laws in recent years or updated old ones, holding sellers strictly accountable for the quality of what's sold, especially food. These laws typically require sellers to provide completely pure products, and they can't defend themselves by claiming ignorance or innocence if the items turn out to be impure. For example, if a grocer sells cottonseed oil as olive oil, even if done unknowingly and without any intent to deceive, they would still be held liable under the laws that most states have today; and public opinion strongly supports strict enforcement of these laws.

[344]X. COMMON CARRIERS

What is meant by a common carrier? A person or company that is obliged to carry merchandise or passengers for a price or compensation from place to place. A common carrier cannot select his business, like a private carrier, but must carry all merchandise that is offered; or, if he is a carrier of persons, all persons who desire to go and are willing to respect all reasonable regulations that relate to carrying them. The principal common carriers are railroads, steamboats, and canal companies.

What is a common carrier? A person or company that is required to transport goods or passengers for a fee from one place to another. A common carrier can't choose the business they take on, like a private carrier can; they must carry all goods offered to them or, if they’re transporting people, they must accommodate all passengers who want to travel and agree to all reasonable rules related to the service. The main common carriers are railroads, steamboats, and canal companies.

The liability of common carriers is very important to all who travel or send merchandise. A common carrier is liable for all losses not happening by the act of God or by the public enemy. By "act of God" is meant unavoidable calamity, such as lightning and tempests, and by "public enemy" is meant a nation at war with another. Once these were the only exceptions. Carriers were therefore insurers of the goods left with them to be carried to some other place.

The liability of common carriers is crucial for anyone who travels or sends goods. A common carrier is responsible for all losses unless they are caused by an act of God or an enemy nation. An "act of God" refers to unavoidable disasters like lightning or storms, and a "public enemy" refers to a country at war with another. These were once the only exceptions. Therefore, carriers were essentially insurers of the goods entrusted to them for transport to another location.

This early rule of law fixing their liability has been greatly changed. Carriers can now make a contract relieving themselves of all liability for losses in carrying goods except those arising from their own negligence. The courts in a few cases have said that they can relieve themselves even from this, but this is not generally the[345] law. They can, though, by special contract relieve themselves from all other liability. A railroad company, therefore, can make a contract for carrying wheat from Chicago to New York, relieving itself from all liability for loss by fire unless this shall be caused by its negligence. If a fire should occur without any negligence on the part of the company and goods on the way should be destroyed, it could not be held responsible for the loss if there was such a contract between the shipper and carrier. A carrier is no longer an insurer for the safe carrying of goods.

This early rule of law determining their liability has changed a lot. Carriers can now enter into contracts that free them from all liability for losses while transporting goods, except for those caused by their own negligence. In a few cases, courts have said they could be exempt from even that, but that's not the general rule. However, they can, through special contracts, relieve themselves of all other liability. So, a railroad company can make a contract to transport wheat from Chicago to New York, freeing itself from all liability for loss due to fire unless it results from their negligence. If a fire happens without any negligence on the company's part and the goods are destroyed en route, they can't be held responsible for the loss if there was such a contract between the shipper and the carrier. A carrier is no longer responsible for ensuring the safe transport of goods.

The courts have permitted carriers to thus lessen their liability because they are willing to take goods at lower prices than they would if they were to be responsible for all losses. They now virtually say to the shippers: "If you are willing to be your own insurers, or insure in insurance companies, and hold us for no losses except those arising from our own negligence, we are willing to carry your goods at a much lower rate." And, as shippers are willing to take the risks themselves for the sake of getting lower rates, the practice has become universal for lessening the liability of carriers in the manner described.

The courts have allowed carriers to reduce their liability because they're willing to transport goods at lower prices than they would if they were responsible for all losses. They essentially say to shippers: "If you're okay with being your own insurers or getting insurance from other companies, and you only hold us accountable for losses caused by our own negligence, we can carry your goods at a much lower rate." Since shippers are willing to take on the risks themselves to get these lower rates, this practice has become widespread for reducing carrier liability in this way.

Suppose that goods are burned up by fire. The shipper must be the loser unless he can show that it was caused by the negligence of the carrier. As he often can show this, he imagines that the carrier is still living under the old law and is liable as he was in the early days of railroad and steamboat companies. In truth, this is not so. His liability is measured by his contract, and there can be no recovery for any loss unless negligence on the carrier's part is clearly shown, and in many cases this is not easily done.

Suppose goods are destroyed by fire. The shipper will take the loss unless they can prove it was due to the carrier's negligence. Since the shipper can often prove this, they think the carrier is still under the old laws and is responsible as they were in the early days of railroads and steamboat companies. However, that’s not the case. The carrier's liability is determined by their contract, and recovery for any loss requires clear evidence of the carrier's negligence, which is not always easy to demonstrate.

Though common or public carriers are obliged to take and transport almost everything, they may make reasonable regulations about the packing, etc., of merchandise. Suppose a shipper were to come to a railroad company's[346] clerk with a quantity of glass not in boxes, and should say to him, "I wish this glass to be carried to New York"; and the clerk should say to him that the rules of the company required all glass to be packed in boxes lined with straw, and that the rule could not be set aside, however short might be the distance. Very likely the shipper would say to the agent: "This is expensive; I wish you to take it as it is." And if he should say to the agent that he was willing to run the risk of breakage, then, perhaps, the clerk might take it in; yet, even on those terms, some carriers would not. At all events, if the clerk should insist on following the rules, the shipper could not justly complain, for this rule is a very reasonable one, as the courts have many times declared.

Though common or public carriers are required to accept and transport almost anything, they can establish reasonable rules regarding the packing, etc., of goods. Imagine a shipper approaching a railroad company’s[346] clerk with a bunch of glass that isn't in boxes, and saying, "I want this glass shipped to New York"; and the clerk responds that the company's rules state that all glass must be packed in boxes lined with straw, and that this rule can't be overlooked, regardless of how short the distance is. The shipper might then say, "This is too costly; I want you to take it as it is." If he tells the agent that he's willing to risk breakage, then the clerk might agree to accept it; still, some carriers might not. In any case, if the clerk insists on following the rules, the shipper can't justly complain, as this rule is very reasonable, as the courts have stated many times.

Suppose a shipper should ask a carrier to take a load of potatoes or apples to Montreal in very cold weather. The carrier says to him: "There is danger of the apples being frozen. I am unwilling to carry them unless you will take the risk of their freezing." He could insist on these terms, because it would be unreasonable to require carriers to transport such merchandise and keep their cars heated. They are not made in that way and every shipper knows it, nor are carriers required to heat them.

Suppose a shipper asks a carrier to take a load of potatoes or apples to Montreal in very cold weather. The carrier responds, "There's a risk the apples could freeze. I'm not willing to transport them unless you're okay with that risk." He can set these terms because it's unreasonable to expect carriers to transport such goods and keep their trucks heated. They're not designed for that, and every shipper knows it, nor are carriers required to heat them.

The courts have said that any reasonable regulations respecting the merchandise to be carried, the packing, etc., must be respected. A carrier could refuse positively to carry dynamite or powder unless it was packed in a very careful manner. Doubtless many things are carried in ways quite contrary to the regulations, without the knowledge of the carrying companies. Packages are rarely examined and things may be put within, out of sight, of which carriers know nothing.

The courts have stated that any reasonable regulations regarding the merchandise being transported, the packing, etc., must be followed. A carrier can definitely refuse to transport dynamite or explosives unless they are packed very carefully. It's likely that many items are shipped in ways that go against the regulations without the carriers knowing. Packages are seldom inspected, and items may be placed inside, out of sight, that the carriers are completely unaware of.

A carrier is not required to have cars enough to carry all goods on unusual occasions. But it must have enough to carry without delay all that come from day to day.

A carrier isn't required to have enough vehicles to handle all goods during rare situations. However, it must have enough to transport everything that arrives daily without delay.

[347]XI. THE CARRYING OF PASSENGERS

Millions ride on steamboats, in the street-cars, and by steam-railways, and the question is an important one with them. What are the rights and duties of company and passenger? First, it is the duty of a company carrying passengers to provide every one with a seat. This rule does not apply to street-cars but it does to steam-railways. In some cases it is said of the street-car passengers that those who use the straps pay the money from which dividends are paid. But the rule is otherwise that applies to railway companies. They must furnish seats for their passengers and cannot demand fares until seats are secured.

Millions travel on steamboats, in streetcars, and by trains, and this is an important issue for them. What are the rights and responsibilities of the company and the passenger? First, it is the duty of a company transporting passengers to provide everyone with a seat. This rule does not apply to streetcars but does apply to trains. In some cases, it’s said that streetcar passengers who hold onto the straps are paying the money that funds the dividends. However, the rule for railway companies is different. They must provide seats for their passengers and cannot charge fares until seats are available.

Having taken him on board and seated him, what degree of care must the company use in carrying the passenger? It may seem strange to say that the company is not obliged to use as much care as in carrying a barrel of apples or an animal. Goods must be moved, kept dry, perhaps, and cared for in other ways. An animal must be fed. In carrying cattle stops must be made for rest. But the passenger takes care of himself. He gets in and out and provides his own rations. Therefore the law puts on the carrier the duty of using only a reasonable degree of care in taking him from place to place. In other words, the railway is not an insurer of life, as it is of goods or other merchandise. As passen[348]gers are of themselves able to get around and use some care with respect to their own movements, the law lessens the responsibility.

Having taken him on board and seated him, what level of care must the company provide in transporting the passenger? It might seem odd to say that the company isn't required to use as much care as it does when carrying a barrel of apples or an animal. Goods need to be transported, kept dry, and taken care of in various ways. An animal needs to be fed, and when transporting cattle, breaks must be taken for resting. But the passenger manages their own needs. They enter and exit the transport and supply their own food. Therefore, the law places on the carrier the obligation to exercise only a reasonable level of care in getting them from one place to another. In other words, the railway is not a guarantor of safety for passengers, unlike it is for goods or other merchandise. Since passengers are capable of moving around and taking care of themselves, the law reduces the level of responsibility.

Perhaps the reader would like to know what the company must do in carrying a passenger's baggage. This is a very practical question. If he takes his grip in the seat with him, he alone is responsible for its safety. If some one should get in the seat beside him and in going out should take the grip along with him, the owner could not ask the company to make good his loss. On the other hand, if he delivers his grip to the company, then the company is bound by the same rule as when carrying other goods and merchandise. The price paid for his ticket is also enough to pay the cost of carrying his trunk or other baggage, therefore the carrier cannot escape paying for its loss when having possession of it on the ground that the service is purely voluntary and without compensation. As the company gets compensation it must pay for any loss while taking baggage from one place to another unless the loss or damage should be due to no fault or negligence of the company.

Perhaps the reader would like to know what the company must do in carrying a passenger's baggage. This is a very practical question. If the passenger takes their bag with them to their seat, they alone are responsible for its safety. If someone else sits beside them and accidentally takes the bag when leaving, the owner cannot hold the company liable for the loss. On the other hand, if they hand their bag over to the company, then the company is obligated to the same rules as when transporting other goods. The fare paid for the ticket also covers the cost of transporting their trunk or other baggage, so the carrier cannot avoid responsibility for its loss while it is in their possession, claiming that the service is purely voluntary and without charge. Since the company receives payment, it must cover any loss while transporting baggage from one location to another unless the loss or damage is due to something beyond the company’s control or negligence.

Every now and then we receive a cheque for a trunk or other piece of baggage stating that in the event of loss the company will not be responsible beyond a certain amount—$50, or $100, or other sum. Is that statement on the cheque worth anything? The courts have held that if one of these cheques is taken by a passenger and he reads it he is bound thereby. This is a contract between carrier and passenger, consequently he is bound by the figures mentioned under ordinary circumstances. This rule is just and is based on a good reason. As every one knows, whenever a trunk is lost it is very difficult for the carrier to get any proof of the real value of its contents. All the evidence is in the hands of the passenger. If he is without a conscience and apparently[349] proves that the things in it were worth $200 or $300, he may succeed in getting this much, although it might have been full of shavings. It is because of much experience of this kind that carriers have tried to limit the amount for which they will be responsible, and so long as they do this in a fair, open way the law regards their conduct with favour. If, however, a passenger receives such a cheque and at once puts it in his pocket and does not know its true nature, then the courts have held that he was not bound by any limit of this kind.

