This is a modern-English version of Are we ruined by the Germans?, originally written by Cox, Harold.
It has been thoroughly updated, including changes to sentence structure, words, spelling,
and grammar—to ensure clarity for contemporary readers, while preserving the original spirit and nuance. If
you click on a paragraph, you will see the original text that we modified, and you can toggle between the two versions.
Scroll to the bottom of this page and you will find a free ePUB download link for this book.
ARE WE RUINED BY THE
GERMANS?
BY
BY
Republished from the “Daily Graphic” for the Cobden Club.
Republished from the "Daily Graphic" for the Cobden Club.
CASSELL and COMPANY, Limited:
CASSELL and COMPANY, Limited:
LONDON, PARIS & MELBOURNE.
LONDON, PARIS & MELBOURNE.
PREFACE.
The greater part of the contents of this little volume appeared originally in the Daily Graphic, in the form of a series of six articles written in criticism of Mr. Ernest Williams’s “Made in Germany.” To these articles Mr. Williams replied in two letters, and to that reply I made a final rejoinder. In the present reproduction this sequence has been abandoned. For the convenience of readers, and for the economy of space, I have anticipated in the text all of Mr. Williams’s objections which appeared to me to have any substance, and, in addition, I have modified or omitted phrases, in themselves trivial, upon which he had fastened to build elaborate but unsubstantial retorts. By doing this I have been able to preserve the continuity of my argument and at the same time to cut down a somewhat lengthy rejoinder into a brief concluding chapter. Incidentally a few new points and some further figures have been added to the articles. This arrangement, unfortunately, deprives Mr. Williams’s reply of most of its original piquancy; but, in order that my readers may have an opportunity of seeing what the author of “Made in Germany” was able to say for himself, his letters are reprinted verbatim in an Appendix. I am indebted to the proprietors of the Daily Graphic for their courteous permission to republish the articles, and to the Committee of the Cobden Club for undertaking the republication. I have only to add that the opinions expressed throughout are my own, and that the Cobden Club does not necessarily endorse every one of them.
The majority of the contents of this small book were originally published in the Daily Graphic, as a series of six articles critiquing Mr. Ernest Williams’s “Made in Germany.” Mr. Williams responded with two letters, to which I made a final reply. In this new version, that order has been changed. For the convenience of readers and to save space, I have anticipated all the objections from Mr. Williams that I deemed significant, and I have also adjusted or removed trivial phrases that he used to create elaborate but weak counterarguments. This way, I've managed to maintain the flow of my argument while condensing a fairly long reply into a shorter concluding chapter. Additionally, I've included a few new points and further figures in the articles. Unfortunately, this arrangement diminishes the original edge of Mr. Williams’s reply; however, to give my readers a chance to see what the author of “Made in Germany” had to say, his letters are included verbatim in an Appendix. I am grateful to the proprietors of the Daily Graphic for their kind permission to republish these articles, and to the Committee of the Cobden Club for handling the republication. I just want to add that the opinions expressed here are my own, and the Cobden Club does not necessarily support every one of them.
H. C.
H. C.
Gray’s Inn,
December, 1896.
Gray's Inn,
December 1896.
CONTENTS.
CHAP. | PAGE | |
---|---|---|
I.— | Our Expanding Trade | 1 |
II.— | Germany: One of Our Best Customers | 8 |
III.— | Picturesque Exaggerations | 14 |
IV.— | More Misrepresentations | 21 |
V.— | Our Growing Prosperity | 33 |
VI.— | Let Well Alone | 43 |
VII.— | Conclusion | 54 |
APPENDIX | 57 |
CHAPTER I.
Growing Trade.
In a little book recently published, an attempt is made to show that British trade is being knocked to pieces by German competition, that already the sun has set on England’s commercial supremacy, and that if we are not careful the few crumbs of trade still left to us will be snapped up by Germany. This depressing publication, aptly entitled “Made in Germany,” has received the quasi-religious benediction of an enterprising and esoteric journalist, and the puff direct from a sportive ex-Prime Minister. Thus sent off it is sure to be widely circulated, and, being beyond dispute well written, to be also widely read. Unfortunately—such is the nature of the book—it cannot be so widely criticised. It consists largely of quoted statistics and deductions therefrom, and few readers will have the means at hand for verifying the many figures quoted, while fewer still will have the patience to compare them with other figures which the author omits to mention. As a necessary consequence, a large number of persons will believe that Mr. Williams has proved his case, and some of them will jump to the conclusion, which is evidently the conclusion to which Mr. Williams himself leans, that the only way to prevent the commercial downfall of our country is to reverse the Free Trade policy which we deliberately adopted fifty years ago.
In a recently published book, an attempt is made to show that British trade is being severely harmed by German competition, that England’s commercial dominance is already fading, and that if we aren’t careful, the few remaining trade opportunities will be taken by Germany. This grim book, aptly titled “Made in Germany,” has garnered the almost religious endorsement of an ambitious and niche journalist, along with praise from a playful former Prime Minister. With this support, it’s bound to be widely shared and, due to its quality writing, widely read. Unfortunately—such is the nature of the book—it cannot be easily critiqued. It mostly consists of cited statistics and interpretations of them, and few readers will have the resources to verify the numerous figures presented, while even fewer will have the patience to compare them with other figures that the author chooses not to mention. As a result, many people will likely believe that Mr. Williams has made a convincing argument, and some of them will hastily conclude, which clearly aligns with Mr. Williams’s own viewpoint, that the only way to prevent our country’s commercial decline is to reverse the Free Trade policy we intentionally adopted fifty years ago.
THE ART OF EXAGGERATION.
That may or may not be a wise thing to do, but at least let us be certain before taking action, or before taking thought which is preliminary to action, that we know our facts, and all our facts. The second point is as important as the first. On hastily reading Mr. Williams’s book for the first time, my impression was that he had only [2]erred by overlooking facts which told on the other side. On general grounds, considering the signs of prosperity on every side, it seemed to me impossible that the condition of our foreign trade could be so bad as the author of “Made in Germany” paints it. A cursory glance at a few staple figures convinced me that my general impression was a sound one, that our trade was not going to the dogs, and that Mr. Williams had only succeeded in producing so gloomy a picture by fixing his gaze on the shadows and shutting his eyes to the sunlight. On this supposition I began a more critical examination of his book, not with a view to refuting his positive statements, but with a view to showing that in spite of the ugly facts which he had, on the whole usefully, brought to light, there were counterbalancing considerations from which we might draw, at any rate, partial consolation. This I propose to do, but in addition I shall be able to show that many of Mr. Williams’s alleged ugly facts are not in reality so ugly as he makes them look, and that what he has done, in his eagerness to prove his case, is to so choose his figures and so phrase his sentences as to convey in particular instances an entirely false impression. How this is done will be shown in detail later on. For the present it is sufficient to state that it is done, and that some of the most alarmist statements in “Made in Germany” will not bear critical examination. In a word, the author, in his polemical zeal, has sinned both sins—he has suggested the false and he has omitted the true; he has misrepresented, in particular instances, the facts to which he refers, and he has not referred at all to facts which refute his general argument.
That might be a wise thing to do, but at least let's make sure before taking action, or before thinking the thoughts that lead to action, that we know all the facts and every detail. This second point is as crucial as the first. When I quickly skimmed Mr. Williams’s book for the first time, I felt he had only erred by ignoring facts that presented a different perspective. Given the signs of prosperity all around us, it seemed impossible that the state of our foreign trade could be as dire as the author of “Made in Germany” claims. A quick look at a few key figures confirmed my overall impression was correct—that our trade wasn’t going downhill and that Mr. Williams had only created such a bleak picture by focusing on the negatives and ignoring the positives. With this thought in mind, I began a more thorough examination of his book, not to dispute his claims, but to illustrate that despite the troubling facts he highlighted—factually useful though they might be—there were balancing factors from which we could find at least some comfort. I intend to do this, but additionally, I can show that many of Mr. Williams’s purported troubling facts aren’t as grim as he presents them and that in his eagerness to prove his point, he has selectively chosen his data and crafted his sentences in a way that gives a misleading impression in certain cases. How this is accomplished will be explained in detail later. For now, it’s enough to state that it is indeed happening, and that many of the most alarming claims in “Made in Germany” won’t hold up under scrutiny. In short, the author, in his argumentative fervor, has fallen into both traps—he has suggested untruths and left out truths; he has misrepresented certain facts and entirely disregarded facts that contradict his overall argument.
THE WHOLE TRUTH.
It is with these that I propose first to deal, with the facts which show that our trade is in a very healthy condition, and that though Germany is also doing well and hitting us hard in some trades, there is no reason to believe that her prosperity is, on the whole, injuring us. And to guard myself, at the outset, against a temptation to which Mr. Williams has frequently succumbed—the temptation of picking out years peculiarly favourable to my argument—I propose to take the last ten or the last fifteen years, for which statistics are available, and to give wherever possible the figures for each year in the whole period. The figures that will be here quoted are all taken from official records, except when otherwise stated.
I want to start by addressing the facts that show our trade is doing really well. Even though Germany is also thriving and competing strongly in some areas, there's no reason to think that their success is harming us overall. To avoid the temptation that Mr. Williams often gives in to—selecting years that support my argument—I plan to look at the last ten or fifteen years for which we have statistics. I will provide figures for each year in that timeframe whenever possible. All the figures I'll reference come from official records, unless stated otherwise.
[3]OUR TOTAL TRADE FOR TEN YEARS.
The first point to attack is the question of the total import and export trade of the United Kingdom. The figures are contained in the following table:—
The first issue to address is the total import and export trade of the United Kingdom. The numbers are shown in the following table:—
Ten Years of Trade in the United Kingdom
(Exclusive of Bullion and Specie).
In Millions Sterling.
(Exclusive of Bullion and Specie).
In Millions Sterling.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total Imports | 350 | 362 | 388 | 428 | 421 | 435 | 423 | 405 | 408 | 417 |
Total Exports | 269 | 281 | 299 | 316 | 328 | 309 | 292 | 277 | 274 | 286 |
Excess of Imports over Exports | 81 | 81 | 89 | 112 | 93 | 126 | 132 | 128 | 134 | 131 |
These figures may be illustrated as follows:—
These numbers can be shown like this:—
These figures hardly bear out the statement that “commercial dry rot,” to use one of Mr. Williams’s favourite phrases, has already laid hold of us. In spite of the fall in prices, the money value of our trade, both import and export, has fully maintained its level. It is [4]true that the year 1886, with which the diagram starts, was a year of depression, but the point which I wish to bring out by the diagram is not that 1895 was a better year than 1886, but that the general course for the whole period of ten years shows no downward tendency. Later on I shall give a diagram, covering a period of fifteen years, which brings out the same point even more clearly. It is important, however, at once to point out that the mere comparison of the money totals of our trade in different years is necessarily inconclusive, because no account is taken of prices. To get a true comparison between any two years, say 1895 and 1890, we ought to calculate what the value of our trade in 1895 would have been if each separate commodity had been sold at the prices of 1890. Were this done, it would probably be found that 1895, instead of showing a decline, would show an immense advance. A similar comparison has been privately worked out in one of the Government offices for the years 1873 and 1886 with startling results, which I am permitted to quote. It must be premised that only certain articles are entered in our returns by quantity as well as by value, and it is therefore only between these that such a comparison as I have indicated can be made. In 1873, the total declared value of our exports of these articles was 172 millions sterling; in 1886, it was 131 millions, showing an apparent fall of 41 millions. But if these exports of 1886 had been declared at the prices of 1873 the total value would have been 215 millions. In this sense, then, our aggregate trade in these commodities in 1886, instead of being 41 millions worse than 1873, was 43 millions better. This is undoubtedly an extreme illustration, for the prices of 1873 were exceptionally high, and those of 1886 exceptionally low. Nevertheless, the illustration is most instructive as showing how extremely misleading it may be to compare values only, without taking account of quantities. Unfortunately, when we are dealing with the total trade of a country, a comparison of values is the only comparison possible, for there is no other common denominator by means of which varied articles—say, steam ploughs, cotton piece-goods, and patent medicines—can be brought into our table.
These numbers hardly support the claim that “commercial dry rot,” as Mr. Williams likes to say, has already taken hold of us. Despite falling prices, the monetary value of our trade, both import and export, has stayed stable. It is true that the year 1886, which the diagram starts with, was a year of decline, but what I'm trying to highlight with the diagram isn't that 1895 was better than 1886, but rather that the overall trend over the entire ten-year period shows no downward slope. Later, I'll provide a diagram covering a longer fifteen-year period that makes this point even clearer. However, it's important to note right away that simply comparing the monetary totals of our trade in different years is inconclusive because it doesn't account for prices. To accurately compare any two years, like 1895 and 1890, we need to calculate what the value of our trade in 1895 would have been if every individual item had been sold at the prices of 1890. If we did that, we would probably find that 1895 actually shows a huge increase rather than a decline. A similar comparison has been privately done in one of the Government offices for the years 1873 and 1886, yielding surprising results that I am allowed to share. It should be noted that only certain items are recorded in our reports by both quantity and value, so we can only make such a comparison for those items. In 1873, the total declared value of our exports for these items was 172 million pounds; in 1886, it was 131 million, indicating an apparent drop of 41 million. But if the exports of 1886 had been valued at the prices of 1873, the total would have been 215 million. So, in this sense, our overall trade in these goods in 1886 was actually 43 million better than in 1873, instead of being 41 million worse. This is undoubtedly an extreme example, as prices in 1873 were exceptionally high and those in 1886 exceptionally low. Nonetheless, this example clearly shows how misleading it can be to compare values alone without considering quantities. Unfortunately, when looking at a country's total trade, comparing values is the only option available, since there’s no other common measure to bring together different items—like steam ploughs, cotton fabric, and patent medicines—into our table.
OUR IMPORTS OF GOLD AND SILVER.
To return to our diagram—it may be asked, “How does it happen that there is such a large and growing excess of imports over exports? Surely that is a bad sign.” On the face of it, why should it be? It only means that we are, apparently, getting more than we [5]give, and most people do not in their private relations regard that as a hardship. There are, however, people to be found who, seeing that we every year buy more goods than we sell, will jump to the conclusion that we must pay for the difference in cash. Where we are to get the cash from they do not pause to think. Hitherto the Welsh hills have resolutely refused to give up their gold in paying quantities, and as for the silver which we separate from Cornish lead, it is worth something less than £50,000 a year. The notion then that we pay for our foreign purchases with our own gold and silver may be dismissed at once, although a hundred years ago this same delusion had not a little influence in shaping our commercial policy. As a matter of fact, instead of sending gold and silver out of the country to pay for our excess of imports, we almost every year import considerably more bullion and specie than we export. The actual figures are given in the following table:—
To go back to our diagram—it might be asked, “How is it that there’s such a large and growing gap between imports and exports? Surely that’s a bad sign.” At first glance, why should it be? It just means that we’re, apparently, getting more than we’re giving, and most people don’t see that as a problem in their personal lives. However, there are people who see that we buy more goods than we sell each year and jump to the conclusion that we must pay for the difference in cash. They don’t stop to think about where we would get that cash. So far, the Welsh hills have stubbornly refused to provide us with gold in usable amounts, and as for the silver we extract from Cornish lead, it’s worth less than £50,000 a year. The idea that we pay for our foreign purchases with our own gold and silver can be dismissed right away, even though a hundred years ago, this same misconception had quite an impact on our trade policies. In reality, instead of sending gold and silver out of the country to cover our excess imports, we import significantly more bullion and coins than we export nearly every year. The actual figures are provided in the following table:—
The Movement of Bullion and Coins.
In Millions Sterling.
In Millions Sterling.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Imports Gold | 12·9 | 10·0 | 15·8 | 17·9 | 23·6 | 30·3 | 21·6 | 24·8 | 27·6 | 36·0 |
Imports Silver | 7·5 | 7·8 | 6·2 | 9·2 | 10·4 | 9·3 | 10·7 | 11·9 | 11·0 | 10·7 |
Exports Gold | 13·8 | 9·3 | 14·9 | 14·5 | 14·3 | 24·2 | 14·8 | 19·5 | 15·6 | 21·4 |
Exports Silver | 7·2 | 7·8 | 7·6 | 10·7 | 10·9 | 13·1 | 14·1 | 13·6 | 12·2 | 10·4 |
Total excess or deficiency of imports over exports of gold and silver together | - | + | - | + | + | + | + | + | + | + |
·6 | ·6 | ·5 | 2·0 | 8·8 | 2·3 | 2·4 | 3·6 | 10·8 | 15·0 |
EXCESS OF IMPORTS OVER EXPORTS.
The movements of gold and silver then, instead of helping to explain the excess of imports over exports, only increase the need for explanation. Happily, the explanation that can be given, though it cannot be statistical, is fully sufficient. It is fourfold. In the first place the Custom House returns do not include in the tables of exports the large export which we every year make of ships built to order for foreign buyers, so that our exports appear smaller than they really are by at least five millions a year. Secondly, an allowance must be made for the profit on our foreign trade. If, in return [6]for every pound’s worth of British goods sent out from our ports, only a pound’s worth of foreign goods came back, our merchants would make a better living by selling penny toys along the Strand. What the average profit is on our foreign trade there is no means of knowing, but putting it as low as 10 per cent. on the double transaction, we at once account for some £30,000,000 sterling in the difference between our exports and imports. The third item in the explanation is the sum earned by British shipowners for carrying the greater part of the sea-commerce of the world. This sum has been estimated at £70,000,000 a year, but that is only a guess, and it is certainly a high one. Lastly, we have the enormous sum annually due to this country for interest on the money we have lent abroad. The amount of this annual payment can again only be guessed at, but it probably exceeds £100,000,000 a year. Adding then these four items together, and making every allowance for over-estimates, we not only account for the whole excess of imports over exports, but have a balance over, which means that we are still exporting capital to foreign countries. The capital we export goes out in the form of mining machinery to South Africa, steel rails to India, coal to South America; the interest due to us comes home in the form of American wheat, Argentine beef, Australian wool, Indian tea, South African diamonds.
The movements of gold and silver back then, instead of clarifying the excess of imports over exports, only made the need for an explanation greater. Fortunately, while the explanation isn't statistical, it's still completely adequate. It has four parts. First, the Custom House returns don't include in the export tables the significant amount we export each year of ships built on order for foreign buyers, so our exports seem smaller than they actually are by at least five million a year. Second, we need to account for the profits from our foreign trade. If we sent out a pound’s worth of British goods from our ports and only received a pound’s worth of foreign goods in return, our merchants would be better off selling cheap toys along the Strand. We can't know the exact average profit on our foreign trade, but if we estimate it at as low as 10 percent on the whole transaction, that accounts for about £30,000,000 in the difference between our exports and imports. The third point in the explanation is the earnings of British shipowners for transporting most of the world's sea trade. This amount has been estimated at £70,000,000 a year, but that's just a guess and likely on the high side. Finally, we have the huge sum owed to this country each year in interest on the money we've lent abroad. We can only guess the amount of this annual payment, but it's probably over £100,000,000 a year. When we add these four points together and consider potential over-estimates, we not only account for the entire excess of imports over exports, but we also have a surplus, indicating that we are still exporting capital to foreign countries. The capital we send out takes the form of mining machinery to South Africa, steel rails to India, and coal to South America; the interest owed to us comes back as American wheat, Argentine beef, Australian wool, Indian tea, and South African diamonds.
THE WORLD’S TRIBUTE.
Of what do the Protectionists complain? Would they have us forego the interest we are owed? Apparently Mr. Williams would, for he says (page 19) that we ought not to spend all our income from foreign investments “in foreign shops.” How else, in the name of the Prophet, are we to receive all or any part of what is due to us from foreigners, whether it be due for interest on investments, or for goods carried, or for ships sold? Does Mr. Williams mean that we are to compel foreign nations to pay us a couple of hundred millions a year in actual gold and silver, and then dig a hole in the ground and sit on our hoard like an Indian cook who has saved money out of the perquisites of his profession? Gold and silver are useless to us beyond a very few millions every year; if more bullion were sent the market would reject it. If we are to be paid at all we must be paid in foreign commodities, and the mechanism of commerce enables us to select just those commodities which we most want. This is the whole story of our excess of imports over exports. Furthermore, that excess would be even greater than it is did we not every year send [7]fresh millions abroad on loan to our Colonies and foreign countries, to produce in due course (it is to be hoped) additional hundreds of thousands in the way of interest.
What are the Protectionists complaining about? Do they want us to give up the interest we’re owed? It seems Mr. Williams does, since he says (page 19) that we shouldn’t spend all the income from our foreign investments “in foreign shops.” How else, for goodness' sake, are we supposed to receive any part of what foreigners owe us, whether it's interest from investments, payment for goods transported, or money from ships sold? Does Mr. Williams think we should force foreign nations to pay us a couple of hundred million a year in actual gold and silver, and then just bury it and sit on it like some frugal cook who saved up from his tips? Gold and silver are pretty much useless to us beyond a few million each year; if more bullion came, the market would just turn it away. If we’re going to be paid at all, it needs to be in foreign goods, and the trade system allows us to choose the goods we want most. That’s the whole reason for our imports exceeding our exports. Besides, that excess would be even bigger than it is if we didn't send out [7] fresh millions each year on loan to our Colonies and other countries, which hopefully will eventually bring us back hundreds of thousands in interest.
OUR ENTREPÔT TRADE.
There is one other important point to be dealt with in considering the movement of our trade as a whole. It is this—that part of the enormous quantity of goods we import is not consumed by ourselves, but is re-exported to foreign countries or to our Colonies. For many reasons it is interesting to distinguish these re-exports from the exports of goods produced within the United Kingdom. The separate figures for the last fifteen years are given in the following table:—
There’s one more important point to consider when looking at the overall movement of our trade. This is that a portion of the huge quantity of goods we import isn’t consumed by us, but is instead re-exported to foreign countries or our Colonies. For many reasons, it’s useful to separate these re-exports from the goods produced in the United Kingdom that we export. The separate figures for the last fifteen years are provided in the following table:—
Our Warehouse Trade and our Home Trade.
In Millions Sterling.
In millions of pounds.
1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Re-exports of Imported Goods | 63 | 65 | 66 | 63 | 58 | 56 | 59 | 64 | 67 | 65 | 62 | 65 | 59 | 58 | 60 |
Exports of Home Produce | 234 | 242 | 240 | 233 | 213 | 213 | 222 | 235 | 249 | 264 | 247 | 227 | 218 | 216 | 226 |
Total Exports | 297 | 307 | 306 | 296 | 271 | 269 | 281 | 299 | 316 | 329 | 309 | 292 | 277 | 274 | 286 |
There is not much to grumble at in these figures. Our entrepôt trade, which was supposed to be slipping away, seems somewhat to halt in the process, in spite of the notorious and not entirely unpleasing fact that our Colonies are now doing a larger direct trade with foreign countries than ever before. At the same time the figures for the exports of our own goods are most satisfactory if we take into account the lower range of prices at which our manufacturers are now working. Altogether there is nothing in the general figures of our trade to justify the wild statements that “dry rot” has set in, and that “the industrial glory of England is departing.”
There isn't much to complain about with these numbers. Our entrepôt trade, which was expected to decline, seems to have stabilized, despite the well-known and somewhat pleasing fact that our colonies are now engaging in more direct trade with foreign countries than ever before. At the same time, the export figures for our own goods are quite encouraging, especially considering the lower prices at which our manufacturers are currently operating. Overall, there’s nothing in the general trade figures that supports the exaggerated claims that “dry rot” has taken hold and that “the industrial glory of England is fading.”
[8]CHAPTER II.
Germany: One of Our Top Customers.
