This is a modern-English version of The Principles of Economics, with Applications to Practical Problems, originally written by Fetter, Frank A. (Frank Albert). It has been thoroughly updated, including changes to sentence structure, words, spelling, and grammar—to ensure clarity for contemporary readers, while preserving the original spirit and nuance. If you click on a paragraph, you will see the original text that we modified, and you can toggle between the two versions.

Scroll to the bottom of this page and you will find a free ePUB download link for this book.


THE PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS

WITH APPLICATIONS TO PRACTICAL PROBLEMS

BY

FRANK A. FETTER, PH.D.

PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL ECONOMY AND FINANCE,
CORNELL UNIVERSITY

NEW YORK
THE CENTURY CO.
1904

Copyright, 1904, by
The Century Co.

The DeVinne Press


TO THE STUDENTS
OF THREE UNIVERSITIES
—INDIANA, STANFORD, AND CORNELL—
FOR WHOM, WITH WHOM, AND BY WHOSE AID
THIS BOOK CAME TO BE WRITTEN

NEW YORK
THE CENTURY CO.
1904

Copyright, 1904, by
The Century Company.

The DeVinne Press


TO THE STUDENTS
OF THREE UNIVERSITIES
—INDIANA, STANFORD, AND CORNELL—
FOR WHOM, WITH WHOM, AND WITH THEIR HELP
THIS BOOK WAS WRITTEN


CONTENTS

PART I

PAGE
The Value of Material Things 1-169


DIVISION A—WANTS AND PRESENT GOODS

CHAPTER

1 The Nature and Purpose of Political Economy: Name and Definition; Place of Economics Among the
Social Sciences; The Relation of Economics to Practical Affairs
3

2 Economic Motives: Material Wants, The Primary Economic Motives; Desires for Non-material Ends,
as Secondary Economic Motives
9

3 Wealth and Welfare: The Relation of Men and Material Things to Economic Welfare; Some Important
Economic Concepts Connected with Wealth and Welfare
15

4 The Nature of Demand: The Comparison of Goods in Man's Thought; Demand for Goods Grows Out
of Subjective Comparisons
21

5 Exchange in a Market: Exchange of Goods Resulting from Demand; Barter Under Simple Conditions;
Price in a Market
30

6 Psychic Income: Income as a Flow of Goods; Income as a Series of Gratifications[Pg viii] 39


DIVISION B—WEALTH AND RENT

7 Wealth and Its Direct Uses: The Grades of Relation of Indirect Goods to Gratification; Conditions of
Economic Wealth
46

8 The Renting Contract: Nature and Definition of Rent; The History of Contract Rent and Changes
in It
53

9 The Law of Diminishing Returns: Definition of the Concept of (Economic) Diminishing Returns; Other
Meanings of the Phrase "Diminishing Returns"; Development of the Concept of Diminishing Returns
61

10 The Theory of Rent: The Market Value of the Usufruct: Differential Advantages in Consumption
Goods; Differential Advantages in Indirect Goods
73

11 Repair, Depreciation, and Destruction of Wealth: Relation to its Sale and Rent: Repair of Rent-bearing
Agents; Depreciation in Rent-earning Power of Agents Kept in Repair; Destruction of
Natural Stores of Material
81

12 Increase of Rent-bearers and of Rents: Efforts of Men to Increase Products and Rent-bearers;
Effects of Social Changes in Raising the Rents of Indirect Agents
90

DIVISION C—CAPITALIZATION AND TIME-VALUE

13 Money as a Tool in Exchange: Origin of the Use of Money; Nature of the Use of Money; The Value of
Typical Money
98

14 The Money Economy and the Concept of Capital: The Barter Economy and its Decline; The Concept of
Capital in Modern Business
108

15 The Capitalization of All Forms of Rent: The Purchase of Rent-charges as an Example of Capitalization;
Capitalization Involved in the Evaluating of Indirect Agents; The Increasing Role of Capitalization
in Modern Industry
118

16 Interest on Money Loans: Various Forms of Contract Interest; The Motive for Paying Interest[Pg ix] 131

17 The Theory of Time-value: Definition and Scope of Time-value; The Adjustment of the Rate of Time-discount 141

18 Relatively Fixed and Relatively Increasable Forms of Capital: How Various Forms of Capital May
Be Increased; Social Significance of These Differences
152

19 Saving and Production as Affected by the Rate of Interest: Saving as Affected by the Interest Rate;
Conditions Favorable to Saving; Influence of the Interest Rate on Methods of Production
159


PART II

The Value of Human Services 171-355


DIVISION A—LABOR AND WAGES

20 Labor and Classes of Laborers: Relation of Labor to Wealth; Varieties of Talents and of Abilities
in Men
173

21 The Supply of Labor: What Is a Doctrine of Population? Population in Human Society; Current Aspect
of the Population Problem
184

22 Conditions for Efficient Labor: Objective Physical Conditions; Social Conditions Favoring Efficiency;
Division of Labor
195

23 The Law of Wages: Nature of Wages and the Wages Problem; The Different Modes of Earning Wages;
Wages as Exemplifying the General Law of Value
205

24 The Relation of Labor to Value: Relation of Rent to Wages, Relation of Time-value to Wages; The
Relation of Labor to Value
215

25 The Wage System and its Results: Systems of Labor; The Wage System as it Is; Progress of the Masses
Under the Wage System
[Pg x] 226

26 Machinery and Labor: Extent of the Use of Machinery; Effect of Machinery on the Welfare and Wages
of the Masses
236

27 Trade-unions: The Objects of Trade-unions; The Methods of Trade-unions; Combination and Wages 245

DIVISION B—ENTERPRISE AND PROFITS

28 Production and the Combination of the Factors: The Nature of Production; Combination of the Factors 257

29 Business Organization and the Enterpriser's Function: The Direction of Industry; Qualities of a Business
Organizer; The Selection of Ability
265

30 Cost of Production: Cost of Production from the Enterpriser's Point of View; Cost of Production from
the Economist's Standpoint
273

31 The Law of Profits: Meaning of Terms; The Typical Enterpriser's Services Reviewed; Statement of the
Law of Profits
282

32 Profit-sharing, Producers' and Consumers' Coöperation: Profit-sharing; Producers' Coöperation; Consumers'
Coöperation
292

33 Monopoly Profits: Nature of Monopoly; Kinds of Monopoly; The Fixing of a Monopoly Price 302

34 Growth of Trusts and Combinations in the United States: Growth of Large Industry in the United
States; Advantages of Large Production; Causes of Industrial Combinations
312

35 Effect of Trusts on Prices: How Trusts Might Affect Prices; How Trusts Have Affected Prices 323

36 Gambling, Speculation, and Promoters' Profits: Gambling vs. Insurance; The Speculator as a Risk taker;
Promoter's and Trustee's Profits
[Pg xi] 333

37 Crises and Industrial Depressions: Definition and Description of Crises; Crises in the Nineteenth
Century; Various Explanations of Crises
345

PART III

The Social Aspects of Value 357-563

DIVISION A—RELATION OF PRIVATE INCOME TO SOCIAL WELFARE

38 Private Property and Inheritance: Impersonal and Personal Shares of Income; The Origin of Private
Property; Limitations of the Right of Private Property
359

39 Income and Social Service: Income from Property; Income from Personal Services 370

40 Waste and Luxury: Waste of Wealth; Luxury 381

41 Reaction of Consumption on Production: Reaction upon Material Productive Agents; Reaction upon
the Efficiency of the Workers; Effects on the Abiding Welfare of the Consumer
392

42 Distribution of the Social Income: The Nature of Personal Distribution; Methods of Personal Distribution 402

43 Survey of the Theory of Value: Review of the Plan Followed; Relation of Value Theories to Social
Reforms; Interrelation of Economic Agents
412

DIVISION B—RELATION OF THE STATE TO INDUSTRY

44 Free Competition and State Action: Competition and Custom; Economic Harmony through Competition;
Social Limiting of Competition
422

45 Use, Coinage, and Value of Money: The Precious Metals as Money; The Quantity Theory of Money[Pg xii] 431

46 Token Coinage and Government Paper Money: Light-Weight Coins; Paper Money Experiments; Theories
of Political Money
443

47 The Standard of Deferred Payments: Function of the Standard; International Bimetallism; The Free-silver
Movement in America
453

48 Banking and Credit: Functions of a Bank; Typical Bank Money; Banks of the United States To-day 462

49 Taxation in its Relation to Value: Purposes of Taxation; Forms of Taxation; Principles and Practice 471

50 The General Theory of International Trade: International Trade as a Case of Exchange; Theory of
Foreign Exchanges of Money; Real Benefits of Foreign Trade
480

51 The Protective Tariff: The Nature and Claims of Protection; The Reasonable Measure of Justification
of Protection; Values as Affected by Protection
491

52 Other Protective Social and Labor Legislation: Social Legislation; Labor Legislation 504

53 Public Ownership of Industry: Examples of Public Ownership; Economic Aspects of Public Ownership 514

54 Railroads and Industry: Transportation as a Form of Production; The Railroad as a Carrier; Discrimination
in Rates on Railroads
525

55 The Public Nature of Railroads: Public Privileges of Railroad Corporations; Political and Economic
Power of Railroad Managers; Commissions to Control Railroads
534

56 Public Policy as to Control of Industry: State Regulation of Corporate Industry; Difficulties of
Public Control of Industry; Trend of Policy as to Public Industrial Activity
544

57 Future Trend of Values: Past and Present of Economic Society; The Economic Future of Society 555

Questions and Critical Notes 565

Index 595

PAGE
The Importance of Material Possessions __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-169


DIVISION A—WANTS AND PRESENT GOODS

CHAPTER

1 The Nature and Purpose of Political Economy: Name and Definition; The Role of Economics Among the
Social Sciences; The Connection of Economics to Real-World Issues
3

2 Economic Motives: Basic Material Needs, The Primary Economic Motives; Desires for Non-material Goals,
as Secondary Economic Motives
9

3 Wealth and Welfare: How People's Relationship with Material Things Affects Economic Welfare; Key Economic Concepts Related to Wealth and Welfare 15

4 The Nature of Demand: Comparing Goods in People's Minds; Demand for Goods Arises from Personal Comparisons
21

5 Market Exchange: Trading Goods Based on Demand; Bartering in Basic Situations;
Pricing in a Market
30

6 Psychic Income: Income as a Flow of Goods; Income as a Series of Rewards[Pg viii] 39


DIVISION B—WEALTH AND RENT

7 Wealth and Its Direct Uses: How Indirect Goods Relate to Satisfaction; Conditions of
Economic Wealth
46

8 The Rental Agreement: Understanding Rent; The Evolution of Rental Contracts and Their Changes 53

9 The Law of Diminishing Returns: Understanding the Concept of (Economic) Diminishing Returns; Other Meanings of the Term "Diminishing Returns"; Evolution of the Concept of Diminishing Returns 61

10 The Theory of Rent: The Market Value of Usufruct: Differential Advantages in Consumer Goods; Differential Advantages in Indirect Goods 73

11 Repair, Depreciation, and Destruction of Wealth: Impact on Sale and Rent: Repair of Income-generating Assets; Decrease in the Income-earning Capacity of Maintained Assets; Destruction of Natural Resource Supplies. 81

12 Increase in Rent-generating Assets and Rents: Efforts to Enhance Products and Rent-generating Assets; Impact of Social Changes on Rent of Indirect Assets 90

DIVISION C—CAPITALIZATION AND TIME-VALUE

13 Money as a Tool for Exchange: The Origins of Using Money; The Nature of Currency Use; The Value of Typical Money 98

14 The Money Economy and the Idea of Capital: The Barter Economy and Its Decline; The Idea of Capital in Modern Business 108

15 The Capitalization of All Types of Rent: Buying Rent-charges as an Example of Capitalization; Capitalization Involved in Assessing Indirect Assets; The Increasing Importance of Capitalization in Today’s Industry 118

16 Interest on Money Loans: Various Types of Contracted Interest; The Purpose of Paying Interest[Pg ix] 131

17 The Theory of Time Value: Definition and Scope of Time Value; Adjusting the Rate of Time Discount 141

18 Relatively Fixed and Relatively Expandable Forms of Capital: How Different Types of Capital Can Be Increased; Social Significance of These Differences 152

19 Saving and Production in Relation to Interest Rates: How Interest Rates Affect Saving; Conditions That Promote Saving; Impact of Interest Rates on Production Methods 159


PART II

The Importance of Human Services __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-355


DIVISION A—LABOR AND WAGES

20 Labor and Types of Workers: The Connection Between Labor and Wealth; Different Talents and Abilities in People 173

21 The Supply of Labor: What is the Population Doctrine? Population in Human Society; Today's View on the Population Issue 184

22 Conditions for Effective Work: Objective Physical Conditions; Social Conditions that Encourage Efficiency; Division of Labor 195

23 The Law of Wages: Understanding Wages and the Wage Debate; The Different Methods to Earn Wages; Wages as Examples of the General Law of Value 205

24 The Relationship Between Labor and Value: Link Between Rent and Wages, Connection of Time-value to Wages; The Relationship of Labor to Value 215

25 The Wage System and Its Effects: Labor Systems; The Wage System as It Exists; Advancement of the Masses Under the Wage System[Pg x] 226

26 Machinery and Labor: Level of Machinery Usage; Effect of Machinery on People’s Well-Being and Wages 236

27 Trade Unions: Goals of Trade Unions; Strategies of Trade Unions; Cooperation and Wages 245

DIVISION B—ENTERPRISE AND PROFITS

28 Production and Combining Factors: The Nature of Production; Combining Factors 257

29 Business Organization and the Role of the Entrepreneur: Leading the Industry; Characteristics of a Business Organizer; Choosing the Right Talent 265

30 Cost of Production: Production Costs from the Entrepreneur's Perspective; Production Costs from the Economist's Perspective 273

31 The Law of Profits: Definitions; Review of the Typical Entrepreneur's Services; Overview of the Law of Profits 282

32 Profit Sharing, Collaboration Among Producers and Consumers: Profit Sharing; Cooperation Among Producers; Cooperation Among Consumers 292

33 Monopoly Profits: What a Monopoly Is; Types of Monopolies; How to Set a Monopoly Price 302

34 Growth of Trusts and Collaborations in the U.S.: Expansion of Major Industries in the U.S.; Advantages of Large-Scale Production; Reasons for Industrial Collaborations 312

35 Impact of Trusts on Prices: How Trusts Could Affect Prices; How Trusts Have Affected Prices 323

36 Gambling, Speculation, and Promoter Profits: Gambling vs. Insurance; The Speculator as a Risk Taker; Profits of Promoters and Trustees[Pg xi] 333

37 Crises and Industrial Declines: Definition and Description of Crises; Crises in the 1800s; Different Explanations for Crises 345

PART III

Social Value Aspects __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-563

DIVISION A—THE CONNECTION BETWEEN PRIVATE INCOME AND SOCIAL WELFARE

38 Private Property and Inheritance: Impersonal and Personal Income Shares; The Origin of Private Property; Restrictions on the Right to Private Property 359

39 Income and Social Services: Income from Property; Income from Personal Services 370

40 Waste and Luxury: Waste of Wealth; Overindulgent Luxury 381

41 The Effect of Consumption on Production: Impact on Material Productive Agents; Influence on Worker Efficiency; Consequences for the Long-Term Welfare of Consumers 392

42 Distribution of Social Income: The Character of Personal Distribution; Methods of Personal Distribution 402

43 Overview of Value Theory: Examination of the Approach Used; Connection Between Value Theories and Social Reforms; Interrelationship of Economic Agents 412

DIVISION B—THE STATE'S ROLE IN INDUSTRY

44 Free Competition and Government Action: Competition and Tradition; Economic Balance through Competition; Social Constraints on Competition 422

45 Use, Coinage, and Value of Money: Precious Metals as Currency; The Quantity Theory of Money[Pg xii] 431

46 Token Coinage and Government Paper Money: Lightweight Coins; Experiments with Paper Money; Theories of Political Money 443

47 The Standard for Deferred Payments: Purpose of the Standard; International Bimetallism; The Free-Silver Movement in the U.S. 453

48 Banking and Credit: The Role of a Bank; Typical Bank Money; Banks in the U.S. Today 462

49 Taxation and Its Relation to Value: Reasons for Taxation; Types of Taxation; Principles and Practices 471

50 The General Theory of International Trade: International Trade as an Example of Exchange; Theory of Foreign Currency Exchange; Real Advantages of International Trade 480

51 The Protective Tariff: Nature and Claims of Protection; Justification for Protection; Values Impacted by Protection 491

52 Other Protective Social and Labor Laws: Social Laws; Labor Laws 504

53 Public Ownership of Industry: Examples of Public Ownership; Economic Aspects of Public Ownership 514

54 Railroads and Industry: Transportation as a Means of Production; Railroads as Transporters; Price Discrimination in Railroads 525

55 The Public Aspect of Railroads: Public Benefits of Railroad Companies; Political and Economic Influence of Railroad Executives; Commissions to Oversee Railroads 534

56 Public Policy on Industry Regulation: State Control of Corporate Industry; Challenges of Public Oversight in Industry; Trends in Public Industrial Policy 544

57 Future Trends in Values: The Past and Present of Economic Society; The Economic Future of Society 555

Questions and Feedback 565

Index 595


PREFACE

This book had its beginning ten years ago in a series of brief discussions supplementing a text used in the class-room. Their purpose was to amend certain theoretical views even then generally questioned by economists, and to present most recent opinions on some other questions. These critical comments evolved into a course of lectures following an original outline, and were at length reduced to manuscript in the form of a stenographic report made from day to day in the class-room. The propositions printed in italics were dictated to the class, to give the key-note to the main divisions of the argument. Repeated revisions have shortened the text, cut out many digressions and illustrations, and remedied many of the faults both of thought and of expression; but no effort has been made to conceal or alter the original and essential character of the simple, informal, class-room talks by teacher to student. To this origin are traceable many conversational phrases and local illustrations, and the occasional use of the personal form of address.

This book started ten years ago with a series of brief discussions that supplemented a textbook used in the classroom. The goal was to address certain theoretical views that were already widely questioned by economists and to present the latest opinions on other issues. These critical comments developed into a series of lectures based on an original outline and were eventually compiled into a manuscript from daily stenographic notes taken in the classroom. The statements printed in italics were dictated to help emphasize the main points of the argument. Through multiple revisions, the text has been condensed, unnecessary digressions and examples removed, and various flaws in both thought and expression corrected; however, no attempts have been made to hide or change the original, essential nature of the straightforward, informal talks between teacher and student. This origin accounts for many conversational phrases and local examples, as well as the occasional use of the personal form of address.

The lectures, at the outset, sought to give merely a summary of widely accepted economic theory, not to offer any contribution to the subject. While they were in progress, however, special studies in the evolution of the economic concepts were pursued, and the manuscript of a book on that more special subject was carried well toward completion. That work, which it is hoped some time to complete, was, for several reasons, put aside while the present text was preparing for publication. The economic theories of the present transition period show many discordant elements,[Pg xiv] yet the author felt that his attempt to unify the statement of principles, in an elementary text explaining modern problems, and consistent in its various parts, helped to reveal to him both difficulties and possible solutions in the more special theoretical field. The unforeseen outcome of these varied studies is an elementary text embodying a new conception of the theory of distribution, an outline of which will be found in Chapter Forty-three. It is, in brief, a consistently subjective analysis of the relations of goods to wants, in place of the admixture of objective and subjective distinctions found in the traditional conceptions of rent, interest, and price.

The lectures initially aimed to provide just a summary of widely accepted economic theory, rather than to contribute anything new to the topic. However, during this time, special studies on the development of economic concepts were conducted, and a book manuscript on that specific subject was well on its way to completion. This work, which is hoped to be finished someday, was set aside for several reasons while preparing the current text for publication. The economic theories of this transitional period reveal many conflicting elements,[Pg xiv] but the author believed that his effort to unify the principles in an introductory text addressing modern issues, consistent in its various parts, helped him identify both challenges and potential solutions in the more specialized theoretical area. The unexpected result of these diverse studies is a basic text that presents a new understanding of the theory of distribution, a summary of which can be found in Chapter Forty-three. In short, it provides a consistently subjective analysis of the relationship between goods and wants, instead of mixing objective and subjective distinctions as seen in traditional concepts of rent, interest, and price.

The beginning of the systematic study of economics, like the first steps in a language, is difficult because of the entire strangeness of the thought, and it is not to be hoped that any pedagogic device can do away with the need of strenuous thinking by the student. The aim, however, in the development of this theory of distribution, has been to proceed by gradual steps, as in a series of geometrical propositions, from the simple and familiar acts and experiences of the individual's every-day life, through the more complex relations, to the most complex, practical, economic problems of the day. The hope has long been entertained by economists that a conception of the whole problem of value would be attained that would coördinate and unify the various "laws,"—those of rent, wages, interest, etc. This solution has here been sought by a development of recent theories, the unit of the complex problem of value being the simplest, immediate, temporary gratification.

The start of a systematic study of economics, much like learning a new language, is tough because the ideas are so unfamiliar. There's no teaching method that can eliminate the need for serious thinking from the student. However, the goal of developing this theory of distribution has been to move step by step, like a series of geometric propositions, from the simple and familiar actions and experiences of daily life to more complex relationships and ultimately to the complicated, real-world economic issues we face today. Economists have long hoped that a complete understanding of the entire value problem could be achieved, one that would connect and unify the various "laws"—like those of rent, wages, and interest. This solution has been pursued here by exploring recent theories, with the simplest, immediate, temporary satisfaction serving as the foundation of the complex value problem.

Possibly some teachers will observe and regret the almost entire absence of critical discussions of controverted points in theory, which make up so large a part of some of the older texts. The more positive manner of presentation has been purposely adopted, and only such reference is made to conflicting views as is needed to guard the student against misunderstanding in his further reading. The author would[Pg xv] not have it thought that he doubts the disciplinary value of economic theory or its scientific worth for more advanced students, for, on the contrary, he believes in it, perhaps to an extreme degree; but, for his own part, he has become convinced of the unwisdom of carrying on these subtle controversies in classes of beginners. The inherent difficulties of the subject are great enough, without the creation of new ones.

It's possible that some teachers will notice and regret the almost complete lack of critical discussions on debated points in theory, which constitute a large part of some of the older texts. The more straightforward presentation style has been intentionally chosen, and only minimal references to differing views are included to help the student avoid misunderstandings in their further reading. The author would[Pg xv] not want anyone to think that he questions the educational value of economic theory or its scientific importance for more advanced students, because, on the contrary, he believes in it, maybe to an extreme extent; however, for his own part, he has become convinced that continuing these subtle debates in beginner classes is unwise. The inherent challenges of the subject are already significant, without introducing new ones.

The fifty-seven chapters represent the work of the typical college course in elementary economics, allowing two chapters a week, and a third meeting weekly for review and for the discussion of questions, exercises, and reports. The subject is so large that the text is, in many places, hardly more than a suggestive outline. In class-room work it should be supplemented by other sources of information, such as personal observation by the students (many of the questions following the text serving to stimulate the attention); visits to local industries; interchange of opinions; examples given by the teacher; study and discussion, in the light of the principles stated in the text, of some such problems as are suggested in the appended list of questions; collateral reading; the preparation of exercises and the use of statistical material from the census, labor reports, etc.; history and description of industries; history of the growth of economic ideas. Suggestions, from teachers, of changes that will make the text more useful in their classes, will be thankfully received by the author.

The fifty-seven chapters cover what a typical college course in basic economics entails, allowing for two chapters a week, plus a third weekly session for review and discussion of questions, exercises, and reports. The topic is so vast that the text often serves merely as a starting point. In classroom activities, it should be paired with other sources of information, such as students' personal observations (many of the questions after the text are intended to grab their attention); visits to local businesses; sharing opinions; examples provided by the teacher; studying and discussing issues in light of the principles outlined in the text, based on the list of questions included; additional reading; preparing exercises and using statistical data from the census, labor reports, etc.; and exploring the history and description of industries as well as the evolution of economic ideas. Suggestions from teachers on improvements that would enhance the text's usefulness in their classes will be greatly appreciated by the author.

Lack of space makes it impossible to mention by name the many sources to which the writer is indebted. Special acknowledgment, however, is gratefully made to C. H. Hull, of Cornell University; to E. W. Kemmerer, now of the Philippine Treasury Department, and to U. G. Weatherly, of Indiana University, who have read large portions of the manuscript, and have made many valuable suggestions; to W. M. Daniels, of Princeton University, who has read every page of the copy, and to whom are due the greatest[Pg xvi] obligations for his numerous and able criticisms both of the argument and of the expression; to R. C. Brooks, now of Swarthmore College, for a number of the questions in the appended list, and for helpful comments given while the course was developing; and to R. F. Hoxie and to A. C. Muhse, whose thoughtful reading of the proof has eliminated many errors. For the defects remaining, not these friendly critics, but the author alone, should be held accountable.

Lack of space makes it impossible to name all the many sources the writer is grateful to. Special thanks, however, go to C. H. Hull from Cornell University; E. W. Kemmerer, now with the Philippine Treasury Department; and U. G. Weatherly from Indiana University, who have read large parts of the manuscript and provided valuable suggestions; to W. M. Daniels from Princeton University, who has gone through every page of the manuscript and deserves the greatest[Pg xvi] appreciation for his numerous and insightful critiques on both the arguments and the writing; to R. C. Brooks, now at Swarthmore College, for several questions in the attached list and for helpful feedback while the course was being developed; and to R. F. Hoxie and A. C. Muhse, whose careful reading of the proofs has corrected many errors. For any remaining flaws, only the author should be held responsible, not these supportive critics.

No book on economics can to-day satisfy everybody—"Or even anybody," adds a friend. But with this book may go the hope that what has been written with love of truth and of democracy may serve, in its small way, both to further sound economic reasoning and to extend among American citizens a better understanding of the economic problems set for this generation to solve.

No book on economics today can satisfy everyone—"Or even anybody," as a friend likes to say. But with this book comes the hope that what has been written with a passion for truth and democracy can, in its small way, help promote solid economic reasoning and foster a better understanding among American citizens of the economic challenges our generation needs to tackle.

Frank A. Fetter.

Ithaca, N. Y., August, 1904.

Frank A. Fetter.

Ithaca, NY, August, 1904.


THE PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS


PART I

DIVISION A—WANTS AND PRESENT GOODS


CHAPTER I

THE NATURE AND PURPOSE OF POLITICAL ECONOMY

§ I. NAME AND DEFINITION

Verbal definition of economics

1. Economics, or political economy, may be defined, briefly, as the study of men earning a living; or, more fully, as the study of the material world and of the activities and mutual relations of men, so far as all these are the objective conditions to gratifying desires. To define, means to mark off the limits of a subject, to tell what questions are or are not included within it. The ideas of most persons on this subject are vague, yet it would be very desirable if the student could approach this study with an exact understanding of the nature of the questions with which it deals. Until a subject has been studied, however, a definition in mere words cannot greatly aid in marking it off clearly in our thought. The essential thing for the student is to see clearly the central purpose of the study, not to decide at once all of the puzzling cases.

1. Economics, or political economy, can be briefly defined as the study of how people make a living; or, more fully, as the study of the material world and the activities and interactions of people, as these serve as the objective conditions for satisfying desires. To define means to set the boundaries of a subject, to clarify which questions are included and which are not. Most people's ideas on this topic are unclear, but it would be very helpful if students could approach this study with a precise understanding of the types of questions it addresses. However, until a subject has been explored, a mere verbal definition is unlikely to help clarify it in our minds. The most important thing for students is to clearly grasp the main goal of the study, rather than trying to resolve all the confusing cases right away.

Natural sciences deal with material things

2. A definition that suggests clear and familiar thoughts to the student seem at first much more difficult to get in any social science than in the natural sciences. These deal with concrete, material things which we are accustomed to see, handle, and measure. If a mere child is told that botany is a study in which he may learn about flowers, trees, and plants, the answer is fairly satisfying, for he at once thinks of many things of that kind. When, in like manner zoölogy is defined as the study of animals, or geology as the study of rocks and the earth, the words call up memories of many familiar objects. Even so difficult and foreign-looking a word as ichthyology seems to be made clear by the statement that it is the name of the study in which one learns about fish. It is true that there may be some misunderstanding as to the way in which these subjects are studied, for botany is not in the main to teach how to cultivate plants in the garden, nor ichthyology how to catch fish or to propagate them in a pond. But the main purpose of these studies is clear at the outset from these simple definitions. Indeed, as the study is pursued, and knowledge widens to take in the manifold and various forms of life, the boundaries of the special sciences become not more but less sharp and definite.

2. A definition that presents clear and familiar ideas to the student seems much harder to grasp in social sciences than in natural sciences at first. Natural sciences focus on concrete, tangible things that we’re used to seeing, touching, and measuring. If you tell a young child that botany is the study of flowers, trees, and plants, that makes sense to them because they can easily think of many of those things. Similarly, when zoölogy is described as the study of animals, or geology as the study of rocks and the earth, those definitions bring to mind many familiar objects. Even a complex term like ichthyology becomes understandable when it’s explained as the study of fish. While there might be some confusion about how these topics are studied—since botany isn't just about gardening and ichthyology isn't solely about fishing or breeding fish in a pond—the main purpose of these fields is clear from the simple definitions. In fact, as you dive deeper into these subjects, and your knowledge expands to include the diverse forms of life, the lines between these specific sciences become less, not more, distinct.

Economics studies some social acts and relations

Political economy, on the other hand, as one of the social sciences, which deal with men and their relations in society, seems to be a very much more complex thought to get hold of. We are tempted to say that it deals with less familiar things; but the truth may be, as a thoughtful friend suggests, that the simple social acts and relations are more familiar to our thought than are lions, palm-trees, or even horses. Every hour in the streets or stores, one may witness thousands of acts, such as bargains, labor, payments, that are the subject-matter of economic science. Their very familiarity may cause men to overlook their deeper meaning.

Political economy, on the other hand, as one of the social sciences that focus on people and their relationships in society, seems to be a lot more complex to grasp. We might be tempted to say it deals with less familiar concepts; however, as a thoughtful friend points out, simple social actions and relationships can actually be more familiar to us than lions, palm trees, or even horses. Every hour in the streets or stores, you can see thousands of actions, like negotiating deals, working, and making payments, which are the focus of economic science. Their very familiarity might make people overlook their deeper significance.

Many other definitions have been given of political economy. It has been called the science of wealth, or the science of exchanges. Evidently there are various ways in which[Pg 5] wealth may be considered or exchanges made. The particular aspects that are dealt with in political economy will be made clear by considering two other questions, the place of economics among the social sciences and the relation of economics to practical affairs.

Many other definitions of political economy exist. It's been referred to as the science of wealth or the science of exchanges. Clearly, there are different ways to think about wealth or conduct exchanges. The specific areas addressed in political economy will become clearer by examining two other questions: the role of economics among the social sciences and its connection to real-world issues.

§ II. PLACE OF ECONOMICS AMONG THE SOCIAL SCIENCES

Economics contrasted with the natural sciences

1. Political economy, as one of the social sciences, may be contrasted with the natural sciences, which deal with material things and their mutual relations, while it deals with one aspect of men's life in society, namely, the earning of a living, or the use of wealth. It is true that political economy also has to do with plants and animals and the earth—in fact, with all of those things which are the subject-matter of the natural sciences; but it has to do with them only in so far as they are related to man's welfare and affect his estimate of the value of things; only in so far as they are related to the one central subject of economic interest, the earning of a living.

1. Political economy, as a social science, can be contrasted with the natural sciences, which focus on physical things and their interactions. Instead, it addresses a specific part of human life in society: making a living or utilizing wealth. While it's true that political economy also involves plants, animals, and the earth—essentially everything studied by the natural sciences—it only pertains to them in relation to human welfare and how they influence our perception of value. It's relevant only in connection to the primary topic of economic interest: earning a living.

Character of the social sciences

2. The social sciences deal with men and their relations with each other. The word "social" comes from the Latin socius, meaning a fellow, comrade, companion, associate. As men living together have to do with each other in a great many different ways, and enter into a great many different relations, there arise a great many different social problems. Each of the social sciences attempts to study man in some one important aspect—that is, to view these relations from some one standpoint.

2. The social sciences focus on people and their relationships with one another. The term "social" comes from the Latin word socius, which means a fellow, comrade, companion, or associate. Since people living together interact in many different ways and form various types of relationships, many different social issues emerge. Each of the social sciences seeks to explore human behavior in a specific important aspect—that is, to examine these relationships from a particular perspective.

Man's acts, his life, and his motives are so complex that it is not surprising that there has been less definiteness in the thought of the social sciences, and that they have advanced less rapidly toward exactness in their conclusions, than have the natural sciences. This complexity also explains the discouragement of the beginner in the early lessons in this subject. Usually the greatest difficulties appear in the first few[Pg 6] weeks of its study. The thought is more abstract than in natural science; it requires a different, I will not say higher, kind of ability than does mathematics. But little by little the strangeness of the language and ideas disappears; the bare definitions become clothed with the facts of observation and recalled experiences; and soon the "economic" acts and relations of men in society come to be as real and as interesting to the student as are the materials in the natural world about him—often, indeed, more interesting.

Man's actions, his life, and his motivations are so complicated that it's not surprising there has been less clarity in social sciences, and that they've progressed more slowly toward precise conclusions compared to natural sciences. This complexity also helps to explain why beginners often feel discouraged during the early lessons in this subject. Typically, the toughest challenges arise in the first few[Pg 6] weeks of study. The concepts are more abstract than those in natural sciences; it requires a different, though not necessarily superior, type of ability than mathematics. But gradually, the unfamiliarity of the language and ideas fades away; the bare definitions become enriched with observable facts and personal experiences; and soon the “economic” actions and relationships among people in society feel as real and engaging to the student as the materials in the natural world around them—often, in fact, even more interesting.

Economics, politics, law, and ethics

3. Political economy is related to all the other social sciences, it being the study of certain of men's relations, while politics, law, and ethics have to do with other relations or with relations under a different aspect. Politics treats of the form and working of government and is mainly concerned with the question of power or control of the individual's actions and liberty. Law treats of the precepts and regulations in accordance with which the actions of men are limited by the state, and the contracts into which they have seen fit to enter are interpreted. Ethics treats the question of right or wrong, studies the moral aspects of men's acts and relations. The attempt just made to distinguish between the fields occupied by the various social sciences betrays at once the fundamental unity existing among them. The acts of men are closely related in their lives, but they may be looked at from different sides. The central thought in economics is the business relation, the relation of men in exchanging their services or material wealth. In pursuing economic inquiries we come into contact with political, legal, and ethical considerations, all of which must be recognized before a final practical answer can be given to any question. Nevertheless the province of economics is limited. It is because of the feebleness of our mental power that we divide and subdivide these complex questions and try to answer certain parts before we seek to answer the whole. When we attempt this final and more difficult task, we should rise to the standpoint of the social philosopher.

3. Political economy is connected to all the other social sciences, as it involves studying certain relationships among people, while politics, law, and ethics focus on different relationships or aspects of those relationships. Politics deals with how governments are structured and operate and is mainly about power or control over individuals' actions and freedoms. Law concerns the rules and regulations that limit people's actions by the state, as well as the interpretation of the contracts they choose to enter into. Ethics explores the concepts of right and wrong, examining the moral dimensions of people's actions and relationships. The effort to distinguish between the areas of the different social sciences reveals the fundamental unity that exists among them. People's actions are closely interconnected in their lives, but they can be viewed from various perspectives. The core idea in economics centers on business relationships, specifically how people exchange their services or material wealth. While conducting economic research, we encounter political, legal, and ethical issues that must be acknowledged before we can arrive at a practical answer to any question. However, the field of economics is limited. Our mental limitations lead us to break down and categorize these complex issues, tackling specific parts before addressing the whole. When we attempt to tackle this final and more challenging task, we should elevate our perspective to that of a social philosopher.

§ III. THE RELATION OF ECONOMICS TO PRACTICAL AFFAIRS

Economics is first a science

1. The ideal of political economy here set forth is that it should be a science, a search for truth, a systematized body of knowledge, arriving at a statement of the laws to which economic actions conform. It is not the advocacy of any particular policy or idea, but if it arrives at any conclusions, any truths, these cannot fail to affect the practical action of men.

1. The goal of political economy presented here is that it should be a science, a quest for truth, a structured collection of knowledge, leading to a clear understanding of the laws that govern economic actions. It doesn't promote any specific policy or idea, but if it reaches any conclusions or truths, these will inevitably influence people's actions in the real world.

But it touches many practical interests

Political economy, because defined as the science of wealth, has been described by some as a gospel of Mammon. It is hardly necessary to refute such a misconception. Political economy is not the science of wealth-getting for the individual. Its study is not primarily for the selfish ends and interest of the individual. (Certainly some of its lessons may be of practical value to men in active business) for many economic "principles" are but the general statement of those ideas that have been approved by the experience of business men, of statesmen, and of the masses of men. Some of its lessons must have educational value in practical business, for political economy is not dreamed out by the closet philosopher, but more and more it is the attempt to describe the interests and the action of the practical world in which men must live. Many men are working together to develop its study—those who collect statistics and facts bearing on all kinds of practical affairs, and those who search through the records of the past for illustrations of experiments and experiences that may help us in our life to-day.

Political economy, defined as the study of wealth, has been described by some as a gospel of Mammon. It's not necessary to challenge this misconception. Political economy isn't just about accumulating wealth for the individual. Its study isn't primarily focused on the selfish interests of one person. (Of course, some of its lessons can be practically useful for people in business) because many economic "principles" are simply a general reflection of ideas validated by the experiences of businesspeople, politicians, and the general public. Some lessons have educational value in practical business, as political economy isn't just a theory devised by an armchair philosopher; it increasingly aims to describe the interests and actions of the real world where people have to live. Many individuals are collaborating to advance this study—those who gather statistics and facts related to various practical matters and those who sift through historical records for examples of experiments and experiences that can assist us in our lives today.

Economic study needed in a democracy

2. But, in the main, the study of political economy is a social study for social ends and not a selfish study for individual advantage. The name political economy was first suggested in France when the government was monarchical and despotic in the extreme. As domestic economy indicates a set of rules or principles to guide wisely the action of the[Pg 8] housekeeper or the owner of an estate, so political economy was first thought of as a set of rules or principles to guide the king and his counselors in the control of the state. The term has continued to bear something of that suggestion in it, though of late the term "economics," as being broader and less likely to be confused with politics, has very generally come into use. But in the degree in which unlimited monarchy has given way to the rule of the people, the conception of political economy has been modified. In a democracy there is need for a general diffusion of knowledge. The power now rests not with the king and a few counselors, but in the last resort with the people, and therefore the people must be acquainted with the experience of the past, must have all possible systematic knowledge to enlighten public policy and to guide legislation.

2. Overall, the study of political economy is a social study aimed at social goals, not just a self-serving pursuit for individual gain. The term political economy was first introduced in France when the government was strictly monarchical and highly oppressive. Just as domestic economy refers to a set of rules or principles that wisely guide the actions of a[Pg 8] housekeeper or the owner of a property, political economy was originally imagined as a set of rules or principles to guide the king and his advisors in managing the state. The term has continued to carry some of that meaning, although recently the term "economics," which is broader and less likely to be confused with politics, has become widely used. However, as unlimited monarchy has shifted to the rule of the people, the concept of political economy has evolved. In a democracy, there is a need for widespread knowledge. Power now lies not with the king and a select few advisors but ultimately with the people, who must understand past experiences and possess all available systematic knowledge to inform public policy and guide legislation.

Is of growing interest and influence

Moreover, with the growth of the modern state, with the interest increasing importance of business, and of industrial and commercial interests, as compared with changes of dynasty or the personal rivalries of rulers, economic questions have grown in relative importance. In our own country, particularly since the subjects of slavery and of States' rights ceased to absorb the attention of our people, economic questions have pushed rapidly into the foreground. Indeed, it has of late been more clearly seen that many of the older political questions, such as the American Revolution and slavery, formerly discussed almost entirely in their political and constitutional aspects, were at bottom questions of economic rivalry and of economic welfare. The remarkable increase in the attention given to this study in colleges and universities in the last twenty years is but the index of the greatly increased interest and attention felt in it by citizens generally.

Moreover, with the rise of the modern state and the growing importance of business, along with industrial and commercial interests, compared to changes in leadership or personal rivalries among rulers, economic issues have become more significant. In our country, especially since the topics of slavery and States' rights stopped dominating the public’s attention, economic issues have quickly come to the forefront. In fact, it's become clearer recently that many older political issues, like the American Revolution and slavery, which were once discussed mainly in their political and constitutional contexts, were fundamentally about economic competition and well-being. The notable increase in focus on this subject in colleges and universities over the past twenty years reflects the heightened interest among citizens overall.

To sum up, it may be said that in the study of political economy we are seeking the reason, connection, and relations in the great multitude of acts arising out of the dependence of desires on the world of things and men.

To sum up, we can say that in studying political economy, we are looking for the reasons, connections, and relationships among the countless actions that come from the way our desires depend on the world of things and people.


CHAPTER 2

ECONOMIC MOTIVES

§ I. MATERIAL WANTS, THE PRIMARY ECONOMIC MOTIVES

Feeling urges to economic actions

1. A logical explanation of industry must begin with a discussion of the nature of wants, for the purpose of industry is to gratify wants. An economic want may be defined as a feeling of incompleteness, because of the lack of a part of the outer world or of some change in it. Often the question asked when one first sees a moving trolley car or automobile or bicycle is: What makes it go? The first question to ask in the part of the study of economic society here undertaken is: What is its motive force? Without an answer to that question one cannot hope to understand the ceaseless and varied activities of men occupied in the making of a living. The question merits long and careful study, but the general answer is so simple that it seems almost self-evident: The motive force in economics is found in the feelings of men. It is men's desire to make use of men and things about them which calls forth all the manifold phenomena studied in economics.

1. A logical explanation of industry must start with a discussion of the nature of wants, since the purpose of industry is to satisfy those wants. An economic want can be defined as a feeling of incompleteness due to lacking something from the outside world or needing some change in it. Often, when one first sees a moving trolley car, automobile, or bicycle, the question that comes to mind is: What makes it go? The first question to consider in this study of economic society is: What drives it? Without answering that question, it's hard to understand the endless and varied activities of people trying to make a living. This question deserves thorough and careful investigation, but the general answer is so straightforward that it seems almost obvious: The driving force in economics lies in human emotions. It’s people’s desire to utilize both other people and things around them that generates all the diverse phenomena explored in economics.

Animal species shaped by their environment

2. Wants among animals depend on the environment; that is to say, the utmost that creatures of a lower order than man can do is to take things as they find them. The imagination and intelligence of animals are not developed enough to lead them to desire much beyond that which is ordinarily to be obtained. And so the environment shapes and affects the animal. The fish is fitted to live in the water and thrives there, and we must believe, enjoys living there.[Pg 10] The horse and the cow like best the food of the fields, and so each species of animal, in order to survive in the severe struggle for existence, has been forced to fit itself to the conditions in which it lives. After the animal has been thus fitted, its desire is for those things normally to be found in its surroundings. So different animals desire or want different things, but always it is the environment that determines the want, and not the want that determines the environment.

2. Animals' needs are influenced by their environment; essentially, the most that creatures lower than humans can do is accept things as they are. Animals don’t have the imagination and intelligence to want much beyond what is usually available. So, their environment shapes and influences them. Fish are adapted to live happily in water, and we can assume they enjoy it there.[Pg 10] Horses and cows prefer the food found in the fields, so each species has adapted to survive in the harsh reality of existence. Once adapted, their desires align with what they typically find in their surroundings. Different animals want different things, but ultimately, it's always the environment that dictates those wants, not the wants that shape the environment.

Simple wants of primitive men

3. In simpler human societies, wants are mostly confined to physical necessities; that is, in the earlier stages of society, man's wants are very much like those of the animals. Man bends his energies to securing the things necessary to survival. He feels the pangs of hunger and he strives to secure food. He feels the need of companionship, for it is only through association and mutual help that men, so weak as compared with many kinds of animals, are able to resist the enemies which beset them. He needs clothing to protect him against the harsher climates of the lands to which he moves. For the same purpose, to protect himself against the cold and rain, he needs a shelter, a cave, a wigwam, or a hut; for a house is but a larger dress.

3. In simpler human societies, people mainly focus on basic needs; during the early stages of society, human desires are quite similar to those of animals. People direct their efforts toward getting the essentials for survival. They experience hunger and work hard to find food. They feel the need for companionship because it’s only through working together and supporting one another that humans, who are much weaker than many animals, can fend off the threats around them. They need clothing to shield themselves from harsher climates in the areas they inhabit. For the same reason, to protect against cold and rain, they need shelter, whether it’s a cave, a wigwam, or a hut; after all, a house is just a larger form of clothing.

Manifold wants in civilized society

4. In human society, wants develop and transform the world. In the rudest societies of which there is any record, savages are found with wants developed in a great number of directions beyond the wants of any animals. Man is not a passive victim of circumstances; his wants are not determined solely by his environment; his desires soar beyond the things about him. As men become more the masters of circumstances, their desires anticipate mere physical wants; they seek a more varied food of finer flavor and more delicately prepared. Dress is not limited by physical comfort, for one of the earliest of the esthetic wants to develop is the love of personal ornament. The rude hut or communal lodge to protect against rain and cold becomes a home. Out of the earlier rude companionship develop the[Pg 11] noblest sentiments of friendship and family life. Seeking to gratify the senses and the love of action, men develop esthetic tastes, the love of the beautiful in sound, in form, in taste, in color, in motion. And finally, as the imagination and intellect develop, there grow up the various forms of intellectual pleasures—the love of reading, of study, of travel, and of thought.

4. In human society, wants develop and transform the world. In the most primitive societies recorded, people are found with wants that extend far beyond those of any animals. Humans are not just passive victims of their surroundings; their wants aren’t determined only by their environment; their desires reach beyond the immediate things around them. As people gain more control over their circumstances, their desires move beyond basic physical needs; they look for more diverse and tastier food that is prepared with greater care. Clothing goes beyond just physical comfort, as one of the earliest aesthetic wants to emerge is the desire for personal adornment. The basic shelter that protects against rain and cold evolves into a home. From early simple companionship, the[Pg 11] noblest feelings of friendship and family life develop. In seeking to satisfy their senses and their desire for activity, people cultivate aesthetic tastes, appreciating beauty in sound, form, flavor, color, and movement. Finally, as imagination and intellect advance, various forms of intellectual enjoyment arise—the love of reading, studying, traveling, and thinking.

The various wants of man are sometimes classified as necessities, comforts, and luxuries, but all economists take care to emphasize that these terms have only relative meanings which, in the rapidly changing conditions of modern life, are changing constantly. The comforts of one generation, or of one country, become the necessities in another; and luxuries becoming comforts, are looked upon finally as necessities. And as the desires grow, they more and more alter the world. Man has changed the face of the earth; he has affected its climate, its fertility, its beauty, because, either for better or for worse, his desires have impressed themselves upon the world about him.

The different needs of people are often categorized as necessities, comforts, and luxuries, but all economists emphasize that these terms are relative and constantly changing in our fast-paced modern world. What was considered a comfort in one generation or country can become a necessity in another; luxuries can become comforts and eventually be seen as necessities. As desires increase, they increasingly transform the world. People have altered the earth's landscape; they've impacted its climate, fertility, and beauty, because, for better or worse, their desires have left a mark on the world around them.

Wants must precede wealth

5. In human society the growth of wants is necessary to progress. From the earliest times teachers of morals have argued for simplicity of life and against the development of refinements. We do not now raise the moral question, but there is no doubt that the economic effect of developing wants is in the main to impel to greater effort. They are the mainspring of economic progress. In recent discussion of the control of the tropics, the too great contentedness of tropical peoples has been brought out prominently. Some one has said that if a colony of New England school-teachers and Presbyterian deacons should settle in the tropics, their descendants would, in a single generation, be wearing breech-clouts and going to cock-fights on Sunday. Certain it is that the energy and ambition of the temperate zone are hard to maintain in warmer lands. The negro's content with hard conditions, so often counted as a virtue, is one of the difficulties in the way of solving the race problem in our[Pg 12] South to-day. Booker T. Washington, and others who are laboring for the elevation of the American negroes, would try first to make them discontented with the one-room cabins, in which hundreds of thousands of families live. If only the desire for a two- or three-room cabin can be aroused, experience shows that family life and industrial qualities may be improved in many other ways.

5. In human society, the desire for more is essential for progress. Since ancient times, moral teachers have advocated for a simple life and opposed the rise of luxuries. We aren’t discussing the moral implications now, but it’s clear that developing desires mainly drives people to put in more effort. They are the driving force behind economic progress. Recently, in discussions about controlling tropical regions, the excessive contentment of tropical populations has been highlighted. Someone once remarked that if a group of New England teachers and Presbyterian deacons settled in the tropics, their descendants would, within one generation, end up wearing minimal clothing and participating in cockfights on Sundays. It's certain that the energy and ambition found in temperate climates are difficult to sustain in hotter areas. The satisfaction that some individuals of African descent find in harsh conditions, often seen as a virtue, creates challenges in addressing the race issues we face in our[Pg 12] South today. Booker T. Washington and others working for the advancement of African Americans aim to first instill a sense of discontent with the single-room homes that hundreds of thousands of families live in. If they can spark a desire for a two- or three-room home, experience shows that family life and work skills can improve in many other respects.

But impossible hopes lessen gratifications

Not only in America, but in most civilized lands to-day, is seen a rapid growth of wants in the working-classes. The incomes and the standard of living have become increasing, but not so fast as have the desires of the working-classes. Regret has been expressed by some that the workers of Europe are becoming "declassed." Increasing wages, it is said, bring not welfare, but unhappiness, to the complaining masses. If discontent with one's lot goes beyond a moderate degree, if it is more than the desire to better one's lot by personal efforts, if it becomes an unhappy longing for the impossible, then indeed it may be a misfortune. But a moderate ambition to better one's condition is the "divine discontent" absolutely indispensable if energy and enterprise are to be called into being.

Not just in America, but in most developed countries today, there's a rapid increase in the needs of the working class. Incomes and living standards have been rising, but not as quickly as the desires of the working class. Some people are concerned that workers in Europe are becoming "declassed." It's said that higher wages don’t necessarily bring happiness, but rather discontent among the complaining masses. If dissatisfaction with one's situation goes beyond a reasonable limit, if it turns into more than just a desire to improve one's circumstances through personal effort, and instead becomes an unhappy craving for the unattainable, then it could indeed be a negative thing. However, a reasonable ambition to improve one's situation is the "divine discontent" that is completely necessary if we want to spark energy and initiative.

Wants grow refined as wealth advances

It is a suggestive fact that civilized man, equipped with all of the inventions and the advantages of science, spends more hours of effort in gaining a livelihood than does the savage with his almost unaided hands. Activity is dependent not on bare physical necessity, but on developed wants—in the economic sense of the term. Such social institutions as property and inheritance owe their origin and their justification to their average effect on the motives to activity. If society is to develop, if progress is to continue, human wants—not of the grosser sort, but ever more refined—must continue to emerge and urge men to action.

It’s interesting that modern humans, armed with all the inventions and advancements of science, put in more effort to earn a living than a primitive person does using just their hands. Activity isn't driven solely by basic physical needs but by more advanced wants—in the economic sense. Social structures like property and inheritance exist and are justified based on their overall impact on people’s motivation to work. For society to grow and progress to move forward, human desires—not the most basic ones, but increasingly sophisticated ones—must keep arising and inspiring people to take action.

§ II. DESIRES FOR NON-MATERIAL ENDS, AS SECONDARY ECONOMIC MOTIVES

The real man in economics

1. The spiritual nature of man must not be ignored in economic reasoning. There has been much and just criticism of the earlier writers and of their conclusions because so little account was taken by them of any but the motive of self-interest in economic affairs. Generally it was assumed that men knew their own interest, and sought in a very unsympathetic way those things which would gratify their material wants. Thus man in economic reasoning was made an abstraction, differing from real men in his lack of manifold spiritual and social elements.

1. We can’t overlook the spiritual side of humanity in economic thinking. There has been a lot of valid criticism of earlier writers and their conclusions because they focused almost entirely on self-interest in economic matters. It was generally assumed that people understood their own interests and pursued, in a rather indifferent manner, the things that would satisfy their material needs. As a result, the idea of man in economic discussions became a simplified version, lacking the complex spiritual and social aspects found in real individuals.

Desires for the non-material may become economic motives

2. The main classes of non-material wants that are secondarily economic are fear of temporal punishment; sentiments of moral and religious duty; pride, honor, and fear of disgrace; and pleasure in work for itself, for social approval, or for a social result. The first is best illustrated by slavery, where the slave is not impelled to seek wealth for his own welfare, but is driven by punishment to perform the task. The object is to create within the mind of the slave a motive that will take the place of the ordinary economic motive. The feeling of religious or moral duty leads men to act often in direct opposition to the usual economic motive. The taboo is faithfully observed by the members of a savage tribe who suffer as a result the severest hardships. A religious injunction prevents the use of food that would save from starvation. Pride, either of family or of calling; the soldier's honor leading him to sacrifice not only his future but his life; the love of social approval, holding men to the most disagreeable tasks—these illustrate how strongly social sentiments oppose the narrower motive of immediate self-interest as generally thought of. Pleasure in work for work's sake, and pride in the result, may act as motives quite as strong in some cases as desire for the product that can[Pg 14] be used. And even where this does not change the kind of work done, it comes in to influence the interest and earnestness with which the work is performed.

2. The main types of non-material wants that are indirectly economic include fear of punishment, feelings of moral and religious obligation, pride, honor, fear of disgrace, and enjoyment of work for its own sake, for social approval, or for a societal outcome. The best example of this is slavery, where the slave isn’t motivated to pursue wealth for their own benefit but is compelled by the fear of punishment to carry out their duties. The goal is to instill a motivation in the slave's mind that replaces the typical economic drive. Feelings of religious or moral obligation often lead people to act in ways that go against conventional economic incentives. Members of a tribal community may strictly follow taboos, enduring significant hardships as a result. A religious command might prevent them from eating food that could save them from starvation. Pride in one's family or profession, a soldier's sense of honor driving them to sacrifice their future and even their life, and the desire for social approval that pushes individuals into unpleasant tasks—these examples show how powerful social feelings can be in opposition to the more straightforward motive of personal gain as typically understood. Enjoyment of work for its own sake, and pride in its outcome, can sometimes serve as potent motivations just as strong as the desire for tangible rewards that can[Pg 14] be utilized. Even when this doesn’t change the type of work being done, it influences the level of interest and dedication with which the work is carried out.

Economists must overlook no influence on value

3. Whatever motive in man's complex nature makes him desire things more or less, becomes for the time, and in so far, an economic motive. These various social and spiritual motives sometimes work positively, in the direction of magnifying man's desire for things; sometimes negatively, to diminish it. If we are to understand economic action, we must take men as they are. A religious motive that leads men to refrain from the eating of meat or to eat fish in preference on certain days, is a fact which the economist has but to accept, for it is sure to affect the value of meat and fish at that place and time. Moral convictions, whatever be their origin, whether due to the teaching of parents, to unconscious influences, or to native temperament, may be quite as effective as the pangs of hunger in determining what men desire. Therefore, while these various motives are primarily social or moral or religious, they may be said to be secondarily economic motives, and they may become in certain cases the most important influences of which the economist must take account.

3. Whatever drives people to want things, whether a lot or a little, becomes an economic motive at that moment and to that extent. These different social and spiritual reasons can either increase or decrease a person's desire for things. To understand economic actions, we need to look at people as they are. If a religious belief causes someone to avoid eating meat or to prefer fish on certain days, that's something economists must recognize, as it will definitely impact the value of meat and fish in that time and place. Moral beliefs, regardless of their source—whether from parental guidance, unconscious influences, or natural temperament—can be just as powerful as hunger in shaping what people want. So, while these various motives are mainly social, moral, or religious, they can also be seen as secondary economic motives and can become, in some cases, the most significant factors that economists need to consider.


CHAPTER 3

WEALTH AND WELFARE

§ I. THE RELATION OF MEN AND MATERIAL THINGS TO ECONOMIC WELFARE

Man is the center of economic reasoning

1. The gratifying of economic wants depends on things outside of the man who feels the wants. Man is to himself the center of the world. He groups things and estimates things with reference to their bearing on his desires, be these what are called selfish or unselfish. If we were discussing the economics of an inferior species of animals, things would be grouped in a very different way. But economics being the study of man's welfare, everything must be judged from his standpoint, and things are or are not of economic importance according as they have relation to his wants and satisfactions. Things needful for any of the lower animals are spoken of as "ministering to welfare" in the economic sense only in case these animals are useful to men. Examples are the mulberry-tree on which the silkworm feeds, the flower visited by the honey-bee. In the same view some men are seen to minister to the welfare of other men and therefore bear the same relation for the moment to the welfare of the others as do material things. In any case we study man's welfare as affected by the world which surrounds him.