Every so often, we get a check for a trunk or other piece of luggage stating that if it gets lost, the company won't be responsible for more than a certain amount—$50, $100, or some other sum. Is that statement on the check worth anything? The courts have ruled that if a passenger takes one of these checks and reads it, they are bound by it. This creates a contract between the carrier and passenger, so they're held to the amounts mentioned under normal circumstances. This rule is fair and makes sense. As everyone knows, when a trunk is lost, it's very hard for the carrier to prove the actual value of its contents. All the information is with the passenger. If they’re dishonest and claim that the items inside were worth $200 or $300, they might get that much, even if the trunk was filled with shavings. Because of many experiences like this, carriers have tried to limit their liability, and as long as they do this openly and fairly, the law supports them. However, if a passenger receives such a check and simply stashes it away without understanding what it means, the courts have ruled that they are not bound by any limits like that.

Again, a person has no business to put diamonds and rubies and jewellery and the like in his trunk. If he does and they are lost, he cannot compel the carrier to pay for them. The courts have said that passengers have no right to put such things in their trunks expecting to make carriers pay for them when they are lost. If there are things of unusual value in a trunk, the carrier should be informed or else the owner should assume the risk.

Again, a person shouldn’t pack diamonds, rubies, jewelry, and similar items in their suitcase. If those items go missing, they can’t force the carrier to compensate them. The courts have ruled that passengers don’t have the right to put such valuable items in their luggage expecting the carriers to cover the loss. If there are items of significant value in a suitcase, the carrier should be notified, or the owner needs to take on the risk.

One word more. An express company is a common carrier and is bound by the same rules as other carriers except so far as such rules may be changed by definite contract. When a definite contract is made, then the rules of ordinary carriers do not apply.

One more thing. An express company is a common carrier and is required to follow the same rules as other carriers, unless those rules are changed by a specific contract. When a specific contract is made, then the rules for ordinary carriers don’t apply.

[350]XII. ON THE KEEPING OF THINGS

There are some principles of every-day importance relating to the keeping of things.

There are some important principles related to keeping things.

In our last lecture was mentioned the carriage of merchandise by common carriers. They not only carry merchandise—they also keep it. When merchandise reaches its destination and shippers have had a reasonable time to take it away, but neglect to do so, a common carrier is no longer liable for its safe keeping as a common carrier but only as a warehouseman. What do we mean by this? As we have seen, a common carrier, unless he makes a special contract for carrying the merchandise, is liable for everything lost or injured except "by the act of God or the public enemy"; or, as we have already said, he is an insurer for safely taking and keeping the merchandise while it is in his charge. When the merchandise has reached the final station, and the person to whom it is shipped or sent has had ample time to take it away and does not do so, the carrier still keeps the merchandise in his warehouse or depot, but he is no longer liable as a carrier for keeping it but simply as a warehouseman. In other words, if goods are kept by him for this longer period, he is liable for their loss only in the event of gross negligence on his part. If a fire should break out and the goods be burned, unless it happened[351] by his own gross negligence, he would not be liable for the loss. So, too, if a thief should break into his warehouse and steal the goods, he would not be liable for the theft unless it was shown that he was grossly negligent in not providing a safer building. If the rats and mice should destroy the goods while they were in the common carrier's building, the same rule would apply; or if they were injured or destroyed in any other manner, he would not be responsible for the loss unless gross negligence was shown.

In our last lecture, we talked about how common carriers transport merchandise. They don’t just move goods—they also store them. Once the merchandise arrives at its destination and the shippers have had a reasonable amount of time to pick it up but fail to do so, the common carrier is no longer responsible for keeping it safe as a carrier but only as a warehouse operator. What does this mean? As we’ve discussed, a common carrier is liable for any loss or damage unless it’s due to "Acts of God or the public enemy"; in other words, they are responsible for safely transporting and storing the merchandise while it’s in their possession. When the goods arrive at the final point and the recipient has had plenty of time to collect them but doesn’t, the carrier still keeps the items in their warehouse or depot, yet they are no longer liable as a carrier for storage, only as a warehouse operator. This means that if they store the goods for this extra time, they are only responsible for loss if there's gross negligence on their part. For example, if a fire occurs and damages the goods, unless it’s proven that it happened due to their own gross negligence, they wouldn’t be liable for the loss. Similarly, if a thief breaks into their warehouse and steals the goods, they wouldn't be responsible unless it can be shown that they were grossly negligent in not securing a safer building. If rats or mice damage the goods while they’re in the common carrier’s facility, the same principle applies; if they are harmed or destroyed in any other way, the carrier won’t be held accountable for the loss unless gross negligence is proven.

Different rules apply, depending on whether the keeper, or bailee, gets any compensation for storage. In our lecture relating to sales we stated that the seller would not be liable for the loss of anything intrusted to his keeping after it had been bought of him unless he was grossly negligent, for the reason that no reward or compensation is paid to him for storage. There are, therefore, two rules which govern many cases. If a person keeps a thing for a reward or compensation, then he is bound by a stricter rule of diligence than in those cases in which he receives nothing for his service. This accords with the common reason of mankind. Evidently if a person keeps a thing simply as an act of kindness, he ought not to be responsible in the same sense that one is held responsible who is paid a fixed price for such service.

Different rules apply depending on whether the keeper or bailee receives any compensation for storage. In our sales lecture, we mentioned that the seller wouldn't be responsible for the loss of anything entrusted to him after it was purchased unless he was grossly negligent, since he doesn’t get paid for storage. Therefore, there are two main rules that govern many situations. If someone is keeping something for a reward or payment, they are held to a stricter standard of care than in cases where they receive nothing for their service. This aligns with common sense. Clearly, if someone is keeping something purely out of goodwill, they shouldn’t be held responsible in the same way as someone who is paid a fixed amount for that service.

Another good illustration is that of a bank which keeps the bonds of a depositor in its safe for his accommodation. The bank does not pretend to be a safe-deposit company or anything of the kind, but it has a large vault and wishes to accommodate its customers by keeping their stocks and bonds and other articles for them while they are off on vacations or for other reasons. It is a common thing for a customer to go to his bank, especially in the country, and ask the cashier to keep his valuables during his absence. The cashier is willing to comply, and[352] the things are intrusted to him; but as the bank receives no compensation for this service it is not responsible for their loss unless it is grossly negligent in the matter. Suppose they are put in the safe among other valuables belonging to the bank and a robber breaks in and takes them away—is the bank responsible? Certainly not. On the other hand, if the customer should leave his valuables at a safe-deposit company, a different rule would apply, because that company charges him for keeping the articles. It is therefore bound by a stricter rule than the bank. It must use the greatest care, and if neglectful in any respect it is responsible for the consequences.

Another good example is a bank that keeps a depositor's bonds in its vault for convenience. The bank doesn't claim to be a safe-deposit company or anything like that, but it has a large vault and wants to help its customers by storing their stocks, bonds, and other items while they are away on vacation or for other reasons. It's common for a customer, especially in smaller towns, to go to their bank and ask the teller to hold their valuables during their absence. The teller is happy to help, and[352] the items are entrusted to them; however, since the bank doesn't charge for this service, it isn't responsible for any loss unless it is grossly negligent. If the items are placed in the vault with other valuables belonging to the bank and a thief breaks in and steals them, is the bank liable? Absolutely not. On the flip side, if the customer leaves their valuables at a safe-deposit company, a different rule applies because that company charges for storing the items. Therefore, it has a stricter obligation than the bank. It must exercise the utmost care, and if it fails in any way, it is responsible for the consequences.

Suppose a person should say to me: "Will you be good enough to leave this package with a jeweller on your way down street?" I say to my friend: "Certainly, with the greatest pleasure." What degree of care must I use in carrying that package? Only ordinary care. Suppose in going along the street a thief, without my knowledge, should walk beside me and slip his hand into my pocket and take the package, and on my arrival at the jewellery store I should find that it was gone. Should I be responsible for the loss? Certainly not, because I had neither received nor expected to receive any reward for taking the package to the store. Of course, if it could be shown that I was unnecessarily negligent in carrying the parcel, the owner might be justified in claiming damages.

Suppose someone says to me, "Could you please leave this package with a jeweler on your way down the street?" I reply to my friend, "Of course, I'd be happy to." What level of care do I need to use while carrying that package? Just regular care. Now, imagine that while I'm walking down the street, a thief sneaks up next to me, slips his hand into my pocket, and takes the package, and when I get to the jeweler, I discover it's missing. Should I be held responsible for the loss? Absolutely not, because I didn't receive or expect any reward for delivering the package to the store. However, if it could be proven that I was carelessly negligent in carrying the parcel, the owner might have a valid reason to seek damages.

One thing more may be added. If a bailee should be a scoundrel and sell the thing left with him for safe-keeping and receive the money, the true owner could, nevertheless, claim the thing wherever he could find it. The owner would not get a good title. This rule of law applies to everything except negotiable paper. A person who buys that in good faith, honestly, not knowing that it was stolen, and pays money, gets a good title. This is the only exception to the above rule in the law.

One more thing can be added. If a bailee turns out to be dishonest and sells the item they were supposed to keep safe, and takes the money, the true owner can still claim the item wherever they find it. The owner wouldn’t get a valid title. This rule of law applies to everything except negotiable instruments. A person who buys these in good faith, honestly, and without knowing they were stolen, and pays money for them, receives a valid title. This is the only exception to the above rule in the law.

[353]XIII. CONCERNING AGENTS

Very many persons act as agents for others. Much of the business of modern times is carried on by persons of this class. All the managers of corporations are agents of the railways, banks, manufacturing companies, and the like. They are to be seen everywhere. Every salesman is an agent. In short, the larger part of the modern commerce of the world is done by agents.

Very many people act as agents for others. A lot of today’s business is conducted by individuals in this role. All the managers of corporations are agents for railways, banks, manufacturing companies, and similar businesses. They can be found everywhere. Every salesperson is an agent. In short, the majority of modern commerce in the world is conducted by agents.

Agents are of two kinds, special and general; and there are important differences between the two. A general agent is a person who transacts all the business of the person hiring or appointing him, called a principal, or all his business of a particular kind. A principal might have several general agents for the different kinds of business in which he was engaged. Suppose he has a cotton-factory and a store and a farm; he might have three general agents, each managing one of these enterprises.

There are two types of agents: special and general.; and there are significant differences between them. A agent is someone who handles all the business for the person hiring or appointing them, known as the principal, or all their business of a specific type. A principal might have multiple general agents for the different types of business they are involved in. For example, if they own a cotton factory, a store, and a farm, they could have three general agents, each managing one of these operations.

A general agent may be appointed in different ways. This may be done by a written contract. Very often, however, no such contract is made, and the person comes to act in a different way. A cashier of a bank, for example, is a general agent to transact its business, but the mode of appointing him rarely consists of anything more than a resolution of the board of directors. More[354] often than otherwise his appointment is purely verbal, by word of mouth. And, again, the authority of an agent thus to act is often found out by his acts, known and approved by his principal, or in other ways. Suppose that A should manage B's store for him, buying and selling merchandise with A's knowledge; by thus putting him before the world as B's agent the law would say that he really was so, and B would be bound by his acts within a limit soon to be explained. This, perhaps, is the more common way in which the world learns of the authority of an agent's act. He does a great variety of things which it is well known must be within the knowledge of his principal or employer and, as they are known by the employer and the employer says nothing in the way of disowning or repudiating these acts, he is bound by them.

A general agent can be appointed in various ways. This can happen through a written contract. However, often no such contract is created, and the person acts in a different manner. For instance, a bank's cashier is a general agent for conducting its business, but their appointment usually involves nothing more than a resolution from the board of directors. More[354] often than not, their appointment is purely verbal, simply communicated. Additionally, the authority of an agent to act is often determined by their actions, which are known and approved by their principal, or through other means. For example, if A manages B's store, buying and selling goods with B's awareness, by presenting himself to the public as B's agent, the law recognizes him as such, and B would be held accountable for his actions up to a certain limit that will be explained soon. This is perhaps the most common way in which the public learns about an agent's authority. The agent performs a variety of tasks that should be well-known to their principal or employer, and since the employer is aware of these actions and does not speak out to deny or reject them, they are held responsible for them.