In the previous chapter it was shown that the general figures of our import and export trade gave no indication of the ruin of our commerce either by Germans or by anybody else. In the present chapter it is proposed to show that though Germany is among the keenest of our trade competitors, she is also one of our best customers. For a sufficient indication of the truth of this proposition we have only to turn to the annual statement of the trade of the United Kingdom. It is true that the figures there published are not entirely satisfactory, because much of the trade of Germany is shipped from Dutch or Belgian ports, and credited to Holland and Belgium respectively. But this is probably also true, and to about the same extent, of British goods destined for Germany, and travelling viâ Belgium or Holland, so that in comparing imports and exports this factor may be neglected. The same cause of error will probably be also present to the same extent in successive years, so that we can ignore it when comparing one year with another. Purely for comparative purposes then the annexed table, and the diagram illustrating it, are sufficiently accurate, although the actual figures for any one year by itself have, for the reasons given, little positive value.
In the previous chapter, it was shown that the overall figures of our import and export trade didn’t indicate any destruction of our commerce by Germans or anyone else. In this chapter, we aim to show that while Germany is one of our toughest trade rivals, she is also one of our best customers. To support this claim, we only need to refer to the annual statement of the UK's trade. It’s true that the published figures aren’t entirely satisfactory because a lot of Germany's trade is shipped from Dutch or Belgian ports, and is recorded as trade with Holland and Belgium, respectively. But this is likely also true, to a similar degree, for British goods going to Germany via Belgium or Holland, so we can overlook this factor when comparing imports and exports. The same source of error will probably be present to the same extent in consecutive years, allowing us to disregard it when looking at year-to-year comparisons. For purely comparative purposes, then, the attached table and the diagram illustrating it are accurate enough, even though the specific figures for any single year hold little positive value for the reasons stated.
Our Entire Trade with German Ports.
In Millions Sterling.
In Millions of Pounds.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Imports from Germany | 21·4 | 24·6 | 26·7 | 27·1 | 26·1 | 27·0 | 25·7 | 26·4 | 26·9 | 27·0 |
Exports to Germany | 26·4 | 27·2 | 27·4 | 31·3 | 30·5 | 29·9 | 29·6 | 28·0 | 29·2 | 32·7 |
These figures may be illustrated diagrammatically as follows:—
These figures can be shown in a diagram like this:—
A VERY SATISFACTORY TRADE.
These figures furnish a striking answer to the alarmists who can see in Germany nothing but a vigorous and not too scrupulous rival. In every year during the last ten years she has apparently bought more from us than she has sold to us. It is quite true that all the things she has bought from us were not produced or manufactured by us. A portion of her purchases consists of foreign or colonial goods sent to London, or Liverpool, or Hull, and there purchased for re-sale in Germany. But in the same way some of the goods we buy from Germany certainly had their origin in other countries, and have only passed through Germany on their way to us; so that the fairest way of making a comparison is to take the whole trade in each case. Moreover, this entrepôt trade of ours is not in itself a thing to be sneezed at; it contributes a goodly fraction of the wealth of the city of London. In order, however, to complete the picture of our trade with Germany, the following table is appended, distinguishing in each of the ten years under review the home produce exported from the foreign and colonial goods re-exported. This table shows that in purely British goods we are doing a very satisfactory trade with Germany. Taking averages, we see that during the ten years our export of our [10]own manufactures and produce to German ports was at the rate of £17,800,000 a year, against a total import from German ports of £25,900,000, this figure including both German goods and other countries’ goods passing through Germany. If we recollect that on the whole our imports from the outside world must be very much larger than our exports, for the reasons detailed in the preceding chapter, it will be seen that these two figures, even by themselves, are not unsatisfactory.
These numbers provide a clear response to those alarmists who only see Germany as a strong and somewhat unscrupulous competitor. Over the last ten years, Germany has consistently bought more from us than it has sold to us. It's true that not everything Germany purchased from us was actually produced or made by us. Some of its purchases include foreign or colonial goods that were sent to London, Liverpool, or Hull, and then bought for resale in Germany. However, the same could be said about some of the goods we buy from Germany, which also originated in other countries and just passed through Germany on their way to us. Therefore, the best way to compare is to look at the entire trade for each case. Additionally, our re-export trade is significant; it contributes a substantial portion of London’s wealth. To give a complete picture of our trade with Germany, the following table is included, which breaks down for each of the ten years the home-produced goods exported from the foreign and colonial goods re-exported. This table indicates that we have a very healthy trade in purely British goods with Germany. On average, during the past decade, our export of our own manufactured goods and produce to German ports was about £17,800,000 a year, while our total imports from German ports amounted to £25,900,000, which includes both German products and goods from other countries that passed through Germany. If we remember that, overall, our imports from the world are likely much larger than our exports, for the reasons discussed in the previous chapter, it's clear that these two figures, on their own, are not disappointing.
Analysis of Our Trade with German Ports.
In Millions Sterling.
In Millions GBP.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
British Goods exported to German ports | 15·7 | 15·7 | 15·8 | 18·5 | 19·3 | 18·8 | 17·6 | 17·7 | 17·8 | 20·6 |
Foreign and Colonial Goods exported from British ports to German ports | 10·6 | 11·5 | 11·6 | 12·8 | 11·2 | 11·1 | 12·1 | 10·3 | 11·4 | 12·2 |
OUR PRINCIPAL CUSTOMERS.
Let us now go a step further and compare our trade with Germany and our trade with other principal customers. The comparison is worked out in the following table, which shows the total imports into the United Kingdom from the respective countries, and the total exports from the United Kingdom to the same countries:—
Let’s take it a step further and compare our trade with Germany to our trade with other key customers. The comparison is detailed in the following table, which shows the total imports into the United Kingdom from each country, as well as the total exports from the United Kingdom to those same countries:—
Trade of the United Kingdom with these Countries.
Ten Years’ Average, in Millions Sterling, according to British Returns.
Ten Years’ Average, in Millions Sterling, according to British Returns.
Imports into U.K. | Exports from U.K. | |
---|---|---|
From and to Germany | 25·9 | 29·2 |
" " France | 42·6 | 21·7 |
" " United States | 91·8 | 40·2 |
" " British India | 30·5 | 31·3 |
" " Australasia | 28·3 | 23·1 |
" " British North America | 12·2 | 8·4 |
These figures are taken from the British Custom House returns, and are subject to the objection to which allusion has already been [11]made, that the Custom House authorities have no means of ascertaining the real origin of goods entering this country, nor the real destination of goods leaving it. Thus, for example, everyone knows that there is a considerable trade between Great Britain and Switzerland, yet Switzerland has no place at all in the Custom House returns, because, having no seaboard, all her goods must pass through foreign territory, and each package is credited by our Customs House to the port—French, or Belgian, or Dutch—through which the package passes to England. In order, therefore, to provide some check on the above figures, I have averaged in the same way the figures collected by the different foreign countries in their Customs Houses. These foreign and colonial figures have no more title to be considered absolutely accurate than ours, nor do they cover quite the same ground. Their value lies in the rough confirmation they give of the very rough conclusion which we are able to draw from our own figures:—
These figures come from the British Custom House returns and are subject to the issue previously mentioned, that the Custom House authorities have no way of determining the true origin of goods coming into this country or the actual destination of goods leaving it. For instance, it's well-known that there is a significant trade between Great Britain and Switzerland, yet Switzerland doesn't appear at all in the Custom House returns because, lacking a seacoast, all its goods must go through foreign territory. Each package is recorded by our Customs House at the port—whether French, Belgian, or Dutch—through which it passes before reaching England. Therefore, to provide a check on these figures, I have averaged the data collected by various foreign countries at their Customs Houses in the same way. These foreign and colonial figures are no more reliable than ours and do not cover exactly the same scope. Their usefulness lies in the rough validation they provide for the very rough conclusion we can draw from our own figures:—
Trade between the following countries and the United Kingdom.
Ten Years’ Average, in Millions Sterling, according to Foreign and Colonial returns.
Ten Years’ Average, in Millions Sterling, based on Foreign and Colonial returns.
Exports to U.K. | Imports from U.K. | |
---|---|---|
Germany | 29·1 | 26·6 |
France | 38·2 | 22·0 |
United States | 84·6 | 34·2 |
British India[1] | (Rx) 36·4 | (Rx) 60·4 |
Australasia[1] | 28·5 | 27·2 |
British North America[1] | 10·5 | 9·1 |
On the whole, these figures tally more closely with those derived from British returns than might have been expected, and if we make allowance for the fact that the Colonial figures include treasure, it will be seen that both tables show that Germany is our best customer after the United States and India.
Overall, these numbers align more closely with those from British statistics than we might have anticipated. When we consider that the Colonial figures include treasure, it becomes clear that both tables indicate that Germany is our top customer after the United States and India.
THE ALARMIST’S ARTS.
In order to obscure this important fact, while alarming the British public with the notion that English manufacturers are being ruined by German competition, Mr. Williams picks out half a dozen or so items of our imports from Germany, and then exclaims in horror at [12]the amount of “the moneys which in one year have come out of John Bull’s pocket for the purchase of his German-made household goods.” He prefaces his list with the unfortunate remark that the figures are taken from the Custom House returns, “where, at any rate, fancy and exaggeration have no play.” That is so; the fancy and exaggeration are supplied by Mr. Williams. In 1895, he says, Germany sent us linen manufactures to the value of £91,257. He omits, however, to mention that according to the same authority—the Custom House returns—the value of the linen manufactures which we sold to Germany was £273,795. Again, he mentions that we bought from Germany cotton manufactures to the value of £536,000, but he is silent on the fact that our sales to Germany amounted to £1,305,000. He does not even hesitate to pick out such a trumpery item as £11,309 for German embroidery and needlework, but he forgets to tell his readers that the silk manufactures which in the same year we sold to Germany were worth £92,000. In the same way, were it worth doing, one could go through the whole of Mr. Williams’s list, pitting one article against another. It would be labour wasted. The simple fact is that, according to the authority upon which Mr. Williams relies for all the figures just quoted, our total exports to Germany exceed our total imports from Germany, and no trickery with particular items can destroy, though it may obscure, that broad fact.
To hide this important fact while scaring the British public into thinking that English manufacturers are being ruined by German competition, Mr. Williams highlights a handful of our imports from Germany and then exclaims in shock at [12] the amount of “the money that in one year has come out of John Bull’s pocket for the purchase of his German-made household goods.” He starts his list with the unfortunate remark that the figures come from the Custom House returns, “where, at least, fancy and exaggeration have no role.” That’s true; the fancy and exaggeration come from Mr. Williams. In 1895, he states that Germany sent us linen products worth £91,257. However, he fails to mention that according to the same source—the Custom House returns—the value of the linen products we sold to Germany was £273,795. Again, he mentions that we bought cotton products from Germany worth £536,000, but he doesn’t mention that our sales to Germany reached £1,305,000. He even picks a trivial amount of £11,309 for German embroidery and needlework but forgets to tell his readers that the silk products we sold to Germany that same year were worth £92,000. Similarly, if it were worth it, one could go through Mr. Williams’s entire list, comparing one item against another. But that would be a waste of effort. The simple fact is that, according to the authority Mr. Williams relies on for all the figures mentioned, our total exports to Germany exceed our total imports from Germany, and no manipulation of specific items can change, although it may obscure, that overarching fact.
A SELF-DESTRUCTIVE POLICY.
But, for the reasons already explained, in replying to Mr. Williams I do not rely wholly on British figures. It is from the double testimony of British and foreign figures that I deduce the fact that of all our customers Germany is one of the best. The practical moral of this fact is sufficiently obvious. In private business a tradesman does not go out of his way to offend a good customer, even though that customer is also a keen trade competitor. He bestirs himself instead to keep ahead, if possible, of his rival without doing anything to destroy the mutually profitable trade relationship between them. Such palpable considerations of expediency are ignored by our latter-day Protectionists, among whom Mr. Williams deservedly ranks as a leading prophet. Their ambition is to induce the Colonies to discriminate in their tariffs between goods from the Mother Country and goods from foreign countries, admitting the former on favourable terms and penalising the latter. It is avowedly against German [13]competition that this policy is directed, and we are light-heartedly told to risk our trade with one of our best customers on the chance of encouraging trade with Colonies which so far have shown much more eagerness to sell their goods to us than to buy ours. Even supposing that this policy succeeded in destroying the whole of the German export trade to our Colonies and Possessions, the possible gain to us would be very small.
But, for the reasons already explained, when responding to Mr. Williams, I don’t rely solely on British data. It’s from the combined evidence of both British and foreign statistics that I conclude that, among all our customers, Germany is one of the best. The practical lesson here is pretty clear. In private business, a seller doesn’t go out of their way to offend a good customer, even if that customer is also a strong trade competitor. Instead, they work to stay ahead of their rival without harming the beneficial trade relationship between them. Such obvious practicalities are overlooked by today’s Protectionists, among whom Mr. Williams rightly stands out as a leading advocate. Their goal is to persuade the Colonies to have different tariffs for goods from the Mother Country versus goods from foreign countries, allowing the former favorable terms and penalizing the latter. This policy is openly targeted at reducing competition from Germany, and we are carelessly told to gamble our trade with one of our best customers just to encourage trade with Colonies that, so far, have shown much more interest in selling to us than in buying from us. Even if this policy were to completely wipe out German exports to our Colonies and Territories, the potential benefit to us would be very minimal.
Here are the figures of the trade of our three principal Colonies with the United Kingdom and with Germany, derived in each case from the Colonial returns:—
Here are the trade figures of our three main Colonies with the United Kingdom and with Germany, taken from the Colonial records:—
Trade between the following British possessions, the United Kingdom, and Germany.
Ten Years’ Average, in Millions Sterling or Millions Rx.
Ten Years’ Average, in Millions Sterling or Millions Rx.
Imports. | Exports. | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
From Germany. | From U.K. | To Germany. | To U.K. | |
India (Rx) | ·9 | 58·4 | 3·8 | 36·4 |
Australasia | ·9 | 27·4 | ·7 | 28·2 |
Brit. N. America | ·8 | 9·1 | ·1 | 10·1 |
Thus these great groups of Colonies and Dependencies together buy rather less than £3,000,000 worth of German goods against more than £60,000,000 worth of British goods. Yet in order to crush this fractional competition of Germany in neutral markets, in order to scrape up these crumbs that have fallen from our table, we are invited to risk the loss of a direct trade with Germany worth nearly ten times as much as all the crumbs heaped up together.
Thus, these large groups of Colonies and Dependencies together purchase just under £3,000,000 worth of German goods compared to over £60,000,000 worth of British goods. Yet, to eliminate this minor competition from Germany in neutral markets, and to collect these scraps that have fallen from our table, we are encouraged to jeopardize a direct trade with Germany that's nearly ten times more valuable than all those gathered scraps combined.
[14]CHAPTER III.
Picture-Perfect Exaggerations.
It has now been shown, first that there is nothing in the general figures of our import and export trade to warrant the alarmist view expressed in “Made in Germany,” and secondly, that the country whose rivalry is supposed to be ruining us is one of the best of all our customers. What I propose to do in the present chapter is to examine some of the detailed statements in Mr. Williams’s book and to show that in many cases the inferences he draws are so seriously exaggerated as to amount to a positive misrepresentation of the facts. For the purposes of this examination we cannot do better than begin with the chapter which Mr. Williams devotes to chemicals. “The chemical trade,” he tells us, “is the barometer of a nation’s prosperity.... The discomforting significance of the appearance of chemicals in this Black List of mine will, therefore, be at once apparent.” More follows about a “Bottomless pit for capital,” and “Germany seizing the occasion while England has let hers slide,” and so on.
It has now been shown, first that there is nothing in the overall figures of our import and export trade to justify the panic expressed in “Made in Germany,” and secondly, that the country we’re supposedly competing against, which is claimed to be harming us, is actually one of our best customers. In this chapter, I plan to examine some of the detailed claims in Mr. Williams’s book and demonstrate that in many instances the conclusions he draws are so significantly exaggerated that they misrepresent the facts. To start this examination, we can begin with the chapter that Mr. Williams dedicates to chemicals. “The chemical trade,” he tells us, “is the barometer of a nation’s prosperity.... The troubling significance of the presence of chemicals in my Black List will, therefore, be immediately clear.” He goes on about a “Bottomless pit for capital,” and “Germany taking advantage while England has let hers slip,” and so on.
THE ALKALI TRADE.
Thus much for generalities with regard to the chemical trade; now for details. Let us begin with alkalies, which Mr. Williams selects for special comment. He says:—
Thus much for generalities about the chemical trade; now for the specifics. Let's start with alkalies, which Mr. Williams chooses to highlight. He says:—
“Here we are confronted with the damning fact that whereas fresh uses and (owing to the growth of manufactures abroad) fresh markets for alkali products are continually being found, the export of the greatest alkali trader of the world was last year of little more than half its value in the early seventies. Nor do the latest years show any sign of recuperation. The decline since 1891 has been continuous.... There is no question here of an insidious advance. The matter is simply that our trade has gone to the devil, while the Germans are piling up fortunes.”
“Here we face the harsh reality that while new uses and, due to the expansion of manufacturing overseas, new markets for alkali products keep emerging, the export value of the biggest alkali trader in the world last year was barely more than half what it was in the early seventies. The most recent years also show no signs of recovery. The decline since 1891 has been steady.... There’s no doubt about it—our trade has tanked, while the Germans are amassing wealth.”
To the average reader this paragraph would certainly suggest that at least half our trade in alkali had already disappeared, and that the remainder would soon be gone to the devil or elsewhere. I have not verified Mr. Williams’s statement with regard to the early seventies, but it is quite sufficient to point to the course of the trade during the [15]last fifteen years. Both quantities and values are given in the following table:—
To the average reader, this paragraph would definitely imply that at least half of our alkali trade had already vanished, and that the rest would soon be lost for good. I haven't confirmed Mr. Williams's claim about the early seventies, but it's enough to look at the trade trends over the last fifteen years. Both quantities and values are provided in the following table:—
Exports of alkali from the United Kingdom.
1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Quantities—million Cwts. | 6·8 | 6·7 | 6·9 | 6·6 | 6·7 | 6·2 | 6·2 | 6·3 | 6·0 | 6·3 | 6·2 | 5·9 | 5·8 | 6·0 | 6·2 |
Values—million £’s | 2·1 | 2·1 | 2·1 | 2·1 | 2·0 | 1·8 | 1·7 | 1·6 | 1·6 | 2·1 | 2·3 | 2·1 | 1·9 | 1·6 | 1·6 |
These figures show that our alkali trade has been on the whole remarkably steady, except for the slight ups and downs in successive years to which all trades are liable.
These figures indicate that our alkali trade has generally been quite stable, apart from the minor fluctuations in different years that affect all industries.
To show these ups and downs more graphically, I have drawn the following diagram, covering the last ten years’ exports:—
To illustrate these fluctuations more clearly, I've created the following diagram, which covers the export data from the last ten years:—
Diagram of the Amounts of British Alkali Exported.
If the reader will examine this diagram and the more complete figures given above he will be able to see how completely misleading are Mr. Williams’s sensational statements about the British alkali trade. I do not for a moment deny that the German alkali trade has made remarkable progress; I only assert that there is no evidence that “our trade has gone to the devil.”
If the reader looks at this diagram and the more detailed figures provided above, they will see how completely misleading Mr. Williams’s sensational claims about the British alkali trade are. I don’t deny that the German alkali trade has made impressive progress; I just insist that there is no evidence that “our trade has gone to the devil.”
CHEMICAL MANURES.
We turn next to chemical manures. On this subject Mr. Williams remarks:—
We’ll now move on to chemical fertilizers. On this topic, Mr. Williams says:—
“Every farmer will testify to the exceeding value of these stuffs. ’Tis a modern means of fertilising the soil, and there can be no [16]doubt that it has a very great future. Obviously then it is in the highest degree important that England should keep a firm hold of the trade. What, alas! is equally obvious is that England’s grip on it is relaxing, but that Germany is tightening hers.”
“Every farmer will agree on the immense value of these materials. It’s a modern way to fertilize the soil, and there’s no doubt it has a significant future. Therefore, it’s crucial for England to maintain a strong hold on the trade. Unfortunately, it’s also clear that England’s control is slipping while Germany is strengthening its grip.”
It may be true—probably is true—that the industry of Germany is expanding in this as in almost every other branch of the chemical trades. It is also true that the value of chemical manures sent by Germany to this country—still only a quarter of what we send to Germany—is increasing. What is not true is the statement that England’s grip on the trade is “obviously relaxing.” The figures are given below. They do not look much like a relaxed grip.
It might be true—probably is true—that Germany's industry is growing in this and nearly every other area of the chemical trade. It’s also true that the value of chemical fertilizers shipped from Germany to this country—which is still only a quarter of what we send to Germany—is on the rise. What isn't true is the claim that England's hold on the trade is “clearly loosening.” The figures below tell a different story. They definitely don’t look like a loose grip.
Exports of Chemical Fertilizers from the United Kingdom.
In Millions Sterling.
In millions GBP.
1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1·8 | 2·0 | 2·2 | 2·1 | 1·7 | 1·6 | 1·6 | 1·8 | 2·1 | 2·1 | 2·1 | 2·1 | 2·3 | 2·3 | 1·9 |
The figures for the past ten years are illustrated in the following diagram:—
The numbers from the last ten years are shown in the following diagram:—
SOME SUPPOSITIONS ABOUT SALT.
Salt is the next subject to which Mr. Williams turns. What he has to say about it is more picturesque than accurate:—
Salt is the next topic that Mr. Williams discusses. What he has to say about it is more colorful than accurate:—
“The story is worth study. The Salt Union was formed in England in 1889, and the manufacture of salt thereby converted into a big monopoly.... The directors reckoned without their [17]Germany. They can make salt there, too. It is not so good as the Cheshire product, but it is salt, and it is much cheaper than that sold by the Salt Union. When that syndicate’s price went up the German manufacturers pushed into the world market, and that to a purpose which is strikingly illustrated in the case of our great Dependency. India needs much foreign salt, and the Indian ryot needs it cheap: for the salt he uses has to bear the burden of a tax. The natural result followed: German salt to a large extent ousted English from the Indian market.”
“The story is worth studying. The Salt Union was established in England in 1889, creating a major monopoly on salt production.... The directors didn't anticipate their competition from Germany. They can produce salt there as well. It might not be as good as the Cheshire product, but it’s still salt, and it’s much cheaper than what the Salt Union sells. When the syndicate raised their prices, German manufacturers entered the global market, which is clearly demonstrated in our major Dependency. India requires a lot of foreign salt, and the Indian ryot needs it to be affordable because the salt he uses comes with a tax. The obvious result was that German salt largely replaced English salt in the Indian market.”
Most impressive! if only it were true. So far as the world market is concerned, the figures below give no indications of the havoc alleged to have been wrought by the machinations of the Salt Union.
Most impressive! If only it were true. As far as the world market is concerned, the figures below show no signs of the chaos claimed to have been caused by the actions of the Salt Union.
British Salt Exports.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Quantities—thousand tons | 805 | 819 | 899 | 667 | 726 | 671 | 654 | 636 | 769 | 741 |
Values—thousand £’s | 588 | 525 | 486 | 539 | 653 | 596 | 539 | 505 | 604 | 546 |
So far as India is concerned, Mr. Williams is doubly wrong. In the first place, German salt has not “to a large extent ousted English.” During the past five years—it was only in 1889 that the wicked Salt Union came into being—Indian imports of salt have been as follows:—
So far as India is concerned, Mr. Williams is completely mistaken. First of all, German salt has not “to a large extent replaced English.” Over the past five years—it was only in 1889 that the infamous Salt Union was established—Indian salt imports have been as follows:—
India's Salt Imports.
Thousands of Tons.
Thousands of tons.
Years ending March 31st. | From U.K. | From Germany. |
---|---|---|
1891 | 273 | 61 |
1892 | 222 | 103 |
1893 | 241 | 47 |
1894 | 269 | 48 |
1895 | 315 | 82 |
This does not look as if English salt were being ousted by German. In the second place, it is not true that German salt is much cheaper than Cheshire, at any rate so far as the Indian market is concerned. It will be found by reference to the Indian Blue Books that the price of German salt imported into India in 1894-5 works out to 17·6 rupees per ton, and the price of English salt only to 17·0 [18]rupees per ton. In other words, German salt was of the two slightly the dearer. So much for the salt bogey which Mr. Williams had conjured up.