1. Satisfying economic needs relies on factors beyond the person experiencing those needs. A person sees themselves as the center of their world. They categorize and assess things based on how they relate to their wants, whether those wants are considered selfish or unselfish. If we were talking about the economics of a less advanced species, the categorization would look quite different. However, since economics focuses on human welfare, everything must be evaluated from a human perspective, and things are deemed economically significant based on their connection to human wants and satisfaction. The needs of lower animals are only described as "contributing to welfare" in an economic sense if those animals serve a purpose for humans. Examples include the mulberry tree, which feeds the silkworm, and the flower that the honeybee visits. Similarly, some people help meet the needs of others, thus relating to their welfare just like material items do. Ultimately, we analyze human welfare in relation to the surrounding world.

Physical nature is an unchangeable fact

2. Material things and natural forces differ in kind and nature. This is an axiom which we must take as a basis for reasoning in economics. Things have certain physical qualities quite apart from any action or influence of man.[Pg 16] They are operated on by mechanical laws; the force of gravitation causes them to fall at a certain rate under given conditions. They differ in specific gravity, reflect the rays of light, absorb or transmit heat. All these things are for man ultimate physical facts, but unless he knows these facts he cannot take full advantage of the favorable qualities of things or weigh properly their importance to his welfare. Things differ in a multitude of ways in their chemical qualities. Niter, charcoal, and saltpeter, combined in certain proportions, give certain reactions; different combinations give various results. Solids combine to form gases, and liquids unite to form solids, and these qualities and reactions of material things are for man ultimate truths of chemistry. Likewise many things have certain physiological effects. Sunshine acts on living bodies, whether plant, animal, or man, in certain ways. Some plants are nourishing to man, others are poisonous. If man were not on the earth, things would have the same physical and chemical qualities, mechanical laws would be the same as at present so far as we can conclude. Man cannot change the nature of things; but he can acquaint himself with that nature and then put the things into the relations where a given result will follow.

2. Material things and natural forces are fundamentally different. This is a basic principle that we need to use as a foundation for economic reasoning. Objects have specific physical properties that exist independently of any human action or influence.[Pg 16] They are governed by mechanical laws; for example, gravity causes them to fall at a predictable rate under certain conditions. They vary in density, reflect light, and either absorb or transmit heat. All of these aspects are essential physical facts for humans, but without understanding these facts, we can't fully leverage the beneficial properties of these objects or accurately assess their importance to our well-being. Objects also differ in many ways in their chemical properties. For instance, when niter, charcoal, and saltpeter are mixed in specific ratios, they produce certain reactions; different mixtures yield varying results. Solids can combine to create gases, and liquids can merge to form solids, and these properties and interactions among materials represent fundamental truths of chemistry for humans. Similarly, many things have specific physiological effects. Sunshine impacts living organisms—plants, animals, and humans—in predictable ways. Some plants provide nourishment to people, while others are toxic. If humans didn't exist on Earth, objects would retain their physical and chemical properties, and mechanical laws would remain unchanged as far as we can infer. Humans cannot alter the nature of things; however, they can understand that nature and arrange materials in ways that will lead to specific outcomes.

But economics has to do with psychological effects

3. As a result of these differences, things have different relations to wants. These various qualities, physical, chemical, physiological, are important in an economic sense only as they produce psychological effects, that is, as they affect the feelings and judgments of men. We come to some general thoughts which it will be well to define.

3. Because of these differences, things have different relationships to wants. These various qualities, whether physical, chemical, or physiological, matter economically only as they create psychological effects, meaning they influence people's feelings and judgments. We reach some broader ideas that it's important to clarify.

Some definitions

Gratification is the feeling that results when a want has been met. Feelings are hard to define in words; the best definition is found in the experience of each individual. We can only say, therefore, that gratification is the attainment of desire, the fulfilment of wants. The word that has usually been employed in this sense in economic discussion is "satisfaction"; but by its derivation and general usage satisfaction[Pg 17] means "the complete or full gratification" of a desire, and this meaning is quite inconsistent with the thought in many connections in which the word is used. We shall therefore prefer here the word gratification, and its corresponding verb, gratify.

Gratification is the feeling you get when a desire is fulfilled. Feelings are tough to describe in words; the best way to define them is through personal experience. So, we can say that gratification is achieving what you desire and getting what you want. In economic discussions, the term "satisfaction" has often been used in this context; however, its origin and common usage imply "the complete or full gratification" of a desire, which doesn't fit well in many scenarios where it's used. Therefore, we will prefer the term gratification and its related verb, gratify.

Wealth is the collective term for those things which are felt to be related to the gratification of wants. The word is applied in economic discussion to any part of those things, no matter how small. We shall have occasion later to define and discuss this term more fully.

Wealth is the general term for things that are considered to satisfy wants. In economic discussions, the term refers to any part of those things, no matter how small. Later, we'll define and discuss this term in more detail.

Welfare, in an immediate or narrow sense, is the same as gratification of the moment; in a broader sense, it means the abiding condition of well-being. We have here a distinction very much like that often made between pleasure and happiness. If we think of only the present moment, welfare is the absence of pain, and the presence of the pleasureable feeling; but if we consider a longer period in a man's life or his entire lifetime, it is seen that many things that afford a momentary gratification do not minister to his ultimate, or abiding, welfare. Moralists and philosophers often have dwelt on this contrast. The difference is illustrated by the thoughtlessness and impulsiveness of a child or savage as contrasted with the more rational life of those with foresight and patience.

Welfare, in a immediate or narrow sense, is the same as instant gratification; in a broader sense, it refers to a lasting state of well-being. This distinction is similar to the one often made between pleasure and happiness. If we only think about the present moment, welfare is the lack of pain and the presence of pleasurable feelings; however, if we consider a longer stretch of a person's life or their entire lifetime, it becomes clear that many things that provide momentary satisfaction do not contribute to their ultimate, or lasting, welfare. Moralists and philosophers have frequently emphasized this contrast. The difference is highlighted by the thoughtless and impulsive behavior of a child or savage compared to the more rational approach of those who possess foresight and patience.

Economics first studies wealth

Wealth, in the general economic sense, is judged with reference to gratification rather than with reference to abiding welfare. It is the first duty of the economist not to preach what should be, but to understand things as they are. He must, in studying the problem of value, recognize any motive that leads men to attach importance to acts and things. He will therefore take account of abiding welfare and of immediate gratification to exactly the degree that men in general do, and the sad fact is that the present impulse rules a large part of the acts of men. Whether tobacco or alcohol or morphine minister to the abiding happiness of those who use them does not alter the immediate fact that[Pg 18] here and now they are sought and an importance is attached to them because of their power to gratify an immediate desire.

Wealth, in a general economic sense, is assessed based on satisfaction rather than lasting well-being. The main role of an economist is not to advocate for what should happen, but to grasp things as they are. In analyzing the issue of value, he must acknowledge any reasons that lead people to value certain actions and things. Therefore, he will consider both lasting well-being and immediate satisfaction to the extent that people in general do, and the unfortunate reality is that current desires heavily influence a significant portion of human actions. Whether tobacco, alcohol, or morphine contribute to the long-term happiness of their users doesn’t change the immediate fact that[Pg 18] right now, they are sought after and valued for their ability to satisfy a current desire.

Then wealth and welfare

5. In studying the question of social prosperity, however, we must rise to the standpoint of the social philosopher and consider the more abiding effects of wealth. Wants may be developed and made rational, and the permanent prosperity of a community depends upon this result. Any species of animal that continued regularly to enjoy that which weakens the health and strength would become extinct. Any society or individual that continues to derive gratification, to seek its pleasure, in ways that do not, on the average, minister to permanent welfare, sinks in the struggle of life and gives way to those men or nations that have a sounder and healthier adjustment of wants and welfare. We touch here, therefore, on the edge of the great problems of morals, and while we must recognize the contrast that often exists in the life of any particular man between his "pleasures" and his health and happiness, we see that there is a reason why, on the whole, and in the long run, these two cannot remain far apart. The old proverbs, "Be virtuous and you will be happy," "Honesty is the best policy," and "Virtue is its own reward," have a sound basis in the age-long experience of the world. Cynics or jesters may easily disprove these truths in a multitude of particular cases.

5. When examining the question of social prosperity, we need to take a step back and look at it from the perspective of a social philosopher, focusing on the lasting impacts of wealth. Desires can be developed and made reasonable, and the lasting prosperity of a community relies on this outcome. Any animal that consistently consumes things that harm its health and strength would eventually die out. Likewise, any society or individual that continues to find satisfaction in ways that generally do not contribute to lasting well-being will struggle in life and give way to those people or nations that have a healthier and more balanced approach to their needs and welfare. We thus touch on significant moral issues, and while we must acknowledge the frequent conflict in a person's life between their "pleasures" and their health and happiness, we recognize that, overall and in the long term, these two aspects cannot remain too far apart. The old sayings, "Be virtuous and you will be happy," "Honesty is the best policy," and "Virtue is its own reward," are grounded in the timeless experiences of humanity. Cynics or jokers might easily challenge these truths with numerous specific examples.

Freemen are not economic wealth

6. Wealth does not include such personal qualities as honesty, integrity, good health. Some economists speak of these as "internal goods," but it is far better not to speak of free men or of their qualities as wealth. Many difficulties arise from such a use of the term in practical discussion. One of the most important of all distinctions to maintain in economics is that between material things and men. Only in the case of human slavery may persons be counted as economic wealth. It is a different thing, however, to consider human services as wealth of an ephemeral kind at the moment they are rendered. We are, thus merely recognizing[Pg 19] that men may bear at the given moment the same relation to our wants as do material things.

6. Wealth doesn’t include personal qualities like honesty, integrity, or good health. Some economists refer to these as "internal goods," but it's better not to define free individuals or their qualities as wealth. Using the term this way causes many issues in practical discussions. One of the most important distinctions to maintain in economics is between material things and people. Individuals can only be considered economic wealth in the context of human slavery. However, it's different to classify human services as a temporary form of wealth when they are provided. We are simply recognizing[Pg 19] that, at any given moment, people may fulfill our needs in the same way that material things do.

§ II. SOME IMPORTANT ECONOMIC CONCEPTS CONNECTED WITH WEALTH AND WELFARE

Popular meaning of useful

1. Utility, in its broadest usage, is the general capability that things have of ministering to human well being. The term is evidently one without any scientific precision. It expresses only a general or average impression that we have in reference to the relation of a class of goods to human wants. Every one would agree to the statement that "water is useful," thinking of the fact that it is indispensable to life and that it ministers to life in a multitude of ways. But what of water in one's cellar, water soaking one's clothes on a cold day, water breaking through the walls of a mountain reservoir and carrying death and destruction in its path? The poison that is doing what we at the moment desire, we call useful; that doing what we would prevent, we call harmful. Noxious weeds become "useful" by the discovery of some new process by which they can be worked into other forms, though they may still continue to be noxious in many a farmer's fields. The utility of anything, therefore, is seen to be of a relative and limited nature. The term "utility" in popular speech is very inexact. It can be employed in economic discussion only when carefully modified and defined.

1. Utility, in its broadest sense, refers to the general ability of things to contribute to human well-being. The term clearly lacks precise scientific meaning. It simply reflects a general or average idea we have about how a category of goods relates to human needs. Most people would agree that "water is useful," considering that it is essential for life and supports it in many ways. However, what about water in your basement, water soaking your clothes on a chilly day, or water breaking through the walls of a dam and causing chaos and destruction? The harmful substance that fulfills our immediate desires is labeled useful; the one that we wish to avoid is labeled harmful. Harmful weeds can become "useful" once we find a new way to utilize them, even if they still remain troublesome in many farmers' fields. Thus, the utility of anything is clearly relative and limited. The term "utility" in everyday conversation is quite vague. It can only be used in economic discussions when carefully clarified and defined.

Kinds of goods

2. Goods consist of all those things objective to the user which have a beneficial relation to human wants. They fall into several classes. We may first distinguish between free and economic goods. Free goods are things that exist in superfluity, that is, in quantities sufficient not only to gratify, but to satisfy all the wants that may depend on them. Economic goods are things so limited in quantity that all of the wants to which they could minister are not satisfied. The whole thought of economy begins with scarcity; indeed,[Pg 20] even the conception of free goods is hardly possible until some limitation of wants is experienced. Practical economics is the study of the best way to employ things to secure the highest amount of gratification. The problem itself arises out of the fact that many things are used up before all wants dependent on them are completely satisfied.

2. Goods are all the things that are useful to people and have value in meeting human needs. They can be divided into different categories. First, we can distinguish between free goods and economic goods. Free goods are those that are available in abundance, meaning there are enough to satisfy all the related wants. Economic goods, on the other hand, are limited in supply, so not all wants that depend on them can be fulfilled. The entire concept of economics starts with scarcity; in fact, [Pg 20] the idea of free goods is almost impossible to understand without experiencing some limitation of needs. Practical economics focuses on finding the best ways to use resources to achieve the greatest satisfaction. This challenge occurs because many resources are exhausted before all related wants are fully met.

A distinction is often made between consumption and production goods, or it may be better to say immediate and intermediate goods. Consumption goods are those things which are immediately at the point of gratifying man's desires. Production goods are those things which are not yet ready to gratify desires; some of them, being merely means of securing consumption goods, never will themselves immediately gratify desire.

A distinction is often made between consumer goods and producer goods, or it might be more accurate to say immediate and intermediate goods. Consumer goods are items that directly satisfy people's wants. Producer goods are items that aren't yet ready to satisfy those wants; some of them, being just means to obtain consumer goods, will never directly satisfy a desire themselves.

Value is utility given precision

3. Value, in the narrow personal sense, may be defined as the importance attributed to a good by a man. The vagueness and inexactness of the word "utility," or the word "good," disappears when we reach the word "value." It is not a usual relation or a vague degree of benefit sometimes present and sometimes absent, but it refers to a particular thing, person, time, and condition. Value is in the closest relation with wants, and in this narrow sense depends on the individual's estimate. From the meeting and comparison of the estimates of individuals, arise market values or prices, which are the central object of study in economics.

3. Value, in a personal sense, can be defined as the importance that a person assigns to a good. The ambiguity and vagueness of the terms "utility" or "good" fade away when we talk about "value." It’s not just a general relationship or an unclear level of benefit that can be present at times and absent at others; it specifically refers to a unique thing, person, time, and situation. Value is closely linked to our wants, and in this personal sense, it relies on an individual’s judgment. From the gathering and comparison of these individual judgments, market values or prices emerge, which are the main focus of study in economics.


CHAPTER 4

THE NATURE OF DEMAND

§ I. THE COMPARISON OF GOODS IN MAN'S THOUGHT

Wants and goods must be constantly adjusted

1. As wants differ in kind and degree, so goods differ in their power to gratify wants. This general and simple statement unites the leading thoughts of the two chapters preceding. Confirmation of its truth may be found in observation and experience. The purpose of this chapter is to show how, starting from the general nature of wants and the nature of goods, we can arrive at an explanation of the exchange of goods. Recognizing the simple but fundamental fact stated at the opening of this paragraph, an exchange may be seen to be a rational and a logical result when men are living together in society.

1. As desires vary in type and intensity, so do goods vary in their ability to satisfy those desires. This straightforward statement connects the main ideas from the two preceding chapters. We can confirm its validity through observation and experience. The goal of this chapter is to explain how, starting from the basic nature of desires and the nature of goods, we can understand the exchange of goods. Acknowledging the simple yet essential fact mentioned at the beginning of this paragraph, we can see that exchange is a rational and logical outcome when people coexist in society.

Ripe and unripe goods

2. Immediately enjoyable goods are the first objective things whose value is to be explained. Goods come into relation with wants in a multitude of ways. Some things will not gratify a want until after the lapse of a long time, as ice cut in December and stored for summer use. Other things will never themselves directly gratify a want, but will be of help in getting things that do; such are the young fruit trees planted in the orchard, and the hammer that will be used to drive nails in a house that will shelter men. Still other things are gratifying wants at this moment, or are ready for use and will be used up in a very short time; examples of such are the food on the table and in the pantry, and the cigar in the pocket. All these things are called goods, because of their beneficial relation to man's desires, but the[Pg 22] relation is very immediate in some cases, very remote in others. The value of all goods is to be explained, but the explanation will be more or less complex according to the directness or indirectness of their relation with wants. As it is the power of goods to gratify wants that alone causes value to be attributed to them, those goods which are ripest, which are ready to gratify wants, are nearest to the source of an explanation. The value of unripe enjoyments must be traced to some expected gratification as its cause or basis. In order to attack the difficulties one by one we will, therefore, in the following discussion, deal first with this class of ripe, consumable goods, as food, personal services, enjoyments of any sort that are immediately available. The explanation of these cases of value must precede that of cases in which the relation to wants is less obvious and direct.

2. Immediately enjoyable goods are the first objective items whose value needs to be explained. Goods relate to wants in many ways. Some items won’t satisfy a need until a long time has passed, like ice cut in December and stored for summer. Other items might never directly satisfy a need but will help in obtaining things that do, such as young fruit trees planted in an orchard or the hammer used to drive nails into a house for shelter. Then there are items that are fulfilling wants right now or are ready to be used up quickly, like the food on the table and in the pantry, or the cigar in your pocket. All these items are called goods because of their beneficial relationship to human desires, but the[Pg 22] relationship varies greatly; in some cases, it’s very immediate, while in others, it’s quite distant. The value of all goods needs to be explained, but the complexity of the explanation will depend on how direct or indirect their connection to wants is. Since it's the ability of goods to satisfy wants that gives them value, those that are most ready to fulfill wants are closest to the core of this explanation. The value of unripe goods has to be traced back to some expected gratification as its cause or foundation. To tackle the challenges one at a time, we will first discuss this category of ripe, consumable goods—such as food, personal services, and available enjoyments. Understanding these cases of value must come before examining cases where the relationship to wants is less clear and direct.

The law of diminishing utility

3. As the amount of any good increases, after a certain point the gratification that the added portions afford decreases. This is called the law of the diminishing utility of goods or of the decreasing gratification afforded by goods. The reason for the truth of this proposition is found in the very nature of man and his nervous organization. Any stimulus to the nerves, however pleasant at first, becomes painful when long continued or increased unduly. The trumpet too distant at first for the ear to distinguish its notes, may swell to pleasing tones as it approaches, until at length its volume and its din may become absolutely painful. If we were to express the degree of gratification by a curve, we should see the curve rising gradually to a maximum, and then falling somewhat suddenly and becoming a negative quantity, when pain, not pleasure, resulted. The same change could be illustrated by any sensation or by any of men's activities.

3. As the amount of any good increases, after a certain point, the satisfaction that the extra portions provide diminishes. This is known as the law of diminishing utility of goods or the decreasing satisfaction provided by goods. The reason this is true lies in human nature and our nervous system. Any stimulus to the nerves, no matter how enjoyable at the beginning, can become uncomfortable if it's prolonged or too intense. A trumpet that's initially too far away for the ear to make out its notes may produce pleasing sounds as it gets closer, but eventually, its volume and noise can become downright unbearable. If we were to represent the level of satisfaction on a graph, we would see it rising gradually to a peak and then dropping somewhat sharply, eventually becoming negative when pain, rather than pleasure, occurs. This same pattern can be seen in any sensation or in various human activities.

The proposition must be understood as applying to the gratification resulting from each added portion of the sensation. There is a maximum point in the gratification afforded by any nerve-stimulus. A man coming in from[Pg 23] the winter's storm and holding out his hands before the fire, feels an intense pleasure in the grateful warmth; a few moments later, the same heat becomes unpleasant. In winter we wish for a moderation of the temperature; on the sultry days of summer, we think of a cool breeze as the most to be desired of all things. Whether the temperature rises or falls, there is a point beyond which the change is no longer an addition to, but a subtraction from, pleasure. A man, however hungry at first, may be made miserable if forced to eat beyond his capacity. Each added portion of the good consumed contributes to the gratification up to a certain point. The sum of these pleasurable sensations may be called the total gratification, which finally reaches satisfaction or fullness. Then begins what may be called in algebraic phrase a "negative gratification" which, if it becomes large enough, will make the total gratification a negative quantity. Each added portion, dose or increment beyond a certain point reduces thus the welfare of the user. One may have too much of a good thing.

The idea here is about how we feel satisfaction from each addition of a particular sensation. There’s a limit to how much pleasure any nerve stimulus can provide. For example, a person coming in from a winter storm and warming their hands by the fire feels a strong pleasure from the heat, but after a few moments, that same warmth can become uncomfortable. In winter, we want it to be a bit warmer; during the hot summer days, we long for a cool breeze. Whether it gets hotter or colder, there’s a point where changes stop adding to our pleasure and start taking away from it. A person who is very hungry might feel miserable if they’re forced to eat more than they can handle. Each extra bit of something good adds to our pleasure up to a point. The total amount of these pleasurable feelings can be called total gratification, which eventually reaches a point of satisfaction or fullness. After that, we enter what could be thought of as “negative gratification,” which, if it becomes significant enough, will turn our total gratification into a negative experience. Each additional bit, dose, or increment beyond a certain point actually decreases the user’s well-being. It’s true that you can have too much of a good thing.

The marginal utility

4. Marginal utility is the gratification afforded by the added portion of the good. The marginal dose, increment, or portion is that which may be logically considered as coming last in the case of any good or group of goods divisible into small parts. In considering the strict theory of the case, in order to get at the principle involved, the doses may be spoken of as infinitesimally small. The marginal utility expresses the importance that men attach to one unit of this kind of goods under the particular circumstances at the moment existing, and not under certain conceivable conditions which do not in fact exist or need to be taken into account by the persons affected. The marginal unit of a homogeneous supply cannot be considered to have a greater utility than any other unit at the moment, and therefore the product of the marginal utility by the number of units, gives the total measure of importance of the supply then and there, and this is the value.

4. Marginal utility is the satisfaction gained from an additional amount of a good. The marginal dose, increment, or portion is what can logically be regarded as the last in any good or group of goods that can be divided into smaller parts. When examining the strict theory of the case to understand the principles involved, these doses can be referred to as infinitesimally small. The marginal utility represents the value that people assign to one unit of this type of good given the specific circumstances at that moment, rather than under hypothetical conditions that don't actually exist or that the individuals involved do not need to consider. The marginal unit of a uniform supply cannot be deemed to have more utility than any other unit at that moment, so multiplying the marginal utility by the number of units gives the total measure of importance of the supply at that time, which is the value.

The value of goods, as has been indicated, is the measure of the dependence felt by men on a portion of the outer world, as the condition of gratifying their wants. From the very nature of wants, which reside in feelings, a dependence that is not felt, a relation between things and gratification that is not recognized, can have no influence on value. Now, it is at this margin of supply that dependence is felt. Men do not concern themselves about that which they have in superfluity—unless, indeed, the excess causes them some discomfort. It is well that they do not, for a wise direction of effort can only take place when men think mainly of their need of things that they want, and want most, and direct their efforts toward securing them.

The value of goods, as mentioned earlier, reflects how much people rely on certain parts of the outside world to fulfill their needs. Since wants are tied to feelings, any dependence that isn't recognized or a connection between things and satisfaction that goes unnoticed has no impact on value. This is where dependence is most felt, at the edge of availability. People don’t worry about what they have in excess—unless, of course, that surplus causes them some discomfort. It’s good that they don’t, because effective effort can only be directed when people focus mainly on their needs for the things they truly want and prioritize their efforts to obtain them.

From marginal utility to value

The diminishing utility of successive portions (doses or increments, as they are called) may be represented by a curve of utility.

The decreasing value of each additional portion (doses or increments, as they're known) can be illustrated by a utility curve.

Supply Scale

The diagram is constructed on the hypothesis that a tenth unit of a certain good would have a utility expressed as 36; a fifteenth unit of 30, etc., and that the value of the whole supply is estimated according to these marginal units. Of course if the conditions were that "all or none" was to be taken, the result would be different.

The diagram is based on the idea that the tenth unit of a certain good would have a utility of 36, the fifteenth unit would be 30, and so on, with the overall value being determined by these marginal units. However, if the conditions were such that it was "all or none," the outcome would be different.

Unit of SupplyMarginal UtilityValue of Whole Supply
1036360
1530450
2025500
3019570
4015600
5010500
605300

This diagram is frequently used, and it is important to guard against some misunderstandings. The marginal unit of any given supply—for example, ten units—is not any particular unit, it is any one of the ten units. In the presence of nine units of the good the person or persons find all the various wants that are dependent on that good gratified to such a degree that the tenth unit has an importance expressed by 36. But as this last or marginal unit of supply may be used for any of the purposes, the importance of each and every unit likewise will be expressed by 36. Any one of the units, when once present is, in a logical sense, a marginal unit. When, however, it is a question of increasing the supply, some one unit may properly be looked upon as marginal. The dependence felt by men on the whole group is the product of the units by the marginal utility. As the number of units increases, the marginal utility decreases, until at length it may reach zero, and the total value would be nothing. A point of maximum value evidently will be found somewhere between the two extremes.

This diagram is commonly used, and it’s essential to be aware of some potential misunderstandings. The marginal unit of any given supply—for instance, ten units—is not a specific unit; it's any one of the ten units. With nine units of the good available, individuals find that all their various wants dependent on that good are met to such an extent that the tenth unit has an importance rated at 36. However, since this last or marginal unit of supply can be used for any purpose, the importance of each unit will also be rated at 36. Any one of the units, once present, is logically considered a marginal unit. When it comes to increasing the supply, one specific unit can be regarded as marginal. The reliance people feel on the entire group is the result of the units multiplied by the marginal utility. As the number of units increases, the marginal utility decreases, until it may ultimately reach zero, making the total value nothing. A point of maximum value will clearly exist somewhere between these two extremes.

Only one marginal utility at one moment

Note carefully that on the one diagram are represented a large number of marginal utilities which never exist at one and the same moment. At any one moment there is a given number of units and there is but one marginal utility, and this is the same for each of the units. It is quite erroneous to say that when there are 30 units the utility of the tenth unit is 36; of the twentieth, 25; of the thirtieth, 19. It is equally incorrect to say that when there are 60 units the "total utility" is equal to the area between the right angle and the[Pg 26] curve a-g, while the value is equal to the rectangle below and to the left of the point g. The curve from a-g but marks the height of marginal utilities that have no existence when the supply is 30. The "total utility," often spoken of in this connection, if it has any existence certainly cannot be calculated. The diagram must be understood as representing indicatively at any given moment but one marginal utility, the same for every unit of like goods. The other perpendicular lines are expressed in the conditional mood; they are what the marginal utility would be were the numbers of units different.

Note that the diagram shows a lot of marginal utilities that don’t all exist at the same time. At any moment, there’s a fixed number of units, and there’s only one marginal utility, which is the same for all of those units. It’s wrong to say that when there are 30 units, the utility of the tenth unit is 36, the twentieth is 25, and the thirtieth is 19. It’s also incorrect to state that when there are 60 units, the "total utility" is equal to the area between the right angle and the [Pg 26] curve a-g, while the value equals the rectangle below and to the left of point g. The curve from a-g only shows the height of marginal utilities that don’t exist when there are 30 units. The "total utility," often referenced in this context, if it exists at all, definitely cannot be calculated. The diagram should be understood as only representing one marginal utility at any moment, which is the same for each unit of similar goods. The other vertical lines are framed as hypothetical; they illustrate what the marginal utility would be if the number of units were different.

Changing feelings changes utility

5. Since goods possess utility only as they gratify wants, it follows that if wants change, the utility changes. Utility does not rest unchanging in the goods as something "intrinsic," but it depends on the relation of goods to men. This truth, unrecognized for many centuries, is now seen to be fundamental to the whole problem of value. The portions of a good added later do not appeal to the same man as the earlier portions. The man has been changed by what he has enjoyed. In changing his feelings, goods have also changed his wants. Hence, the added portions of the good are changed in respect to their utility or power to gratify a man's wants. Though physically and chemically, i.e., in every material way, they are exactly like the earlier portions, they cannot have the same want-gratifying power until he again changes, for they are not in the presence of the same feelings.

5. Since goods only have value when they meet our needs, it makes sense that if our needs change, the value also changes. Utility doesn't stay the same in goods as something "inherent," but relies on how goods relate to people. This idea, overlooked for many centuries, is now understood to be central to the entire issue of value. The later parts of a good don't appeal to the same person as the earlier parts. The person has changed because of what they've experienced. As their feelings change, the goods have also altered their needs. Therefore, the later parts of the good are different in terms of their value or ability to satisfy a person's wants. Although physically and chemically, i.e., in every material sense, they are exactly like the earlier parts, they can't satisfy needs in the same way until the person changes again, since they are not experiencing the same feelings.

Wants are constantly shifting; different kinds of goods are compared in man's thought and arranged on a scale at every moment according to their felt utility. An increase in the amount of a good will drop the marginal utility of the added portions down the scale of usefulness for the next moment. When we rise in the morning, we want our breakfast; the breakfast eaten, another breakfast does not appeal to us. Our tasks done, we take a boat-ride or go golfing; then, appetite returning, we are tempted to our dinner. And thus from hour to hour wants are gratified, are altered and[Pg 27] are shifted, until, wearied with the day's labor and pastimes, we go to rest. In a well-ordered life, in an advanced economic society, the means for gratifying our wants as they arise are provided in advance. The changing series of desires is met by a changing series of goods. Life has been defined as a constant adjustment of inner relations to outer conditions. Economic life is therefore like physical life, a constant adjustment; and this adjustment of goods but reflects the shifting and adjustment of feelings.

Wants are always changing; we compare different types of goods in our minds and rank them based on their perceived usefulness at every moment. When the supply of a good increases, the extra portions drop in value for the next moment. When we wake up in the morning, we crave breakfast; after we've eaten, another breakfast isn’t appealing. After completing our tasks, we might want to take a boat ride or go golfing; then, as our appetite returns, we get tempted by dinner. This cycle of wants being satisfied, changing, and shifting continues from hour to hour until we're tired from the day's work and activities, prompting us to rest. In a well-structured life, in an advanced economic society, the resources needed to meet our wants as they come up are planned out in advance. The evolving series of desires is matched by a changing series of goods. Life has been described as a constant adjustment of our inner feelings to external circumstances. Economic life, therefore, is similar to physical life—a constant adjustment; and this adjustment of goods reflects the changing dynamics of our feelings.

Choice is constantly shifting

6. The substitution of goods in men's thought is the shifting of the choice from a good that does not give the highest gratification economically possible at the time, to another good that does. The shifting that takes place on the scale of gratification makes it necessary for man to shift constantly his choice of goods. This again is the problem of "economy." Waste results when goods continue to be used to secure a lower degree of gratification, if they might be used to secure a higher. The change of choice may be because of a change in the man, or because of a change in the quality or the quantity of the goods; or because of a change in the ratio at which the goods can be secured.

6. The replacement of products in people's minds is when they switch their choice from a product that doesn’t provide the highest possible satisfaction to another product that does. The changes that occur in satisfaction levels require people to constantly adjust their choices of products. This is essentially the issue of "economy." Waste occurs when products are still being used to achieve a lower level of satisfaction when they could be used to achieve a higher one. The change in choice can be due to a personal change in the individual, a change in the quality or quantity of the products, or a change in the ratio at which the products can be acquired.

§ II. DEMAND FOR GOODS GROWS OUT OF SUBJECTIVE COMPARISONS

Desire may become demand

1. Demand is desire for goods united with the power to give something in exchange. An example frequently given to show the difference between desire and demand is the hungry boy looking longingly at the sweetmeats in the confectioner's window. He represents desire, but not until the kind-hearted gentleman gives him a nickel does he represent effective demand. Desire, therefore, must be united with power to give something in exchange before it can be called demand. It must be for something that is attainable; yearning for something beyond reach, sighing for the moon, is desire that never can become effective demand.

1. Demand is the desire for goods combined with the ability to trade something in exchange. A common example used to illustrate the difference between desire and demand is the hungry boy gazing longingly at the candy in the shop window. He represents desire, but it's not until the kind-hearted man gives him a nickel that he represents effective demand. So, desire must be paired with the ability to offer something in exchange before it can be considered demand. It has to be for something that can actually be obtained; longing for something out of reach, like sighing for the moon, is desire that can never turn into effective demand.

Demand the Social expression of shifting choice

2. Demand is the social aspect of the individual man's comparison of utilities. It is the expression of the man's wish to substitute some of his goods for some one else's goods in order to get a higher satisfaction. This comparison is often made between two goods owned in different quantities. When men are constantly comparing things in their own possession, it is a short step to compare their goods with their neighbor's.

2. Demand is the social aspect of how an individual compares the usefulness of different things. It reflects a person's desire to trade some of their goods for someone else's in order to achieve greater satisfaction. This comparison is often made between two goods that one person has in different amounts. When people are continually evaluating the items they have, it’s an easy jump to compare their goods with those of their neighbors.

Demand for consumption goods is thus the manifestation of the man's desire to redistribute his enjoyments. In demand for goods men virtually say: "Part of what I have I am ready to give for part of what you have." The strength of their desire is expressed by the amount of their offer. When he makes this comparison and this offer, man enters into a social, economic relation with his fellows.

Demand for consumer goods is basically a reflection of people's desire to share in their pleasures. When people want goods, they essentially say, "I'm willing to exchange some of what I have for some of what you have." The intensity of their desire is shown by how much they are willing to offer. By making this comparison and offer, individuals enter into a social and economic relationship with each other.

The limit of the exchanger's demand

3. The law of individual demand is: The trader will reduce his stock of a particular good to the point where its marginal utility equals that of the alternative goods. The greater the divergence in his estimates of the marginal utilities of two goods, the more ready is he to trade the lower utility for the higher one. Exchange is but the effort to adjust goods to wants in the best way. The less useful (marginally viewed) is traded for the more useful. The greater the difference, in the one trader's judgment, between the marginal utilities of the two goods, the greater is the maladjustment, and the greater, therefore, is the motive to seek readjustment by means of exchange. As the quantity of the good parted with declines, its marginal utility increases; and as more of the other good is acquired, its marginal utility declines. The marginal utility of the two exchangeable units must come to equilibrium in the individual's judgment. At this point demand ceases, not because an additional unit of the one good could afford no gratification, but because it would afford less gratification than the other good in which demand must be expressed to be effectual.

3. The law of individual demand is: The trader will lower his stock of a particular good until its marginal utility matches that of alternative goods. The bigger the difference in his assessments of the marginal utilities of two goods, the more willing he is to trade the lower utility for the higher one. Exchange is simply the attempt to align goods with wants in the most effective way. The less useful (from a marginal perspective) is traded for the more useful. The greater the perceived difference, in one trader's view, between the marginal utilities of the two goods, the more significant the mismatch, and therefore, the stronger the motivation to seek readjustment through exchange. As the quantity of the good he is giving up decreases, its marginal utility increases; conversely, as he acquires more of the other good, its marginal utility decreases. The marginal utility of the two exchangeable units must reach equilibrium in the individual's assessment. At this point, demand stops, not because an extra unit of one good can no longer provide satisfaction, but because it provides less satisfaction than the other good, in which demand must be expressed to be effective.

The Demand curve

4. Demand thus varies at different ratios of exchange between goods, and may be expressed graphically by a demand curve. This would show for any one man the decline of the marginal utility of each added portion of a good, and these individual demand curves may be united into a demand curve for a group of men. The demand curve expresses graphically what a man would be willing to pay at each particular stage in the increase of goods. We have here come to the very threshold of the subject of markets and exchange.

4. Demand changes based on the different exchange rates between goods, and it can be illustrated visually with a demand curve. This curve would show how the additional satisfaction from each extra unit of a good decreases for a single person, and these individual demand curves can be combined to create a demand curve for a group of people. The demand curve visually represents how much a person is willing to pay at each level of increased goods. We are now at the very beginning of the topic of markets and exchange.

Elasticity of demand

5. Elasticity of demand, in the case of any good, expresses the degree in which a change in its ratio to other goods will increase the demand. Elasticity varies for different classes of men according to their wealth and to the cost of the goods. If strawberries are a dollar a box in the city market, a slight fall in the price, say to seventy-five cents, will increase the demand but slightly. But if the price is fifteen cents and falls to ten, the increase in the demand will be marked, for the number of consumers to whom a difference of five cents is important is then very great. The demand for the staples is comparatively inelastic. A certain amount of simple food is necessary to support life; an increase in its price will not quickly check the demand. On the other hand, if the price of staple foods falls, no very great increase will take place in the demand.

5. The elasticity of demand for any good reflects how much a change in its price relative to other goods will affect the demand for that good. Elasticity differs among different groups of people based on their income and the cost of the goods. If strawberries cost a dollar a box at the city market, a small drop in price, like to seventy-five cents, will only slightly increase demand. However, if the price is fifteen cents and drops to ten, the increase in demand will be significant because there are many consumers for whom a five-cent difference matters. The demand for basic staples is relatively inelastic. A certain amount of simple food is necessary for survival; a rise in its price won't quickly reduce demand. Conversely, if the prices of staple foods decrease, there won't be a substantial increase in demand.


CHAPTER 5

EXCHANGE IN A MARKET

§ I. EXCHANGE OF GOODS RESULTING FROM DEMAND

Reciprocal demand becomes exchange

1. Exchange in the usual economic sense is the transfer of two goods by two owners, each of whom deems the good taken more than a value-equivalent for the one given. The comparison of goods that has been discussed above is a kind of exchange. When a person chooses one thing rather than another, one form of gratification may be said to be mentally exchanged for another. This is exchange in that person's mind, or subjective exchange. But the word "exchange" as usually employed means an exchange of goods between persons. It is objective exchange, and when the word is used without modification, it is to be understood in the objective sense. In the last chapter were analyzed the motives of the individual man. Robinson Crusoe on his desert island would in very many ways be acted upon by the same motives in reference to economic goods that men are in society. Yet, it is exchange in society and the complicated problems arising from this transfer of goods from person to person that constitute nearly the whole of the subject-matter of political economy.

1. Exchange, in the typical economic sense, is the transfer of two goods between two owners, each of whom values the good received more than the equivalent value of the good given away. The comparison of goods discussed earlier is a type of exchange. When someone chooses one item over another, they can be said to mentally trade one form of satisfaction for another. This is exchange in that person's mind, or subjective exchange. However, the term "exchange" as commonly used refers to the trade of goods between people. It is objective exchange, and when the term is used without any qualifiers, it should be understood in this objective context. In the last chapter, the motivations of individual people were analyzed. Robinson Crusoe on his deserted island would, in many ways, be influenced by the same economic motivations concerning goods as people are in society. Yet, it is the exchange within society and the complex issues that arise from the transfer of goods from one person to another that make up nearly all of the subject matter of political economy.

Exchange is seen to arise out of the differences in the situations of men with reference to goods. The different subjective valuations give rise to demand, and demand leads to exchange. In early societies differences in natural products were the most usual causes of exchange. Salt, though so essential to life, is found in few places. The metals early became[Pg 31] indispensable for weapons of defense or for the chase, and were sought far and wide. Rare shells, feathers, jewels, and the precious metals appealed in early times to a universal desire for ornament. Products like these are the objects of a rude sort of exchange in the first simple efforts made to adjust possessions to wants. Within the tribe, differences in the skill and ability of men to produce arrow heads or weapons or ornaments, bring about the exchange of goods.

Exchange arises from the differences in people's situations regarding goods. These different personal valuations create demand, and demand leads to exchange. In early societies, variations in natural products were the most common reasons for exchange. Salt, essential for life, is found in only a few places. Metals quickly became[Pg 31] necessary for defense weapons or hunting tools, and were sought after far and wide. Rare shells, feathers, jewels, and precious metals catered to a universal desire for decoration in ancient times. Items like these were part of a basic form of exchange as people tried to align their possessions with their needs. Within the tribe, differences in skills and abilities to create arrowheads, weapons, or ornaments led to the exchange of goods.

Mutual advantage in exchange

2. The advantage of exchange consists in the raising of the want-gratifying power of goods to both parties. It generally was assumed by medieval thinkers that if one party to an exchange gained, the other must lose. The mistaken idea prevailed that value is something fixed in the good, and unchangeable. Where the exchange is voluntary (and only that kind is here being considered), it is mutual advantages which make the exchange rational. Many false conclusions on practical questions still result from a failure to grasp this simple truth. It follows from this that the act of exchange is itself useful, for goods having a small importance to men are given a higher importance by being brought into better relations with wants. Merchants, peddlers, traders, and common carriers of all sorts, therefore, are adding to the utility of goods. This idea has been only slowly apprehended, but is now one of the least disputed propositions in economics.

2. The benefit of trading is that it increases the value of goods for both parties involved. Medieval thinkers generally believed that if one person benefited from an exchange, the other must suffer. The incorrect notion was that value is something fixed and unchangeable in the goods themselves. In cases of voluntary exchange (which is what we are discussing here), both parties gain advantages that make the trade worthwhile. Many incorrect conclusions about real-world issues still arise from not understanding this straightforward fact. This means that the act of exchanging is valuable in itself since goods that may seem less important to people gain more significance when they better meet people's needs. Therefore, merchants, peddlers, traders, and all kinds of carriers are enhancing the value of goods. This idea has been understood slowly over time, but it is now one of the least debated concepts in economics.

Demand is supply in another aspect

3. Barter is the exchange of goods without the use of money. Either one of the goods traded in cases of barter may be considered as sold, and either one as bought, according as the matter is looked at from the standpoint of the one or the other party to the exchange. Demand, therefore, is supply, and supply is demand when the point of view is shifted from one party to another. The fisherman's demand for venison is expressed in terms of fish; the hunter's demand for fish is expressed in terms of venison. But to the fisherman the venison is the supply offered to[Pg 32] him. The term "marginal utility" of a good, therefore, does not refer merely to the demand of the consumer; for it expresses by a single phrase the idea both of demand and of supply. The utility of the goods composing the supply is expressed in terms of the goods that represent demand and vice versa. The only way in which man can give definite, concrete, numerical expression to his desire for goods is to state it in terms of other goods. In expressing numerically, in terms of other objects, an estimate of the utility of an apple, a horse or a house, one inevitably gives expression to a ratio of exchange; demand for one good is the offer of another good.

3. Barter is the exchange of goods without using money. Either of the goods involved in barter can be seen as sold or bought, depending on which party's perspective you take. So, demand is supply, and supply is demand when you switch from one party's point of view to the other. The fisherman’s demand for venison is expressed in terms of fish, while the hunter’s demand for fish is expressed in terms of venison. However, to the fisherman, the venison is the supply being offered to[Pg 32] him. The term "marginal utility" of a good, therefore, doesn't just refer to consumer demand; it captures both demand and supply in one phrase. The usefulness of goods in the supply is shown in terms of the goods that represent demand and vice versa. The only way a person can clearly and specifically express their desire for goods is by stating it in terms of other goods. When numerically expressing, in terms of other items, the value of an apple, a horse, or a house, one inevitably reflects a ratio of exchange; the demand for one good equals the offer of another good.

§ II. BARTER UNDER SIMPLE CONDITIONS

In isolated exchange the price is not economically fixed

1. In isolated exchange, where only two traders engage in barter, their estimates give respectively the upper and the lower figures of the ratio at which the trade can take place. Let us recall the fact that a difference in the relative estimates that men place on goods is the first essential of exchange. Those estimates may be expressed in a ratio; we may say that A will give four apples for one orange, would be glad to give fewer, but will not give more; while B will give one orange for three apples, would be glad to get more apples, but will not take fewer. The outside limits of the ratio at which the exchange must take place will, therefore, be one orange for three or four apples.

1. In a direct exchange, where only two traders barter, their valuations establish the highest and lowest points of the ratio for the trade. It's important to remember that the difference in the relative valuations people place on goods is the key factor for exchange. These valuations can be expressed in a ratio; for example, A might be willing to trade four apples for one orange, would prefer to give fewer, but won't give more; while B would offer one orange for three apples, would prefer to receive more apples, but won't settle for fewer. Therefore, the limits of the ratio for the exchange will be one orange for three or four apples.

A, seller of apples, offers 4 (or fewer) apples for 1 orange.

A, the apple seller, offers 4 (or fewer) apples for 1 orange.

B, buyer of apples, demands 3 (or more) apples for 1 orange.

B, the buyer of apples, wants 3 (or more) apples for 1 orange.

There is, in entirely isolated exchange, therefore, a lack of definiteness in the price, much depending on what Adam Smith called the "higgling of the market." In the old-time American horse trade much depended on "bluff"; in such cases it was as important to be able to judge character as to judge horses. A thorough analysis of the trade, however,[Pg 33] would probably show that the bargain is concluded at a point which exactly balances the hopes of gain and fears of loss of one of the parties.

In completely isolated exchanges, there's a lack of clarity in pricing, largely influenced by what Adam Smith referred to as the "higgling of the market." In the traditional American horse trade, a lot relied on "bluff"; in those situations, it was just as important to assess character as it was to evaluate horses. However, a thorough analysis of the trade,[Pg 33] would likely reveal that the deal is struck at a point that perfectly balances one party's hopes for profit against the other’s fears of loss.

Competitive bidding narrows the limits of price

2. Where one-sided competition exists, the ratio of the exchange will be somewhere between the estimates of the two buyers most eager for the last portion offered. By competition is here meant the independent seeking of the same thing at one time by two or more persons. Where there is one market price paid by a number of buyers, it may be that no two of the subjective estimates are alike; the exchange value may differ from all of their estimates, and yet must correspond closely to two. Auction sales well illustrate the principle. If there is one ax to be sold and ten possible buyers for an ax, and there is no combination among them, the bidding will go on until the estimate of the buyer next to the most eager, has been reached. The most eager buyer can then secure the ax by bidding just a little above his next competitor. But if there are ten axes and ten buyers who know that there will be ten axes offered, the more eager buyers will refuse to bid much above the less eager ones. A shrewd auctioneer, therefore, often conceals the fact that there is more than one of an article, and having sold it off, brings out a second or a third one of the same kind, thus keeping the buyers in ignorance of the supply and getting somewhere near the estimate of the most eager buyer in each case. Advertisements of "a limited supply," "the last chance," "positively the last appearance," are meant to stimulate the demand of the patrons, and to lead them to buy at once. In general, therefore, where competition exists on one side, price is fixed with greater definiteness than in isolated exchange. Not so much depends on shrewd bargaining, on bluff, or on the stubbornness of an individual. Far more depends on forces outside the control of any one man. The bidders are impelled by self-interest to outbid their competitors, and thus the limits within which the market price must fall are narrowly fixed.

2. Where one-sided competition exists, the exchange rate will be somewhere between the estimates of the two buyers most eager for the last item offered. Competition here refers to the independent pursuit of the same item at the same time by two or more people. When there is one market price paid by multiple buyers, it's possible that no two subjective estimates are the same; the exchange value might differ from all of their estimates, yet it must align closely with two of them. Auction sales exemplify this principle. If there’s one axe to be sold and ten potential buyers for it, and there’s no collusion among them, the bidding will continue until the estimate of the buyer who is just less eager than the most eager buyer is reached. The most eager buyer can then secure the axe by bidding just a bit above their next competitor. However, if there are ten axes and ten buyers who know there will be that many available, the more eager buyers will hesitate to bid much above the less eager bidders. A clever auctioneer often hides the fact that there is more than one of the item, and after selling the first one, brings out a second or third one of the same type, keeping buyers unaware of the supply and getting close to the estimate of the most eager buyer each time. Advertisements stating "limited supply," "last chance," or "definitely the last appearance," are designed to spark demand and encourage patrons to buy immediately. Generally, in situations of competition, the price is determined with more precision than in isolated exchanges. It relies less on clever negotiating, bluffing, or one person's stubbornness. Much more depends on forces beyond any individual's control. Bidders are driven by their self-interest to outbid their competitors, thus tightly fixing the range within which the market price must fall.

Buyers fix price of perishable goods

If things already brought to market must be sold at any price that can be secured, the buyers may be said to fix the price. This does not mean that they can buy it for any sum that they wish, but it means that when each one is trying to get it as cheap as possible, their bids finally determine how much it will sell for. In such cases, therefore, the competition is for the moment one-sided.

If items already on the market must be sold for any price possible, then buyers essentially set the price. This doesn’t mean they can purchase it for any amount they want, but it does mean that as each buyer tries to get it for the lowest price, their offers ultimately decide how much it will sell for. In these situations, the competition is, at that moment, one-sided.

If a part of the supply can be withdrawn and kept without great loss, this will be done if the price is low. Strawberries, fish, and meat may be sold Saturday night at any price that will secure purchasers, but every thing that can be kept with little or no depreciation will be withheld from sale for a time. It may even be of advantage to the seller to destroy a part of the supply, when the increased price of the smaller amount will give a larger total.

If a portion of the supply can be taken out and stored without losing much value, that will happen if the price is low. Strawberries, fish, and meat can be sold on Saturday night for any price that attracts buyers, but anything that can be kept with little or no loss in value will be held back from being sold for a while. It might even benefit the seller to destroy some of the supply if the higher price for the reduced amount results in a larger total return.

The margin of advantage and the marginal pair

3. Where two-sided competition exists, the bidding goes on until a price is reached where the least eager seller and the least eager buyer have the narrowest possible motive to exchange. As the market ratio varies from those in the minds of the individuals when they come to the market, there is left a considerable margin to some and a very small one to others. This difference between the market value and the ratio of exchange at which any given individual would continue to exchange for the good may be called the margin of advantage. Moreover, the buyers will have a margin and the sellers a margin, and as that margin narrows there is less and less motive to continue the exchange until, finally, the margin disappearing, the buyer or seller, withdrawing from the market, ceases to be an exchanger, at least for that particular part of the goods.

3. Where there is competition on both sides, the bidding continues until a price is reached where the least motivated seller and the least motivated buyer have the smallest possible reason to make a deal. As the market price changes from what individuals think when they arrive at the market, some people have a large margin while others have a very small one. This difference between the market value and the exchange rate at which any individual would keep trading for the good can be referred to as the margin of advantage. Additionally, both buyers and sellers will have their own margins, and as these margins shrink, the reasons to keep trading diminish until, ultimately, when the margin disappears, either the buyer or seller pulls out of the market, stopping their trading activities, at least for that specific item.

The least eager buyer and the least eager seller may be called the marginal pair. They are the buyer and the seller respectively having the narrowest margin of advantage. Their outside estimates are nearest to the market ratio. If the market ratio shifts slightly in either direction, one of them will drop out of the exchange. It is evident that a buyer[Pg 35] who is taking ten units may be on the margin with reference to the tenth unit, and yet may continue to be one of the most eager buyers to secure one unit. Thus, the marginal buyer is to be thought of as that person who, logically considered, is the least eager, or on the margin, with reference to a particular unit of supply, however eager he may be with reference to any other unit of supply. It would be well to recall here the discussion of the nature of wants and the variation in the intensity of demand.

The least eager buyer and the least eager seller can be referred to as the marginal pair. They are the buyer and seller who have the smallest margin of advantage. Their outside estimates are closest to the market ratio. If the market ratio changes slightly in either direction, one of them will stop participating in the exchange. It’s clear that a buyer[Pg 35] who is purchasing ten units may be on the margin concerning the tenth unit, but still be one of the most eager buyers for one unit. Therefore, the marginal buyer is considered as the person who, when logically viewed, is the least eager, or on the margin, regarding a specific unit of supply, no matter how eager they might be for any other unit of supply. It’s also useful to remember the earlier discussion about the nature of wants and the variation in the intensity of demand.

Goods Units
Market values built on individual estimates

4. Market values are built up on subjective valuations. The idea of market values, therefore, is that of the want-gratifying power of goods as expressed in terms of other goods, where there are various buyers and sellers. They are not an average of the subjective valuations, nor are they made up of the extremes. They correspond closely with the subjective estimates of two of the exchangers. The other parties to the exchange are willing to accept the market ratio, for it offers them more inducements than it does to either one of the marginal pair.

4. Market values are based on personal opinions. The concept of market values represents the ability of goods to satisfy wants, reflected in terms of other goods, where there are various buyers and sellers involved. They aren't just an average of personal opinions, nor are they derived from the extremes. They closely match the personal evaluations of two of the participants in the exchange. The other parties involved in the exchange are willing to accept the market rate, as it provides them with more incentives than it does for either of the two marginal participants.

§ III. PRICE IN A MARKET

One price in a market

1. A market is a body of buyers and sellers in such close business relations that the actual price conforms closely to the valuation of the marginal pair. The word "price" which we have used, may be defined as value expressed in terms of some commonly exchanged commodity. The term is used more broadly of anything given in exchange. The very terms of this definition imply that there can be but one price in a market. This is a somewhat abstract but a useful economic proposition. Very often within sound of each other's voices traders are paying different prices for a good. On the occasion of a break in the stock-market, excited traders within ten feet of each other make bids that differ by thousands of dollars. Retail and wholesale merchants may be purchasing goods in the same room at the same time at very different prices. But within a group of buyers and sellers where competition is approximately complete, price is fixed with some degree of exactness. The more nearly the actual conditions approach to the ideal of a market, the less are prices fixed by higgling, and the more impersonal they become, the buyers and sellers being compelled to adjust their bids to the needs of the market, and not being able to vary them greatly one way or the other.

1. A market is a group of buyers and sellers who are so closely connected in business that the actual price closely matches the value of the last pair of transactions. The term "price" we’ve used can be defined as value expressed in terms of a commonly exchanged commodity. It’s also used more generally to refer to anything given in exchange. This definition implies that there should be only one price in a market. While this is somewhat abstract, it’s a useful economic idea. Often, traders who can hear each other are paying different prices for the same good. For instance, during a stock market crash, excited traders just feet apart may make bids that differ by thousands of dollars. Retailers and wholesalers can be buying goods in the same room at the same time for very different prices. However, in a group of buyers and sellers where competition is relatively complete, prices are set with a fair amount of precision. The closer the actual market conditions are to the ideal market, the less prices are determined by bargaining, and the more impersonal they become, as the buyers and sellers must adjust their bids to fit market needs, unable to change them significantly in either direction.

The earlier markets

2. Markets are steadily widening through the improvement of means of communication and transportation. The earliest markets were established on the borders between tribes, villages or nations as a common ground where strangers met to trade. At such markets were brought together from sparsely settled districts a comparatively large number of merchants and customers. Buyers had the opportunity of wide selection both in kind and quality, and the sellers found a large body of customers gathered at one point. Throughout the Middle Ages purchases were made by the more prosperous husbandmen in great quantities once a[Pg 37] year at the fairs or markets. As both the buyers and sellers came from widely separated places, there was, in most respects, no combination, and the conditions of a competitive market were present.

2. Markets are steadily expanding thanks to better communication and transportation. The earliest markets were set up on the borders between tribes, villages, or nations, serving as common ground where strangers would meet to trade. These markets gathered a relatively large number of merchants and customers from sparsely populated areas. Buyers had the chance to choose from a wide variety of goods in both type and quality, while sellers found many customers all in one place. During the Middle Ages, wealthier farmers would make large purchases once a[Pg 37] year at fairs or markets. Since both buyers and sellers came from far-flung locations, there was generally no collusion, and the conditions for a competitive market were established.

The growth of markets

The number of buyers and sellers that can constitute a single market is limited both directly and indirectly by the means of transportation. A dense population cannot usually be maintained without easy means of transportation to bring in a large supply of food, and to carry back manufactured goods great distances. The remarkable growth in the means of commerce since the application of steam to water traffic, and the invention of the railroad, have made it possible for goods to be gathered from most distant points. A market implies a common understanding among traders. Modern means of communication such as newspapers, post-offices, telegraph and cable, trade bulletins, commercial travelers, the consular service, and many forms of special agencies, are diffusing information widely. As a result of these changes, there has been a widening of the village-market to the markets of the province, of the nation, and finally of the world. While a part of every one's purchases continues to be made in the neighborhood, a greater and greater portion of the total business is done by traders who are widely separated and who are indeed members of the world market. Various articles produced in the same locality may seek different markets. The market for wheat may be in Liverpool, while that for fruit and eggs is in the village near the farm-house. If a given product of any community is sold in different markets, the net prices secured must be very nearly equal.

The number of buyers and sellers that can make up a single market is limited both directly and indirectly by transportation. A dense population usually can’t be supported without easy transportation to bring in a large supply of food and to ship manufactured goods over long distances. The significant growth in trade since the introduction of steam-powered water transport and the invention of the railroad has allowed goods to be collected from far-off locations. A market implies a shared understanding among traders. Modern communication methods like newspapers, post offices, telegraphs and cables, trade bulletins, traveling salespeople, consular services, and various special agencies are spreading information widely. As a result of these changes, the local village market has expanded to provincial, national, and ultimately global markets. While everyone still makes some purchases nearby, an increasing portion of total business is transacted by traders who are far apart and are, in fact, part of the global market. Different products made in the same area may target different markets. The market for wheat might be in Liverpool, while the market for fruit and eggs could be in the village close to the farmhouse. If a certain product from any community is sold in different markets, the overall prices achieved must be very close to equal.