Sometimes, indeed, persons pretend to be agents for others when really they have no authority to act. When this is done, and the person for whom they are pretending to act finds out what they are doing, then it is his immediate duty to take such action as the circumstances require to disown the acts of such pretenders. If this is not done he may be bound by them. His action in adopting or approving is called the ratifying of an agent's act; and when this is done the agent's action is just as valid as though authority had been given to him to act in the beginning. The principal's conduct in thus ratifying an agent's acts relates back to the time when the agent first began to act.

Sometimes, people pretend to be representatives for others when they don't actually have the authority to act. When this happens, and the person they’re pretending to represent finds out, it is their immediate responsibility to take whatever action is necessary to disown the actions of these pretenders. If they don’t, they may be bound by those actions. Their act of accepting or approving is called the approving of an agent's act; and when this happens, the agent's actions are just as valid as if they had been given authority to act from the start. The principal’s actions in ratifying an agent’s acts relate back to the time when the agent initially began to act.

A special agent is appointed to do a particular thing and this is more often done in writing. Perhaps the most common illustration is the appointment of some one to act for another at the annual meeting of a corporation to vote on stock. Such a person is called a proxy, and persons often act as through another in this manner.[355] Sometimes one person serves as a proxy or agent for a very large number of shareholders.

A special agent is chosen for a specific purpose, usually in writing. A common example is when someone is appointed to represent another person at a corporation's annual meeting to vote on stock. This individual is known as a proxy, and it's common for people to act on behalf of others in this way.[355] Sometimes, one person serves as a proxy or agent for a large number of shareholders.

The liability of a principal for the acts of a general agent are very different from his liability for the acts of a special agent. In the former case the principal is said to be responsible for all the acts of his agent that are within the general scope of his business. In other words, if it is generally known that A is acting as the general agent of B in conducting his business,—we will say managing his cotton-factory,—A will bind his principal B for everything done by him as general agent in conducting that business.

The principal's liability for the actions of a general agent is quite different from their liability for the actions of a special agent. In the first case, the principal is considered responsible for all the actions of the agent that fall within the general scope of their business. In other words, if it is commonly understood that A is acting as B's general agent in running his business—let's say managing his cotton factory—A will legally bind his principal B for everything he does as the general agent in running that business.

Suppose A was acting as a general agent of an insurance company and, among other things, was told by the president or board of directors of the company not to insure property in a given place below a stated rate. Suppose a person should go to this agent, desiring to have his property insured, but at a lower rate, and suppose that the agent should finally yield and make a lower rate as requested. Could his company repudiate the contract? Clearly not, for it was A's duty to make contracts for insuring properties. If the insured knew that the agent had been expressly limited in the rates for insuring and that he was going contrary to his instructions in making the lower rate, then, indeed, the company would not be bound by the contract. Otherwise it could not repudiate the act, for it would fall within the general principle that a principal is bound by the acts of his agent done within the general scope of his business or employment; and such a contract clearly would be within the limit. For, indeed, this is the very business of the agent—to effect insurance.

Suppose A was acting as a general agent for an insurance company and was instructed by the president or board of directors not to insure property in a particular area below a certain rate. If someone approached this agent wanting to insure their property but at a lower rate, and the agent eventually agreed to the lower rate, could the company reject the contract? Clearly not, because it was A's responsibility to make insurance contracts. If the insured person knew that the agent had specific limits on the rates for insurance and that the agent was going against those instructions by offering a lower rate, then the company wouldn't be bound by the contract. Otherwise, they couldn't reject the action, as it follows the general principle that a principal is responsible for the actions of their agent made within the scope of their business or employment; and this type of contract would clearly fall within those limits. After all, this is exactly what the agent is there to do—provide insurance.

The only thing necessary, therefore, for a person doing business with a general agent is to find out whether he is such an agent; and when this is learned then a person can safely transact business with him, doing anything[356] within the general scope of his powers, unless the person actually knows that some limit or restriction has been put upon the agent. It is not his duty to find out what the powers of a general agent are, but simply whether he is a general agent or not.

The only thing someone needs to do when working with a general agent is to determine if they are indeed such an agent. Once that's established, a person can confidently do business with them, engaging in anything[356] that falls within the agent's general authority, unless they are aware that there are specific limits or restrictions placed on the agent. It is not their responsibility to uncover the powers of a general agent, just to confirm whether they are a general agent or not.

But the rule is very different that applies to the liability of a principal who employs a special agent. In such cases it is the duty of the person doing business with him to inquire what his powers are, for the principal will not be bound beyond these. Such an inquiry, therefore, must be made. He must ask the agent to show the authority under which he is appointed, or in some way clearly convince the other what his powers are before any business can be safely done.

But the rule is quite different when it comes to the liability of a principal who hires a special agent. In these situations, it's the responsibility of the person doing business with the agent to find out what their powers are, as the principal won't be held responsible beyond that. Therefore, this inquiry must be made. The person should ask the agent to present the authority under which they were appointed or somehow clearly demonstrate what their powers are before any business can be safely conducted.

The authority of a special agent is often stated in writing, and the paper is called a power of attorney. In selling land an agent should always have such a power, because a good title to land can only be given in writing, and this power of attorney should be copied in the records kept for this purpose with the deed itself to show by what authority the agent acted in selling the land. Every now and then when a person buys a piece of land and examines the title to find out whether it is perfect or not, he discovers that somewhere in the chain of title a deed was made by the agent of the seller instead of the seller himself, and the buyer had forgotten to put the power of attorney on record with his deed. The omission to do this is often serious. It is in truth just as important for an agent to have a proper power of attorney in such a case as to give a proper deed for his principal, and the one paper should be recorded quite as much as the other, as both are parts of the same story.

The authority of a special agent is usually documented in writing, and this document is called a power of attorney. When selling land, an agent should always have this power, because a valid title to land can only be conveyed in writing, and this power of attorney should be included in the records kept for this purpose along with the deed to show the authority under which the agent acted in selling the land. Occasionally, when someone buys a piece of land and reviews the title to determine if it’s clear or not, they find out that at some point in the chain of title, a deed was executed by the seller’s agent instead of the seller themselves, and the buyer forgot to record the power of attorney with their deed. Failing to do this can be quite serious. It's just as essential for an agent to have a valid power of attorney in such a situation as it is for them to provide a proper deed for their principal, and both documents should be recorded equally, as they are both part of the same narrative.

Sometimes an agent appoints a subagent. This may be orally or in writing. A good illustration is that of the collection of a cheque deposited with a bank. Suppose a[357] cheque is deposited in a bank in Chicago drawn on a bank in Newark, N. J. The Chicago bank is, in the first instance, the agent for collecting it. The bank would send the cheque to another in New York, which would be its subagent, and that bank in turn would send it to a third bank in Newark, which would be a subagent of the New York bank. Thus there would be two subagents, besides the agent, employed in collecting the cheque.

Sometimes an agent appoints a subagent. This can be done either verbally or in writing. A good example is when collecting a check deposited with a bank. Imagine a[357] check is deposited at a bank in Chicago that’s drawn on a bank in Newark, N.J. The Chicago bank acts as the initial agent for collecting it. This bank would then send the check to another bank in New York, which would serve as its subagent, and that New York bank would subsequently send it to a third bank in Newark, which would be a subagent of the New York bank. So, there would be two subagents, in addition to the agent, involved in collecting the check.

There is an important question relating to the liability of one of these agents or subagents in the event of the negligent performance of the duty; which is responsible? Generally, it is said, if the general agent appoints a subagent he is nevertheless responsible for his act. Suppose a street contractor employs a subagent to repair a street and he digs a hole and improperly guards it and some one falls into the place and is injured, can the person thus injured look to the contractor or to the subcontractor for compensation for his injury? The contractor is liable in such cases. It may be added, however, that although he is liable to the person injured, he may be able to recover of the subcontractor or subagent. But this rule does not apply to the banks in every State. In some of them the first bank in which the cheque was deposited is liable for the negligence of others that may be afterward employed in collecting it, and this rule prevails in the federal courts. In a larger number of States the first bank fully performs its duty in selecting a proper or reputable agent, and in sending the cheque to it for collection. Should the second or subagent be neglectful, the depositor of the cheque could compel that agent, and not the first, to make its loss good.

There’s an important question about the liability of these agents or subagents in cases of negligent performance of their duties: who is responsible? Generally speaking, if a general agent hires a subagent, the general agent is still responsible for the subagent’s actions. For instance, if a street contractor hires a subagent to repair a street, and the subagent digs a hole without proper safety measures, causing someone to fall in and get hurt, can the injured person seek compensation from the contractor or the subcontractor? In such cases, the contractor is liable. However, it's worth noting that while the contractor is responsible to the injured person, they may be able to recover damages from the subcontractor or subagent. This rule doesn't apply to banks in every state. In some states, the first bank where the check was deposited is liable for the negligence of any later parties involved in collecting it, and this rule is upheld in federal courts. In many other states, the first bank fulfills its responsibility by choosing a proper and reputable agent to handle the collection of the check. If the second agent or subagent is negligent, the depositor of the check can hold that agent accountable for any loss, not the first bank.

[358]XIV. THE LAW RELATING TO BANK CHEQUES

A cheque has come to be one of the most common of all writings. Almost everybody receives more or less of them. There are some principles that ought to be understood by every holder or receiver of a cheque which, we fear, are not as well known as they should be.

A check has become one of the most common forms of writing. Almost everyone receives them to some degree. There are some principles that every holder or receiver of a cheque should understand, which, we fear, are not as well known as they should be.

First of all, a person ought to present his cheque for payment soon after receiving it. Some people are quite negligent in this matter and carry cheques around in their pocket-books for several days before presenting them for payment. It may not be convenient to take them to a bank, and so they are carried around; perhaps their owners forget they have them. They ought not to do so, for the reason that the maker of a cheque really says to the holder: "This is an order that I give to you on my bank for the money mentioned. If you go at once you can get payment, but I do not promise to keep it there always for you—only for a short time." Now if a person is willing to accept a cheque at all, he ought to present it within the time the holder intended, and if he does not and the bank fails, the loss falls on the holder and not on the maker.

First of all, a person should cash their cheque soon after receiving it. Some people are pretty careless about this and keep cheques in their wallets for several days before getting them cashed. It might not be convenient to go to a bank right away, so they hang onto them; maybe they even forget they have them. They really shouldn't do this because the person who wrote the cheque is essentially saying to the holder: "This is a request I’m making to my bank for the amount specified. If you go right away, you can get paid, but I can't guarantee that the funds will be available forever—only for a short while." So, if someone is willing to accept a cheque, they should cash it within the time frame intended. If they don’t, and the bank goes under, the loss is on the holder, not the person who issued the cheque.

What time does the law fix for presenting cheques for payment? The rule everywhere is that the holder must present a cheque received by him, if drawn on a bank in the place where he lives, on the day of receiving it or[359] on the next day. If the cheque is drawn on a bank at a distance, out of town, then he should send it to that bank, either directly or by leaving it with another bank for that purpose, on the same day as he received it or the next day. In other words, he must take steps to collect the cheque either on the day of receiving it or the following one.

What time does the law set for presenting checks for payment? The rule everywhere is that the holder must present a check he received, if it's drawn on a bank in the area where he lives, on the day he gets it or[359] on the next day. If the check is drawn on a bank that's out of town, then he should send it to that bank, either directly or by leaving it with another bank for that purpose, on the same day he received it or the next day. In other words, he must take steps to collect the check either on the day he receives it or the following one.

A friend of mine gave a cheque to a merchant in payment of a small bill. Both lived in the same town, where the bank on which the cheque was drawn was also located. About a week afterward the bank failed and the merchant wrote to him, stating the unwelcome fact and that the cheque had not been collected and desired him to send another. I asked my friend if he complied with the request, and he said: "Certainly." I told him that he ought not to have done so, for he was under no obligation either in law or morals to do such a thing. Had he known the above rule he would not have sent the second cheque, for it was pure negligence on the part of the merchant in not presenting it—in fact, on the same day it was received.