This doesn’t seem like English salt is being replaced by German salt. Additionally, it’s not true that German salt is considerably cheaper than Cheshire, at least when it comes to the Indian market. If you check the Indian Blue Books, you'll see that the price of German salt imported to India in 1894-5 was 17.6 rupees per ton, while the price of English salt was only 17.0 [18]rupees per ton. In other words, German salt was actually slightly more expensive. So much for the salt scare that Mr. Williams brought up.
CHEMICAL DYE STUFFS.
We next pass to chemical dye stuffs. It is undoubtedly true that in this branch of manufacture Germany has gone ahead at a remarkable rate, and it is also probable that some of our manufacturers have allowed themselves to be passed in the race by neglecting the scientific methods which Germans employ. But that is no reason why Mr. Williams should exaggerate his case. In order to magnify the fall in our trade, if such there be, he picks out the year of highest export (1890) and says, Lo! since 1890 our export of dye stuffs has dropped from £530,000 to £473,000. One cannot tell whether this is a real drop in trade, or merely the consequence of a fall in price, but this we do know—that the value of our exports fluctuates largely from year to year, and that 1895 was a good average year. The figures for ten years are given below:—
We now move on to chemical dyes. It's clear that Germany has advanced significantly in this industry, and it's likely that some of our manufacturers have fallen behind by not adopting the scientific methods that Germans use. However, that doesn’t justify Mr. Williams exaggerating his argument. To highlight the decline in our trade, if there is one, he points to the year with the highest exports (1890) and claims, “Look! Since 1890, our dye exports have dropped from £530,000 to £473,000.” It's hard to determine whether this is an actual decline in trade or just a result of falling prices, but one thing is certain: the value of our exports varies greatly from year to year, and 1895 was an average year. The figures for the last ten years are provided below:—
Values of Exported Dyes.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Thousands of £’s | 483 | 499 | 469 | 492 | 531 | 524 | 443 | 452 | 415 | 473 |
FANCY SOAPS AND FANCY ASSERTIONS.
The last point in Mr. Williams’s chapter on the chemical trades with which it is worth while to deal is what he says about soap:—
The last point in Mr. Williams’s chapter on the chemical trades that’s worth discussing is what he says about soap:—
“In the old days, when brown Windsor was a luxury, Englishmen washed with soap of English make; and those who could not afford ‘scented’ cleansed themselves with ‘yellow’ or ‘mottled.’ Thanks (partly) to Continental chemistry, we have changed all that.... The progress of practical chemistry has evidently reached a point at which the manufacture of agreeable toilet soaps at a low figure is possible. But why should this manufacture be so largely in foreign hands? They twit us with our debased fondness for the tub, and they do but add injury to insult when they send us soap for use therein. The Germans—a non-tubbing race—have not yet invaded the English soap market so victoriously as is their wont, though even here the Teuton hand may be discerned by the expert in forged trade marks.”
“In the past, when brown Windsor soap was a luxury, Englishmen used soap made in England; those who couldn’t afford ‘scented’ soap cleaned themselves with ‘yellow’ or ‘mottled’ varieties. Thanks (in part) to European chemistry, we’ve changed all that…. The advancement of practical chemistry has clearly reached a stage where it’s possible to make nice toilet soaps at low prices. But why is so much of this production in foreign hands? They mock us for our cheap obsession with baths, and it’s an added insult when they send us soap to use in them. The Germans—a culture that doesn't traditionally use baths—haven’t yet taken over the English soap market as they usually do, although even here a skilled eye can spot their influence through fake brand labels.”
[19]If this paragraph means anything at all, it means that even in the soap industry our manufacturers are being beaten by the foreigner. To what extent foreign soap is imported into the United Kingdom it is impossible to ascertain, for no separate entry under that head is kept at the Custom House. But from the German Green Books one may learn that in 1895 Germany sent to Great Britain soap valued at £35,700. The amount sent by France may have been as much, and probably the United States also sent us a little. The total export of German soap to all parts of the world in 1895 was valued at £197,000. Now for the British side of the case! As to the total production and consumption of soap in this country, no figures are available, but everyone knows how enormous is the consumption of soap produced by English firms whose names are household words. In addition to their providing for the wants of probably ninety-nine out of a hundred of their own countrymen, our soap manufacturers do an enormous and rapidly growing business abroad.
[19]If this paragraph means anything at all, it suggests that even in the soap industry, our manufacturers are being outperformed by foreign companies. It's impossible to determine the exact amount of foreign soap imported into the United Kingdom, as the Custom House doesn’t keep a separate record for it. However, from the German Green Books, we can see that in 1895, Germany exported soap to Great Britain worth £35,700. France likely sent a similar amount, and the United States probably sent us some too. The total export of German soap worldwide in 1895 was valued at £197,000. Now, let's look at the British side! There are no available figures for the total production and consumption of soap in this country, but it's widely acknowledged how massive the consumption is of soap produced by English firms, whose names are well-known. Besides meeting the needs of nearly everyone in their own country, our soap manufacturers are also doing a huge and rapidly growing business overseas.
Here are the figures:—
Here are the numbers:—
Exports of soap from the United Kingdom.
1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Quantities—thousd. cwts. | 354 | 409 | 392 | 476 | 402 | 427 | 453 | 500 | 493 | 497 | 524 | 541 | 605 | 577 | 728 |
Values—thousd. £’s. | 398 | 458 | 450 | 548 | 472 | 447 | 452 | 482 | 503 | 534 | 571 | 586 | 644 | 621 | 757 |
The following diagram illustrates the almost continuous increase in the value of our soap exports during the last ten years:—
The following diagram shows the nearly constant rise in the value of our soap exports over the past ten years:—
[20]Looking at the above figures, it will be seen that in the last six years alone we have added to our exports a sum greater than the total yet attained by Germany. Is it necessary to say more? What pessimistic madness could have led Mr. Williams to “black-list” such a splendidly-thriving and notoriously profitable industry as this, just because he finds a few thousand hundredweight of foreign soap creeping into the country?
[20]Looking at the figures above, it’s clear that in just the last six years, we’ve increased our exports by an amount greater than what Germany has achieved in total. Do we need to say more? What kind of pessimistic thinking would lead Mr. Williams to "black-list" such a thriving and well-known profitable industry just because he notices a few thousand hundredweight of foreign soap coming into the country?
[21]CHAPTER IV.
More Misinformation.
Attention was called in the last chapter to some of the picturesque exaggerations—to use the mildest possible term—in which Mr. Williams had indulged in dealing with the chemical trades. We now pass to the two chapters which he devotes to the iron and steel and their “daughter trades.” And at the outset let it be clearly understood that I do not for a moment deny that in some of these trades the progress of Germany has been relatively more rapid than our own. A child, if it is to grow at all, must move faster than an adult. An infant four weeks old doubles its age in a month; an adult takes thirty or forty years to double his. Nor can we expect that the whole world will stand still while Great Britain goes on every year adding to her strength. All that I do argue is that the shooting-up of the German infant does us on the whole no harm, and that there is nothing whatever in the figures of our trade to suggest that full-grown England is approaching senile decay.
Attention! was drawn in the last chapter to some of the over-the-top exaggerations—using the mildest term—Mr. Williams made while discussing the chemical industries. Now we move on to the two chapters he dedicates to iron and steel and their “daughter trades.” Let it be clear from the start that I don’t deny that in some of these sectors, Germany has been progressing faster than we have. A child, if it’s going to grow at all, has to move quicker than an adult. A four-week-old baby doubles its age in a month, while an adult takes thirty or forty years to do the same. We can’t expect the entire world to stay still while Great Britain continues to add to her strength every year. What I argue is that the rapid growth of the German ‘infant’ doesn’t harm us overall, and there’s nothing in our trade figures to indicate that fully grown England is nearing old age.
“ICHABOD! OUR TRADE HAS GONE.”
With this general prelude let us turn to what Mr. Williams has to say about the industries connected with iron and steel. He opens by referring to a visit of the English Iron and Steel Institute to Düsseldorf in 1880:—
With this general introduction, let's look at what Mr. Williams has to say about the industries related to iron and steel. He begins by mentioning a visit from the English Iron and Steel Institute to Düsseldorf in 1880:—
“And when the time of feasting and talk and sight-seeing was over, they returned to their native land, and there, in the fulness of time, they perused the fatuous reports of the British Iron Trade Association, which bade them sleep on, sleep ever. And they did as they were bid, until the other day, when they awoke to the fact that their trade was gone.”
“And when the time for feasting, talking, and sightseeing was over, they returned to their home country, and there, eventually, they reviewed the ridiculous reports from the British Iron Trade Association, which told them to keep sleeping, to always sleep. And they did as they were told, until recently when they realized that their trade was gone.”
Another paragraph, headed “Ichabod!” begins:—
Another paragraph, titled “Ichabod!” begins:—
“And now all that is changed. The world’s consumption (of iron) is greater than ever before. Yet our contribution in the years since 1882 has dropped at a rate well nigh unknown in the history of any trade in any land. From the 8,493,287 tons of 1882 pig iron has gone hustling down to the 7,364,745 tons of 1894.”
“And now everything is different. The world’s consumption of iron is higher than ever. Yet our contribution since 1882 has fallen at an unprecedented rate in the history of any trade anywhere. From 8,493,287 tons of pig iron in 1882, it has plummeted to 7,364,745 tons in 1894.”
[22]Truly Mr. Williams is an ingenious person. By picking out the two years 1882 and 1894 he has cunningly obscured the fact that the production of pig iron, as of everything else, is subject to fluctuations, and that 1894, following worse years than itself, will in all probability be followed by better. Here are all the figures for the last fifteen years for which statistics are available, with the German figures set beside them:—
[22]Mr. Williams is truly clever. By highlighting the years 1882 and 1894, he has cleverly hidden the fact that the production of pig iron, like everything else, varies over time, and that after the tough years leading up to 1894, it’s likely that better years will come next. Here are all the figures for the last fifteen years for which statistics are available, along with the German figures shown next to them:—
Pig Iron Production.
In Millions of Tons.
In millions of tons.
1880 | 1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
In the United Kingdom | 7·7 | 8·1 | 8·6 | 8·5 | 7·8 | 7·4 | 7·0 | 7·6 | 8·0 | 8·3 | 7·9 | 7·4 | 6·7 | 7·0 | 7·4 |
In Germany | 2·7 | 2·9 | 3·4 | 3·5 | 3·6 | 3·7 | 3·5 | 4·0 | 4·3 | 4·5 | 4·7 | 4·6 | 4·9 | 5·0 | 5·4 |
These figures show that Germany has without doubt been rapidly gaining upon us, but it is the grossest exaggeration to say that our trade “has gone.” As a matter of fact the output of pig iron in the United Kingdom rose to 7·9 million tons in 1895, and—according to the Economist of November 11th—the estimated output for the present year (1896) is 8·7 million tons. If that figure is realised it will be the largest on record. So much for Mr. Williams’s “Ichabods,” and all his talk of departed glory!
These numbers clearly show that Germany has been quickly catching up to us, but it's a huge exaggeration to claim that our trade “has disappeared.” In reality, the production of pig iron in the United Kingdom increased to 7.9 million tons in 1895, and—according to the Economist from November 11th—the estimated output for this year (1896) is 8.7 million tons. If that number is achieved, it will be the highest on record. So much for Mr. Williams’s “Ichabods,” and all his talk about lost greatness!
COMPARISONS SAID TO BE “ODIOUS.”
Turning to another paragraph headed “Odious Comparisons,” we find—
Turning to another paragraph titled “Odious Comparisons,” we find—
“Under the general heading of iron, wrought and unwrought, the returns of our German exports exhibit a fall from 374,234 tons in 1890 to 295,510 tons in 1895.... Of unenumerated iron manufactures Germany supplied us with 219,841 cwt. in 1890 and with 311,904 cwt. in 1895.”
“Under the general category of iron, both processed and unprocessed, our German export data shows a decrease from 374,234 tons in 1890 to 295,510 tons in 1895.... For unspecified iron products, Germany provided us with 219,841 hundredweight in 1890 and 311,904 hundredweight in 1895.”
Had Mr. Williams taken the trouble to convert the German figures from cwts. into tons he might have found this comparison somewhat less “odious.” If we send Germany 295 thousand tons against 15 thousand tons she sends us, our iron manufacturers have not much to grumble at. But, as a matter of fact, no reliance can be placed upon these particular figures, because, as was pointed [23]out in a previous chapter, much of the stuff that we get from Germany is credited in our Blue Books to Holland and Belgium, and these countries in the same way are debited with a large amount of British stuff that ultimately finds its way to Germany. Exactly the same causes of error vitiate the figures published in the German Green Books, and it may safely be asserted that there is no means of ascertaining with even approximate accuracy how much British iron and steel goes to Germany and how much German steel and iron comes to Great Britain. What can be ascertained is the total export of German iron from Germany to all parts of the world, and the total export of British iron from the United Kingdom to all parts of the world. This comparison, which is one of the best means of testing the relative progress of Great Britain and Germany, is worked out in the following table:—
If Mr. Williams had taken the time to convert the German figures from hundredweights to tons, he might have found this comparison a little less "odious." If we send Germany 295 thousand tons compared to the 15 thousand tons she sends us, our iron manufacturers don’t have much to complain about. However, we can't really rely on these specific figures because, as mentioned in a previous chapter, much of what we receive from Germany is credited in our Blue Books to Holland and Belgium, and these countries are similarly credited with a significant amount of British products that end up in Germany. The same errors affect the figures published in the German Green Books, and it can be confidently stated that there's no way to determine even approximately how much British iron and steel goes to Germany and how much German steel and iron comes to Great Britain. What we can know is the total export of German iron from Germany to all parts of the world and the total export of British iron from the United Kingdom to all parts of the world. This comparison, which is one of the best ways to assess the relative progress of Great Britain and Germany, is detailed in the following table:—
Iron and Steel Products.
In Millions of Tons, Metrical and British.
[A Metrical Ton = 2,204 lb.; a British Ton = 2,240 lb.]
In Millions of Tons, Metric and British.
[A Metric Ton = 2,204 lb.; a British Ton = 2,240 lb.]
1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Total Exports from Germany (Metrical Measure) | ·8 | ·7 | ·8 | ·8 | ·7 | ·7 | ·6 | ·8 | ·8 | ·8 | ·9 |
Total Exports from Belgium (Metrical Measure) | ·4 | ·3 | ·3 | ·4 | ·4 | ·5 | ·4 | ·4 | ·4 | ·4 | ·4 |
Total Exports from United Kingdom (British Meas.) | 3·5 | 3·1 | 3·4 | 4·1 | 4·0 | 4·2 | 4·0 | 3·2 | 2·7 | 2·9 | 2·6 |
The above figures undoubtedly show a distinct decline in British exports of iron and steel, but they also show that that decline is not due to the increased invasion of our own or of neutral markets either by Germany or by Belgium. It is due to a decline which subsequent events have shown to be temporary in the world’s demand for iron and steel goods. Even were this decline permanent, it would not be the fault of our manufacturers, nor—except as a device for reducing their personal expenditure—is there any reason why these gentlemen should sit in sackcloth and ashes.
The figures above clearly indicate a noticeable drop in British exports of iron and steel, but they also show that this decline is not caused by increased competition from Germany or Belgium in our markets or neutral markets. It's due to a decrease that later events have proven to be temporary in the global demand for iron and steel products. Even if this decline were permanent, it wouldn't be the fault of our manufacturers, nor is there any reason for these gentlemen to feel sorry for themselves, except as a way to cut their personal expenses.
STATISTICAL LEGERDEMAIN.
We pass to the subject of shipbuilding. Mr. Williams is good enough to admit that England is actually at the head of the shipbuilding trade. But having made this admission, a pang of regret [24]comes over him, and he tries to show that he is justified in putting even the British shipbuilding trade on his “black list.” This is his argument:—
We move on to the topic of shipbuilding. Mr. Williams is kind enough to acknowledge that England is currently leading in the shipbuilding industry. However, after making this acknowledgment, a wave of regret washes over him, and he attempts to justify placing even the British shipbuilding trade on his “black list.” Here is his argument:—
“In 1883 the total tonnage built in the United Kingdom was 892,216; in 1893 it reached only 584,674; in 1894, ’tis true, it rose to 669,492, but this is much below the total even of 1892, which was 801,548.”
“In 1883, the total tonnage built in the United Kingdom was 892,216; in 1893, it only reached 584,674; in 1894, it did increase to 669,492, but that’s still far below the total from 1892, which was 801,548.”
Again one can only admire Mr. Williams’s ingenuity. Reading his paragraph, who would dream that between the years so skilfully selected for comparison the trade had experienced an enormous drop, and afterwards, to all intents and purposes, completely recovered itself; that then a smaller drop had occurred, and that this in turn was being fast made good? The best way to expose the above piece of statistical legerdemain is to give without further comment the whole of the figures for the past fifteen years. They will be found in the following table. With figures such as these before him—and they must have been before him—it is astounding that Mr. Williams should have ventured to put shipbuilding on his black list.
Once again, one can only admire Mr. Williams's cleverness. After reading his paragraph, who would guess that between the years he so skillfully chose for comparison, the industry had seen a massive decline, and then, for all practical purposes, fully recovered? Then there was a smaller decline, which was also in the process of bouncing back? The best way to reveal this piece of statistical manipulation is to present, without further comment, all the figures from the past fifteen years. They can be found in the following table. With such figures in front of him—and they must have been in front of him—it’s incredible that Mr. Williams dared to place shipbuilding on his blacklist.
15 Years of British Shipbuilding.
Total Output of British and Irish Yards.
In Thousands of Tons.
Total Output of British and Irish Yards.
In Thousands of Tons.
1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
609 | 783 | 892 | 588 | 441 | 331 | 377 | 574 | 855 | 813 | 809 | 801 | 585 | 669 | 648 |
These figures may be illustrated as follows:—
These figures can be shown as follows:—
[25]SHIPS BUILT FOR FOREIGNERS.
But his perverse ingenuity does not end with the paragraph quoted. A few lines lower down he says:—
But his twisted creativity doesn’t stop with the paragraph quoted. A few lines down, he says:—
“All these figures include vessels built for foreigners as well as those for home and the Colonies. The year in which we built most vessels for other nations was 1889, when we supplied them with 183,224 tons. The four following years showed a progressive decrease, getting down as low as 89,386 tons in 1893; and though 1894 showed an increase to 94,876 tons, their upward movement was slight compared with the successive decreases of the previous years.”
“All these figures include ships built for foreign countries as well as those for the home country and the Colonies. The year when we built the most ships for other nations was 1889, when we supplied them with 183,224 tons. The four years that followed showed a steady decline, dropping as low as 89,386 tons in 1893; and although 1894 saw an increase to 94,876 tons, the upward trend was minimal compared to the successive decreases of the previous years.”
The man who wrote these sentences obviously intended to convey to his readers the impression that our trade in the building of ships for foreign purchasers was a declining trade. That impression is false, and it is a little hard to understand how Mr. Williams could fail to see its falsity. The following figures show—what to most persons would be sufficiently obvious on reflection—that the tonnage of ships launched at our great yards varies largely from year to year. To pick out the year 1889, as Mr. Williams does, and declare that since that year there has been a decline in our sales to foreigners, is as grossly unfair as it would be, on the other hand, to pick out the year 1885, and say that since then there had been a fourfold increase.
The guy who wrote these lines clearly wanted to give his readers the impression that our business of building ships for foreign buyers is on the decline. That impression is wrong, and it's a bit surprising that Mr. Williams didn't notice this. The following figures show—what would seem obvious to most people upon reflection—that the amount of ships launched at our major yards varies quite a bit from year to year. Highlighting the year 1889, like Mr. Williams does, and claiming that there has been a drop in our sales to foreigners since that year is just as unfair as picking 1885 and saying there’s been a fourfold increase since then.
Ships We Build for Foreigners.
Thousands of Tons.
Thousands of tons.
1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
108 | 116 | 124 | 91 | 36 | 39 | 70 | 91 | 183 | 161 | 139 | 109 | 89 | 95 | 128 |
WAR-SHIPS FOR FOREIGNERS.
The above figures include war-ships as well as merchant-ships built by us for foreigners, and, noting this fact, Mr. Williams is distressed to find what he calls a drop in our output of foreign war-ships. He writes:—
The above figures include warships as well as merchant ships built by us for foreign countries, and, noting this fact, Mr. Williams is upset to see what he calls a decline in our production of foreign warships. He writes:—
“Still more remarkable is the drop in our supply of foreign war-ships from 12,877 tons in 1874 to 2,483 in 1894.”
“Even more surprising is the decline in our supply of foreign warships from 12,877 tons in 1874 to 2,483 in 1894.”
What is even more remarkable still is the fact that Mr. Williams should have dared to put such a statement before the public, knowing, as he must have known, how completely it misrepresents the truth. I wonder what he would have said of me if I had spoken of the remarkable [26]growth in our output of foreign war-ships as evidenced by an increase from 14 tons in 1876 to 4,152 tons in 1895! Yet this statement would have been every bit as justifiable as his own. The whole truth of the matter of course is, that such an industry as the construction of foreign war-ships must vary enormously from year to year, and a comparison between any two single years can prove nothing, except the folly or the mala fides of the person who makes it. In order that the reader may see for himself the source from which Mr. Williams drew his “remarkable” statement, I append all the figures since 1870:—
What’s even more surprising is that Mr. Williams had the courage to present such a statement to the public, fully aware, as he certainly must have been, of how completely it distorts the truth. I wonder what he would have thought of me if I had mentioned the remarkable [26]growth in our foreign warship production, shown by an increase from 14 tons in 1876 to 4,152 tons in 1895! Yet this statement would have been just as justified as his own. The whole truth is that an industry like foreign warship construction can vary significantly from year to year, and comparing any two individual years proves nothing but the foolishness or mala fides of whoever makes the comparison. To help the reader see the source of Mr. Williams’ “remarkable” statement, I’m including all the figures since 1870:—
Warships Built for Foreigners.
Years. | Tons. | Years. | Tons. | Years. | Tons. |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
1870 | 970 | 1879 | 716 | 1888 | 1,899 |
1871 | 80 | 1880 | 385 | 1889 | 726 |
1872 | 40 | 1881 | 5,338 | 1890 | 3,437 |
1873 | 280 | 1882 | 447 | 1891 | 300 |
1874 | 12,877 | 1883 | 270 | 1892 | 2,792 |
1875 | 12,280 | 1884 | 2,339 | 1893 | 2,471 |
1876 | 14 | 1885 | 5,462 | 1894 | 2,483 |
1877 | 3,435 | 1886 | 840 | 1895 | 4,152 |
1878 | 2,482 | 1887 | 3,966 |
MACHINERY AND STEAM ENGINES.
It is becoming monotonous to follow Mr. Williams in detail through his ingenious misrepresentations. I will therefore hastily pass over the many pages which he devotes to “black-listing” sundry iron and steel manufactures. His black list, which includes “steam engines,” “other machinery,” and “tools and implements” of industry, is arrived at by giving only the figures for 1890 onwards and ignoring the preceding years. The unfairness of this procedure need not be again pointed out. The figures for a decade, or for a longer period, show that trade moves up and down, and that a depression in one year or group of years is succeeded by an elevation a few years later. Throughout his book, in instances too numerous to be especially mentioned, Mr. Williams has persistently ignored this obvious fact. Again and again he has picked out years favourable to his argument, while even a cursory glance at a series of years must have shown him that the truth was the exact opposite to his representation of the facts. Here are the figures for the last fourteen years, showing the relative progress of Great Britain and Germany in the export of all kinds of [27]machinery, including the domestic sewing machine and the locomotive engine.