The conceptions normal and market price

3. Normal price is spoken of in contrast to market price when the actual market price results from exceptional circumstances and probably will not be maintained. The term "normal price," much used in economic discussion, is the price which, apart from exceptional conditions, is expected to prevail, and to which actual prices seem constantly striving[Pg 38] to adjust themselves. As actual prices are nearly always either more or less than so-called normal price, and only momentarily ever correspond with it, the term "normal" would appear to be something of a misnomer. Moreover, as the circumstances of production change, this normal price itself is altered so that what is normal one day may be quite abnormal the next. The thought of "normal price" is an abstract one, but despite the inaptness of the word it is not without some practical validity. In determining whether he shall continue to produce certain goods, the business man is practically guided by his view of normal price. An example of departure from normal price as above defined, is found in the price of food when an expected ship has failed to arrive at a port with its cargo of grain. A scarcity amounting almost to famine might thus exist in a seaboard city, and the market price would rise; but as this would be due to an accident and would afford a larger gain than usual to those who happened to have a supply of grain, men would say that the market price was above the normal price. The arrival of the expected ship would cause the market price to return to the normal.

3. "Normal price" is discussed in contrast to market price when the actual market price is influenced by rare circumstances and likely won't last. The term "normal price," commonly used in economic discussions, refers to the price that is expected to prevail under regular conditions, to which actual prices often try to adjust[Pg 38]. Since actual prices are almost always either above or below this so-called normal price, and only briefly ever match it, the term "normal" seems somewhat misleading. Additionally, as production circumstances change, this normal price itself shifts, so what is considered normal one day may seem quite abnormal the next. The concept of "normal price" is abstract, yet despite the inaccuracy of the term, it holds some practical significance. When deciding whether to continue producing certain goods, a businessperson is practically guided by their perspective of normal price. An example of a deviation from normal price, as defined above, is seen in food prices when an anticipated ship fails to arrive at a port with its grain cargo. This could lead to a shortage nearly resembling famine in a coastal city, causing the market price to rise; however, since this would be due to an accident, it would yield unusually high profits for those who had a supply of grain, leading people to say that the market price is above the normal price. The arrival of the expected ship would bring the market price back down to normal.

Review of the argument

In review, we see that the market value of goods grows out of the different personal estimates made by men. Market value itself being a complex and difficult problem, it can be mastered only by dividing it. First, therefore, must be studied the more general and obvious motives of men, the nature of wants and their effects on man's subjective estimates. The same simple motives that influence the subjective valuations made by individual men, may be traced to the conditions of the complicated market. It is their workings that are seen in the obscurest problems of market price.

In summary, we can see that the market value of goods comes from the various personal evaluations made by people. Market value itself is a complex and challenging issue that can only be understood by breaking it down. Therefore, the first step is to examine the more general and obvious motivations of people, the nature of their wants, and how these affect their personal evaluations. The same basic motivations that shape the personal valuations of individuals can also be traced back to the conditions of the intricate market. It's these dynamics that are reflected in the most puzzling issues of market price.


CHAPTER 6

PSYCHIC INCOME

§ I. INCOME AS A FLOW OF GOODS

The recurrence of wants

1. Satisfaction and gratification being only temporary conditions, economic wants appear in more or less regularly recurring series. Impressions are short lived, sensations are temporary, wants that have been satisfied recur. Wants recur for the same reason that they first arose. No impression on the nerves or on the senses is lasting. Man's senses were developed for the purpose of bringing him into relation with the outer world, of enabling him to survive in his struggle with the forces of nature. So, when a good has been enjoyed, the utility to that person of that thing or service for that particular moment, falls, it may be even to zero. To keep wants satisfied is impossible; we cannot do next year's reading or next week's eating now; we cannot live the life of to-morrow. The best results in reading or eating come from taking the right amount day by day. But it is a need in the life of men that wants should recur after a time, otherwise there would be no motive for action.

1. Satisfaction and pleasure are just temporary states, and economic wants come in recurring cycles. Impressions are short-lived, sensations fade quickly, and wants that have been fulfilled come back. Wants come back for the same reasons they first appeared. No impression on the nerves or senses lasts forever. Human senses evolved to connect us with the outside world and help us survive against the forces of nature. So, once we enjoy something, its usefulness to us for that moment decreases, possibly even to nothing. It's impossible to keep all wants satisfied; we can’t do next year's reading or eat next week's meals now; we can’t live tomorrow’s life today. The best outcomes in reading or eating happen when we take the right amount each day. However, it's essential for humans that wants reappear after a while; otherwise, there would be no reason to act.

Series of wants and series of goods

2. The economic ideal is that this series of recurring wants should be met by a corresponding series of goods. It is evident that if a series or succession of goods varies, at different times, moments, and conditions, in its power to gratify wants, the closer the correspondence between the two series, that of wants and that of goods, the greater will be the total of gratification. We may liken man's life to a journey in which the supplies of food are gotten at the stations.[Pg 40] If any one of these supplies fails, the traveler suffers the pangs of hunger, and if two or three supplies are at one point, they do not serve the needs of man so well as if distributed along the way. This constant inflow of goods is one of the fundamental needs of life. The savage dimly understands this need. Even the birds and the beasts adjust their lives to it either by travel or by toil. The spring and autumn migrations to new feeding grounds are the attempts of the bird to gratify this series of wants as they arise. The ant, the bee, and the squirrel anticipate, and work to fill their storehouses against the days of need.

2. The economic ideal is that this series of recurring wants should be met by a corresponding series of goods. It's clear that if the availability of goods changes at different times and under different conditions, the closer the match between the two series—wants and goods—the greater the overall satisfaction will be. We can compare a person's life to a journey where food supplies are collected at various stops.[Pg 40] If any one of these supplies is missing, the traveler feels hunger, and if two or three supplies are available at one stop, they don't meet a person's needs as effectively as if they were spread out along the journey. This continuous supply of goods is a basic requirement of life. Even primitive people have a vague understanding of this need. Birds and animals adapt their lives to it through migration or hard work. The spring and autumn migrations to new feeding areas show how birds try to satisfy their needs as they come up. Ants, bees, and squirrels plan ahead, gathering resources to stock up for future needs.

Social and private incomes

3. Objective income consists of the additional sums of goods acquired by individuals or by society during the income period. The term national or social income may be contrasted with individual or private income in the objective sense. The nature of the acquisition of objective incomes may, in some cases, be different if viewed from the social and individual standpoints. Society, as a whole, may be said to acquire income only when goods are produced; individuals may acquire income by gift, bequest, theft, or other modes of transfer from other individuals. In many cases the two kinds of income, however, agree, the objective income of society being the algebraic sum of the goods acquired or parted with by all the individuals.

3. Objective income refers to the extra amounts of goods gained by individuals or society during the income period. The terms national or social income can be differentiated from individual or private income in an objective sense. The way objective incomes are acquired may differ depending on whether we look at it from a social or individual perspective. Society as a whole can be said to earn income only when goods are produced; individuals can earn income through gifts, inheritances, theft, or other methods of transfer from others. In many cases, however, the two types of income align, with the objective income of society being the total sum of the goods obtained or given up by all individuals.

We should not understand that either social or private objective incomes include only material goods, for many utilities and labor services that never take on a material or money expression are included in either case. Indeed, we are close here to the conception of psychic income which is to be developed more fully.

We shouldn't think that social or private income only refers to material goods, as many services and utilities that don’t have a physical or monetary form are also included. In fact, we are approaching the idea of psychic income, which will be explored in more detail.

Money income

Income of money is not often the same as income of things. Usually many of these subtler utilities are overlooked and omitted from the recognized money income. In this day the use of money is so common that we are sometimes led to ignore the value of things to which the money expression is not given. The money income is merely the money expression[Pg 41] of the value of currently acquired goods, and it is the only medium through which such varied sources of gratification can be compared.

Income from money isn't always the same as income from things. Often, many of these subtler benefits are overlooked and left out of the recognized money income. Nowadays, the use of money is so widespread that we sometimes forget the value of things that don't have a monetary expression. Money income is simply the dollar value[Pg 41] of the value of goods we currently acquire, and it's the only way to compare these diverse sources of satisfaction.

Gross and net income

4. Income in the logical sense must be a net addition, but the term gross income is not without popular and practical meaning. Gross income is sometimes spoken of in the sense of total receipts, as the total of goods secured; net income is the remainder after deducting expenditures and after replacing the goods employed to secure the income. In order to produce some goods technically, men make use of other goods. While they are storing up a supply of wood or coal it may be looked upon as the income, but they may burn it to help grow hothouse plants. While they gather flowers with one hand, they destroy fuel with the other. Only the net increase in value can be accounted income in the second period. The goods that come into a man's possession in any period are of many sorts: to get some he has destroyed many previously existing goods; while to get others he has not needed to use up the accumulations of the past or to mortgage the future. The one kind is gross, the other net income.

4. Income in a logical sense should be considered a net gain, but the term gross income has its own popular and practical significance. Gross income is often referred to as the total receipts or the total value of goods acquired; net income is what’s left after subtracting expenses and replacing the goods used to generate the income. To produce certain goods, people use other goods. While they’re stockpiling wood or coal, it could be seen as income, but they might burn it to help grow hothouse plants. As they collect flowers with one hand, they're using up fuel with the other. Only the net increase in value can be classified as income in the second period. The goods a person acquires during any period come in many forms: to obtain some, they have destroyed previously existing goods; while for others, they haven’t needed to deplete past resources or jeopardize the future. One type is gross income, the other is net income.

Wealth and income

5. An income of consumption goods is a part of wealth, but not the whole of it. The consumption goods, the "present goods" at the moment available, are the essential part of wealth for the moment's enjoyment. The only essential and immediate conditions of a series of gratifications is a regular series of consumption goods. But many things existing which could be used to secure a gratification are not in fact treated as consumption goods. A crop of corn is not all income. In a time of famine it could be used, but seed-corn was saved from last year, and some must be kept for next year. This is a part of wealth, but not of "present goods" as we understand the term.

5. An income of consumable goods is a part of wealth, but not the whole thing. The consumable goods, the "present goods" currently available, are the key part of wealth for immediate enjoyment. The only essential and immediate conditions for a series of pleasures are a steady supply of consumable goods. However, many things that could be used to obtain satisfaction aren't actually considered consumable goods. A harvest of corn isn't all considered income. In a famine, it could be utilized, but seed corn was saved from last year, and some has to be saved for next year. This is part of wealth, but not of "present goods" as we typically understand it.

Some goods never can become enjoyable goods

Further, in the economic world there is much wealth that never can gratify any want directly; many forms of wealth never can be consumption goods. It is true that everything called wealth is expected to contribute sooner or later in some[Pg 42] way to the sum of gratifications. It is for that reason it is called wealth. It is, however, a mere figure of speech to say indirect want-gratifiers become want-gratifying goods. For example, the engine transporting a load of coal is indirectly gratifying wants; if it is transporting a train-load of passengers, the gratification is direct. A machine making cloth for next year is gratifying wants only in a metaphorical sense. A field used to produce food is not a direct want-gratifier until it is transformed into a residence site, a playground, or a tennis-court.

Furthermore, in the economic world, there’s a lot of wealth that can never satisfy any immediate need directly; many types of wealth can never be considered consumer goods. It’s true that everything labeled as wealth is expected to eventually contribute in some[Pg 42] way to overall satisfaction. That’s why it’s called wealth. However, it’s essentially a figure of speech to say that indirect want-satisfiers become want-satisfying goods. For instance, an engine hauling a load of coal is indirectly satisfying wants, while one transporting a train full of passengers provides direct satisfaction. A machine producing fabric for next year is only satisfying wants in a metaphorical sense. A field used to grow food isn’t a direct want-satisfier until it’s turned into a home site, a playground, or a tennis court.

It is necessary therefore to recognize the distinction between present and future incomes. The value of the mass of wealth in possession and yielding income, rests in large part upon its power of contributing to income in some future period. Thus, any durable good may be looked upon as embodying a series of incomes ranging from present to future in varying degrees. This will be fully considered under the subject of capital.

It is important to understand the difference between current and future incomes. The value of the wealth we have now, which generates income, largely depends on its ability to contribute to income in the future. Therefore, any long-lasting item can be seen as representing a series of incomes that span from the present to the future in different ways. This will be explored in detail under the topic of capital.

Income from wealth and from labor

6. Incomes are called funded or unfunded according to the sources from which they are derived. Funded income arises from the possession of wealth or of claims on wealth, such as lands, railroad stocks, government bonds, etc. The income is "funded" because it corresponds to an abiding fund of wealth. The income arising from current labor is unfunded, because there is no permanent fund of accumulated wealth corresponding to it.

6. Incomes are referred to as funded or unfunded based on their sources. Funded income comes from owning wealth or claims on wealth, like land, railroad stocks, government bonds, and so on. It's considered "funded" because it comes from a lasting source of wealth. On the other hand, income that comes from current work is unfunded, as there isn't a permanent source of accumulated wealth behind it.

The idea of regularity connected with funded income is not essential to the idea of income in general, i.e., we cannot refuse to call a thing income because it occurs only this year. If it is part of the sum of goods that flows in, that is newly available for the man's use, it is income. But funded income is the more abiding, for income from wages stops when the man dies or fails to perform his work, while the income from wealth continues after he ceases to be active. Thus, families with equal incomes may differ greatly in wealth, the one depending entirely on salaries, the other on rents.

The concept of regular income tied to funded sources isn't vital to the broader definition of income. In other words, we can't say something isn't income just because it only happens this year. If it contributes to the total goods available for a person to use, it counts as income. However, funded income is more stable since wage income stops when a person dies or can no longer work, while income from wealth continues even after they stop being active. As a result, families with the same income can have very different levels of wealth, with one relying completely on salaries and the other on rents.

§ II. INCOME AS A SERIES OF GRATIFICATIONS

Gratification the test of psychic income
All sources of income are productive

1. The value of consumption goods is derived from the pleasurable psychic impressions which they aid to produce, and these psychic effects constitute the psychic income. The objective income is sometimes called the "real" income, but certainly it is not income in the most essential sense. Things outside of men cannot be feelings, they can only call out or occasion feeling, and it is the attainment of pleasurable conditions in mind or soul that is the aim of all economic activity. Material income and immaterial income are both related to and reducible to psychic income. Some portions at least of the objective incomes of goods are continually by use becoming subjective incomes of enjoyment. Men talk of material income as consisting of bushels of wheat, head of cattle, etc., and of immaterial income as the uses that durable goods yield directly or that men perform for each other, e.g., those of the singer, physician, teacher, judge—all services that do not take on material form. There was a long-standing dispute in economic literature regarding the difference between productive and unproductive labor. Productive labor was said to be that which embodied itself in abiding material form. The distinction led to some peculiar puzzles and paradoxes. The bartender mixing drinks, adds to the value of those ingredients; in a minute that value is dissipated. According to the distinction in question, he is a productive laborer because his services are embodied in material form, whereas the lecturer is regarded as an unproductive laborer because the results of his labor are not embodied in material form. But whether or not the service has for a moment embodied itself in material form is of no essential economic import. The presence of the waiter is as essential to the well-served dinner as are the polished silver and china, or as the well-cooked food. The distinction in question is not now made by economists, all labor that contributes to[Pg 44] value being regarded as productive. But a similar distinction is inconsistently preserved by many writers in the case of material things. A building used as a factory is called productive, but used by the owner as a dwelling it is called unproductive because the service it renders does not appear in material form. But the use of the house, or that of land for a school ground or campus, secures a certain gratification, an immaterial good. Consistency requires that the services of men and the use of material things be judged by their psychic results, the question whether the service takes on a material or an immaterial form being disregarded.

1. The value of consumer goods comes from the enjoyable mental experiences they help generate, and these mental effects make up our mental income. Objective income is sometimes referred to as "real" income, but it's definitely not income in the most fundamental sense. Things outside of people can't be feelings; they can only elicit or provoke feelings, and the goal of all economic activity is to achieve enjoyable conditions in the mind or spirit. Material income and immaterial income are both connected to and can be reduced to mental income. Some parts of the objective incomes of goods are continuously transforming through use into subjective incomes of enjoyment. People often describe material income as consisting of bushels of wheat, heads of cattle, etc., and immaterial income as the benefits that durable goods provide directly or the services that people perform for one another, e.g., those of the singer, doctor, teacher, judge—all services that don't take on a physical form. There has been a long-standing debate in economic literature about the difference between productive and unproductive labor. Productive labor was defined as that which takes on lasting physical form. This distinction created some curious puzzles and paradoxes. For example, a bartender mixing drinks adds to the value of those ingredients; however, that value disappears in a moment. According to this distinction, he is considered a productive worker because his services are represented in a physical form, while a lecturer is seen as an unproductive worker because the results of his work aren't in physical form. But whether the service has taken on a physical form for even a moment doesn't significantly impact economics. The presence of a waiter is just as essential to a well-served dinner as the polished silver and china, or as the properly cooked food. Economists no longer make that distinction, viewing all labor that contributes to[Pg 44] value as productive. However, a similar distinction is inconsistently maintained by many writers regarding physical items. A building used as a factory is labeled productive, but when it's used by the owner as a home, it's labeled unproductive because the service it provides doesn't manifest in physical form. But using the house, or land for a schoolyard or campus, provides a certain sense of satisfaction, an immaterial good. Consistency demands that we judge the services of people and the uses of physical items based on their mental outcomes, disregarding whether the service appears in physical or immaterial form.

All wealth is logically related to psychic income

2. Only those things and actions that are in some causal relation to gratifications can have value to man. This proposition of theory is demonstrated every hour in practical life. The business man always is trying to trace a causal relation between things that do not and cannot themselves directly satisfy wants, and things that do. The vineyard has no value to Tantalus, unable to reach its fruit. A captive, chained to a rock, attaches value only to the things within his reach. Men living in savagery and ignorance starve amid the possibilities of plenty. Chained by their ignorance and improvidence to a little spot of earth, they do not see clearly, either in time or space, the economic relations about them.

2. Only things and actions that have some connection to satisfactions can be valuable to people. This idea is proven every hour in real life. Businesspeople are always trying to figure out the connection between things that don’t directly satisfy needs and things that do. The vineyard means nothing to Tantalus, who can’t reach its fruit. A prisoner, tied to a rock, only values what’s within reach. People living in primitive conditions and ignorance starve despite the abundance around them. Bound by their lack of knowledge and foresight to a small area of land, they don't clearly see the economic connections around them, either in terms of time or space.

Values of things distant in time

3. Man's foresight and knowledge enable him to think of many periods at once, and thus his felt dependence on goods extends over a series of future productive agents. In order to simplify the problem, we have spoken of the economic man as living only in and for the moment. If he had no more knowledge, memory, or imagination than is necessary to compare goods here, only present goods could have value to him. Even the higher animals, and much more the savages, rise above that level of improvidence. With increased intelligence the economic life of man expands, and he attaches importance to things which at the present moment have not, and cannot have, the slightest influence on his immediate[Pg 45] gratification. The extension of man's view works a momentous change in his economic estimates. Of the thousands of forms of matter in the world, only a comparatively few ever will make an immediate gratifying impression on man's senses. But many of them are so connected in his thought by chains of association with pleasures or uses, that almost instinctively and most intensely he attaches an importance to them. In most cases it would require close thought to see that the service attributed directly to them was but a reflection of that performed by some other good. Thus, more and more, the estimates placed by men on goods come to depend on knowledge and foresight, and not on immediate impressions and feelings.

3. Human foresight and knowledge allow people to consider many time periods at once, so their perceived reliance on goods stretches over a series of future productive resources. To make things simpler, we've described the economic man as living only in and for the moment. If he had no more knowledge, memory, or imagination than what's needed to compare goods in front of him, only current goods would hold value for him. Even higher animals, and definitely more primitive humans, rise above that level of shortsightedness. With increased intelligence, human economic life expands, and individuals begin to value things that, at this moment, have no impact on their immediate[Pg 45] satisfaction. Expanding perspectives leads to significant changes in how people evaluate the economy. Of the thousands of types of matter in the world, only a relatively small number will make an immediate satisfying impression on a person's senses. Yet many are so linked in their thoughts to pleasures or uses that they instinctively and intensely attach importance to them. In many cases, it would take careful consideration to realize that the benefit attributed directly to them is just a reflection of that provided by some other good. Therefore, increasingly, the values people assign to goods rely on knowledge and foresight, rather than on immediate impressions and feelings.

Goods related in varying degrees to psychic income

4. Things are causally related in varying degrees to the psychic income, and have value only as their relation is known and felt. The explanation of value is not complete till value has been traced back to its source in gratification. Often the complex nature of the problem is ignored. If one discusses the trading of a bushel of grain, to be used by a hungry man for food, for a sheep to be kept for breeding, or for wool to be made into cloth next year, he may overlook the difference in the grade of wants compared. In this case, a gratification of the present moment is compared with a gratification of a very different kind at a future time. The problem involved is complex because of differences in time, in place, and in the nature of the want-gratifiers. The student should endeavor to reduce the problem of value to its simplest form by considering first the exchange, at the present moment, of immediately enjoyable goods. The logical starting-point in the theory of value is in those goods that are in closest touch with feeling, and on this basis may be built up an explanation of values in which reason and forethought have a greater part. Starting from the proposition that psychic income is the foundation of all values, we shall go on, however, to trace causes that give value to all the physical agents, and to the most indirect of want-gratifiers.

4. Things are connected to psychic income in different ways and hold value only when that connection is understood and experienced. The explanation of value isn't complete until it has been traced back to its source in satisfaction. Often, the complicated nature of the issue is overlooked. For instance, if someone talks about trading a bushel of grain, which a hungry person will use for food, for a sheep to breed, or for wool that will be turned into cloth next year, they might miss the difference in the levels of wants being compared. In this case, immediate satisfaction is being compared with a very different kind of satisfaction at a later time. The issue is complex because of differences in time, location, and the types of things that satisfy our wants. The student should aim to simplify the problem of value by first considering the exchange of goods that can be enjoyed right now. The logical starting point in the theory of value is those goods that are most closely linked to feeling, and from this foundation, a more comprehensive explanation of values that includes reason and planning can be developed. Beginning with the idea that psychic income is the basis of all values, we will also explore the causes that provide value to all physical resources and to the most indirect sources of satisfaction.


DIVISION B—WEALTH AND RENT


CHAPTER 7

WEALTH AND ITS INDIRECT USES

§ I. THE GRADES OF RELATION OF INDIRECT GOODS TO GRATIFICATION

Technical rank of agents

1. Goods may be ranked according to their technical relation to wants. The technical rank of goods (sometimes spoken of as the degree of roundaboutness of the process) signifies the number of steps or processes that intervene between the agent used and the desired form. If one wishing the hickory-nut hanging above his head must first pick up a stick to throw at it, the nut is removed one step from desire. But even among savages the processes are much more complicated. The Indian with a crude knife fashions his bow and arrow, fastens the flint and cord which represent still other processes of industry, and shoots the bird which satisfies his hunger. In modern conditions the relations are vastly more complicated; only at the end of a long series do men arrive at the thing which gratifies their wants.

1. Goods can be ranked based on how they relate to our needs. The technical rank of goods (sometimes referred to as the degree of roundaboutness in the process) indicates the number of steps or stages that stand between the tool used and the wanted item. If someone wanting the hickory nut above their head has to first pick up a stick to throw at it, the nut is one step further from desire. However, even among primitive people, the processes are much more complex. An Indian using a simple knife crafts his bow and arrow, attaches the flint and string, which involves additional steps of making tools, and then shoots the bird to satisfy his hunger. In today's world, the connections are far more intricate; people often go through a long series of actions before they get what they want.

Time relations of goods to wants

2. Goods may be ranked by their relation to wants in time. The relation in respect to time is measured by the period that must elapse before the utility of an agent results in, is converted into, gratification. No agent or influence intervening, a thing may yet be removed a long way from[Pg 47] gratification. A tree may not be fitted to bear fruit for ten years to come. Meantime, there are many other possible uses for the tree: it may be used for fuel, or to make a canoe with which to catch fish, or to follow some other indirect method of production. Evidently the technical and time relations of goods are very different. The number of steps has no necessary relation to the time. A number of technical steps may be taken in half an hour, or a process of a single technical step may last a year. In the mechanic arts the technical relations are of primary significance, but in economics the time relations are mainly to be considered.

2. Goods can be ranked based on their relationship to wants over time. This relationship regarding time is measured by how long it takes before the usefulness of a resource leads to satisfaction. Without any factors in between, an item can still be far from[Pg 47] satisfaction. For example, a tree might not be able to produce fruit for another ten years. In the meantime, there are many other potential uses for the tree: it can be used for firewood, or to make a canoe for fishing, or for various other indirect production methods. Clearly, the technical and time relationships of goods differ significantly. The number of steps involved doesn't necessarily correlate to the time it takes. A number of technical steps might be completed in half an hour, while a single technical step could take a year. In the mechanical arts, the technical relationships are crucial, but in economics, the time relationships are what should be primarily considered.

3. Economic goods may be classified as immediately enjoyable goods and durable agents. Enjoyable goods are goods in a final form, producing gratification or just ready to give gratification the next moment, as the cool draft of air made by a fan on a hot day, the cup of coffee steaming on the table.

3. Economic goods can be categorized as things we can enjoy right away and those that last a long time. Enjoyable goods are those that are ready to use, providing satisfaction or about to provide it at any moment, like the refreshing breeze from a fan on a hot day or the steaming cup of coffee sitting on the table.

Enjoyable goods and durable agents

Many goods of just the same form as the foregoing may not be affording current gratification (except that afforded by thrift and forethought), but are kept because later they will gratify a more intense want or gratify a want better. Apples and potatoes are kept in a cellar so that their use is distributed throughout the winter; cider and wine are kept till they get a quality that appeals more to the palate. Coal, wood, and stocks of goods, are thus kept in the form of enjoyable goods, destined to be physically destroyed when at length they yield a gratification. Evidently they must be storing up meantime a certain additional utility, for otherwise there would be no reason why they should be kept for the future. Such goods as these are sometimes called unripened consumption goods, but until ripened they bear in part the character of durable agents.

Many items that are similar to the ones mentioned earlier might not provide immediate satisfaction (other than the satisfaction that comes from saving and planning ahead), but they are stored because they will satisfy a deeper need later on or fulfill a need more effectively. Apples and potatoes are stored in a cellar so their use is spread out over the winter; cider and wine are kept until they develop flavors that are more appealing. Coal, wood, and supplies of goods are kept as enjoyable items, meant to be physically used up when they finally provide satisfaction. Clearly, they must be accumulating some extra value in the meantime, since there would be no reason to keep them for the future otherwise. These goods are sometimes referred to as unripened consumption goods, but until they are ready, they also have some qualities of durable goods.

Abiding sources of economic enjoyments are called durable agents. The inhabited house is a source of continued gratification in each moment's shelter it affords; but, further, it is the durable source of a series of future uses, as yet unripened.[Pg 48] The hammer, the hoe, the tree, the field may all be considered as agents to secure consumption goods. Some of these are but one step removed from direct gratification, as the hoe helping the gardener to get food for his own use. Other agents are bound by many technical links to the ultimate gratification.

Abiding sources of economic enjoyment are known as durable agents. A house provides ongoing satisfaction with each moment of shelter it offers; moreover, it is a lasting source for a range of future uses that are not yet realized.[Pg 48] Tools like the hammer, the hoe, the tree, and the field can all be viewed as agents to obtain consumable goods. Some of these are just a step away from direct satisfaction, like the hoe that helps a gardener grow food for personal use. Other agents are connected through many technical steps to the final satisfaction.

Degrees of durableness

4. This classification of goods is abstract, in that it is a classification, not of concrete goods, but of qualities shared in some degree by nearly all goods. Most goods unite in some degree both characters, but in varying measure. This is, therefore, a continuity classification, the varying classes of goods grading from those whose durableness is zero (just at the moment of consumption) to those most durable, which yield an endless series of uses or products. Yet the classification is practical, corresponding as it does with thoughts which men have in the use of goods. By repairs and other methods goods become, and are looked upon as, durable sources of a series of uses.

4. This classification of goods is abstract because it categorizes not specific items, but qualities that nearly all goods share to some extent. Most goods combine both characteristics to varying degrees. Therefore, this is a continuum classification, where goods range from those with zero durability (right at the moment of consumption) to the most durable, which provide an endless series of uses or products. However, the classification is practical, as it aligns with how people think about using goods. Through repairs and other methods, goods are seen as long-lasting sources for a variety of uses.

It is to be noted further that the enjoyable goods pass over into psychic income, that is, they are the stream of objective utilities that is each moment detaching itself as income from the great mass of wealth. The durable goods are those utilities which for the time remain, not yet ripened or ready to be converted into psychic income.

It should be noted that enjoyable goods transform into psychological income, meaning they are the flow of useful things that, at each moment, separate themselves as income from the overall wealth. Durable goods are those useful items that currently remain, not yet matured or ready to be turned into psychological income.

§ II. CONDITIONS OF ECONOMIC WEALTH

Income as affected by climatic conditions

1. The bounty and variety of the natural supply of indirect goods in the material world are the prime conditions of a bountiful income to society. The effect of climate on the supply of goods available for man is complex. Climate is itself a direct source of gratification. As temperature must be adjusted to man's need, climate satisfies wants directly. Health, energy, the beauty of noonday woods and of sunlit clouds are conditioned on the favor of nature. Climate affects, further, the supply of material economic goods. All[Pg 49] the earlier civilizations arose in warmer countries. But, after man had gained a certain mastery over the obstacles of nature, he was able to soften the harsher features of climate, and with better shelter and clothing, with better stocks of winter food and fuel, the more favorable features of the temperate zone could be utilized. So civilization moved northward from Egypt and India to Greece and Rome, to northern Europe and America.

1. The abundance and variety of natural resources in the material world are key to providing a healthy income for society. The impact of climate on the availability of goods for people is complicated. Climate itself directly contributes to satisfaction. As temperatures need to be adjusted for human comfort, climate meets basic needs directly. Health, energy, and the beauty of sunny woods at noon and bright clouds depend on nature's favor. Furthermore, climate influences the availability of physical economic goods. All[Pg 49] early civilizations developed in warmer regions. However, once humans learned to overcome some of nature's challenges, they could mitigate the harsher aspects of climate. With better housing and clothing, along with improved supplies of winter food and fuel, they could take advantage of the more favorable aspects of the temperate zone. This is how civilization progressed northward from Egypt and India to Greece and Rome, and eventually to northern Europe and America.

By natural resources

Soil conditions for vegetable life determine first the amount and kind of animal life. Animal life from one point of view is a parasite, living on the vegetable; it is only the vegetable that has power to assimilate most inorganic compounds. Water being a need of plant life, the amount of rainfall is one of the most important conditions of industry. Man, therefore, depends on the resources of the soil directly or indirectly; a fertile soil furnishes him either directly a supply of vegetable food, or indirectly a supply of animal food.

Soil conditions for growing vegetables primarily determine the types and amounts of animal life. From one perspective, animals can be seen as parasites, relying on plants since only plants can transform most inorganic materials. Water is essential for plant life, so the amount of rainfall is a key factor in industry. Therefore, humans depend on the soil's resources, either directly or indirectly; fertile soil provides them with a direct supply of plant-based food or an indirect supply of animal-based food.

Natural supplies of metals, of coal, and of timber are important consumption goods, but they are also indirectly the condition for a vast variety of other goods. The industry that could exist without iron, copper, and coal would be of a very low grade.

Natural sources of metals, coal, and timber are essential resources, but they also indirectly serve as the foundation for a wide range of other products. An industry that could exist without iron, copper, and coal would be significantly less advanced.

By flora and fauna

The variety of flora and fauna, and their fitness for man's needs, largely condition the possible production. If, in the course of evolution, it had chanced that wheat and corn, the horse and the cow, had been crowded out in the struggle for existence, we should have had a very different civilization. The possibilities of civilization in Peru, and those of all the Indians on the American continent, were limited for lack of domestic animals. Animals that are fit for domestication are a necessary intermediate agent by aid of which man can appropriate and turn to his use the fertile qualities of the soil.

The variety of plants and animals, and how well they serve human needs, greatly influence potential production. If, throughout evolution, wheat and corn, horses and cows had been eliminated in the struggle for survival, our civilization would be very different. The development of civilization in Peru, and that of all the Indigenous peoples on the American continent, was restricted due to a lack of domesticated animals. Animals that can be domesticated are essential intermediaries that allow humans to harness and utilize the fertile qualities of the land.

Not content with the material world about him, even when it is at its best, man alters it in many ways. He enriches the soil, improves the varieties of animals, he even in some[Pg 50] slight degree affects the climate, and by the use of a multitude of artificial bits of matter called tools, works profound changes in the world in which he lives.

Not satisfied with the material world around him, even at its best, people change it in many ways. They enrich the soil, improve animal breeds, and even slightly influence the climate. Using a variety of artificial tools, they make significant changes to the world they inhabit.

By motion and energy

2. A large part of the utility of goods is conditioned on motion and energy. It has been said that man's power in production is limited to moving things. The outer world is to man the sole source of motive forces. He can bring things together and they produce the result. Further, it may be said that nearly every kind of utility is conditioned on motion. It is man's aim to secure a constant inflow of goods. To secure this either he must move to get the goods, or he must cause goods to move toward him.

2. A big part of the usefulness of goods depends on movement and energy. It's been said that a person's ability to produce is restricted to moving things. The outside world is the only source of energy for people. They can bring things together, and this creates results. Additionally, nearly every type of usefulness relies on movement. People aim to ensure a steady supply of goods. To achieve this, they either need to go out and get the goods or make the goods come to them.

The law of "conservation of energy" helps to explain economic action; the supply of energy in the universe cannot be increased or diminished, but may take on new forms. So a limited supply in man's control may take on various forms and so have different effects on gratifications. One and the same source of energy may be converted into the different forms of heat, light, motion, electricity, etc. But there must be some source. Man's desire is directed to getting force at the right place and in the right degree. If light or heat is too intense, it causes pain; the glare of the sun blinds instead of giving keener vision. A moderate force applied to any of the senses gives the maximum clearness or pleasure. Man is constantly endeavoring to secure forces from the outer world and to adjust motion so that it will directly or indirectly best serve his purposes.

The law of "conservation of energy" helps explain economic activity; the total amount of energy in the universe can't be increased or decreased, but it can change forms. So, a limited supply that humans can control may take on various forms and produce different effects on satisfactions. The same source of energy can be transformed into different types like heat, light, motion, electricity, and so on. However, there must be a source. People aim to harness energy in the right place and in the right amount. If light or heat is too strong, it can cause discomfort; the brightness of the sun can blind rather than enhance vision. A moderate amount of energy applied to any of the senses provides maximum clarity or pleasure. Humans are always trying to tap into forces from the outside world and adjust motion so that it best serves their needs, either directly or indirectly.

By food, animals, and fuel

3. Among the main sources of power used by men are food, domestic animals, and fuel. In eating food man stores up force in his own body. When he draws the bow he puts force into it to lie latent until liberated at the right moment. There must be a source of energy likewise that mental action may go on, and the power of sunbeams, stored for a time in food, is liberated in the processes of thought.

3. Some of the main sources of power that people rely on are food, domesticated animals, and fuel. By consuming food, a person stores energy in their body. When drawing a bow, they apply force, which remains ready to be released at the perfect moment. There also needs to be an energy source for mental activities to occur, and the energy from sunlight, absorbed in food, is released during the process of thinking.

This first natural mode of liberating energy within their own bodies does not satisfy the growing needs and aims of[Pg 51] men. Such a mode is "labor," which becomes at times painful and distasteful. In the earliest societies known, some sorts of domestic animals are found supplementing man's efforts and acting upon the material world to alter it for man. The dog joining in the chase guards his master's safety, and helps to bear his burdens. The draft-beast in the field turns the heavy soil, and aids in the final harvest. The trained elephant does the work of twenty men piling logs, loading ships, or carrying burdens.

This basic way of releasing energy in their own bodies doesn’t meet the increasing needs and goals of[Pg 51] men. This way is "labor," which can sometimes be painful and unappealing. In the earliest known societies, some domestic animals helped enhance human efforts and changed the environment for people. The dog, while running with its master, ensures his safety and helps carry his loads. The draft animal in the field turns the tough soil and assists in the final harvest. The trained elephant can do the work of twenty men by stacking logs, loading ships, or carrying heavy loads.

Man further increases his control over the material world by making other men do his bidding. Domestic slavery, where wife or child serves the father of the family, or chattel slavery, where the vanquished toils for the victor, are all but universal in early communities. Such a method of increasing one's control over the forces of the world requires only superior strength, no special intelligence in mechanics, and is thus one of the first crude devices in a primitive civilization.

Man further increases his control over the material world by making others do his bidding. Domestic slavery, where a wife or child serves the father of the family, or chattel slavery, where the defeated work for the conqueror, are nearly universal in early societies. This way of boosting control over the forces of the world relies solely on superior strength, requiring no special mechanical intelligence, making it one of the earliest crude methods in a primitive civilization.

Fuel has been, up to the present time, perhaps the most important source of energy. Fire in the hands of savage man gave him dominion over the forests and over the metals. In this age of steam the liberation of the energy of the sun, stored up in coal in ages past, is still the indispensable condition of our developed industry.

Fuel has been, until now, probably the most important source of energy. Fire, when used by early humans, gave them control over forests and metals. In this era of steam, harnessing the energy of the sun, which has been stored in coal for ages, remains essential for our advanced industries.

By the energy in wind and flowing water

4. The greatest and most exhaustless reservoirs of power for man's use are in wind and water. While the supply of fuel is being used at a progressive rate and will soon approach exhaustion, there are elsewhere exhaustless stores of energy awaiting man's command. To make use of the wind for sailing a boat, only the simplest arrangements are needed; a windmill fixed at one place requires more ingenuity and machinery. The energy of the wind is derived from the sun and will last until the sun loses its heat. If some means can be found for equalizing the flow and for storing the power of the wind, it may yet become a great agency of industry. The force of falling water, long used in a petty[Pg 52] way by the old water-mills, is just beginning to be employed on a large scale at such points as Niagara. Where fuel is high, as on the Pacific coast, wave motors have been successfully used in a small way, but wave motion is too irregular to serve well the needs for power. But the constant motion of the tides offers, at some favored points, a source of power that will remain as long as the earth revolves upon its axis.

4. The greatest and most limitless sources of energy for people's use are wind and water. While we're using up fuel at a rapid pace and it's going to run out soon, there are abundant supplies of energy just waiting for us to harness. Using the wind to sail a boat only requires basic setups, but a windmill fixed in one spot needs more creativity and machinery. The energy in the wind comes from the sun and will continue as long as the sun gives off heat. If we can find ways to balance the flow and store wind power, it could become a major force in industry. The power of falling water, which has been used on a small scale by old watermills, is just starting to be tapped more widely at places like Niagara. In areas where fuel costs are high, like the Pacific coast, wave motors have been used successfully on a small scale, but wave motion is too unpredictable to meet power needs efficiently. However, the steady movement of tides offers, at select locations, a power source that will last as long as the earth spins on its axis.

By the intelligent utilization of all these agencies

5. Man studies and compares the durable goods that give him command over enjoyable goods, and attaches value to them. Thus energy is found dissipating itself throughout the world in ways useless to man, and in places where it cannot serve his purposes. As man grows in power of control over nature, he seeks to apply these forces in forms and at places he has selected. If he can arm himself with the energies of mine and torrent, he can react with giant strength on the material world. He ceases to accept passively its conditions, and to live on its grudging gifts; he becomes its fashioner, in a sense its creator. His intelligence and his wants are most important factors determining what the form of the physical world about him shall be.

5. People study and compare the durable goods that give them control over enjoyable goods and assign value to them. Thus, energy is found wasting itself throughout the world in ways that are useless to people and in places where it cannot serve their purposes. As individuals gain more control over nature, they strive to apply these forces in forms and at locations they have chosen. If they can harness the energies of mines and rivers, they can exert tremendous strength on the material world. They stop passively accepting its conditions and living off its begrudging gifts; they become its shapers, in a sense its creators. Their intelligence and desires are key factors that determine what the physical world around them will look like.

But all the efforts of men in the most developed economy cannot make to disappear the differences in the quality of goods and agents. Desirable goods to consume are limited in quantity, and they vary in quality; hence they have value and some higher than others. Likewise, durable material agents and sources of power are limited in number and vary in convenience of location and efficiency. As men seek to gratify their desires, they attach importance to these agents of power. Each is valued for its service or its series of services. When anything is seen to contain a series of uses, it becomes a rent-bearer, and the economic problem of rent arises, one step more complex than the problem of valuing simple consumption goods.

But even with all the efforts of people in the most developed economy, the differences in the quality of goods and resources can’t be eliminated. The desirable goods available for consumption are limited in quantity and vary in quality; therefore, they have value, with some holding more value than others. Similarly, durable resources and sources of power are limited in number and differ in location and efficiency. As people try to satisfy their desires, they place importance on these power sources. Each is valued for its service or the range of services it provides. When something is recognized as having multiple uses, it becomes capable of generating rental income, and the economic issue of rent comes into play, which is a step more complex than simply valuing consumption goods.


CHAPTER 8

THE RENTING CONTRACT

§ I. NATURE AND DEFINITION OF RENT

Temporary use and permanent possession of agents

1. The temporary use of materials and power and their sources is necessary to bring most enjoyable goods into being. Indirect goods have value solely because they help to get direct goods. The apple-tree is valued because it bears fruit, and the orchard because the trees give promise of yielding a succession of crops for years to come. There are thus two problems of value in connection with durable goods: that of the value of a temporary use for a brief period, as for a year; and that of the value of a thing itself, the use-bearer, for a long series of years or in perpetuity. To explain what fixes the value of the temporary use is the problem of rent; to explain what determines the value of long-continued use or of permanent control and ownership of a use-bearer is the problem of capitalization.

1. The temporary use of materials and energy and their sources is essential for creating the most enjoyable products. Indirect goods hold value only because they help us obtain direct goods. An apple tree is valued because it produces fruit, and an orchard is valuable because the trees promise a steady yield of crops for years to come. There are, therefore, two value-related issues regarding durable goods: the value of temporary use for a short time, like a year; and the value of the item itself, the use-bearer, over a long period or indefinitely. Understanding what determines the value of temporary use is the issue of rent; understanding what influences the value of long-term use or the permanent control and ownership of a use-bearer is the issue of capitalization.

Origin of the term rent

2. The term rent is used in a number of senses, which must be carefully distinguished. The original meaning of rent was any regular income or revenue arising from wealth. The word comes from the low Latin renta from renda, in turn from redditus, that which is given, yielded or given back, or rendita, that which is given or returned. The French rendre (English render), to give or return that which belongs to one, is used very early. Chaucer used "rente" as an income. "Cattle had he enough and rente," cattle probably meaning property (chattels), and rente income. Rental is a collective term for a number of rents.[Pg 54] The total yield of an estate was called its rental or rent-roll, and a list of the various sources of income, including all payments from tenants in money, produce or services, constituted its rental.

2. The term rent is used in several ways, which need to be clearly distinguished. The original meaning of rent referred to any regular income or revenue generated from wealth. The word comes from the low Latin renta from renda, which in turn comes from redditus, meaning what is given, yielded, or returned, or rendita, which refers to something that is given or returned. The French rendre (English render), which means to give or return what belongs to someone, has been used for a long time. Chaucer used "rente" to describe income. "Cattle had he enough and rente," where cattle likely refers to property (chattels), and rente refers to income. Rental is a broad term encompassing various types of rents.[Pg 54] The total income from an estate was referred to as its rental or rent-roll, and a list of the different sources of income, including all payments from tenants in cash, produce, or services, made up its rental.

Popular and special meaning of rent

3. The popular meaning of rent is the amount paid for the use of material things which must be returned to the owners after the time of use agreed upon. We speak of the rent of a house, boat, etc., using the word as a synonym for hire. In the European languages the word is used more frequently in that sense. In the French la rente means the income from any kind of property; but corporate securities and national bonds came particularly to be called les rentes, because they are a form of investment yielding a permanent income. The one who has a perpetual income from bonds or rents is called a rentier. In German the term Rente is used more broadly than in English, as an income of any sort, Grundrente meaning the rent of land, and Capitalrente the income usually in England called interest.

3. The common definition of rent is the amount paid for using physical items that must be returned to their owners after the agreed-upon period. We talk about the rent of a house, boat, etc., using the term as a synonym for hire. In European languages, this word is used more often in that context. In French, la rente refers to income gained from any type of property; however, corporate securities and national bonds specifically became known as les rentes, since they represent a type of investment that provides a steady income. Someone who receives a steady income from bonds or rents is called a rentier. In German, the term Rente is used more broadly than in English, referring to any type of income, with Grundrente meaning the rent of land, and Capitalrente signifying the income normally referred to as interest in England.

A restricted meaning has long been applied by economists to the word: the income yielded by lands, etc. This was put in contrast with interest for money and capital, and with wages of labor. This meaning is now being abandoned by economic students.

A limited meaning has long been used by economists for the term: the income generated by land, etc. This was contrasted with interest from money and capital, and with wages from labor. This definition is now being abandoned by economics students.

A wider meaning recently given to the word by many economists turns on the supposed relation of some portions of price to cost of production. Thus, frequent use is made of the expressions: consumer's rent, producer's rent, buyer's rent, seller's rent, etc. In the well-founded opinion of some recent critics this usage rests on a mistaken reasoning. However, in the midst of this wide variety of usage the student must be forewarned and alert. Doubtless agreement will at length be arrived at. Meantime, no economist can dictate what meaning is to be attached to the term, but one may suggest the definition that seems to him most expedient. Throughout this work we shall endeavor to use the term rent uniformly and consistently as it is now to be defined.

A broader meaning recently assigned to the word by many economists relates to the supposed connection between certain parts of price and production costs. As a result, terms like: consumer's rent, producer's rent, buyer's rent, seller's rent, etc., are often used. Some recent critics believe that this usage is based on faulty reasoning. Nevertheless, amid this diverse usage, students must be cautious and attentive. Eventually, a consensus will likely be reached. In the meantime, no economist can dictate what meaning should be given to the term, but one can propose the definition they find most practical. Throughout this work, we will strive to use the term rent consistently and uniformly as it will be defined.

The essence of rent

4. The essential thought in rent, as we shall use it, is that it is the value of the usufruct as distinguished from the value of the use-bearer or thing itself. The meaning of usufruct is the use of the fruits, or in legal phrase: "the right of using and enjoying the income of an estate or other thing belonging to another, without impairing the substance." The obvious fact is that fruits can be eaten without destroying the tree, the harvest gathered without destroying the field. By a metaphor the word in legal discussion is applied to the use of any product, and we shall employ it, as in common speech, in reference to one's own goods as well as to the goods of another.

4. The main idea behind rent, as we’ll define it, is that it's the value of using something, separate from the value of the person or thing providing it. Usufruct means the right to use the fruits, or in legal terms: "the right to use and enjoy the income from an estate or other property that belongs to someone else, without damaging the actual asset." The clear point is that you can eat the fruit without harming the tree; you can harvest crops without ruining the field. In legal discussions, this term is metaphorically applied to the use of any product, and we’ll use it, like in everyday language, in relation to both personal belongings and those of others.

Rented agents are looked upon as durable

The qualities whose use gives value are not usually indestructible, but they are treated as undestroyed. There is a famous phrase used by Ricardo, "rent is paid for the original and indestructible qualities of the soil." He said "indestructible," but the word is not apt. There are many qualities in the fertile field that must be destroyed when it is used. Every economist since Ricardo's time has recognized this, and many excuses for the inaccuracy have been given. After every harvest, the field is less serviceable than before, and if it is to be of the same grade of efficiency, the fertile elements must be restored. We cannot assert that Ricardo meant undestroyed, for he was not quite clear on the question. But it is evident that one can count as true income only that part of the value of product that remains after full repairs have been made. It is only by a fiction that most indirect agents can be regarded as indestructible. Things yielding rent are not indestructible, but generally they are preserved undestroyed.

The qualities that create value aren’t usually permanent, but they’re treated as if they are. There’s a well-known saying by Ricardo: “rent is paid for the original and indestructible qualities of the soil.” He used the term “indestructible,” but that’s not quite right. There are many qualities in a fertile field that must be diminished when it’s used. Every economist since Ricardo has acknowledged this, and there have been numerous justifications for the mistake. After each harvest, the field becomes less productive, and to maintain the same level of efficiency, the nutrient elements need to be replenished. We can’t assume that Ricardo meant undestroyed, as he wasn’t entirely clear on the subject. However, it is obvious that true income can only be considered as the portion of the product’s value that remains after all necessary repairs have been made. Most indirect agents are only seen as indestructible through a kind of fiction. Things that generate rent aren’t indestructible, but typically they are kept from being destroyed.

True rent a net income

5. A distinction must be made between gross and net, or true and false rent. Before the usufruct is estimated, allowance must be made for repairs, depreciation, and for various expenses which absorb a good portion of the gross product. When this allowance has been made, the income may be considered as a net sum not due to the sale, or to[Pg 56] the using up of any part of the thing rented. This is the essential thought in typical rent—that it is the value of the surplus, or net product, of an economic agent leaving the agent itself unimpaired in efficiency. The total product is sometimes called the "gross rent," but economic rent is "net rent." This thought is made clearer by the following discussion.

5. You need to differentiate between gross and net, or true and false rent. Before estimating the usufruct, you should account for repairs, depreciation, and various expenses that take up a significant portion of the gross product. Once these deductions are made, the income can be viewed as a net amount that isn't tied to the sale or to[Pg 56] the consumption of any part of the rented item. This is the key idea behind typical rent—it represents the value of the surplus or net product of an economic agent while keeping the agent itself fully functional. The total product is sometimes referred to as "gross rent," but economic rent is "net rent." This concept becomes clearer in the following discussion.

§ II. THE HISTORY OF CONTRACT RENT AND CHANGES IN IT

Economic and contract rent distinguished

1. Economic rent (likewise called natural, competitive, and sometimes rack rent) is to be distinguished from contract rent. Economic rent is the market value of the usufruct, and contract rent is the amount a man pays for the use of wealth by virtue of an existing agreement. The one is impersonal or economic; the other is personal or legal, being fixed by agreements between persons. The rents usually spoken of are contract rents.

1. Economic rent (also known as natural, competitive, and sometimes rack rent) is different from contract rent. Economic rent is the market value of the use of assets, while contract rent is the amount someone pays to use those assets based on an existing agreement. The first is impersonal or economic; the second is personal or legal, set by agreements between individuals. The rents that are typically discussed are contract rents.

The two diverge more or less. If the contract has been lately made the two will be nearly the same. Contracts of long standing often bind the tenant or borrower to pay either more or less than the present competitive price. If, after a time, the value of the use is greater than the contract rent, the tenant is fortunate in having his lease. But he is the loser if he is bound by lease or agreement to pay rent in a locality where land has become less valuable.

The two diverge more or less. If the contract was made recently, the two will be pretty much the same. Long-standing contracts often require the tenant or borrower to pay more or less than the current market price. If, over time, the value of the use is higher than the contract rent, the tenant is lucky to have their lease. But they lose out if they're stuck in a lease or agreement to pay rent in an area where land has become less valuable.

Economic and contract rent usually diverge also because of the agreement that the owner, or lender, keep up the repairs and pay the taxes. Here it is simply the difference between gross and net rent.

Economic and contract rent often differ because the owner or lender is responsible for maintaining repairs and paying taxes. Essentially, it comes down to the difference between gross and net rent.

Custom may prevent the owner from charging all the usufruct of the agent is worth. If the contract rent is less than the economic rent, evidently the borrower enjoys a part of the usufruct, without charge, and to that degree is in the position of an owner. The usufruct in this case is divided between the two parties. Such instances were numerous in[Pg 57] the Middle Ages in the renting of land, and still are found in many countries.

Custom may stop the owner from charging the full value of what the agent's usufruct is worth. If the rent specified in the contract is lower

Contract rent is based on economic rent and tends to conform to it whenever there is competition. The existence of economic rent is the basis of the agreement to pay contract rent. Prospective hirers of agents forecast what the use will be worth to them and make their bids accordingly.

Contract rent is based on economic rent and usually aligns with it when there is competition. The presence of economic rent is the foundation for the agreement to pay contract rent. Potential renters of agents predict what the use will be worth to them and place their bids accordingly.

The renting contract for the use of wealth

2. The renting contract is the agreement of a borrower to pay for the use of a thing and, at the end of the time, to restore it in good condition or pay for its complete repair. In practical business it is necessary to have definite agreements to prevent disputes. Some provide that one party, some that the other party, shall keep up repairs. The form of the renting contract is observed by men in estimating the uses of their own wealth where no contract exists. If they count the gross product of an agent as rent, it is bad bookkeeping. In many cases it is necessary, therefore, to follow the form of the renting contract in order to determine the net yield of indirect goods.

2. A rental agreement is a contract between a borrower and a lender where the borrower pays to use an item and agrees to return it in good condition or cover the full cost of its repairs at the end of the rental period. In business, clear agreements are essential to avoid conflicts. Some agreements specify that one party is responsible for maintenance, while others assign that responsibility to the other party. The type of rental agreement is also reflected in how people evaluate the value of their own assets when there's no formal contract in place. If they mistakenly treat the total income from an asset as rent, it's poor accounting. Thus, in many situations, it's crucial to adhere to the structure of a rental agreement to accurately assess the net returns from indirect goods.

The renting contract in the middle Ages

3. In early stages of industry the use of nearly all wealth is estimated under the renting contract. In the lower stages of culture, in hunting, fishing, or nomadic pastoral tribes, land is not recognized as wealth to be exchanged or owned. But at a later stage, as in the Middle Ages in Europe, land and the things pertaining to it, as ditches, houses, mills, cattle, stock, and the few simple implements, constituted the larger portion of the wealth. Land was granted to the tenant or serf in return for services. The contract was pretty strictly drawn and all items were specified. It was not hard to hold the tenant to his contract to keep the land in about the same condition. There was a certain rotation of crops; the tenant was obliged to keep his stock up to standard; and, moreover, he had a certain interest in the land because his contract rent (as explained above) was less than the economic rent. The landlord, therefore, could count[Pg 58] pretty surely on the undiminished power of his land and stock from one year to another.

3. In the early stages of industry, nearly all wealth is assessed based on rental agreements. In the more primitive stages of culture, such as among hunting, fishing, or nomadic pastoral tribes, land isn't seen as something to be exchanged or owned. However, later on, especially during the Middle Ages in Europe, land and things associated with it, like ditches, houses, mills, cattle, livestock, and a few basic tools, made up a large part of wealth. Land was given to tenants or serfs in exchange for their services. The agreements were usually very detailed, specifying all aspects involved. It wasn't difficult to ensure that tenants upheld their agreements to maintain the land's condition. There was a system of crop rotation; tenants had to keep their livestock at a certain level; additionally, they had a vested interest in the land because their contract rent (as previously explained) was lower than the market rent. Thus, landlords could rely[Pg 58] on the consistent value of their land and livestock from year to year.

At that time, truck and barter were the common modes of exchange, and rents were paid in products and services, not in money. The fruits of the soil were consumed on the spot instead of being sold as now. Land was rarely, if ever, sold outright, so that there was no occasion to estimate its total selling value. It was thought of as a place on which to live and as a source of livelihood. Its yearly use was all that was subject to contract, sale, and exchange. Not the land itself but a rent charge on the land was sold, the term rent charge meaning an annual sum payable out of the yield of an estate. Many medieval estates were so tied up by legal conditions that they could not be sold outright; all that the owner could do was to sell or mortgage the annual rental. Thus, in the Middle Ages, it was all but universal to look upon most indirect agents as exchangeable only under the renting contract, as subject to renting but not to complete transfer and sale.

At that time, trading and bartering were the usual methods of exchange, and rents were paid in goods and services instead of cash. The produce from the land was consumed right there rather than being sold as it is today. Land was rarely, if ever, sold outright, so there was no need to assess its total market value. It was seen as a place to live and a source of income. Only its annual use was subject to contracts, sales, and exchanges. Not the land itself, but a rent charge on the land was sold, with rent charge referring to an annual amount paid from the estate's revenue. Many medieval estates were so bound by legal restrictions that they couldn't be sold outright; the owner could only sell or mortgage the annual rental. Therefore, in the Middle Ages, it was nearly universal to view most indirect agents as exchangeable only through rental agreements, subject to renting but not to complete transfer and sale.