A friend of mine gave a check to a store owner to pay off a small bill. They both lived in the same town, where the bank that issued the check was also located. About a week later, the bank went under, and the merchant wrote to him to share the unfortunate news that the check hadn’t been cashed and asked him to send another one. I asked my friend if he went along with the request, and he said, "Of course." I told him he really shouldn’t have done that because he wasn’t legally or morally required to. If he had known this rule, he wouldn’t have sent the second check, as it was the merchant's fault for not cashing it—actually, he should have done so the very same day he received it.

A person may, of course, hold a cheque for a much longer period than the time above mentioned and present it and receive payment, but the point that we are trying to make clear is that the risk of holding it during this period is the holder's and not the risk of the maker of the cheque. I suppose the merchant in the above case had, perhaps, lost the cheque. Every now and then one is mislaid and, consequently, is not presented for payment when it should be, but the maker ought not to suffer for the negligence of the receiver of his cheque. The rule of law that we have given is founded on justice, and if the receiver is negligent in not presenting it as he should, the holder ought not to suffer.

A person can definitely keep a check for longer than the time mentioned and then present it for payment, but the key point we're making is that the risk of holding it during that time falls on the holder, not the maker of the check. I guess the merchant in the example might have lost the check. It's not uncommon for a check to get misplaced and, as a result, not be presented for payment when it should be, but the maker shouldn't be penalized for the receiver's carelessness. The legal principle we've stated is based on fairness, and if the receiver is careless in not presenting it as they should, the holder shouldn't have to face the consequences.

It is the duty of a bank to pay a cheque just as it is drawn, and if it makes any mistakes it must suffer.[360] The reason for this rule is that the maker does not expect to see his cheque again after it leaves his hand, and when he puts his money in a bank for safe-keeping the bank virtually says to him that it will pay only on his order just as he has written. It will guard his interests carefully and pay no forged cheques or cheques that have been altered in dates or amounts, to his injury. Now, it is quite a common thing for cheques to be forged, and still more common for them to be raised. A scoundrel gets a cheque that is genuine, ordering a bank to pay $18, and changes it to $1800. He presents it for payment and it is paid. By and by the depositor finds out that he has not as much money in the bank as he supposed he had there. What has happened? Some one has altered one of his cheques and drawn out too much. He goes to the bank and makes inquiry, learns that this is so, and then demands that it shall make the amount good to him. Usually a bank is obliged to pay.

It's the bank's responsibility to pay a cheque exactly as it's written, and if it makes any errors, it has to take the consequences.[360] The reason for this rule is that the cheque writer doesn’t expect to see their cheque again once it's handed over. When they deposit their money in a bank for safekeeping, the bank essentially assures them that it will only pay according to their instructions as stated on the cheque. The bank will protect their interests carefully and refuse to pay any forged cheques or cheques that have been tampered with in terms of dates or amounts, to their detriment. However, cheque forgery is quite common, and cheque alteration is even more frequent. A fraudster might receive a legitimate cheque instructing the bank to pay $18 and then alter it to $1800. They present it for payment, and the bank pays it. Eventually, the account holder discovers that they don’t have as much money in the bank as they thought. What happened? Someone altered one of their cheques and withdrew too much. They go to the bank to inquire, find out this is true, and then demand that the bank make up the difference. Typically, the bank is required to cover the loss.

There is one limit to this rule. A man making a cheque must be careful to write it in such a way that changes or alterations cannot easily be made. If he is careless, leaving ample space so that changes can be made in the amount, then he will be considered negligent, and a bank would not be obliged to make good his loss. If, on the other hand, he is careful in drawing his cheques then a bank's duty to protect him is plain, and it is liable in the event of neglecting to do so.

There is one limit to this rule. A person writing a check must be careful to do it in a way that makes it difficult to change or alter. If they are careless and leave enough space for changes to be made in the amount, they will be seen as negligent, and a bank wouldn’t have to cover their loss. Conversely, if they are careful when writing their checks, then the bank has a clear duty to protect them and is responsible if it fails to do so.

A few years ago a man drew a cheque for $250, dated it three days ahead, and left it with his clerk, directing him to draw the money on the day written in the cheque and pay the men who worked for him, and went away. The clerk thought that he would like to keep that money himself and take a little journey also, so he changed the date to one day earlier, went into the bank on that day[361] and drew the money, and started for the Klondike or some other place. The maker of the cheque soon found out what had happened and demanded of the bank to make the amount good. The bank said to him: "Suppose the clerk had waited one day longer and then drawn the money, you would have been the loser just the same." The man admitted all this, but replied, nevertheless, that he had not changed the date; that the bank ought to have seen the alteration before paying, and as it did not it was negligent in that regard, and the bank was obliged to lose.

A few years ago, a man wrote a check for $250, dated it three days in the future, and left it with his clerk, instructing him to withdraw the money on the date on the check and pay the workers. He then left. The clerk decided he wanted to keep that money and take a little trip, so he changed the date to one day earlier, went to the bank on that day[361] and withdrew the money, then set off for the Klondike or somewhere similar. The man who wrote the check soon discovered what had happened and demanded the bank cover the amount. The bank told him, "If the clerk had waited one more day and then withdrawn the money, you would have lost just the same." The man agreed with this, but insisted that he hadn’t changed the date; the bank should have noticed the alteration before paying, and since it didn’t, it was negligent and should bear the loss.

When a person takes a cheque he naturally supposes that the bank on which it is drawn owes the money to him because he can truly demand it. Suppose a bank refuses to pay, can the holder then sue the bank for money? In six States—Illinois, South Carolina, Missouri, Kentucky, Colorado, and Texas—the holder of such a cheque can sue the bank and get his money. The courts in those States say that a cheque is an assignment or transfer of the amount of money stated to the holder of the cheque from the time that the cheque was given him. The law in all of the other States is otherwise, and a bank for a good reason can decline to pay a cheque, and, in any event, the holder cannot sue the bank for the amount. If it will not pay he must look to the maker and not the bank for payment. Of course, a cheque must always be drawn against a deposit, and it is a fraud on the part of a person to draw a cheque on a bank when he has no money there. Sometimes mistakes are made by banks in their bookkeeping, and they think they have not the money to pay when in truth they have. In such cases they sometimes decline to pay, but even if they had the money the law says that there is no contract between the holder of a cheque and the bank on which it is drawn,[362] and therefore the holder cannot sue it should it refuse to pay. This rule, however, is rather losing ground and the other is coming into more general favour—that a cheque does operate to transfer the money of the maker to the holder and, consequently, that he has a right to sue the bank for the money.

When someone receives a check, they naturally assume that the bank it’s drawn on owes them the money because they can rightfully request it. If a bank refuses to pay, can the holder then sue the bank for the money? In six states—Illinois, South Carolina, Missouri, Kentucky, Colorado, and Texas—the holder of such a check can sue the bank and get their money. Courts in those states assert that a check is an assignment or transfer of the specified amount of money to the holder from the moment the check is issued. The law in all other states is different, and a bank can justifiably refuse to pay a check, meaning the holder cannot sue the bank for the funds. If the bank won’t pay, the holder must seek payment from the check’s maker instead. Of course, a check must always be drawn against a deposit, and it is fraudulent for someone to write a check on a bank where they have no funds. Occasionally, banks might make errors in their bookkeeping and mistakenly believe they don’t have enough money to cover a check when they actually do. In such cases, they might refuse payment, but even if they do have the money, the law states that there is no contract between the holder of a check and the bank it is drawn on,[362] so the holder cannot sue if the bank refuses to pay. This rule is gradually losing traction, however, and the opposing view—that a check does transfer the maker’s funds to the holder, giving them the right to sue the bank for the money—is gaining more acceptance.

Cheques are made payable either to bearer or order. If a cheque is made payable to bearer it can be transferred from one person to another simply by handing it to him—by delivery; but if a cheque is made payable to order, then the person who receives it, if wishing to transfer it to some one else, must write his name on the back. If he writes his name on the back it is called a blank indorsement, and this form is often used in transferring cheques. If, however, a person intends to send a cheque through the mail he should never write it payable to bearer, but always payable to the order of a particular person, so as to require his name to be written thereon in order to make a good transfer. This is a much safer way of sending cheques than simply by making them payable to bearer.

Cheques can be made payable either to bearer or to order. If a cheque is payable to bearer, it can be transferred from one person to another just by handing it over—through delivery; however, if a cheque is payable to order, then the person who receives it and wants to transfer it to someone else must write their name on the back. Writing their name on the back is called a blank endorsement, and this method is commonly used for transferring cheques. If someone plans to send a cheque through the mail, they should never make it payable to bearer. Instead, they should always make it payable to the order of a specific person, requiring their name to be written on it for a valid transfer. This is a much safer way to send cheques than making them payable to bearer.

[363]XV. THE LAW RELATING TO LEASES

A lease is an agreement, and, as every one knows, usually relates to the hiring of lands and houses. If the agreement is to be for a longer period than one year it should be in writing, for if it be not either party can avoid it, not morally but in law. The statute of frauds, which has been explained, would shield either party in not carrying out such an agreement if it were not in writing if by its terms it was to last for a longer period than one year.

A lease is a contract, and, as everyone knows, it usually involves the rental of land and homes. If the agreement is for a term longer than one year, it should be in writing, because if it’s not, either party can back out of it, not because it's right, but legally. The statute of frauds, as explained, protects either party from being held to an agreement that isn't in writing if it’s supposed to last more than one year.

There is another very important reason for putting such an agreement in writing. Much of the law relating to the two parties, landlord and tenant, is one-sided and in favour of the landlord. Our law on that subject is based on the English law. It was imported in the early colonial days, and, though it has been greatly changed by statute and by decisions of the courts, it is still very one-sided, as we shall see before finishing this paper. For this reason, especially, all leases relating to houses and stores or other buildings, even for a short period, should be in writing, with the rights and duties of both parties fully stated, so that both may clearly know what to do and to expect.

There’s another really important reason to have such an agreement in writing. A lot of the law regarding the two parties, landlord and tenant, is biased and favors the landlord. Our laws on this topic are based on English law. They were brought over during the early colonial days, and while they've been significantly changed by legislation and court decisions, they still tend to favor landlords significantly, as we’ll discuss before this paper concludes. For this reason, it's especially important that all leases for houses, stores, or other buildings—even for a short period—are written down, clearly outlining the rights and responsibilities of both parties, so everyone knows what to do and what to expect.

Unless something is said in the lease concerning repairs[364] the landlord is not obliged to make any. This statement shows at once the need of having a written lease. If the house is out of order—the locks, blinds, doors, and windows are not in good order—the tenant cannot claim anything of the landlord or require him to put them in good condition. Even if a house should become unfit for habitation in consequence of fire, or is blown down, or is flooded with water, the landlord is not bound to do anything unless he has stated that he will in his lease.

Unless the lease mentions repairs[364], the landlord isn't required to make any. This highlights the importance of having a written lease. If the house has issues—like broken locks, blinds, doors, or windows—the tenant can't demand anything from the landlord or insist that they be fixed. Even if a house becomes unlivable due to fire, is destroyed, or is flooded, the landlord isn't obligated to take any action unless it's specified in the lease.

A fire broke out not long since in a large warehouse and burned it so completely as to render it wholly unfit for use; indeed, all the merchandise in it was wholly consumed. Nevertheless, when the lease expired and the tenants refused to pay as they had agreed to do, the landlord brought a legal proceeding against them to compel them to pay during the entire period, as though they had been staying there and selling goods and making money, and they were compelled to pay. This is the common law on the subject, and every tenant is bound to pay in such cases unless he has clearly stated in his lease that he is not to be holden in the event of the destruction of the building by fire, flood, lightning, or other cause.