It’s getting tedious to follow Mr. Williams in detail through his clever misrepresentations. So, I’ll quickly skip over the many pages he spends “black-listing” various iron and steel manufacturers. His blacklist, which includes “steam engines,” “other machinery,” and “tools and implements” of industry, is based only on figures from 1890 onward, while ignoring the years prior. The unfairness of this method doesn’t need to be pointed out again. The figures for a decade or longer show that trade fluctuates, and a downturn in one year or set of years is typically followed by an upturn a few years later. Throughout his book, in too many instances to mention, Mr. Williams has consistently overlooked this obvious fact. Time and again, he has highlighted years that support his argument, while even a quick look at a series of years should have shown him that the reality was the exact opposite of what he presented. Here are the figures for the last fourteen years, showing the relative progress of Great Britain and Germany in the export of all kinds of [27] machinery, including domestic sewing machines and locomotive engines.
Exports of All Types of Machinery.
(Including Steam Engines and Sewing Machines.)
In Millions Sterling.
(Including Steam Engines and Sewing Machines.)
In Millions of Pounds.
1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
From United Kingdom | 11·9 | 13·5 | 13·2 | 11·2 | 10·2 | 11·1 | 12·9 | 15·3 | 16·4 | 15·7 | 13·9 | 13·8 | 14·2 | 15·0 |
From Germany | 3·1 | 3·3 | 2·8 | 2·5 | 2·4 | 2·6 | 2·8 | 3·1 | 3·3 | 3·3 | 3·1 | 3·2 | 3·9 | — |
TEXTILES.
To our textile industries Mr. Williams has devoted a chapter which is one of the gloomiest in his book. Let it be at once admitted that we are no longer the monopolists of the textile industries of the world to the extent to which we once were. Nor could any sane man expect that we should for ever retain our former exceptional position. Other nations move as well as we. They buy the machines which we invent and make; they employ our foremen to teach them the arts we have acquired, and in time they learn to weave and spin for themselves instead of coming to us for every yard of cloth or every pound of yarn. This relative advancement of foreign nations and, too, of our own Colonies and Dependencies was and is inevitable. It is part of the general industrialization of the world. But what we have to note with satisfaction is that this process has involved little or no positive loss to us, that we are still far ahead of all other nations in the production of textiles, and that even in those cases, notably the woollen industry, where our export has fallen off we can point to an increased demand by our own people for the goods we manufacture. It is not in this spirit that Mr. Williams will look at any British industry. Even where he has a fairly good case, he spoils it by gross exaggeration and by the suppression of counterbalancing facts.
Mr. Williams has dedicated a chapter to our textile industries, and it's one of the darkest in his book. We must admit that we are no longer the world’s sole leaders in textile production like we used to be. No sensible person would expect us to hold onto that unique position forever. Other countries are making progress just like we are. They purchase the machines we create; they hire our foremen to teach them the skills we've mastered, and eventually, they learn to weave and spin for themselves instead of relying on us for every yard of fabric or every pound of yarn. This relative progress of foreign nations, as well as our own colonies and dependencies, was and is unavoidable. It’s part of the overall industrialization of the world. However, what we can take comfort in is that this process has not resulted in any significant loss for us; we still lead all other nations in textile production, and even in cases like the woolen industry where our exports have declined, we can see an increased demand from our own people for the products we make. Mr. Williams does not view any British industry in this way. Even when he has a valid point, he undermines it with gross exaggeration and by leaving out important facts that could balance his claims.
COTTON YARN AND THE PRICE THEREOF.
Dealing first with cotton, he follows his usual device of picking out bumper years, and then exclaiming, “See what a fall since then!” he goes on:—
Dealing first with cotton, he uses his usual tactic of highlighting great years and then exclaiming, “Look at how much it has dropped since then!” He continues:—
“A consideration of moment is that this decline in values does not signify a corresponding decline in quantities. On the contrary, in yarn manufactures, with an actual increase in the exported weight, there is a decrease in the cash return. Thus in bleached [28]and dyed cotton yarn and twist there was a qualitative rise between 1893 and 1895 from 36,105,100 lb. to 40,425,600 lb., with a fall in the value thereof from £1,862,880 to £1,832,477. Between 1865 and 1895 the average price per lb. of cotton yarn declined from 23·98d. to less than 8·85d. ’Tis a good enough explanation of the vanishing dividends, the low wages, the lack of enterprise and initiative.”
A key point to note is that this decline in values doesn’t mean there’s a similar drop in quantities. On the contrary, in yarn manufacturing, while the exported weight actually increased, the cash returns fell. For example, in bleached and dyed cotton yarn and twist, there was a rise in quantity from 36,105,100 lb. to 40,425,600 lb. between 1893 and 1895, but the value dropped from £1,862,880 to £1,832,477. Between 1865 and 1895, the average price per lb. of cotton yarn dropped from 23.98d. to less than 8.85d. This is a good explanation for the shrinking dividends, the low wages, and the lack of enterprise and initiative.
Mr. Williams must either be very innocent, or expect his readers to be. He apparently has forgotten that the most important element in the price of cotton yarn is the price of the raw cotton out of which the yarn is spun. What the Lancashire spinner cares about is not the absolute price of yarn or the absolute price of raw cotton, but the margin between the two. If that be satisfactory his profit is secure. Therefore, the mere statement that the prices of yarn have fallen so much in so many years, by itself explains nothing. As a matter of fact the price of cotton yarn has followed, and continues to follow, very closely the price of raw cotton, the spinners’ margin remaining fairly constant. It is useless to go back to 1865, when the most careless economist might surely have remembered that the American war made cotton dear, and machines were less efficient than they now are. But I have taken the trouble to work out for the last ten years, from figures kindly supplied by the Manchester Chamber of Commerce, the average margin between the price of a pound of standard yarn (32’s twist) and a pound of standard cotton (middling American). The result shows that while the spinners’ margin was slightly less in 1895 than in 1893, it stood at practically the same figure as in 1892 and 1894, and was a good deal higher than it had been in 1886. So that here again there is no real foundation for Mr. Williams’s statement.
Mr. Williams must either be very naïve or expect his readers to be. He seems to have forgotten that the most important factor in the price of cotton yarn is the price of the raw cotton used to make the yarn. What matters to the Lancashire spinner isn’t the actual price of yarn or the price of raw cotton, but the difference between the two. If that difference is good enough, his profit is secure. So, simply saying that yarn prices have dropped over the years doesn’t explain much. In fact, the price of cotton yarn has closely followed the price of raw cotton, with the spinners’ margin staying pretty consistent. It’s pointless to reference 1865, as even the most careless economist should remember that the American Civil War made cotton expensive and machines were less efficient back then. However, I took the time to analyze the last ten years using figures provided by the Manchester Chamber of Commerce, looking at the average margin between the price of a pound of standard yarn (32’s twist) and a pound of standard cotton (middling American). The results show that while the spinners’ margin was slightly lower in 1895 than in 1893, it was nearly the same as in 1892 and 1894, and much higher than it had been in 1886. So, once again, there’s no real basis for Mr. Williams’s statement.
THE DAYS OF BIG FORTUNES.
It is undoubtedly true that big fortunes are no longer made in the cotton trade, or at any rate not so rapidly as in the days when cotton spinners waxed fat on the labour of tiny children who had to be flogged to keep them awake. It is also true that many joint-stock spinning companies have paid no dividends, and that many have collapsed altogether. But those who know anything of Lancashire know that a very large number of these companies were not started in response to any real increase in the demand for cotton goods, nor on account of any genuine anticipation of such an increase. They were started, as a good many companies are started in a county south of Lancashire, in order to put money into the promoters’ pockets. [29]Having served that purpose they were allowed quietly to collapse. Lancashire does not miss them. That the cotton trade, as a whole, is in a healthy condition in spite of these manœuvres of the company-promoter will be seen from the figures relating to cotton in the following table, and from the diagram that illustrates them:—
It’s definitely true that large fortunes aren’t made in the cotton trade anymore, or at least not as quickly as they were back when cotton spinners profited from the labor of young children who had to be beaten to stay awake. It’s also true that many joint-stock spinning companies have failed to pay dividends, and that many have completely gone under. But anyone familiar with Lancashire knows that a significant number of these companies weren’t established due to a real increase in demand for cotton goods, nor were they based on any genuine expectation of such an increase. They were set up, like many companies in a county south of Lancashire, to benefit the promoters financially. [29]Once they served that purpose, they were allowed to quietly collapse. Lancashire doesn’t miss them. The overall health of the cotton trade, despite these actions by the company promoters, will be evident from the figures related to cotton in the following table, and from the diagram that illustrates them:—
Fabrics.
Yarns. Ten Years’ Exports. In Millions of Lbs.
Stories. Exports Over Ten Years. In Millions of Pounds.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Cotton | 254 | 251 | 256 | 252 | 258 | 245 | 233 | 207 | 236 | 252 |
Jute | 31 | 24 | 27 | 34 | 34 | 33 | 26 | 29 | 35 | 35 |
Linen | 16 | 16 | 15 | 14 | 15 | 15 | 15 | 16 | 16 | 17 |
Silk | ·6 | ·6 | ·6 | ·8 | ·8 | 1·0 | ·7 | ·8 | ·8 | ·7 |
Woollen | 46 | 40 | 43 | 45 | 41 | 41 | 45 | 50 | 53 | 61 |
Fabric, etc. Ten Years’ Exports. In Millions of Yards.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Cotton | 4,850 | 4,904 | 5,038 | 5,001 | 5,125 | 4,912 | 4,873 | 4,652 | 5,312 | 5,033 |
Jute | 216 | 244 | 232 | 265 | 274 | 284 | 266 | 265 | 233 | 255 |
Linen | 164 | 164 | 177 | 181 | 184 | 159 | 171 | 158 | 156 | 204 |
Silk | 7 | 7 | 8 | 10 | 10 | 6 | 6 | 6 | 6 | 7 |
Woollen[2] | 273 | 281 | 264 | 268 | 253 | 223 | 213 | 194 | 168 | 242 |
The figures for cotton piece goods may be illustrated as follows:—
The statistics for cotton fabric can be shown like this:—
[30]LINEN, SILK, AND WOOLLENS.
So much for cotton! With regard to linen, it is unnecessary to follow in detail what Mr. Williams says, for he himself admits that the decline which has taken place since the ’sixties is largely due to a change in fashion, jute and cotton goods taking the place of linen. In the last decade, however, as will be seen from the above table, the linen industry has held its own. With regard to silk, the figures show that there is no cause for serious alarm. In woollens, on the other hand, there is apparently better ground for Mr. Williams’s mourning. The table on the preceding page points to a distinct downward tendency in our export of woollen manufactures, a tendency which has been only partly checked by the inflation of 1895. If this were the whole truth about our woollen trade, it might be conceded that here at any rate Mr. Williams had made out his case. But it is not the whole truth. Almost pari passu with this decline in our export of woollens, which began some twenty years back, there has been a steady increase in the consumption of our woollen manufactures by our own people, and this increased home demand has more than made good the decline in the foreign demand.
So much for cotton! When it comes to linen, there's no need to go into detail about what Mr. Williams says, since he admits that the decline since the '60s is mainly due to changing fashion, with jute and cotton products replacing linen. However, in the last decade, as shown in the table above, the linen industry has maintained its position. Regarding silk, the figures indicate no serious cause for concern. In the case of woolens, though, there seems to be a stronger reason for Mr. Williams's sadness. The table on the previous page shows a clear downward trend in our woolen exports, a trend that has only been partially mitigated by the inflation of 1895. If this were the complete picture of our woolen trade, it might be agreed that Mr. Williams has made his point. But that's not the whole story. Almost simultaneously with the decline in our woolen exports, which started about twenty years ago, there has been a steady rise in the consumption of our woolen products by our own population, and this increased domestic demand has more than compensated for the drop in foreign demand.
THE EXPANSION OF OUR WOOLLEN INDUSTRY.
The proof of this statement will be seen in the following figures. During the five years, 1870 to 1874, the average yearly import of raw wool into the United Kingdom was 342,000,000 lb.; during the years 1890-94 the average was 475,000,000. That gives the measure of the enormous increase in the amount of the raw material worked up by our woollen manufacturers. Take next the question of the amount of labour employed. Unfortunately, there are no official figures since 1890, but that year will serve. Here is the comparison:—
The proof of this statement will be shown in the following figures. During the five years from 1870 to 1874, the average yearly import of raw wool into the United Kingdom was 342,000,000 lb.; during the years 1890-94, the average was 475,000,000 lb. That shows the huge increase in the amount of raw material processed by our woollen manufacturers. Next, let's look at the amount of labor employed. Unfortunately, there are no official figures since 1890, but that year will work for our comparison:—
People Employed in Wool and Worsted Mills.
Men. | Women. | Children. | |
---|---|---|---|
1870 | 94,000 | 116,000 | 24,000 |
1890 | 118,000 | 156,000 | 23,000 |
These figures are doubly satisfactory, for they point, first, to a large increase in the adult labour employed; and, secondly, to a small but gratifying decrease in child labour.
These numbers are really encouraging because they show, first, a significant increase in the number of adults working; and second, a small but satisfying decrease in child labor.
[31]THE NATURE OF GERMAN COMPETITION.
To still further reassure politicians and others who have been alarmed by Mr. Williams’s book, I may quote two passages from lectures on German competition recently delivered in the West Riding. The first is from a lecture by Professor Beaumont, delivered in the Yorkshire College in October last. From the report in the Leeds Mercury of October 10th, I take the following:—
To further reassure politicians and others who were worried by Mr. Williams’s book, I can quote two passages from lectures on German competition recently given in West Riding. The first is from a lecture by Professor Beaumont, which took place at the Yorkshire College last October. From the report in the Leeds Mercury dated October 10th, I’ll share the following:—
“In the woven fabrics imported from Germany we have examples of the standard of workmanship attained in German mills. These textures chiefly comprise low mantle cloths and cloakings, and limited quantities of dress stuffs composed of mixed materials, showing that almost invariably it was the price which caused these goods to sell in British markets. Viewed from this standpoint, there is an impregnable argument in favour of our industrial pursuits; for in all classes of fancy fabrics of a high quality, whether in woollen, worsted, cotton, linen, or jute materials, the manufacturers of the United Kingdom have scarcely felt the effects of German competition.”
“In the woven fabrics imported from Germany, we see examples of the high-quality craftsmanship achieved in German mills. These fabrics mainly include low mantle cloths and cloakings, along with small amounts of dress materials made from mixed fibers, indicating that the price was almost always the reason these goods were popular in British markets. From this perspective, there’s a strong argument in favor of our industries; because in all types of high-quality fancy fabrics, whether made from wool, worsted, cotton, linen, or jute, manufacturers in the United Kingdom have hardly been affected by German competition.”
My second quotation is from a lecture delivered by Mr. Swire Smith, of Keighley, at the Bradford Technical College, and reported in the Bradford Observer of November 27th last:—
My second quote is from a lecture given by Mr. Swire Smith from Keighley at the Bradford Technical College, reported in the Bradford Observer on November 27th last year:—
“Those who tell us that our English worsted industry is being ruined by the competition of Germany, must be unaware of the fact that the German worsteds, whose increasing exports were creating such alarm among the Fair-traders, are mainly composed of yarns ‘made in Bradford.’ Indeed, Bradford afforded a concrete example of the effect of German competition, for it would be difficult to say which country had benefited most by it. The export of woollen, worsted, and alpaca yarns to Germany in the average of the following periods of years amounted in 1880-85 to 41,500,000 lb. per year; 1890-95, to 63,800,000 lb. per year; and 1895, to 78,900,000 lb. Bradford had been the greatest contributor to German success in the weaving of worsteds and alpacas, and Germany had been the greatest contributor to the success of the spinning industry of Bradford by buying its yarns. To put a tax on German worsteds that would shut them out of England would stop the sale of Bradford yarns in Germany.”
“Those who claim that our English worsted industry is being ruined by competition from Germany must not realize that the German worsteds, whose rising exports have caused such concern among Fair-traders, are primarily made from yarns ‘made in Bradford.’ In fact, Bradford serves as a clear example of the impact of German competition, as it’s hard to determine which country has benefited the most from it. The export of wool, worsted, and alpaca yarns to Germany averaged 41,500,000 lb. per year from 1880-85; 63,800,000 lb. per year from 1890-95; and 78,900,000 lb. in 1895. Bradford has been the biggest contributor to German success in weaving worsteds and alpacas, and Germany has been the biggest contributor to Bradford's spinning industry by purchasing its yarns. Imposing a tax on German worsteds that would block them from entering England would also halt the sale of Bradford yarns in Germany.”
THE “PERCENTAGE TRICK.”
That is enough about woollens. About jute a couple of sentences will suffice. In order to make the facts in this trade look worse than they are—there is nothing really bad about them—Mr. Williams first places German figures in marks side by side with English figures in [32]pounds sterling, and then plays what can only be called the “percentage trick.” The German increase in eleven years, he says, is at the rate of 1,100 per cent., while the British is only 19 per cent. Remarkable! Yet Mr. Williams might have discovered from his own figures, if he had only taken the trouble to turn marks into pounds, that the German increase in eleven years was only £107,000, while the British increase was £412,000. In other words, our increase was almost four times as great as Germany’s, and our total is now £2,588,000, against their total of £117,000. Exactly the same percentage trick is employed by Mr. Williams in comparing German and English trade with Japan. In this case there is also an important error in his arithmetic; but let that pass. The trick consists in deluding the uncritical reader into the belief that German trade with Japan is increasing faster than our own, whereas during the period selected by himself for comparison our increase has been almost exactly double the German increase. It is by devices such as these that Mr. Williams has succeeded in filling his pages with gloomy statements and gloomier prophecies. To track him further along his tortuous path would be profitless. “Here ends,” he writes at the close of one of his most despairing and most deceptive chapters, “the tale of England’s industrial shame.” If candour should be an essential to fair controversy, there is other shame than England’s to be ended.
That's enough about wool. A couple of sentences about jute will do. To make this trade look worse than it is—there's really nothing bad about it—Mr. Williams first lines up German figures in marks next to English figures in [32] pounds sterling, and then uses what can only be called the “percentage trick.” He claims that the German increase over eleven years is 1,100 percent, while the British is only 19 percent. Impressive! Yet, Mr. Williams could have figured out from his own data, if he had just bothered to convert marks into pounds, that the German increase in eleven years was only £107,000, while the British increase was £412,000. In other words, our increase was nearly four times greater than Germany’s, and our total is now £2,588,000, compared to their total of £117,000. He uses the same percentage trick when comparing German and English trade with Japan. In this instance, there's also a significant error in his math, but let's skip that. The trick is designed to mislead the uncritical reader into thinking that German trade with Japan is growing faster than ours, when in fact, during the specified period, our increase has been almost exactly double that of Germany. It’s through tricks like these that Mr. Williams has managed to fill his pages with depressing statements and even gloomier predictions. Following his twisted argument further would be pointless. “Here ends,” he writes at the end of one of his most despairing and misleading chapters, “the tale of England’s industrial shame.” If honesty should be essential in fair debate, there are other shames besides England’s that need to be acknowledged.
[33]CHAPTER V.
Our Increasing Wealth.
Having now shown, both generally and in detail, how absolutely void of foundation are many of the most gloomy statements in “Made in Germany,” we can dismiss Mr. Williams and his fanciful forebodings, and examine instead the direct and abundant evidence of the growing prosperity of our country. The first point to notice is the immense development of our shipping industry. In the last quarter of a century the tonnage of shipping engaged in foreign trade entering our ports has more than doubled, and this increase has been steady and persistent, with no retrogression worth noticing in any year. But that is not all. Twenty years ago the proportion of British ships engaged in this foreign trade of ours was only 67 per cent. of the total; it is now well over 72 per cent. In the same period the number of tons of shipping per hundred of the population, taking entries and clearances together, has risen from 130 tons to 200 tons. No other country can point to such figures. Germany, starting from small beginnings, has improved rapidly, but her totals are insignificant compared with our own. Only 43 per cent. of her foreign trade is carried in her own ships, as against nearly 73 per cent. in our case, while per hundred of the population the shipping to and from her ports is less than a quarter of ours. If we turn to France we find that while the total shipping to and from French ports has increased as rapidly as with us, the proportion carried under the French flag has appreciably fallen. In the case of the United States there has been a still greater fall. Twenty years ago 33 per cent. of the foreign trade of the United States was carried in United States ships, now the proportion is only 23 per cent. The following table shows the growth of shipping of all kinds to and from British ports:—
Having now demonstrated, both generally and in detail, how completely unfounded many of the bleak statements in “Made in Germany” are, we can ignore Mr. Williams and his fanciful predictions, and instead look at the clear and abundant evidence of our country's growing prosperity. The first thing to note is the massive growth of our shipping industry. In the last 25 years, the tonnage of ships involved in foreign trade entering our ports has more than doubled, and this increase has been consistent and steady, with no significant declines in any year. But that’s not all. Twenty years ago, British ships made up only 67 percent of this foreign trade; now, it’s over 72 percent. During the same period, the amount of shipping per 100 people, considering entries and clearances, has grown from 130 tons to 200 tons. No other country can claim such figures. Germany, starting from a small base, has improved quickly, but her totals are minor when compared to ours. Only 43 percent of her foreign trade is carried by her own ships, compared to nearly 73 percent for us, while the shipping going to and from her ports per 100 people is less than a quarter of our amount. When we look at France, we find that although the total shipping to and from French ports has increased as rapidly as ours, the share carried under the French flag has noticeably declined. The United States has seen an even greater drop. Twenty years ago, 33 percent of the U.S. foreign trade was carried in American ships, but now that figure is only 23 percent. The following table shows the growth of shipping of all kinds to and from British ports:—
[34]Twenty-Five Years of Shipping To and From Ports in the United Kingdom.
Entries and Clearances together, in Millions of Tons.
Entries and Clearances combined, in millions of tons.
Average of Five Years. | International Trade. | Coastal Shipping. | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Under British Flag. | Total. | In this Trade practically all the Shipping is British. | ||
1870-74 | 28 | 42 | 38 | |
1875-79 | 35 | 51 | 46 | |
1880-84 | 43 | 61 | 50 | |
1885-89 | 49 | 67 | 54 | |
1890-94 | 55 | 75 | 58 | |
Year 1895 | 59 | 81 | 61 |
In order to further compare our progress with the progress of other countries the following table has been prepared to show the relative position of the principal countries now and twenty years ago. If we consider merely the rate of progress, the German percentage of increase is undoubtedly better than ours. But in national life, as in individual, it is not percentages but amounts that are important, and the table shows that while Germany has added 6,000,000 tons to her shipping, we have added 27,000,000 tons to ours. As long as anything similar to that proportion is maintained we have no need to fear German rivalry.
To better compare our progress with that of other countries, the following table has been created to show the relative standings of the main countries now and twenty years ago. If we look only at the rate of progress, Germany’s percentage increase is definitely better than ours. However, in national life, just like in personal life, it’s not percentages but actual amounts that matter, and the table reveals that while Germany has added 6,000,000 tons to its shipping, we’ve added 27,000,000 tons to ours. As long as we maintain a similar ratio, we have no reason to worry about competing with Germany.
UK and International Shipping.
In Millions of Tons.
In millions of tons.
Average Annual Entries and Clearances. | 1870-74 | 1890-94 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
British tonnage | engaged | in the | foreign trade of | the U.K. | 28 | 55 |
German | " | " | " | Germany | 4 | 10 |
French | " | " | " | France | 5 | 9 |
United States | " | " | " | the U.S. | 7 | 9 |
The figures for 1890-94 may be illustrated diagrammatically as on opposite page.
The numbers for 1890-94 can be shown visually on the opposite page.
It must be noticed that this comparison takes no account of the enormous carrying trade done by this country for foreign countries or British Colonies trading with one another; nor are there figures available for showing how in this matter we compare with our rivals. The figures, if they existed, would show that in this international industry Great Britain is first, and the rest of the world nowhere.