The renting contract not convenient in commerce

4. As industry developed, the renting contract remained almost wholly confined to cases of renting lands and houses. The materials and appliances needed for manufacture and commerce are so manifold and varying in quality that the rent-form of contract is very cumbersome and difficult for exchangers to enforce. If a merchant about to embark on a trading journey wished to rent a ship and a stock of goods, the renting contract became most difficult to interpret. He must agree to repay the loan in goods of the same kind and quality as those received, a contract most difficult to execute, and giving occasion to costly tests and countless disagreements. It was much easier for the merchant to get his loan under the interest contract, i.e., a money loan, with which to buy the goods. With the growth of industry and commerce, wealth increased in towns, taking many forms, as those of ships, wagons, tools, and stocks of goods, that could not conveniently be rented.

4. As industry grew, rental agreements mostly remained limited to renting land and homes. The materials and equipment needed for manufacturing and commerce are so diverse and vary greatly in quality that rental contracts are very cumbersome and hard for people to enforce. If a merchant wanted to rent a ship and some goods for a trading journey, the rental agreement became very complicated to understand. He would have to agree to repay the loan in goods of the same type and quality as those he received, a contract that was very challenging to fulfill and led to expensive tests and countless disputes. It was much easier for the merchant to take out a loan based on interest, i.e., a cash loan, to buy the goods. As industry and commerce expanded, wealth in towns increased in various forms, such as ships, wagons, tools, and stocks of goods, which could not easily be rented.

The thought of it remains associated with a rural economy

In England, the country which developed its industrial system earliest, the idea of rent, therefore, gradually became disassociated almost entirely from the use or hire of any wealth but land and real property. Because in the Middle Ages rent was associated almost entirely with natural resources, they being the only important forms of wealth which men rented from others, there was fostered the idea that the essential mark of rent is the connection with natural resources. It is a simple example of the association of ideas. In the transfer or loan of movable goods, the rent contract was quite overshadowed by the other form of contract, that of a money loan. According to this explanation the essential and primary difference between renting wealth and borrowing money at interest is not in the kind of wealth whose use is thus temporarily transferred, but in the nature of the contract. But as forms of wealth differ in their fitness for transfer under the two forms of contract, there goes on a competition between them, as a result of which each becomes associated with certain groups of goods. In the Middle Ages the renting contract was the dominant form, but it has been progressively displaced by loans in the money form, and its importance is still declining.

In England, the first country to develop its industrial system, the concept of rent has gradually become almost completely detached from the use or rental of anything other than land and real estate. In the Middle Ages, rent was mainly linked to natural resources, as those were the primary forms of wealth that people rented from one another, reinforcing the notion that the defining characteristic of rent is its connection to natural resources. This is a straightforward example of how ideas become connected. In the case of movable goods, the rent agreement was largely overshadowed by the loan agreement for money. The key difference between renting an asset and borrowing money at interest lies not in the type of wealth being temporarily transferred, but in the nature of the contract itself. However, since different types of wealth vary in their suitability for transfer under these two types of contracts, a competition arises, leading to each being linked to specific categories of goods. During the Middle Ages, rental agreements were the most common, but they have gradually been replaced by money loans, and their significance continues to decline.

Renting contracts most used with land

5. The main forms of wealth whose usufruct is still sold under long renting contracts are land and its more durable improvements. In England farms are let under long leases, a very common form being the thirty-year lease. Under the old, almost fixed, conditions in agriculture such a lease was equitable, but when prices are rapidly changing and when new methods are being introduced, it gives rise to great hardships. About twenty-five years ago, the great fall in the price of agricultural products brought ruin to many of the tenant farmers. The land troubles in Ireland have been largely about tenants' improvements. When the lease expired, the landlord could appropriate all the improvements that the tenant had made. In America farms are let usually on shares, and from year to year, but the plan of a money rent is increasingly followed. The difficulty of getting an equitable arrangement between landlord and tenant is recognized[Pg 60] by all. The landlord must make the proper repairs or see that they are made; he must specify in the contract whether the products can be taken away or are to be fed on the place so that the soil may not be impoverished, and he must provide for the purchase of other fertilizers. On the other hand, the tenant under the renting contract has little motive for improvement, and many occasions for discontent. So in America, far more than in the older countries, land changes hands by sale, the purchaser going into debt for it, giving his note and paying interest on the loan rather than rent for the farm.

5. The primary forms of wealth whose usage rights are still sold under long-term rental agreements are land and its more permanent improvements. In England, farms are often leased under long leases, with the thirty-year lease being quite common. Given the old, nearly fixed conditions in agriculture, such a lease was fair, but with rapidly changing prices and new methods being introduced, it leads to significant challenges. About twenty-five years ago, the sharp decline in agricultural product prices devastated many tenant farmers. The land issues in Ireland have largely revolved around tenant improvements. When the lease ended, the landlord could take all the improvements that the tenant had made. In America, farms are usually rented on a share basis or from year to year, but the system of cash rent is becoming more popular. Everyone recognizes the difficulty in achieving a fair agreement between landlord and tenant[Pg 60]. The landlord must handle necessary repairs or ensure they're completed; he must clarify in the contract whether the products can be removed or are to be consumed on-site to avoid depleting the soil, and he must make provisions for purchasing other fertilizers. On the flip side, the tenant under the rental agreement has little incentive for making improvements and many reasons for dissatisfaction. Thus, in America, much more than in older countries, land frequently changes hands through sales, with the buyer often going into debt, signing a note, and paying interest on the loan rather than paying rent for the farm.

But many other goods are rented

Many less durable goods are rented for brief periods. Carriages are rented for the day, bicycles by the week or month. Sewing-machines, boats, guns, tents, and even diamond engagement rings, yield their joys under the renting contract. People frequently hesitate between the renting and the purchase of a piano, and in some cases renting is the more convenient and desirable way of securing its use. The purchase of a dress-coat or of a masquerade-suit to be worn but once, involves for some an excessive and needless sacrifice. For a moderate sum its temporary use may be had, and it is then returned, little the worse for wear, to the accommodating clothier.

Many less durable items are rented for short periods. Carriages are rented for the day, bicycles by the week or month. Sewing machines, boats, guns, tents, and even diamond engagement rings bring joy through rental agreements. People often weigh the options between renting and buying a piano, and in some cases, renting is the more practical and preferred way to use it. Buying a dress coat or a costume to be worn just once can be an excessive and unnecessary expense for some. Instead, they can rent it for a reasonable price and then return it in good condition to the friendly clothier.

Economic rent much wider than the renting contract

A final word of caution may be given. Economic rent is not confined to the cases of contract rent. It exists in every case where a more or less durable agent yields a use that is scarce and desirable. The owner who uses a thing himself gets the advantage in the product as clearly as if he collected rent from a borrower. Houses lived in by the owners, house furnishings, clothing, books, all scarce and durable agents, are yielding rents in this logical sense. To the economist, therefore, the problem of economic rent, as one of the grand divisions of the problem of value, remains of undiminished importance, for in these unceasing streams of uses emanating from our environment, is found the basis for the value of all durable wealth.

A final word of caution: economic rent isn't just limited to contract rent cases. It exists anytime a relatively durable resource provides a use that is limited and desirable. When an owner uses an item themselves, they benefit from its output just as if they were collecting rent from someone else. Homes occupied by their owners, furniture, clothes, and books—all these scarce and durable resources—are generating rent in this logical sense. For economists, the issue of economic rent, as a major aspect of value, remains highly significant. In the continuous flow of uses coming from our surroundings lies the foundation for the value of all durable wealth.


CHAPTER 9

THE LAW OF DIMINISHING RETURNS

§ I. DEFINITION OF THE CONCEPT OF (ECONOMIC) DIMINISHING RETURNS

Economic agents contain uses to be obtained only with progressive difficulty

1. The phrase "diminishing returns of industrial agents" is the expression of the fact that there is an elastic limit to the utility any indirect good can afford within a given time. Successive attempts to get additional services from a thing are usually in part successful, but each additional service is gained with more difficulty, or a smaller added service is gained for an equal expenditure of materials or effort. A book stands many hours untouched on the shelves of the library; but if, as often happens, two or more persons wish to use it at the same hour, time and energy are wasted. The book has a potential use during the twenty-four hours, but all this can be secured only at the cost of the greatest inconvenience. The greatest net uses, therefore, are seen to be to the first user and in the first hour, for these uses cost the least time and trouble. If the members of a family will take turns, one chair will serve for all of them; but if all are to be able to sit down together, a chair must be provided for each. Often it will happen that only one chair is in use, the other nine chairs being valued only for their potential uses. I knew two young men who owned a dress-coat in partnership, and as they had different evenings free from business all went well until both were invited to a reception which both were very eager to attend.

1. The phrase "diminishing returns of industrial agents" means that there's a limit to how much value any indirect good can provide in a certain timeframe. While you can often get some additional benefits from something, each extra benefit usually comes with more effort, or you get less benefit for the same amount of resources or effort. A book might sit on the library shelf for hours without being touched; however, if two or more people want to use it at the same time, it leads to wasted time and energy. The book has potential value throughout the twenty-four hours, but accessing that value comes with significant inconvenience. The biggest advantages, therefore, are for the first person who uses it and in the first hour, because those uses require the least time and effort. If family members take turns, one chair can be enough for all of them; but if everyone wants to sit down together, they'll need a chair for each person. Often, it happens that just one chair is being used while the other nine are only valued for their potential use. I knew two young men who shared ownership of a dress coat, and everything worked out fine until both got invited to a reception they both wanted to go to on the same evening.

This is true of all classes of agents

Illustrations of this principle may be drawn from every class of durable goods. The example generally given is that of a field used for agriculture. It was long ago seen that a larger crop could usually be obtained on the same area, only with greater effort or expenditure; but this fact has been thought to be peculiar to the use of land. The examples given above have been purposely chosen from very different fields, to show that the truth is a general one: a good that affords a given service can be made to increase that service, ordinarily, only on condition that men put forth greater effort, or sacrifice more goods.

Illustrations of this principle can be found in all types of durable goods. The most common example is an agricultural field. It was realized long ago that you could usually get a bigger crop from the same area, but it requires more effort or investment; however, this fact was believed to be unique to land use. The examples provided above were intentionally selected from very different areas to demonstrate that this truth is a general one: a good that provides a specific service can typically only increase that service if people put in more effort or give up more resources.

The decreased utility is most clearly seen in the diminished effect which other agents produce when used in connection with the thing. When several are trying to use the same book, and are wasting time trying to get it, we often say their study hours are less fruitful because of the poor library facilities. Again, we speak either of the diminished returns of the field, or of the labor applied to the field. Either the particular thing is said to show diminished returns or the other coöperating agents are said to show them.

The reduced usefulness is most obvious in the lesser impact that other factors have when they're used alongside the thing. When multiple people are trying to use the same book and wasting time trying to get access to it, we often remark that their study hours are less effective because of the inadequate library facilities. Similarly, we talk about either the reduced returns of the field or the effort put into the field. Either the specific thing is said to show decreased returns, or the other collaborating factors are described that way.

Decreasing technical effectiveness of material things

2. As the agents used in connection with a fixed amount of any other agent (for mechanical, chemical, physiological, psychological, and other purposes) increase, their objective effectiveness after a given point decreases. Objective or technical effectiveness means effectiveness independent of the thought or estimate of men. It is not the effectiveness to produce a feeling in men, but to produce results on the material world. In a mechanism, if one part is increased without increasing the other parts, a point is reached where it does not add to the result. If in the building of a bridge the weight of the floor is increased beyond a certain point, the rest of the bridge being left unchanged, the bridge is weakened instead of strengthened. If the weight of the iron in the framework is increased beyond a certain point without strengthening the piers, the structure is weakened. If the pier is greatly enlarged, the bridge may not be weakened, but there is an utter waste of material and effort, and perhaps[Pg 63] the main purpose of the bridge is defeated by the damming up of the stream. A bicycle frame, like a chain, is no stronger than its weakest part. If the strength of all parts of the wheel and frame is in equal proportion to the strain they must bear, added weight to any single part weakens the whole machine. The development of the modern type of bicycle, by many experiments, is a good example of the adjustment of materials according to the principle of technical efficiency.

2. As the agents used with a fixed amount of any other agent (for mechanical, chemical, physiological, psychological, and other purposes) increase, their objective effectiveness decreases after a certain point. Objective or technical effectiveness means effectiveness that is not influenced by people's thoughts or estimates. It's not about creating feelings in people but about achieving results in the physical world. In a machine, if one part is increased without adjusting the other parts, there comes a point where it no longer contributes positively to the outcome. For instance, if the weight of a bridge's floor is increased beyond a certain limit, while keeping the rest of the bridge unchanged, the bridge becomes weaker instead of stronger. If the amount of iron in the framework is boosted too much without reinforcing the piers, the overall structure is compromised. Even if the piers are significantly enlarged, while the bridge might not weaken, it results in a complete waste of materials and effort, and it could potentially undermine the main goal of the bridge by blocking the water flow. A bicycle frame, similar to a chain, is only as strong as its weakest part. If the strength of all components of the wheel and frame is balanced in relation to the load they need to handle, adding extra weight to any single part weakens the entire machine. The evolution of the modern bicycle, through numerous experiments, serves as a solid example of how materials are adjusted based on the principle of technical efficiency.

A variation of the same principle is seen in chemical combinations. Exact proportions of materials must be used to get a certain result. Increase of one ingredient will not increase the desired product. Either the added part is rejected, does not enter at all into the compound, or it unites to form another and different product.

A variation of the same principle is seen in chemical combinations. Exact proportions of materials must be used to achieve a specific result. Increasing one ingredient will not enhance the desired product. Either the extra part is rejected, does not contribute at all to the compound, or it combines to create another and different product.

That the same principle holds good of the psychological effects of things, we have already fully recognized in discussing wants and marginal utility. A given amount of a good will affect the senses in a pleasurable way, but an increase in the amount will not cause a proportional addition to pleasure of sight, sound, or smell. On the contrary, such an increase may defeat the object entirely. Here we are at the threshold of the economic problem, for we have touched on "feeling."

That the same principle applies to the psychological effects of things is something we've already acknowledged when discussing needs and marginal utility. A certain amount of a good will provide pleasure to the senses, but increasing that amount won’t necessarily lead to a proportional increase in pleasure from sight, sound, or smell. In fact, such an increase might completely defeat the purpose. Here, we stand at the beginning of the economic problem, as we have touched on "feeling."

Economic diminishing returns relate to value

3. The idea of economic diminishing returns arises when man recognizes these technical facts and their relation to gratification, in his use of a limited supply of indirect agents. All economy begins with scarcity. The varying effects produced by different agents therefore require to be studied or the sum or direct goods of enjoyment will not be as great as is possible. Waste will take place. A bridge will have its maximum use with a minimum outlay when the parts are in a certain proportion. Beyond that point, the increase of any part may add something to the usefulness of the bridge, but the agents must be taken from some other and greater use.

3. The concept of diminishing returns in economics comes into play when people understand these technical facts and how they relate to satisfaction, given their use of a limited supply of indirect resources. All economies start with scarcity. Therefore, the different effects produced by various resources need to be analyzed, or the total enjoyment from direct goods won't be maximized. Waste will occur. A bridge will have its best use with minimal cost when its parts are in a specific proportion. Beyond that point, increasing any part may enhance the bridge's usefulness, but resources must be diverted from something else that’s more valuable.

The thought of economic diminishing returns always has reference to value. If a particular kind and amount of a certain material is used in varying combinations with other agents, the value of the added product will not always be in the same proportion to the value of the added agent. The bridge-builder must consider not only what the added material will add to strength, but what it will cost, and whether the result will justify this expense. So the economic problem of diminishing returns is more complicated than the mechanical one, for it contains not only the technical but other factors.

The idea of economic diminishing returns always relates to value. If a certain type and amount of a specific material is used in different combinations with other resources, the value of the resulting product won't always match the value of the added resource. The bridge builder has to consider not just what the extra material will contribute to strength, but also its cost, and whether the outcome will be worth that expense. Therefore, the economic issue of diminishing returns is more complex than the mechanical one, as it includes not only technical aspects but also other factors.

The marginal utility in goods

If the value of the product increases less rapidly than the cost of the agents successively added to secure it, a point must at length be reached where the value of the added agents and of the additional product just balance; this is called the point of marginal utility.

If the value of the product grows slower than the cost of the resources added to create it, there will eventually come a point where the value of the added resources and the extra product are equal; this is known as the point of marginal utility.

If a certain value in labor, fertilizer, or material, be applied to an acre of land, it may be more than recovered in the value of the product. Further applications give a product increased not in equal proportion to the former yield, and so on till the value of the last-added agent just balances that of the added product. This is the best adjustment possible, and beyond this point there will be a deficit in value. Just where the equilibrium is found at any time is the margin of cultivation.

If a certain amount of labor, fertilizer, or materials is applied to an acre of land, it may yield more value than what was put in. However, further applications result in increased yields that are not proportional to the previous output, continuing until the value of the last added input just matches the value of the additional product. This is the optimal balance, and going beyond this point will result in a loss in value. The point at which this balance is found at any given time is known as the margin of cultivation.

The term "cultivation" is taken from agriculture but must be understood in the broader sense of utilization, as the principle is not confined to the case of land or agriculture, but applies as well to the use of furniture, books, clothing, horses, or any other indirect agents.

The term "cultivation" comes from agriculture but should be understood more broadly as utilization, since the principle isn't limited to land or farming; it also applies to the use of furniture, books, clothing, horses, or any other indirect resources.

Meaning of intensive margin of utilization
The extensive margin of utilization

4. There are two margins, the intensive and the extensive. The margin of utilization in the case of a single piece of wealth is called the intensive margin. Any form of indirect wealth, anything kept to use, may be considered as containing a series of uses. Using one thing more and more while uniting other things with it, is using it more intensively.

4. There are two margins, the intensive and the extensive. The margin of utilization for a single asset is known as the intensive margin. Any kind of indirect wealth, anything saved for use, can be seen as having a range of uses. Using one item more frequently while combining it with other items means using it more intensively.

Getting more use out of the book by effort, out of the farm by applying more fertilizer, out of the house by putting more people into it, is intensive utilization. The earlier uses come easily, naturally; the later ones are gotten with increasing difficulty.

Getting more out of the book by putting in effort, out of the farm by using more fertilizer, and out of the house by accommodating more people is intensive utilization. The initial uses come easily and naturally; the later ones require more effort to achieve.

When a number of agents are of different qualities, the point between the one last used and the next unused is the extensive margin of utilization. The best agents that are available are naturally used first, but as they are more intensively used there is increasing inconvenience. Then recourse must be made to the inferior agents, whose first uses, however, are greater than the later, intensive uses, of the better grades. When the step is made to the use of agents that were before unused because inferior, it is extending the margin of utilization. The intensive margin of use is in the particular thing; the extensive margin of use lies outside of this.

When several agents have different qualities, the gap between the last one used and the next one not used is called the extensive margin of utilization. The best available agents are naturally used first, but as their usage increases, it becomes more inconvenient. At that point, we have to start using the less effective agents, whose initial uses are actually more effective than the later, heavier uses of the better ones. When we switch to using agents that were previously unused because they are inferior, we are extending the margin of utilization. The intensive margin of use relates to a specific item; the extensive margin of use refers to everything beyond that.

Multiple Uses

The relation of the two margins may be shown in a simple diagram. Let the better grades of indirect agents be represented by longer rectangles, the upper parts of which represent the more accessible, more easily secured utilities. Each agent consists of many strata of uses. The best uses are grades a, b, and c, in M; but after M has been utilized intensively[Pg 66] down to d, N will begin to be utilized at its highest point. When utilization goes down to f, O comes into use, and so on. Therefore it will be seen that until the intensive margin takes in d, M is on the extreme margin of utilization, and N is just outside it; when the intensive margin falls to g and h, P is inside the extensive margin, and Q is just outside.

The relationship between the two margins can be illustrated with a simple diagram. Let the better grades of indirect agents be shown as longer rectangles, where the upper parts represent the more accessible and easily acquired resources. Each agent consists of many layers of uses. The best uses are categories a, b, and c, in M; but once M has been used intensively[Pg 66] down to d, N will start to be utilized at its highest point. When usage drops to f, O will come into play, and so on. So, it’s clear that until the intensive margin reaches d, M is at the outer limit of utilization, and N is just beyond it; when the intensive margin decreases to g and h, P is within the extensive margin, and Q is just outside.

Equilibrium of the two margins

The marginal utility or effectiveness of added agents tends to be equal on the intensive and the extensive margins. This is simply a case of the substitution of goods in the use of indirect agents. If the value of the added product in the use of a particular good decreases, a point finally is reached where it is better to transfer the outlay to another agent, to change from intensive to extensive utilization, to go over to the use of another field or of another machine not so good. The effectiveness of the labor or capital that men have to apply is being compared constantly in the two cases, and to the extent that this comparison is perfect the effectiveness of the agents tends to be equal on the margin in the two applications.

The marginal utility or effectiveness of additional resources is generally equal at both intensive and extensive margins. This is simply about substituting goods when using indirect resources. If the value of the extra output from a specific good goes down, there comes a point where it makes more sense to shift the investment to another resource, to move from intensive to extensive use, or to switch to a different area or a less efficient machine. The effectiveness of the labor or capital that people apply is constantly being compared in both scenarios, and as this comparison becomes more accurate, the effectiveness of the resources tends to equal out at the margin in both applications.

§ II. OTHER MEANINGS OF THE PHRASE "DIMINISHING RETURNS"

Does not mean declining prosperity

1. The phrase diminishing returns is sometimes taken as meaning merely a decrease in prosperity. Many ideas are connected with this phrase. It is not self-explanatory. It suggests various thoughts according to context and these have not failed to give rise to different uses. The student must be cautious if he is to think clearly about it. If population declines, or industry changes from one place to another, or from one kind of goods to another, it is sometimes said that returns are diminishing in the deserted district.

1. The term diminishing returns is often interpreted simply as a decline in prosperity. Many concepts are associated with this term. It’s not immediately clear what it means. It evokes different ideas depending on the context, and this has led to various interpretations. Students should be careful if they want to think clearly about it. If the population goes down, or if industries shift to a different area or change from one type of product to another, it’s sometimes stated that returns are diminishing in the areas that are being deserted.

Nor exhaustion of the soil

2. A more common misuse of the term is to apply it to the exhaustion of the soil. If the soil of a district has been robbed of its fertile qualities and smaller crops are raised[Pg 67] than was the case fifty years before, it is said to be a case of of the increased difficulty in the extraction of natural stores in mining. The veins near the surface being mined first, later the galleries must be cut deeper and greater expense incurred to get the stores. But the conditions here are very different from those we have considered under diminishing returns. Mines are used not under the renting contract, but under the royalty contract, which permits and contemplates a progressive using up of the limited stores of natural resources.

2. A more common misuse of the term is to apply it to the exhaustion of the soil. If the soil in an area has lost its fertile qualities and smaller crops are being grown[Pg 67] than fifty years ago, it's considered a case of increased difficulty in extracting natural resources in mining. The veins near the surface are mined first, and later, the galleries have to be cut deeper, leading to higher costs to access the resources. However, the situation here is very different from what we've discussed regarding diminishing returns. Mines operate not under a rental agreement but under a royalty agreement, which allows and anticipates a gradual depletion of the limited natural resources.

Fallacious contract between manufacture and agriculture
All industries if limited as to one factor, as area, show diminishing returns

3. Manufactures are often said to show increasing returns in contrast with agriculture as an industry of decreasing returns. There is here an inconsistent shifting of thought. Agriculture is thought of as limited to a certain area of ground, whereon evidently diminishing returns will take place. But the fixed limit of ground-space is not thought of in connection with manufactures. Taking the same view of manufactures, commerce, education, etc., that is, assuming each industry to be confined to limited area of ground, each is seen to be subject to diminishing returns. Some ground-space is one of the essentials to carry on any business. If the attempt is made to accumulate a large library in one small room, a point is reached where much energy is wasted in trying to find the books. In a university the psychical product, education, may be limited by the need of space. The school-room, laboratory, or college class-room could be used at midnight, it is true, but not conveniently; and as students increase, buildings must be added. The same is true of any industry. We cannot conveniently increase the business of a lumber-yard without a larger yard-space, or of a factory without a larger floor-space. But the added space may be gotten by spreading horizontally or piling up perpendicularly. A ten-story building on an acre lot represents ten acres of floor-space. Putting up higher buildings is an expansion in area by the more intensive utilization of the land. Devices like elevators, and more compact appliances,[Pg 68] make possible an increasing business in manufacture, trade, or commerce upon the same area of land. All industries, if looked at consistently from this standpoint, are subject to the same condition, though it is true this will make itself felt in varying degrees in different lines of industry. In agriculture some similar devices are possible by the use of greenhouses, but it is true that in it, on account of the need of sun, light, and air, the limits of space are more quickly felt, and are less elastic than in most other industries. The difference, however, is one of degree, and not of kind. Higher factories, larger stores, enable manufacturers to adapt themselves to the law as applied to the surface of land, but not to escape its operations. Neither the law of gravitation nor the law of diminishing returns is violated or broken when materials are lifted to build the upper stories. Both "laws" are at work, even when the building is rising from the ground. Men are merely adapting their conduct to the conditions imposed by gravitation and diminishing returns.

3. Manufacturing is often seen as having increasing returns, while agriculture is viewed as having decreasing returns. This creates a confusing shift in thinking. Agriculture is usually limited to a specific piece of land, where diminishing returns are expected to occur. However, the same spatial limitations are not considered when discussing manufacturing. If we apply the same perspective to manufacturing, commerce, education, etc.—that is, assuming each industry is confined to a limited area of land—each will also be subject to diminishing returns. Some land area is essential for any business to operate. If you try to cram a large library into a small room, there will come a point when a lot of energy is wasted just trying to locate the books. In a university, the product of education may be limited by the need for space. While classrooms, laboratories, or lecture halls could technically be used at midnight, it wouldn’t be practical; as the number of students grows, more buildings must be added. The same principle applies to any industry. We can't easily expand a lumber yard without more space, or a factory without more floor area. However, that added space can be achieved by expanding horizontally or stacking vertically. A ten-story building on one acre can provide the equivalent of ten acres of floor space. Building upwards is a way to maximize land use. Features like elevators and more compact equipment[Pg 68] make it possible for manufacturing, trade, or commerce to grow on the same parcel of land. All industries, when considered consistently from this perspective, are affected by the same conditions, though the impact may vary across different sectors. In agriculture, some similar advancements are possible, such as using greenhouses, but here, the need for sunlight, light, and air makes space limitations more immediate and less flexible than in most other industries. The difference is one of degree, not kind. Taller factories and bigger stores allow manufacturers to comply with land-use laws but don’t let them escape those laws. Neither the law of gravity nor the law of diminishing returns is ignored or disrupted when materials are lifted to build upper floors. Both "laws" are in operation, even as the building rises. People are simply adjusting their actions to the conditions set by gravity and diminishing returns.

Confused with the question of large production

Manufactures usually are thought of as enlarging by increase of the amount of capital employed, without limitation as to the area covered. But even here a limit is reached in the amount of capital that can be employed at any one location because of the difficulty of widening the market. The question, however, is one of the advantages of large production with large capital, not of the increasing use of a limited area of land. If manufactures and agriculture are to be compared with reference to their economic nature, it is essential to clear thinking that both be looked at with reference to the same conditions, and from the same point of view.

Manufacturing is often seen as growing by increasing the amount of capital invested, without restriction on the area covered. However, there comes a limit to how much capital can be invested at a single location due to the challenges of expanding the market. The key issue is the benefits of large-scale production with significant capital, rather than the expanding use of a confined piece of land. When comparing manufacturing and agriculture in terms of their economic nature, it’s important that both are considered under the same conditions and from the same perspective.

Technical confused with historical diminishing returns

4. Technical diminishing returns are often confused with historical diminishing returns. The principle of technical diminishing returns is that at any given moment the uses obtainable from any indirect agent cannot be indefinitely increased without increasing difficulty. Historical diminishing returns occur when, in fact, human effort is less bountifully[Pg 69] rewarded in a later period than in an earlier one. If to-day a day's labor in agriculture produced less than fifty years ago, historical diminishing returns would have occurred. In fact, labor is more bountifully rewarded in agriculture than fifty years ago, yet it is true to-day that there are few fields or appliances which, if used more intensively with the prevailing prices of labor and material, would not show a diminishing return to the additional capital applied. Therefore, in the historical sense, increasing returns have prevailed, yet at every moment it has been necessary to apply resources under the guidance of the principle of diminishing returns.

4. Technical diminishing returns are often confused with historical diminishing returns. The principle of technical diminishing returns states that at any given moment, the benefits you can get from any indirect resource can't be increased indefinitely without facing more challenges. Historical diminishing returns happen when, in fact, human effort is less rewarding in a later period than it was in an earlier one. If today, a day's work in agriculture yields less than it did fifty years ago, that would mean historical diminishing returns have occurred. However, labor is actually rewarded more generously in agriculture now than it was fifty years ago. Still, it’s true today that there are few areas or tools where, if used more intensively given the current prices of labor and materials, wouldn’t show diminishing returns on the extra capital spent. So, in the historical context, increasing returns have been the norm, yet at every moment, it has been necessary to apply resources while considering the principle of diminishing returns.

§ III. DEVELOPMENT OF THE CONCEPT OF DIMINISHING RETURNS

Recognition of diminishing returns to land

1. The law of "diminishing returns" was first recognized and expressed with reference to the use of land in agriculture. There are several evident reasons why this occurred. It is obvious to every farmer and gardener that he cannot indefinitely increase his crop, that two men cannot always produce twice as much as one man, and that in general the product does not always vary in proportion to the labor and materials applied. Moreover, the food supply is a fundamental factor in industry and in the welfare of states. The limit to the supply of food on a given area, cultivated by a given method, early appeared and became a serious practical problem.

1. The law of "diminishing returns" was first recognized and explained in relation to using land for agriculture. There are several clear reasons why this happened. Every farmer and gardener knows that they can't keep increasing their crop indefinitely, that two people can’t always produce twice as much as one person, and that generally the output doesn’t always change in proportion to the labor and resources used. Additionally, the food supply is a crucial factor in industry and the wellbeing of nations. The limit on food production in a specific area, using a specific method, quickly became apparent and turned into a significant practical issue.

The circumstances in Europe in the eighteenth century drew attention to the subject. Population was increasing, and the pressure for food was strong. While all the forms of industry most common in cities were increasing, and the wealth of the cities was growing, poverty was increasing among the peasantry. Especially was this true in England during the Napoleonic wars, 1793-1815, owing to exceptional conditions. The food-supply from abroad was cut off, and[Pg 70] when the English farmers, tempted by the high prices, took poorer land into cultivation, and sought to get larger crops from their older fields, a great object-lesson was presented on the principle of diminishing returns in agriculture.

The situation in Europe during the eighteenth century highlighted the issue. The population was growing, leading to a strong demand for food. Although urban industries were thriving and city wealth was increasing, poverty was on the rise among rural communities. This was particularly the case in England during the Napoleonic wars from 1793 to 1815, due to unique circumstances. Food supplies from abroad were disrupted, and[Pg 70] as English farmers, drawn by high prices, cultivated less productive land and tried to increase yields from their existing fields, a significant lesson on the principle of diminishing returns in agriculture emerged.

This confused with historical diminishing returns

2. This truth of diminishing returns in agriculture was confused with the thought of historical diminishing returns. Circumstances of the time led to the belief that because of lack of food misery must continue among the masses of men. It was thought inevitable that the population would continue to increase and food become more scarce. The idea of diminishing returns became thus a prophecy of what would happen, a social philosophy, that affected the thought of men on every practical social question.

2. This reality of decreasing returns in agriculture was mistaken for historical decreasing returns. The situation at the time created the belief that, due to food shortages, misery would persist among the general population. It was seen as unavoidable that the population would keep growing while food became scarcer. The concept of diminishing returns turned into a prediction of what was to come, a social philosophy that influenced people's thoughts on every practical social issue.

The principle applies to land in all of its uses

3. The application of the principle of diminishing returns was soon broadened to include land in other than agricultural uses. This was a natural and inevitable extension of the thought. It was evident that an unlimited use could not be made of a limited area of land, in any industry whatever. There is no explanation of rent of business sites, residences, lots, wharves, waterfalls, etc., unless account is taken of diminishing returns. If it were possible to do an unlimited amount of business upon a limited area of land, it would never get more scarce and could never rise in value. The idea of diminishing returns came properly, therefore, to be applied to land in all its uses. It is true, however, that the relatively large areas needed in agriculture make the phenomenon of diminishing returns much more striking in it than in most other industries.

3. The principle of diminishing returns was soon expanded to include land used for purposes other than agriculture. This was a natural and unavoidable extension of the concept. It was clear that unlimited use could not be made of a limited area of land in any industry. There’s no explanation for the rent of business sites, homes, lots, wharves, waterfalls, etc., without considering diminishing returns. If it were possible to conduct unlimited business on a limited area of land, that land would never become scarce and its value could never increase. Therefore, the idea of diminishing returns was rightly applied to land in all its uses. However, it’s true that the relatively large areas needed for agriculture make the phenomenon of diminishing returns much more noticeable in that sector compared to most other industries.

And to all indirect agents

4. "Diminishing returns" should be broadly applied to all wealth having indirect uses. The argument for this view may take both a negative and a positive form. Why should we say that the principle applies to land and not to cases of other industrial agents? Why in the case of a waterfall and not in the case of the water-wheel? Why in the case of the field and not in the case of the trees in the[Pg 71] field? Are they not all scarce and desirable goods yielding a limited supply of uses?

4. "Diminishing returns" should be applied broadly to all wealth with indirect uses. The argument for this can be presented in both negative and positive ways. Why should we say that this principle applies to land but not to other industrial resources? Why does it apply to a waterfall but not to a water wheel? Why to a field but not to the trees in the[Pg 71] field? Aren't they all scarce and desirable goods that provide a limited supply of uses?

Positively it can be argued that the concept of diminishing returns is indispensable to a reasonable explanation of the value of any indirect agents. Anything that could afford an infinite series of uses at once would be an infinite supply. If an infinite number of uses could be gotten out of one hammer in all places at once, it would pound all the nails in the world. One wagon, one acre of land, one ax, one book of each kind, would serve for all men, and duplicates would be valueless. But in the case of every material thing there is a limit of convenient and economic use.

Positively, it can be argued that the concept of diminishing returns is essential for understanding the value of any indirect resources. Anything that could provide an endless number of uses at the same time would mean infinite supply. If you could get an infinite number of uses out of one hammer everywhere at once, it would drive all the nails in the world. One wagon, one acre of land, one ax, and one book of each type would be enough for everyone, and duplicates would have no value. However, with every material item, there is a limit to how much can be used conveniently and economically.

Diminishing returns related to diminishing gratification

5. Diminishing returns of indirect agents is a special case of the universal law of the diminishing utility of goods. Diminishing returns have to do with indirect goods, while diminishing gratification has to do with direct or consumption goods. They are two species or aspects of the same general principle. If the supply of certain indirect agents is increased, thereby increasing consumption goods, the utility of the indirect agents per unit diminishes. In such a case a diminishing return is the reflection, back to the indirect good, of the diminishing utility of the direct goods it helps to secure. Any indirect agent, added to a fixed amount of other agents with which it is technically used, is credited with a diminished utility, just as an additional supply of enjoyable goods, coming to meet a fixed demand, falls in value.

5. The diminishing returns of indirect agents is a specific example of the universal principle of diminishing utility of goods. Diminishing returns relate to indirect goods, while diminishing gratification pertains to direct or consumable goods. They are two facets of the same overarching principle. When the supply of certain indirect agents increases, leading to more consumption goods, the utility of each unit of the indirect agents decreases. In this context, diminishing returns reflect back to the indirect good the diminishing utility of the direct goods it helps secure. Any indirect agent added to a fixed amount of other agents it’s used with has reduced utility, just like when an additional supply of enjoyable goods meets a fixed demand, its value decreases.

The concept of technical diminishing returns has reference to a limited period of time. Though a definite agent may have bound up in it a long series of uses, these cannot be secured at the moment. If a rent-bearer, such as a fruit-tree, were permanent, and men could wait through eternity for its yield, they would get an infinite yield of fruit. But in any finite period, there can be only a limited yield.

The idea of technical diminishing returns relates to a limited time frame. Even if a specific resource has a long list of possible uses, those uses can’t be accessed all at once. If a source of rent, like a fruit tree, lasted forever and people could wait as long as needed for its produce, they could get an endless amount of fruit. However, within any finite time period, there can only be a limited amount of produce.

The basal law of economics

The concept of diminishing returns is one aspect of the great economic law of proportionality, that is, it is one expression of the fundamental, axiomatic truth, that there is a best or proper adjustment of means and ends. It is, therefore, the central and essential thought in political economy. On it depend all important conclusions with reference to the value of indirect goods. Out of it grow the important economic theories of rent and capitalization.

The idea of diminishing returns is a part of the significant economic law of proportionality, which reflects the basic truth that there is an optimal balance between means and goals. Thus, it is the key concept in political economy. All major conclusions about the value of indirect goods rely on it. From it arise the crucial economic theories of rent and capitalization.


CHAPTER 10

THE THEORY OF RENT: THE MARKET VALUE OF THE USUFRUCT

§ I. DIFFERENTIAL ADVANTAGES IN CONSUMPTION GOODS

Connection between gratification, rents, and value of wealth

1. Both rent and the value of durable wealth are based on the value of the fruits or products yielded by the wealth. Gratification, afforded directly or indirectly, is the basis of all values. The relation of most kinds of wealth to wants is indirect; but gratification thus afforded indirectly is none the less the basis on which the usufruct of wealth is estimated. Men find the logical or causal connection between direct goods, or final product, and indirect goods, or agents.

1. Both rent and the value of long-lasting assets rely on the value of the goods or products produced by those assets. Satisfaction, provided directly or indirectly, is the foundation of all values. The relationship of most types of wealth to needs is indirect; however, the satisfaction provided in this way is still the basis on which the benefits of wealth are assessed. People recognize the logical or causal link between direct goods, or end products, and indirect goods, or means.

To explain the value of the durable wealth, or rent-bearer, a still farther step in thought must be taken. The value of the rent-bearer is based on the series of rents which it affords. To explain how these rents are added to give the value of the indirect agents is the task of a theory of capitalization. This being the relation, a change in the value of the product changes the rent, and this in turn changes the value of the rent-bearer. The theory of rent, therefore, has to begin with a review of the valuation of enjoyable goods.

To explain the value of durable wealth, or rent-generating assets, we need to take a further step in our thinking. The value of a rent-generating asset is based on the series of rents it provides. Explaining how these rents combine to determine the value of indirect agents is the job of a theory of capitalization. Since this is the relationship, a change in the value of the product affects the rent, which in turn changes the value of the rent-generating asset. Therefore, the theory of rent must start with an examination of the valuation of enjoyable goods.

Effect of scarcity on utility of uniform goods

2. In a group of consumption goods, all of the same quality, the marginal utility declines as the quantity increases. If the quantity of an article capable of ministering to man's wants is very limited, its value is high. If the supply of something of uniform quality, for which there is no substitute, is scanty, the value is estimated without reference to any other grade. If a fishing tribe caught very few fish,[Pg 74] but these were all equally good, and if no other food were to be had, fish would have a high ratio of exchange with every other kind of goods.

2. In a group of consumer goods, all of the same quality, the extra satisfaction you get from each additional unit decreases as the quantity increases. If there's a very limited amount of something that can satisfy people's needs, its value is high. When the supply of a uniform quality item, for which there's no substitute, is scarce, its value is assessed on its own, without comparing it to other types. For instance, if a fishing community caught very few fish,[Pg 74] but all the fish were equally good, and there was no other food available, fish would have a high exchange value with other goods.

If the quantity increases, the value of each unit of the whole supply falls, as the importance attributed to its parts declines. If an Indian hunting-party met with unusual success, the value of buffalo meat declined. If there is a remarkable potato crop, potatoes fall in value.

If the quantity goes up, the value of each unit in the total supply goes down, as the significance given to its parts decreases. If a Native American hunting party has great success, the value of buffalo meat drops. If there’s an exceptional potato harvest, potatoes lose value.

Relation of different grades of consumption goods

3. In a series of consumption goods of different qualities, the lower grades acquire value only as scarcity increases in the higher grades. If difference in quality between two grades of apples is marked and there is a superabundant supply of the best grade, no importance is attached to the poorer. But if the better grade becomes scarce, the appetite for the poorer grade increases, and finally it, too, will be consumed. In some years the small, knotty apples are allowed to rot on the ground; in other years they are gathered and are sold at good prices. But if there is an abrupt difference in quality, and hence in the marginal utility of the two grades, the value of the better goods may rise considerably before there is any recourse to the poorer. If the differences in quality are very slight, the presence of the lower grades has the effect of limiting the increase of value of the higher grades. Practically in almost all kinds of goods there are gradations in quality. Complete uniformity is of the rarest occurrence. When did one ever see a basket of peaches that were all of the same size, ripeness, color, flavor, and perfection? If the step from the higher to the lower grade is very slight, resort is immediately made to the next lower grade, some of which is substituted for the higher.

3. In a range of consumer goods with different qualities, the lower grades only become valuable when the higher grades become scarce. If there's a noticeable difference in quality between two types of apples and there's an excess supply of the top-quality ones, the lower-quality ones don't matter much. However, if the top-quality apples become rare, people start to want the lower-quality ones more, and eventually, they'll be eaten too. Some years, the small, misshapen apples are left to rot on the ground; other years, they're picked and sold for decent prices. But if there's a big difference in quality and thus in how useful the two grades are, the value of the better apples can rise significantly before anyone turns to the lower ones. If the quality differences are minor, the presence of the lower grades keeps the value of the higher grades from rising too much. In almost all types of goods, there are various quality levels. Complete uniformity is extremely rare. When was the last time you saw a basket of peaches that were all the same size, ripeness, color, flavor, and perfection? If the difference between the higher and lower grade is small, people will quickly start using the next lower grade, substituting some of it for the higher grade.

There is an independent reason for the value of each grade of goods; each grade would have value if there were none of the other, but they mutually affect each other's value when they exist, side by side, in the same market. The marginal utility of each is lessened by the presence of the other.[Pg 75] And thus, two or ten grades constitute for many purposes a single supply as they shade into each other or are merged by substitution.

There’s a separate reason for the value of each level of goods; each level would hold value on its own if the others didn’t exist, but they impact each other’s value when they’re available together in the same market. The marginal utility of each is reduced by the presence of the other.[Pg 75] Therefore, two or ten levels can be considered a single supply for many purposes as they blend into one another or can replace each other.

Quality Ratings of Consumer Goods
Free goods are on the margin of utilization

4. Goods of the lowest grades, having no marginal utility, are free goods. This is a simple truth, but it has important bearings. There may be said to be an "extensive margin of utilization" of many consumption goods. The poorer grades of apples, rotting on the ground, the multitudes of waste things not valued, are on the margin of utilization. When a lower grade is used, the margin is extended. The value of goods is measured upward from the margin of utilization, but this is simply to say that their value is measured from zero upward.

4. Goods of the lowest quality, which have no additional value, are considered free goods. This is a straightforward fact, but it has significant implications. There is often an "extensive margin of utilization" for many consumer goods. The lower-quality apples that are rotting on the ground and the many worthless items that are wasted exist at this margin of utilization. When a lower-quality item is used, this margin is pushed out further. The value of goods is determined from this margin of utilization going upward, but this simply means that their value is assessed from zero and up.

Likewise, there is an intensive marginal utility in consumption goods. As the better grade of apples becomes more scarce, they will be used more sparingly and kept to satisfy only the intenser wants. The superiority of some consumption goods, either in quantity or quality, often is exactly analogous to the "differential advantage" spoken of by economists in the case of productive agents. The differential advantage of the highest grade over the grade of free goods, whose value is zero, evidently is the whole value of the highest grade.

Similarly, there's a strong marginal utility in consumer goods. As higher quality apples become less available, they will be consumed more carefully and saved to meet only the strongest desires. The superiority of certain consumer goods, whether in quantity or quality, is often directly comparable to the "differential advantage" that economists talk about regarding production factors. The differential advantage of the highest quality over that of freely available goods, which have zero value, clearly represents the entire value of the highest quality.

§ II. DIFFERENTIAL ADVANTAGES IN INDIRECT GOODS

Differential advantage of agents in the quality of their products

1. Rent varies with the quality of the products yielded by agents, other things being equal. Let us take first a[Pg 76] simple case where the agent is the sole condition of the product. If there is but one tree bearing a certain luscious fruit, or but one spring yielding a mineral water, the rent of the tree or spring being equal to the value of the products must vary as the quality of the products varies. If two or more trees are standing side by side, they will be compared with regard to the difference in the quality of their fruits. If two fields differ in quality, greater importance will be attached to the field capable of producing the better grade or variety of fruit or product. A peculiar mineral quality in the soil may impart to wine a choice flavor that can at once be recognized by experts; while other fields, distant but a few rods, cannot by any effort be made to produce wine of the same rare quality. There is said to be a marked difference in the success of vineyards lying only a short distance apart on the shores of the larger lakes of New York. Nearness to the water moderates the temperature, often prevents frosts, and hence insures the ripening and quality of the fruit. In the Santa Clara valley, as in other parts of California, there is a frostless belt, sharply marked off from the lands where it is unsafe to attempt to cultivate the delicate orange-tree and other semi-tropical plants. In manifold ways differences in geological formation affect the use of land and the success of many industries. On one side of a little creek is limestone land, on the other shale, the limestone producing a crop larger and of better quality. When the peculiar nature of the one field is found to be the cause of the exceptional quality of its fruits, the difference in value is attributed to it.

1. Rent varies with the quality of the products produced by agents, all else being equal. Let's first look at a[Pg 76] simple example where the agent is the only factor affecting the product. If there's only one tree that bears a certain delicious fruit, or one spring that provides a mineral water, the rent for the tree or spring will be equal to the value of the products and must change as the quality of those products changes. If there are two or more trees standing next to each other, they will be compared based on the quality of their fruits. If two fields have different qualities, more importance will be given to the field that can produce the better grade or variety of fruit or product. A unique mineral quality in the soil might give wine a distinctive flavor that experts can easily identify, while other nearby fields cannot produce wine of the same rare quality, no matter what. It is noted that there is a significant difference in the success of vineyards that are only a short distance apart along the shores of the larger lakes in New York. Proximity to the water helps moderate the temperature, often preventing frost, which ensures the ripening and quality of the fruit. In the Santa Clara Valley, as in other areas of California, there is a frost-free zone that is clearly set apart from lands where it's risky to grow delicate orange trees and other semi-tropical plants. In many ways, differences in geological formation impact land use and the success of various industries. On one side of a small creek there is limestone land, while on the other side is shale, with the limestone producing larger and better-quality crops. When the unique characteristics of one field are identified as the reason for the exceptional quality of its fruits, the difference in value is attributed to that.

The lower grade limits the value of the higher grade

If there is but one grade of agent, it is, of course, valued without reference to any lower grade. The effect of the presence of lower grades of agents is to lower the value of the higher, inasmuch as the lower grades are substituted for the higher. There may be at first enough of the higher grade of agents to produce all the fruit wanted of the better quality. If, then, there is an increasing demand, and the additional[Pg 77] yield can be secured only with greater effort, the value of the product will rise. The presence of poorer grades, however, checks that rise, because use can be shifted to them. The value of grade one is not high because grades two, three, and four, which are worse than it, are available, but because they are not of better quality than they are. Poor as they are, their presence reduces somewhat the intensity of demand for the best grade. Indirect agents, therefore, are seen to be subject to just the same comparisons, substitutions, and estimates, when their value is considered, as are direct consumption goods.

If there's only one grade of agent, it's obviously valued independently of any lower grade. The presence of lower-grade agents decreases the value of the higher-grade ones since the lower grades can replace the higher. Initially, there may be enough of the higher-grade agents to produce all the desired quality fruit. However, if demand increases and the extra yield can only be obtained with more effort, the product’s value will go up. Still, having lower grades around holds back that increase because people can switch to using them. The value of the top grade isn’t high because grades two, three, and four, which are worse, are available, but because they aren’t of better quality. Even though they’re poor, their existence somewhat dampens the demand for the highest grade. Thus, indirect agents are also subject to the same comparisons, substitutions, and evaluations regarding their value as direct consumer goods.

Differential advantage of agents in the amount of their products

2. The rents of two agents differ as do the quantities of goods yielded by them, other things being equal. In the case just considered, the quantity remained the same while the quality differed; now is to be considered the case where the quantity differs while the quality remains the same. It is possible that one grade of agents is "poorer" because it produces less fruit, not fruit of poorer quality. Consider first the static problem. If both agents yield fruits exactly alike, the value of equal units at the same place and time must be equal, and the usufructs would vary in just proportion with the quantity of product. Now consider the dynamic problem. If the desire for that fruit increases, rent would grow as scarcity became more felt. The agents yielding, under the prevailing conditions, the largest product, would first be used; later, the poorer agents. The possibility of resorting to the poorer agents would keep the better from rising so high.

2. The rents of two agents vary just like the amounts of goods they produce, assuming everything else is equal. In the situation previously discussed, the amount stayed the same while the quality changed; now we’ll look at the case where the amount changes but the quality stays the same. It’s possible that one group of agents is "poorer" because it produces less fruit, not because the fruit is of lower quality. First, let’s consider the static problem. If both agents produce identical fruits, then the value of equal units at the same location and time must be the same, and the benefits would change directly in proportion to the amount produced. Now, let’s look at the dynamic problem. If the demand for that fruit increases, rent would rise as scarcity becomes more apparent. The agents that produce the highest yield under current conditions would be used first, followed by the less productive agents. The option to use the less productive agents would prevent the rents of the more productive ones from rising too high.

Agent Ratings by Quantity of Consistent Quality Product
Complementary agents unite to form a product

3. When two agents are necessary to secure a product, the value attributed to each is influenced by competing uses. The thought of one agent independently producing a certain product is far too simple to correspond with reality. Two or more agents unite to produce a single product, and each agent at the same time can be used for acquiring other products. Complex as the problem appears, it is solved according to the principle of marginal utility at every moment in every market. The different uses, figuratively speaking, bid for an agent, and thus its marginal utility is determined just as is the price of a good by the bidding of buyers. Indeed, it is the bidding of buyers, indirectly. The more urgent the use, the higher the bid. The felt importance is reflected from the consumption goods that are sought, to the agent that will aid to get them. Two or more agents that are mutually needed for the acquiring of a product are complementary goods. A complementary agent may be either other material agents or labor.

3. When two agents are needed to secure a product, the value assigned to each one is influenced by competing uses. The idea of one agent independently producing a certain product is way too simplistic to reflect reality. Two or more agents come together to create a single product, and each agent can also be used to obtain other products at the same time. Although the problem seems complex, it is resolved according to the principle of marginal utility at every moment in every market. Different uses, so to speak, compete for an agent, and its marginal utility is determined just like the price of a good through the bidding of buyers. In fact, it’s the buyers’ bidding that drives it, indirectly. The more urgent the use, the higher the bid. The perceived importance is reflected from the consumption goods being sought to the agent that will help acquire them. Two or more agents that are jointly needed to obtain a product are complementary goods. A complementary agent can be other material agents or labor.

Complementary agents used intensively show diminishing returns

When labor is applied to an agent, either to improve the Quality or to increase the quantity, it is subject to the law of diminishing returns. In the effort to increase the quantity of products, labor is applied first more intensively to the better agents. If it meets with resistance, if returns diminish, it is transferred to any of the poorer agents that have in them uses of as high grade as those still in the better agent. The superior effectiveness of the earlier over the later units of the added agent is called the "differential advantage" of the two fixed agents. The result of a day's labor applied to a field may be represented by 100, a second day's labor by 90 (it being only ninety per cent, as effectual), a third day's labor by 75; but it is more usual to say that the first field produces 10 more than the second and 25 more than the third, the second 15 more than the third. To the agent fixed in supply is attributed the difference in the effectiveness of the agent that is applied.

When labor is applied to a resource, either to improve its quality or to increase its quantity, it follows the law of diminishing returns. To boost the amount of products, labor is initially focused more intensively on the better resources. If there is resistance or returns start to decrease, the labor shifts to the poorer resources that can produce outputs as good as those from the better resource. The greater effectiveness of the earlier applied labor compared to the later is called the "differential advantage" between the two fixed resources. The outcome of a day's labor on a field can be represented by 100, a second day's labor by 90 (as it's only ninety percent as effective), and a third day's labor by 75; however, it's more common to say that the first field produces 10 more than the second and 25 more than the third, with the second producing 15 more than the third. The difference in effectiveness is attributed to the fixed supply of resources that are being used.

The relentless extensive margin of agents

4. The marginal uses of indirect goods are free uses.[Pg 79] Here again is noted the close parallelism in the process of evaluating direct and indirect goods. There is an extensive margin in the use of an indirect agent, a point in the gradation from the better to the poorer agents where the materials and forces are left unused and have no value. Land beyond that point is free. Outworn goods in manifold forms, old pictures, old machines, having no longer charms even for a rummage sale, form a no-rent margin of wealth. On every hand a great multitude of things unused and worthless differ by only a shade from things that still are used and valued. Every rubbish-heap, rag-bag, junk-shop, and garret contains things once prized, now lingering on the margin of utilization.

4. The marginal uses of indirect goods are free uses.[Pg 79] Here again, we see a close similarity in how we evaluate direct and indirect goods. There is a significant margin in the use of an indirect agent, a point in the scale from better to worse agents where materials and resources are left unused and have no value. Land beyond that point is free. Worn-out goods in many forms, such as old pictures and old machines, no longer appealing even for a garage sale, create a no-rent margin of wealth. Everywhere, there is a vast number of unused and worthless items that differ only slightly from things that are still used and valued. Every junk pile, rag bag, thrift store, and attic holds items that were once valued but are now lingering at the edge of usefulness.

There is also in agents an intensive margin, beyond which are certain unexploited uses in the things that we already have. This is a more subtle thought, but it has been already discussed in connection with diminishing returns. These potential uses in agents, uses which in the existing conditions lie outside the margin of utilization, of course have no value. We have noted that there is an equilibrium between these two margins. Rent is measured from a zero point of utility either in a good, or in other poorer grades of goods.

There is also an intensive margin in agents, beyond which certain untapped uses exist in the things we already possess. This is a more nuanced idea, but it has already been discussed in relation to diminishing returns. These potential uses in agents, which under current conditions fall outside the margin of utilization, obviously have no value. We've noted that there is an equilibrium between these two margins. Rent is measured from a zero point of utility, either in a good or in other lower-quality goods.

A corollary of this proposition is that there is a limit to the rental that anything can yield under any given condition. Below the present margin of utility of any goods there exist great quantities of free goods, unused goods, or unexploited uses. It is only uses above this margin that yield rent. Rent is the difference between the value of the better grades and the value of the free goods. It is therefore due to the limitation in the supply of indirect agents of the better quality, or to the scarcity of the more effective uses in those agents.

A consequence of this idea is that there’s a cap on the rent that anything can generate under specific conditions. Below the current utility threshold of any goods, there are large amounts of free goods, unused items, or untapped uses. Only the uses above this threshold generate rent. Rent is the difference between the value of higher-quality goods and the value of free goods. Thus, it results from the limited supply of better-quality indirect resources or the scarcity of more effective uses of those resources.

Restatement of rent, economic and contract
Economic rent is primary

5. Rent may be redefined as the value of the scarce uses of wealth within a given period. Rent is the felt importance of the usufructs of agents in securing gratification. It is measured by the marginal utility of any particular grade[Pg 80] of agents in securing products. These definitions and the discussion throughout this chapter applies to economic rather than to contract rent. In fixing and agreeing on contract rent, men are seeking to estimate the importance of indirect goods, the importance that an agent will have in getting a product. They are bidding for the use of things, and what they bid is contract rent. Contract rent is based on the existence of economic rent. Economic rent does not depend on contract rent, but on the differences in the effectiveness of agents to secure a given product. If there were not differences in the product, and no limits to the supply of indirect agents, rent could not exist; it would be inconceivable. But these differences existing, economic rent inevitably arises, for men cannot keep from attaching value to the things that affect their desires. Contract rent in turn appears wherever the use of wealth becomes an object of exchange and agreement between men in a free society.