A fire recently broke out in a large warehouse and completely destroyed it, making it totally unusable; in fact, all the merchandise inside was entirely consumed. However, when the lease ended and the tenants refused to pay as they had agreed, the landlord took legal action against them to force them to pay for the entire duration, as if they had still been there selling goods and making money, and they were compelled to pay. This is the common law on the subject, and every tenant is required to pay in such cases unless they have clearly stated in their lease that they are not responsible for payment in the event of the building's destruction by fire, flood, lightning, or any other cause.

Furthermore, it may be added that leases nowadays are often furnished with blank spaces to be filled up with names, the amounts to be paid, times of payment, etc., and persons often sign them without even reading them. They should not do this. They should be careful to read them over two or three times or more, until they fully understand them and are sure of their nature before signing or executing them. People are still more negligent in taking out insurance policies without reading them. They are very long and parts of them are printed in fine type and, perhaps, are quite difficult, especially for old eyes, to read. In truth some of the most impor[365]tant parts are put in the finest print—some of the exceptions against loss and other matters, which, we are quite sure, if a person when taking out a policy should read over and understand he would insist on having changed.

Furthermore, it's important to note that leases today often have blank spaces for names, payment amounts, payment dates, and so on, and people frequently sign them without even reading the details. They shouldn't do this. It's crucial to read these documents two or three times or more until they completely understand them and are certain of what they entail before signing or executing them. People are even more careless when it comes to insurance policies, often signing them without reading the fine print. These documents tend to be very lengthy, with sections in small type that can be quite challenging to read, especially for older individuals. In reality, some of the most important details are printed in the smallest font—such as exceptions regarding loss and other matters—which, we believe, if a person were to read and understand these parts while obtaining a policy, they would insist on having them changed.

If a house becomes unfit for living therein by its own fault—for example, if it is overrun with rats, or becomes so decayed that the weather invades and is thereby rendered unfit—the tenant, so the law says, has indeed the privilege of quitting, if he did not know these things at the time of entering; but if he did, he would be required to live there, however much he might dislike the company of rats or the presence of the snow or rain, and also to pay his rent; or, if quitting for that reason, he would still be responsible for the rent as he would if living in the house. An eminent legal writer has stated the principle in this way: The tenant can leave if the defect was not known or anticipated by him, or known or anticipated if he had made a reasonable investigation or inquiry before he took the lease.

If a house becomes unlivable due to its own issues—like being infested with rats or falling apart so much that the weather comes in and makes it unfit—the tenant, according to the law, has the right to leave if they didn’t know about these problems when they moved in. However, if they did know, they must stay there, no matter how much they dislike the rats or the snow and rain, and they still have to pay rent. If they leave for that reason, they would still be responsible for the rent as if they were living in the house. A noted legal expert has explained the principle this way: The tenant can leave if they weren’t aware of the issue or if they couldn’t have reasonably discovered it before signing the lease.

A tenant is not required to make general repairs without an agreement, but he must make those that are necessary to preserve the house from injury by rain and wind. If the shingles are blown off or panes of glass are broken others must be put in their places; and it is said that he would be bound even for ornamental repairs, like paper and painting, if he made an agreement to return the house in good order.

A tenant doesn't have to make general repairs unless there's an agreement, but they must take care of any repairs needed to protect the house from damage caused by rain and wind. If shingles are blown off or windows are broken, they need to be replaced. It's also said that the tenant would be responsible for decorative repairs, like wallpaper and painting, if they agreed to return the house in good condition.

A tenant of a farm must manage and cultivate it by the same rules of husbandry as are practised in his vicinity, and if his lease ends by any event that is uncertain and could neither have been foreseen nor foretold, he is entitled to the annual crop sowed or planted by him while he was in possession.

A tenant of a farm must manage and cultivate it according to the same farming practices used in the area. If his lease ends due to an unforeseen event that couldn't have been predicted, he has the right to the yearly crop that he sowed or planted while he was in possession.

As we have stated, if the house is wholly destroyed the[366] tenant must still pay the rent, for the reason, which to many may seem absurd, that the law regards the land as the principal thing and the house as secondary. It is true that a man, in the event of his house burning down, might pitch a tent on the ground and live there, but it would be a decidedly chilly way of living, especially in the winter-time, in the northern part of our country. If a tenant should agree to return and deliver the house at the end of the term in good order and condition, reasonable wear and tear only excepted, he would be obliged to rebuild the house if it burned down. Once more, we ask, in view of these things, ought he not to make a written lease and well understand its terms before signing it?

As we mentioned, if the house is completely destroyed, the[366] tenant still has to pay the rent because, to many, it may sound strange, the law sees the land as the main thing and the house as secondary. It's true that if someone's house burned down, they could pitch a tent on the ground and live there, but that would be a pretty cold way to live, especially in winter in the northern part of our country. If a tenant agrees to return the house at the end of the term in good condition, except for reasonable wear and tear, they would have to rebuild the house if it burned down. Once again, we ask, given all this, shouldn't they make a written lease and fully understand its terms before signing it?

The times for paying rent are usually specified in the lease, if one is made. When they are not the tenant is governed by the usage of the country or place where he lives.

The times for paying rent are usually outlined in the lease, if one is created. If not, the tenant follows the customs of the area where they live.

When nothing is said about underletting the whole or a part to some one else the tenant has a right to do this, but remains bound to the landlord for his rent. Generally when written leases are made there is a clause stating that the tenant cannot underlet any portion or all without the landlord's consent.

When nothing is mentioned about subletting the whole or part of the property to someone else, the tenant has the right to do so but is still responsible to the landlord for paying rent. Usually, when leases are written, there is a clause that says the tenant cannot sublet any part or all of the property without the landlord's permission.

A tenant is not responsible for taxes unless it is expressly agreed that he shall pay them.

A tenant isn't responsible for taxes unless it's specifically agreed that they will pay them.

If a lease be for a fixed time the tenant loses all right or interest in the land as soon as the lease comes to an end, and he must leave then or the landlord may turn him out at once, or, in other language, eject him. If, however, he stays there longer with the consent of the landlord he is then called a tenant at will and cannot be turned out by the landlord without giving a notice to him to quit. The statutes of the several States have fixed the[367] length of time that a notice must be given by the landlord to his tenant before he can turn him out. In many States a notice of thirty days must be given; sometimes sixty days' notice is required, or even longer.

If a lease is for a specific period, the tenant loses all rights or interest in the property as soon as the lease ends, and they must leave at that time, or the landlord can evict them immediately. If, however, the tenant continues to stay with the landlord's permission, they are considered a tenant at will and cannot be evicted without the landlord giving them notice to leave. The laws in various States have established the[367] required notice period that a landlord must give a tenant before eviction. In many States, a thirty-day notice is required; sometimes, a sixty-day notice is necessary, or even longer.

It is an important question what things a tenant may take away with him at the expiration of his lease. Of course, there is no question whatever with respect to many things. Besides his wife and children he may take all his furniture and other movable property. But there are many things fixed to the house by the tenant that he desires to remove if he has the right to do so, and many questions have been asked and decided by the courts relating to this subject. The method of fastening them to the house is the test usually applied to determine whether they can be taken away or not. If they are fastened by screws in such a way as to show that the tenant intended to take them away, he can do so, otherwise he cannot.

It's an important question what items a tenant can take with them when their lease ends. Obviously, there's no question about many things. Along with their spouse and kids, they can take all their furniture and movable property. However, there are many items fixed to the house by the tenant that they want to remove if they're allowed, and numerous questions have been raised and decided by the courts on this topic. The way these items are attached to the house is usually the key factor in determining whether they can be taken or not. If they’re secured with screws in a way that shows the tenant intended to take them, they can; otherwise, they can't.

In modern times the rule has been changed in favour of the tenant, and whatever he can remove without injuring the house, leaving it in as good condition as it would otherwise be, he can take away; for example, ornamental chimney-pieces, coffee-mills, cornices that are furnished with screws, furnaces, stoves, looking-glasses, pumps, gates, fence rails, barns or stables on blocks, etc. On the other hand, a barn placed on the ground cannot be removed, nor benches fastened to the house, nor trees, plants, and hedges not belonging to a gardener by trade, nor locks and keys. Of course, all these things may be changed by the written lease, and it should be clearly stated what things may be removed concerning which any doubt may arise. We have heard of a case in which a tenant put a pier-glass into a house, fastening it by means of cement. He asked and was given the landlord's[368] permission to do this at the time of putting it in, but when the lease ended the landlord would not allow him to take it out, and an appeal was made to a court, which decided in favour of the landlord. Doubtless this decision is correct. If the glass could have been taken away without injuring the wall then it belonged to the tenant. This shows the need of putting such matters in writing; otherwise the tenant will suffer unless the landlord be a man of the highest integrity.

In modern times, the rule has changed to favor the tenant, allowing them to remove anything they can without damaging the property, as long as it remains in as good a condition as it would have been. For example, this includes decorative chimney pieces, coffee grinders, cornices secured with screws, furnaces, stoves, mirrors, pumps, gates, fence rails, barns, or stables on blocks, etc. However, a barn placed directly on the ground cannot be removed, nor can benches attached to the house, trees, plants, and hedges that don’t belong to a professional gardener, nor locks and keys. Naturally, all these points can be modified by the written lease, which should clearly outline what items can be removed to avoid any confusion. We’ve heard of a situation where a tenant installed a large mirror in a house, securing it with cement. He sought and received the landlord's[368] permission to do this, but when the lease ended, the landlord wouldn’t let him take it out, leading to a court appeal that ruled in favor of the landlord. Clearly, this decision was correct. If the mirror could have been removed without damaging the wall, it would have belonged to the tenant. This highlights the importance of putting such agreements in writing; otherwise, the tenant may face issues unless the landlord is completely trustworthy.

[369]XVI. LIABILITY OF EMPLOYER TO EMPLOYÉS

Persons who are employed in mills, in erecting buildings, by railroad companies, and others, are frequently injured while pursuing their employment, and the question has often arisen whether the employer was liable for the injury thus suffered by them. The more important of these questions we propose to answer in this and the following lecture, as they are matters of every-day importance to many people.

People who work in mills, construction, railroad companies, and similar jobs often get injured while on the job, leading to the question of whether their employer is responsible for those injuries. We plan to address the most significant of these questions in this lecture and the next, as they are important issues that affect many individuals daily.

First of all, an employé to recover anything for the loss that may have happened must show that in some way his employer was negligent. He cannot get something simply because he has been injured. The law in no country has ever said that he could. In all cases he must show that his employer failed in his duty in some way toward him to lay the foundation of an action against him. This is the first principle to keep clearly in mind.

First of all, an employee looking to recover for any losses has to prove that in some way his employer was negligent. He can't just get compensation because he was injured. The law in any country has never said that he could. In every case, he must demonstrate that his employer neglected his duty in some way towards him to establish a basis for a claim against him. This is the first principle to keep clearly in mind.

Again, it is said that an employé cannot recover if the injury has happened to him in consequence of the negligence of a fellow-servant. By this is meant a person engaged in the same common employment. It is not always easy to determine whether two persons employed by the same company are fellow-servants, as we shall soon see, but the principle of law is plain enough that[370] in all cases where they are thus acting as fellow-servants they cannot recover for any injury. The law says this is one of the risks that a person takes when he enters the service of another. Suppose a person is at work mining coal and is injured by another person working by his side through his negligence. However severely injured he may be he cannot get anything, because the person through whose negligence he has been injured is a fellow-workman.

Again, it is said that an employee cannot recover if the injury happened due to the negligence of a co-worker. This refers to someone involved in the same job. It’s not always easy to determine if two individuals employed by the same company are co-workers, as we will soon see, but the legal principle is clear that[370] in all cases where they are acting as co-workers, they cannot recover for any injury. The law states that this is one of the risks a person accepts when they take a job with someone else. For instance, if someone is working in a coal mine and gets injured by a co-worker due to that co-worker's negligence, no matter how seriously they are injured, they cannot seek compensation because the person who caused the injury is a fellow worker.

But many employés may have the same common employer and yet not be fellow-servants. For example, a brakeman would be a fellow-servant with the conductor and engineer and other persons running on the same train or on other trains belonging to the same company, but he would not be a fellow-servant working in the same line of employment with those who are engaged in the repair-shop of the company.