It should be noted that this comparison doesn’t consider the huge amount of trade this country conducts for foreign countries or British colonies trading among themselves; nor are there any available figures to show how we stack up against our competitors in this regard. If those figures existed, they would reveal that in this global industry, Great Britain is at the top, and the rest of the world is far behind.
[35] | ||
Before passing to another point it is worth while to call attention to the enormous development of the coasting branch of our shipping trade, as shown in the figures given above. This branch of shipping is really of the nature of internal traffic, as distinguished from foreign trade. That it should have increased so steadily and so rapidly is by itself a striking proof of the commercial activity of the country.
Before moving on to another point, it's worth noting the significant growth of the coasting sector of our shipping trade, as indicated by the figures mentioned above. This part of shipping is essentially a form of internal traffic, in contrast to foreign trade. The fact that it has steadily and quickly increased is clear evidence of the country’s commercial activity.
THE DEVELOPMENT OF OUR RAILWAYS.
Proof even more convincing is apparent in the enormous development of our railway system. It is difficult to know from which side first to approach the tremendous figures in which this development is portrayed. Taking, at hazard, mileage first, we find within the last twenty-five years an increase of 6,000 miles in our railway system—namely, from 15,000 in 1870, to 21,000 in 1895. Of this increase, 2,000 miles are due to the last decade. Looking next at the capital expenditure, we find that in the ten years from 1885 to 1895 the total capital of the various railway companies of the United Kingdom rose from 816 millions sterling to 1,001 millions. Part of this immense increase was, it is true, only nominal, being due to consolidation of stock, etc. But when all allowance has been made on that score, we are left with a real net increase in the ten years of 170 millions [36]sterling. During the same period of ten years the receipts from passenger traffic rose from 30 millions sterling to 37 millions, while the receipts from goods traffic rose from 36 to 44 millions. In the last quarter of a century the number of passengers carried by the railways, exclusive of season-ticket holders, has risen from 337 millions to 930 millions. Were it possible to record the number of journeys made by season-ticket holders, we should obtain an even more striking picture of the development of passenger traffic on our railways. Such figures as are available are given in the next table, and illustrated by the accompanying diagrams:—
Proof that's even more convincing can be seen in the huge expansion of our railway system. It’s hard to know how to approach the impressive statistics that showcase this growth. If we randomly start with mileage, we see that over the past twenty-five years, our railway system has increased by 6,000 miles—from 15,000 in 1870 to 21,000 in 1895. Of this increase, 2,000 miles are from the last decade. Next, looking at capital investment, we find that in the ten years from 1885 to 1895, the total capital of various railway companies in the United Kingdom jumped from 816 million pounds to 1,001 million. Part of this massive increase was, admittedly, just on paper, due to the consolidation of stock, etc. However, even after accounting for this, we still see a real net increase of 170 million pounds over those ten years. During the same decade, the revenue from passenger traffic grew from 30 million pounds to 37 million, while income from goods traffic increased from 36 to 44 million. In the last twenty-five years, the number of passengers transported by the railways, excluding season-ticket holders, has grown from 337 million to 930 million. If we could track the number of journeys made by season-ticket holders, the growth of passenger traffic on our railways would be even more remarkable. The available figures are shown in the next table and illustrated by the accompanying diagrams:—
The Railways of the UK.
Ten Years’ Work and Receipts.
Ten Years of Work and Receipts.
1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | 1895 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Goods carried:—Million Tons | 255 | 269 | 282 | 297 | 303 | 310 | 309 | 293 | 324 | 334 |
Passengers carried: Million persons | 726 | 734 | 742 | 775 | 818 | 845 | 864 | 873 | 911 | 930 |
Goods receipts:—Million £’s | 36·4 | 37·3 | 38·7 | 41·1 | 42·2 | 43·2 | 42·9 | 41·0 | 43·4 | 44·0 |
Passenger receipts: Million £’s | 30·2 | 30·6 | 31·0 | 32·6 | 34·3 | 35·1 | 35·7 | 35·8 | 36·5 | 37·4 |
The figures may be illustrated diagrammatically as follows:—
The figures can be shown in a diagram like this:—
(With permission from the Proprietors of the “Daily Graphic.”)
[38]These diagrams and the figures they illustrate hardly look as if the nation were on the verge of decay, ruined by German cheap goods. If such be the signs of national collapse, no country in the world can be called prosperous. For there is this feature about our railway development which entirely differentiates it from the railway expansion of newer countries—that every pound of capital required has come out of our own pockets: we have borrowed from no one. Instead, while planking down in ten years 170 new millions to add to our own railways, we have been lending with large hands to railway builders in every part of the globe.
[38]These diagrams and the figures they show hardly suggest that the country is on the brink of decline, brought down by cheap German goods. If these are the signs of national failure, then no country in the world can be considered prosperous. One key difference about our railway development compared to the expansion in newer countries is that every pound of capital needed has come from our own resources: we haven’t borrowed from anyone. Instead, while investing 170 million over ten years to expand our own railways, we have been lending generously to railway builders all around the world.
LENGTHENING TRAM LINES.
From railways we pass to tramways. Here the figures are less considerable in amount, but they are striking enough. In 1876 there were only 158 miles of tramway open for public traffic; by 1885 that number had risen to 811 miles, and by 1895 to 982 miles. In the same periods the paid-up capital had increased from 2 millions sterling to 12, and thence to 14 millions. Lastly, between 1885 and 1895 the number of passengers carried upon tramways has risen from 365 millions to 662 millions. These figures are principally interesting because the tramcar is essentially a popular means of conveyance. If the working-classes of this country are being reduced to starvation, as the Protectionists say, by the invading Teuton, it is astounding that they should be able to afford so many pennies to pay for tram fares.
From railways, we move on to tramways. The numbers here are smaller, but they’re still impressive. In 1876, there were only 158 miles of tramway open for public use; by 1885, that number had grown to 811 miles, and by 1895, it reached 982 miles. During the same periods, the paid-up capital went from 2 million pounds to 12 million, and then to 14 million. Finally, between 1885 and 1895, the number of passengers using tramways increased from 365 million to 662 million. These figures are particularly interesting because the tramcar is a fundamentally popular mode of transport. If the working class in this country is indeed being driven to starvation, as the Protectionists claim, by the invading Germans, it’s remarkable that they can still afford to spend so many pennies on tram fares.
POST OFFICE EXPANSION.
From this last comparatively limited but not unimportant test of the general prosperity of the country, we pass to the Post Office returns. Next to the test of railway traffic, already dealt with, no better evidence of the prosperity and commercial activity of a country can be found than is furnished by the growth of post office business. A nation whose trade is being filched from it by foreigners, whose blast furnaces are cold, and whose looms are silent, as Mr. Williams would have us believe, does not add every year forty million letters to the amount of its correspondence. Yet this is what we have been doing in the United Kingdom for a good many years past. Starting from the year ending March 31st, 1878, when a slight alteration was made in the method of presenting the statistics, we find that in the [39]nineteen years that have since elapsed the number of letters delivered annually has increased from 1,058 millions to 1,834 millions. In the same period postcards have increased from 102 millions to 315 millions; newspapers and book packets, from 318 to 821 millions. Moreover, the increase has been steady, with one significant exception. In the year 1894-95, which was notoriously a year of bad trade, there was a drop in the number of letters delivered. The drop was more than made good in 1895-96. Turning to telegrams, we find a similar story. Here we are compelled to start with the year 1886-87, the first complete year after the introduction of sixpenny telegrams. In the ten years that have since elapsed the number of telegrams delivered has steadily increased from 50 millions to 79 millions.
From this last relatively limited but still significant test of the country's overall prosperity, we move on to the Post Office returns. Right after railway traffic, which we’ve already looked at, there's no better evidence of a nation's prosperity and commercial activity than the growth of post office business. A country that is losing its trade to foreigners, with its blast furnaces cold and its looms silent, as Mr. Williams would have us think, doesn’t add an extra forty million letters to its annual correspondence. Yet this is exactly what we’ve been doing in the United Kingdom for many years now. Starting from the year ending March 31st, 1878, when a small change was made in how the statistics were presented, we see that in the [39] past nineteen years, the number of letters delivered each year went up from 1,058 million to 1,834 million. In the same time frame, postcards rose from 102 million to 315 million; newspapers and book packets grew from 318 million to 821 million. Moreover, the increase has been consistent, with one notable exception. In the year 1894-95, which was notoriously a year of poor trade, there was a decline in the number of letters delivered. This drop was fully recovered in 1895-96. Looking at telegrams, we find a similar trend. Here we need to start with the year 1886-87, the first complete year after sixpenny telegrams were introduced. In the ten years that have followed, the number of telegrams delivered has steadily grown from 50 million to 79 million.
EVER-GROWING INCOMES.
Another test of our national prosperity is furnished by the income tax returns. When the annual value of the property and profits assessed for income tax exhibits a steady increase, it is hard to believe that our manufacturers, and all the classes that depend upon them for support, are being ruined by Germans or by anybody else. Here are the figures:—
Another measure of our national prosperity is shown by the income tax returns. When the yearly value of the property and profits assessed for income tax keeps rising, it’s hard to believe that our manufacturers, and all the groups that rely on them for support, are being destroyed by Germans or anyone else. Here are the numbers:—
Tax Assessments.
In Millions Sterling.
In Millions GBP.
Five Years’ Average. | Schedule D. | All Schedules. |
---|---|---|
1870-74 | 210 | 490 |
1875-79 | 263 | 575 |
1880-84 | 268 | 601 |
1885-89 | 292 | 634 |
1890-94 | 350 | 699 |
The return from which the above figures are taken stops with the year 1894; but a somewhat similar comparison was brought up to date in the last Budget speech of the Chancellor of the Exchequer. The following table is taken from the “explanatory memorandum” that accompanied that speech:—
The data from which the above figures are taken ends with the year 1894; however, a similar comparison was updated in the last Budget speech by the Chancellor of the Exchequer. The following table is from the “explanatory memorandum” that came with that speech:—
[40]Yield per Penny of Income Tax.
Year Ending March 31st. | Yield per Penny. | Ten Years’ Growth, after allowing for alterations in the incidence of the tax. | |
---|---|---|---|
Amount of Growth. | Percentage of Growth. | ||
Thousand £ | Thousand £ | Per Cent. | |
1876 | 1,978 | — | — |
1886 | 1,980 | 62 | 3·23 |
1896 | 2,012 | 207 | 11·47 |
With such figures as these available it is difficult to understand how people can continue to pour forth nonsense about the ruin of our national industries. During the very decade in which the blight of German competition was supposed to have destroyed the profits of our manufacturers, it is clear from the above infallible test that the incomes of our commercial, professional, and property-owning classes have been growing with increasing rapidity.
With numbers like these at hand, it's hard to see how anyone can keep spreading nonsense about the decline of our national industries. In the very decade that people claimed German competition was supposed to ruin our manufacturers' profits, it's clear from the reliable evidence provided that the incomes of our business, professional, and property-owning classes have been rising at an increasing rate.
REDUCTION OF NATIONAL DEBT.
Passing from taxation to the question of what has been done with the taxes, it is sufficient to select one fact for comment—the enormous reduction in the National Debt. Here are the figures:—
Passing from taxes to the issue of how those taxes have been used, it's enough to highlight one fact—the significant decrease in the National Debt. Here are the figures:—
The Nation's Debt.
Aggregate Gross Liabilities. | Per Head of Population. | |
---|---|---|
1876 | £776,000,000 | £23 13 9 |
1886 | £745,000,000 | £20 13 8 |
1896 | £652,000,000 | £16 13 2 |
That is to say, that within the past ten years—the years of alleged depression and blight—we have reduced our national indebtedness by over 90 millions sterling. During the same period it is worth while to point out that we have expended enormous sums in the almost complete reconstruction of our navy. Meanwhile Germany—the hated rival—has, since the war, added as many millions to her debt as we in ten years have taken from ours.
That is to say, in the last ten years—the years of supposed depression and decline—we have cut our national debt by over 90 million pounds. During that same time, it's worth noting that we've spent huge amounts on nearly completely rebuilding our navy. Meanwhile, Germany—the despised rival—has added as many millions to her debt since the war as we have eliminated from ours in ten years.
[41]SOME STAPLE COMMODITIES.
In case the pessimists and the Protectionists should be still unconvinced by these proofs of national prosperity, let us turn to a new series of tests, the test of consumption. The great staple commodities which we will first take (cotton, wool, and coal) are partly required for manufacturing purposes and subsequent export, and partly for home use. The word “consumption” covers both uses, and we cannot, except in the case of wool, readily ascertain to which use the greater effect is attributable. In the case of wool it so happens, as was previously pointed out, that our export trade in manufactured goods has declined. But since the total consumption of raw wool by the United Kingdom has gone on increasing, it is clear that the decline in woollen exports has been more than made good by the increased home demand, unless, indeed, it be imagined that woollen manufacturers go on weaving an endless web which nobody wears. Nor is that all, for the figures of our import trade show that in addition we are importing considerable and increasing quantities of foreign woollen manufactures. So that not only have the home consumers more than recouped the British woollen manufacturer for the decline of his export business, but so great is their purchasing power that they can, at the same time, afford to send abroad for fresh woollen stuffs to please their fancy. Here are the figures showing the consumption by the inhabitants and manufacturers of the United Kingdom of three staple articles referred to:—
If the pessimists and Protectionists are still not convinced by these signs of national prosperity, let’s look at a new set of tests, the test of consumption. The key staple commodities we’ll focus on first (cotton, wool, and coal) are needed both for manufacturing purposes and for use in the home. The term “consumption” includes both these uses, and aside from wool, we can’t easily determine which use has a greater impact. In the case of wool, as previously noted, our export of manufactured goods has decreased. However, since total consumption of raw wool in the United Kingdom has continued to grow, it’s evident that the drop in woollen exports has been more than offset by increased domestic demand, unless we believe that woollen manufacturers are weaving endless textiles that no one buys. That’s not all; the data on our import trade shows that we’re also bringing in significant and growing amounts of foreign woollen products. Therefore, not only have home consumers more than compensated British woollen manufacturers for the loss in their export business, but their purchasing power is so strong that they can also afford to import additional woollen goods that appeal to their tastes. Here are the figures showing the consumption by the inhabitants and manufacturers of the United Kingdom of the three staple articles mentioned:—
Consumption of Cotton, Wool, and Coal in the United Kingdom.
Average of Five Years. | Cotton (Raw) Million lbs. | Wool (Raw) Million lbs. | Coal Million Tons. |
---|---|---|---|
1870-74 | 1,178 | 342 | 108 |
1875-79 | 1,221 | 353 | 118 |
1880-84 | 1,445 | 354 | 136 |
1885-89 | 1,467 | 416 | 141 |
1890-94 | 1,590 | 475 | 151 |
Year 1895 | 1,635 | 510 | 157 |
With regard to the figures for cotton in the above table, it is only necessary to remark that the British manufacturer, whether for sale abroad, or for sale at home, is clearly working up more stuff than ever before. The figures for wool have already been explained. [42]With regard to coal, the figures necessarily include both domestic and industrial consumption; but whichever be the more important element, the totals are remarkably healthy.
Concerning the cotton figures in the table above, it’s worth noting that British manufacturers, whether selling internationally or domestically, are clearly processing more material than ever before. The wool figures have already been discussed. [42] As for coal, the figures include both household and industrial use; regardless of which is more significant, the totals are impressively strong.
PERSONAL AND DOMESTIC EXPENDITURE.
An even better test of the increased spending power of the nation is furnished by the figures giving the rate of consumption of such articles of everyday use as tea, sugar, and tobacco. It will be seen from the following table how rapidly our national consumption of these staple articles has increased during the past decade—the decade of alleged ruin:—
An even better indication of the country’s increased purchasing power is shown by the figures reflecting the consumption rates of everyday items like tea, sugar, and tobacco. The following table illustrates how quickly our national consumption of these basic items has risen over the past ten years—the so-called decade of ruin:—
Tea, Sugar, and Tobacco.
Year ending March 31st. | Lbs. consumed by every 100 persons. | ||
---|---|---|---|
Tea. | Sugar. | Tobacco. | |
1876 | 451 | 6,078 | 147 |
1886 | 465 | 7,028 | 144 |
1896 | 574 | 8,916 | 169 |
It is useless to worry the reader with further figures. Evidences of the prosperity of the country are around us on every side for those to see that have eyes to see—a higher standard of dress in every class of the community; better built and better furnished houses for artisan and labourer, as well as for millionaire; new public buildings, new libraries, new hospitals; improved paving, improved water-supply, improved drainage; more newspapers, more theatres, more lavish entertainments; in a word, a higher standard of comfort or of luxury in every domain of life.
It's pointless to overwhelm the reader with more numbers. Signs of the country’s prosperity are everywhere for anyone who looks—a better standard of clothing in every class of society; better constructed and furnished homes for workers and affluent individuals alike; new public buildings, new libraries, new hospitals; improved roads, better water supply, improved drainage; more newspapers, more theaters, more extravagant entertainment; in short, a higher standard of comfort or luxury in every aspect of life.
[43]CHAPTER VI.
Leave well enough alone.
The preceding chapters have been mainly statistical. Their object has been to show, by producing the best evidence available, that alarmists like the author of “Made in Germany” have no real ground for their fears, that British trade is not going to the devil, but that, on the contrary, the nation as a whole is in a condition of marvellous and still rapidly-growing prosperity. If that be so, if there be no disease, then obviously is there no need for the remedy which Mr. Williams and other Protectionists are anxious to foist upon the country. But though that conclusion will be sufficiently obvious to most minds, there are among us hypochondriacal persons who never think that they are quite well, and these unfortunates will still hanker after some patent medicine to cure their imaginary ills. It is worth while, therefore, briefly to point out how utterly unsuited to our alleged ailments, even if they existed, is the remedy which the Protectionists propose.
The previous chapters have been primarily focused on statistics. Their goal has been to demonstrate, using the best evidence available, that alarmists like the author of “Made in Germany” have no real basis for their fears, that British trade is not failing, but rather, the nation as a whole is enjoying remarkable and rapidly growing prosperity. If this is true, if there is no problem, then there is obviously no need for the solution that Mr. Williams and other Protectionists are eager to impose on the country. While this conclusion should be clear to most people, there are those among us who are hypochondriacs, never believing they are truly well, and these individuals will continue to seek out some miracle cure for their imagined problems. It is important, therefore, to briefly highlight how completely ill-suited the remedy proposed by the Protectionists is to our supposed issues, even if they did exist.
THE CASE FOR PROTECTION.
Personally I am not a fanatical believer in Free Trade, or, for that matter, in anything else except the law of gravitation and the rules of arithmetic. I am quite willing to admit that there are circumstances under which a Protectionist tariff might be advantageous to a country. But the practical question is whether, under the present circumstances of Great Britain, Protection is likely to bring any advantage to her. In dealing with that question I will venture at the outset to deny that Protection has been any real advantage to Germany. The Protectionists are fond of arguing that the heavy import duties which Germany levies on British goods have enabled German manufacturers in the first place to secure their home market, and in the second place to build up an enormous export trade at our expense. The argument is plausible, but it suffers from one fatal defect: it is [44]unsupported by facts. As one reads the writings and listens to the talk of Protectionists, one’s mind becomes unconsciously saturated with the notion that British trade is rapidly declining and German trade as rapidly increasing. It is upon this implied proposition that all their arguments are based; this is the primary postulate upon which rests their whole house of cards.
Personally, I’m not a die-hard believer in Free Trade, or in anything else besides the law of gravity and the rules of math. I’m more than willing to admit that there are situations where a Protectionist tariff could benefit a country. But the real question is whether, given the current situation in Great Britain, Protection is likely to offer her any benefit. In addressing that question, I’ll boldly say that Protection hasn’t provided any real advantage to Germany. Protectionists like to argue that the high import duties Germany imposes on British goods have allowed German manufacturers to secure their domestic market and, in turn, build a huge export business at our expense. The argument sounds plausible, but it has one major flaw: it’s [44]not supported by facts. As you read the writings and listen to the conversations of Protectionists, you unconsciously start to believe that British trade is quickly declining while German trade is quickly rising. This implied belief is the foundation for all their arguments; it’s the basic assumption that their entire case is built on.
THE ALLEGED EXPANSION OF GERMAN TRADE.
But what are the facts? I have looked carefully through the figures showing the progress of German trade during the last ten or fifteen years, and I can discover no difference in character from the figures which show the progress of British trade. Let the reader look for himself. He will find the figures for fifteen years set out in the following table, and a diagram to illustrate them. Let him notice that what is called the entrepôt trade, consisting of goods merely passing through the one country or the other, is in these figures excluded from the comparison. Thus “British imports” here means the total imports into the United Kingdom, minus those goods which are subsequently re-exported; “British exports” means all articles of British production exported from the United Kingdom. The same interpretation applies to the German figures, all goods in transit through Germany one way or the other being excluded. The comparison is therefore complete. And what does it show? That, so far from Germany’s export trade increasing by leaps and bounds, while ours is steadily declining, German trade has followed, though at a lower level, the same general course as British trade. Therefore, whatever else Protection may have done for Germany, it certainly has not improved her export trade as compared with that of the United Kingdom. An even more striking demonstration of the utter hollowness of the Protectionist case can be seen when we turn from exports to imports. If Protection is to do anything for a country it must at least diminish imports from abroad while increasing exports from home. That is the whole object of Protection, the great ambition which every Protectionist statesman sets before him. Has Protection done this for Germany? Once again let the reader look for himself at the figures and the diagram. He will see that while German exports have remained stationary, German imports have very largely increased, and moreover that their increase has been relatively greater than the increase of imports into Free-Trade England.
But what are the facts? I've carefully examined the data showing the growth of German trade over the last ten to fifteen years, and I can’t find any significant difference from the figures that show the growth of British trade. Let the reader take a look himself. He will find the data for fifteen years laid out in the following table, along with a diagram for illustration. Notice that what’s referred to as the entrepôt trade, which consists of goods simply passing through one country or the other, is not included in the comparison. So, “British imports” here means the total imports into the United Kingdom, minus those goods that are later re-exported; “British exports” refers to all British-produced items exported from the United Kingdom. The same interpretation applies to the German data, with all goods in transit through Germany being excluded. Therefore, the comparison is thorough. And what does it reveal? That, contrary to the belief that Germany's export trade is booming while ours is steadily declining, German trade has followed, albeit at a lower level, the same general trend as British trade. Therefore, whatever else Protection may have done for Germany, it certainly has not enhanced her export trade compared to that of the United Kingdom. An even more striking demonstration of the complete emptiness of the Protectionist argument can be seen when we shift our focus from exports to imports. If Protection is meant to benefit a country, it must at least reduce imports from abroad while boosting exports from home. That is the primary goal of Protection, the key ambition every Protectionist politician strives for. Has Protection achieved this for Germany? Once again, let the reader examine the figures and the diagram. He will see that while German exports have remained stagnant, German imports have significantly increased, and notably, their growth has been relatively larger than the increase of imports into Free-Trade England.
[45]UK and Germany Trade Compared.
Fifteen Years’ Imports and Exports, exclusive of Goods in Transit.
In Millions Sterling.
Fifteen Years of Imports and Exports, excluding Goods in Transit.
In Millions Sterling.
1880 | 1881 | 1882 | 1883 | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888 | 1889 | 1890 | 1891 | 1892 | 1893 | 1894 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Brit. Imports | 348 | 334 | 348 | 362 | 327 | 313 | 294 | 303 | 324 | 360 | 356 | 373 | 360 | 346 | 350 |
Brit. Exports | 223 | 234 | 242 | 240 | 233 | 213 | 213 | 222 | 234 | 249 | 263 | 247 | 227 | 218 | 216 |
Ger. Imports | 141 | 148 | 156 | 163 | 163 | 147 | 144 | 156 | 165 | 201 | 208 | 208 | 202 | 199 | 198 |
Ger. Exports | 145 | 149 | 160 | 164 | 160 | 143 | 149 | 157 | 160 | 158 | 166 | 159 | 148 | 155 | 148 |
These figures may be illustrated diagrammatically as follows:—
These figures can be shown in a diagram like this:—
[46]WOULD PROTECTION HELP US?