5. Rent can be redefined as the value of the limited uses of wealth within a specific time frame. Rent reflects the perceived significance of the benefits agents gain in obtaining satisfaction. It's measured by the marginal utility of any particular grade[Pg 80] of agents in producing goods. These definitions and the discussions throughout this chapter pertain to economic rent rather than contract rent. When determining and agreeing on contract rent, people are trying to assess the value of indirect goods and the role an agent plays in obtaining a product. They are competing for the use of these resources, and what they offer is contract rent. Contract rent is based on the presence of economic rent. Economic rent exists independently of contract rent and relies on the differences in how effectively agents can secure a specific product. Without variations in the product and no limits on the supply of indirect agents, rent couldn't exist; it would be unimaginable. However, with these differences present, economic rent naturally emerges, since people can't help but attach value to things that influence their desires. Contract rent, in turn, appears wherever the use of wealth is subject to exchange and agreement among people in a free society.


CHAPTER 11

REPAIR, DEPRECIATION, AND DESTRUCTION OF WEALTH: RELATION TO ITS SALE AND RENT

§ I. REPAIR OF RENT-BEARING AGENTS

The necessity of repairing nearly all economic agents

1. The continued rent of indirect agents is dependent on the continual repair of certain parts necessary for their efficiency. All earthly things wear out or decay. Whenever man's hand is withheld, nature takes possession of his work, regardless of his purposes. Dust gathers on unused clothes, and moths burrow in them. Shut up a house, and windows are shattered, roofs leak, and vermin swarm. To close a factory is to hasten the time when buildings and machinery will be piled upon the rubbish heap. The most magnificent and solid works of man have crumbled under the finger of time. The earth is strewn with ruins of gigantic engineering works, aqueducts, canals, temples, and monuments, whose restoration would be no less a task than was their first building. Everywhere vigilance and repairs are the conditions of continued uses of wealth. Some works of nature, such as waterfalls, may appear to have a continued use without repair, but they bear rent only when used with other things that must be constantly mended. A certain amount of labor on the banks of the mill-stream, and certain repairs on the dam, the water-wheel, and the gates are necessary. By a fiction in business contracts the waterfall may be dealt with apart from those conditions to its use, and may be rented, as a field is, with the agreement that the tenant keep up the repairs.

1. The ongoing rent of indirect agents depends on the regular maintenance of certain parts needed for their efficiency. Everything in the world wears out or decays. When people stop working, nature takes over their creations, regardless of their intentions. Dust collects on unused clothes, and moths get into them. If a house is shut up, windows break, roofs leak, and pests invade. Closing a factory speeds up the process of turning buildings and machinery into junk. Even the most impressive and sturdy human creations have crumbled away over time. The earth is littered with the ruins of enormous engineering feats, like aqueducts, canals, temples, and monuments, whose restoration would be as challenging as their original construction. Everywhere, constant vigilance and repairs are necessary for the continued use of resources. Some natural features, like waterfalls, might seem to have a lasting use without maintenance, but they only provide value when used in conjunction with other items that need regular upkeep. A certain amount of labor on the riverbanks, as well as repairs to the dam, waterwheel, and gates, is essential. Due to a legal fiction in business contracts, the waterfall can be treated separately from the conditions required for its use and can be rented out like a field, with the tenant agreeing to maintain the repairs.

The efficiency of land as mere standing-room usually does not seem to be dependent on repairs. But here again the land yields rent in connection with other rent-bearing agents (such as houses and other agents above ground), which must be repaired. Standing-room on land is not a complete indirect agent; it is but one of the conditions for carrying on an industry, and even it often requires repairs to make it usable. Ranging from these extreme cases of stableness and durability, indirect agents vary to the extremes of fragility and ephemeralness.

The effectiveness of land as just a space for standing generally doesn’t seem to rely on repairs. However, the land still generates rent when it's linked with other rental-producing assets (like buildings and other above-ground structures) that do require maintenance. Standing-room on land isn’t a fully independent factor; it's just one of the conditions needed to run an industry, and it often needs repairs to be functional. Indirect agents range from extreme stability and durability to extreme fragility and short-lived nature.

The fertile lands of large regions have lost their usefulness

2. Most of the qualities that contribute to make land fertile in agriculture being destructible, the constant repair of tilled land is necessary to its continued fertility. If any things could be said to be indestructible, they would be some of the works of nature. In a sense, all matter is indestructible. Man cannot annihilate it, he can simply change its condition. But in economic discussion it is the value of things that is being considered, and from this point of view everything is in some degree destructible. The effects of bad husbandry are everywhere apparent, and in many regions fertile fields have been physically and economically destroyed. In Asia, lands that once supported millions, perhaps hundreds of millions, of population are now deserts. Egypt, for a time reduced to a semi-desert condition, has only in the past century been restored to a certain extent by the use of new methods and a return to the old ones. Many of the areas that were the granaries of Rome can now hardly support a sparse, half-starving population. The lands, or at any rate, the elements that gave them value, have been destroyed.

2. Most of the qualities that make land fertile for farming can be destroyed, so it's important to consistently repair cultivated land to keep it productive. If anything could be considered indestructible, it would be some of nature's creations. In a way, all matter is indestructible. People can't eliminate it; they can only change its state. However, in economic discussions, the focus is on the value of things, and from that perspective, everything can be somewhat destroyed. The consequences of poor farming practices are obvious everywhere, and in many places, once productive fields have been both physically and economically ruined. In Asia, lands that once supported millions, possibly even hundreds of millions, of people are now deserts. Egypt, which was once partially turned into a desert, has only somewhat recovered in the past century through new methods and a return to old practices. Many of the regions that used to be Rome's grain suppliers can now barely sustain a sparse, near-starving population. The land, or more specifically, the factors that gave it value, have been lost.

Wearing out of some American lands

Even in young America may be seen the effect of a failure to keep land in repair. As the new rich lands of the West were opened up, the old lands in the East were allowed to wear out, and many of them were abandoned. On the new lands in turn the same methods were followed, using up the first rich store of fertility with no attempt to keep up the quality of the soil. This may have been the best policy for[Pg 83] the time; it would not have been economical to employ Old World methods of intensive husbandry when such rich extensive areas were being opened up. But the process was one destructive of natural resources. As settlement moved westward, great forests fell in ashes, and the soil was robbed of the fertile elements which it had taken centuries for nature to store up.

Even in young America, you can see the impact of not maintaining the land. As the new wealthy regions in the West opened up, the old lands in the East were allowed to deteriorate, and many were left abandoned. The same practices were used on the new lands, depleting the initial rich soil without making an effort to maintain its quality. This might have been the best approach for[Pg 83] that time; it wouldn't have been practical to use Old World intensive farming methods when such rich, expansive areas were becoming available. However, this process was harmful to natural resources. As settlement spread westward, vast forests were burned to the ground, and the soil lost the fertile elements that nature had taken centuries to build up.

Wearing out of the parts the railroad

3. The machinery and appliances used in transportation and manufacturing are all perishable in varying degrees. Take as an example the great agency for transportation, the railway. The roadbed, which is but the natural soil excavated or filled to a better grade, is the most permanent part; yet every frost weakens, every rain undermines, a portion of it. Earthquake, landslide, and flood fill up the ditches, or tear down the embankments. Constant work is needed to keep it fit and safe for use. Above this is the track, slightly less permanent, more frequently changed. The ties rot, and even the rails of steel must be at times replaced. The rolling-stock is still less durable, and the different parts vary in length of life. It is said that the wheel-tires are renewed four times, the boiler three times, and the paint seven times, before a locomotive is entirely worn out. The oil used in the wheel, which is a necessary part of the running machine, has to be applied every day.

3. The equipment and tools used in transportation and manufacturing all have a limited lifespan to some extent. Take the railway, for example, which is a major transportation method. The roadbed, made from the natural soil that has been dug up or built up to improve its level, is the most durable part; however, every frost weakens it, and every rain erodes a part of it. Earthquakes, landslides, and floods can fill ditches or wash away embankments. Continuous maintenance is required to keep it safe and usable. On top of this is the track, which is slightly less durable and needs to be replaced more often. The wooden ties decay, and even the steel rails occasionally need to be changed. The rolling stock is even less durable, and different components last for varying amounts of time. It’s said that the wheel-tires are replaced four times, the boiler three times, and the paint seven times before a locomotive is completely worn out. The oil for the wheels, which is essential for the machine to run, has to be applied every day.

Depreciation of manufacturing appliances

There is a great difference in the length of life of manufacturing appliances. The building is fairly durable; yet an average depreciation-rate of one and one half per cent. a year must be allowed to offset a reduction in its value of over fifty per cent, in thirty years. Machinery differs greatly in durability; well-made, substantial machinery depreciates about five per cent. yearly. The engines and boilers depreciate more rapidly than the running gear; the loose tools have to be replaced every second to fourth year; while the materials consumed in the industry must be repaired and replaced at every repetition of the process of manufacture. If a factory is to be maintained in its efficiency in accordance[Pg 84] with the terms of the renting contract, and is to continue its renting power, everything about it must be from time to time repaired and replaced.

There’s a significant difference in the lifespan of manufacturing equipment. The building itself lasts fairly long, but you have to account for an average depreciation rate of 1.5% per year to offset a decrease in its value of over 50% in thirty years. Machinery varies widely in how long it lasts; well-built, sturdy machines lose about 5% of their value each year. Engines and boilers depreciate faster than the machinery; loose tools need to be replaced every two to four years, and the materials used in production have to be repaired and replaced every time the manufacturing process is repeated. To keep a factory running efficiently according to the terms of the rental contract and maintain its rental value, everything in it needs to be repaired or replaced periodically.

Neglect of repairs often has evil effects

4. Neglect or postponement of repairs must cause a falling off of the rent-earning power. The neglect of repairs may have different results in the factory. The neglect of one kind simply reduces present rental while not preventing the future restoration of the plant to its full efficiency. If certain necessary tools wear out and are not replaced, the factory as a whole will be less efficient. Each part of the entire outfit being needed in due proportion, the loss in rental will correspond not merely to the lost efficiency of the missing tools, but to the crippled efficiency of the remaining appliances. Failure to apply seed to the land causes the land as a whole to be useless for that year's crop. In other cases, neglect of repairs increases the expenses of repairs and cuts off future rental. The adages, "A stitch in time saves nine," and "An ounce of prevention is worth a pound of cure," must be acted upon in every industry. The neglect to repair a roof causes damage to an amount many times the cost of a new roof. Failure to replace a bolt costing five cents may result in the rack and ruin of a machine worth many dollars. A handful of earth on a dike may save a whole country from destruction.

4. Neglecting or delaying repairs will reduce the ability to earn rent. Ignoring repairs can lead to different outcomes in a factory. Neglecting one type of repair may lower current rental income but won’t stop the plant from being restored to full efficiency in the future. If essential tools wear out and aren’t replaced, the factory overall will be less efficient. Since each part of the entire setup is needed in balance, the loss in rental income will be due not only to the missing tools' lost efficiency but also to the decreased efficiency of the remaining equipment. Failing to plant seeds means that the land won’t produce anything for that year’s crop. In other situations, neglecting repairs increases repair costs and future rental losses. The sayings, "A stitch in time saves nine," and "An ounce of prevention is worth a pound of cure," should be applied in every industry. Not repairing a roof can lead to damage that far exceeds the cost of a new roof. Not replacing a five-cent bolt could lead to the breakdown of a machine worth many dollars. A bit of dirt on a dike can prevent a whole country from being destroyed.

But sometimes is economical

Neglect of repairs may be economical, however, when outer conditions have first reduced the demand for the agent and consequently the rental. When the line of travel changes, it does not pay to keep an old hotel up to the same state of repair as when it had a great patronage. Old factories sometimes may better be allowed to depreciate while the price of repairs is invested in more prosperous industries. In a declining neighborhood the houses fall into decay, the owners seeing that "it would not pay" to keep them up.

Neglecting repairs might save money, especially when outside factors have lowered the demand for the property and, in turn, the rental income. When travel routes change, it's not worth it to maintain an old hotel to the same standards as when it had a lot of customers. Sometimes, it’s better to let old factories decline while investing the money for repairs into more successful businesses. In a neighborhood that's going downhill, homes start to fall apart, with owners realizing that "it wouldn't be worth it" to maintain them.

§ II. DEPRECIATION IN RENT-EARNING POWER OF AGENTS KEPT IN REPAIR

Repairs can not always prevent ultimate decay of agents

1. Even where repairs are thoroughly kept up and present rent is undiminished, future rents may be decreasing because of natural decay. Changes go on in the substance of things which cannot be prevented by any attention to repairs. The wood in a framework will decay, the metals crystallize. There is also an unpreventable wear of parts that cannot be replaced without replacing the whole machine. It is the aim of the modern manufacturers to make machines like the wonderful one-horse shay, every part of equal durability. The development in America of the system of "interchangable parts" has greatly simplified and cheapened repairs, and has lengthened the working life of machines; nevertheless their lot is the scrap-heap at last. This general depreciation appears to be nearly avoided in large factories where there is serial replacement of the parts, but occasionally some invention or some improvement of process necessitates an almost completely new equipment. An old man once said to me: "I have lived in this house forty years: it was well built, has been repainted regularly, has never been allowed to leak a drop, and it is as good as it ever was. I see no reason why it could not be kept to eternity if always kept in repair." But the same could not be said of the house now. In general, there is finally a termination of the rent-earning power of wealth, and the whole has to be replaced.

1. Even when repairs are consistently maintained and current rent remains steady, future rents might decline due to natural wear and tear. Changes occur in the makeup of things that can't be stopped no matter how much you focus on repairs. The wood in a structure will rot, and the metals will crystallize. There's also unavoidable wear on parts that can't be replaced without swapping out the entire machine. Modern manufacturers aim to make machines like the impressive one-horse shay, where every part lasts equally long. The development of "interchangeable parts" in America has made repairs much simpler and cheaper and has extended the lifespan of machines; however, they ultimately end up in the scrap heap. This overall depreciation seems to be mostly avoided in large factories where parts are regularly replaced, but sometimes a new invention or process improvement requires almost completely new equipment. An old man once told me: "I've lived in this house for forty years: it was well built, has been repainted regularly, has never leaked a drop, and it's as good as it ever was. I see no reason why it couldn't be maintained indefinitely if it’s always kept in good shape." But that can’t be said about the house now. Overall, the earning potential of wealth eventually comes to an end, and everything has to be replaced.

Technical changes destroy the uses of agents

2. A change in inventions and processes may reduce the rent of agents, independently of their material condition. Rent is dependent on the indirect relation of things to wants; that relation may be changed if some other agent is found fitted to serve these wants more directly. Not only do the materials of houses change, but fashion and engineering skill change, making the old mansions cheerless and inconvenient,[Pg 86] and affecting their rent-earning power. At every moment, in a progressive society, many rent-earning agents are being thrown out of use. The machinery in flour-mills has been almost completely changed, parts of it repeatedly, while the roller process has been substituted for the old millstones. Water-power, because of its uncertainty, has been replaced in many places by steam-power, and in many places steam-power in turn, has been rivaled by water-power since the improvements in the generation and transmission of electricity. A change in the process of making paper threw out of use much machinery that was only in part saved by its removal and adaptation to the making of coarser grades of paper. Many minor inventions in the iron industry, still more the invention of the Bessemer process, threw out of use great numbers of the old appliances.

2. A shift in inventions and processes might lower the rent of agents, regardless of their material condition. Rent depends on the indirect relationship between things and needs; that relationship can change if another agent is found that better meets those needs. Not only do building materials change, but trends and engineering skills also evolve, making older mansions feel gloomy and impractical,[Pg 86] which affects their ability to earn rent. In a progressive society, at any given moment, many rent-generating agents are becoming obsolete. The machinery in flour mills has changed almost entirely, with parts swapped out repeatedly, while the roller process has replaced the old millstones. Water power, due to its unreliability, has been replaced by steam power in many areas, and in turn, steam power has been challenged by water power again because of improvements in generating and transmitting electricity. A change in the paper-making process rendered much machinery obsolete, with only some being salvaged by being reconfigured for producing lower grades of paper. Numerous smaller inventions in the iron industry, especially the Bessemer process, also led to the obsolescence of a significant number of old tools.

Industrial circumstances affect the uses of agents

3. A change in the outer conditions that give occasion to the use of agents may cause depreciation. The exhaustion of materials on which machinery is employed may reduce its usefulness. A sawmill located in the midst of a forest has a high-earning power while the forest lasts, but when the forest is cut off the mill itself declines in value. Unless it can be removed to another forest and thus have its earning power renewed, it will have the value only of scrap-iron; it has become an indirect agent in the wrong place. Oil-boring machinery where a rich supply of oil is found has a high rental for a time, but when the oil-fields give out the machinery falls in value, being worth more or less than the cost of transporting it according as the next oil-field is near or far. Changes in fashions, calling for different kinds of products, cause a depreciation in the value of the old agents. Coarse salt, evaporated by the sun, was used by our fathers, but the finer product of the steam process is driving out the product of the old solar plants. As homespun went out of use, much machinery still in good physical condition was cast aside. Changes in transportation work revolutions in industrial methods. Many prosperous small forges on the country[Pg 87] roads of Pennsylvania became valueless after the building of the railroads. New forges were built at favored points where materials and products could be shipped by rail.

3. A change in the external conditions that lead to the use of agents can cause a decrease in value. The depletion of resources needed for machinery can diminish its effectiveness. A sawmill situated in a forest has a high earning potential as long as the forest exists, but once the forest is cut down, the mill's value decreases. If it can't be moved to a new forest to renew its earning potential, it will only be worth scrap metal; it has become an indirect agent in the wrong location. Oil drilling equipment may have a high rental value when there's a rich supply of oil, but when the oil fields are depleted, the machinery loses value, being worth more or less depending on how close the next oil field is. Shifts in consumer preferences that require different types of products diminish the value of older agents. Coarse salt, evaporated by the sun, was used by previous generations, but the finer product made through steam processing is replacing the older solar products. As homespun materials became obsolete, much machinery that was still in good working order was discarded. Changes in transportation revolutionize industrial methods. Many thriving small forges along the country[Pg 87] roads in Pennsylvania lost their value after the railroads were built. New forges were established in locations where materials and products could be shipped by rail.

Various grades of efficiency in rent-bearers

4. The agents employed in any industry range from the more efficient, high rent, down to the less efficient, low rent, grades in a more or less regular series. It follows that as these changes are going on, the place of agents on the scale of efficiency is constantly shifting. The various agents represent all grades of efficiency. One depreciates, possibly is restored later and takes a high place, and again depreciates until finally it is thrown out of use. One loom embodies the latest improvements and corresponds to the most fertile field; another can still be made to yield a little rent; the use of a third results in certain loss. A great mass of no-rent agents lie just below the margin of utilization in every industry. Some of these are permanently abandoned; some will be taken back into use when business conditions improve. When the iron industry is dull, many forges are out of blast; but when iron is again in demand, there is a gradual taking up of the abandoned forges, factories, and machines as they are brought within the margin of profitable utilization. Many agents not actually earning a rent, may become rent-earning through a change in business conditions.

4. The workers used in any industry range from the more efficient, high-cost ones, down to the less efficient, low-cost ones, in a fairly consistent order. This means that as changes happen, the position of these workers on the efficiency scale is always shifting. The various workers represent all levels of efficiency. One may lose value, possibly regain it later and rise to a high position, then lose value again until it’s finally no longer used. One loom includes the latest improvements and serves the most productive area; another can still generate a bit of revenue; the use of a third leads to some losses. A large number of non-earning workers exist just below the level of being used in every industry. Some of these are permanently set aside; others might be brought back into use when business conditions get better. When the iron industry slows down, many forges are inactive; but when the demand for iron increases again, old forges, factories, and machines are gradually put back to work as they become profitable to use. Many workers that aren’t currently earning money might start earning rent again if business conditions change.

§ III. DESTRUCTION OF NATURAL STORES OF MATERIALS

Destruction of the American forests

1. A large part of industry is now conducted without regard to the preservation of the source of income. A striking example of this is the use, or rather the destruction, of the American forests. In the last century the demand for lumber grew rapidly both on account of domestic needs and of the needs of the older countries. Great quantities of wood have been used and still greater quantities wasted, trees being girdled, the ground burned over, the timber destroyed in any way that would clear the soil—timber which to-day would be of far more value than is the cleared land on which[Pg 88] it stood. Considering present needs and conditions, the labor seems to have been worse than wasted.

1. Much of the industry today operates without considering the future of its income sources. A clear example of this is the use, or more accurately, the destruction, of American forests. In the last century, the demand for lumber grew rapidly due to both domestic needs and the demands from older countries. Huge amounts of wood have been consumed and even larger amounts wasted, with trees being stripped, the land burned, and timber destroyed in ways that would clear the land—timber that now would be worth far more than the cleared land on which[Pg 88] it stood. Given current needs and conditions, the effort seems to have been completely wasted.

Effects on value of timber

The direct effect of this destruction of the supply has been the increase in the value of timber. To the settlers much of the timber was worse than useless; they paid and labored to get rid of it; now the supplies of lumber must be sought on the very margins of our territory: Florida, Maine, northern Michigan and Wisconsin, Washington, and Oregon. The supplies in Washington and Oregon are almost unavailable in the Eastern states on account of the cost of transportation. Professor Marsh, thirty years ago, strikingly characterized the policy that has been pursued: "We are breaking up the foundation timbers and the wainscoting of the house in which we live in order to boil our mess of pottage."

The immediate result of this destruction of the supply has been the rise in the value of timber. For the settlers, much of the timber was more of a burden than a help; they had to pay and work hard to get rid of it. Now, lumber supplies have to be sourced from the very edges of our territory: Florida, Maine, northern Michigan and Wisconsin, Washington, and Oregon. The supplies in Washington and Oregon are nearly impossible to get to the Eastern states because of shipping costs. Professor Marsh, thirty years ago, clearly described the policy that has been followed: "We are breaking up the foundation timbers and the wainscoting of the house in which we live in order to boil our mess of pottage."

Physical effects

The indirect effects of these changes are fully as great as the direct ones. Forests greatly affect climate, temperature, and soil; they influence the humidity. They equalize the flow of streams, moderate floods, and by preventing the washing down of the rich soil, keep the mountain sides from becoming bare and sterile rocks. So, within the last two decades, the people in America have begun to think of forestry. Its purpose is to restore the forests to the condition of permanent rent-earners, to make the mountains yield not a temporary supply, but a perpetual crop of timber.

The indirect effects of these changes are just as significant as the direct ones. Forests have a big impact on climate, temperature, and soil; they also influence humidity. They help regulate the flow of streams, reduce flooding, and by preventing soil erosion, keep the mountains from turning into bare and lifeless rocks. Over the past twenty years, people in America have started to prioritize forestry. Its goal is to restore forests to a state where they can consistently generate income, ensuring that the mountains provide not just a temporary supply, but a steady, ongoing harvest of timber.

Possible exhaustion of the coal-supply

2. The extraction of coal and other mineral deposits reduces for future generations a supply already limited. The coal deposits in the earth have only recently been drawn upon. A small city like Ithaca probably uses to-day a greater quantity of coal than was used in all Europe two centuries ago. The large deposits of coal and their early development in England long gave a great advantage to English industry over that of other countries. In England, however, has first been felt the fear of the exhaustion of the coal-supply. Professor Jevons, in 1861, sounded the note of alarm; he prophesied that because the coal deposits of America were many times as great as those of England, industrial[Pg 89] supremacy must inevitably pass to America. Already the supremacy in coal and iron production has passed to America, and that in textiles soon will come. In England the accessible supply of coal is limited, deeper shafts must be sunk, and the coal gotten with greater difficulty and at greater expense. Coal has risen in price in England within the last few years, and will continue to rise in the future. The coal deposits of America are thirty-seven times as great as those of England, but even these will soon be exhausted. And yet on the part of all except the coal trust, there appears in America a thoughtless disregard for the future. Supplies of copper, iron, and lead in favored positions are likewise limited, and are being rapidly centered in the hands of great companies. The increasing demand for these products insures a steadily rising income from their annual use. The value of the mines, being based on the series of incomes they will yield, may increase while their unused treasures dwindle in quantity.

2. The extraction of coal and other mineral resources is depleting a supply that's already limited for future generations. We’ve only recently started using the coal deposits in the earth. A small city like Ithaca today probably uses more coal than all of Europe did two centuries ago. The large coal deposits and their early development in England gave English industry a significant advantage over other countries for a long time. However, England was the first to feel the worry about running out of coal. In 1861, Professor Jevons raised the alarm, predicting that since America's coal deposits are many times larger than those of England, industrial dominance would inevitably shift to the United States. Already, the U.S. has taken the lead in coal and iron production, and dominance in textiles is coming soon. In England, the accessible coal supply is dwindling; deeper mines need to be dug, making coal extraction more difficult and more expensive. The price of coal in England has increased over the last few years and will keep rising in the future. America's coal deposits are thirty-seven times larger than those in England, but even those will run out soon. Yet, apart from the coal trust, there seems to be a careless disregard for the future in America. Supplies of copper, iron, and lead in desirable locations are also limited and are quickly being concentrated in the hands of large corporations. The growing demand for these resources ensures a consistently rising income from their annual usage. The value of the mines, which is based on the future incomes they will generate, may increase while their untouched resources decrease in quantity.

Many natural resources are being rapidly exhausted

3. The exhaustion of natural stores of material is due to civilization, but it threatens to put an end to industrial progress. The savage does not go deep enough to use up permanently the world in which he lives. He uses the fruits that he finds, and those fruits are, almost without exception, renewed the next year. The only mines that were worked out in ancient times were gold and silver mines, while the mines of useful metals were touched but lightly. Within the last century the earth's crust has been exploited with startling rapidity. Scientific knowledge and mechanical improvement have combined to unlock the storehouses of the geologic ages. At the ever-increasing rate of their use, many important materials must be exhausted in the not far distant future. While it is probable that substitutes will be discovered for many of them, the outlook in some directions has little promise. To treat terminable incomes, exhaustible sources of supply, as permanent sources of income, leads alike to unsound theory and to reckless practice.

3. The exhaustion of natural resources is caused by civilization, but it's putting industrial progress at risk. Primitive people don’t go deep enough to permanently deplete the environment they inhabit. They gather what fruits they find, which almost always regrow the following year. The only mines that were heavily exploited in ancient times were those for gold and silver, while useful metal mines were only lightly tapped. Over the past century, the Earth’s surface has been exploited at an alarming pace. Scientific advancements and technological improvements have come together to unlock the resources of geological ages. At the growing rate of their consumption, many critical materials could run out in the near future. While substitutes will likely be found for many of them, the outlook for some is not very promising. Treating limited incomes and exhaustible resources as if they were permanent leads to both flawed theories and irresponsible practices.


CHAPTER 12

INCREASE OF RENT-BEARERS AND OF RENTS

§ I. EFFORTS OF MEN TO INCREASE PRODUCTS AND RENT-BEARERS

Desire for better agents impels men to improvements

1. While man destroys some agents of production he multiplies many others. We have noted many kinds of depreciation, destruction, and wearing out of wealth; but the normal thing in a healthy society is an increase, on the whole, of rent-bearers. The increase of rents is due to two causes: changes in the agents by which they become more efficient technically, or more numerous; and changes taking place outside of the agents, affecting the utility of the products. The first of these will be considered in this section.

1. While people are destroying some resources for production, they're multiplying many others. We've observed various forms of depreciation, destruction, and wear and tear on wealth; however, what's typical in a healthy society is an overall increase in rent-generating assets. The rise in rents can be attributed to two factors: changes in the resources that make them more efficient technically or more abundant, and external changes that impact the usefulness of the products. We'll focus on the first of these in this section.

The increase of the efficiency of agents is usually the aim of the individual producer, and thus is brought about an increase of the stock of wealth. In some cases, however, improvements such as the dredging of harbors or as the protecting of forests, are made by men collectively through the agency of governments. Somewhere, however, the desire for these changes must arise in the minds of individuals. Increase of most things involves "cost" or sacrifice, in the psychological sense; that is, man must strive, perhaps suffer, to get a certain result. This end, therefore, must be in itself desirable, and social organization must be such as to present a motive to the men to make the needed effort.

The goal of each producer is usually to boost their efficiency, which in turn leads to an increase in overall wealth. However, sometimes improvements, like dredging harbors or protecting forests, are made collectively by people through government action. Still, the desire for these changes must start in the minds of individuals. Achieving most things requires "cost" or sacrifice, in a psychological sense; that is, people must work hard, and sometimes endure hardship, to achieve certain results. Therefore, the desired outcome must be appealing in itself, and society must be organized in a way that motivates people to put in the effort needed.

Improvements by adaptation of natural resources

2. Rent-bearers may be increased in quantity and improved in quality by the adaptation of natural resources to man's purposes. To get food, men use the tracts of land that under the conditions give the largest product. Other tracts[Pg 91] less fertile, or for some reason less available, are ditched, tiled, and diked, and fertilizers are carried up steep hillsides to make a soil upon the very crags. In commerce and transportation, new ways are opened by canals, railroads, and tunnels. An isthmian canal will raise the efficiency of ships plying between New York and San Francisco, enabling them to carry a greater amount of freight within a year. The tolls will represent to the users an expenditure only partially offsetting the increased efficiency of the agents of transportation. By the building of wharves, the dredging of harbors, and by many other methods, indirect agents are constantly growing in number and efficiency.

2. Rent-bearers can be increased in amount and improved in quality by adapting natural resources for human use. To obtain food, people utilize the areas of land that yield the highest output under current conditions. Other areas[Pg 91] that are less fertile or not as accessible are drained, tiled, and fortified, while fertilizers are transported up steep hillsides to enrich even the rocky soil. In commerce and transportation, new pathways are created through canals, railroads, and tunnels. An isthmian canal will enhance the efficiency of ships traveling between New York and San Francisco, allowing them to carry more cargo within a year. The tolls will cost the users a sum that only partially offsets the increased efficiency of the transportation methods. Through the construction of wharves, dredging of harbors, and various other techniques, indirect means of transport are continually increasing in number and effectiveness.

Machinery is an adaptation of natural resources

3. Rent-bearers may be increased by inventions and improvements that make machines stronger, quicker, and better. This proposition is not logically different from the preceding. A machine is an arrangement of material things through which force may be indirectly applied to move matter. No fast line divides machinery as regards form, purpose, or cause of value, from the artificially improved natural agents that we have been discussing. Just as a field is drained, plowed, and cultivated to fit it better to yield a crop, so is the iron ore shaped into a form called a machine, better fitted to cut, carve, and weave as man wills. Machines are merely adaptations of natural resources.

3. We can increase the output from machines through inventions and advancements that make them stronger, faster, and more efficient. This idea isn’t logically different from the previous one. A machine is a setup of physical materials that allows us to indirectly apply force to move things. There’s no clear boundary separating machinery in terms of design, purpose, or value from the artificially enhanced natural resources we've been talking about. Just like a field is drained, plowed, and cultivated to improve crop yields, iron ore is shaped into machines that are better suited for cutting, carving, and weaving as needed by humans. Machines are simply adaptations of natural resources.

Bettering quality of agents

Increase in machinery may be either in quality or quantity. The two causes have in most cases the same result. If the quality or efficiency of looms is doubled, it is as if their number had grown in like proportion. In its economic function the beast of burden may not illogically be classed with inanimate machines. The horses in America have been remarkably improved of recent years by the importation of thoroughbred stock from Europe. Ten or fifteen years ago the number of horses in the United States was found to have decreased, and there was much comment on this evidence of a declining industry. It was not at once recognized that there was embodied in horse-flesh more horse-power than ever before,[Pg 92] as a single Norman horse has the strength of several Mexican mustangs. Numbers alone are not the measure of efficiency.

An increase in machinery can happen in either quality or quantity. Usually, both causes lead to the same outcome. If the quality or efficiency of looms is doubled, it’s like their number has also increased proportionally. In economic terms, it makes sense to consider working animals alongside inanimate machines. In recent years, horses in America have been greatly improved by importing thoroughbred stock from Europe. Ten or fifteen years ago, the number of horses in the United States had decreased, and there was a lot of talk about this as a sign of a struggling industry. It wasn't immediately recognized that in horse-flesh, there was more horsepower than ever before,[Pg 92] since a single Norman horse has the strength of several Mexican mustangs. Just having more numbers doesn’t equate to greater efficiency.

Increasing number and better grouping of agents

4. The increase of wealth and the betterment of environment go on as well through the increase in the number of appliances and through their improved arrangement, as through changes in their kind. A machine is an adjustment of various natural agents to each other so as to make a more efficient agent, and machines in turn may be adjusted as parts of a larger system of production. The ideal of the modern factory system is so to arrange the machinery that no bit of material will make an unnecessary motion. The log, once started through the mill, is carried automatically from one machine to another until it emerges as a roll of paper or as a box of tooth-picks, ready for use. In an American watch-factory one man tends twelve or fifteen automatic machines. A small brass rod is fed automatically to the machine; a piece is cut off, is picked up by a human-like metal hand; is put into a lathe, and shifted or held firmly while it goes through fifteen or twenty processes; and then is dropped into a box where it is ready for the "assembling" of the watch. As the machinery improves, factories making allied products are grouped to make a system still more efficient.

4. The growth of wealth and the improvement of our environment happen through an increase in the number of machines and their better arrangement, as well as changes in their type. A machine is a combination of different natural forces working together to create a more efficient tool, and machines can be adjusted as parts of a larger production system. The goal of the modern factory system is to arrange machinery so that no material makes unnecessary movements. Once a log is processed through the mill, it is automatically transported from one machine to another until it turns into a roll of paper or a box of toothpicks, ready to use. In an American watch factory, one person operates twelve to fifteen automatic machines. A small brass rod is automatically fed into the machine; a piece is cut off, picked up by a robotic arm, placed into a lathe, and held securely while it undergoes fifteen to twenty processes; then it is dropped into a box, ready for "assembling" the watch. As machinery continues to advance, factories that produce related products are clustered together to create an even more efficient system.

As the number of agents increases they are distributed so as to be where most useful to the owner. A man having two umbrellas keeps one at his office and the other at home; a student having two books of the same kind keeps one at his room and the other at the university; a farmer having two hoes keeps one at the barn and the other in a distant field, and by this distribution the agents are increased in efficiency.

As the number of agents grows, they're placed where they're most beneficial to the owner. A guy with two umbrellas leaves one at his office and the other at home; a student with two of the same book keeps one in his room and the other at school; a farmer with two hoes stores one in the barn and the other in a far-off field. This way, the agents work more effectively.

A larger and better environment

The aim of a progressive society is to enlarge the environment, and constantly to adapt it better to the service of wants. This is done largely by mechanical agents, which capture the natural forces of the world, put them into the right place at the right time, and make them do the right thing, or which group and relate the materials of the[Pg 93] world in the right ways. Some of the groupings in the chemical and physical world that do not fit man's purposes may be made to do so. The world in this way becomes more and more a great workshop, better and better adjusted to man's wants.

The goal of a progressive society is to expand the environment and continuously improve it to meet people's needs. This is largely achieved through mechanical agents that harness the natural forces of the world, position them properly at the right moments, and make them function effectively, or that organize and connect materials in the[Pg 93] world in useful ways. Some groupings in the chemical and physical world that don't initially serve human purposes can be modified to do so. In this way, the world increasingly becomes a vast workshop, more and more tailored to human needs.

Increasing some rent-bearers reduces the rents of others

5. The betterment of the environment of society in some directions reduces the rent of other parts. The wish of the individual is to raise his own rent-bearers in efficiency, but in doing that he affects the agents owned and controlled by others. The ideal from a social standpoint is to increase not rent but the welfare of society, and this is not always the ideal of individuals seeking their own interest. However, as the efficiency of some agents rises, it becomes unnecessary and unprofitable to use the less fertile fields; they cease to be rent-bearers, and the rent of the richer fields falls under the influence of the new supply of products. Some inventions suddenly increase the efficiency of free goods to such a degree that the less efficient rented agents are thrown out of use, and the margin of utilization is moved to a higher plane than it was on before. Improved types of machinery more or less rapidly displace the older, less efficient types, which, therefore, more or less completely lose their rent-bearing power long before they are physically worn out. When improvements in agriculture that are applicable to a considerable area of land take place, and the product thus is increased and cheapened, the poorer land is abandoned. Inventions and improvements thus gradually becoming common property, increase the free goods and free uses not bearing rent and open to every one. One who improves the quality of a machine or the economy of a process may thus unintentionally injure some of the owners of low-rent agents, while unintentionally increasing the welfare of the mass of men for whom the margin of utilization is thus lifted.

5. Improving certain aspects of society’s environment can lower the value of other areas. Individuals aim to enhance their own sources of income, but in doing so, they impact the resources owned and controlled by others. The ideal perspective for society is to boost overall welfare rather than just income, but this isn’t always the goal for those pursuing their individual interests. However, as the productivity of some resources increases, it becomes unnecessary and unprofitable to use less productive land; these lands stop generating income, and the income from more productive areas decreases due to the new supply of products. Some inventions drastically improve the efficiency of free resources to the point that less efficient rented resources are rendered obsolete, shifting the margin of their use to a higher level than before. Improved machinery tends to replace older, less efficient types relatively quickly, causing them to lose their income-generating capacity long before they are physically worn out. When agricultural advancements that can be applied over large areas occur, production increases and costs decrease, leading to the abandonment of poorer land. As inventions and improvements gradually become widely available, they increase the amount of free resources and uses that don’t generate income and are accessible to everyone. Someone who enhances a machine's quality or improves a process’s efficiency might inadvertently harm some owners of low-income resources while simultaneously raising the overall welfare of the general population by lifting the margin of resource utilization.

§ II. EFFECTS OF SOCIAL CHANGES IN RAISING THE RENTS OF INDIRECT AGENTS

Effect of decrease of the competing agents

1. Changes in the number and kind of competing resources may raise the rents of particular agents. Rents may increase without increase in the quantity or number of a particular group of agents or without change in their technical efficiency. As changes in the conditions of society may reduce rents, so other changes may increase them. Agents of the same kind may diminish in number, either absolutely or relatively. If some of the competing machines are destroyed, the rents of the machines that remain rise, while if new supplies are found, either in nature or by improved industrial processes, the rents of the older agents fall.

1. Changes in the number and type of competing resources can increase the rents of specific agents. Rents can go up without an increase in the quantity or number of a certain group of agents or without changes in their technical efficiency. Just as changes in societal conditions can lower rents, other changes can raise them. Agents of the same type can decrease in number, either absolutely or relatively. If some competing machines are taken out of commission, the rents of the machines that are still operational go up, while if new resources are discovered, either naturally or through enhanced industrial methods, the rents of the older agents drop.

Effect of new uses for agents

2. The discovery of new uses for agents or for their products raises their rents. Farm land of the poorest kind often is found to contain valuable mineral deposits. Such a lucky find has lifted the mortgage from a farm in eastern Pennsylvania, from which, in two or three years, has been taken feldspar exceeding in value the agricultural products of the same land in the last fifty years. The discovery of building stone, coal, natural gas, or oil land may make the annual rent (or royalty) of land tenfold its former total value. Fitness to produce nettles is not ordinarily a virtue in land, but the discovery that certain fields produce a superior quality of the nettle used for heckling cloth, causes them to take on a new value. A mineral spring, because of the supposed or proved healing properties of its waters, may be as good as a mine to the owner. Peculiar fitness for the cultivation of celery may convert marsh land into a substantial source of income.

2. The discovery of new uses for materials or their products increases their value. Even the least desirable farmland can end up having valuable mineral deposits. A fortunate find has helped pay off a mortgage on a farm in eastern Pennsylvania, where feldspar worth more than the agricultural products from that land in the last fifty years has been extracted in just two or three years. Finding building stone, coal, natural gas, or oil can boost the annual rent (or royalty) of land to ten times its previous value. While being suitable for growing nettles isn't typically a benefit for land, the realization that certain fields yield a superior quality of nettle used in cloth production gives them new worth. A mineral spring, due to its reputed or confirmed healing properties, can be as valuable as a mine to its owner. Uncommon suitability for growing celery can turn marshland into a significant income source.

Social changes are constantly causing agents to shift from lower to higher uses. As population grows and groups about new industries, farm land is used for residence lots, and in turn for business purposes. Rents therefore rise, and this[Pg 95] rise is reflected in the higher selling value of the land. If a new demand arises for the product of any machine, its rent rises, although it may continue to turn out the same product as measured by number or quantity. For, if consumers increase, a given supply of agents becomes relatively smaller than before.

Social changes are continuously causing resources to be repurposed from lower to higher uses. As the population increases and new industries emerge, farmland is converted into residential lots, which in turn are used for business purposes. As a result, rents go up, and this[Pg 95] increase is reflected in the higher selling price of the land. If there’s a new demand for a product from any machine, its rent increases, even if it continues to produce the same quantity as before. Because when the number of consumers rises, the available supply of resources becomes relatively smaller than it was.

Sudden variations in demand

3. A rise in rents due to social changes may be relatively permanent or temporary. Business conditions sometimes change quickly. An urgent demand for special machinery raises quickly its rent and value. It is said that lace machinery is sometimes thrown out of use for several years, until a sudden renewal of the demand for lace causes the rental to equal, in two years, more than the original cost. At such times the value of factories increases greatly, but after a few years of prosperity business again collapses. Such prosperous periods are the opportunity of the business man and of the promoter to sell the factory at its highest price. Machinery adapted only for a special product will not sell as readily when less needed for its special use, as that which, like a turning-lathe, can be used for many purposes; but the more special the appliances needed for a certain product, the higher, more abnormal will be their temporary value when they are suddenly needed. Land near the site of an exposition takes on a very great value and again falls after the exposition is over. During the Boer War horses and mules rose in price in the United States on account of British purchases.

3. Rent increases due to social changes can be either permanent or temporary. Business conditions can change rapidly. A sudden demand for specialized machinery can quickly drive up its rent and value. It's noted that lace machinery may sit unused for several years until a sudden surge in demand for lace makes its rental in just two years exceed its original cost. During these times, the worth of factories can soar, but after a few prosperous years, business can once again decline. These prosperous periods present opportunities for businesspeople and promoters to sell factories at peak prices. Machinery designed for a specific product won't sell as easily when demand decreases compared to something like a lathe that serves multiple purposes; however, the more specialized the equipment needed for a particular product, the greater its temporary value will be when demand spikes. Land close to the site of an exposition experiences a significant increase in value, only to drop again after the event concludes. During the Boer War, the prices of horses and mules rose in the United States due to British purchases.

Cause efforts to increase the supply of agents

A rise in the value of any agent at once causes an attempt to duplicate it or to find a substitute for it; this attempt, if successful, puts a check or sets a limit to the rise. In this search for new devices the man who can see most quickly and clearly has a key to wealth. Some kinds of agents, as rare minerals or tools that can be produced only by highly skilled labor, cannot be increased rapidly in number and remain high in price for a long period; and favorably located building sites illustrate the same principle. In some cases,[Pg 96] it is true, the demand may be due to some temporary cause, as in a period of unsound land speculation, but usually the growing value of location is due to a steady and abiding change in population or business.

A rise in the value of any asset immediately leads to efforts to replicate or find a replacement for it; this attempt, if successful, limits or stops the increase. In this quest for new solutions, the person who can perceive quickly and clearly holds the key to wealth. Certain assets, like rare minerals or tools that can only be made by highly skilled workers, can't be rapidly increased in quantity and tend to stay high in price for an extended time; well-located building sites demonstrate the same principle. In some cases,[Pg 96] the demand might stem from a temporary factor, such as during a time of shaky land speculation, but usually, the rising value of a location results from a consistent and lasting change in population or business.

Franchises guard the growing rents from the influence of substitution

4. Such public utilities as are guarded from competition by franchises, often rise in rental with increase in population. The leading classes of public utilities referred to are waterworks, gas-works, street-railways, ferries, and wharves. This evidently is only a special illustration of the principle just stated, where it is not easy to find a substitute for certain agents. Public franchises entitle the owners to special, sometimes exclusive, privileges, and protect them legally from competition. Not all franchises are valuable; many street-railways are unfortunate ventures, the earnings being insufficient to pay expenses, to say nothing of interest on the investment. But when they pay greatly, their high value is due to the impossibility of competition. The cars, mules, dynamos, steam-engines, and other agents combined to furnish transportation, have a special earning power because other similar agents are forbidden to be used in that market.

4. Public utilities that are protected from competition by franchises often see their rental prices increase as the population grows. The main types of public utilities mentioned here are water systems, gas companies, streetcars, ferries, and docks. This is clearly just a specific example of the principle already discussed, where it's hard to find alternatives for certain resources. Public franchises give the owners exclusive rights and legally shield them from competition. Not all franchises are beneficial; many streetcar systems are unsuccessful, with revenues not covering expenses, let alone providing returns on investment. However, when they are profitable, their high value comes from the lack of competition. The buses, horses, electric engines, steam engines, and other resources used for transportation have unique earning potential because similar resources are banned from operating in that market.

Various kinds of "unearned increments"

5. Industry abounds with cases of unearned increments of value due to accidental and social causes raising the rents of wealth. The term unearned increment may be defined as an increase in rents (or value) of agents, due to something other than the efforts or merits of the owner; in fact, it is that of which we have been speaking. In some cases powerful or wealthy men can bring about social changes in entirely legitimate ways. The owner of a large factory, moving it into the country, may buy up surrounding land and found a city, converting pasture lands and corn-fields into valuable building lots. Again, social changes are produced immorally, if not illegitimately, when wealthy men or influential politicians cause laws to be passed which inure to their advantage but which may ruin many other citizens.

5. The industry is full of examples of unearned increases in value due to random and social factors driving up the value of wealth. The term unearned increment can be defined as an increase in rents (or value) of assets, due to something other than the efforts or merits of the owner; in fact, this is what we've been discussing. In some instances, powerful or wealthy individuals can bring about social changes in completely legitimate ways. The owner of a large factory, relocating it to the countryside, might purchase nearby land and create a city, turning pastures and cornfields into valuable building lots. Conversely, social changes can occur immorally, if not illegally, when wealthy individuals or influential politicians push for laws that benefit them but could harm many other citizens.

Also many chances of loss

In most cases, however, social changes are impersonally caused. The individual owner who profits by them is powerless[Pg 97] to affect the result. He can only adapt his conduct in some measure so as to reap an advantage. He can strive to increase the number and quality and to get control of such agents as he foresees will yield higher rents. In making such a forecast there is chance of loss as well as of gain. The term "unearned increment" has been frequently used in recent years. It is often assumed to be a peculiar thing, sharply in contrast to other changes in value. The foregoing hasty review may serve to suggest how manifold and complex are the instances of it, and what an important part it plays in modern industry.

In most cases, social changes happen without personal influence. The individual owner who benefits from them has no power[Pg 97] to change the outcome. They can only adjust their actions to take advantage of the situation. They can work to increase the quantity and quality of resources and gain control over those that are likely to yield higher profits. When making such predictions, there’s a risk of both loss and gain. The term "unearned increment" has been widely used in recent years. It's often seen as something unique, distinctly different from other changes in value. The quick overview above highlights the varied and complex instances of it and emphasizes its significant role in modern industry.


DIVISION C—CAPITALIZATION AND TIME-VALUE


CHAPTER 13

MONEY AS A TOOL IN EXCHANGE

§ I. ORIGIN OF THE USE OF MONEY

The consideration of money can no longer be postponed

1. The exchange of goods by barter is extremely difficult in most cases. Thus far we have not considered the subject of money and have so far as possible avoided even the use of the term. Value in economics does not depend on money, and is not necessarily connected with it. Things can be compared in their utility, their importance to our welfare can be estimated, without the use of money. Many problems of economics can be discussed pretty thoroughly and solved without the use of the word money or any term of similar meaning. But to-day it is impossible to go very far in the discussion of economic questions without using the concept of money, which is interwoven with every practical and theoretical problem in economics. We have delayed to the farthest limit the formal recognition of the subject; but we are now approaching the question of capital and interest, and it is no longer possible to avoid a preliminary consideration of the money concept.

1. Bartering goods is really challenging in most situations. Up to now, we haven't really talked about money and have avoided using the term as much as possible. In economics, value isn't based on money and isn't necessarily tied to it. We can compare things based on their usefulness, and we can judge their importance to our well-being without using money. Many economic issues can be discussed in depth and resolved without mentioning money or any similar term. However, today it’s hard to get far in discussing economic questions without referring to the idea of money, which is intertwined with every practical and theoretical issue in economics. We've pushed the formal acknowledgment of this topic to the limit, but we are now getting close to discussing capital and interest, and it’s no longer feasible to avoid considering the concept of money.

Exact measurement of utilities is not possible without some medium of exchange

In considering the problem of exchange of consumption goods, we have assumed that it is possible to weigh small differences in the marginal utility of goods, and that such[Pg 99] differences have influence on exchange. Now in exchange by barter such a small estimate is impossible. In barter things are exchanged directly for each other in kind. If the two things do not chance to coincide in value, the exchange cannot be completed. An equivalent must be found, or a multiple, if the marginal utility of two goods is to be equalized for either party by exchange. As in most cases this adjustment must be very incomplete, many exchanges that otherwise would be advantageous cannot take place. In the earlier stages of development, this careful estimate of value is not found. Children do not make it. The typical trade of the small boy is a "trade even"; Johnny exchanges his gingerbread for Jimmie's jack-knife. It marks an epoch in the industrial development of the boy when he begins to keep store with pins, and no longer trades candy for apples, but both for pins, which have become the medium of exchange in his boy world. He then can express values in much more exact terms. In our society most children begin early to grow familiar with this conception; but travelers find some savage tribes still in the earlier childish stage of development, unable to grasp the thought of a general medium of exchange. When, through lack of a medium of exchange, there is a failure to adjust utilities, there is a loss of the possible advantage in each defeated exchange. There is a further waste of time and of vain efforts to find something that will be accepted in exchange, and the loss offsets a large part of the gain even when the barter is effected.

In looking at the issue of trading consumable goods, we have assumed that it is possible to measure small differences in the marginal utility of goods, and that such[Pg 99] differences influence exchange. However, in barter, this small measurement is not feasible. In barter, items are exchanged directly for one another. If the two items don’t happen to have the same value, the exchange can’t happen. An equivalent needs to be found, or a multiple, if the marginal utility of two goods is going to be balanced for either party through exchange. Since this adjustment is often very incomplete, many exchanges that would otherwise be beneficial cannot occur. In the earlier stages of development, this careful value assessment is absent. Children don’t engage in it. A typical trade for a young boy is a "trade even"; for example, Johnny swaps his gingerbread for Jimmie's jackknife. A significant milestone in a boy’s industrial development occurs when he starts trading with pins instead of candy for apples, which have become the means of exchange in his little world. He can then express values in much clearer terms. In our society, most children start to become familiar with this concept early on; however, travelers discover some primitive tribes still stuck in the earlier, child-like phase of development, unable to comprehend the idea of a universal medium of exchange. When a lack of a medium of exchange results in a failure to balance utilities, it leads to a loss of potential advantages in each unfulfilled exchange. Additionally, there’s a further waste of time and effort in trying to find something that will be acceptable for trade, and this loss significantly diminishes the benefits, even when barter does occur.

Money is found to serve as a general medium of exchange

2. Some kind of enjoyable good in general use comes to be money, that is, to be accepted as a medium of exchange. The difficulties just mentioned are met by the use of a medium of exchange. A medium of exchange is simply one kind of wealth which is taken, not for itself, but to pass along, in the belief that it will enable the taker to gratify his wants and distribute his purchasing power in a more effective way. Money is an "invention" in that it is a means of exchange that came into use independently in a great[Pg 100] number of communities. It is not an invention in the sense of a mechanical device suddenly hit upon, but rather in the sense of a social custom that grows as its convenience is tested by practice. Money is used, in some degree, everywhere except in the most primitive tribes. Historically viewed, the money first used in any community is seen in every case to be a commodity capable of giving immediate gratification, a direct good in immediate use. It then gradually comes to be used as money, which is an indirect agent. Still later, when the money habit is well established, a kind of material having no utility except as a medium of exchange may come to be used.

2. A generally accepted good that people enjoy becomes money, meaning it's used as a medium of exchange. The challenges mentioned earlier are addressed by using a medium of exchange. A medium of exchange is simply a type of wealth that is taken not for its own sake, but to transfer, with the belief that it will help the individual meet their wants and distribute their purchasing power more effectively. Money is an "invention" because it's a means of exchange that emerged independently in many different communities. It's not an invention like a mechanical device suddenly discovered, but more like a social custom that evolves as its usefulness is proven over time. Money is used to some extent almost everywhere, except in the most primitive tribes. When looking at history, the first type of money used in any community is always seen as a commodity that provides immediate satisfaction, a direct good in immediate use. Gradually, it starts to be used as money, which serves as an indirect agent. Eventually, when the habit of using money is well established, a type of material that has no purpose other than as a medium of exchange may begin to be used.

Qualities of the primitive money

3. Money in its origin is that good which best unites the qualities that make it easy to sell, to carry, to know, to keep, to divide, and unite. It is evident that if some one commodity is gradually to take on this use as a medium of exchange there will be a choice; some things will be better fitted than others. First, this thing must have the quality of salability, or marketability. In the channels of exchange it is taken not because it is wanted for itself, but because it will help to get something else that is wanted. To be sure of a ready sale in a primitive community it must, however, be something that is generally desired. Food and clothing, which supply the fundamental physical needs, are the most generally used and desired of all goods. But they do not have the second quality of a good money material, that of great value in small bulk, transportability. Food is bulky. The carrying of a venison or of a bag of wheat on one's back a short distance requires an effort as great as that for the procuring of the food. Furs, however, have this quality in a high measure, united with other qualities of money, as is shown by their general use in the exchanges of northern tribes. Thirdly, a thing must be recognizable; counterfeits must be easily avoided, and the quality must be easy to test: this is the quality of cognizability. The love of ornament is universal in human societies, and gives value to many[Pg 101] materials combining in a high degree the qualities thus far named. Fourthly, the money material, when taken in exchange, must remain without loss of quality, perhaps for long periods, until it can be exchanged again. Food does not answer to this requirement, being organic and perishable. But some of the metals, having value in small bulk, salability, cognizability, and durability, step by step displaced other forms of money. Finally, money must be made of a material easy to divide and unite. It is a great convenience in small transactions to be able to represent a fractional value by a small coin. The money material thus, likewise, is easily shifted to and from its money use. It is a very poor money that has not this quality, yet a thing may serve for money in larger transactions without it. Cattle, slaves, and land have been thus used, although they answer in a very rough way these fundamental requirements of the money material.

3. Money, at its core, is the good that best combines the qualities that make it easy to sell, carry, recognize, store, break down, and combine. It's clear that if one commodity gradually becomes the medium for exchange, there will be a selection; some items will be better suited than others. First, it must have the quality of being marketable. In trade, it’s taken not for its own sake, but because it helps in getting something else that is desired. To ensure a quick sale in a basic community, it has to be something that is widely sought after. Food and clothing, which fulfill essential physical needs, are the most commonly used and desired goods. However, they lack the second quality needed for good money: high value in a small size and ease of transport. Food is bulky. Carrying a deer or a bag of wheat a short distance takes as much effort as getting the food itself. Furs, on the other hand, possess this quality to a great extent, along with the other characteristics of money, as evidenced by their widespread use among northern tribes. Third, a thing must be easy to recognize; counterfeits must be simple to spot, and it should be easy to assess its quality: this is the quality of recognizability. The desire for decoration is universal in human societies, adding value to many[Pg 101] materials that combine the qualities mentioned so far. Fourth, the money material must maintain its quality for potentially long periods after being exchanged, until it can be traded again. Food doesn't meet this requirement since it is organic and perishable. However, some metals, which have value in small amounts, marketability, recognizability, and durability, gradually replaced other forms of money. Finally, money must be made from a material that is easy to divide and combine. It is very convenient in small transactions to represent a smaller value with a small coin. Thus, the money material can also be easily shifted back and forth from its monetary use. Money that lacks this quality is not very effective, although items can still serve as money in larger transactions without it. Cattle, slaves, and land have been used in this way, even though they only roughly meet the basic requirements for money.

Industrial changes affect the convenience of certain money forms

4. The changing material and industrial conditions of society change the kind of money that is used. The money use, as has just been shown, is a resultant of a number of different motives in men. Things that have the highest claim to fitness for money with a people at one stage of development would have a low claim at another. As each of these stages is passed, the thing used as money either increases or decreases in its fitness. The final choice depends on the resultant of all the advantages. The use of a material may become more general or less so. Shells used for ornament in poor communities cease to be so used in a higher state of advancement, and thus their salability ceases. Furs, used at some stage of development as money in all northern climes, cease to be generally marketable when the fur-bearing animals are nearly killed off and the fur trade declines. Tobacco was at one time in Virginia a great staple. Merchants were always ready to take it, and its market price was known by all; but as it ceased to be the almost exclusive product of the province, it lost the knowableness and marketability it[Pg 102] had before. In agricultural and pastoral communities where every one had a share in the pasture, cattle were a fairly convenient form of money, but to-day would be a most inconvenient one; a city merchant exchanging goods for Poland China pigs and Texas steers would envy the proverbial owner of a white elephant.