But many employees might have the same common employer and still not be fellow-workers. For example, a brakeman would be a fellow-worker with the conductor, engineer, and others operating on the same train or on different trains that belong to the same company, but he wouldn’t be a fellow-worker with those who are working in the company’s repair shop.

This statement is quite sufficient to show the difficulty there is sometimes in deciding whether a person is a fellow-servant or not. If a person is injured through the negligence of another employed by the same company who is not a fellow-servant, then he can recover if there are no other difficulties in the way, otherwise he cannot. It does not follow that fellow-servants are of the same grade or rank; the test is whether they are acting in the same line of employment. The brakeman's position is not so high as that of the engineer or conductor, yet all three are acting in the same line of employment, and if any one of them was injured by another in that part of the service the employer would not be liable.

This statement clearly illustrates the challenges that can arise in determining whether someone is a fellow servant. If a person gets hurt due to the negligence of another employee from the same company who is not a fellow servant, they can seek compensation if there are no other obstacles. If there are, then they cannot. It’s important to note that fellow servants do not need to hold the same position or rank; the key factor is whether they are working in the same field. For example, a brakeman's role is not as high as that of an engineer or conductor, but all three are in the same line of work, and if one of them is injured by another in that capacity, the employer wouldn't be held responsible.

In a very large number of cases, therefore, employers are not liable for accidents happening to their employés, because they are injured through the negligence of other employés engaged in the same line or subdivision of the[371] common service. Perhaps employers escape more frequently on this ground than on any other from paying anything for losses.

In many cases, employers aren't responsible for accidents that happen to their employees because the injuries occur due to the carelessness of other employees working in the same area of the[371] common service. Employers likely avoid paying for losses on this basis more often than for any other reason.

Yet there is another ground on which they often escape paying anything. An employé is supposed when making his contract with his employer to take on himself all the ordinary risks arising from his employment. These in many cases are very numerous. He does not assume extraordinary risks, but he does assume all ordinary risks that are likely to happen to him. Employés are injured every day and yet can recover nothing, because their injury is simply a common one, the risk of which they have assumed.

Yet there's another reason they often avoid paying anything. An employee is expected when entering a contract with their employer to take on all the usual risks that come with their job. These risks can be quite numerous. While they don't take on extraordinary risks, they do accept all the ordinary risks that could likely happen to them. Employees get injured every day and still can't recover anything, because their injury is just a common one, and they have accepted the risk.

Would it not be possible to make an employer liable for them all? Undoubtedly an employé could make a contract of this kind if he wished and his employer was willing to do so, but if they did the employer would be unwilling to pay as high wages. The greater the risk assumed by the employé the larger is the compensation paid; the one thing is graded by the other. It was stated when considering the rights and duties of common carriers that they have been lessening their liabilities; on the other hand, they are carrying for smaller prices than they once did. Doubtless a carrier would be willing to assume more risks—every kind of risk, in short—if he were paid enough for it, but shippers ordinarily are willing to assume many risks for the sake of the lower rates and insure their risks in insurance companies. Just so the working-men prefer higher wages and assume many risks of their employment. There is nothing unfair in this. For example, the persons who are engaged in making white lead run an unusual risk in pursuing their employment. It is said nowadays that if they use the utmost care in protecting themselves from inhaling the[372] fumes that arise in some stages of this process, they can live quite as long as other people. But unless they do exercise every precaution their system finally becomes charged with the poison that arises from this process and their lives are shortened. They well understand this before beginning the work; they are told of the risks and are paid high wages. If, therefore, they undertake such employment, well knowing the risks, they have no right to complain if their health after a time suffers. No fraud has been practised on them, and we do not know that they do complain if they suffer any ill effects from their work.

Would it be possible to hold an employer responsible for everything? Clearly, an employee could agree to a contract like this if they wanted to and if their employer was on board, but if that happened, the employer wouldn’t be willing to pay high wages. The bigger the risk taken by the employee, the more compensation they would get; one is balanced by the other. It was pointed out when looking at the rights and responsibilities of common carriers that they have been reducing their liabilities; on the flip side, they are charging lower prices than they used to. Surely, a carrier would be open to taking on more risks—any type of risk, really—if they were compensated enough for it, but shippers usually prefer to take on several risks for the sake of lower rates and insure those risks with insurance companies. Similarly, workers prefer higher wages and take on many risks associated with their jobs. There’s nothing unfair about this. For instance, people who work in white lead manufacturing face significant risks in their jobs. It’s said these days that if they take maximum precautions to avoid inhaling the fumes released during certain parts of this process, they can live as long as anyone else. However, if they don’t take every precaution, their bodies eventually become saturated with the poison from this process, and their lives are shortened. They are well aware of this before starting the job; they are informed about the risks and are compensated with high wages. If they choose to take on such work, fully understanding the risks, they have no right to complain if their health deteriorates over time. No deception has been committed against them, and we don’t know if they actually do complain about any negative effects from their work.

[373]XVII. LIABILITY OF EMPLOYERS TO EMPLOYÉS (Continued)

In our last lecture we stated some of the principles relating to the liabilities of employers to their employés; in this lesson the subject will be continued. An employer is bound to use some care or precaution, and if he does not will be responsible for his neglect. One of these is he must employ persons who are fit for the work they are set to do. If an employer in mining should put a man to work by the side of another to mine coal who he knew was not a skilful workman, and, in consequence of this unskilful workman's unskilfulness, other miners were injured, he would be responsible for hiring such a man. Every one will see the justice of this rule.

In our last lecture, we discussed some principles concerning the responsibilities of employers towards their employees; we'll continue that topic in this lesson. An employer is required to exercise a certain level of care or caution, and if he fails to do so, he will be held accountable for his negligence. One aspect of this is that he must hire people who are qualified for the work they are assigned. If an employer in mining assigns someone to work alongside another person to mine coal, knowing that this individual is not skilled, and as a result of this unskilled worker's lack of ability, other miners are injured, the employer would be held responsible for hiring that person. Everyone can see the fairness of this rule.

The employer must also give proper instructions to the person employed whenever he does not understand his duties. If a person is employed to run a laundry machine who does not understand how to work it, and other employés are injured through his ignorance, the employer would be liable. He must, therefore, tell such a person what to do; he has no right to hazard the lives of others by putting any one who has no knowledge of a machine to work without instructing him properly. Again, if a person pretends to be capable, and the employer, believing[374] him, engages him, and it is soon found out that he is not, then it is the duty of the employer either to dismiss him or to give him proper instructions. The rule, however, on this subject is not the same everywhere. It is sometimes said that if an employé continues to work by the side of another after knowing that this other is incompetent, it is his duty to give notice to the employer, and if the employer continues to employ him, to quit. If he does not he assumes the greater risk arising from his knowledge of the incompetency of the other.

The employer must also give clear instructions to the employee whenever they don’t understand their responsibilities. If someone is hired to operate a laundry machine but doesn't know how to use it, and others get hurt because of their lack of knowledge, the employer could be held responsible. Therefore, the employer must explain what the employee needs to do; they have no right to endanger the lives of others by letting someone without knowledge of a machine work without proper training. Additionally, if someone pretends to be qualified, and the employer, believing[374] them, hires them, only to discover they are not qualified, it becomes the employer's responsibility to either fire them or provide proper training. However, the rule regarding this situation isn't consistent everywhere. It’s sometimes said that if an employee continues to work alongside someone they know is incompetent, they should inform the employer; if the employer still chooses to keep that person employed, then the employee should resign. If they don’t, they take on a greater risk because they are aware of the other’s incompetence.

It is the duty of the employer to furnish proper appliances for his workmen. He must furnish proper tools and machinery and safe scaffolding, and in every respect must show a reasonable degree of care in all these particulars. But the courts say that he is not obliged to exercise the utmost care, because the employé takes on himself some risk with respect to the tools and machinery he uses. For example, it is said that employers are not obliged to use the latest appliances that are known or appear in the market for the use of their workmen. If an employer has an older one that has been in use for years, and the employés have found out all the dangers attending its use, and a new one appears that is less dangerous to use, the law does not require the employer to throw the older one away and get the other. It is true that in many States within the last few years statutes have been passed by the legislatures requiring employers to be much more careful than they were formerly in protecting their machinery. Many injuries have happened from the use of belting, and the statutes in many cases have stated what must be done in the way of enclosing belts, and of putting screens around machinery, and in various ways of so protecting it that persons will be less liable to suffer. Furthermore, inventors have been very busy in[375] inventing machinery with this end in view. The old-fashioned car-coupler was a very dangerous device, and many a poor fellow has been crushed between cars when trying to couple them. A coupler has been made in which this danger no longer exists; in truth, there has been a great advance in this direction.

It’s the employer's responsibility to provide the right tools for their workers. They must supply appropriate tools and machinery, ensure safe scaffolding, and show a reasonable level of care in all these areas. However, courts have stated that employers are not required to exercise utmost care, as employees do accept some risk when using tools and machinery. For instance, employers aren't obligated to use the latest equipment available on the market for their workers. If an employer has an older tool that has been safely used for years and the workers are aware of its associated risks, the law doesn't require the employer to replace it with a new, safer version. It's true that in many states, recent laws have been enacted that require employers to be more diligent in safeguarding their machinery. Many injuries have occurred due to the use of belts, and these laws often specify necessary actions to enclose belts, place screens around machinery, and otherwise protect it to reduce the risk of injury. Additionally, inventors have been very active in[375] creating machinery with this goal in mind. The old-fashioned car coupler was extremely dangerous, and many workers have suffered injuries trying to couple cars. Now there’s a coupler designed to eliminate this danger, and there have been significant advancements in this area.

An employer must also select suitable materials on which to work. This is a well-known principle. If he does not, then he is responsible for the consequences. In one of the cases a person was injured while erecting a scaffolding from the breaking of a knotty timber. The testimony was that the knot was visible on the surface and if the stick had been examined the defect would have been seen. That seemed a slight defect, surely, but the consequence of using the timber was very serious, and the court rightly held that as this defect could have been seen, had the timber been properly examined, the employer was responsible for the injury to a workman who was injured by the breaking of it.

An employer must also choose appropriate materials to work with. This is a well-known principle. If they fail to do so, they are accountable for the outcomes. In one case, someone was injured while putting up scaffolding because a piece of timber broke due to a knot. Witnesses testified that the knot was visible on the surface, and if the wood had been inspected, the flaw would have been noticed. It seemed like a minor defect, but the result of using the timber was very serious. The court rightfully determined that, since the defect could have been seen with a proper inspection, the employer was liable for the injury to the worker who was harmed by the breakage.

An employer must also select suitable places for his employés. In one of the cases a court said a master does not warrant his servant's safety. He does, however, agree to adopt and keep proper means with which to carry on the business in which they are employed. Among these is the providing of a suitable place for doing his work without exposure to dangers that do not come within the reasonable scope of his employment. In one of the cases a company stored a quantity of dynamite so near a place where an employé was working that he was killed by its explosion. The court held that it was negligence on the part of the company in requiring its employé to work so near the place where this explosive material was kept.

An employer must also choose appropriate locations for their employees. In one case, a court stated that an employer doesn't guarantee their employee's safety. However, the employer does agree to take and maintain proper measures to conduct the business in which the employees are engaged. This includes providing a safe workspace free from dangers that fall outside the reasonable scope of their duties. In a particular case, a company stored a large amount of dynamite so close to where an employee was working that he was killed by its explosion. The court found that it was negligence on the company’s part to have required the employee to work so near the storage of this explosive material.

It is said that if an employé knows that a machine which he is to operate is defective when accepting em[376]ployment he can recover nothing for the consequences. He assumes the risk whenever he thus engages to work. If the service be especially perilous and yet he clearly understands the nature of it and is injured when performing it, he can get nothing. Doubtless in many of these cases he is paid a larger sum for working under such conditions. Whatever may be the truth in this regard, the principle of law is well understood that, if he has a full knowledge of the risk of his situation and makes no complaint about the nature of the machinery that he is to operate, he accepts the risks, however great they may be. In one of the cases an employé was injured by the kick of a horse belonging to his employer, but he recovered nothing, because he understood the vicious nature of the animal. The horse had kicked others; in fact, its reputation for kicking was well known, and the employé began work with his eyes wide open.