So far, therefore, as Germany is concerned, Protection has been, for the general ends for which it was intended, a complete failure. Is there any reason to believe that it would be more successful in Great Britain? Every consideration of common sense points the other way. What Germany had to do was to build up comparatively new industries, in face of the overwhelming competition of Great Britain. In some instances she has been successful, and in some instances it is possible that Protection may have helped her by giving particular manufacturers an advantage in their home market at the expense of the whole German nation. But in England we have no such task to undertake. Our industries are already established; our wares are already known in every quarter of the globe; it is our competition that every other manufacturing country dreads. Nor is that the only difference. In Germany and in France and in the United States it is the home market that Protectionist manufacturers and Protectionist statesmen are anxious to secure. All their efforts are directed towards preventing their own citizens from purchasing British or other foreign goods. But with us the home market is not the primary consideration. Our business is with the whole world: our customers are of every race and colour from the patient Chinaman to the restless New Englander, from the supple Bengalee to the African savage. If we can keep their custom we need have no fear of our power to satisfy the wants of our own countrymen.
So far, as Germany is concerned, protectionism has been a complete failure for its intended purpose. Is there any reason to think it would work better in Great Britain? Every bit of common sense suggests otherwise. What Germany needed to do was develop relatively new industries while facing the overwhelming competition from Great Britain. In some cases, they have succeeded, and perhaps protectionism has helped certain manufacturers gain an advantage in their local market, but at the cost of the entire German nation. However, in England, we don’t have that challenge. Our industries are already established; our products are known worldwide; it's our competition that other manufacturing countries fear. That's not the only difference. In Germany, France, and the United States, protectionist manufacturers and politicians are focused on securing the home market. Their efforts are aimed at stopping their own citizens from buying British or other foreign goods. But for us, the home market isn’t the main priority. Our business is global: our customers come from every background, from the patient Chinese to the restless New Englander, from the adaptable Bengali to the African tribesman. If we can keep their business, we don’t have to worry about meeting the needs of our own countrymen.
ON WHAT SHALL WE LAY A TAX?
It is, indeed, just because the advance of Germany in a few limited directions has scared some people into the belief that we are losing our foreign trade, that such books as Mr. Williams’s “Made in Germany” are written. The whole point of their lament is that Germany is ousting us from neutral markets. Assume that it is so—though it is not—what then? How will Protection help us to maintain the hold we are said to be losing? All that Protection can do is to make more difficult the entry of foreign goods into our own country. But what are the foreign goods that enter our country? Four-fifths at least are food or the raw materials of manufacture. In support of this statement I must refer the reader to the Custom House returns to make his own classification. After going through the figures carefully I arrive at the following rough result for 1895:—
It’s true that Germany’s growth in a few specific areas has made some people fear that we are losing our foreign trade, which is why books like Mr. Williams’s “Made in Germany” are being written. The main concern they express is that Germany is taking over our neutral markets. Let’s say that’s true—though it’s not—what then? How will Protection help us keep the grip we’re supposedly losing? All Protection can do is make it harder for foreign goods to enter our country. But what foreign goods are we talking about? At least four-fifths are food or raw materials for manufacturing. To back up this claim, I encourage the reader to check the Custom House returns to categorize them. After carefully reviewing the figures, I come to the following rough conclusion for 1895:—
Million £’s. | |
---|---|
Food and Drink | 177 |
Raw Materials | 163 |
Manufactured Goods | 76 |
Total Imports | 416 |
Colonel Howard Vincent, I see, puts the total of manufactured goods at 80 millions. His figure will serve as well as mine. Either shows clearly enough the character of the great mass of our imports. On which of the two main branches, on food or on raw materials, do the Protectionists propose to levy a tax? It is a strange way of helping our manufacturers in their struggle for the markets of the world to impose additional taxation on the food of their workpeople or on the raw materials of their industry.
Colonel Howard Vincent estimates the total manufactured goods at 80 million. His number works just as well as mine. Both clearly illustrate the nature of the vast majority of our imports. Which of the two main categories, food or raw materials, do the Protectionists plan to tax? It’s odd that to support our manufacturers in their quest for global markets, they would impose extra taxes on the food for their workers or on the raw materials for their industry.
A NEW ROAD TO FORTUNE.
There remains the comparatively small amount of manufactured goods we import, representing articles which our manufacturers cannot or will not produce at all, or cannot produce so cheaply as the foreigner does. Supposing we taxed every one of these articles as it entered our ports, where would the advantage be to British manufacturers whose main ambition is to send their goods abroad? There is, it is true, just one possibility of benefit to them. It is possible that the imposition of a tax on some of these foreign manufactured articles would enable the British manufacturer so to raise his prices in the home market that he could afford to forego all profit on his sales abroad and sell to his foreign customers at or below cost price. That is the only conceivable way in which a Protective tariff could help the British manufacturer in his rivalry with his German competitors for the markets of the world. As for the cost of this topsy-turvy system of trade it is to be borne of course by that patient ass the British public. The British consumer is to be compelled to pay more dearly for certain goods in order that some other people, Japs or Chinamen, may be able to buy those goods below cost price. Here, again, I will not assert that such an apparent act of folly is not worth committing under given conditions. I can imagine a firm or a country consenting for a time to work for less than no profit in order to get a foothold in a new market. But we already have the foothold, and have already worked it for what it is worth. If now we discover that, for one reason or another, there is no more profit in it, [48]surely our wisest policy is to try something else. Otherwise we might continue for ever to sell at a loss—individual or national—for the sole pleasure of adding to the total figures of our turnover. Even the Protectionists would hardly contend that along such lines lay national prosperity.
We still import a relatively small number of manufactured goods that our manufacturers either can't produce at all or can't produce as cheaply as foreign companies. If we taxed all these imported items as they came into our ports, how would that benefit British manufacturers who mainly want to sell their products overseas? There is one potential advantage for them. It's possible that by imposing a tax on some foreign-made goods, British manufacturers could raise their prices in the domestic market enough to sell to foreign customers at or below cost price without making a profit on those sales. That's the only way a protective tariff could help British manufacturers compete with their German rivals in global markets. As for the cost of this upside-down trade system, it's obviously going to fall on the British public. British consumers would have to pay more for certain goods so that some other people, like Japanese or Chinese buyers, can purchase those goods below cost. Again, I'm not saying this kind of apparent foolishness isn't worth considering under certain circumstances. I can picture a company or a country willing to operate at a loss for a while to establish a presence in a new market. But we've already established that presence and have exploited it for all it's worth. If we now find that there’s no longer any profit to be made from it, [48]then surely our best option is to try something different. Otherwise, we might end up selling at a loss—either personally or nationally—just for the sake of increasing our total sales figures. Even the protectionists would probably agree that such an approach doesn't lead to national prosperity.
INTER-IMPERIAL TRADE.
There is, however, another, though not entirely distinct, proposal for dealing with the alleged mischief of German competition. It is this—that we should try and persuade our Colonies and Possessions to give preferential treatment to our goods in return for a similar preference accorded by us to their goods. It would be unfair to call this scheme Protectionist in the ordinary sense of the term, for it is inspired as much by the desire to bring about a closer union of different portions of the empire as by the fear of foreign competition; but as it is with the question of foreign competition that we are here primarily concerned, we will deal first with the Protectionist side of the proposal. On this side the object aimed at is the destruction or diminution of foreign competition in our Colonial markets. Undoubtedly, were the Colonies willing to make the necessary tariff adjustments in our favour, that object could be attained and our German rivals could be excluded in part or in whole from Canada, from Australia, from India, or from the Cape. So far so good. But what would that exclusion be worth to us? In a previous article I referred to figures showing how insignificant as compared with our own is German trade with our Colonies. It is worth while to present these figures in a fuller form. They will be found in the following table:—
There is, however, another, although not completely different, proposal for addressing the concerns regarding German competition. This proposal suggests that we should try to convince our Colonies and Territories to prioritize our goods in exchange for us giving similar preference to their goods. It wouldn’t be fair to label this scheme as Protectionist in the traditional sense, since it is motivated as much by the desire for closer unity among different parts of the empire as by concerns over foreign competition; however, since our primary focus here is on foreign competition, we'll first tackle the Protectionist aspect of the proposal. On this side, the goal is to reduce or eliminate foreign competition in our Colonial markets. Clearly, if the Colonies were willing to make the necessary tariff adjustments in our favor, we could achieve that goal and significantly limit or completely exclude our German competitors from Canada, Australia, India, or the Cape. So far, so good. But what would that exclusion really mean for us? In a previous article, I referred to statistics showing how minor German trade with our Colonies is compared to our own. It’s worthwhile to present these figures in more detail. They will be found in the following table:—
Imports into the following British territories.
Average of the Three Years—1890, 1891, 1892.
In Millions Sterling.
Average of the Three Years—1890, 1891, 1892.
In Millions Sterling.
Total Imports from all Countries. | Amount from United Kingdom. | Amount from United States. | Amount from Germany. | Amount from France. | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
India | 84 | 58·9 | 1·5 | 1·6 | 1·2 |
Australasia | 66·6 | 28·4 | 2·6 | 1·6 | ·3 |
South Africa | 12·7 | 10·3 | ·4 | ·2 | ·04 |
North America | 24·6 | 9·2 | 11·2 | ·8 | ·5 |
West Indies | 6·4 | 2·8 | 1·9 | ·05 | ·1 |
Other British Possessions | 31·4 | 6·6 | ·6 | ·4 | ·6 |
Total | 225·7 | 116·2 | 18·2 | 4·6 | 2·8 |
[49]These figures are, unfortunately, two or three years behind date, and probably a later return would show that the proportion of British exports to our principal Colonies had fallen off and the German proportion somewhat increased, but this change has certainly not been sufficiently great to affect the general aspect of the table. That table shows that more than half of the total import trade of our Colonies is in our hands, and that our three principal rivals together have little more than a tenth of the whole trade. Indeed, were it not for the inevitably big trade of the United States with Canada, our three rivals together would only have about one-fifteenth of the trade of our Colonies. As for Germany in particular the table shows that the amount of the trade she has so far been able to secure is absolutely insignificant in comparison with our figures.
[49]These numbers are unfortunately two or three years outdated, and a more recent report would likely show that the share of British exports to our main Colonies has decreased while the German share has increased somewhat. However, this change hasn’t been significant enough to alter the overall picture in the table. That table indicates that more than half of the total import trade of our Colonies is under our control, while our three main competitors together hold just over a tenth of the total trade. In fact, if it weren't for the large trade between the United States and Canada, our three competitors would collectively only have about one-fifteenth of the trade of our Colonies. Regarding Germany specifically, the table clearly shows that the amount of trade it has managed to secure is negligible compared to our figures.
THE COST TO THE COLONIES.
“But,” argue the preferentialists, “German trade with our Colonies has been growing rapidly, and may continue to grow.” Possibly it may, if our manufacturers go to sleep; but what we have here to consider is whether it is worth while to take any political action to stop the possible growth of a competing trade which at present is insignificant in amount. Remember that if such action is taken by the Colonies to please us, we shall have to pay a price for their complaisance—for their loss by the exclusion of German or any other foreign goods would be twofold. In the first place the Colonial consumer would suffer. He now buys certain German goods because they suit him best, either in quality or in price. That privilege it is proposed to take from him. His loss is therefore certain. Secondly, there is a considerable danger of injury to the Colonial producer. If the Colonies close their markets to German goods Germany may retaliate by closing her markets to Colonial goods; and Germany is, so far as the trade goes, a fair customer to the British Colonies. Here are the figures:—
“But,” argue the preferentialists, “German trade with our Colonies has been growing quickly and might keep growing.” It might, if our manufacturers become complacent; but what we need to think about is whether it’s worth taking any political action to stop a potentially competing trade that is currently minimal. Keep in mind that if the Colonies take such action to satisfy us, we will have to pay a price for their compliance—because their loss from excluding German or any other foreign goods would be twofold. First, the Colonial consumer would be affected. He currently buys certain German products because they are the best fit for him, either in quality or price. That freedom is what is being proposed to take away from him. His loss is definitely guaranteed. Secondly, there is a significant risk of harming the Colonial producer. If the Colonies shut their markets to German goods, Germany might retaliate by closing its markets to Colonial goods; and Germany is, as far as trade goes, a reasonable customer for the British Colonies. Here are the figures:—
Trade between British Territories and Germany.
Average of Three Years (1890, 1891, 1892).—In Thousands Sterling.
Average of Three Years (1890, 1891, 1892).—In Thousands of Pounds.
Imports from Germany. | Exports to Germany. | |
---|---|---|
India | 1,556 | 5,338 |
Australasia | 1,631 | 1,106 |
South Africa | 228 | 113 |
North America | 781 | 113 |
West Indies | 52 | 85 |
Other British Possessions | 351 | 691 |
Total | 4,599 | 7,446 |
[50]WHAT CAN WE OFFER?
This table shows that the Colonial producer stands to lose as much, or more, than the Colonial consumer by cutting off trade connections with Germany. What can we offer in return? It is suggested by the advocates of preferential trade that we should offer better terms to Colonial products in our markets. But already all Colonial products, except tea and coffee, enter the United Kingdom free, therefore we can only give better terms to the Colonies by imposing a tax on those foreign products which compete with the principal Colonial products. What, then, are these competing products? With some trouble I have extracted from the Custom House returns the following list of articles in which there seems to be tangible competition between foreign countries and British Possessions:—
This table indicates that the Colonial producer risks losing as much, if not more, than the Colonial consumer by cutting off trade ties with Germany. What can we offer in exchange? Supporters of preferential trade suggest that we should provide better terms for Colonial products in our markets. However, currently, all Colonial products except tea and coffee can enter the United Kingdom duty-free, so we can only improve conditions for the Colonies by imposing a tax on foreign products that compete with key Colonial goods. So, what are these competing products? With some effort, I have gathered the following list of items from the Custom House returns where there appears to be significant competition between foreign countries and British territories:—
Colonial vs Foreign Goods.
Principal Competing Articles Imported into the United Kingdom in 1895.
Millions Sterling.
Principal Competing Articles Imported into the United Kingdom in 1895.
Millions Sterling.
From Foreign Countries. | From British Possessions. | |
---|---|---|
Animals, Living | 7·5 | 2·4 |
Bacon and Hams | 10·1 | ·7 |
Butter and Cheese | 14·8 | 4·0 |
Caoutchouc and Guttapercha | 2·9 | 1·2 |
Copper | 3·9 | 1·1 |
Corn and Flour | 44·0 | 5·7 |
Dye Stuffs and Dye Woods | 2·3 | 2·5 |
Fruits | 5·8 | ·6 |
Hides, Skins, and Furs | 3·8 | 3·6 |
Leather | 4·6 | 3·5 |
Linseed | 2·3 | 1·1 |
Meat, Salt and Fresh | 6·9 | 4·8 |
Oils | 2·9 | 1·6 |
Rice | ·6 | 1·4 |
Sugar (Unrefined) | 6·8 | 1·5 |
Tallow and Stearine | ·4 | 2·1 |
Wood and Timber | 12·4 | 4·0 |
Wool | 4·6 | 22·8 |
Coffee | 2·6 | 1·1 |
Tea | 1·6 | 8·7 |
Cotton (Raw) | 29·6 | ·8 |
Jute (Raw) | ·0 | 4·3 |
Other Articles | 150·8 | 16·0 |
Total | 321·2 | 95·5 |
[51]It will be seen that without exception the articles in the above list belong either to the category of raw materials or to that of food. Any taxation therefore imposed upon any portion of these articles for the benefit of the Colonial producer would be a disadvantage to the British manufacturer, either by increasing the cost of his raw material or by diminishing the effective wages of his workpeople. Remembering that the main object of the British manufacturer is to keep his hold on the markets of the world, is it likely that he would ever consent to allow himself to be handicapped by such taxation? For all you can offer him in return is preferential treatment in Colonial markets, whereas more than three-quarters of the trade he wishes to retain is with foreign countries.
[51]It's clear that every article in the list above falls into the category of either raw materials or food. Any taxes imposed on these items for the benefit of the Colonial producer would put British manufacturers at a disadvantage, either by raising their raw material costs or reducing the effective wages of their workers. Considering that the primary goal of British manufacturers is to maintain their presence in global markets, would they realistically agree to be burdened by such taxes? After all, the only thing you can offer them in exchange is preferential treatment in Colonial markets, while more than three-quarters of the trade they aim to keep is with foreign countries.
DIVERGENT AMBITIONS.
There is, however, an even more fundamental difficulty, which neither Colonial nor British preferentialists have yet had the courage to face. It is this:—That the Colonist and the Britisher are aiming at different ends. The Britisher wishes to expand in ever-increasing proportions his manufacturing business, and it is solely because he thinks that he may possibly get a better market for his manufactures in the Colonies than in foreign countries that he gives even momentary approval to the idea of preferential trade. But no Colonist looks forward to his country remaining for ever the dumping ground for British manufactures. He wishes, and wisely wishes, to manufacture for himself, and he has deliberately arranged his tariffs with that end. Towards realising this ambition it will advance him nothing to shut out the puny Teutonic infant and let in the British giant. In like manner, if we turn from manufactures to agriculture we find the same essential divergence of view. The Colonial producer regards England as the best market for his meat and corn and butter. But the British farmer wants none of it. If he is to be ruined by competition from abroad he would as lief that the last nail were driven into his coffin by Argentine beef as by New Zealand mutton.
There’s an even more fundamental issue that neither the Colonists nor British supporters of preferential trade have had the guts to confront. It’s this: the Colonist and the Britisher are after different goals. The Britisher wants to continually grow his manufacturing business, and he’s only interested in preferential trade because he thinks he might find a better market for his products in the Colonies than in foreign countries. But no Colonist wants his country to be just a dumping ground for British goods forever. He wants, quite rightly, to manufacture for himself, and he has set up his tariffs to achieve that. To realize this ambition, it won’t help him at all to block the struggling German products and welcome in the British ones. Similarly, when we shift from manufacturing to agriculture, we see the same fundamental difference in perspective. The Colonial producer sees England as the best market for his meat, grain, and butter. But the British farmer doesn’t want any of it. If he’s going to be driven out of business by foreign competition, he’d rather it be by Argentine beef than by New Zealand mutton.
A DREAM OR A NIGHTMARE?
These objections go to the root of the matter, and show how futile it is to hope that the Mother Country and the Colonies will ever agree on any scheme of preferential trade. But need we, therefore, sit down sorrowing? Does the dream of inter-Imperial trade, if we [52]come to examine it closely, really hold all the beauties that its shadowy shape suggests? Take it either way. Take the scheme either as an end in itself, or as a means to an end. As for the first hypothesis, if trade is itself an end, it matters to us nothing whether we trade with foreigners or fellow subjects; all we have to think of is the profitableness, immediate or prospective, of the trade itself. And from this point of view a growing trade with Germany is worth a good deal more than a declining trade with Australasia. But most advocates of inter-Imperial trade would not admit that their dream is an end in itself. They adopt the second of the two hypotheses just mentioned, and look upon the expansion of inter-Imperial trade as the most convenient means of drawing the Colonies closer to the Mother Country, and to one another.
These objections get to the heart of the issue and show how pointless it is to think that the Mother Country and the Colonies will ever reach an agreement on any kind of preferential trade plan. But should we just sit around feeling sorry for ourselves? Does the idea of inter-Imperial trade, when we really examine it, actually have all the benefits that its vague outline suggests? Consider it from either perspective. Look at the plan as an end in itself or as a means to an end. For the first scenario, if trade is an end in itself, it doesn’t really matter whether we trade with foreigners or fellow subjects; what matters is the profitability, whether immediate or potential, of the trade itself. From this standpoint, an increasing trade with Germany is worth a lot more than a declining trade with Australasia. However, most supporters of inter-Imperial trade wouldn’t argue that their vision is an end in itself. They prefer the second scenario mentioned and view the growth of inter-Imperial trade as the most effective way to bring the Colonies closer to the Mother Country and to each other.
DOES TRADE UNITE?
With that end no one will quarrel; but how will preferential trade promote it? The preferentialists assume that mutual trade must of necessity promote the closer union of different parts of the Empire. Neither in individual life nor in national life can any fact be found to support that assumption. A man does not necessarily make a bosom friend of his baker and his butcher; he may even be at daggers drawn with his tailor. As for nations it might almost be said that there is the least love exchanged between those who exchange most goods. We are splendid customers to France; we buy French goods with open hands and ask for more, yet where is the love of France for England? Never for a moment do the French cease to gird at us and to try and thwart our national projects solely because we are doing in Egypt what they have done in Tunis and are on the way to do in Madagascar. Germany, on the other hand, is one of our best customers; yet at the beginning of this year, when there seemed to be a chance of war with Germany, a feeling of elation ran through the whole of England. One more illustration: when in December, 1895, President Cleveland’s Message aroused all decent folk on both sides the Atlantic to protest that war between the United Kingdom and the United States was impossible, was it of trade interests that all men thought, or of the tie of common blood? Or, again, did Canada pause to calculate that her best customer was her Southern neighbour, or did she for a moment weigh that fact against the loyalty she owed to the Mother Country?
With that goal, no one will argue; but how will preferential trade help with it? The supporters of preferential trade believe that trading more with each other will naturally strengthen the bond between different parts of the Empire. However, there’s no evidence in personal or national life to back that belief. Just because someone buys bread from their baker and meat from their butcher doesn’t mean they’ll become best friends; they might even have a conflict with their tailor. When it comes to countries, it could almost be said that there’s the least affection shared between those who trade the most. We are excellent customers for France; we buy French products eagerly and always ask for more, yet where’s the affection from France towards England? The French never stop making jabs at us and trying to undermine our national efforts just because we’re doing in Egypt what they’ve done in Tunisia and are planning to do in Madagascar. On the other hand, Germany is one of our best customers, yet at the beginning of this year, when a war with Germany seemed possible, a wave of excitement spread across England. One more example: when in December 1895, President Cleveland's message prompted decent people on both sides of the Atlantic to argue that war between the UK and the US was out of the question, was it trade interests that concerned everyone, or was it the bond of shared heritage? Or when Canada considered its best customer was its Southern neighbor, did it pause to weigh that fact against the loyalty it owed to the Mother Country?
[53]A NEXUS STRONGER THAN CASH.
The simple truth is that trade has no feelings. We all of us buy and sell to the best advantage we can, and on the whole we do wisely. It is a shrewd saying that warns men to beware of business transactions with their own kinsfolk; nor do we need a prophet to tell us that an attempt to fetter Colonial trade for our own benefit may lose us more affection than it wins us custom. After all, why worry? Our world-embracing commerce is to-day as prosperous as ever it has been. The loyalty of our Colonists no one questions. Let well alone. Our industrial success has not hitherto been dependent on favouring tariffs, nor is there the slightest evidence that old age has yet laid his hand upon our powers. As for the closer union between our Colonists and ourselves, it will hardly be promoted by asking them to sacrifice their commercial freedom to increase the profits of our manufacturers, nor by taxing our food to please their farmers. It is indeed a sign of little faith to even look for a new bond of empire in an arrangement of tariffs. The tie that binds our Colonists to us will not be found in any ledger account, nor is ink the fluid in which that greater Act of Union is writ.
The simple truth is that trade doesn’t have feelings. We all buy and sell to get the best deal we can, and for the most part, we do it wisely. There's an old saying that warns people to be cautious about doing business with their relatives; we don't need a prophet to tell us that trying to restrict Colonial trade for our own gain might earn us less goodwill than it brings us customers. After all, why stress? Our global commerce is as thriving as it has ever been. Nobody questions the loyalty of our Colonists. Let’s leave things as they are. Our industrial success has never really depended on favorable tariffs, and there’s no sign that age has weakened our abilities yet. As for a closer connection between our Colonists and us, it won’t be achieved by asking them to give up their trade freedom to boost our manufacturers’ profits, nor by taxing our food to satisfy their farmers. It’s truly a sign of little faith to look for a new bond of empire in tariff agreements. The connection that ties our Colonists to us isn’t found in any financial records, and it isn’t ink that writes the greater Act of Union.