4. The changing material and industrial conditions of society change the kind of money that is used. The way money is used, as we've just seen, results from a variety of different motives among people. Things that are seen as most suitable for money at one stage of development may be considered less suitable at another. As each of these stages is reached, the items used as money either gain or lose their suitability. The final choice depends on the overall advantages. The use of a material can become more widespread or less so. Shells that were used for decoration in poorer communities lose that purpose as society advances, and so they stop being tradable. Furs, which were once used as money in northern regions, become less marketable when fur-bearing animals are nearly extinct and the fur trade declines. Tobacco was once a major crop in Virginia. Merchants were always eager to accept it, and everyone knew its market price; but as it stopped being the primary product of the area, it lost the recognition and marketability it[Pg 102] once had. In agricultural and pastoral communities where everyone shared access to the pasture, cattle were a pretty convenient form of money, but today it would be quite impractical; a city merchant trading goods for Poland China pigs and Texas steers would envy the classic owner of a white elephant.

The proved fitness of gold and silver as money

The value of the money material may fall so greatly as a result of greater production, as in the case of iron, tin, copper, that it becomes unsuitable. Again, as wealth grows, as exchanges increase, as the use of money develops, as commerce extends to more distant lands, the heavier, less precious metals fail to serve the money need, especially in the larger transactions. Thus, in a sense, different commodities compete, each trying to prove its fitness to be a medium of exchange; but only one, or two, or three at the most, can at one time hold such a place. Silver and gold, step by step, often making little progress in a century, have displaced other commodities, and are the staple and dominant forms of money in the world to-day. Every community has witnessed some stage of this evolution. Now nations are divided into two great groups, silver- and gold-using, in accordance with the metals they use as standards. The gold-using countries are the most advanced industrially, requiring the most valuable money metal. Many countries have passed in the last century from the silver to the gold standard, and in an intermediate period have tried to use both standards. The Asiatic and South American countries mainly use silver, while most of those in North America and Europe use gold.

The value of money materials can drop significantly due to increased production, like with iron, tin, and copper, making them impractical. As wealth increases, exchanges grow, money usage develops, and trade expands to farther regions, the heavier, less valuable metals become inadequate for monetary needs, especially in larger transactions. In a way, different goods compete to prove they can be used as a medium of exchange; however, only one, two, or at most three can fill that role at any given time. Silver and gold have gradually displaced other commodities, becoming the main and dominant forms of money worldwide today. Every community has experienced some phase of this evolution. Now nations fall into two main groups based on whether they use silver or gold as their standard. The countries that use gold are more industrially advanced and require a more valuable money metal. Many nations have switched from the silver standard to the gold standard over the last century, with some even trying to use both during the transition. Asian and South American countries primarily use silver, while most in North America and Europe use gold.

While industrial changes thus affect the choice of money, in turn money reacts upon the other industrial conditions. If a new and more convenient material is found, or the value of the money metal changes to a degree that affects the generalness of its use, industry is greatly affected. The discovery of mines in America brought into Europe, in the sixteenth century, a great supply of the precious metals, and this change in the use of money reacted powerfully on[Pg 103] industry. Money being itself one of the most important of the industrial conditions, is affected by and in turn affects all others.

While changes in industry influence the choice of currency, currency also impacts other industrial conditions. If a new and more convenient material is discovered, or if the value of the metal used for money changes significantly, it greatly affects industry. The discovery of mines in America brought a large supply of precious metals to Europe in the sixteenth century, and this shift in the use of money had a strong impact on[Pg 103] industry. Money, being one of the most vital industrial conditions, is both influenced by and influences all other conditions.

§ II. NATURE OF THE USE OF MONEY

Money is an indirect agent, a tool to effect exchanges

1. Money in all its money uses is an indirect agent, to be judged just as other indirect agents are. The key to this section is the thought that the function of money is to serve as an indirect agent. Money is often, by a figure of speech, called a tool. Literally a tool is a bit of material which, taken in the hand, is used to apply force to other things, to shape them or move them. Figuratively, this is just what money does. A man takes it in his hand not to get enjoyment out of it, but to apply force, to move something, and that which he moves is the other commodity. Adam Smith aptly likened money to the road and wagons that transport goods, thus gratifying wants by putting things into a more convenient place. Money is only one of a multitude of forms of wealth. It is not even the most "valuable"; it has value just as other indirect agents have. The loss caused by taking away an indirect agent entirely is greater than the benefit usually attributed to it. Its utility in the extremest conditions is greater than its marginal utility under ordinary conditions. Food is not credited in the market with enormous value, but if starvation threatened, all else would be given for food. In a like manner, each individual values money according to the importance of the marginal service it renders, but the marginal service is far from measuring the loss that would be caused by the entire disuse of money. In a society without money, industrial processes would be very different, and exchange would be hampered in almost inconceivable ways. It is true, therefore, that money is an economic factor of high importance, but it is not so indispensable as many other factors to which far less value is attributed.

1. Money, in all its uses, is an indirect agent, just like other indirect agents. The main idea in this section is that money acts as an indirect agent. People often refer to money as a tool. Literally, a tool is a piece of material that you hold in your hand to apply force to other things, to shape or move them. Figuratively, that's exactly what money does. A person holds it not to enjoy it, but to exert influence, to move something, and what they move is another commodity. Adam Smith fittingly compared money to the road and wagons that transport goods, fulfilling needs by placing things in a more convenient location. Money is just one of many forms of wealth. It's not even the most "valuable"; it holds value like other indirect agents. The loss from completely removing an indirect agent is greater than the benefit usually associated with it. Its usefulness in extreme situations surpasses its marginal utility in normal circumstances. Food isn't seen as having immense value in the market, but if someone were facing starvation, they would trade anything for food. Similarly, each person values money based on the significance of the marginal service it provides, but that marginal service doesn't come close to measuring the loss caused by completely doing away with money. In a moneyless society, industrial processes would look very different, and trade would be hindered in nearly unimaginable ways. Therefore, while it's true that money is a highly significant economic factor, it's not as essential as many other factors that are given far less value.

Why a poor community lacks money

A poor community has little money because it cannot afford[Pg 104] more; it gets along with less money than is convenient just as it gets along with fewer indirect agents of every other kind than it could use. Pioneers in a poor community where the average wealth is low, cannot afford to keep a large number of wagons, plows, good roads, or school-houses. If the community were wealthy enough it would have more of these and of other things, and great as is the convenience of money, poorer communities have to do with little of it. It is, therefore, a confusion of cause and effect for poor communities to imagine that their poverty is due to lack of money.

A struggling community has limited financial resources because it simply can't afford[Pg 104] more. It manages with less money than is practical, just as it copes with fewer indirect resources of all kinds than it could actually benefit from. Pioneers in a low-income community, where the average wealth is minimal, can't afford to maintain many wagons, plows, good roads, or schools. If the community were rich enough, it would have more of these and other essentials. Despite the significant benefits that money brings, poorer communities must make do with very little of it. Therefore, it's a misunderstanding for these communities to think that their poverty stems from a lack of money.

The use of money as a common denominator

2. Out of its use as a medium of exchange comes the use of money as a common denominator of values. Money serves as a "common denominator," for, as all other things can be expressed in terms of money, through it the value of other things can be compared. The other things can be expressed in money because they are constantly exchanged for it. All things being compared with money, can in turn be compared with each other. Some consider this service as a common denominator to be the primary and most important function of money. Sometimes a money of account is found, which is not in use as a medium of exchange. Cattle and slaves have served as money of account while not used as a medium of exchange in larger transactions. Money of account is used, as the shilling in New York, which for a century has not been in use at all as a medium of exchange. It is, however, only apparently a denominator of value; the shilling represents five fourths of ten cents. The actual standard is the dollar; the shilling is only a habitual form of speech and is mentally reduced to terms of the money in use. A decimal system is a great convenience in the use of money as a common denominator, but not indispensable. It is a striking fact that England, until a few years ago the greatest industrial nation, still uses a money unit requiring cumbrous calculations.

2. The use of money as a way to trade leads to its role as a standard for measuring value. Money acts as a "standard," because everything else can be valued in terms of money, allowing us to compare their worth. Other items can be represented in money because they are regularly exchanged for it. Since all things are compared to money, they can also be compared to each other. Some people think this role as a standard is the main and most important function of money. Sometimes there is a unit of account that isn’t actually used to trade. Cattle and slaves have served as units of account even when they weren't used for bigger trades. A unit of account is used, like the shilling in New York, which hasn’t been used as a trade medium for a century. However, it's only seemingly a value standard; the shilling equals five-fourths of ten cents. The real standard is the dollar; the shilling is just a common way of speaking and is mentally converted to the money currently in use. A decimal system makes it easier to use money as a standard, but it isn’t essential. It’s interesting that England, until a few years ago the largest industrial country, still uses a currency system that requires complicated calculations.

Money used as a storehouse for saving.

3. Other uses of money are as a storehouse of saving[Pg 105] and as a standard of deferred payments. These uses grow out of those before mentioned. The standard of deferred payments is the unit of value in which debts are agreed to be paid later. It is evidently most convenient, and therefore almost inevitable, that the common denominator in which all values are expressed from day to day should continue to be taken as the value unit when the completion of the exchange is delayed a day, a month, or a year. This will be more fully discussed at a later stage of our study.

3. Other uses of money include being a savings tool[Pg 105] and serving as a standard for future payments. These functions develop from the ones mentioned earlier. The standard for future payments is the unit of value used to agree on how debts will be paid later. It’s obviously more convenient, and therefore almost unavoidable, that the common measure for all values expressed daily should also be used as the value unit when the actual exchange is postponed for a day, a month, or a year. We will explore this topic further in a later part of our study.

The use of money as a storehouse of saving was more common formerly than it is now, when better ways than the hoarding of money are found for "laying up for a rainy day." In some measure, however, money is hourly serving this use, which is still an important one. Money kept to be used to-morrow or five years hence is a storehouse of value for twenty-four hours or for five years. In either case it is being kept to complete at a later time its use as a medium of exchange. A thing ceases to be money, logically viewed, the moment its owner keeps it without the purpose that it shall be spent ultimately. The typical miser is a man who has lost his reason as regards the money use. Money must be deemed, therefore, to perform the same essential service as a storehouse of saving that it does as a medium of exchange. In either case it is to be kept only to the moment when it will afford the maximum of pleasure.

The use of money as a way to save was more common in the past than it is today, when people have better options than just keeping cash to "prepare for emergencies." Nonetheless, money still serves this purpose regularly, which remains significant. Money set aside to be used tomorrow or in five years acts as a store of value, whether for twenty-four hours or for five years. In both cases, it's held to later fulfill its role as a medium of exchange. Something stops being considered money, in a logical sense, the moment its owner keeps it without intending to eventually spend it. The typical miser is someone who has lost sight of the practical use of money. Therefore, money should be viewed as fulfilling the same essential role as a store of savings that it does as a medium of exchange. In either situation, it should be kept only until it can provide the greatest joy.

§ III. THE VALUE OF TYPICAL MONEY

The money use is added to other uses

1. The money use, historically considered, is a new use added to a good, and increases the demand for that good. The history of any particular kind of money may be traced back to a point where it was not money, since which the money use has been added gradually to the other uses. The value of the material later to become money is determined, as is that of any good, according to its marginal utility in all possible applications. No new theory is required to explain[Pg 106] the value of this same commodity as it gradually acquires the added use of a medium of exchange. The new use influences demand for the thing just as do the other uses. What is here said must be understood as applying to typical money, which is at the same time a commodity having other uses. Other things that are not typical money come later to be used as money, under legal regulations.

1. The use of money, when looked at historically, is a new application added to a good, which increases the demand for that good. The history of any specific type of money can be traced back to a time when it wasn't considered money, during which the use of money has been gradually added to its other uses. The value of the material that later becomes money is determined, just like any good, based on its marginal utility across all possible uses. No new theory is needed to explain[Pg 106] the value of this same product as it slowly gains the additional role of a medium of exchange. This new use affects demand for the item in the same way as the other uses do. What is stated here should be understood as applying to typical money, which is also a commodity with other uses. Other items that aren't typical money later come to be used as money, following legal regulations.

The other uses continue, slightly modified by the money use

2. A good that comes to be used as money continues to have a commodity use along with the money use. When a thing is wanted for some quality that gives immediate gratification to the user, the explanation of its value is simple. Ornaments, shells, feathers, food can be seen to have a direct want-gratifying power. The money use is one that works no physical or visible change in goods, and to many minds it appears so different from other utilities that it remains quite mysterious and incomprehensible. To persons accustomed to thinking on problems of value, this case appears to be no more difficult than that of anything else having two or more uses. Cows are used for milk, for meat, and as beasts of burden. Each of these uses is logically independent as a cause of value, yet all are mutually related, the values of cattle being determined by the consideration of all their uses united into one scale of diminishing utility.

2. A good that starts being used as money still has its original use as a commodity. When something is desired for a quality that provides immediate satisfaction, understanding its value is straightforward. Ornaments, shells, feathers, and food clearly have a direct ability to satisfy wants. However, the use of money doesn’t result in any physical or visible change in goods, and to many people, it seems so different from other benefits that it remains quite mysterious and hard to understand. For those who are used to thinking about value problems, this situation isn’t any more difficult than anything else with multiple uses. Cows are utilized for milk, for meat, and as draft animals. Each of these uses independently contributes to their value, yet all are interconnected, with the values of cattle being determined by considering all their uses combined into one scale of decreasing utility.

Money yields a series of rents which are the basis of its value

3. The uses of money make it a rent-bearing form of wealth. The rent that money yields is in the form of convenience and economy. This is sometimes rendered directly as psychic income, as in enabling the traveler to buy his dinner, for the money thus yields gratification just as does the carriage in which he rides. One may go for a day to the seashore without a parasol and suffer from heat, or without money and suffer from hunger. In every case where money is retained for a time in possession, there is expected from it a usufruct as great as, or greater than, can be secured from anything else for which it can be exchanged. This usufruct is a net surplus, or income, yielded by a sum of money undiminished in amount up to the moment it is spent, but[Pg 107] meantime increasing in the gratification it will help to secure. In many cases in practical business money yields gratification only indirectly, as the objective contract rent received as interest for borrowed money in business uses, or as economic rent when the use of money in business enables one to secure a larger income. Because money yields a rent men make the sacrifice involved in keeping a stock of it on hand. On this rent is based that part of the value of money that is derived from its money use. As the use of money as a standard of deferred payment, or basis of commercial obligations, does not require that it be owned by the parties writing the contract, this use of money is a free good, a sort of social by-product of the medium of exchange. When money is in use in a community, any person may draw up contracts in terms of money, borrowing and lending, buying and selling wealth, later to be repaid in other wealth or services expressed in the circulating medium.

3. The ways we use money make it a source of wealth that produces income. The value that money provides comes from the convenience and savings it offers. This is sometimes directly experienced as psychological benefit, like when a traveler uses money to buy dinner, since it brings pleasure just like the carriage he rides in. You could go to the beach for a day without a sunshade and suffer from heat, or without money and suffer from hunger. In every case where money is kept for a while, there’s an expectation of a benefit as significant as, or greater than, anything else it could be exchanged for. This benefit is a net gain or income from a sum of money that remains unchanged until it is spent, but[Pg 107] in the meantime, it grows in the enjoyment it can provide. In many business situations, money only indirectly generates enjoyment, such as the actual rental income received as interest for borrowed money or as economic rent when using money in business allows someone to earn a higher income. Because money generates this income, people are willing to keep a supply of it available. This income forms part of the value of money that comes from its monetary use. Since using money as a standard for future payments or as a basis for commercial obligations doesn’t require that the parties involved own it, this application of money is a public good, a sort of social by-product of the exchange medium. When money is active in a community, anyone can create contracts based on money, borrowing and lending, buying and selling goods, with the understanding that they will later be paid back in different goods or services reflected in the money being used.

The general use of money is characteristic of this age

4. Money may be defined as a generally accepted material means of payment and medium of exchange. This, its primary and essential function, may appear to be less important as new modes of balancing accounts of wealth are devised. But its functions as a common denominator of values and as a standard of deferred payment are increasingly important in an advancing society. It is this expression of the value of all other things in terms of money which may well be deemed the essential characteristic of the capitalistic age. In earlier periods wealth was thought of and expressed in concrete terms; now it is expressed in money. The general use of money affects men's ways of looking at wealth and speaking of it. Without appreciating the nature and function of money, it is impossible to grasp the significance of capital in modern industry, the consideration of which we are now to enter upon.

4. Money is a widely accepted physical means of payment and a method of exchange. This primary and essential function may seem less crucial as new ways of balancing wealth accounts emerge. However, its roles as a common measure of value and a standard for future payments are becoming increasingly vital in a progressing society. The way we express the value of everything in terms of money is likely the defining feature of the capitalist era. In past times, wealth was viewed and expressed in tangible terms; now it's quantified in money. The widespread use of money influences how people perceive and talk about wealth. Without understanding the nature and purpose of money, it's impossible to comprehend the importance of capital in modern industry, which we are about to discuss.


CHAPTER 14

THE MONEY ECONOMY AND THE CONCEPT OF CAPITAL

§ I. THE BARTER ECONOMY AND ITS DECLINE

Various points of view of the students regarding money

1. The use of money prevails in very different degrees in various parts of the United States. The members of this class, representing nearly every state and territory in the Union, have lived amid very diverse industrial conditions. Some know best the country where conditions are similar to those of a hundred years ago; some, the villages where may be seen the handicrafts and the small general store. Others know better the cities with their varied industries; while doubtless still others, through family relations, know of the methods of great wholesale business, perhaps even of the larger commerce and foreign trade. Methods differ in the different lines of business, and according as a man is a farmer, a merchant, or a banker, he has different ideas as to the use of money and of the part it plays in modern industry. You come to this study with different experiences and preconceptions; as a result every statement produces a somewhat different impression on each of you. This is true in general of the statements made in political economy; but it is most strikingly true in the discussions of money. A city boy rarely sees a case of barter; whereas in many parts of the West and Southwest, and in the mountainous districts of the East, a large part of the business is carried on in this way. Town and city in New York state differ in this respect, but hardly more than do the rural districts of the different[Pg 109] sections of our country. Banks are very numerous in the East, are few in the Northwest, and still fewer in the South. Men can understand each other better in a discussion if they are conscious of the fact that they do not instinctively take the same point of view.

1. The use of money varies greatly across different parts of the United States. Members of this group, representing almost every state and territory in the Union, have experienced a wide range of industrial conditions. Some are most familiar with areas that resemble conditions from a hundred years ago; others know smaller towns with local crafts and general stores. Still others are more acquainted with cities that have diverse industries; and undoubtedly, some are familiar with large-scale wholesale businesses, perhaps even extensive commerce and foreign trade, through family connections. Business practices vary across different sectors, and depending on whether someone is a farmer, merchant, or banker, they have different perspectives on how money is used and the role it plays in modern industry. You approach this study with different experiences and assumptions, so each statement will resonate differently with each of you. This is generally true for discussions in political economy, but it is especially noticeable in discussions about money. A city boy rarely encounters barter, whereas in many areas of the West and Southwest, and in the mountainous regions of the East, a significant amount of business is conducted this way. Towns and cities in New York state differ in this regard, but not much more than the rural areas across various[Pg 109] regions of our country. Banks are abundant in the East, sparse in the Northwest, and even fewer in the South. People can engage in discussions more effectively if they recognize that they don't automatically share the same perspective.

Countries differ in their use of money

2. The extent to which, on an average, money is used in different countries of the world, differs widely. Statements in political economy must be guarded; few of them can be taken as universally true. As the different parts of one country may be contrasted, so may the different countries. The use of money in Siberia would be much less than that in Moscow and St. Petersburg, and again the average use in Western Russia is doubtless less than that in Austria. In Austria the money use is less developed than in Germany. While there is now little difference between Germany and France in this respect, France for a long time was the more developed industrially and made greater use of money.

2. The amount of money used on average varies greatly between countries around the world. Statements in political economy need to be made cautiously; very few can be considered universally accurate. Just as we can compare different regions within a country, we can also compare different countries. The use of money in Siberia is much lower than in Moscow and St. Petersburg, and the average usage in Western Russia is likely lower than in Austria. In Austria, money usage is less advanced than in Germany. While there is currently little difference between Germany and France in this regard, France was industrially more developed for a long time and made greater use of money.

There is greater use of money in the cities of the outlying countries than in the rural districts. In the cities of Mexico banks and credit agencies are employed as in the American cities. The rural districts are more backward and make far less use of money than is the case in the United States. The great ports of China are provided with all the facilities of modern banking. In the great cities of India one can get a bank draft that will be paid in any part of the world. But go a very little way out of the cities of China and India, and conditions greatly change; money is far less used and principally as a storehouse of saving.

There is more use of money in the cities of the surrounding countries than in the rural areas. In the cities of Mexico, banks and credit agencies operate just like they do in American cities. The rural areas are less developed and utilize money much less than in the United States. The major ports of China have all the features of modern banking. In the large cities of India, you can get a bank draft that will be honored anywhere in the world. However, if you travel just a short distance outside the cities of China and India, the situation changes dramatically; money is used much less and mainly as a way to save.

Slight use of money in the Middle Ages

3. In a historical view the European nations are seen to begin with a barter economy and to pass through great changes as regards the use of money. Here the view shifts from a comparison of different nations at the same moment to a comparison of the same nation through a period of centuries. To understand, even in a measure, what is about them men must know out of what it grows. In the early Middle Ages money was used chiefly in cities, and there[Pg 110] only to a limited extent. Almost universally a "barter economy" prevailed, or, as it has been called, a "natural economy," a term taken from the German "Naturalien," which means natural products, enjoyable things, as opposed to money. Natural economy, therefore, means that condition of society in which things are exchanged in kind. In the Middle Ages land was the great and dominant form of wealth. The prince himself was dependent on land for his income. The conquering chief or invader took possession of the land and parceled it out to his followers, and they in turn to their vassals. The income of the rulers was in the form of "Naturalien" (wheat, chickens, eggs), the kind and amount of which was fixed by contract or by immemorial usage. The landlord had land as his wealth and income-getter; the tenant received the use of the land in payment for his labor.

3. Historically, European nations started with a barter economy and underwent significant changes in how they used money. This perspective shifts from comparing different nations at the same time to examining the same nation over centuries. To understand the situation, people need to know its origins. In the early Middle Ages, money was mainly used in cities, and even there[Pg 110] it was limited. Almost everywhere, a "barter economy" was the norm, or what is referred to as a "natural economy," a term derived from the German "Naturalien," which means natural products or desirable items, as opposed to money. A natural economy, therefore, describes a societal condition where goods are exchanged directly. During the Middle Ages, land was the primary form of wealth. Even princes relied on land for their income. Conquering leaders or invaders would take over land and distribute it to their followers, who would then pass it on to their vassals. The rulers' income consisted of "Naturalien" (like wheat, chickens, eggs), with their type and quantity established by agreements or long-standing traditions. Landlords possessed land as their source of wealth and income, while tenants used the land in exchange for their labor.

Land, the main form of wealth, was rented without the use of money

The condition of the serf appears to have been, under these circumstances, inevitably connected with the "barter economy" as applied to the renting of land. A farm cannot be moved, and in medieval conditions its products mainly had to be used on the spot. If the serf was to use and enjoy the land, he had to stay upon it. Having no money he had to pay in labor or in products, for its usufruct. In those times the powerful man, politically, was also a wealthy man whose wealth consisted of landed estates. Between the landlord and the serf existed a lasting relation, inherited rather than voluntary, but similar in its conditions to the renting contract. The villein had the use of the stock, pastures, fields, woodlands, provided he kept them undiminished and undestroyed to transmit to his children. Under such conditions there was great fixity of economic relations. While in some respects this was a happy condition, it had its disadvantages. The renting contract, in connection with a fixed rotation of crops and some communal modes of cultivation, hindered improvements. The more intelligent cultivator could not change his methods for the better. It may be seen not only[Pg 111] that the use of money on a medieval manor was slight, but that the conditions for the growth of the money habit were most unfavorable. The terms of agricultural contracts, the modes of speech, the habits and thought of the mass of the people, were therefore determined by the conditions of the barter economy. A change in these respects was slowly worked by forces originating outside, in a very different industrial environment.

The situation of the serf seems to have been inevitably tied to the "barter economy" in relation to land rental. A farm can’t be moved, and in medieval times, its products mostly had to be consumed on-site. For the serf to use and enjoy the land, he had to remain on it. With no money, he paid in labor or goods for the right to use it. Back then, a politically powerful person was also wealthy, and their wealth came from owning land. There was a lasting relationship between the landlord and the serf, which was inherited rather than chosen, but it resembled a rental agreement. The villein could use the livestock, pastures, fields, and woodlands, as long as he maintained them to pass on to his children. Under these circumstances, economic relations were quite stable. While this could be considered a positive situation in some ways, it also had its downsides. The rental agreement, along with a set crop rotation and some communal farming practices, limited improvements. The more skilled farmer couldn’t alter his methods for the better. It can be observed not only[Pg 111] that money usage on a medieval manor was minimal, but also that conditions for developing a money-based system were highly unfavorable. The terms of agricultural contracts, common expressions, and the habits and thoughts of most people were shaped by the barter economy. Changes in these areas slowly emerged from external forces coming from a vastly different industrial context.

Contrast between city wealth and feudal estates in the Middle Ages

4. With the growth of cities developed a new class of wealthy men and a new view of wealth. The student of history knows of the conflict that grew up during the Middle Ages between the cities and the landed aristocracy. It found its cause in economic conditions. There were obvious differences between the wealth of the feudal landlords, and the wealth that grew up in cities. One must be used mostly on the spot, the other can be moved. The fruits of one are perishable for the most part; the fruits of the other can be kept for a longer period. The methods of agriculture are exceptionally stable; production by handicraftsmen is dependent on the peculiar skill of the workman, giving greater room for invention and a premium on skill. The one industry may be carried on by servile labor; the other can be efficiently followed only by free workers having the ambition to excel.

4. As cities grew, a new class of wealthy individuals emerged, along with a new perspective on wealth. History students are aware of the conflict that arose during the Middle Ages between urban areas and the landed aristocracy. This conflict stemmed from economic conditions. There were clear differences between the wealth of feudal landlords and the wealth generated in cities. The former had to be used primarily on-site, while the latter could be transported. The produce from one type is mostly perishable, while the produce from the other can be stored for a longer time. Agricultural methods are generally stable; however, production by craftsmen relies on the unique skills of individual workers, allowing for more innovation and rewarding expertise. One industry can be supported by servile labor, while the other can only thrive with free workers who have the drive to succeed.

Money thus more used in city trade

The use of money grew up in the city. The density of population made it easy, the growth of wealth made it possible, and the nature of the exchanges made it necessary. Whereas the relation of landlord and serf under the renting contract continues from year to year, the relation of the buyer and seller of shoes, hats, etc., in the city, is temporary, these things forming only a part of man's economic needs. Barter with a particular individual is much more inconvenient if exchange is only occasional than where the contract is a continuing one, and there is an annual balancing and settlement of accounts. So, as city industry and commerce grew the use of money increased, both in small[Pg 112] neighborhood trade and in the larger transactions with distant countries; and thus the business methods of the cities grew into sharper contrast with those of the rural districts.

The use of money developed in the city. The high population density made it easier, the increase in wealth made it possible, and the nature of trades made it necessary. While the relationship between landlord and tenant continues year after year, the relationship between buyers and sellers of shoes, hats, etc., in the city is temporary, as these items only represent part of people's economic needs. Bartering with a specific individual is much more inconvenient if exchanges are only occasional compared to a scenario where the contract is ongoing and there is an annual adjustment and settling of accounts. As city industry and commerce expanded, the use of money increased, both in small neighborhood trade and in larger transactions with distant countries; thus, the business practices of the cities became more distinct from those of rural areas.

Money loaned and borrowed in cities

5. The loan and hire of wealth in medieval cities came to be expressed as a money loan. The loan of money and of other wealth expressed in terms of money, began in the cities. The use of money and the expression of the value of things in terms of money was common there throughout the Middle Ages. Moreover, as the movable forms of wealth multiplied, the agreement to return borrowed wealth in kind became impossible in cities; the loan in terms of money became the only practicable thing. A merchant embarking on a trading expedition must have such a number and variety of goods, that he finds it both very difficult to rent them and wasteful in time to enumerate them and return them in like kind. It therefore became usual to make a loan either of the things expressed in terms of money, or of money with which to buy the things, thereby reducing to a single, simple, easily interpreted contract, the indebtedness which the borrowing of a thousand different things occasioned.

5. The loan and rental of wealth in medieval cities became expressed as a money loan. The lending of money and other forms of wealth quantified in monetary terms started in the cities. The use of money and the representation of value in terms of money were common throughout the Middle Ages. Additionally, as the types of movable wealth increased, it became impractical to return borrowed wealth in its original form in cities; loans in monetary terms became the only viable option. A merchant preparing for a trading venture needed such a wide range of goods that it was both challenging to rent them and a waste of time to itemize and return them in kind. As a result, it became standard to either loan items represented as money or to lend money to purchase the items, streamlining the borrowing process into a single, straightforward, easily understood contract instead of managing a debt composed of a thousand different items.

The medieval opposition to loans at interest

Such a contract differed not in economic purpose, but only in form and terms of obligation, from the renting of wealth. The church writers, however, got much confused in regard to the nature of money loans. They did not see that it was things which the merchant wished to borrow. They did not see that the money loan was simply a more convenient mode of transferring the use of wealth from one person to another. The moralists and lawmakers of that day said: Money is unfruitful, therefore taking interest for it is robbery. We cannot follow here the controversy as to the justice of interest on money which involved other ideas than those mentioned, but even to the present time traces of the old fallacy may be seen more or less plainly in the economic theory as well of conservative writers as of the socialistic opponents of interest. The principal sum expressed in the loan contract was called the capital sum, from caput, head, and the amount[Pg 113] paid for its use was first called usury, money for the use. How the word interest came to take its place, and the word usury came to mean excessive interest is one of the most interesting chapters in economic history. The term capital then came to be connected with city wealth, with movable forms of wealth, with things supposed to be peculiarly "the product of labor"; and interest was assumed to be connected only with this capital. The term rent on the other hand was connected especially with the use of land. The connection was a historical accident, but it has had an important influence on economic theory.

Such a contract wasn’t different in economic purpose, just in its form and obligations, from renting assets. Church writers, however, got really confused about the nature of money loans. They missed the fact that it was things the merchant wanted to borrow. They didn’t realize that a money loan was simply a more convenient way to transfer the use of wealth from one person to another. The moralists and lawmakers of that time argued: Money doesn’t generate profit, so charging interest on it is theft. We can't dive into the debate about the justice of interest on money that involved other ideas beyond those mentioned, but even today, traces of that old misconception can be seen, to varying degrees, in the economic theories of both conservative writers and the socialistic critics of interest. The principal sum stated in the loan contract was called the capital sum, from caput, meaning head, and the amount[Pg 113] paid for its use was originally referred to as usury, or money for use. How the word interest took over and usury came to mean excessive interest is one of the most fascinating stories in economic history. The term capital then became associated with urban wealth, movable assets, and things thought to be specifically "the product of labor"; and interest was assumed to be linked only to this capital. On the other hand, the term rent was especially associated with the use of land. This connection was a historical accident, but it has had a significant impact on economic theory.

Rivalry of the commercial and landholding classes in Europe

6. The owners of city wealth and of country landed estates often were opposed as well in social and political as in economic affairs. The practical economic questions of the Middle Ages and the practical political questions largely turned on these two groups of interests. The men of wealth in the cities, the merchants and manufacturers, often were found opposed to the landed aristocracy. This social division between the commercial and agricultural classes doubtless helped to strengthen the prejudgment as to the nature of the two kinds of wealth. Indeed, in view of the situation, it may have been in a measure justifiable and expedient to contrast the thought of city wealth, which has come to be called capital, with that of landed wealth. But even if it were, it is now misleading and erroneous to continue the use of such concepts in a new country and in our modern conditions.

6. The owners of city wealth and country estates were often opposed not just in economics but also in social and political matters. The key economic and political issues of the Middle Ages largely revolved around these two groups of interests. Wealthy city dwellers, such as merchants and manufacturers, frequently found themselves at odds with the landed aristocracy. This social divide between commercial and agricultural classes likely reinforced preconceived notions about the nature of the two types of wealth. In light of the situation, it might have been somewhat justifiable and practical to distinguish between city wealth, now known as capital, and landed wealth. However, even if that were true, it is now misleading and incorrect to keep using such concepts in a new country and under our modern circumstances.

Land continues to be rented while city wealth is borrowed in money form

Indeed, for centuries the sharper features of the contrast have been steadily softened. The money economy of the city gradually spread to the rural districts, but never entirely displaced barter, which lingers everywhere. Important steps toward a money economy were the commuting of forced or customary labor of the serfs into a money payment to the lord, and at the same time the substitution of money payments for payments in kind (use of lands, specified goods, etc.) to the peasants. Thus arose a free peasant[Pg 114] class receiving wages. But land continued to be rented and landed estates to be hereditary throughout Europe. As they did not pass from hand to hand as a commercial or marketable form of wealth, their value was rarely, if ever, expressed in terms of money and as a ratio to the rent they bore. The result was the fixing of the erroneous idea that agricultural wealth is essentially different in the character of its service and yield from wealth used in manufactures. One phase of the error was the idea held by the physiocratic writers and by Adam Smith that in agriculture "nature labors along with man," while in manufacture "nature does nothing, man does all." This view was corrected by later critics (Buchanan, Ricardo, and others), but the main portion of the fallacy persisted in the supposed contrast between the characters of the services performed by natural resources and by artificially produced wealth.

For centuries, the differences have gradually become less pronounced. The money economy of the city slowly made its way into rural areas, yet barter never completely disappeared and is still present everywhere. Key developments towards a money economy included converting forced or customary labor of the serfs into cash payments to the lord, while simultaneously replacing payments in kind (like land use and specific goods) to the peasants with money payments. This led to the emergence of a free peasant[Pg 114] class earning wages. However, land continued to be rented, and land estates remained hereditary throughout Europe. Since they didn't transfer ownership as a commercial or marketable asset, their value was seldom expressed in monetary terms or relative to the rent they produced. This led to the mistaken belief that agricultural wealth is fundamentally different in its service and yield compared to wealth from manufacturing. One aspect of this misconception was held by physiocratic writers and Adam Smith, who claimed that in agriculture, "nature works alongside man," whereas in manufacturing, "nature does nothing; man does everything." Later critics (such as Buchanan, Ricardo, and others) corrected this perspective, but much of the fallacy continued in the assumed differences between the roles of natural resources and artificially produced wealth.

§ II. THE CONCEPT OF CAPITAL IN MODERN BUSINESS

Extension of the use of the money loan and of the capital concept

1. The development of the use of money and credit has led to the expression of the value of all indirect agents, without distinction, in terms of money. This is a capitalistic age. The development of a class of money-lenders has led to a transfer of all sorts of wealth from owners to users by means of money. As in medieval Europe city wealth was bought and sold, and measured and expressed, so in twentieth century America are the farm, the waterfall, and the mine. Every purchase with money owned or borrowed is to-day called an investment of capital. To invest means to clothe, and an investment of capital is clothing money in any kind of wealth, whether it be a ship, a factory, or a farm.

1. The rise of money and credit has resulted in the valuation of all indirect contributors, without exception, in monetary terms. We live in a capitalist era. The emergence of a class of moneylenders has facilitated the transfer of various forms of wealth from owners to users through money. Just as city wealth was bought, sold, measured, and quantified in medieval Europe, so too are farms, waterfalls, and mines in twentieth-century America. Nowadays, every purchase made with money, whether owned or borrowed, is referred to as a capital investment. To invest means to put something into use, and a capital investment involves putting money into any form of wealth, be it a ship, a factory, or a farm.

Interest on money is the contractual form in which more and more the use of wealth is paid for. The borrower does not ask the wealthy man to buy for him a factory and to rent it to him. It is not impossible for the transaction to take that form; but in practice it is inconvenient. The capital[Pg 115] concept, the expression of wealth in the form of money, spreads over almost the whole face of the economic world. In promissory notes, mortgages, capital stock, bonds, and many other forms, are expressed the obligations of borrowers bound to pay regularly a sum called interest for the use of the multifarious wealth they have chosen to employ.

Interest on money is the agreed-upon way more and more people pay for using wealth. The borrower doesn’t ask the wealthy person to buy a factory for them and then rent it out. While that type of transaction could happen, it’s usually not practical. The concept of capital[Pg 115], which represents wealth in the form of money, is widespread across the economic landscape. In promissory notes, mortgages, capital stocks, bonds, and various other forms, borrowers’ obligations are detailed, requiring them to regularly pay a sum known as interest for the use of the diverse wealth they have decided to utilize.

Definition of capital

2. Capital to-day may be defined as economic wealth expressed in terms of the general unit of value. In economic discussion new conditions must be recognized and an attempt made to adapt definitions to the language and needs of practical life. By this definition, capital, at any given moment of time, includes all economic goods in existence, when they are thought of in terms of their value. But things have different durations, some are parts of the capital of the world only for an instant, others for a week, a month, or years. Most capital is composed of things durable in a large degree.

2. Capital today can be defined as economic wealth expressed in terms of the general unit of value. In economic discussions, we need to recognize new conditions and try to adapt definitions to the language and needs of practical life. This definition means that, at any given moment, capital includes all economic goods that exist when we consider their value. However, items have different lifespans; some are part of the world's capital for just an instant, while others last for a week, a month, or even years. Most capital consists of durable items to a significant extent.

It has been seen above that there is no reason for keeping things unless they will increase in value, that is, unless a rental is logically attributable to them. Everything kept for a day, a month, a year, is kept because thus it will continually give off uses or by accumulating them it will become more useful. Hence, when interest is defined as the payment for the use of capital, it is connected with all wealth that is expressed in the capital form. In practical business and in theoretical discussion this is the idea of capital that alone can be consistently followed. Capital is the value equivalent of a sum of money "invested," "clothed" in forms of wealth purchased and exchanged. Wealth has become fluid in modern times; it was crystallized in medieval times. Under the new conditions, wealth, expressed in the mobile form of capital, flows into the most distant corners of the industrial world.

It has been shown previously that there's no reason to hold onto things unless they will increase in value—meaning unless there's a logical rental value tied to them. Anything kept for a day, a month, or a year is retained because it continuously provides benefits, or by accumulating them, it becomes more useful. Therefore, when we define interest as the payment for using capital, it relates to all wealth expressed in capital form. In both practical business and theoretical discussions, this is the concept of capital that can be consistently applied. Capital represents the value equivalent of a sum of money "invested," "embodied" in forms of wealth that are bought and sold. Wealth has become more fluid in modern times; it was more rigid during medieval times. Under the new conditions, wealth, in the flexible form of capital, flows into the farthest reaches of the industrial world.

Distinction between money and capital

3. Capital must not be identified with money although it is expressed in terms of money. While money and capital are not identical, neither are they opposite or mutually contradictory.[Pg 116] Money is but one species of the genus capital. It is a particularly durable form when industry as a whole is considered, a particularly fleeting form in the individual's possession, and a particularly important, though not necessarily the most important, form in its social significance. The things composing capital are concrete things, scarce forms of wealth, some of which are yielding gratification at the present moment, or are destined to do so at some future moment; others of which are not themselves giving direct gratification, but are indirect agents for the gratifying of wants. To this latter group belongs money.

3. Capital shouldn't be confused with money, even though it's expressed in monetary terms. While money and capital are not the same, they're also not opposites or contradict each other.[Pg 116] Money is just one type of capital. It’s a particularly stable form when looking at the whole industry, a temporary form in a person's hands, and a significant, though not necessarily the most critical, form in its social context. The components of capital are tangible items, limited forms of wealth, some of which provide immediate satisfaction or are intended to do so in the future; others may not provide direct satisfaction but serve as means to fulfill wants. Money belongs to this latter group.

The caution contained in this proposition may appear to some to be superfluous, but it is most needed. The mind is so prone to identify things that are expressed currently by the same words. The ease with which money and capital are thus confused has led to various popular fallacies on practical economic questions.

The caution in this statement might seem unnecessary to some, but it's very important. The mind has a tendency to confuse things that are described using the same words. The way money and capital are often mixed up has resulted in several common misunderstandings about practical economic issues.

Contractual interest and rent involve a difference of business procedure

4. Renting wealth and borrowing capital have the same economic purpose, but the capital contract presents certain peculiar features. In the interest contract for the loan of capital the interest always is and must be expressed in money; the capital sum must be expressed as value; and the interest rate expresses the relation between these two values. In each of these features the interest contract is in contrast with the renting contract. While the rent itself may or may not be expressed in terms of money, the value of the rented wealth is not so expressed, and there is no rent-rate expressing the relation between the two values.

4. Renting wealth and borrowing capital serve the same economic purpose, but the capital contract has some unique characteristics. In a loan agreement for capital, the interest must always be stated in money; the total capital amount must be represented as a value; and the interest rate shows the relationship between these two values. Each of these aspects makes the interest contract different from the renting contract. While the rent can be expressed in money or not, the value of the rented wealth isn’t expressed in the same way, and there is no rent rate that shows the relationship between the two values.

The wealth concept and the capital concept contrasted

As here presented, the essence of the capital concept is in the mode or form of expression of wealth, not in the physical nature, the origin of its value, or any peculiarity in the kind of wealth; the content of the concept is limited only by man's thought of wealth, every good becoming capital when it is capitalized, that is, when the totality of its uses is expressed as a present sum of values. The difference between the wealth concept and the capital concept is therefore subjective,[Pg 117] not objective; it is a difference in the mode of man's thought regarding wealth. The rent contract and the interest contract are modes of borrowing and lending which reflect this difference of conception. In their effort to express more exactly to themselves and to others the relative felt importance of their environment, men take in turn different points of view, and use different modes of expression. The most developed and exact of these devices for the social expression of valuations, which became possible only with a money economy and widened markets, is the capital concept, whose nature has been analyzed here.

As presented here, the core idea of capital is not about the physical nature, origin of value, or any specific type of wealth, but rather in how wealth is expressed. The concept only limits itself to human thoughts about wealth; anything can become capital once it is capitalized, meaning when all its uses are represented as a current total value. The distinction between wealth and capital is therefore subjective, not objective; it reflects different ways people think about wealth. Rental agreements and interest contracts are ways of borrowing and lending that highlight this difference in understanding. To better articulate the relative importance of their surroundings, people adopt various perspectives and use different expressions. The most developed and precise way to express social valuations, which became feasible only with a money economy and expanded markets, is the capital concept discussed here.

The capital concept now prevalent

Summarizing the thought of this chapter, it may be said that the capital concept has gradually developed with industry, and is now the most widely prevailing mode of expressing the quantity of wealth. It is used in the discussion of all the most important problems of modern industry. The questions of income from wealth, of trusts and corporations, nearly all that is most notable in the development of modern industry, require the use of the capital concept. Yet (returning to the thought with which this chapter started) in many of the outlying districts other modes of looking upon wealth are employed. References to modern industry must be understood usually as applying to the most developed capitalistic conditions.

Summarizing the ideas in this chapter, we can say that the concept of capital has gradually evolved alongside industry and is now the most common way to express the amount of wealth. It's used in discussing all the key issues in modern industry. Topics like income from wealth, trusts, and corporations—almost everything notable in the growth of modern industry—require the concept of capital. However, going back to the initial thought of this chapter, in many remote areas, different ways of viewing wealth are still in use. References to modern industry typically refer to the most advanced capitalist conditions.


CHAPTER 15

THE CAPITALIZATION OF ALL FORMS OF RENT

§ I. THE PURCHASE OF RENT-CHARGES AS AN EXAMPLE OF CAPITALIZATION

The nature and sale of rent-charges

1. From the twelfth to the sixteenth centuries the sale and purchase of rent-charges was the most general form of borrowing and lending wealth. A rent-charge in the Middle Ages was a definite income that was to be paid out of the rents of an estate, business house, manor, etc. The property was said to be "charged" with the payment of that income, and some estates were passed on for generations from father to son charged with a certain rent. It was thus possible for the owner of money to buy a rent-charge, either one that had been created a generation before, or a new one created by some landowner for the especial purpose of borrowing money to go on a crusade or of improving his estate or of investing in other business. The transaction took this form: the purchaser of the rent-charge paid a sum of money, called the capital sum, and obtained in return a rent-paper entitling him to receive permanently a given income. The house or land was security for the debt. The seller gave up the right to the rent as it came in year by year, and received in return a capital sum in hand. Generally he had the right to repay the sum whenever he wished and thus extinguish the rent-charge. Logically viewed, the purchaser bought an equitable part of the income, therefore an equitable part of that rent-bearing wealth. In effect it was just like a loan except that the purchaser of the rent-charge[Pg 119] could not demand the repayment of his money. He could, however, sell the rent-charge when he wished to get his capital out. Gradually it became usual to sell and transfer rent-papers just as is done to-day with mortgages and bonds. Rent-papers thus came in the fifteenth century to be negotiable paper in somewhat general use. There was a rise and fall of the value of the rent-paper with changes in the demand for investment in rent-charges or with changes in the security.

1. From the twelfth to the sixteenth centuries, buying and selling rent-charges was the most common way to borrow and lend money. A rent-charge in the Middle Ages was a specific income to be paid from the rents of a property, business, manor, etc. The property was considered "charged" with making that payment, and some properties were handed down from father to son with a set rent attached. This allowed money owners to buy a rent-charge, either one that had been established a generation earlier or a new one created by a landowner specifically to borrow money for a crusade, improving their estate, or investing in another business. The process involved the buyer paying a sum of money, called the capital sum, in exchange for a rent-paper that entitled them to receive a fixed income indefinitely. The property served as collateral for the debt. The seller gave up their right to receive the rent as it came in each year, getting a capital sum in return. Typically, they had the option to repay the sum whenever they chose, thereby ending the rent-charge. From a logical standpoint, the buyer purchased an equitable share of the income, and therefore an equitable share of that income-generating wealth. In practice, it functioned similarly to a loan, except that the buyer of the rent-charge[Pg 119] could not demand repayment. However, they could sell the rent-charge whenever they wanted to recover their capital. Over time, it became common to buy and transfer rent-papers similarly to how mortgages and bonds are handled today. By the fifteenth century, rent-papers became negotiable instruments that were used frequently. The value of the rent-paper fluctuated with changes in demand for investment in rent-charges or shifts in security.

Rent-charges were a convenient investment in medieval cities

2. The sale of rent-charges grew out of an industrial need of the exchange of safe permanent incomes for larger sums of wealth. The custom of the purchase of rent-charges grew up in the cities. The increasing wealth of cities, the growth of commerce and enterprise, caused rent-charges to be sold by the owners of houses and real estate in the cities, and the custom spread to the country. It is an instance of the way income became more fluid in the cities during the Middle Ages. This kind of loan contrasted strikingly in the Middle Ages with those loans made commonly by reckless kings, prodigal nobles, and distressed peasants to secure consumption goods. Merchants needed large amounts of wealth for their growing enterprises, and they felt that if they could get a capital sum down they could make it earn more than the rent-charge. A perpetual income of one hundred units was therefore exchanged for a sum at the moment of twenty or twenty-five times that amount. As the wealth of the cities increased, there were some men who wished to retire from active business, and there were widows and children with property which they could not manage directly. Such persons either could not afford to take the risks of active business, or could not judge of them, and they formed a class of lenders or investors seeking some safe income. Between the two classes of active merchants and capitalist lenders, each of whom saw his own advantage and followed it, the practice of buying and selling rent-charges thus grew up.

2. The sale of rent charges emerged from an industrial need to exchange reliable, steady incomes for larger sums of wealth. The practice of buying rent charges developed in the cities. As cities became wealthier, fueled by increased commerce and entrepreneurship, property owners began selling rent charges on houses and real estate, and this practice spread to rural areas. This illustrates how income became more flexible in cities during the Middle Ages. This type of loan was quite different from those typically taken by reckless kings, extravagant nobles, and struggling peasants to secure consumable goods. Merchants needed significant amounts of capital for their growing businesses, believing that if they could obtain a lump sum, they could generate more income than the rent charge. Consequently, a perpetual income of one hundred units was exchanged for a one-time payment of twenty or twenty-five times that amount. As cities grew richer, some individuals wanted to step away from active business, and there were widows and children with assets they couldn’t manage directly. These individuals either couldn’t afford the risks of active business or weren’t able to assess them, forming a group of lenders or investors in search of safe income. The practice of buying and selling rent charges developed between these two groups: active merchants and capitalist lenders, each pursuing their own interests.

Rent-charges were not forbidden by the church

The practice was allowed by the church, though interest and the lending of money were forbidden. The loan was substantially a loan of capital and the rent-charge was substantially interest, but in the eyes of the church moralists there was a marked difference, in that the obligation to the purchaser of the rent-charge was secured by a permanent and substantial form of wealth, and the contract usually was favorable to the borrowers. In its origin the practice was not merely an evasion of the law against usury, but a convenient form of contract. It doubtless came, however, to be used as a means of evading the law of the church against usury, and thus became an entering wedge for the general use of money loans.

The church permitted the practice, even though charging interest and lending money were forbidden. The loan was essentially a loan of capital, and the rent-charge was essentially interest. However, church moralists saw a clear distinction since the obligation for the buyer of the rent-charge was backed by a permanent and substantial asset, and the contract was typically beneficial to the borrowers. Initially, the practice wasn't just a loophole around the law against usury, but a practical form of agreement. Yet, it likely evolved into a way to circumvent the church's usury laws, thereby paving the way for the broader acceptance of money loans.

The market value of rent-charges reflects the exchange ratio between present and future money incomes

3. Rent-charges had a market-value, varying with time and place, and expressed as a number of years' purchase of the rent-charge. The sellers of rent-charges were influenced by many motives: a lord wished to build a castle, or go on a crusade; a farmer wished to improve his estate; a merchant wished to embark on larger ventures. Opportunities thus opened in the cities for men of wealth to get a fixed income for a payment of ready money. In the cities, the buyers seeking a fixed income would bid down, or bid up, the value of the rent-charges, which thus came to have a quotable market value. In time, greater and greater amounts were paid by the investors in return for the guarantee of a given income. In rural districts the value of the charges was low, that is, the capital sum was but ten or twelve times the value of the annual rent-charge; while in the cities it rose to twenty and even twenty-five times the annual rent-charge.

3. Rent charges had a market value that changed with time and location, typically expressed as a multiple of years' worth of the rent charge. Sellers of rent charges had various reasons: a lord might want to build a castle or go on a crusade; a farmer might want to improve his land; a merchant might seek to invest in bigger opportunities. This created chances in the cities for wealthy individuals to secure a steady income in exchange for a lump sum. In urban areas, buyers looking for fixed income would lower or raise the price of rent charges, giving them a market value that could be quoted. Over time, investors paid increasingly higher amounts in exchange for the assurance of a specific income. In rural areas, the value of the charges was lower, meaning the capital amount was only ten to twelve times the annual rent charge, while in cities it could rise to twenty or even twenty-five times the annual rent charge.

A memento of this practice, probably, is the manner in which the price paid for land is spoken of still in England and the continental countries in a phrase quite unfamiliar to American ears, as a certain number of "years' purchase." If an estate is sold for twenty times the annual net rental it is said to be sold at twenty "years' purchase." This does not mean that the rental for twenty years only[Pg 121] is sold, but that the rental in perpetuity is sold for twenty times the annual rent; that is, the land is sold outright for twenty years' rent paid at once. The estate is looked upon primarily as yielding a fixed income; the value of the permanent possession of the estate is thought of as a certain number of times the value of the income secured. "Years' purchase" means, therefore, the length of time required for the income to amount to the purchasing price.

A reminder of this practice is how the price paid for land is still referred to in England and some European countries using a phrase that's quite unfamiliar to American ears: a certain number of "years' purchase." If a property is sold for twenty times the annual net rental, it is said to be sold at twenty "years' purchase." This doesn’t mean that the rental for just twenty years is sold, but that the rental in perpetuity is sold for twenty times the annual rent; in other words, the land is sold outright for twenty years' rent paid upfront. The property is mainly considered as providing a fixed income; the value of the permanent ownership of the estate is viewed as a certain number of times the value of the secured income. "Years' purchase" signifies the amount of time needed for the income to equal the purchasing price.

This attains the thought of the present value of the estate, or capital sum in it, though the capital sum is thought of as a multiple of the income, instead of the income being calculated as a percentage of the capital value. Now at the rate of "ten years' purchase" an investment of money in land affords an annual interest of ten per cent., as each year the rental is one tenth of the original investment; twelve years' purchase yields eight and one third per cent., twenty years' purchase, five per cent., and twenty-five years' purchase, four per cent. Increase in the number of years' purchase corresponds to a decrease in the rate of interest which the original investment of money, the capital sum, is expected to yield. This is equally true whether the investment be in the legal form of a purchase of the fee-simple of land, or in that of the purchase of a rent-charge. We are brought to this conclusion: that the present value of the rents in perpetuity, of any given wealth, is the capital value of the wealth; and that the reciprocal of the number of years' purchase is the rate of interest that an investment is expected to yield.

This reflects the idea of the current value of the estate, or the capital amount within it, though the capital amount is viewed as a multiple of the income, rather than the income being calculated as a percentage of the capital value. At a rate of "ten years' purchase," an investment in land yields an annual return of ten percent, since the yearly rent is one-tenth of the initial investment; twelve years' purchase provides eight and one-third percent, twenty years' purchase gives five percent, and twenty-five years' purchase offers four percent. An increase in the number of years' purchase leads to a decrease in the expected rate of return on the original investment, the capital amount. This holds true whether the investment is in the legal form of purchasing the fee-simple of land or in the form of buying a rent-charge. We arrive at this conclusion: that the current value of the rents in perpetuity of any given wealth is the capital value of that wealth; and that the inverse of the number of years' purchase indicates the expected rate of return on an investment.

Purchase and sale of rent-charges gives way to more modern contracts

4. The sale of rent-charges has gradually given place to the modern form of money loan. The conditions of the contract in the sale of rent-charges were gradually changed for greater convenience. When the purchaser (the lender) was given the right to require repayment of the capital sum at the end of a specified time, the transaction was brought still closer to an ordinary loan. In this form, the sale of rent-charges is still found in southern Germany, but the greater[Pg 122] simplicity of the money loan, and of the sale outright, has led to the almost total disuse of the older form of transaction.

4. The sale of rent-charges has slowly been replaced by the modern form of money loan. The contract terms in the sale of rent-charges were gradually modified for more convenience. When the buyer (the lender) was given the option to demand repayment of the principal amount at the end of a set period, the transaction became even more similar to a typical loan. This type of rent-charge sale still exists in southern Germany, but the greater[Pg 122] simplicity of money loans and outright sales has resulted in the almost complete abandonment of the older transaction method.

The purchase of rent-charges was long looked upon as a very different thing from the loan of money, but to modern eyes it is not, and the old distinctions between the moralities of the two kinds of income appear now mainly quibbles, justified in a slight degree by certain social facts of the time. The rise of industry led to different ideas on the lending of money; the prejudice against it weakened in large classes of the population, especially in Protestant countries, and its use rapidly spread. Not until 1830 did a decision of Rome remove all disapproval on the part of the church. Rent-charges are instructive now as showing the mode in which rents began to be capitalized in earlier centuries.

The buying of rent-charges used to be seen as very different from lending money, but today, it's not. The old distinctions between the morals of these two types of income now seem more like technicalities, only slightly supported by some social conditions of that time. The growth of industry brought about new views on borrowing money; the negative attitudes toward it diminished among many groups, especially in Protestant countries, and its use quickly became widespread. It wasn't until 1830 that a decision from Rome eliminated all church disapproval. Rent-charges are now insightful because they illustrate how rents started to be capitalized in earlier centuries.

§ II. CAPITALIZATION INVOLVED IN THE EVALUATING OF INDIRECT AGENTS

The capital value of durable wealth is the sum of its expected rents

1. The buying of any indirect agent is practically the purchasing of a "rent-charge." To account rationally for the market value of anything, its importance must be traced back to "gratification." We have examined and accepted the proposition that if a good is not affording enjoyment at the present moment it is kept because it will yield a rent until it is used. If it is never to afford direct enjoyment, if it is never to mature physically into the class of enjoyable goods, the explanation for its value must be found in the fact that it is capable of yielding a series of rents of enjoyable goods. In the last analysis the value of anything must be found in its power of affording psychic income, a series of psychic rents. Now when such a durable income is bought outright, what is the basis on which its value is estimated? What other than the rents it will afford? Exactly as did the purchasers of a medieval rent-charge, the buyer of the durable wealth pays a definite sum in return for the right to enjoy a series of future rents. As was the case with rent-charges,[Pg 123] however, the amount paid will be less than the full matured value of the rents. A long series, even a perpetual series, may be exchanged for no more than ten, twenty, or twenty-five annual rents. While therefore the selling value of the good is the sum of the values of the rents, it evidently is that sum discounted. Immediately, when we have reached this point in the reasoning, our proposition must suggest itself as self-evidently true in this form: the value of any good is the sum of the entire series of rents it contains, discounted, at some rate, to their present worth. What determines the rate of discount is a question that will call later for a fuller explanation.