It’s said that if an employee knows that the machine he’s going to operate is faulty when he takes the job, he can’t claim anything for the consequences. He takes on the risk as soon as he agrees to work. If the job is particularly dangerous and he clearly understands that, but gets hurt while doing it, he won’t be compensated. It’s true that in many of these cases, he might be paid a higher wage for working under those conditions. Regardless of the situation, the legal principle is clear: if he fully understands the risks involved and doesn’t complain about the machinery he’s operating, he accepts those risks, no matter how severe they might be. In one case, an employee was injured when a horse owned by his employer kicked him, but he didn’t receive any compensation because he was aware of the horse's dangerous nature. The horse had kicked others before; in fact, it was well-known for being a kicker, and the employee started working fully aware of the risks.

This rule also applies if tools, machinery, etc., become defective and the employé continues to work after the defects are found out. Of course, every one knows that tools wear out and machinery becomes weaker, and that is one of the natural consequences of using them. And so it is regarded as one of the risks ordinarily taken by an employé, and therefore he can get nothing whenever he is injured through the operation of a defective machine caused by the natural wear and tear of time.

This rule also applies if tools, machinery, etc., become faulty and the employee keeps working after the issues have been identified. Naturally, everyone understands that tools wear out and machinery gets weaker, which is just a normal result of using them. So, it's considered one of the risks typically accepted by an employee, and as a result, they cannot claim anything if they get injured due to the operation of a defective machine that has deteriorated from normal wear and tear over time.

[377]EXAMINATION PAPER

Note.The following questions are given as an indication of the sort of knowledge a student ought to possess after a careful study of the course. The student is advised to write out the answers. Only such answers need be attempted as can be framed from the lessons.

Note.The following questions are provided to show the kind of knowledge a student should have after thoroughly studying the course. Students are encouraged to write out their answers. Only attempt answers that can be developed from the lessons.

  1. (a)  What is a contract? (b)  What is the difference between a simple and a special contract? (c)  What contracts can be made by a minor? When and how can he ratify them? (d)  If a person makes a contract to work for one year and breaks it after working six months can he collect six months' wages? (e)  Give illustrations of six different kinds of contracts.
  2. (a)  When is it necessary that contracts be in writing? (b)  In what case is a failure of consideration a good defence to a contract? (c)  Is a consideration required to make an offer binding? (d)  Is the delivery of goods essential to make a sale complete?
  3. (a)  What are the different kinds of warranties? (b)  Suppose A should buy goods and pay for them, but not take them away, and afterward B should buy them and take them away—could A recover the goods from B?
  4. (a)  What is the difference between a public and a private carrier? (b)  Must a public carrier take everything offered? (c)  What rules of liability apply to common carriers, and how can they be modified?

[381]PREPARING COPY FOR THE PRESS AND PROOF-READING

I. PREPARING COPY

Our purpose in these few lessons is to give some explicit directions as to the general make-up of manuscripts intended for printing. Every person who has even a business card or a circular to print should have a knowledge of the common phraseology of a printing house.

Our goal in these lessons is to provide clear guidance on the general format of manuscripts meant for printing. Anyone who has even a business card or a flyer to print should understand the common terminology used in a printing house.

As to paper, the size in most common use for manuscripts is what is known as letter. The sheets in any case should be of uniform size. Avoid all eccentricity and affectation in the preparation of your manuscript, or "copy," as printers call it. The more matter-of-fact and businesslike it is the better.

As for paper, the most commonly used size for manuscripts is what’s known as letter. The sheets should definitely be the same size. Avoid any odd styles or pretentiousness when preparing your manuscript, or "copy," as printers refer to it. The more straightforward and professional it is, the better.

If at all possible have your manuscript type-written, and under no circumstances should you roll the sheets when preparing them for the mails. There are a number of large publishing houses which positively refuse to touch rolled manuscripts. The very first impression created by such a manuscript is one of extreme irritation. A rolled proof is pretty nearly as discouraging, yet many printers still follow the annoying practice of rolling their proofs.

If possible, have your manuscript typed, and under no circumstances should you roll the sheets when preparing them for mailing. There are several large publishing houses that absolutely refuse to accept rolled manuscripts. The first impression created by such a manuscript is one of extreme irritation. A rolled proof is almost as discouraging, yet many printers still annoyingly roll their proofs.

Every printing establishment of any note has its methods and customs as regards orthography, the use of cap[382]itals and of punctuation. As a rule it is best to leave doubtful points to the printer. Any little deviation desired may be easily remedied in the proofs.

Every reputable printing company has its own rules and practices concerning spelling, the use of capital letters, and punctuation. Generally, it's best to let the printer handle any uncertain issues. Any minor changes you want can be easily adjusted in the proofs.

Paragraphs should be boldly indicated by setting the line well back in the "copy." Extract matter included in the text should be clearly shown, either by marking it down the side with a vertical line from beginning to end or by setting the whole well back within the compass of the text. Such matter is commonly set in slightly smaller type.

Paragraphs should be clearly marked by starting the line further back in the text. Any content extracted from the text should be clearly indicated, either by marking it down the side with a vertical line from start to finish or by indenting the entire section within the text. This content is usually set in a slightly smaller font.

With regard to the corrections in the proofs it must be remembered that the more carefully an article is written the smaller the expense for author's corrections. This charge is often a great source of contention between the author and the printer, and, altogether, is an unsatisfactory item. A printer is bound, with certain reservations, to follow the "copy" supplied. If he does that and the author does not make any alterations there is no extra charge and nothing to wrangle about. A small correction, trivial as it may seem to the inexperienced, may involve much trouble to the printer. A word inserted or deleted may cause a page to be altered throughout, line by line, and a few words may possibly affect several pages. The charges made for corrections are based on the time consumed in making the necessary alterations.

Regarding the corrections in the proofs, it should be noted that the more carefully an article is written, the lower the cost for the author's corrections. This fee is often a significant source of disagreement between the author and the printer and is generally an unsatisfactory issue. A printer is required, with certain exceptions, to follow the provided "copy." If he does this and the author makes no changes, there are no extra charges, and nothing to argue about. A minor correction, as insignificant as it may seem to someone inexperienced, can lead to a lot of work for the printer. Adding or removing a word can result in a page needing to be adjusted throughout, line by line, and a few words might impact several pages. The fees for corrections are determined by the time spent making the necessary changes.

II. ON THE NAMES AND SIZES OF TYPE

The beauty of printed matter depends very largely upon the selection of a suitable style of type. For books and newspaper work there are in use two general classes known as (a) old style, (b) modern. These names refer to the shape of the letter and not to its size. The several[383] sizes of type commonly used in all plain work are as follows:

The beauty of printed materials largely depends on choosing the right font style. For books and newspapers, there are two main types known as (a) old style and (b) modern. These names refer to the shape of the letters, not their size. The various[383] font sizes commonly used in all standard printing are as follows:

  1. pearl
  2. agate.
  3. unmatched.
  4. minion.
  5. brevier font.
  6. middle class.
  7. long article.
  8. small pixel.
  9. pica
  10. english.
  11. great introduction.

Pica is universally considered as the standard type, just as the foot is the standard of measurement. The twelfth part of a pica is the unit, called a point, by which type bodies are measured. In many printing offices the type is known as 6-point, 8-point, 10-point, etc., instead of as nonpareil, brevier, long primer, etc. The following specimens show the sizes of the type in common use:

Pica is widely recognized as the standard type, much like the foot is the standard for measurement. The twelfth part of a pica is the unit known as a point, which is used to measure type sizes. In many printing shops, the type is referred to as 6-point, 8-point, 10-point, etc., instead of the traditional names like nonpareil, brevier, long primer, etc. The following examples show the sizes of the type commonly in use:

Sample type faces pearl, agate, nonpareil, minion, brevier, bourgeois, primer, small pica, pica, English, primer.

The student must bear in mind the fact that these names refer to the size of the type. For instance, there may be a dozen different styles of brevier or of pica; a particular specimen of printing may be entirely in long[384] primer, yet some words may be capitals, others italic, others boldface, and so on.

The student should remember that these names indicate the size of the type. For example, there could be several styles of brevier or pica; a specific print job may be completely in long[384] primer, but some words might be in uppercase, others italic, and some bold, and so on.

Agate is the size of type used in measuring advertisements. There are fourteen agate lines in an inch.

Agate is the size of type used to measure advertisements. There are fourteen agate lines in an inch.

A complete series of type of a particular size is called a font; as a font of brevier, or of pica. Such a font would include:

A complete set of type in a specific size is called a font; for example, a font of brevier or pica. This font would include:

CAPITALS
small caps
lower-case
ITALIC CAPITALS
italic lower-case.

Also figures, fractions, points, references, braces, signs, etc. Printers divide a font of letters into two classes:

Also numbers, fractions, punctuation marks, references, braces, symbols, etc. Printers categorize a font of letters into two types:

1. The upper-case sorts. }
2. The lower-case

The upper-case sorts are capitals, small capitals, references, dashes, braces, signs, etc.

The upper-case types are capitals, small caps, references, dashes, braces, signs, etc.

The lower-case sorts consist of small letters, figures, points, spaces, etc.

The lower-case sorts consist of small letters, numbers, punctuation, spaces, etc.

Type lines are often bulked out by the insertion of thin strips of lead, this being called leading. Where no leads are employed the matter is said to be solid.

Type lines are often thickened by adding thin strips of lead, which is called leading. When no leads are used, the text is referred to as solid.

III. THE TERMS USED IN PRINTING

Composition. This is the name given by printers to the work of setting the type. The compositor holds in his hand a composing-stick, into which he places the type letter by letter, adding the spaces where necessary. A[385] great deal of the newspaper work of the present day is set by type machines.

Composition. This is what printers call the process of arranging the type. The typesetter holds a composing-stick in their hand, placing the letters one by one and adding spaces where needed. A[385] lot of today's newspaper work is done using type machines.

Distributing. The type of a particular page or article after it has been used on the press or for electrotyping is distributed letter by letter in the cases. This work is much more rapid than composition. Type to be used a second time is said to be standing or is called standing matter.

Distributing. The type of a specific page or article after it has been used for printing or electrotyping is sorted letter by letter in the cases. This process is much faster than composing. Type that is being reused is referred to as standing or is known as standing matter.

Spaces. Spaces are short blank types and are used to separate one word from another. To enable a compositor to space evenly and to "justify" properly, these spaces are cast to various thicknesses. An em quadrat is a short blank type, in thickness equal to the letter m of the font to which it belongs. Quadrats are of various sizes.

Spaces. Spaces are short blank characters used to separate one word from another. To help a compositor space things evenly and "justify" correctly, these spaces come in different thicknesses. An em quadrat is a short blank character, with a thickness equal to the letter m in the font it belongs to. Quadrats come in various sizes.

Calendered Paper. This name is given to very highly rolled or glazed paper such as is used in illustrated work. Laid paper has a slightly ribbed surface. Antique paper is rough and usually untrimmed at the edges. It is made in imitation of old styles.

Calendared Paper. This term refers to paper that has been rolled or glazed to a high shine, often used in illustrated publications. Laid paper has a slightly textured surface. Antique paper is rough and typically has untrimmed edges. It is designed to mimic the look of older styles.

Caps. and Lower-case. These names are used to designate capitals and small letters.

Hats. and lowercase. These terms refer to capital letters and small letters.

Clarendon. This name is commonly given to a bold and black-faced type, such as used in text-books to bring out prominently particular words.

Clarendon. This name is commonly used for a bold and black-faced type, like the one found in textbooks to highlight specific words.

Dummy. An imitation in style and size of a book or pamphlet that is wanted, usually made up with blank paper.

Dummy. A replica that looks like a book or pamphlet in style and size, usually filled with blank pages.

Electrotype. Electrotype or stereotype plates are made from type. Books are usually printed from such plates.

Electrotyping. Electrotype or stereotype plates are made from type. Books are typically printed from these plates.