[54]CHAPTER VII.
Conclusion.
In the foregoing pages I have been obliged more than once to accuse Mr. Williams of misrepresenting facts in order to bolster up his argument. That accusation I cannot withdraw. It has been deliberately made because the facts compelled it. Doubtless in the ordinary affairs of life Mr. Williams is not less honourable than other men, but in his zeal to establish a case, which cannot be established, he has blinded himself to the main facts of the matter with which he was dealing, and has often so quoted facts and figures as to convey an impression the reverse of the truth. Even from his own point of view this was a pity, for it throws discredit upon the whole of his work, whereas several of his statements are quite true. It is, for example, true that Germany has made great progress in the chemical and in the iron trades. It is also true that her commerce is gaining a foothold in Eastern markets once almost exclusively our own. These, and several other perfectly true statements, are to be found in Mr. Williams’s pages, and might have been edifying to exalted persons who can only discover a distorted image of the truth ten years after the main facts have been clearly seen by those common folk who are primarily concerned with them. To such individuals Mr. Williams, without his picturesque exaggerations and strange twistings of the truth, might have been really useful. As it is, he has only helped to lead them astray. Indeed, it is much to be feared that these hasty students of a big subject have by the perusal of Mr. Williams’s neatly-turned sentences and epigrammatic phrases acquired an impression which no drab-coloured statement of simple fact will ever be able to dislodge.
In the previous pages, I've had to call out Mr. Williams more than once for twisting facts to support his argument. I can't take back that accusation. It's been made intentionally because the facts demanded it. No doubt, in everyday life, Mr. Williams is as honorable as anyone else, but in his eagerness to prove a case that can't be proven, he's blinded himself to the main facts he was addressing and has often quoted facts and figures in a way that suggests the opposite of the truth. Even from his perspective, this is unfortunate, as it discredits his entire work, despite some of his statements being true. For instance, it's true that Germany has made significant strides in the chemical and iron industries. It's also true that her trade is gaining a foothold in Eastern markets that were once almost exclusively ours. These, along with several other completely accurate statements, can be found in Mr. Williams’s writings and could have been enlightening for those high-ranking individuals who only grasp a distorted image of the truth ten years after the main facts have been clear to the everyday people affected by them. Without his exaggerated claims and strange twists on the truth, Mr. Williams might have been genuinely helpful to them. As it stands, he has only misled them. Indeed, it’s quite concerning that these eager learners of a vast topic have come away from reading Mr. Williams’s polished sentences and catchy phrases with an impression that no straightforward statement of fact can ever shake off.
NOT ONLY A PROTECTIONIST PAMPHLET.
One ground of complaint Mr. Williams may possibly feel that he has against me—that I have so far treated his book as if it were only a Protectionist pamphlet. My excuse is that the spirit of the Protectionist breathes in almost every page he has written. Nowhere does he show the slightest grasp of the central fact that all commerce [55]must be mutual, that exports cannot exist unless there are imports to pay for them; everywhere he speaks as if each useful commodity sent us from abroad were a net loss to the British nation, and as if the people who sent it were “robbing” us of our wealth. Nor is that all. I take his chapter dealing with the reasons “why Germany beats us,” and I find that after examining some half dozen reasons in succession and dismissing them as unimportant, he comes to Protection and exclaims, “Here at last, we are on firm ground.” Again, in his next chapter he specifies “Fair Trade” as the first of the “things that we must do to be saved.” The second is the commercial federation of the Empire. I think, therefore, that I have had good reason for concentrating my argument on these two points.
One complaint Mr. Williams might have against me is that I’ve treated his book as if it were just a Protectionist pamphlet. My excuse is that the spirit of Protectionism is present on almost every page he’s written. He doesn’t show any understanding of the key fact that all trade must be mutual, meaning exports can't exist without imports to pay for them. He talks as if every useful product we get from abroad is a loss for the British nation and that the people sending it are “robbing” us of our wealth. That’s not all. In his chapter about “why Germany beats us,” after looking at several reasons and dismissing them as insignificant, he finally arrives at Protection and declares, “Here at last, we are on firm ground.” Then, in the next chapter, he lists “Fair Trade” as the first of the “things we must do to be saved.” The second is the commercial federation of the Empire. So, I think I have valid reasons for focusing my argument on these two points.
TECHNICAL EDUCATION AND THE METRIC SYSTEM.
There are, however, several minor suggestions in “Made in Germany,” and I am glad to be able to express my full agreement with what Mr. Williams said about technical education, about metric weights and measures, and about the excessive conservatism of the English people. I agree with him that it is monstrous that English lads should nowadays have no chance of thoroughly learning any trade. The old system of apprenticeship is almost dead, and the modern device of technical education remains a pure farce, mainly owing to the political influence of trade unions. In the same way I agree that it is ridiculous that Great Britain should go on using a clumsy and exclusive system of weights and measures, when the rest of the world is rapidly adopting the almost ideally perfect system invented a hundred years ago by the French. This is a striking instance of the conservatism and self-conceit of the English race, of which Mr. Williams so justly complains. But in this particular case, as it happens, it is not the commercial classes who are to blame. For years Chambers of Commerce throughout the Kingdom have petitioned for the legalisation of the metric system, and yet last Session when a Bill to grant this prayer was at length introduced into the House of Commons by the Government the most audible comment from the assembled wisdom of the nation was a silly guffaw.
There are, however, several minor suggestions in “Made in Germany,” and I’m glad to express my full agreement with what Mr. Williams said about technical education, metric weights and measures, and the excessive conservatism of the English people. I agree with him that it’s outrageous that English kids today have no chance of thoroughly learning any trade. The old system of apprenticeships is almost extinct, and the modern approach to technical education is basically a joke, mainly due to the political influence of trade unions. Similarly, I agree that it’s ridiculous for Great Britain to keep using a clumsy and exclusive system of weights and measures when the rest of the world is quickly adopting the nearly perfect system created a hundred years ago by the French. This is a clear example of the conservatism and self-importance of the English people, which Mr. Williams rightly criticizes. But in this specific case, it’s not the commercial classes who are at fault. For years, Chambers of Commerce across the country have been asking for the legalization of the metric system, and yet last session, when a Bill to fulfill this request was finally introduced in the House of Commons by the Government, the loudest response from the assembled wisdom of the nation was a ridiculous laugh.
NO SIGNS OF DECAY.
Let me, however, not be misunderstood. I agree with Mr. Williams that these things are desirable, but not for the reason for which he desires them. By him they are put forward as devices to [56]help to stave off the impending ruin of the country. For that purpose they are not needed, for there is not the slightest real evidence that ruin is impending. On the contrary, we are progressing rapidly in trade abroad and in prosperity at home. It is solely because I believe that we are capable of making even more rapid progress, and because I realise how great is the mass of misery still to be removed, that I support Mr. Williams’s demand for technical education, for metric weights and measures, for the more careful study of foreign languages, and generally for a greater readiness to receive new ideas, and a greater promptitude to meet new wants.
Let me clarify; I don’t want to be misunderstood. I agree with Mr. Williams that these things are important, but not for the reasons he suggests. He proposes them as solutions to prevent the country from falling into ruin. However, we don’t need them for that reason, as there’s no real evidence that disaster is on the horizon. In fact, we’re doing well in trade internationally and thriving at home. I support Mr. Williams’s call for technical education, metric weights and measures, a more thorough study of foreign languages, and generally a greater willingness to embrace new ideas and respond quickly to new needs, solely because I believe we can achieve even greater progress and because I see how much suffering still needs to be addressed.
THE CRY OF “WOLF!”
One word more—Mr. Williams’s book has been defended, by himself and by others, on the ground that it is a useful warning, that the nation requires to be stirred up, and so on. Has Mr. Williams forgotten the story of the little boy who cried “Wolf! Wolf!” when there was no wolf? It is one thing to warn the country of a problematic danger in the dim future; it is another to scream in the market-place that the danger is at our doors. Mr. Williams’s book is one long scream—a literary scream, I admit, and therefore in some measure harmonious, but still a scream in the sense that there is no reason behind the noise that is made. The danger is not at our doors, our industrial glory is not departing from us, our trade is not being ruined by Germany. On the contrary, in spite of the remarkable progress of Germany in a few limited directions, the general figures show that we are fully maintaining our splendid lead, if indeed we are not actually bettering it. I cannot, therefore, admit this attempted justification of the character of Mr. Williams’s book. To quote Mr. Punch’s admirable picture, Mr. Williams, like his pupil Lord Rosebery, has been trying to make our flesh creep. There is more harm than humour in such a pastime. That the motives of both these disturbers of our nerves were patriotic I do not for a moment doubt; but their conduct is neither patriotic nor wise. It does us no manner of good to be for ever cheapening ourselves in the eyes of the world. A great nation should have dignity enough to be silent about her own greatness, neither on the one hand perpetually boasting of her pre-eminent virtue, nor on the other fretfully asking how her credit stands with other countries. We are what we are—what our forefathers and our own brains and arms have made us. Let us be content to possess our souls in peace, and to get on with our work.
One more thing—Mr. Williams's book has been defended, both by him and by others, on the grounds that it's a useful warning, that the nation needs to be shaken up, and so on. Has Mr. Williams forgotten the story of the little boy who cried "Wolf! Wolf!" when there was no wolf? It's one thing to alert the country about a potential danger in the distant future; it's another to shout in the square that danger is knocking at our door. Mr. Williams's book is one long shout—a literary shout, I admit, and therefore somewhat harmonious, but still a shout in the sense that there's no reason behind the noise being made. The danger isn't at our doorstep, our industrial success isn't slipping away, and our trade isn't being ruined by Germany. On the contrary, despite Germany's significant progress in a few areas, the overall figures show that we're fully maintaining our fantastic lead, if not actually improving it. Therefore, I can't accept this attempt to justify Mr. Williams's book. To quote Mr. Punch's brilliant illustration, Mr. Williams, like his student Lord Rosebery, has been trying to make us uneasy. There’s more harm than humor in that kind of activity. I don't doubt for a second that both of these nervous disturbers were motivated by patriotism; however, their actions aren't patriotic or wise. It does us no good to constantly undermine our image in the eyes of the world. A great nation should have enough dignity to remain silent about its own greatness, neither constantly boasting about its superior virtues nor anxiously checking its reputation with other countries. We are what we are—what our ancestors and our own efforts have built. Let's be content to maintain our composure and focus on our work.
[57]APPENDIX.
To the Editor of the “Daily Graphic.”
To the Editor of the “Daily Graphic.”
Sir,—The first reflection arising from a perusal of your correspondent’s criticism of “Made in Germany” is that perhaps it is as well that he and I are English and not French journalists. Across the Channel disagreeable formalities sometimes ensue when one writer takes to dealing in such expressions as “artfully picked out,” “trickery,” “gross exaggeration and suppression,” “misrepresentations,” “exaggerations—to use the mildest possible term,” “grossest exaggeration,” “skilfully conveyed a false impression,” “twisting the truth,” and others of like offensiveness. As they are a direct impeachment of my honour as a man, apart from my ability as an economist, I am compelled to preface my defence with a protest. The adoption of this style is a pity, too, in that it was wholly unnecessary. My antagonist was not in the position of the proverbially abusive lawyer; he had a case to state; and, apart from personalities and some other faults to be mentioned later, I sincerely congratulate him on the ability with which he has stated that case. Of course no one will mistake my meaning. By admitting that my opponent has a case I am not confessing defeat; I am simply testifying to the general truth of the saying that there are two sides to every question, albeit one side is the right one.
Sir,—The first thought after reading your correspondent’s critique of “Made in Germany” is that it’s probably a good thing he and I are English and not French journalists. Over there, unpleasant formalities sometimes happen when one writer uses phrases like “artfully picked out,” “trickery,” “gross exaggeration and suppression,” “misrepresentations,” “exaggerations—to use the mildest possible term,” “grossest exaggeration,” “skilfully conveyed a false impression,” and “twisting the truth,” among others that are just as offensive. Since these are a direct insult to my honor as a person, aside from my skills as an economist, I feel I must start my defense with an objection. It’s unfortunate that he chose this style, especially since it was completely unnecessary. My opponent wasn’t like the proverbially abusive lawyer; he had a case to present, and despite personal jabs and some other issues I'll discuss later, I genuinely congratulate him on the skill with which he made his argument. Of course, no one can misunderstand me. By acknowledging that my opponent has a case, I’m not admitting defeat; I’m just recognizing the truth in the saying that there are two sides to every issue, even if one side is the correct one.
[3] This reply has been reprinted verbatim from the Daily Graphic. On the other hand, in preparing my own articles for republication I have made certain modifications with a view of meeting Mr. Williams’s objections, where I thought they were worth that trouble. Many of the objections have therefore lost their point; but I thought it better to let Mr. Williams’s reply stand as he wrote it.
[3] This response has been reprinted verbatim from the Daily Graphic. In contrast, while getting my own articles ready for republication, I made some adjustments to address Mr. Williams’s objections, when I believed it was worth the effort. As a result, several of the objections have lost their significance; however, I decided it was best to leave Mr. Williams’s reply as he originally wrote it.
THE “ADVOCATUS DIABOLUS.”
It is possible to raise objections (and not necessarily foolish objections) to almost any thesis, and the thesis is not hurt thereby. The Vatican wisely employs an advocatus diabolus, whose paradoxical function is to establish the sanctity of a candidate for canonisation by alleging all of what is not saintly that he can rake up in the candidate’s career. Your correspondent has acted as advocatus diabolus to “Made in Germany.” He has said what there is to be said for the other side, and my book, I respectfully submit, is uninjured. Unfortunately in this case it is the case of the advocatus diabolus only with which most of his readers are acquainted—a circumstance calculated to obscure their judgment. To them I would say: Read my book; you can buy it for half-a-crown, or you can get it for nothing out of the Free Library. This is not a puff of my own wares; it is a necessity of the case. Until you have read the book you cannot form an opinion on the worth of the attack. The small space allotted to me for criticism of my critic is obviously quite insufficient to prove a case which was with difficulty compressed into 174 octavo pages; neither, apart from consideration of space, would you thank me for copying out matter already published elsewhere. You will therefore kindly bear in mind that the ensuing remarks are not a complete statement of my position, but only some supplementary criticisms prompted by the attack.
You can raise objections (even valid ones) to almost any thesis, and that won’t damage the thesis. The Vatican wisely uses an advocatus diabolus, whose unusual job is to affirm the holiness of someone proposed for sainthood by pointing out everything unholy they can find in the candidate’s life. I have taken on the role of advocatus diabolus for “Made in Germany.” I’ve presented the other side’s arguments, and I believe my book stands strong despite that. The issue is that most of his readers only know the perspective of the advocatus diabolus, which can cloud their judgment. To those readers, I say: Read my book; you can buy it for a half-crown, or you can get it for free from the Free Library. This isn’t just a promotion for my work; it’s essential for understanding the situation. Until you’ve read the book, you can’t properly evaluate the attack against it. The limited space I have to criticize my critic is clearly not enough to address a case that was challenging to fit into 174 pages; also, you wouldn’t appreciate me rehashing material that’s already been published elsewhere. So please keep in mind that the following comments are not a complete account of my views, but merely some additional criticisms triggered by the attack.
NOT A PROTECTIONIST PAMPHLET.
First, I join issue with respect to the motive and nature of my book. Your correspondent says that I lean to the conclusion that “the only way to prevent the commercial downfall of [58]our country is to revise the Free Trade policy which we deliberately adopted fifty years ago,” and, as his readers will remember, he proceeds on that assumption, and reiterates that statement throughout his articles. It is really unpardonable. Would any of those readers, who were not also readers of my book, imagine that the first chapter of that book contains a disclaimer of holding a brief in favour of any particular doctrine or remedy, Fair Trade being specially named; that not more than seven of my 174 pages are concerned with Protection; that I strenuously and at considerable length advocate other reforms, and often point to other matters as being the determining causes of the decline in a particular trade? Your correspondent knew all this perfectly well, and yet, in order to damage my book with a Free Trade public, deliberately conveyed to them the impression that “Made in Germany” was merely a Protectionist pamphlet. He omitted all reference to technical education, the superiority of German business methods, and the other reforms whose advocacy formed the bulk of the book. And this is the man who sprinkles around charges of “misrepresentation,” and of having “skilfully conveyed a false impression”! From a child I was never much impressed by outbreaks of virtuous indignation.
First, I take issue with the motive and nature of my book. Your correspondent claims that I conclude that “the only way to prevent the commercial decline of [58]our country is to revise the Free Trade policy we intentionally adopted fifty years ago,” and, as his readers will recall, he builds on that assumption, repeating it throughout his articles. It's really inexcusable. Would any of those readers, who weren't also readers of my book, think that the first chapter of that book includes a disclaimer stating that I don't support any specific doctrine or solution, with Fair Trade specifically mentioned; that no more than seven of my 174 pages discuss Protection; that I strongly advocate for other reforms at length, and often point out additional factors as the main causes of the decline in a specific trade? Your correspondent was fully aware of all this, yet, to discredit my book with a Free Trade audience, he intentionally gave them the impression that “Made in Germany” was just a Protectionist pamphlet. He ignored all references to technical education, the superiority of German business practices, and the other reforms that made up the majority of the book. And this is the person who throws around accusations of “misrepresentation” and “skillfully creating a false impression”! Since childhood, I have never been very impressed by displays of righteous indignation.
THE CHARGE OF DATE-COOKING.
He reviles me for my dates, and in his own diagrams proves the wisdom of my choice. The object of my book was to show that England’s industrial supremacy was departing. Clearly the way to do this was to show the height to which that supremacy had attained, and to contrast it with the position to-day. Now, his first diagram shows that the highest point was reached at the commencement of the nineties. Of course, therefore, I made my comparisons beginning with that period, except where the decline had begun earlier. What is there wrong in this? Similarly I am derided as an “ingenious person” because, in order to show that our production of pig-iron was on the downward grade, I gave the figures for 1882, the highest year, and for 1894, the latest available year. If there were any truth in the charge of date-cooking I should have given to my readers the figures for 1892, which was the lowest year since 1882. It has suited the correspondent to misconceive the whole purport of my book. I was not writing an industrial history of Europe for use in schools. My work was to rouse the manufacturers of England to a sense of the danger threatening their dominion, and I went in detail through the various trades wherein this danger was apparent, showing how great they had been and what was their condition to-day. In different trades the decadence had begun at different periods; to take the same starting year of comparison in each case would, therefore, have been a stupid error. “Made in Germany” is a call to arms, not an academic disquisition on the movements of trade.
He criticizes me for my dates, yet his own diagrams demonstrate the validity of my choices. The aim of my book was to show that England's industrial dominance was fading. Clearly, the best way to do this was to highlight the peak of that dominance and compare it to today's situation. His first diagram indicates that the highest point was reached at the start of the 1890s. Naturally, I started my comparisons from that period, except where the decline had begun earlier. What's wrong with that? Similarly, I'm mocked as an "ingenious person" because I used the figures from 1882, the peak year, and from 1894, the most recent year available, to show that our production of pig iron was declining. If there were any truth to the accusation of manipulating dates, I would have presented the figures for 1892, which was the lowest year since 1882. The correspondent has intentionally misunderstood the main purpose of my book. I wasn't writing an industrial history of Europe for educational use. My goal was to alert the manufacturers of England to the danger threatening their control, and I went into detail about the various trades where this danger was evident, showing how significant they had been and what their current state is. In different industries, the decline began at different times; using the same starting year for comparison in each case would have been a foolish mistake. "Made in Germany" is a rallying cry, not an academic discussion on trade trends.
“ARTFUL AND INGENIOUS.”
But what of your correspondent’s method? With a large air of virtuous impartiality he adopts 1886 for his starting-point all through his tables. It may be my denseness, but beyond meaningless uniformity, I can see absolutely nothing in this method to commend it. I see, however, that it is very useful for optimistic purposes. Did it not strike the reader that, in most industries, 1886 was a year of bad trade, and that therefore its adoption as a starting year of comparison would result in a very inaccurate view of England’s former industrial glory? If I felt inclined to adopt his language towards myself I might be tempted to say that his choice of years was “artful” and “ingenious,” for to say, with blunt frankness, “I will take the last decade and stick to it all through,” is an admirable way to score with the unsuspecting public. The pose of impartiality is excellent. Your correspondent’s figures are doubtless as correct as they are interesting, but (in the light of the explanation I have given) I submit that those diagrams might as well have remained undrawn; they do not destroy the tables in “Made in Germany,” and, so far as dates are concerned, are ineffectual as a commentary.
But what about your correspondent's method? With a strong sense of virtuous impartiality, he uses 1886 as his starting point throughout his tables. It might be my ignorance, but aside from bland uniformity, I can't see anything in this method that makes it commendable. However, I do see that it is very useful for positive spin. Didn't it occur to the reader that, in most industries, 1886 was a year of poor trade? Therefore, using it as a starting year for comparison would give a very misleading impression of England's past industrial greatness. If I were inclined to mirror his language, I might call his choice of years "clever" and "ingenious," because to bluntly say, "I will take the last decade and stick with it," is a fantastic way to win over an unsuspecting public. The appearance of impartiality is impressive. Your correspondent's figures are certainly as accurate as they are intriguing, but (given the explanation I provided) I would argue that those diagrams might as well have remained unwritten; they don't undermine the tables in "Made in Germany," and regarding dates, they don't serve as an effective commentary.
[59]THE ABUSE OF STATISTICS.
Your correspondent has a better case for his diagrams when he gives weights as a set-off against money figures, and I cannot, of course, take exception to the use of those statistics. But I do take exception to their abuse; and when he attempts to draw from them the inference that the British manufacturer has nothing to complain of in the matter of falling prices, I suggest that there is an abuse. Of course, in some industries the decrease in the price of raw material has made it possible to manufacture for a lower price, but your correspondent goes much farther than the facts warrant when he assumes that the difference in price is balanced by an all-round difference in raw material. He forgets, for example, that coal, which in most manufactures is an item of prime importance in the cost of production, is not cheaper than it used to be in his favourite year 1886. Then the average price was 8·45s. per ton, in 1894 it was 10·50s. per ton. Wages, too, are an even more important item, and these are on the upward grade. So also are rent, rates and taxes. Take his champion instance of the cotton trade. Men used to make fortunes at it. Whoever hears of fortunes being made to-day in cotton manufacture? What we do learn is that recently fifty-two out of ninety-three spinning companies were paying no dividend at all. Prices are cut because of foreign competition. The foreigners have to cut their prices too, but that does not make the fact of foreign competition any the less disagreeable. I still think, therefore, that I followed the right method in laying more stress on money than on weights and measures, and anyway no harm could be done by it, because I used money figures for comparison in both the English and the German tables. To read your correspondent one would imagine that I had confined myself to money figures when tabulating English trade, and to weights when giving the corresponding instances from Germany. Your correspondent was so preoccupied with my skilful conveyance of false impressions that he apparently overlooked the misleading nature of many of his own impressions.