1. Buying any indirect asset is essentially purchasing a "rent-charge." To logically determine the market value of anything, its significance must be linked to "satisfaction." We've explored and accepted the idea that if a good isn't providing enjoyment right now, it's held because it will generate income until it's used. If it will never provide direct enjoyment, if it won't eventually belong to the category of enjoyable goods, the reason for its value lies in its ability to produce a series of incomes from enjoyable goods. Ultimately, the value of anything must be found in its ability to provide psychological income, a series of psychological rents. Now, when such a lasting income is bought outright, what is the basis for its value? Is it anything other than the rents it will yield? Just like the buyers of a medieval rent-charge, the purchaser of durable wealth pays a set amount in exchange for the right to enjoy a series of future rents. However, similar to rent-charges, [Pg 123] the amount paid will be less than the full matured value of the rents. A long series, even a perpetual series, may be traded for no more than ten, twenty, or twenty-five annual rents. Therefore, while the selling value of the good is the sum of the values of the rents, it is clearly a discounted sum. As soon as we reach this point in the argument, our idea must naturally present itself as obviously true in this way: the value of any good is the sum of the entire series of rents it includes, discounted, at some rate, to their current worth. What determines the rate of discount is a topic that will require a more detailed explanation later.

Capital value is not primary

2. There are two modes of approach to the problem of interest: one from the side of income (rents); the other, from the side of the bearer (capital). The rate of interest expresses a relation between two values, the value of the income and the value of the sum loaned, whether it consists of money or of other wealth expressed in terms of money; But which of these values is primary in a study of the causes of value? Which is the base from which the other is derived by multiplying at the rate expressing their ratio? The answer to this question cannot be a matter of indifference to the economic theorist. Universally heretofore the study of interest has been approached from the side of capital. A capital sum was said to be invested and to earn a certain interest, that is, per cent., of that sum. The usage of speaking of the investment of capital as a sum given, and of "interest on capital" predisposes the mind to this view.

2. There are two ways to approach the issue of interest: one from the perspective of income (rents); the other from the perspective of the holder (capital). The interest rate represents a relationship between two values: the income value and the value of the loaned amount, whether it’s in money or other wealth measured in money. But which of these values is fundamental when studying the causes of value? Which serves as the base from which the other is calculated by multiplying at the rate that shows their ratio? The answer to this question is important for economic theorists. Traditionally, studies of interest have focused on capital. It was said that a capital amount was invested and earned a specific interest rate, that is, a percentage of that amount. The common way of referring to the investment of capital as a given sum and "interest on capital" shapes people's thinking towards this perspective.

Expected rents are primary, and capital value is the "years' purchase"

But the approach from the side of income has been shown to be in some important cases the historical origin of the rate of interest, and we need but reconsider reasoning that has gone before to see that this is the logical order in all cases. Rent, or income, is a link in the chain of value, connecting gratification or psychic income, consumption goods, rent or usufruct value, and finally capital value. To one keeping in mind the logical cause of value, it becomes[Pg 124] inconceivable that capital value could precede income, a view possible only when a fragment of the problem is seen. This being true, the mere mention of a capital sum implies the interest problem, and assumes the interest rate. The capital is of that amount because the anticipated incomes, discounted at some rate, equal that sum. The capital sum is a certain number of years' purchase of the series of rents which can be secured by the use of wealth in various industries. The owner of a number of dollars (or of an amount of other wealth expressed in dollars) has open to him various investments. The value of any wealth is due to the possibility of deriving incomes from it. If, however, the expected income fails to be realized, the capital loses its value, or it is revalued on the basis of the new rents. The investment is then said to be a losing one. Thus, at each stage in the valuation of capital, before it is invested and at every moment thereafter when the valuation is readjusted to the rents realized or expected, rents are logically primary, the source from which the capital sum is derived.

But looking at it from the perspective of income has shown, in some significant cases, to be the historical origin of interest rates, and we only need to reconsider the reasoning that has come before to realize that this is the logical order in all cases. Rent, or income, is a link in the chain of value, connecting satisfaction or psychic income, consumer goods, rent or usufruct value, and ultimately capital value. For those keeping in mind the logical cause of value, it becomes [Pg 124] unimaginable that capital value could come before income, a perspective that only arises when a part of the problem is examined. Given that this is true, simply mentioning a capital sum implies the interest problem and assumes the interest rate. The capital exists at that amount because the expected incomes, discounted at some rate, equal that sum. The capital sum represents a specific number of years' worth of rents that can be obtained by using wealth in various industries. The owner of a certain amount of dollars (or equivalent wealth expressed in dollars) has several investment options. The value of any wealth comes from the potential to earn income from it. However, if the expected income doesn't materialize, the capital loses its value, or it gets revalued based on the new rents. The investment is then described as a losing one. Therefore, at every stage of capital valuation, before it is invested and at every moment thereafter when the valuation is adjusted to actual or expected rents, rents are logically primary, being the source from which the capital sum is derived.

The rate of capitalization of rents is not fixed merely in commerce

3. The capitalization of comparatively safe permanent incomes from real estate contains within itself all the factors for the independent determination of the interest rate, and is not to be explained merely by reference to "the prevailing rate of interest" in other investments. The value of land usually is explained simply as the capitalizing of its rents at "the prevailing rate of interest." The rate is assumed to be fixed by conditions in manufacturing and commerce, and if five per cent, can be gotten there the capitalist would never buy land unless investment in it were made equally attractive. The cause of the rate thus is supposed to rest outside the transaction itself, the exchange of land for other capital seeking investment. The economic student is safe in assuming always that explanations of this sort are fallacious. The cause of value in any one exchange or any one industry is not thus to be juggled and shifted into another industry. It is true that the values of goods are so[Pg 125] wonderfully interrelated by substitution that as the price of fresh beef will affect that of salt mackerel, so the capitalization rate of machinery affects that of land; but the influence is not from one side only, it is mutual. When anything has value, it must have in itself an independent cause of value.

3. The value of relatively safe permanent incomes from real estate includes all the factors needed to independently determine the interest rate and can't just be understood by looking at "the prevailing rate of interest" in other investments. The value of land is often simply explained as the capitalization of its rents at "the prevailing rate of interest." This rate is thought to be set by conditions in manufacturing and commerce, so if five percent can be earned there, an investor wouldn't buy land unless the investment was made equally appealing. The reason for the rate is believed to be outside the transaction itself, which is the exchange of land for other capital looking for investment. The economics student can confidently assume that explanations like this are misleading. The reason for value in any one exchange or industry cannot just be transferred to another. It’s true that the values of goods are so[Pg 125] closely related through substitution that, as the price of fresh beef influences that of salt mackerel, the capitalization rate of machinery affects that of land; but the influence goes both ways, it's mutual. When something has value, it must have within it an independent cause of that value.

The exchange of any present and future rents results in a rate of time discount

It can not be otherwise in the particular problem of value called capitalization. The first task of scientific study is to state clearly the nature of the problem. In this case it is seen to be the exchange of a present sum of wealth for a series of future rents. Whenever there are income-bearers and buyers and sellers of them, there are the conditions required for the determination of the market rate at which those future incomes shall be discounted. Manufactures and commerce have no peculiar relation to this process. By a flight of scientific imagination we might assume that the stock of indirect agents in the world consisted only of natural food producers, and that this stock and its yield were absolutely unchangeable by man's will or efforts. Each man in such case would have to stand with hands tied, and take the fruits as they matured. Even in such a case there would be capitalization and a rate of discount on future rents. The fruit-tree (that is, the whole future series of fruits) would bear a certain relation to one year's yield; the field would bear a certain relation to its crop. Wherever there are buyers and sellers of more or less durable agents of it matters not what kind or origin, there are present the elements and causes for the fixing of a rate of time discount.

It can't be any different when it comes to the specific issue of value known as capitalization. The first step in scientific study is to clearly define the nature of the problem. Here, it involves the exchange of a current amount of wealth for a series of future incomes. Whenever there are income-generating assets along with buyers and sellers, the conditions necessary to determine the market rate at which those future incomes are discounted are established. Manufacturing and commerce don’t have a unique relationship with this process. By using a bit of scientific imagination, we could assume that the stock of indirect agents in the world only consisted of natural food producers, and that this stock and its yield couldn’t be changed by human actions. In that scenario, each person would have to stand still and accept the outcomes as they occurred. Nevertheless, there would still be capitalization and a rate of discount on future incomes. The fruit tree (representing the entire future yield) would be related to the yield of one season, and the field would be related to its harvest. Wherever there are buyers and sellers of more or less durable assets, regardless of their type or origin, the elements and factors necessary for establishing a time discount rate are present.

Capitalization of a perpetual uniform series of rents;

4. In practical business may be seen innumerable instances of the capitalization of both permanent and limited series of incomes. The simplest case is the capitalization of an unvarying and supposedly perpetual series of rents. Whatever the rate of time discount prevailing, rents infinitely distant become infinitesimally small when discount is compounded. The present rent is worth most, next year's less, and so on in a decreasing series.

4. In real business, there are countless examples of turning both ongoing and limited income streams into capital. The easiest case is converting a constant and supposedly endless series of rents into capital. No matter the discount rate applied over time, rents that are infinitely far in the future become negligible when discounted. The current rent has the highest value, next year's is worth less, and this pattern continues in a decreasing series.

Of a probably increasing series of rents;

But social changes alter rental values, and so far as these changes are foreseen, these anticipated or expected rents are made the basis for present capitalization. Investors and owners alike may foresee that a piece of land used only for agriculture will, within a few years, be taken up for city lots, or will be needed for a factory or as the site of a railroad station. The capitalized value would not in this case be based upon a series of uniform rents each of the amount yielded annually now, but on the progressive series expected. In some cases the physical output of an agent may decline while the price of the product increases. Modern foresters foresee that the selling price of the timber will be greater twenty-five years from now than it is to-day, and they therefore estimate the rental value of the forest on the basis of the future price, thus justifying expenditure that would be unwise if present prices were to continue.

But social changes affect rental values, and as long as these changes can be predicted, the expected rents are used to determine current capitalization. Both investors and owners may anticipate that a piece of land currently used for agriculture will soon be developed into city lots, or will be necessary for a factory or a railroad station. In this case, the capitalized value wouldn’t be based on a series of uniform rents reflecting the current annual income, but rather on the expected progressive series. Sometimes, the physical output of an asset might decrease while the price of the product goes up. Modern foresters predict that the selling price of timber will be higher twenty-five years from now than it is today, and they therefore assess the rental value of the forest based on future prices, justifying investments that would be unwise if present prices continued.

And of a declining or fluctuating series of rents

Again the expected series of incomes may be declining, as the royalties (not typical rents) secured from mines. If the income is expected steadily to fall, and to disappear at the end of the twenty-fifth year, the value of the mine would be the capitalized sum of a limited and degressive series of incomes.

Again, the anticipated series of incomes may be decreasing, like the royalties (not regular rents) obtained from mines. If the income is expected to continuously decline and vanish by the end of the twenty-fifth year, the value of the mine would be the capitalized total of a limited and decreasing series of incomes.

Mode of fixing the rate of time discount in practical business

Every exchange of a durable agent involves an estimate, rough and imperfect it may be, of that agent's future. The practical men, however, who are thus fixing the "capital value" of goods, are usually only dimly conscious of the logical nature of the process. In fact the process goes on in a way much less analytical and conscious, much more empirical, than this analysis would indicate. Most men simply buy as cheap as they can the agents which at the price they believe will add most to their income. The future changes are only roughly, not accurately estimated. The shrewd bargainer is the one who foresees more clearly than his fellows the complex changes to come. Other men blindly follow. The ability and the inability to foresee such changes make men rich and poor. In all this bidding for capital[Pg 127] the logical basis of the value is the series of rents. When the agent is bought outright, the very concluding of the bargain fixes a relation between the expected value of the income and the value of the capital invested. In other words, the exchange of durable agents virtually wraps up in them a net income, which it is expected will unfold year by year when rents mature and are secured. At the moment of the investment, the expected rents are expressed as a percentage of the capital sum.

Every transaction involving a durable asset includes an estimate, however rough and imperfect, of that asset's future. However, the practical people who determine the "capital value" of goods often have just a vague understanding of the logical process behind it. In reality, the process is much less analytical and conscious, and far more empirical than this analysis suggests. Most people simply buy the resources they believe will yield the highest returns for the lowest cost. Future changes are only estimated in a rough manner, not precisely. The savvy negotiator is the one who can better foresee the complex changes ahead, while others simply follow along. The ability or inability to anticipate such changes leads to wealth or poverty. In all this bidding for capital[Pg 127], the logical foundation of value is the series of rents. When an asset is purchased outright, the final agreement establishes a relationship between the expected income and the value of the capital invested. In other words, the exchange of durable assets essentially includes a net income that is expected to accumulate year after year as rents come due and are collected. At the time of the investment, the anticipated rents are expressed as a percentage of the total capital amount.

§ III. THE INCREASING ROLE OF CAPITALIZATION IN MODERN INDUSTRY

As exchange increases capitalization of goods becomes more usual

1. Where a system of exchange is highly developed, things are looked upon as capital yielding an objective income rather than as wealth yielding immediate means of enjoyment. In the old organization of industry most men got most of their living from the things they raised or made. At the present time goods are gotten in the most indirect ways; men seek wealth because it will yield them an objective or money income, knowing that if they can get the income, they can get other things by exchange. In business to-day, wherever there is a rental, it is capitalized, has a market value, is bought and sold. Men compete in the purchase of income-yielding agents. There is a continual contest in judgment among investors to secure the largest rent for the smallest outlay. On the other hand, the owners of any rental strive to secure the largest capitalization for it that they can. In this market for capital it is money rents that are exchanged as an indirect means of arriving at gratifications.

1. In a well-developed exchange system, things are viewed as capital that generates a steady income rather than as wealth that provides instant enjoyment. In the past, most people earned their living from what they produced or created. Nowadays, goods are obtained in more roundabout ways; people pursue wealth for the income it generates, aware that if they attain that income, they can acquire other things through trade. In today's business landscape, wherever there is rental, it is capitalized, has a market value, and is bought and sold. People compete to purchase income-generating assets. There is an ongoing competition among investors to secure the highest income for the lowest investment. Conversely, property owners aim to maximize the capitalization of their rentals. In this capital market, money rents are exchanged as a way to indirectly achieve satisfaction.

Various kinds of corporation securities put expected incomes in salable form

2. The issue of capital stock is the putting of the incomes of wealth into marketable form. Stock companies, or corporations, are business enterprises which issue stock, or certificates of a share in their wealth and income. Doubtless the convenience of the sale and transfer of invested capital[Pg 128] by the use of stock, has been one of several reasons for the large increase of this form of organization during the past century. Originally the stock of a company taken collectively represented all the capital invested, and each share entitled the owner to a given portion of the total income earned. The shares were issued in regular denominations in terms of money, and this amount expressed on the face of the stock remained fixed. But as a business proves more or less profitable, the value of a share of its income rises and falls regardless of the original amount of stock issued. At once there is a divergence between the nominal or face value and the market value of the stock. The nominal value is relatively permanent, the same year after year; it may increase by further issues, but rarely is it decreased. But when stock is the only form of claim on the earnings that is issued, the fluctuations of the market value of the stock record the real value of the business, that is, the capital value of the rents it is expected to yield. But in present practice there are several forms (of which stock is but one) in which an investor may buy a share in the earnings of a business. Bonds usually do not give their owner a vote in the management or make him in the technical legal sense a part owner in the business. Bonds representing money loaned to a company, and entitling their holder to regular interest payments, are nearest in form to the medieval rent-charge. Next stands preferred stock, which entitles the owners to share first in the dividends, if there are any; and finally the common stock, which gets a share only when the other claims are satisfied. By the multiplication and further variation of these readily salable claims on industrial incomes, the needs and desires of investors are met more fully and with greater precision.

2. The issue of capital stock is turning the incomes of wealth into something that can be sold on the market. Stock companies, or corporations, are business entities that issue stock, or certificates representing a share in their wealth and income. Definitely, the convenience of buying and selling invested capital[Pg 128] through stock has been one of the main reasons for the significant rise in this type of organization over the past century. Initially, the stock of a company collectively represented all the capital invested, and each share gave the owner a specific portion of the total income earned. The shares were issued in standard denominations in monetary terms, and this amount shown on the face of the stock stayed the same. However, as a business proves to be more or less profitable, the value of a share of its income fluctuates independent of the original amount of stock issued. This leads to a difference between the nominal or face value and the market value of the stock. The nominal value tends to be rather stable, the same year after year; it may increase with additional issues, but it’s rarely decreased. Yet, when stock is the only type of claim on the earnings that is issued, the changes in the market value of the stock reflect the actual value of the business, which is the capital value of the income it is expected to generate. Nowadays, there are various forms (of which stock is just one) through which an investor can buy a share in a business's earnings. Bonds typically do not give their owners a say in management nor make them technically part owners of the business. Bonds represent money loaned to a company and entitle their holders to regular interest payments; they are closest in nature to the medieval rent-charge. Next is preferred stock, which gives owners the first shot at dividends when there are any; and finally, common stock, which receives a share only after the other claims are settled. By increasing the variety of these easily tradable claims on industrial incomes, the needs and wants of investors are met more thoroughly and with greater precision.

Any continuing income can be capitalized

3. Men seek to convert into marketable capital any increase of income in their wealth or business. A man who invests a given capital sum in machines, buildings, and materials buys them, as others do, at prices that represent their[Pg 129] usual, or market, earning power. If he succeeds exceptionally in his business, he makes the capital earn more than the rents on which it was capitalized. The same material wealth becomes worth more because of the reputation of his products, and therefore the trade-mark and good-will of the business can be capitalized. In this sense a good name can be sold, and is at least as much to be desired, even in a mercenary age, as great riches. Likewise, social changes, new needs, the growth of population, increase the net income of wealth, or the rents of a business. The basis of capital value is income, and whatever be its cause, political or economic, material income can and will be capitalized and added to the market value of the privilege, wealth, or industry on which the income is conditioned.

3. People aim to turn any increase in their wealth or business income into profitable capital. When someone invests a certain amount of money in machines, buildings, and materials, they buy them, like everyone else, at prices that reflect their[Pg 129] typical, or market, earning potential. If they excel in their business, they can make that investment yield more than the returns it was based on. The same assets gain value due to the reputation of their products, and thus the trademark and goodwill of the business can be capitalized. In this way, a good reputation can be monetized and is at least as valuable, even in a profit-driven world, as great wealth. Similarly, social changes, emerging needs, and population growth increase the net income from wealth or business rents. The foundation of capital value is income, and regardless of whether it’s due to political or economic factors, material income can and will be capitalized, contributing to the market value of the privilege, wealth, or industry it is linked to.

The capitalizing of franchises for public-service corporations

Notable cases of this sort arise in connection with public franchises. If a street-railway or a gas-company is given the exclusive right to operate in a given locality, any income above average interest on the investment is capitalized either in the higher price of the stock or in additional stock issued without the addition of any material to the plant. If the franchise is unlimited, the income may be capitalized as practically perpetual; if the franchise is limited, and is to expire in thirty or forty years, only the limited series of privileged incomes can ordinarily be capitalized. When, however, the managers are able to exert influence enough to have the franchise extended, and the investors believe in the skill of the managers and perhaps in their power to bribe the legislators, the value of the stock continues higher than it could usually be under a limited franchise. Such circumstances becloud the question whether the exceptional income arising under the franchise should go to the public or to the company. Granted, however, that the company is entitled to the income, the burden of proof is on those who object to the capitalizing of the income as is done in every other business.

Notable cases like this come up with public franchises. If a street railway or a gas company is given the exclusive right to operate in a specific area, any income above the average interest on the investment is reflected either in a higher stock price or in additional stock issued without increasing the plant's assets. If the franchise is unlimited, the income can be valued as practically perpetual; if it’s limited and set to expire in thirty or forty years, only the limited series of allowed incomes can typically be capitalized. However, if the managers can influence an extension of the franchise and the investors trust the managers’ skills and possibly their ability to persuade legislators, the stock's value remains higher than it typically would be with a limited franchise. These situations cloud the issue of whether the extra income from the franchise should go to the public or the company. However, assuming the company is entitled to the income, it’s up to those who oppose capitalizing the income to provide proof, as is customary in every other business.

Some difficulties in the capitalization of corporate incomes

4. The manipulation of dividends and the resulting[Pg 130] changes in capitalization open up great opportunities for the dishonest increase of private fortunes. A great change in the market value of stock is made by a comparatively small change in the income it regularly affords, for if the prevailing rate of interest on money loans is five per cent., each dollar of dividends is capitalized at $20. It might seem that the dividend would be declared if earned, otherwise not. The matter is not so simple and impersonal, however. The control of corporations is vested in the hands of a small group of directors who have both the opportunity and the temptation to withhold dividends when they are earned, to pay them with borrowed money if unearned, and in either case to keep the stockholders and the public in ignorance of the real condition and earning power of the business. The stocks can, by this manipulation of dividends, be made a lottery for the legitimate investor, a trap for the unwary, and a source of unrighteous gain by men recreant to their trusts.

4. The way dividends are manipulated and the resulting[Pg 130] changes in capitalization create significant chances for dishonest people to increase their wealth. A minor shift in the regular income can drastically impact the market value of stocks; for instance, if the typical interest rate on loans is five percent, each dollar of dividends is valued at $20. It might seem logical that dividends would only be declared if they were earned, but it’s not that straightforward. The control of corporations lies with a small group of directors who have both the power and the temptation to withhold dividends when they should be paid, use borrowed money to pay dividends that aren't earned, and keep both shareholders and the public unaware of the actual financial situation and profitability of the business. Through this manipulation of dividends, stocks can turn into a gamble for legitimate investors, a trap for the unsuspecting, and a source of unfair profit for those who betray their responsibilities.

In this way it may be seen that an earning power not known to bidders in the market does not enter into capitalization; a fictitious earning power, however, is capitalized so long as the investors continue to be deceived. Instances of this kind present problems not only of private morality, but of the preservation of free industrial institutions. The solution of these problems would perhaps be hastened if the a economic nature of capitalization were more clearly understood. Capital value in modern industry is everywhere the expression of the serial rents of wealth, discounted at a prevailing rate of time discount.

In this way, it can be seen that earning potential unknown to bidders in the market doesn't factor into capitalization; however, a falsely represented earning potential is still capitalized as long as investors remain misled. Such situations create challenges not only regarding personal ethics but also concerning the sustainability of free industrial systems. Understanding the economic nature of capitalization more clearly might expedite the resolution of these issues. In today’s industry, capital value is essentially the reflection of the ongoing rents of wealth, adjusted at the current discount rate.


CHAPTER 16

INTEREST ON MONEY LOANS

§ I. VARIOUS FORMS OF CONTRACT INTEREST

Distinction between contract interest and time-value

1. Interest, the amount paid according to contract by one person to another for credit given in terms of money, is but one expression of a larger problem, that of the difference in present worth of goods at two periods of time. This larger problem appears under several forms: first, as a difference in value, due to time, where there is no money expression (to be considered in the following chapter); second, in discount on a money loan for a short, definite time; third, in a long-time money loan at a fixed rate of interest; fourth, in a credit loan—that is, the sale of the thing on credit in terms of money.

1. Interest, the amount one person pays another for borrowing money, is just one aspect of a bigger issue: the difference in the current value of goods at two different times. This bigger issue comes in several forms: first, as a change in value over time, with no money involved (which will be discussed in the following chapter); second, as a discount on a short-term money loan; third, as a long-term money loan at a fixed interest rate; and fourth, as a credit loan—which is basically the sale of an item on credit in monetary terms.

The last three cases involve interest more or less clearly. Time-discount, as will be more fully explained, is the basis of interest. The interest may be greater or less than the time-discount in the goods, owing to miscalculation on the part of the borrower or to an unforeseen change in the conditions. Men bid for the use of wealth with the intention of repaying it at some future time, and the interest they agree to pay is based on their estimate of the discount of future rents, which they think is involved in the present valuations of the goods. Time-discount is involved in goods, however, in numberless cases where there is no contract interest. Even a Robinson Crusoe must recognize in his consumption goods and in his various indirect agents differences in value at different periods of time, of which he must take account.

The last three cases clearly relate to interest. Time-discount, which will be explained in more detail later, is the foundation of interest. The interest can be either higher or lower than the time-discount on the goods due to a borrower’s miscalculation or an unexpected change in circumstances. People compete for the use of wealth with the intention of paying it back at a future time, and the interest they agree to pay is based on their assessment of the discount of future rents, which they believe is reflected in the current valuations of the goods. Time-discount affects goods in countless situations where there is no contractual interest. Even a Robinson Crusoe must recognize the differing values of his consumption goods and various indirect agents at different times, which he must account for.

Risk and expenses to the money-lender

2. Gross interest must be distinguished from net interest. The forms of wealth yielding incomes are so mutable, and are used under such complicated conditions, that both in theoretical discussion and in practice much care is needed to distinguish between the yield attributable to the income-bearer, and that attributable to other wealth or services used in connection with it. That the sum paid as interest on a loan contains other elements is recognized constantly in practice. As in the case of contract-rent allowance must be made for repairs and depreciation, so in the case of contract-interest allowance must be made for risk, or the average loss occurring in the industry. Money loaned in hazardous ventures must yield a higher rate of interest. Likewise capital used by the owner in a hazardous venture must frequently earn very high returns (not all logically interest) to offset the losses that are likely to occur.

2. Gross interest must be distinguished from net interest. The types of wealth that generate income are so changeable and are utilized under such complex conditions that in both theoretical discussions and real-world applications, it's important to carefully differentiate between the income that can be attributed to the income-generating asset and that which is connected to other assets or services used alongside it. It's commonly acknowledged in practice that the total amount paid as interest on a loan includes other factors. Just like with rental agreements, where adjustments are made for maintenance and depreciation, with interest payments, adjustments need to be made for risk or the average losses that happen in the industry. Money lent for risky ventures must provide a higher rate of interest. Similarly, capital that the owner invests in a risky project often needs to generate very high returns (not all of which can be directly classified as interest) to make up for the potential losses that might happen.

The lender must also, in estimating net interest, count the cost of placing, supervising, and collecting the loan. A pawnbroker lends only small sums and spends much time and effort to keep at interest a moderate capital. Five thousand dollars loaned in sums averaging ten dollars represents five hundred transactions, and yet if placed at five per cent, it yields but two hundred and fifty dollars a year. While, therefore, the borrower of a small sum estimates the economic interest (or anticipated gain in income) even higher than the oppressively high contract-interest he may be forced to pay, the lender must credit a large part of the gross interest to the labor he expends in carrying on the business.

The lender also needs to factor in the costs of issuing, managing, and collecting the loan when calculating net interest. A pawnbroker typically lends small amounts and invests a lot of time and effort to maintain a moderate amount of capital. For instance, lending five thousand dollars in average amounts of ten dollars involves five hundred transactions, yet at a five percent interest rate, it only generates two hundred and fifty dollars a year. Therefore, while a borrower of a small amount might view the economic interest (or expected increase in income) as even higher than the excessively high contract interest they have to pay, the lender has to attribute a significant portion of the gross interest to the work they put into running the business.

Short-time loans by discounting of commercial paper

3. The most usual form of short-time loan is that made by a bank or broker to business men on security of commercial paper. By commercial paper is meant promissory notes given by customers of the merchants, bills of lading for goods that have been shipped to their customers, and various other evidences of indebtedness that may be offered the banks for discount. When goods have been sold on time (as thirty, sixty, or ninety days) the seller has the[Pg 133] choice between letting the time expire and collecting the bills direct from the customers, and discounting the bills for ready money at the bank. According to the conditions and needs of the particular business, either method may be chosen. In most industries there is need for larger capital at the seasons when the product is put upon the market. The merchant or manufacturer plans his business in the expectation of an average rate of discount at such times, and if it chances that the discount rates are abnormally high, he has no choice but to go on borrowing and paying the high interest out of the expected profits of his business. This risk of a change in the interest rate is one of many chances he has to run.

3. The most common type of short-term loan is provided by a bank or broker to business owners based on commercial paper. Commercial paper refers to promissory notes from the customers of the merchants, bills of lading for goods that have been shipped, and various other forms of debt that banks may discount. When goods are sold on terms (like thirty, sixty, or ninety days), the seller has the[Pg 133] option of either waiting for the period to end and collecting payments directly from customers, or discounting the bills at the bank for immediate cash. Depending on the specific business's needs and conditions, either approach may be taken. In many industries, there is a demand for more capital during the times when products are launched in the market. The merchant or manufacturer organizes their business expecting an average discount rate during those periods, and if discount rates happen to be unusually high, they have no choice but to continue borrowing and paying the elevated interest from the anticipated profits of their business. This variability in interest rates is just one of many risks they have to navigate.

Long-time loans by purchase of mortgages, bonds, and stocks

4. Most debts in modern times are outstanding for a term of years and represent the lender's purchase of a claim on the earnings of some productive enterprise. The simplest forms of long-time loans are those made on the security of real estate, which is mortgaged to the lender for the term of the debt. Usually the debtor is obliged to pay the interest either annually or semi-annually, and often, but not always, is permitted to reduce the principal by partial payments. These real-estate mortgages rest on the security of the particular mortgaged wealth, and, unlike most short-time loans in bank, are not personal obligations resting on the general credit of the borrower. Most other long-time debts share this character of being non-personal; if payment is defaulted, only the particular wealth can be sold for payment, not the general wealth of the borrower. Corporation bonds, issued by railroads and other large stock companies, have increased greatly in number in recent years. They yield an income fixed in advance, and are secured usually by mortgage on the entire property of the corporation issuing them. The income of some special kinds of "preferred stocks" is so guaranteed as to make them for investors substantially the same as bonds. Another large class of long-time loans are those made by national, state, and local[Pg 134] governments. Tens of billions of dollars of public debts are now outstanding, held by private investors in every walk of life.

4. Most debts today last for several years and represent the lender's purchase of a claim on the earnings of a productive business. The simplest types of long-term loans are those secured by real estate, which is mortgaged to the lender for the duration of the debt. Typically, the borrower is required to pay interest either annually or semi-annually, and often, but not always, is allowed to pay down the principal with partial payments. These real estate mortgages are backed by the specific mortgaged property and, unlike most short-term bank loans, are not personal obligations based on the borrower's overall credit. Most other long-term debts have this same non-personal nature; if a payment is missed, only the specific asset can be sold for repayment, not the borrower's overall wealth. Corporation bonds, issued by railroads and other large companies, have significantly increased in number in recent years. They provide a predetermined income and are usually secured by a mortgage on the entire property of the issuing corporation. The income from certain types of "preferred stocks" is so guaranteed that they are essentially the same as bonds for investors. Another major category of long-term loans comes from national, state, and local[Pg 134] governments. Tens of billions of dollars in public debt are currently outstanding, held by private investors from all walks of life.

The contract in the case of each kind of these loans provides for a fixed term after which the borrower must repay or renew, and for a fixed rate on the nominal or par value of the loan. Nearly all the securities (bonds, certificates, evidences of indebtedness) are salable at a market rate. It is therefore the income that is fixed, the selling price (or capital value) fluctuating above or below the nominal sum except just at the moment when it is payable. The long-time loan thus is very similar in its economic character to the old-time rent-charge.

The contract for each type of these loans specifies a set term after which the borrower must either repay or renew the loan, along with a fixed interest rate based on the loan's nominal or par value. Almost all securities (like bonds, certificates, and other proofs of indebtedness) can be sold at market rates. As a result, the income remains fixed while the selling price (or capital value) can fluctuate above or below the nominal amount, except at the moment when it is due. Long-term loans are therefore quite similar in their economic nature to traditional rent charges.

The cost of credit to the improvident buyer

5. The sale of goods on credit is a mode of lending and involves interest in a disguised form. In some cases merchants will not sell cheaper for cash than for credit, for fear of offending their main body of credit customers; but this is exceptional, as there are good reasons why such a difference should be made. The credit sale usually involves interest, and often at a very high rate. In many stores there are two appreciably different prices, one for "slow pay," the other for "spot cash." If a bill paid at the end of the month is five per cent. more than the cash price, the difference is equal to sixty per cent. per annum for the privilege of postponing payment. Such a rate of interest is paid only by the improvident, but that is a large class ranging from factory workers to college students. The cash discounts allowed by merchants clearly express the time difference. On fifty to one hundred dollars of outstanding bills, many perfectly honest persons are paying interest at the rate of seventy-five per cent. per annum. The merchant is forced to make this difference because he must seek not only to earn interest on the capital thus invested, but to recover the costs of bookkeeping and collections, and the risk and loss of unpaid bills. The discounts allowed by manufacturers and wholesale houses measure in the same way[Pg 135] the difference between cash and credit sales. Not unusual is a discount of "six per cent, in ten days, five per cent, in thirty, or sixty net." The buyer allowing his bills to run for two months (six per cent, for sixty days) pays thirty-six per cent, per annum for the use of that money. The difference is so great that it is impossible to carry on in this way a large business against strong competition. Such purchases on credit frequently are made, however, by dealers in small towns.

5. Selling goods on credit is a form of lending and includes interest in a hidden way. In some cases, merchants won’t sell at a lower price for cash than for credit, worried about upsetting their main group of credit customers; however, this is rare, as there are solid reasons to make such a distinction. The credit sale typically involves interest, often at a very high rate. Many stores have two noticeably different prices: one for "slow pay" and another for "spot cash." If a bill paid at the end of the month is five percent more than the cash price, that difference effectively amounts to sixty percent per year for the convenience of delaying payment. Such an interest rate is only paid by those who don't manage their finances well, but that includes a significant group ranging from factory workers to college students. The cash discounts given by merchants clearly show the time difference. On fifty to one hundred dollars in outstanding bills, many perfectly honest people are effectively paying interest at a rate of seventy-five percent per year. Merchants have to create this price difference because they need to earn interest on the capital they’ve invested while also covering bookkeeping and collection costs, along with the risk and losses from unpaid bills. The discounts offered by manufacturers and wholesale businesses reflect this same[Pg 135] difference between cash and credit sales. It’s not unusual to see a discount of "six percent in ten days, five percent in thirty, or sixty net." If the buyer lets their bills go for two months (six percent for sixty days), they end up paying thirty-six percent per year for the use of that money. The difference is so significant that it's nearly impossible to run a large business this way against tough competition. Nonetheless, small-town dealers often make purchases on credit.

Evasion of legal rate of interest

6. Interest is often concealed under other forms which increase the apparent rate. This fact is well shown in the ways by which usury laws fixing the legal rate of interest are evaded. A simple method is for the lender to charge a commission for making the loan, or, if it is a bank, to charge for a pretended cost of exchange to bring the money from some other city. Sometimes the borrower is required to keep larger deposits with the bank than he voluntarily would. Needing $5000, he is compelled to borrow $10,000 and to pay interest on twice as much as he is permitted to use. Again the borrower, in periods of unusual demand for money, is forced to make a long loan instead of a short one. When a one month's loan at ten per cent, would meet his need, he is forced to borrow for twelve months at six per cent., during ten months of which time four or five per cent, is the prevailing rate. In these and other ways the real rate, or burden of the loan, is made different from that which is expressed.

6. Interest is often hidden under other charges that make the rate look higher. This is clearly illustrated by the ways usury laws, which set the legal interest rate, are sidestepped. One straightforward tactic is for the lender to impose a fee for processing the loan, or if it's a bank, to claim a fictitious cost of transferring money from another city. Sometimes, borrowers are required to maintain larger deposits with the bank than they would otherwise choose. For instance, if someone needs $5,000, they might have to borrow $10,000 and pay interest on twice the amount they can actually use. Additionally, during times when there is a high demand for money, borrowers may be forced to take out a longer-term loan instead of a shorter one. When a one-month loan at ten percent would suffice, they may be compelled to borrow for twelve months at six percent, even though for ten of those months the prevailing rate is four or five percent. In these and other ways, the actual cost or burden of the loan differs from what is stated.

§ II. THE MOTIVE FOR PAYING INTEREST

Money borrowed to buy consumption goods

1. Interest for loans to obtain consumption goods is paid because they are felt to have greater importance at the moment than an equal amount (either of goods or of money) will have in the future. A sudden stress of misfortune may impart to a thing at the moment far more than its usual value. One standing face to face with starvation cannot[Pg 136] be worse off a year hence; often there is good ground to hope that if the present misfortune can be relieved, the future better fortune will make it possible to repay a loan with interest. In other cases, the object of a loan of consumption goods is to increase the future earning-power of the borrower. When the student borrows money that represents to him food, clothing, text-books, tuition, and other expenses incidental to a course in college, the expenditure is intended to increase the effectiveness of the worker. When he borrows he has little earning-power, but with that faith in himself which makes the young American so interesting, he pictures himself four years later, sheepskin in hand, drawing a munificent salary with which he can easily satisfy the most exacting Shylock. Such an expenditure is sometimes called "an investment of capital," but it should be called a consumption loan—nevertheless in many cases a loan wisely made. To call this an investment of capital is to confuse man, the end of production, with material means.

1. Interest on loans for purchasing consumer goods is paid because people believe they are more valuable right now than an equal amount (either in goods or cash) will be in the future. A sudden misfortune can make something worth far more than its usual value at that moment. Someone facing starvation cannot[Pg 136] be in a worse situation a year from now; often, there’s a genuine hope that if the current hardship can be alleviated, future prosperity will allow them to repay a loan with interest. In some cases, the purpose of borrowing consumer goods is to boost the borrower’s future earning potential. When a student borrows money for essentials like food, clothing, textbooks, tuition, and other college-related expenses, that spending is meant to enhance their effectiveness as a worker. Although the student has little earning potential at the moment, their optimism— which makes young Americans so engaging— leads them to envision themselves four years later, diploma in hand, earning a generous salary that easily covers even the most demanding lender. This kind of spending is sometimes referred to as "an investment of capital," but it should really be called a consumption loan—yet it can often be a wise loan. To label this as an investment of capital confuses people, who are the ultimate goal of production, with the physical resources involved.

Sometimes this higher estimate of the present good is unwise, viewed in the light of wider experience. Goods that meet momentary desire make an exaggerated appeal to untrained minds. The child, the spendthrift, the savage, cannot properly estimate the relative values of present and future. The improvident sometimes lightly agree to pay an exorbitant interest for an immediate consumption loan, making a ruinous difference between present and future gratifications.

Sometimes this overly optimistic view of immediate benefits is not wise when seen through a broader lens. Things that satisfy short-term desires can seem too appealing to inexperienced minds. Children, reckless spenders, and those lacking civilization often struggle to properly assess the value of the present compared to the future. Those who don’t plan ahead may casually agree to pay extremely high interest rates for a quick loan, creating a damaging gap between immediate enjoyment and future satisfaction.

Money borrowed to buy indirect agents

2. Interest on indirect agents is paid as a more or less indirect means of securing gratification. This can be clearly seen when durable agents are hired that produce gratification directly. A carriage bought with borrowed capital and used for the pleasure of the borrower is expected to afford a utility greater than that to be gotten by the amount of the interest in any other way. A spade bought with borrowed capital and used to cultivate the owner's garden is expected to add products of greater value than the interest.

2. Interest on indirect agents is paid as a somewhat indirect way of getting satisfaction. This becomes evident when long-lasting agents are acquired that provide satisfaction directly. A carriage bought with borrowed money and used for the borrower's enjoyment is expected to offer more value than what would be gained from the interest in any other form. A spade purchased with borrowed funds and used to tend the owner’s garden is expected to produce results of greater value than the interest.

But how is it in case the agent is used to gratify persons other than the owner? The music-teacher who buys a piano on credit expects to increase his earnings by a sum greater than the interest he has to pay. If the addition to his earnings exceeds the interest charge, it is because he has found a use for the borrowed capital greater than that on the basis of which it was capitalized in the market. The amount of the interest is secured through the pleasures and services the piano affords to the patrons of the teacher. In the most complex cases of the borrowing and use of indirect agents, there is ultimately this same basis for the interest: enjoyment afforded by the use of capital in the particular period. To the borrower, what the capital makes possible is an addition to his income as great as, or greater than, the prevailing interest. Most loans in our society are now of this sort. Money is borrowed to invest in business, to get better machinery or a larger stock; with this capital is secured a better or larger product, and the product finally being sold at a profit, the business man is at a point where he can satisfy his wants without encroaching on his capital. Logically, therefore, the consumer of the product pays the interest in the price, and the final consumer's enjoyment must be deemed the logical source of the money interest. The borrower's motive for paying interest on these indirect goods evidently is his hope of profit through realizing a greater money rent than he has contracted to pay for their use.

But what happens if the agent is used to benefit people other than the owner? The music teacher who buys a piano on credit expects to earn more than the interest he has to pay. If his additional earnings exceed the interest, it’s because he has found a way to use the borrowed money that generates more value than what it cost in the market. The interest is covered by the joy and services the piano brings to the teacher’s students. Even in the most complex cases of borrowing and using indirect agents, there’s ultimately the same foundation for interest: the enjoyment provided by the use of capital during a specific period. For the borrower, the capital enables an increase in their income that matches or surpasses the current interest rates. Most loans in our society are like this now. Money is borrowed for business investment, to acquire better equipment or increase inventory; this capital leads to a better or larger product, which is finally sold for profit, allowing the business owner to meet their needs without touching their capital. Logically, the consumer of the product pays the interest through the price, and the final consumer’s enjoyment is the logical source of the interest. The borrower’s reason for paying interest on these indirect goods is clearly his expectation of making a profit by achieving a greater financial return than what he agreed to pay for their use.

The special case of money borrowed to pay debts

3. The money market in which short-time loans are made is peculiar in that the money frequently is borrowed to pay debts, not for investment. In beginning the discussion of interest, it always is remarked that it is not money, but capital, that is borrowed and loaned. This caution against the superficial errors that so easily beset the popular discussion of interest is much needed, but it is well to note a peculiar case which is apparently in contradiction to this statement. The usual method by which money is loaned in the great[Pg 138] industrial centers is called discount, which is the exchange of a certain sum of money for a note or other credit paper of a larger amount, the interest thus being taken out in advance. Much borrowing in the form of discount is for the same purpose as other borrowing—to acquire control of more productive agents, to embark on new enterprises. The peculiarity of the discount money-market is that an unusual number of loans are made to meet contracts that have already been made. There is always a great mass of outstanding obligations, and merchants are compelled to renew these loans on penalty of bankruptcy. This market for short-time loans is not connected closely with the general market for loanable capital. When the need is for ready money, other concrete capital cannot flow in to meet it. This special money demand, therefore, in time of greater or less stress, may fluctuate rapidly, and the interest rate be temporarily higher or lower than the rate on long-time loans. This case is similar to that where two markets, as a retail and a wholesale one, exist side by side, but slowly exerting a mutual influence.

3. The money market for short-term loans is unique because the money is often borrowed to pay off debts, rather than for investment purposes. When discussing interest, it’s often noted that it’s not money being borrowed and lent, but capital. This caution against common misconceptions in public discussions of interest is important, but it’s also worthwhile to point out a specific case that seems to contradict this idea. The typical practice for lending money in major[Pg 138] industrial centers is referred to as discounting, which involves exchanging a certain amount of money for a promissory note or other credit document with a larger value, with the interest taken upfront. Many loans made through discounting serve the same purpose as other loans—to gain control of more productive resources or to start new projects. However, what makes the discount money market unique is that a significant number of loans are taken out to fulfill existing contracts. There is always a substantial amount of unpaid obligations, and merchants must renew these loans to avoid bankruptcy. This market for short-term loans is not closely tied to the broader market for loanable capital. When there’s a need for immediate cash, other forms of capital cannot quickly replace it. Therefore, this specific demand for money can fluctuate significantly during times of stress, causing interest rates to be temporarily higher or lower than those for long-term loans. This situation resembles two markets, like retail and wholesale, that exist alongside each other while gradually affecting one another.

Productive borrowers seek a profit on their investments

4. In the long-time money loan the money generally is borrowed first merely as a medium of exchange to get control of indirect agents. The borrower of a long-time money loan for productive purposes is always seeking to gain by investing the money in wealth that will yield an income larger than the interest he must pay. The borrower, therefore, invests in view of the rate of interest, of the market price of the goods in which he plans to invest, and of the probable chances for earning profits in the business. This case, where certain goods whose price is known are approximately selected before the money is borrowed for investment, is the type of loan to be kept most usually in mind in economic discussion.

4. In a long-term loan, the money is usually borrowed first as a way to get access to indirect resources. The person borrowing a long-term loan for productive reasons is always trying to make more money by investing that loan into assets that will generate an income greater than the interest they need to pay. So, the borrower plans their investment based on the interest rate, the market price of the goods they intend to invest in, and the likelihood of making profits in that business. This scenario, where specific goods with known prices are roughly chosen before borrowing the money for investment, is typically the type of loan that is most often discussed in economics.

Evidently the price of these goods, to control which is the real object of the loan, is merely the sum of the expected rents they will yield, capitalized at the prevailing rate of[Pg 139] time-discount. The borrower expects either to make these particular goods earn rents larger than those on the basis of which they have been capitalized, or to transfer them to an economy where goods are capitalized at a higher rate than he is paying. The income yielded by these goods, if the borrower's expectation is fulfilled, is but the difference between present and future rents that has been wrapped up in their capitalization. As time elapses and the rents emerge in wisely chosen investments, the borrower has a surplus large enough to pay the contract interest. It appears, therefore, that the motive of the borrower is to get control of future rents at prices that already involve, in their capitalization, a rate of discount somewhat greater than the interest he contracts to pay.

Clearly, the price of these goods, which is the main goal of the loan, is simply the total of the expected rents they will generate, calculated at the current rate of [Pg 139] time discount. The borrower hopes to either make these specific goods earn rents that are higher than those used for capitalization or transfer them to a market where goods are capitalized at a higher rate than what he is paying. If the borrower's expectation is met, the income generated by these goods is just the difference between present and future rents that are included in their capitalization. As time passes and the rents begin to emerge from wisely chosen investments, the borrower ends up with enough surplus to cover the contract interest. Thus, it seems that the borrower's motivation is to gain control of future rents at prices that already factor in a rate of discount that is somewhat higher than the interest he agrees to pay.

The developed market for money loans

5. The rate of contract interest on money loans is adjusted at each moment in the money market by the bidding for money loans. This is a true statement only if it is understood in a somewhat superficial sense. No error connected with interest is, however, more crude than the view that the interest rate is in any broad sense due to the quantity of money. Some loans are made apart from the general market, by private agreement between borrower and lender; but in nearly every such case the rate agreed upon is seen to be closely related to that of the general market to which either borrower or lender can resort if he wishes. The greater number of borrowers and lenders of money have a range of choice in their bargaining. The interest rate in modern developed money markets is that rate which brings to equilibrium the demand for money loans and the money capital available within the period. If the ready, loanable money in private hands, in banks, in insurance-company reserves, &c., increases, a lower rate must be offered to borrowers; if the supply decreases, a higher rate will be quoted. In the one case, more men borrow; in the other, fewer borrow and more seek to lend. Thus a rate results, but a rate that is closely connected with larger set of facts—those, indeed,[Pg 140] which determine in the long run the rate of capitalization in the community.

5. The interest rate on money loans is adjusted constantly in the money market through bidding for those loans. This statement is only true if it's understood in a basic way. There’s no bigger misconception about interest than the idea that the interest rate is generally determined by the amount of money available. Some loans happen outside the general market through private agreements between borrowers and lenders; however, in almost every case, the agreed-upon rate is closely linked to the general market rate that either the borrower or lender can access if they choose. Most borrowers and lenders have options when negotiating. The interest rate in modern, developed money markets is the rate that balances the demand for money loans with the available money capital during that time period. If the amount of readily available money in private hands, banks, insurance company reserves, etc., increases, a lower rate must be offered to borrowers; if the supply decreases, a higher rate will be set. In one situation, more people borrow; in the other, fewer borrow and more look to lend. Consequently, a rate emerges that is closely tied to a larger set of factors—those that ultimately determine the rate of capitalization in the community.[Pg 140]

Every person is a buyer or a seller of present goods

6. The individual must adjust his business dealings to the market rate of interest. The market rate is fixed by the bidding of individuals, and every one has something to do with fixing it. In a multitude of minutely small ways, as present and future goods are compared by men, the rate of interest is affected positively or negatively. But for practical purposes the individual, counting for little in the midst of millions, must look upon the interest rate as beyond his influence. Therefore, while the rate is determined by each to some degree, all that any one does is to buy or sell present goods, borrow or lend capital, use up or save wealth, according as his own estimate of time-value is less or more than the market rate. In fact, the estimates of individuals diverge constantly from the market rate, but are brought into harmony by their actions with reference both to money loans and to the use and valuation of the various forms of wealth. A Robinson Crusoe working on his island and valuing future goods relatively to present goods higher than before, consumes less; or, valuing them lower, consumes more. The business man who values indirect agents above the market rate borrows, and if he miscalculates and fails to make them earn the expected rent, he loses. In this experimental way many other acts are influenced by the prevailing interest rate and in turn affect it, thus aiding to formulate society's estimate of the value of present as compared with future rents.

6. The individual must adjust his business dealings to the market interest rate. The market rate is determined by the bids of individuals, and everyone contributes to its determination. In numerous small ways, as people compare present and future goods, the interest rate is impacted positively or negatively. However, for practical purposes, the individual, having little influence amid millions, should view the interest rate as beyond his control. Therefore, while the rate is set by each person to some extent, what anyone does is simply to buy or sell present goods, borrow or lend capital, and either consume or save wealth, based on whether their own assessment of time-value is lower or higher than the market rate. In fact, individual estimates frequently differ from the market rate, but they align through actions related to money loans and the use and valuation of various forms of wealth. A Robinson Crusoe working on his island who values future goods more than before will consume less; or, if he values them less, he will consume more. A businessperson who values indirect agents above the market rate will borrow, and if he misjudges and fails to earn the expected return, he will suffer a loss. In this experimental manner, many other actions are influenced by the current interest rate and, in turn, affect it, thereby contributing to society's assessment of the value of present versus future rents.


CHAPTER 17

THE THEORY OF TIME-VALUE

§ I. DEFINITION AND SCOPE OF TIME-VALUE

The simplest cases of time-value

1. Time-value is the difference between the values of things at different times. Things differ in value according to form, place, quality of goods, and according to the feelings of men, and—not least important factor—according to time. The simplest and clearest case of time-value is the difference noticeable in the same thing at different moments. Is this good worth more now or next week? Shall this apple be eaten now or next winter? These questions can be answered only after comparing the marginal utilities which differ according to the varying conditions of the two periods.

1. Time-value is the difference in how much things are worth at different times. The value of items changes based on their form, location, quality, and people's feelings, and one of the most important factors is time. The most straightforward example of time-value is the difference seen in the same item at different moments. Is this item worth more now or next week? Should this apple be eaten now or held onto until next winter? These questions can only be answered by comparing the marginal utilities, which vary according to the different conditions of the two time periods.

All the other cases of time-value can, by the practical device of substituting other goods of equivalent value, be reduced to the typical case of comparison of the same thing at different times. The comparison may be between very similar things, the one consumed being replaced by a duplicate. An apple borrowed now may be returned next year in the form of one of the same size and quality. The essential thing in this comparison is not physical identity, but equivalence in size, sort, and quality at the two periods. This is borrowing under the renting contract.

All the other instances of time-value can, through the practical method of swapping in other goods of equal value, be simplified to the standard case of comparing the same item at different times. The comparison can involve very similar items, with one consumed and replaced by a duplicate. An apple borrowed now can be returned next year as one of the same size and quality. The key aspect of this comparison is not physical identity, but rather equivalence in size, type, and quality at the two different times. This is borrowing under a rental agreement.

Time-value in the case of different kinds of gratifications

But two or more quite different things may be expressed in terms of another thing and so be made comparable. Money becomes the value-unit through which different things may be reduced to the same terms for comparison. With this mode of expressing the value-equivalence of various[Pg 142] goods, the interest contract first becomes possible, money (the standard of deferred payments) being the thing exchanged (possibly only in name) at two periods of time. What is really compared are various gratifications which may be produced by very different material things or services. In its last analysis comparison of values at different periods of time must be a comparison of psychic incomes, of two sums of gratification. The comparison of the value of a bushel of apples with that of a barrel of potatoes or a suit of clothes at the same moment appears simple enough. When all are expressed in terms of money, the comparison of each with its value-equivalent at a later date becomes easy. The simplicity and obviousness of time-value in the case of money loans at interest led men at first to recognize that phase of the problem exclusively, and later the term "interest," not without much confusion of thought, was given a wider significance. Let us now see how large a part of the whole problem of time-value is outside of the money loan.

But two or more completely different things can be expressed in relation to another thing, making them comparable. Money serves as the unit of value that allows different things to be measured in the same way for comparison. This method of expressing the value equivalence of various[Pg 142] goods makes interest contracts possible, with money (the standard for future payments) being what is exchanged (possibly just by name) at two different times. What’s really being compared are different satisfactions that can come from various material goods or services. Ultimately, comparing values at different times boils down to comparing psychological benefits, or two amounts of satisfaction. Comparing the value of a bushel of apples with that of a barrel of potatoes or a suit of clothes at the same moment seems straightforward enough. Once everything is expressed in terms of money, comparing each with its value equivalent at a later date becomes simple. The obviousness and straightforwardness of time value in the case of money loans with interest initially led people to focus solely on that aspect of the problem, and later the term "interest," although it caused some confusion, was given a broader meaning. Now let’s examine how much of the entire time-value issue exists outside of the money loan.

Time-value is involved in capitalization of land

2. The problem of time-value is quite separable from the concepts of money and capital, though usually connected with them in practice and theory. It is true that the problem of time-value was first clearly recognized in connection with money and a formally expressed capital sum. Misled by this fact, and taking a very narrow view, writers seventy-five years ago recognized but dimly the problem of time-value in connection with the valuation of the incomes derived from land. It is true, as has been shown above, that the mere putting of an estimate on a durable good such as land involves the process of capitalization, which in turn implies a comparison of the values of the rents expected at different periods. Diminishing returns in the use of agents involves a loss of time to secure the usufructs emerging. The relation of these facts was not clearly seen until of late.

2. The issue of time-value can be viewed separately from the ideas of money and capital, although it is often linked to them in both practice and theory. It's true that the concept of time-value was first clearly identified in relation to money and a formally defined capital amount. Misled by this connection and adopting a narrow perspective, writers seventy-five years ago only vaguely recognized the time-value issue in relation to the valuation of income from land. As mentioned earlier, simply estimating the value of a durable good like land involves capitalization, which requires comparing the expected rents over different time periods. Diminishing returns from using resources means that there's a delay in obtaining the benefits that come from them. The relationship between these factors has only recently been understood more clearly.

The phenomenon of time-value as above defined may be[Pg 143] seen to be broader even than that of capitalization. The difference in the value of the successive rents of wealth must have been recognized and in some degree measured before there was any conscious calculation of capital value. Differences in value due to time are everywhere. The problem of time-value often is present where money is not even spoken of or thought of. Money no more causes this time-difference in value than balances cause weight.

The concept of time-value, as defined above, can be[Pg 143] seen as even broader than capitalization. The differences in the value of successive wealth rents must have been acknowledged and somewhat assessed before anyone consciously calculated capital value. Time-related value differences are found everywhere. The issue of time-value often arises even when money isn't mentioned or considered. Money doesn't create this time-difference in value any more than balances create weight.

Time-value is taken account of in the keeping up of repairs

3. The problem of time-value is involved in repairs and depreciation, and in the use of consumption goods. It is possible, as we have seen, to increase the sum available for present needs, and to encroach upon the future by postponing repairs on intermediate goods. The balancing of the cost of repairs against the future income is a never-ending task in practical business. One making repairs must purchase the needed materials and labor at a capitalization determined by their expected earning-power in other industries. If the repairs in question will not ensure an annual saving as great as this expected rent, they will not be made. When an industry is declining, it may, for the sake of putting the capital into a better business, be good policy to let the machinery fall into bad repair. The problem of time-value is involved in the application of one's energy to repairing one's own possessions. It is a thought of wide bearings that numberless minor decisions in every petty business involve, if they are correctly made, a measuring of the rate of capitalization.