Galley Proof. As the type is set up it is removed from the composing-stick to long forms called galleys. A proof taken of the whole galley at once is called a galley proof. Book work should be revised in galleys before it is made up into pages.[386]

Galley Proof. Once the type is set, it's taken out of the composing stick and placed into long trays called galleys. A proof pulled from the entire galley at once is known as a galley proof. Book work should be edited in the galleys before it's put together into pages.[386]

Impression. A flat-pull or first impression is a simple proof usually pulled in job offices by laying a sheet of damp paper on the inked type and pounding with a flat-surfaced weight to get the impression.

Impression. A flat-pull or first impression is a basic proof typically made in print shops by placing a sheet of damp paper on the inked type and pressing down with a flat weight to create the impression.

Indent. To set a line some distance forward, as in the case of a new paragraph.

Indent. To move a line slightly to the right, like at the start of a new paragraph.

Letterpress. Printed matter from type as distinguished from plate printing.

Letterpress printing. Printed materials made using movable type, as opposed to plate printing.

Make-up. To measure off type matter into pages.

Makeup. To layout text on pages.

Off-set. It frequently occurs that as the result of insufficient drying or from other causes the impression of one sheet appears on the back of another; such work is said to off-set.

Offset. It often happens that due to inadequate drying or other reasons, the print from one sheet shows up on the back of another; this is known as off-set.

Overlays. In making ready for the press the pressman finds it necessary to add here and there, by pasting, thicknesses of paper to his roller to bring out properly the light and shade of an illustration or to get an even ink impression from the type or plates. This work is called making overlays. In expensive illustrated work specialists are engaged solely for the purpose of making overlays.

Overlays. When preparing for printing, the press operator often needs to paste layers of paper onto the roller in various spots to get the light and shadow of an illustration just right or to achieve an even ink impression from the type or plates. This process is known as making overlays. In high-end illustrated projects, specialists are hired specifically for the task of making overlays.

Press Proof. The final proof passed by the author or publisher.

Press Proof. The last proof approved by the author or publisher.

Process-blocks. Blocks produced by the photoengraving and other mechanical processes.

Process blocks. Blocks created by photoengraving and other mechanical methods.

Query. A mark made on a proof by the printer to call attention to a possible error, sometimes expressed by a note of interrogation (?).

Search. A note made on a proof by the printer to highlight a potential error, often indicated by a question mark (?).

Register. The exact adjustment of pages back to back in printing the second side of a sheet.

Sign up. The precise alignment of pages back to back when printing the second side of a sheet.

Signature. The letter or figure at the foot of a sheet to guide the binder in folding; also used by printers to identify any particular sheet.

Sign-off. The letter or number at the bottom of a page to help the binder in folding; also used by printers to identify a specific sheet.

The various marks and signs used by printers will be explained in the lesson on proof-reading.

The different symbols and signs used by printers will be explained in the lesson on proofreading.

[387]IV. MARKS USED IN PROOF-READING

The most important of the signs used in making corrections for the printer are as follows:

The most essential symbols used for making corrections for the printer are as follows:

1. Delete or expunge mark. Delete or expunge.
2. A turned letter mark. A turned letter.
3. Wrong-font letter mark. Wrong-font letter.
4. Change capital to small letter mark. Change capital to small letter, ("lower-case").
5. Insert period mark. Insert period.
6. Transpose words or letters as indicated mark. Transpose words or letters as indicated.
7. Change roman to italic mark. Change roman to italic.
8. Change italic to roman mark. Change italic to roman.
9. Space to be inserted mark. Space to be inserted.
10. Matter wrongly altered to remain as it was originally mark. Matter wrongly altered to remain as it was originally. Dots are placed under the matter.
11. A bad or battered letter mark. A bad or battered letter.
12.  Space to be reduced mark. Space to be reduced.
13. Close up mark. Close up.
14. Push down space or lead mark. Push down space or lead.
15. New paragraph mark. New paragraph.
16. Something foreign between the lines, or a wrong-font space mark. Something foreign between the lines, or a wrong-font space making the type crooked.
17. Line to be indented one em of its own body mark. Line to be indented one em of its own body.

[388]When letters or words are set double or are required to be taken out a line is drawn through the superfluous word or letter and the mark No. 1, called dele, placed opposite on the margin. (Dele is Latin for take out.)

[388]When letters or words are duplicated or need to be removed, a line is drawn through the extra word or letter, and the mark No. 1, called dele, is placed in the margin next to it. (Dele is Latin for take out.)

A turned letter is noted by drawing a line through it and writing the mark No. 2 on the margin.

A turned letter is indicated by drawing a line through it and writing the note No. 2 in the margin.

If letters or words require to be altered to make them more conspicuous a parallel line or lines must be made underneath the word or letter—namely, for capitals, three lines; for small capitals, two lines; and for italic, one line; and on the margin opposite the line where the alteration occurs the sign caps., small caps., or ital. must be written.

If letters or words need to be changed to make them stand out more, you should draw a line or lines underneath the word or letter—specifically, for capital letters, three lines; for small capitals, two lines; and for italics, one line; and in the margin next to where the change happens, write the sign caps., small caps., or ital..

Where a letter of a different font is improperly introduced into the page it is noted by drawing a line through it and writing w. f. (wrong font) on the margin.

Where a letter in a different font is incorrectly added to the page, it is marked by crossing it out and writing w. f. (wrong font) in the margin.

Where a word has been left out or is to be added a caret must be made in the place where it should come in and the word written on the margin. A caret is made thus: ^

Where a word is missing or needs to be added, a caret should be made in the spot where it belongs, and the word should be written in the margin. A caret is made like this: ^

Where letters stand crooked they are noted by a line, but where a page hangs lines are drawn across the entire part affected.

Where letters are misaligned, they are marked by a line, but where a page is hanging, lines are drawn across the whole affected area.

Where a faulty letter appears it is denoted by making a cross under it and placing a similar mark on the margin.

Where a mistake in a letter occurs, it is indicated by marking a cross underneath it and placing a similar mark in the margin.

Where several words are left out or where new matter is to be added the added matter is written wherever convenient, and a line is drawn from the place of omission to the written words.

Where several words are missing or where new information needs to be added, the added information is written wherever it's convenient, and a line is drawn from the place of omission to the added words.

In making a correction in a proof always mark the wrong letter or word through and insert the alteration in the margin, not in the middle of the printed matter, because it is liable to be overlooked if there is no marginal reference to the correction. To keep the different[389] corrections distinct finish each off with a stroke, thus /; and to make the alterations more clear or less crowded mark those relating to the left-hand portion on the left margin and those relating to the right-hand portion on the right margin.

When correcting a proof, always cross out the incorrect letter or word and put the correction in the margin, not in the middle of the printed text, as it might be missed without a marginal reference to the correction. To keep the various[389] corrections clear, finish each one with a stroke like this /; and to make the changes clearer or less cluttered, mark those related to the left side in the left margin and those related to the right side in the right margin.


The hints given here are intended for the general public and not for the printer, and to the student of these lessons let us say that the first essential of good proof-reading is clearness. Be very sure that the printer will understand the changes which you desire him to make. Quite often it is an advantage if you wish a particular style of type used to cut out a sample of that style and paste it on your copy or on your proof, indicating that you want it to be used. Instructions to the printer written either on the copy or on the proof should be surrounded by a line to separate them from the text, or to prevent any confusion with other written matter intended as copy or as corrections.

The tips provided here are meant for the general public, not for the printer. For students studying these lessons, the first important rule of good proofreading is clarity. Make sure the printer understands the changes you want made. It's often helpful if you want a specific typeface to cut out a sample of that style and attach it to your copy or proof, clearly indicating your preference. Any instructions for the printer written on either the copy or the proof should be surrounded by a line to distinguish them from the text, preventing confusion with other notes that are meant to be either copy or corrections.

When the corrections have been duly made and approved by the author or editor it is customary to write the word "press" on the top of the first page. If intermediate proofs are wanted, mark on the proofs returned to the printer "Send revise." The final or "press" proof is always retained by the printer in case of any dispute. It is his voucher, and he retains it for future reference.

When the corrections have been made and approved by the author or editor, it's standard to write the word "press" at the top of the first page. If you need intermediate proofs, mark "Send revise" on the proofs returned to the printer. The final or "press" proof is always kept by the printer in case of any disputes. It's his record, and he keeps it for future reference.

It is a good plan to make corrections in a different coloured ink from that used by the printer's proof-reader. If you are having a pamphlet or book printed the different proofs will reach you in the following order:

It’s a smart idea to make corrections in a different colored ink than the one used by the printer's proofreader. If you're getting a pamphlet or book printed, you’ll receive the different proofs in this order:

  1. Galley proofs.
  2. Revised proofs (if any).
  3. Page proofs.
  4. Foundry proofs.
A printer's proof. A print proof.

So far as possible, make all the necessary changes while the type is in galleys. Once made up into pages, a very slight change, particularly such a change as the crossing out or addition of a sentence, may make a great deal of[391] trouble. When the pages are passed upon they are sent to the foundry for casting. The foundry proofs are the last proofs pulled. Corrections made on these make it necessary to alter the electrotype plates, which is rather an expensive process. To change a word, a piece of the metal plate has to be cut out and another with the new word soldered in.

As much as possible, make all the necessary changes while the text is still in galleys. Once it's formatted into pages, even a small change, especially crossing out or adding a sentence, can cause a lot of[391] trouble. After the pages are approved, they go to the foundry for casting. The foundry proofs are the final proofs printed. Making corrections on these requires adjustments to the electrotype plates, which can be quite costly. To change a word, a section of the metal plate must be cut out and replaced with a new piece that has the updated word soldered in.

A printer's corrected proof. Printer's corrected proof.

[392]A page is said to overrun if it is too long. If the space to be occupied is limited it is a good plan to adapt your copy to it by counting the words and by comparing the count with that of some printed page in the same size of type.

[392]A page is considered to overrun if it's too lengthy. If the space available is restricted, it's smart to adjust your text accordingly by counting the words and comparing that count with a printed page of the same type size.

Return proofs to your printer or publisher as promptly as possible. As a rule printing houses cannot afford to keep type locked up and unused waiting for the return of proofs. There are many imperfections in typography, such as wrong-font and inverted letters, awkward and irregular spacing, uneven pages or columns, crooked words and lines, etc., which it is the business of the printing house to correct. No book or pamphlet, therefore, ought to go to press until it has been read and revised by an experienced reader.

Return proofs to your printer or publisher as quickly as you can. Generally, printing companies can't afford to keep type locked up and unused while waiting for the return of proofs. There are many errors in typography, like the wrong font and upside-down letters, awkward and irregular spacing, uneven pages or columns, crooked words and lines, etc., which it is the responsibility of the printing company to fix. So, no book or pamphlet should go to press until it has been read and revised by an experienced reader.

Strict uniformity should always be preserved in the use of capitals, in spelling, and in punctuation.

Strict uniformity should always be maintained in the use of capital letters, spelling, and punctuation.

Where authors have their manuscripts type-written and make two or three revises upon the type-written sheets before their copy is turned over to the publishing house, the labour of proof-reading and the expenses of corrections are reduced to a minimum.

Where authors have their manuscripts typed up and make two or three revisions on the typed pages before their copy is sent to the publishing house, the work of proofreading and the costs of corrections are kept to a minimum.

The errors shown in our illustration are more numerous than are likely to appear in any proof sent out from a publishing house.

The mistakes shown in our illustration are more numerous than those that would typically show up in any proof sent out from a publishing house.

Transcriber's Notes
Page
• favorable changed to favourable 35
• favor changed to favour 49
• (5) changed to 5. 65
• contantly changed to constantly 115
• Ierland changed to Ireland 130
• battle-ships changed to battleships 150
• BREAD-STUFFS changed to BREADSTAFFS 152
• duplicated "from" deleted 162
• bread-stuffs change to breadstuffs 163
• June, 1898 changed to June 30, 1898 205
• proportiona t changed to proportion at 208
• duplicated "in" deleted 223
• typewritten changed to type-written 259
• everyday changed to every-day 350
• comma added after figures 384
• colored changed to coloured 389
• nessary changed to necessary 390

 




        
        
    
Download ePUB

If you like this ebook, consider a donation!