Your correspondent has a stronger argument for his diagrams when he balances weights against monetary amounts, and I can't really argue with his use of those statistics. However, I do take issue with their misuse; when he tries to suggest that British manufacturers have no reason to complain about falling prices, I believe that’s going too far. Sure, in some industries, the drop in raw material prices has allowed for lower production costs, but your correspondent oversteps when he claims that the price difference is offset by a general decrease in raw material costs. He fails to account for the fact that coal, a major expense in production, isn't cheaper now than it was in his favored year of 1886. Back then, the average price was 8.45s. per ton, but by 1894 it had risen to 10.50s. per ton. Wages, another crucial factor, are also on the rise, along with rent, rates, and taxes. Take his ultimate example of the cotton industry. People used to become wealthy from it. Who ever hears of fortunes being made in cotton manufacturing today? What we do see is that recently, fifty-two out of ninety-three spinning companies paid no dividends at all. Prices are being slashed due to foreign competition. While foreigners have to lower their prices too, that doesn't make foreign competition any less unpleasant. Therefore, I still believe I was right to emphasize money over weights and measures; there’s no harm in it, since I used monetary figures for comparison in both the English and German tables. Reading your correspondent might make one think that I only used monetary figures for tabulating English trade and weights for the German examples. He was so focused on criticizing my ability to create false impressions that he seemingly ignored the misleading nature of many of his own assertions.
EXCESS OF IMPORTS OVER EXPORTS.
This anxiety has also seemingly taken his attention away from consistency in his own statements. In the first article he rejoices over the fact that our imports exceed our exports, regarding that circumstance as a sign of prosperity; in his second article (when he has another sort of article in hand) he writes as follows:—“When two tradesmen have mutual transactions, that man will feel that he is doing best who sells more to his neighbour than he buys from him. And rightly so!” That note of exclamation is his. It also represented my feelings when I read the statement. I am also quite at one with him in the quoted remark, but (as in my poor way, I tried to be consistent) I am at issue when in his first article he chuckles over the excess of imports. Suppose that excess to be made up entirely of shipping, sale commissions, and interest on foreign investments, and that it does not imply that we are living on our capital; even then the thing does not work out quite happily. Shipping is all right, of course, but sale commissions less so; they spell enrichment, doubtless, to a certain class of City men, but the working and manufacturing classes generally get nothing out of these foreign manufactures. Still less do they share in the third item. It does not help this country’s industries to aid the establishment of rival industries abroad, which is what foreign investments mostly mean; while when the returns on those investments are used to purchase foreign goods it is again difficult to see exactly where the English industrial classes come in. With regard to the entrepôt trade, your correspondent says that it “seems somewhat to halt in the process” of slipping away; but as his own figures show that the sixty-seven millions of 1889 have dwindled in six years to the sixty millions of 1895, I don’t think I need occupy further space by combating his assertion with figures of my own.
This anxiety has seemingly distracted him from being consistent in his own statements. In the first article, he celebrates the fact that our imports exceed our exports, seeing this as a sign of prosperity; in his second article (when he has a different type of article in front of him), he writes: “When two merchants have mutual transactions, the one who sells more to his neighbor than he buys from him will feel he is doing better. And rightly so!” That exclamation mark is his. It also reflected how I felt when I read that statement. I agree with him on the quoted remark, but (as I tried to be consistent) I have an issue with his first article where he laughs about the surplus of imports. Suppose that surplus is made up entirely of shipping, sales commissions, and interest on foreign investments, and that it doesn’t mean we are living off our capital; even then, the situation doesn’t look too good. Shipping is fine, of course, but sales commissions are less favorable; they certainly bring wealth to a certain group of City men, but the working and manufacturing classes generally don’t benefit from these foreign goods. Even less do they gain from the third item. It doesn’t help our country’s industries to support the development of competing industries abroad, which is mostly what foreign investments mean; and when the returns on those investments are used to buy foreign goods, it’s again hard to see where the English industrial classes fit in. Regarding the entrepôt trade, your correspondent says it “seems somewhat to halt in the process” of slipping away; but since his own figures show that the sixty-seven million in 1889 has dropped in six years to sixty million in 1895, I don’t think I need to take up more space by disputing his claim with my own figures.
Yours faithfully,
Ernest E. Williams.
Yours sincerely, Ernest E. Williams.
(To be concluded.)
(To be continued.)
[60]MR. WILLIAMS’S REPLY.—II.
MR. WILLIAMS'S REPLY.—II.
To the Editor of the “Daily Graphic.”
To the Editor of the “Daily Graphic.”
Sir,—In my first article I endeavoured to show that the charges of disingenuousness brought against me by your critic not only missed their aim, but possessed a boomerang quality. I will ask your attention to another instance. In his second article your correspondent, in order to damage my reputation for intellectual honesty, writes:—“Mr. Williams has artfully picked out half-a-dozen or so items of our imports from Germany, and then exclaims in horror at the amount of ‘the moneys which in one year have come out of John Bull’s pocket for the purchase of his German-made household goods.’” This, in vulgar language, is a staggerer.
Mr.,—In my first article, I tried to demonstrate that the accusations of insincerity made against me by your critic not only completely missed the point but also backfired. I would like to draw your attention to another example. In his second article, your correspondent, in an attempt to harm my reputation for intellectual honesty, writes:—“Mr. Williams has cleverly selected a handful of our imports from Germany and then reacts with shock at the amount of ‘the money which in one year has come out of John Bull’s pocket for the purchase of his German-made household goods.’” This, in common terms, is astonishing.
Let me explain my artfulness. In a half-jocular section in my first chapter, I invited the reader just to look round his own house and make an inventory of the German goods it probably contains. I helped him with a list of the toys in the nursery, the piano in the drawing-room, the servant’s presentation mug in the kitchen, the pencil on the study table, &c., and then tried to give point and solidity to my little excursion into the lighter style of writing by enumerating the yearly national bill which Germany presents to us for these household items. The correspondent (to use his own admirable verb) “twists” this into the implication above quoted, and writes as though these were the only figures I had adduced. Ingenuous, is it not?
Let me explain my creativity. In a lighthearted part of my first chapter, I invited the reader to simply look around their own home and take note of the German products it likely contains. I provided a list of items like toys in the nursery, a piano in the living room, a presentation mug for the servant in the kitchen, and a pencil on the study table, etc., and then tried to add depth to my playful writing by pointing out the annual national cost that Germany sends us for these household goods. The correspondent (using his own clever verb) "twists" this into the implication I mentioned earlier and writes as if these were the only figures I provided. Isn't that naive?
THE ALKALI TRADE.
Now to another matter wherein the correspondent has superficially scored a point, but has done so largely by the process of quoting me in disconnected bits. I refer to his alkali trade section in the third article. He quotes two or three sentences of mine commenting on some startling English export figures I had just given. Then he misses out a couple of most important pages, and finishes the quotation with two sentences referring to the increase of German trade. This leaving-out of the pith of the matter, and the bringing into juxtaposition of two sets of unrelated semi-rhetorical remarks, gives to the quotation a forced and rather non sequitur air. The part that was left out is too long for me to reproduce, but it comprises a number of most pregnant instances of the havoc wrought in England’s alkali trade, and of the great progress made in the German trade. The correspondent might, with advantage to the forwarding of public knowledge on the subject, have made some reference to these facts, even had it cramped the space at his disposal for inveighing against my “grossly inaccurate impressions.” Here is a case which illustrates the necessity of my appeal to the reader to go direct to the incriminated book.
Now, onto another topic where the correspondent has made a superficial point, but has achieved this mostly by quoting me out of context. I'm talking about his section on the alkali trade in the third article. He quotes a couple of my sentences commenting on some shocking English export numbers I had just provided. Then he skips over a couple of crucial pages and ends the quote with two sentences about the increase in German trade. This omission of the main points and the juxtaposition of two unrelated comments makes the quote feel forced and somewhat irrelevant. The part that he left out is too long for me to reproduce, but it includes several significant examples of the damage done to England’s alkali trade and the substantial progress made in German trade. The correspondent could have helped enhance public understanding of the issue by mentioning these facts, even if it meant taking up some of the space he used to criticize my “grossly inaccurate impressions.” This is a clear example of why I urge the reader to go directly to the book in question.
THE CHEMICAL MANURE TRADE.
Neither can I admire the correspondent’s sudden and peculiar change of method in dealing with the chemical manure trade. Anyone acquainted with the trade in sulphate of ammonia knows how the Germans are capturing it, their estimated annual production amounting now to 100,000 tons. It is among the most startling instances of Germany’s wonderful progress in her chemical trades. Even the correspondent loses heart, and is fain to confess the expansion here. But in order that he may at all hazards score a point, he introduces the argument that “probably the British farmer ... does not regard this competition of German with English manure manufacturers as altogether disadvantageous.” This is all very well; but even a hard-pressed critic cannot serve two masters; he cannot set out to prove that the Germans are not beating us, and then, when he tumbles against an instance to the contrary which repulses all attempts to explain it away, turn round and say that it is a very good thing. It is possible to score points in a way which does not improve the scorer’s position. Altogether, I venture to suggest to the correspondent that his general [61]case would have been strengthened had he passed over the chemical trades in discreet silence.
I can't admire the reporter’s sudden and strange shift in how he’s addressing the chemical fertilizer industry. Anyone familiar with the sulfate of ammonia market knows how the Germans are dominating it, with their estimated annual production now reaching 100,000 tons. This is one of the most striking examples of Germany’s impressive advancements in the chemical industry. Even the reporter seems to lose confidence and grudgingly admits to the growth here. But just to make his point, he brings up the argument that “probably the British farmer ... does not see this competition from German manure manufacturers as entirely negative.” That sounds good, but even a desperate critic can’t serve two masters; he can’t try to prove that the Germans aren’t outpacing us, and then, when he encounters undeniable evidence that suggests otherwise, flip and argue that it’s actually a positive thing. It’s possible to make points in a way that doesn’t help the person making them. Overall, I suggest to the reporter that his overall case would have been stronger if he had simply chosen to stay silent about the chemical industry.
SOAP IMPORTS FROM GERMANY.
Especially was he ill-advised when, for the purpose of bringing into greater prominence my addiction to false statement, he burst out into italics in the following sentence: “So far as the Custom House returns show, not one single ounce of foreign soap is imported into the United Kingdom, either from Germany or from any other country.” Because the German returns show an export of soap to England under three different headings. The correspondent should have provided himself with Green Books as well as Blue Books before he set out to demolish me. He would then have learned—what he should have known anyway, considering the attention he has given to the subject—that the English Custom House returns do not show everything.
Especially was he misled when, in an attempt to highlight my tendency to exaggerate, he emphasized his point in italics in the following sentence: “According to the Customs records, not a single ounce of foreign soap is imported into the United Kingdom, whether from Germany or any other country.” In reality, the German records indicate that soap is exported to England listed under three different categories. The correspondent should have consulted both Green Books and Blue Books before trying to discredit me. He would have then realized—what he should have already known given his focus on the topic—that the English Customs records do not provide a complete picture.
IMPORTS OF IRON.
This limited acquaintance with German statistics has caused the correspondent to go wrong on other occasions. For instance, in the fourth article he produces a table purporting to show our iron trade with Germany, in which the iron exports from Germany to England cut a very insignificant figure beside the English exports to Germany. To quote his own words in another place—“Most impressive! if only it were true.” I had occasion the other day to get out a detailed list of the German exports to England of iron and steel manufactures in 1891; they reached a total of 109,956 tons. The correspondent gives 11,000 tons as the total of iron manufactures; the complete total of iron and steel manufactures, according to the source whence he obviously drew his information, was about 16,000 tons. The explanation is of course that the English returns do not always show the actual place of origin. (It doesn’t matter much; competition in any other name hits just as hard, and Germany, after all, is but one rival out of many. I only used her as an instance of foreign competition generally.)
This limited knowledge of German statistics has led the correspondent to be mistaken on other occasions. For example, in the fourth article, he presents a table that claims to show our iron trade with Germany, where the iron exports from Germany to England appear very small compared to the English exports to Germany. To quote him from another place—“Most impressive! if only it were true.” Recently, I had to compile a detailed list of German exports to England of iron and steel products in 1891; they totaled 109,956 tons. The correspondent states that the total for iron products is 11,000 tons; however, the complete total for iron and steel products, based on the source he clearly relied on, was about 16,000 tons. The explanation, of course, is that English records don't always reflect the actual place of origin. (It doesn’t matter much; competition by any other name is just as tough, and Germany is only one competitor among many. I just used her as an example of foreign competition in general.)
A “PETTY ACCUSATION.”
This particular table is, therefore, hopelessly wrong, and is certainly valueless for any purpose of destructive criticism. It is on this page that the correspondent brings against me a petty accusation of which he should have been ashamed. He says that I have “skilfully conveyed a false impression” by giving certain German figures in hundredweights and English figures in tons. Surely he had the wit to see that I was merely transcribing figures without stopping to translate them; and it is difficult to imagine he could think I was so witless as to adopt a silly sleight-of-hand trick such as that of which he accuses me, a trick which would not deceive a child in the lowest standard of a Board school.
This table is completely wrong and is definitely worthless for any kind of critical analysis. On this page, the correspondent makes a petty accusation that he should be ashamed of. He claims that I have “skillfully created a false impression” by presenting certain German figures in hundredweights and English figures in tons. Surely he should have realized that I was simply copying the figures without bothering to convert them; it's hard to believe he thinks I'm so clueless as to use a silly trick like the one he's accusing me of, a trick that wouldn't fool a child in the lowest grade of a public school.
FANCIFUL FOREBODINGS?
Here I must bring to an end my short, detailed criticism of the Daily Graphic correspondent’s attack, for I have already exceeded the space offered to me by the editor, though I have perforce left untouched a number of points on which I should have liked to enlarge my defence. I have not touched the two concluding articles in the series. The last is a statement (more lucidly and ably put than anything I remember ever to have read) of the Free Trade position in general and the case against a Customs Union in particular; but I have recently elsewhere stated my views on those subjects at length. Regarding the penultimate article, I should like to say a word in conclusion. That article attacks me by a side wind. It does not contest the facts contained in my book; on the contrary, it leads off with an airy dismissal of “Mr. Williams and his fanciful forebodings,” and it shows, by much rhetorical writing and some interesting illustrations, that England is a land flowing with milk and honey and manufactures and money, and generally in a wonderful state of millennial prosperity. My answer is two-fold. In the first place I must congratulate the correspondent on the pleasant surroundings among which alone his days can have been passed; but I should like to take him through some awful wildernesses I know—deserts of [62]“mean streets,” where half-clothed, underfed children shiver for warmth and food at the knees of women gaunt and haggard with the suffering which hopeless poverty inflicts on them; and by way of explanation of these grisly phenomena I would take him to the dock gates in the early morning, where not unlikely he would see men literally fighting for entrance because there is not work enough to go round. If that does not point him out the cause with sufficient clearness I would suggest an examination of the employment returns of the trade unions. There, by-the-by, he would see the greatest want of employment to be in those trades where the pinch of foreign competition—“the harmless growth of the German infant,” he phrases it—is most in evidence.
I have to wrap up my brief and detailed critique of the Daily Graphic correspondent's attack, as I've already used more space than the editor allowed me, although I wish I could have elaborated on several points. I haven’t addressed the two final articles in the series. The last one clearly and effectively presents the Free Trade stance in general and argues against a Customs Union specifically; however, I've recently shared my thoughts on those topics in detail elsewhere. As for the second-to-last article, I’d like to make a final comment. That article takes a roundabout shot at me. It doesn’t challenge the facts in my book; instead, it starts with a dismissive remark about “Mr. Williams and his fanciful forebodings” and uses a lot of rhetorical flair and some interesting examples to suggest that England is thriving—filled with prosperity and wealth. My response is two-fold. First, I congratulate the correspondent on the pleasant surroundings he must be enjoying; however, I invite him to visit some of the terrible places I know—areas of [62]“mean streets,” where underdressed, starving children are shivering for warmth and food at the knees of women who are worn out and haggard from the pain that hopeless poverty brings. To help explain these grim realities, I would take him to the dock gates in the early morning, where he might witness men literally fighting for entry because there aren’t enough jobs to go around. If that doesn’t make the cause clear enough, I suggest he check the employment statistics from the trade unions. There he would find the highest levels of unemployment in the industries most affected by foreign competition—what he refers to as “the harmless growth of the German infant.”
A WARNING.
In the second place, I would point out to him that the initial object of my book was to warn the nation in the day of its prosperity—such as it is—that a grave danger was lurking in the way. The fact that the easy-going man of business is surrounded by so many signs of industrial prosperity, such as those which the correspondent details, only made it the more important that he should be aroused to a knowledge of the forces that were undermining the foundations.
In the second place, I would point out to him that the main purpose of my book was to warn the nation in its time of prosperity—whatever that may be—that a serious danger was lurking ahead. The reality that the laid-back business person is surrounded by many signs of industrial success, like those mentioned by the correspondent, only makes it more crucial for him to be aware of the forces that are undermining the foundations.
Printed by Cassell & Company, Limited, La Belle Sauvage, London, E.C.
Printed by Cassell & Company, Limited, La Belle Sauvage, London, E.C.
“LAND NATIONALIZATION.”
“Land Nationalization.”
Being an Examination of various Schemes for
Nationalizing and Taxing Land.
Being an Examination of various Schemes for
Nationalizing and Taxing Land.
LONDON: METHUEN & Co.
LONDON: METHUEN & Co.
Price 2s. 6d.
Price £2.50
COBDEN CLUB LEAFLETS.
Cobden Club Leaflets.
Supplied by Cassell & Company, Limited, in Packets of 100, price 1s.
Those marked * 2s. Those marked † 4s. Those marked ‡ 8s.
Provided by Cassell & Company, Limited, in packs of 100, priced at 1s.
Items marked * 2s. Items marked † $4. Items marked ‡ 8s.
- 6. Bread Tax Once More. (From “Hit.”)
- 12. Mr. Cobden on “Re-distribution of Seats.”
- 14. *Facts for Labourers. By George W. Medley.
- 16. Facts for Farmers. No. I.—Agricultural Depression. By George W. Medley.
- 23. *Facts for Farmers. No. II.—Agricultural Depression. By George W. Medley.
- 30. The British Peasant on the Right Hon. J. Lowther’s Proposition—that he should pay “a farthing a week” on his Bread to benefit the Landed Interest.
- 31. The Farmer of Kent.
- 34. The Rt. Hon. John Bright on “The Safety of the Ballot.”
- 42. The Good Old Times.
- 44. Who Gave the Agricultural Labourer the Vote? By C. Coppack.
- 45. *Richard Cobden.
- 46. Protection in New Countries.
- 48. †Market Rights and Tolls Restrictive of Trade. By Charles Bradlaugh, MP
- 49. The Rt. Hon. John Bright on Fair Trade.
- 53. Sir Robert Peel on “One-sided Free Trade.”
- 56. *Butter-making by Machinery.
- 57. †Mr. Gladstone at Hawarden Flower Show, Aug. 24th, 1888.
- 58. †Small Fruit Farms. By Sampson Morgan.
- 59. †Market Rights and Tolls. No. II. By Charles Bradlaugh, Member of Parliament
- 60. *Co-operative Dairy Farming in Denmark. By G.J. Holyoake.
- 61. †Imported Flowers. By Sampson Morgan.
- 62. Taxing Foreign Competing Imports. By G.W. Medley.
- 66. Sir Lyon Playfair and the Sugar Convention.
- 74. Is Bounty-Fed Sugar Dishonest?
- 75. Merchandise Marks Act. Is Sugar from Bounty-giving Countries like Fraudulently Marked Goods? By the Rt. Hon. Lord Farrer.
- 77. *The West Indies and the Sugar Convention.
- 80. Tithe and Rent, as they Affect the Hop Trade. By J.J. Tylor.
- 91. Protection for Fruit Growers. By Sampson Morgan.
- 92. *Poultry Keeping for Profit. By Edward Brown, F.L.S.
- 93. †Apple Growing in England. By Sampson Morgan.
- 99. *Lord Salisbury and Protection. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Playfair.
- 101. †The Cobden Club and its Work. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Playfair.
- 102. Mr. Gladstone’s Latest Letter on Free Trade.
- 103. *What shall we do with Foreign Brushes? By the Rt. Hon. Lord Farrer.
- 104. Economic Heresies.
- 105. ‡The Neo-Protection Scheme of the Rt. Hon. J. Chamberlain, M.P. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Farrer.
- 106. Migration from the Country to the Towns. By the Rt. Hon. F. Leveson Gower.
- 107. Australian Opinion on Mr. Chamberlain’s Scheme of British and Colonial Protection against Foreign Trade.
WORKS PUBLISHED for the COBDEN CLUB
WORKS PUBLISHED for the COBDEN CLUB
By Cassell & Company, Limited, La Belle Sauvage, London, E.C.
By Cassell & Company, Limited, La Belle Sauvage, London, E.C.
- The German Bogey: A Reply to “Made in Germany.” By George W. Medley. Price 6d.
- A Study of Small Holdings. By W.E. Bear. Price 6d.
- Retaliation and Commercial Federation. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Farrer. Price 3d.
- Richard Cobden. By Richard Gowing. 1s.
- Industrial Freedom. By B. R. Wise. Price 5s.
- Wages and Hours of Labour. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Playfair, K.C.B. Price 3d.
- Tenancy and Ownership. By John Watson, M.A. Price 1s.
- The Sugar Convention. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Farrer. Price 1s.
- The Sugar Convention and Bill. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Farrer. Price 6d.
- What Protection does for the Farmer and Labourer. By I.S. Leadam, M.A. Fifth Edition. Price 1s.
- Pleas for Protection Examined. By Augustus Mongredien. 6d.
- Popular Fallacies regarding Trade and Foreign Duties: Being the “Economic Fallacies” of Frédéric Bastiat. Adapted to the Present Time by Sir E.R. Pearce Edgcumbe. 4th Edition, Revised. 6d.
- Western Farmer of America. By Augustus Mongredien. 3d.
- The Transfer of Land by Registration under the Duplicate Method operative in British Colonies. By Sir Robert Torrens, K.C.M.G. Price 6d.
- Transfer of Land by Registration of Title. By T. R. Colquhoun Dill, B.A. Price 6d.
- The A B C of Free Trade. By E.N. Buxton. New and Revised Edition. Price 3d.
- The Caribbean Confederation. By C.S. Salmon. 1s. 6d.
- Cottage Gardens and Fruit Culture. By the Right Hon. W.E. Gladstone, M.P. Price 1d.
- The Tariffs of the United States. By the Rt. Hon. Lord Playfair, K.C.B. Price 3d.
- Agricultural Distress: Its Causes and Remedies. By the Right Hon. C. Seale-Hayne, M.P.
- Cobden Club Annual Meetings, 1884, 1885, 1890-1, 2, 3, 4, 5.
- Cobden Club Dinner Reports, 1893, 1896.
CASSELL & COMPANY, Limited, Ludgate Hill, London.
CASSELL & COMPANY, Limited, Ludgate Hill, London.
Biographical Works.
Biography.
- Richard Cobden. By Richard Gowing. With Portrait on a Tint as Frontispiece. Thirty-eighth Thousand. Cloth, 1s.
- The Life, Letters, and Friendships of Richard Monckton Milnes, First Lord Houghton. By Sir Wemyss Reid. Two Vols., with Two Portraits. 32s.
- The Diplomatic Reminiscences of Lord Augustus Loftus, P.C., G.C.B. First Series, 1837-1862. With Portrait. Two Vols., 32s. Second Series, 1862-1879. Two Vols., 32s.
- The Life and Adventures of George Augustus Sala. By Himself. Library Edition, Two Vols., 32s. Cheap Edition, One Vol., 7s. 6d.
- The People’s Life of their Queen. By Rev. E.J. Hardy, M.A., Chaplain to H.M. Forces. Fully Illustrated. 1s.
- The People’s Life of William Ewart Gladstone. Profusely illustrated. Limp cloth, 1s.
- The Life and Work of the Seventh Earl of Shaftesbury, K.G. By Edwin Hodder. Illustrated. Cheap Edition, 3s. 6d.
- Henry Allon, D.D., Pastor and Teacher. By the Rev. W. Hardy Harwood. 6s.
- The Life of Nelson. By Robert Southey. Illustrated with Eight Plates. 3s. 6d. (Also at 3d. and 6d. in the National Library.)
CASSELL & COMPANY, Limited, Ludgate Hill, London.
CASSELL & COMPANY, Limited, Ludgate Hill, London.
Download ePUB
If you like this ebook, consider a donation!