3. The issue of time-value relates to repairs and depreciation, as well as the use of consumer goods. As we've seen, it's possible to increase the available funds for immediate needs by delaying repairs on intermediate goods. Balancing the cost of repairs against future income is an ongoing challenge in practical business. When making repairs, one must buy the necessary materials and labor at a value based on their expected earning potential in other industries. If the repairs won't provide an annual saving that's greater than this projected rent, they simply won't happen. In a declining industry, it might be wise to let the machinery fall into disrepair to invest the capital in a more promising venture. The issue of time-value also comes into play when deciding how to use one's energy to fix personal belongings. It's important to recognize that countless small decisions in every minor business involve, if made correctly, an assessment of the rate of capitalization.

And in the choice of enjoyments

As will be more fully shown in discussing the relation of the prevailing rate of interest to saving, the recognition of time-value is implied in the use men make of consumption goods, in their postponement of enjoyment, in their storing of goods for future use. The varying gratifications yielded by consumption goods, and their values in different conditions cannot be explained without taking account of differences in time. Wherever there can be a choice in the time at which, and consequently in the conditions under[Pg 144] which, a thing can be used, there is a choice presented between the different values. Time-value is present even in a period during which no goods continue to exist, as when a good is consumed at a moment of greater need, to be replaced at a time when less valuable. If an apple is borrowed on the promise to return an apple and a peach at the end of a year, the peach represents the time-difference in value but in the meantime there has been no apple in existence. It is only in a figurative sense that it may be said that interest is paid on that "capital." Interest is paid because of a difference in want-gratifying power, but during the interval there is no material capital.

As will be explained further when we talk about the relationship between the current interest rate and saving, the idea of time-value is reflected in how people use consumption goods, delay gratification, and store items for future use. The different satisfactions provided by consumption goods and their values in various situations can't be understood without considering time differences. Whenever there's a choice about when to use something, and thus the conditions under which it’s used, a comparison of different values arises. Time-value exists even during periods when no goods are available, as when a product is consumed in a time of greater need and will be replaced later when it’s less valuable. If someone borrows an apple with a promise to return an apple and a peach after a year, the peach reflects the difference in value over time, but during that period, there is no apple physically existing. It's only figuratively that we can say interest is paid on that "capital." Interest is paid due to a variation in the ability to satisfy wants, but during that time, there is no tangible capital.

Prodigality and vice involve a high discount of future happiness

4. The problem of time-value is involved in much foolish pleasure, in prodigality, and in vice. Economics touches frequently on the borders of ethics. If there were to be formulated an economics of personal conduct, it surely would give a large place to the comparison between present and future pleasures. Forethought, or prudence, is the virtue of recognizing not only future dangers to be avoided, but the greater future joys to be gained in exchange for present pleasures. The reckless and the prodigal underestimate the future and barter all to gratify the moment's impulse. The drinker exchanges the hopes of worthy life for the exhilaration of the spree. Indulgence in social pleasures, if secured at the price of lost sleep, weakened health, and debauched character, are loans from the future made by youthful prodigals at usurious interest. If no one ever paid more than a moderate rate of interest for the gratification of his present whims and impulses, most hospitals, drug-stores, and medical colleges would close, and half, if not all, the prisons would be empty.

4. The issue of the value of time is tied to a lot of foolish pleasures, extravagance, and bad behavior. Economics often overlaps with ethics. If we were to create a personal conduct economics, it would definitely focus on comparing current and future pleasures. Forethought, or prudence, is the ability to see not just future dangers to avoid, but also the greater joys to be gained in exchange for immediate pleasures. The reckless and extravagant underestimate the future, trading everything to satisfy their impulses in the moment. The drinker trades the hope of a meaningful life for the thrill of the party. Enjoyment of social pleasures, if achieved at the cost of lost sleep, poor health, and a damaged character, are like taking out loans on the future with high interest, made by youthful spendthrifts. If everyone only paid a fair interest rate for indulging their immediate desires and impulses, most hospitals, pharmacies, and medical schools would shut down, and half, if not all, prisons would be empty.

Indeed, time difference in value is a universal phenomenon of life and conduct. Contract interest is but one phenomenal form of time-value, and this in turn is but one phase of value. This section may serve to suggest how much more varied and pervasive the fact of time-value is than has[Pg 145] usually been recognized in popular or economic discussion of the subject of interest.

Indeed, the difference in value over time is a universal part of life and behavior. Contract interest is just one form of time-value, and this is only one aspect of value. This section may suggest how much more complex and widespread the concept of time-value is than has[Pg 145] usually been acknowledged in general or economic discussions about interest.

§ II. THE ADJUSTMENT OF THE RATE OF TIME-DISCOUNT

The exchange value of present and future goods

1. The fixing of the discount on future goods is, in its essentials, like the fixing of the market price of consumption goods. This problem appears to be one of the most difficult in economic theory; but reduced to its simplest terms, it is an aspect of exchange value, and its ultimate explanation must be found in a comparison of psychic incomes. There must be noted the conditions of demand and supply, the interplay and final equilibrium of the two forces. The declining and marginal utility to the two parties to exchange must be carefully analyzed. One who can do these things is prepared to find the answer to the problem of time-value. Whenever a group of buyers and sellers meet, a ratio of exchange commonly will be arrived at. The ratio of exchange between buyers and sellers of present and future rents likewise is fixed at the estimates of a "marginal pair," at which point the amount offered and taken comes to equilibrium, for at that point no motive exists for any one to change sides.

1. Setting the discount on future goods is essentially similar to setting the market price of consumer goods. This issue seems to be one of the toughest in economic theory; however, when simplified, it relates to exchange value, and its ultimate explanation lies in comparing psychic incomes. It's important to consider the conditions of demand and supply, as well as the interaction and final balance of these two forces. The diminishing and marginal utility for both parties involved in the exchange need to be analyzed carefully. Anyone who can do this is ready to tackle the problem of time-value. Whenever a group of buyers and sellers comes together, a common exchange ratio is established. The exchange ratio between buyers and sellers of current and future rents is also determined by the estimates of a "marginal pair," at which point the offered and accepted amounts reach equilibrium, since no one has any incentive to switch sides at that moment.

The peculiar nature of the exchange in the case of time-value
Several reasons why this is not easily recognized

2. Time-value as the premium rate on present goods is unlike the ordinary market price, of goods only in the special nature of the utilities exchanged. The one peculiar need in the theory of this subject is a clear understanding on this point. The goods exchanged, or compared, are direct and indirect goods, or present and future goods, or, more generally speaking, two goods or groups of goods unequally distant in time from present enjoyment. What are sold in a case such as capitalization, involving an estimate of time-value, are present goods or gratifications; what are bought are future gratifications, or indirect agents which stand for, typify, or make possible, future gratifications. Practically every man in a market acts on the knowledge of what the[Pg 146] exchange of direct and indirect goods means; yet abstractly stated, the thought seems at first difficult. In valuing any durable good, the theory of time-value is implied. Every time a machine, a house, a book, a field, is bought, the distinction between direct and indirect goods is acted upon, for a choice has been made between present enjoyment and future provision. Anything that endures is an indirect good and implies in its valuation a premium rate on present goods.

2. The time-value as the interest rate on current goods is different from the usual market price of goods only in the specific nature of the utilities exchanged. The key thing to grasp in this theory is a clear understanding of this point. The goods that are exchanged or compared are direct and indirect goods, or present and future goods, or, more generally, two goods or groups of goods that are placed at different distances in time from current enjoyment. In situations like capitalization, where time-value is estimated, what’s being sold are current goods or satisfactions; what’s being bought are future satisfactions, or indirect agents that represent, symbolize, or enable future satisfactions. Practically everyone in the market understands what the[Pg 146] exchange of direct and indirect goods means; yet, when stated abstractly, the idea seems difficult at first. When valuing any durable good, the theory of time-value is involved. Each time a machine, a house, a book, or a field is purchased, the distinction between direct and indirect goods comes into play, since a choice has been made between immediate enjoyment and future resources. Anything that lasts is considered an indirect good and implies a premium rate on current goods in its valuation.

The real nature of the exchange in time-valuation is made unclear by the uncertainty of life, leading men to work on to provide against possibility of mishaps; for the most part the world's treasures never afford to their temporary owners the gratification that they typify, or could give. The nature of this exchange is made unclear also by habit, under the influence of which the exchange in so many cases is not carefully thought out, is not the result of a close comparison of the utilities of goods in present and future moments. The real nature of this exchange is made unclear by the indirect, or induced, gratification derived from wealth. Wealth gives to its owner power, prestige, the esteem of his fellows, and pride in evidences of success and growing prosperity. Its very possession creates a new need and imparts to it another utility, that of insuring against the misery of a declining fortune one who has enjoyed wealth and power. Men make the greatest efforts up to the last moment of life to retain wealth that they will enjoy only in this subtle and indirect way. Thus every motive that leads men to postpone present enjoyment makes them bidders for indirect agents and for future goods, and helps to determine the market rate of premium on the present, and of discount on the future.

The true nature of time-based exchanges is obscured by life's uncertainties, causing people to work hard to guard against potential mishaps. Most of the world's treasures rarely provide their temporary owners with the satisfaction they represent or could deliver. This exchange is further clouded by habit, which often leads to exchanges that aren't thoughtfully considered or the result of a careful evaluation of the benefits of goods in the present versus the future. The actual nature of this exchange is also muddied by the indirect satisfaction gained from wealth. Wealth gives its owner power, status, the respect of others, and pride in symbols of success and increasing prosperity. Owning wealth creates a new need and adds another utility: it acts as a safeguard against the despair of falling fortunes for those who have enjoyed wealth and power. People put in tremendous effort right up to the end of their lives to hold onto wealth that they will only appreciate in this subtle and indirect manner. Therefore, every reason that drives people to delay immediate pleasure turns them into bidders for indirect benefits and future goods, influencing the market's current premium and the future's discount rate.

The scarcity of present gratifications

3. There being a limited number of indirect agents, their limited powers in a given period limit the supply of present goods. The principle is familiar that value is always connected with relative scarcity. Now the desire for the present goods is indefinitely large. If the right kind and[Pg 147] quality could be had at will, an enormously greater amount of present goods would be used. But the present goods are dependent on indirect agents. The psychic income of a civilized community is dependent on a favorable and extremely refined environment: houses, libraries, theaters, the agencies of travel, as well as the sources supplying the more material needs. These indirect agents, even in the richest community, are limited in variety, in quality, and in number.

3. Since there are only a limited number of indirect agents, their limited abilities over a certain time restrict the availability of current goods. It's well-known that value is always linked to relative scarcity. The demand for current goods is practically endless. If the right type and[Pg 147] quality were available on demand, an incredibly larger amount of current goods would be consumed. However, current goods depend on indirect agents. The overall satisfaction of a civilized society relies on a favorable and highly developed environment: homes, libraries, theaters, travel services, as well as sources meeting more basic needs. These indirect agents, even in the wealthiest communities, are limited in variety, quality, and quantity.

The total of future uses in vastly greater

But if indirect agents could produce an indefinitely large product at any given moment, the supply of present goods could be indefinitely increased. The supply of utilities, therefore, is limited by "diminishing returns" in the use of agents, making their maximum yield depend upon the lapse of time. The uses any given material can yield in a limited period have an absolute limit: an acre of land with the most perfect cultivation cannot feed the world; but remove the limit of time, wait an eternity, and the acre would yield an infinite crop. The economic return of a given agent in a given period is reached much sooner than the technical return. If agents are forced to yield more bountifully, it is at the sacrifice of utilities in other agents, and a point of maximum net yield is found in any given period. Here also the lapse of time is the condition of the increase of the net utilities derivable from limited agents.

But if indirect agents could produce an unlimited amount of product at any given moment, the supply of current goods could be infinitely increased. Therefore, the supply of utilities is limited by "diminishing returns" in the use of agents, which makes their maximum output depend on the passage of time. The amount any given material can produce in a limited timeframe has an absolute limit: an acre of land, even with the best cultivation, cannot feed the entire world; but if you remove the time constraint and wait indefinitely, that acre could yield infinite crops. The economic return of a particular agent in a specific timeframe is reached much sooner than its technical return. If agents are pushed to produce more abundantly, it comes at the expense of utilities from other agents, and a point of maximum net yield is found in any given period. Again, the passage of time is essential for increasing the net utilities derived from limited agents.

The choice open to the investor of money

4. The rate of capitalization of income and the rate of contract interest on money capital tend to unite into a single market rate. A person wishing to exchange present goods or income for future goods may buy an income-bearer at its capitalized value, or he may create a new rent-bearer. Having saved a sum of money, either he may purchase a factory known to be profitable; or he may hire the services of men and unite them with materials and machinery to create a new industry or a new form of income-bearer; or he may loan his money to others to make either kind of purchase. In any one of the three cases it is evident that capitalization[Pg 148] (that is, the discounting of future rents in goods) is the primary and important fact making possible the emergence of a surplus, or net yield, over and above the value of the capital. The expected uses contained not only in whole industrial establishments, but in the particular materials and agents united to form new agents, are purchased at their capitalized value; that is, the future uses have been discounted and have entered into the price of the goods as less than they will be when realized as actual rents. This is the crucial point in the theory either of contract interest or of time value; for to explain the rate of interest as due to the process of "producing" capital agents out of other materials, is to beg the question involved. The surplus yielded by capital above its cost is but the realization of a net income made possible by the discounting of future rents.

4. The rate at which income is capitalized and the interest rate on money tend to merge into a single market rate. A person wanting to trade current goods or income for future goods can either buy an income-generating asset at its capitalized value or create a new income-generating asset. After saving some money, they can buy a factory known to be profitable, hire people and combine their efforts with materials and machinery to establish a new industry or income-generating asset, or lend their money to others to make such purchases. In any of these scenarios, it’s clear that capitalization[Pg 148] (which means accounting for future rents in goods) plays a central role in enabling the creation of a surplus or net gain above the value of the capital. The anticipated uses tied to entire industries, as well as the specific materials and resources combined to create new assets, are bought at their capitalized value; that is, future uses have been accounted for and factored into the price of the goods, lower than they will be once realized as actual rents. This is a key aspect of the theory of either contract interest or time value; explaining the interest rate as a result of the process of "producing" capital assets from other materials merely sidesteps the essential question. The surplus generated by capital beyond its cost is simply the realization of a net income made possible by accounting for future rents.

The choice open to the borrower of wealth

A person wishing to make an exchange of the opposite kind to that described may sell his wealth for money; he may exchange for present enjoyable goods his income at its capitalized value; or he may use up what he has, let it depreciate, fail to make repairs, convert it to various consumption purposes, and thus invade his earning power. When the interest rate is five per cent., the sacrifice of any unit of regular income permits the spending of twenty times that amount for present enjoyment. The advantages of these various methods tend to equilibrium. If the owners of developed productive agents hold them at too high a capitalized value, investors will apply their efforts and savings to duplicating these forms of wealth. If, in turn, any of the minor factors, as materials or uses of goods, are overvalued (overcapitalized) it will appear ultimately in a check in the demand for them at these prices, and in a reduction in the demand for money loans. As it is possible for any investor and for any borrower to choose among these investments and loans, there is practically but one rate, the rate which expresses the general ratio of exchange between present and future income. Owners and investors[Pg 149] take the line of least resistance, get the most they can for their money, and choose whatever form is most advantageous. The interrelations between the various interest rates are therefore close and constant. The market rate of interest thus extends over all forms of wealth and pervades every phase of business. The value of every durable agent is fixed with reference to a prevailing interest rate, through the discounting to their present worth of all the incomes it is believed to contain.

A person who wants to make the opposite kind of exchange described can sell their assets for cash; they can trade their income at its present value for goods they enjoy now; or they may use what they have, let it lose value, neglect maintenance, and spend it on various purposes, thereby reducing their earning potential. When the interest rate is five percent, sacrificing any unit of regular income allows for spending twenty times that amount for immediate enjoyment. The benefits of these different methods tend to balance each other out. If the owners of developed productive assets value them too highly, investors will focus their efforts and savings on creating similar forms of wealth. Conversely, if any minor factors, like materials or uses of goods, are overvalued (or overcapitalized), there will eventually be a drop in demand for them at those prices, leading to a decrease in the demand for money loans. Since any investor or borrower can choose among these investments and loans, there is essentially one rate, which reflects the general exchange ratio between present and future income. Owners and investors[Pg 149] take the path of least resistance, aiming to get the most value for their money, and select whichever option is most beneficial. Therefore, the relationships between the different interest rates are close and consistent. The market rate of interest applies to all forms of wealth and influences every aspect of business. The value of any durable asset is determined by the prevailing interest rate, as it discounts all expected future incomes to their present worth.

A sacrifice sale involves a high rate of interest

5. Where goods are sold at forced sale or sacrifice, it is equivalent to a contract loan at a high rate of interest. Market values being dependent upon market conditions, the offer of goods at a given moment may not find the usual or normal number of buyers or the usual demand. Just such conditions are most likely to exist at the times when business men feel an unusual need of money. Two courses are open to them in this emergency, either to borrow the money at a very high rate of interest, holding the goods for better prices, or to sell the goods under the unfavorable conditions. The end of both courses is the same—to get ready money; and the methods are not essentially unlike—the exchange of greater future values for present values. The sacrifice sale thus reveals the merchant's high estimate of the interest rate. The purchaser of some kinds of property in times of depression is securing them at a lower capitalization than they will later have. The rise in value may be foreseen as well by seller as by buyer, but the low capitalization reflects the high interest rate temporarily obtaining. A. T. Stewart is said to have laid the foundation of his fortune when, being out of debt himself, he bought up the bankrupt stocks of his competitors in a great financial panic. The high contract interest at such times is but the reflection of the high premium on present purchasing power. Here then is another mode in which the prevailing rate of interest on money loans is kept in close harmony with the rate of time valuation.

5. When goods are sold at a forced sale or at a loss, it's similar to taking out a loan with a high interest rate. Market values depend on current conditions, and the availability of goods at a specific moment may not attract the usual number of buyers or have the expected demand. Such situations often occur when businesspeople feel a pressing need for cash. In this emergency, they have two options: either borrow money at a very high interest rate while holding onto the goods for potentially better prices, or sell the goods under unfavorable conditions. Both options ultimately aim for the same result—to obtain cash quickly—and the methods are quite similar—the exchange of higher future values for immediate cash. The sacrifice sale shows how much the merchant values the interest rate. Buyers of certain types of property during downturns are acquiring them at a lower investment return than they will later be worth. Both the seller and buyer can anticipate the rise in value, but the low investment return reflects the temporarily high interest rate. A. T. Stewart is said to have built his fortune by buying the bankrupt stocks of his competitors during a major financial crisis when he was debt-free. The high contract interest at such times simply reflects the high demand for immediate purchasing power. This illustrates another way that the prevailing interest rate on loans aligns closely with the rate of time value.

Interrelations of the money interest rate and of time-discount

6. The rate of contract interest on safe long-time loans[Pg 150] registers pretty nearly the prevailing rate of time-discount in the community. There are of course different capital markets, and the estimates put upon next year's income as compared with this year's is very different in Montana, New York, and London. Because of the friction in the transfer of investments from one locality to another, these differences may persist indefinitely; but within each capital market the interest on any particular loan must, for reasons readily seen, tend to conform pretty closely to the prevailing rate. Various groups of men living in the same community have, however, varying estimates of time-value. The increase of safe long-time bonds issued by strong corporations and by wealthy nations as, for example, the New York Central Railroad, and the government of Great Britain, gives a large number of choice investments where the element of risk is almost entirely absent. Various agencies have developed for making the loans, that is, for bringing the borrower and lender together with the minimum of trouble and expense. Other efficient, but somewhat more costly, agencies for bringing together the owners of loanable capital and men wishing to use capital are savings-banks, building and loan associations, insurance companies issuing endowment policies, and mortgage-investment companies of many kinds. While on the one side of the bidding are thousands of lenders offering to exchange ready money for assured incomes, on the other are thousand of borrowers offering to exchange the promise of assured incomes for ready money. If either of these classes got far out of touch with the prevailing rate of capitalization, to which all the valuations are adjusted, that class would lose greatly.

6. The interest rate on safe long-term loans[Pg 150] is almost exactly the same as the current time-discount rate in the community. There are definitely different capital markets, and the projections for next year's income compared to this year's differ significantly in Montana, New York, and London. Due to the difficulties in moving investments from one place to another, these discrepancies may continue indefinitely; however, within each capital market, the interest on any specific loan tends to closely align with the prevailing rate for obvious reasons. Various groups of people living in the same community have different views on time-value. The increase in secure long-term bonds issued by strong corporations and wealthy nations, such as the New York Central Railroad and the government of Great Britain, provides many attractive investments where the risk is nearly nonexistent. Various organizations have emerged to facilitate loans, connecting borrowers and lenders with minimal hassle and expense. Other effective but slightly more expensive organizations, like savings banks, building and loan associations, insurance companies offering endowment policies, and various mortgage investment companies, also help to connect capital owners with those who want to use capital. On one side of the bidding, there are thousands of lenders willing to trade immediate cash for guaranteed income, while on the other side are thousands of borrowers looking to trade promises of guaranteed income for immediate cash. If either group strays too far from the prevailing capitalization rate, to which all valuations are adjusted, that group would suffer significant losses.

Relations between the concepts of rent, interest, and time-value

7. All the net usufructs actually yielded by wealth are rents; economic time-discount is never a realized income; it is merely a calculation form, or anticipation of the difference between present and future gratifications. There has been much discussion as to what should be the relations in thought between rent and interest. Space permits here[Pg 151] only an indication of the view on this question involved in the foregoing treatment. Rent, as the term is here applied, includes all the net productivity attributable to the ownership and use of capital, whether the yield be in economic form (in an increment of value) or in contractual form. Even contract money-interest must be looked upon as a species of the genus contract rent, the peculiarity in the money loan being merely that the thing which it is agreed to return is a certain number of units of the standard money.

7. All the net benefits actually gained from wealth are rents; economic time-discount is never actual income; it’s just a way to calculate or anticipate the difference between current and future rewards. There’s been a lot of debate about how rent and interest should be related in thought. Space allows here[Pg 151] only for a brief mention of the perspective on this issue within the previous discussion. Rent, as we’re using the term, includes all the net productivity linked to owning and using capital, whether the return is in economic form (like a value increase) or in contractual form. Even contract money-interest should be seen as a type of contract rent, with the unique aspect of a money loan being that what’s agreed to be paid back is a specific number of units of standard currency.

The term "interest," first applied in the Middle Ages to a payment for the use of a money loan, came to be used more broadly by the earlier economists as the income attributable to those goods which generally were bought and sold in terms of money. In other words, interest was supposed (though erroneously) to be uniquely connected with the particular production instruments to which the term capital was narrowly and mistakenly confined. Still more to add to the confusion, the term interest was about this same time identified with the broad problem of time-value. The terminology has remained ever since in this stage of arrested development. Our suggestion is to retain the word interest in its original meaning, still almost universal in business circles, of a contractual payment on money loans, applying the term time-value (for lack of a better word) to the subtler economic problem.

The term "interest," originally used in the Middle Ages to describe a payment for borrowing money, has been applied more widely by early economists to refer to the income linked to goods that are typically bought and sold with money. In other words, interest was thought (though mistakenly) to be specifically tied to the production tools that the term capital was wrongly restricted to. Adding to the confusion, the term interest was also associated with the broader issue of time-value around the same period. This terminology has remained stuck in this state of confusion ever since. We suggest keeping the word interest in its original sense, which is still almost universally recognized in business contexts as a contractual payment on loans, and using the term time-value (for lack of a better term) for the more complex economic issue.

Rent and time-value are essentially different phrases of the value problem

Time-value is here understood to be that all-pervading difference in the values of uses and gratifications of wealth at different points of time. A comparison of the value of momently appearing uses of wealth is the rent problem. Here are, therefore, very different aspects of the value problem. The rent conception is earlier grasped by men, is nearer in point of logic; the concept of time-value has only recently been clearly recognized. If men lived only in the moment, they would be concerned only with rent; living in the future also, they are constantly regulating their acts with reference to time-value.

Time-value is understood as the ongoing difference in the value of how wealth is used and enjoyed at different points in time. Comparing the value of uses of wealth that arise at a specific moment is the rent issue. Thus, there are very different aspects to the value problem. The idea of rent is easier for people to grasp and is more straightforward logically, while the concept of time-value has only recently been clearly understood. If people lived only in the moment, they would focus solely on rent; however, since they also consider the future, they constantly adjust their actions based on time-value.


CHAPTER 18

RELATIVELY FIXED AND RELATIVELY INCREASABLE FORMS OF CAPITAL

§ I. HOW VARIOUS FORMS OF CAPITAL MAY BE INCREASED

The older and the modern way of viewing wealth

1. Men seek to increase income by increasing capital. Men may strive to increase their rents without expressing the rent-bearer in terms of capital. Peasant owners and small proprietors, toiling fondly on their little estates, seeking steadily a larger crop, a larger income, accomplish wonders in bringing waste land to a high state of cultivation. Working on the soil that is at once their livelihood and their home, they do not consciously reckon the value of the labor they are putting upon it. No money can buy that which to them is beyond price. But, in our money economy, efforts are largely directed toward the increase of the capital sum. Investment takes the form of putting in a sum of money in the hope of getting an income bearing a certain relation to it. The first thought is of the value of the wealth invested, which has been carefully measured and expressed in dollars and cents. Wealth looked at in the older way was valued for what it did immediately for its owner, for its concrete fruits; looked at in the modern way, it is valued as a marketable income-bearer readily convertible into a multitude of other forms. Thus investments come to be thought of in terms of general purchasing power, from which it is expected to realize an income of a given percentage.

1. People aim to boost their income by increasing their capital. Individuals may try to raise their rental income without relating it to capital. Small landowners and farmers, happily working on their small plots, constantly seek to grow bigger crops and earn more income, achieving remarkable results by turning barren land into productive fields. Since the soil is both their livelihood and home, they don’t consciously calculate the value of the labor they invest in it. No amount of money can buy what they consider priceless. However, in our money-driven economy, efforts are mainly focused on increasing the total capital. Investment means putting in a certain amount of money with the expectation of earning an income that corresponds to it. The first consideration is the value of the invested wealth, which has been carefully calculated in dollars and cents. In the past, wealth was valued based on what it did for its owner in the short term, based on its tangible benefits; today, it is valued as an income-generating asset easily convertible into various other forms. As a result, investments are viewed in terms of general purchasing power, from which a specific percentage of income is expected.

Free goods of unlimited supply
Beginning of scarcity of common materials

2. There are some classes of goods that can be increased without any noticeable increase in difficulty. The extremest[Pg 153] examples are undiminished goods such as air, sea-water, the water of large rivers. These are free goods because, however much is used, the supply is immediately renewed. But they are undiminished only in a relative sense and in reference to present need. The water in the Western rivers long flowed on, undiminished by the uses made of it. But progressing civilization required more water for cities, for mining, and for irrigation, and now states and corporations are going to law over these formerly undiminished free goods. Some kinds of goods are produced from such very common materials that it might seem possible, by the substitution of agents, to produce an unlimited supply. How can bricks be limited in number, being made as they are from one of the commonest materials on the earth's surface? But the largest clay banks are limited in size; a large proportion of the places where bricks are needed are not near a supply of clay of good quality; and after a brick-yard has been used for a time there is increasing difficulty in getting out the material. While, therefore, bricks are scarce and hard to get from the outset in some places, the scarcity grows more marked in many places at first well supplied. If materials are scarce in any degree, their continued use for one purpose increases their scarcity in all other uses. Economic goods are goods having value; value implies scarcity, and an increasing demand means inevitably a higher value at some point. This is true of clay, stone, water, and the commonest kinds of labor.

2. Some types of goods can be produced without any noticeable increase in difficulty. The extreme[Pg 153] examples are unlimited goods like air, seawater, and the water from large rivers. These are considered free goods because, no matter how much is used, the supply is quickly replenished. However, they are only unlimited in a relative sense and in relation to current needs. The water in the Western rivers flowed continuously, unaffected by how much was used. But as civilization progressed, more water was needed for cities, mining, and irrigation, leading to states and corporations disputing these once free resources. Some goods are made from such common materials that it seems possible to produce an endless supply by changing production methods. For instance, how can we limit the number of bricks since they are made from one of the most abundant materials on Earth's surface? But the largest clay deposits are finite; many places that need bricks aren't near a supply of good-quality clay, and after a brick yard has been in use for a while, it becomes harder to extract the material. Therefore, while bricks are initially scarce and difficult to obtain in some areas, the scarcity becomes more pronounced in many places that were once well supplied. If materials are scarce to any extent, their ongoing use for one purpose increases their scarcity for all other purposes. Economic goods are those that have value; value signifies scarcity, and as demand increases, a higher value is inevitable at some point. This applies to clay, stone, water, and the most common types of labor.

No scarce goods can be indefinitely increased

It has long been customary for economists to talk of economic goods that could be increased indefinitely (meaning infinitely or, in any event, without any limit ever appreciable to man) without any increase in the cost or scarcity. This class of goods was considered to be very large. There is no such class of economic goods; it is evidently impossible that there should be. If they are already "scarce," increasing demand must make them scarcer. There are, however, some goods that practically can be increased with so little difficulty[Pg 154] that their limitation is not of great social importance. Progress, population, prosperity, are not primarily conditioned on their amount; limitation will be felt far earlier elsewhere. They are at one end of the scale; they are the relatively increasable goods.

It has long been common for economists to discuss economic goods that could be increased endlessly (meaning infinitely or, at least, without any noticeable limit for humans) without any rise in cost or scarcity. This category of goods was thought to be very extensive. However, no such category of economic goods actually exists; it is clearly impossible for there to be. If they are already "scarce," an increase in demand will make them even scarcer. There are, nevertheless, some goods that can be increased with such minimal effort[Pg 154] that their limitation isn’t of significant social concern. Progress, population, and prosperity are not primarily dependent on their quantity; limitations will be felt much sooner in other areas. They represent one end of the scale; they are the relatively increasable goods.

The products of land are increased at a given time and place at increasing cost

3. There is a large class of goods whose increase is seen to be gained with increasing difficulty. This is seen most clearly in the diminishing returns from land. In the attempt to get some food-products in greater quantity from a given area at a given time, increasing difficulty is met with at once. This attempt continued for a series of years results in historical diminishing returns, as was strikingly illustrated in English experience during the Napoleonic wars, when wheat rose in value because of the greater difficulty of producing the larger supply needed. Some replenishing agents will restore themselves if given time; the forest will grow up if left untouched by man; the field will recover its fertile quality if allowed to lie fallow. But this self-replenishing of agents is a slow process, and time is costly. Man therefore tries in other ways to force more uses out of goods, until checked by the increasing difficulty. The goods subject to "the law of increasing cost," as it was called formerly, were considered to be a peculiar class comprising only a small portion of wealth. But it can now be seen that the law may apply ultimately, though in differing degrees, to every kind of economic goods. Indeed, the principle just discussed is no more than one phase of the law of economic diminishing returns, which has a universal application to the realm of values.

3. There is a large category of goods whose availability increases with growing difficulty. This is most evident in the diminishing returns from land. When trying to produce more food from a specific area at a specific time, one encounters increasing challenges right away. Continuing this effort over several years leads to historical diminishing returns, as vividly illustrated by England's experience during the Napoleonic wars, when the value of wheat rose due to the greater challenges in producing the larger supply that was needed. Some natural resources can replenish themselves if given time; forests will grow back if left undisturbed by humans; fields will regain their fertility if allowed to rest. However, this natural replenishment is a slow process, and time is expensive. Therefore, people seek other ways to extract more utility from goods, until hindered by the mounting difficulty. Goods affected by "the law of increasing cost," as it was previously termed, were thought to be a specific class that made up only a small fraction of wealth. But it's now clear that this law can ultimately apply, albeit in different degrees, to all types of economic goods. In fact, the principle just discussed is merely one aspect of the law of economic diminishing returns, which has a universal relevance in the realm of values.

Agents most nearly fixed in amount are somewhat increasable

4. There is a class of goods, natural agents and stores of materials which appears to be relatively fixed in quantity or which is increasable only with much difficulty. The first part of this proposition expresses mildly the thought that long obtained among economists: it was said that the supply of certain things was absolutely fixed, the chief of these being land used for agriculture. The idea as held by[Pg 155] Malthus and Ricardo was modified by John Stuart Mill in somewhat inconsistent ways. Land, it was said, is a thing which "man cannot make," therefore its supply is fixed. The second part of the opening proposition expresses the view here held: the supply of no important class of goods is absolutely fixed, in any reasonable sense. Most, if not all, belong to the class that is increasable, although it may be with much difficulty. Even when the exact thing cannot be duplicated, as a bust by an ancient sculptor or an autograph of a dead author, many substitutes serving the same or closely related wants, affect and limit the demand, and thus increase the supply. Men cannot, it is true, increase the stores of copper in the earth, but they devise new processes to extract it from ores before worthless, and invent methods of procuring aluminium, which yields some of the same utilities as copper. Even the supply of land, as is shown elsewhere, is constantly changing. Thus all kinds of wealth can be increased in some degree; many kinds in the course of time are very greatly increased with little or no direct effort, but the supply of all alike can be secured in larger amount at any given moment only at the cost of increasing difficulty.

4. There is a category of goods, natural resources, and material stocks that seems to be more or less fixed in quantity, or can only be increased with significant effort. The first part of this statement gently reflects a long-standing idea among economists: it has been said that the supply of certain items is completely fixed, the main example being land used for farming. The perspective held by[Pg 155] Malthus and Ricardo was altered by John Stuart Mill, albeit inconsistently. It was argued that land is something that "man cannot create," so its supply is fixed. The second part of the initial statement expresses the opinion presented here: no major category of goods has a supply that is absolutely fixed in any reasonable sense. Most, if not all, fall into the category that can be increased, even though it might be quite challenging. Even when an exact item can't be replicated, like a bust from an ancient sculptor or an autograph from a deceased author, numerous substitutes that fulfill similar or closely related needs can influence and limit demand, thereby boosting the supply. It's true that people can't increase the amount of copper in the ground, but they can develop new methods to extract it from previously worthless ores and invent processes to obtain aluminum, which serves similar purposes as copper. Even the supply of land, as discussed elsewhere, is always changing. Therefore, all forms of wealth can be expanded to some extent; many types can be significantly increased over time with little or no direct effort. However, obtaining a larger quantity of any wealth at a specific moment will always require greater difficulty.

§ II. SOCIAL SIGNIFICANCE OF THESE DIFFERENCES

Physical amount vs. economic supply

1. Not the fixity of the physical amount of agents, but the economic supply is significant. There is danger of confusion between these two ideas. The statement that "land" cannot be created and that therefore "the supply is fixed" involves a fallacy. The word supply means the amount that is available at the moment or during the period spoken of. The land in Greenland is not, and probably never can be, a part of the supply of land in England. The land in America for centuries was not, but now has become, for some purposes, a part of the supply in the same market as the land of England. The question of importance in economic[Pg 156] discussion is not whether the physical material can be brought into existence, but whether the economic "supply" can be increased. The existence of coal-mines in Venus or Mars is of no economic importance to us, but coal-mines on the earth, yet undiscovered, present a potential supply that at any moment may be realized.

1. It's not the fixed amount of physical resources that matters, but the economic supply. There’s a risk of mixing up these two concepts. The claim that "land" can't be created and that "the supply is fixed" is a misconception. The term supply refers to the amount available at the current time or during the specific period in question. The land in Greenland is not, and likely never will be, part of the land supply in England. The land in America wasn’t part of it for centuries, but now, for certain purposes, has become part of the supply in the same market as the land in England. In economic[Pg 156] discussions, the key issue isn’t whether physical materials can be created but whether the economic "supply" can be expanded. The existence of coal mines on Venus or Mars is irrelevant to us, but undiscovered coal mines on Earth represent a potential supply that could be tapped into at any moment.

Discovery enlarges the supply of natural resources

2. Discovery of new lands and of new natural deposits continually enlarges the economic supply of the agents most nearly fixed in physical amount. This proposition states a historical fact. Any explanation of the economic occurrences of the last five centuries or of the immediate future, that ignores this fact of the increasing supply of many kinds of land and natural resources in the markets of the civilized world, must lead to false conclusions. The rate of this movement has been more rapid in the past century than theretofore, and perhaps more rapid than it will be henceforward; but that this development will continue in large measure and for a long period, is not open to question. Undeveloped areas will be opened to the world, and new geologic realms will be explored. Yet the notion criticized above is found in all the older text-books. The idea arose in England in the first quarter of the nineteenth century when land and food were rapidly rising in price, and it has vitiated a large part of both the economic theory and the practical conclusions on this subject.

2. The discovery of new lands and natural resources continuously increases the economic supply of the most essential physical assets. This statement reflects a historical reality. Any analysis of the economic events of the last 500 years or predictions for the near future that overlooks the growing supply of various types of land and natural resources in the markets of the developed world will lead to incorrect conclusions. The pace of this expansion has been faster in the last century than ever before, and it may be faster than it will be in the future; however, there’s no doubt that this development will continue substantially for an extended period. Untapped regions will be integrated into the global market, and new geological areas will be investigated. Still, the above-mentioned misconception is prevalent in many older textbooks. This idea originated in England during the early 1800s when land and food prices were rising quickly, and it has distorted much of the economic theory and practical conclusions regarding this issue.

The effective supply grows by invention

3. Invention, including new modes of transportation and new processes, increases the economic supply of most scarce goods and provides substitutes for the others. Some inventions increase economic supply by making available the uses in goods that were before unavailable. Subsoil ploughing annexes to agricultural land new layers of soil that are just as important as new acres added to the surface. If land could be used three times as deep, it would be as good for many purposes as if it were of three times the extent. New trade routes and new means of transportation add to the supplies available in the older countries as effectively as if their areas were increased. The building of railroads[Pg 157] in western America had an effect on English rents identical in nature with that which would have been produced had an equal area of somewhat less fertile land touching England, risen out of the ocean. Every country in Europe has repeatedly felt the shock of these great economic changes which have compelled the recapitalization on a lower plane, of nearly all kinds of their landed wealth. Where the same agents have not been multiplied, substitutes have been found that are just as effective in meeting the economic need. It is the result, the gratification, that man seeks: any particular good is but the means to an end.

3. Invention, including new ways of transportation and processes, boosts the economic supply of most scarce goods and provides alternatives for others. Some inventions increase economic supply by making available the uses of goods that were previously unavailable. Subsoil plowing adds new layers of soil to agricultural land that are just as crucial as adding new acres to the surface. If land could be used three times deeper, it would be just as useful for many purposes as if its area were three times larger. New trade routes and new transportation methods increase the supplies available in older countries just as effectively as if their land size were expanded. The construction of railroads[Pg 157] in the western United States had an impact on English rents that was essentially the same as if an equal area of somewhat less fertile land had suddenly emerged from the ocean next to England. Every country in Europe has repeatedly experienced the shock of these significant economic changes, which have forced a recapitalization of nearly all types of their landed wealth at a lower level. Where the same resources have not multiplied, alternatives have been found that effectively meet economic needs. It’s the outcome, the satisfaction, that people are after: any specific good is just a means to an end.

Production of land by physical change

4. Increasing wealth and new labor make possible the increase of the agents that appear most nearly fixed in supply. When the need arises men turn to new enterprises. The reclaiming of land in Holland is a striking but far from isolated example. Among the larger undertakings of this kind are the draining of the Haarlem Lake in 1840-58, by which 40,000 acres of rich land were made available, and the draining of the Zuyder Zee, which is adding 1,300,000 acres. Though there have been many minor undertakings of the kind, the area reclaimed is relatively small compared with the whole area of the land in the world used for agricultural purposes. There are still great areas of fens, swamps, and marshlands, such as those on the Jersey coast in this country, which with moderate effort could be reclaimed. While the possibility must be recognized, the increase of the area of available agricultural land by means of such physical changes is relatively small.

4. More wealth and new labor make it possible to increase the resources that seem to be in fixed supply. When the need arises, people turn to new ventures. The reclamation of land in Holland is a notable, though not unique, example. Among the larger projects of this kind are the draining of Haarlem Lake from 1840 to 1858, which made 40,000 acres of fertile land available, and the draining of the Zuyder Zee, which is adding 1,300,000 acres. Although there have been many smaller projects like this, the amount of land reclaimed is relatively minor compared to the total area of land used for agriculture worldwide. There are still vast areas of fens, swamps, and marshlands, like those along the Jersey coast in the U.S., that could be reclaimed with moderate effort. While this potential should be acknowledged, the increase in available agricultural land through such physical changes is relatively limited.

And by the work of pioneers

The work of the pioneer, as a producer of a supply of land, is, however, of the greatest importance. The pioneer annexes new areas to the economic world and to the market in which he has lived. This is recognized of late by writers that perhaps do not fully mark its significance to economic theory. The work of the explorer and prospector is that of a producer of mineral resources, and daily market quotations reflect the changes in "the supply" of these natural stores.

The role of the pioneer, as someone who creates new land resources, is incredibly important. The pioneer adds new areas to the economic landscape and the market they've inhabited. Recently, writers have acknowledged this, though they may not completely grasp its significance to economic theory. The work of the explorer and prospector contributes to the production of mineral resources, and daily market prices show the fluctuations in the availability of these natural assets.

Successive utilization of various grades of agents

5. Limitation of the supply appears first in the better qualities, and efforts to increase wealth are then directed to making available the poorer grades. Great quantities of the poorer grades of wealth, even of those things that are relatively fixed in supply, lie unused. Great areas on the edge of civilization still await the pioneer, the prospector, and the miner. Here is a source of wealth and a field for enterprise. The growth of society may cause some of the poorer agents in time to become the best. When men crossed the ocean to settle on Manhattan Island, it was a wilderness; but the growth of commerce has caused the land in New York city to become more valuable than that in London. Changes are still in progress, for of late the smaller ports to the south have increased their trade at a more rapid pace than New York has.

5. At first, there's a limitation in the supply of better quality goods, and then efforts to build wealth shift toward making the lower-quality options available. Huge amounts of lower-quality resources, even those that are somewhat limited in supply, remain unused. Vast stretches of land on the fringe of civilization are still waiting for pioneers, prospectors, and miners. This presents a source of wealth and an opportunity for enterprise. As society evolves, some of the lesser resources may eventually become the most valuable. When people sailed across the ocean to settle on Manhattan Island, it was just a wilderness; however, the growth of commerce has transformed land in New York City into something more valuable than land in London. Changes are still happening, as recently the smaller ports to the south have seen their trade grow at a faster rate than New York.

Goods ranged on a scale of increasableness

The difference in increasableness of the various forms of wealth is of importance in considering various social questions such as the effects of an increase of population, and the kinds of taxation most equitable and most favorable to the progress of society. Account must be taken of the fact that the number of bricks can be increased more easily than the amount of land; but there must not be overlooked the possibility of increase in any of these forms of wealth, nor the limits to the increase of any one of them. When one wishes to save or increase wealth, he turns to these great unappropriated fields, unused things or things imperfectly used, and tries to convert them into effective agents. The different forms of wealth may be ranged on a scale according to the ease with which they can be increased by effort. They may therefore be classed as relatively fixed and relatively increasable. Some natural resources belong at one end, and some at the other end of this scale. No hard and fast line divides the different kinds of goods, but the difference in degree of increasableness is a fact of great social importance, affecting the direction in which industry can and must progress.

The difference in how easily various types of wealth can grow is important when thinking about social issues like the effects of population growth and the most equitable and beneficial ways to tax society. We need to recognize that you can increase the number of bricks more easily than the amount of land, but we also shouldn’t overlook the potential for growth in any type of wealth, nor the limitations on how much any one type can grow. When someone wants to save or increase wealth, they look to these large untapped areas, unused resources, or resources that aren’t being used to their full potential, and they try to turn them into productive assets. The different forms of wealth can be arranged on a scale based on how easily they can be increased through effort. They can therefore be categorized as relatively fixed and relatively increaseable. Some natural resources fit at one end of this scale, while others fit at the opposite end. There’s no strict boundary between the different kinds of goods, but the varying degrees of increaseability is a significant social fact that influences how industry can and must evolve.


CHAPTER 19

SAVING AND PRODUCTION AS AFFECTED BY THE RATE OF INTEREST

§ I. SAVING AS AFFECTED BY THE INTEREST RATE

The interest rate traces the division between present and future gratifications

1. In the case of consumption goods, present marginal uses are often less than future uses as judged at the present. The proposition that future goods sometimes have a greater instead of a less value than present goods may at first seem to deny the general fact of economic interest, which is a premium on present over future goods. The contradiction is only apparent, however, and the proposition is merely a proper interpretation of the theory of interest. The assertion that present goods have greater value than future goods, as we have accepted it, requires two explanations. First, it means that this difference exists when the two are judged and compared at the present moment. The future use when it matures may be much greater than the present use; indeed, the very existence of interest depends upon this surplus of value arising by the lapse of time in the future use. Secondly, the proposition does not mean that every concrete good, or every use of the goods, is worth more in the present than in the future; it means merely that the demand for present goods preponderates so that a market rate in favor of present possession prevails. In a great many cases a particular good may have a greater value to be kept for the future than to be used at present, in which case it is kept, or it is exchanged for something else having a higher value in the present. But this preference of the future over the[Pg 160] present cannot pass a moderate limit without condemning the person to present misery, and at length to death. On the other hand the excessive preference of present over future would lead to the using up and wearing out of wealth, to the present enjoyment of every possible resource, on the penalty of future misery. Evidently somewhere between these two extremes there must be, in each economy, a ratio of exchange between present and future, which in fact is the interest rate. This rate applied to utilities traces through each good a line analagous to the isothermal line on the map, marking off a zone of utilities for the present and other zones for each period of the future. There is thus a close relation between saving and the rate of time-discount.

1. When it comes to consumption goods, the current marginal uses are often less than the future uses when assessed now. The idea that future goods can sometimes be valued more highly than present goods might initially seem to contradict the common principle of economic interest, which favors present over future goods. However, this contradiction is only apparent; the idea simply reflects a correct understanding of the theory of interest. The claim that present goods are more valuable than future goods, as we have taken it, needs two clarifications. First, it means that this difference is recognized when both are evaluated and compared at the present moment. The future use, once it arrives, may be significantly higher than the current use; indeed, the existence of interest is based on this increased value that comes with the passage of time regarding future use. Second, the assertion doesn't imply that every specific good, or every use of goods, is worth more now than later; it simply indicates that the demand for present goods outweighs that for future goods, leading to a market tendency favoring present ownership. In many instances, a specific good could be more valuable if saved for the future rather than used now, in which case it is either kept or traded for something else that's worth more currently. However, overly valuing the future over the [Pg 160] present can lead to present suffering, ultimately resulting in hardship or death. Conversely, an extreme preference for the present could result in the depletion of wealth and the immediate consumption of all available resources, risking future hardship. Clearly, there must be a balance between these two extremes in every economy, establishing a ratio of exchange between present and future, which is essentially the interest rate. This rate applied to utility creates a pattern through each good similar to an isothermal line on a map, defining areas of utility for the present and additional areas for future periods. This illustrates a strong link between saving and the rate of time-discount.

Present VALUE feature
The less necessary goods are the ones saved

Let us illustrate by the case of fruit stored in the cellar for future use. In the fall after the appetite for apples has been gratified up to a certain point, there still remains a large stock which affords less gratification if consumed at once than if kept for a time. Thus wood, food, and clothing are stored in the summer for the winter's need. Even the animals act on this principle. Squirrels, bees, and ants store up in the season of superfluity for the season of scarcity. The animals recognize with their feeble intelligence or by instinct, that a time will come when these consumption goods will represent greater importance to their welfare than they do at the moment. It results from the nature of wants and[Pg 161] the principle of diminishing utility that in many cases some portion of a large supply of present goods must be worth less now than at a future time. This part, the marginal, less necessary part, will be left for a future time, and it is to this part that our opening proposition refers. This is roughly illustrated by the diagram.

Let’s consider the example of fruit stored in the cellar for later use. In the fall, after we've satisfied our craving for apples to a certain extent, there's still a lot left that gives us less enjoyment if eaten all at once rather than being stored for a while. Similarly, wood, food, and clothing are stockpiled in the summer to meet winter’s needs. Even animals follow this idea. Squirrels, bees, and ants gather supplies during times of plenty for times of scarcity. Animals, with their limited intelligence or instinct, realize that there will be a time when these resources will be more valuable to their well-being than they are now. This is due to the nature of wants and the principle of diminishing utility, which suggests that in many cases, part of a large supply of goods is worth less now than it will be in the future. This portion, the less essential part, will be saved for later, and this is what our initial statement refers to. This is roughly shown in the diagram.

Things that cannot be kept, perishable goods, do not permit of this comparison. But if goods that can be kept continue to be used after utility has fallen down the scale, their high value for the future is cast away. Man lives not alone in the present but, in a far greater measure than do any animals, he lives in the future also. His economic life and his economic judgment comprehend a great number of periods at once. With the aid of memory and imagination he forecasts the future, and compares it with the present. The diminishing utility of goods, therefore, is modified by this fact that a thing has want-gratifying power at different periods. Before man uses goods for an inferior purpose he will ask whether, if they are kept for the future, they will not gratify a greater want.

Things that can't be stored, like perishable items, can't be compared in this way. However, if items that can be stored are still used after their usefulness has decreased, their potential future value is lost. Humans don’t just live in the present; much more so than animals, they also live in the future. Their economic life and judgment take into account multiple time periods at once. With memory and imagination, they anticipate the future and compare it to the present. Therefore, the decreasing utility of goods is influenced by the fact that an item can satisfy needs at different times. Before someone uses goods for a lesser purpose, they'll consider whether keeping them for the future might satisfy a greater need.

The less valuable rise in value with the lapse of time

2. The gradual rise of a consumption good with the lapse of time from the lower to the higher degree of gratification is the rent it yields. The difference in value of present and future rents is expressed by the discount of the future use when it is capitalized at any earlier moment, and emerges in the rise in value as the thing approaches to the time when it can render the later use. Next year the unit whose use is deferred will afford as much gratification as the earlier units do now, and more than if used at the present moment. The importance of any present utility is compared with its importance a year later, plus interest at a rate which expresses the limit to which future uses are discounted. Anything that makes men feel more the importance of future uses causes them to value those uses more. But the pressure of present want is such that a present use of a lower order competes with a future use of a higher order. Only goods of[Pg 162] a lower order, nearer the margin, are reserved for the future. But just as the possibility of using a thing for several different purposes at present causes it to be valued more highly than if it had but one use, so the possibility of reserving to the future a portion of a stock imparts to every unit a higher marginal utility.

2. The gradual increase in the value of a consumption good over time, moving from a lower to a higher level of satisfaction, is the rent it generates. The difference in value between present and future rents is shown by the discount of future use when it's calculated at any earlier time, and it becomes evident as the value increases as the time approaches when it can provide the later use. Next year, the unit whose use is postponed will provide as much satisfaction as the earlier units do now, and even more than if used at this moment. The significance of any present utility is compared with its significance a year from now, plus interest at a rate that reflects how much future uses are discounted. Anything that makes people more aware of the importance of future uses leads them to value those uses more. However, the pressure of present needs is so strong that a current use of a lower value competes with a future use of a higher value. Only goods of[Pg 162] a lower value, closer to the margin, are set aside for the future. But just like the ability to use a thing for multiple purposes right now makes it more valuable than if it had only one use, the ability to reserve part of a stock for the future gives every unit a higher marginal utility.

Interest is the equalizer of time values

3. The saving of present goods for future use is encouraged by the motive of gaining the interest. Many consumption goods grow into higher uses in the hands of the owner, whether he uses them for himself or not. Ice may be stored in midwinter when it is all but a free good and a little labor serves to fill the ice-house. Kept until the summer months, the ice rises in value as the desire for it grows. Likewise the higher price secured by the owner of a thing kept for sale to others, reflects the change in utility, and affords practically a rent which is the motive for investing capital in that business. Any saver or abstainer puts aside present wants only when the future good, with the addition of time-value or of money interest, appears as large as the present good. Interest is therefore the equalizer of the value of things in different periods. Put into the scale of judgment when present and future are compared, it helps to balance the disparity in the gratifications given by economic goods in different periods of time.

3. Saving current goods for future use is motivated by the desire to earn interest. Many consumption goods can be used for more valuable purposes by the owner, whether they use them personally or not. Ice can be stored during the winter when it's almost free, and a little effort can fill the ice-house. When kept until the summer, the ice increases in value as demand rises. Similarly, the higher price achieved by someone selling an item reflects the change in its usefulness and provides a kind of rent that motivates capital investment in that business. Anyone who saves or refrains from consumption sets aside current needs only when the future benefit, plus the time value or interest, seems to be equal to the present benefit. Interest, therefore, serves to equalize the value of things across different time periods. When comparing present and future, it helps to balance the differences in satisfaction provided by economic goods at different times.

Saving increases and improves economic agents

4. The postponement of present wants results in bettering the economic environment for the future. Economic environment means simply the economic conditions in which men live, the stock of wealth, the supply of useful things with which they are surrounded. This betterment may be only temporary, only for the immediate future. Like the busy bee or the prudent ant, one may in summer store the cellar with consumption goods to be consumed the following winter. But often there is a more lasting way of improving the economic environment by converting savings into durable indirect agents. The accumulation of wealth that will yield its fruits only after years of growth is the record, so[Pg 163] to speak, of the successful competition of forethought with present desires. It means that the two periods have presented their respective claims and that men have decided in favor of the future. Saving thus lifts society from poverty to wealth by the progressive enlargement of the sources of future utilities.

4. Delaying immediate desires leads to improving the economic climate for the future. The economic climate simply refers to the economic conditions in which people live, the wealth available, and the supply of useful things they have around them. This improvement might only be temporary, serving just the near future. Like the busy bee or the wise ant, one may stock up on goods in summer for use during the winter. However, there is often a more lasting way to enhance the economic climate by turning savings into long-lasting indirect resources. The accumulation of wealth that will provide benefits only after years of growth is the record, so[Pg 163] to speak, of successfully prioritizing long-term planning over immediate cravings. It means that both time frames have made their respective cases, and people have chosen to invest in the future. Saving, therefore, elevates society from poverty to wealth by progressively expanding the sources of future utilities.

The kinds of abstinence

5. Abstinence is the faculty of mind that enables present wants to be subordinated to future wants. Abstinence may be considered as a quality, or faculty, of the mind, or as an act resulting from that quality. There is little danger of confusion in this usage, but it is well to note the distinction and the fact that the former is the primary meaning. Abstinence expresses an act of the will, a choice made by man. It is the guardian of the future, so to speak, against the greediness of the present. For convenience we may speak of conservative abstinence as that which keeps men from using up or invading their present stock of resources, and of cumulative abstinence as that which impels them to add to that stock. There is no sharp dividing line, no abrupt break, between these two, yet on the whole they differ. There is a quality of mind very like the inertia or momentum of physical matter. The inertia of mind makes men resist stubbornly the reduction of wealth and of inherited social position; but it requires a more positive quality of mind to add to wealth at the cost of present sacrifice. Abstinence is embodied in individuals, never elsewhere, and is found in most varying degrees of strength. Upon it depends the growth and betterment of man's environment.

5. Abstinence is the ability of the mind that allows current desires to be set aside for future desires. Abstinence can be seen as a quality or capability of the mind, or as an action that comes from that quality. There’s little risk of confusion in this definition, but it’s important to highlight the difference, with the former being the primary meaning. Abstinence represents an act of will, a choice made by individuals. It's like a protector of the future against the immediate temptations of the present. For simplicity, we might refer to conservative abstinence as the kind that prevents people from depleting or encroaching on their current resources, and cumulative abstinence as that which motivates them to increase those resources. There isn’t a clear boundary or sudden shift between these two, yet they generally differ. There’s a mindset that resembles the inertia or momentum of physical matter. The inertia of the mind makes people stubbornly resist losing wealth and inherited social status; however, it takes a more proactive mindset to add to wealth at the expense of immediate gratification. Abstinence exists within individuals, never outside them, and it varies in strength. The growth and improvement of humanity’s surroundings rely on it.

§ II. CONDITIONS FAVORABLE TO SAVING

Political insecurity discourages saving

1. Political security and domestic order are essential to the development of saving. As saving results from a comparison of the future with the present, any lack of certainty regarding the future decreases the appeal it makes. Men employ roughly the theory of probabilities in this matter,[Pg 164] and count a utility only half as much when there is but one chance in two of enjoying it. In countries where there are constant revolutions and border wars, as in Africa and South America, and in lands where brigandage is common, as in Italy, Macedonia, and Bulgaria, the motive for saving is cut in two. Oppressive and irregular taxation kills the motives of providence, and decreases the appeal made by the future. While the miserable subjects of the state live from hand to mouth, the very sources of the public revenue disappear. Improvidence grows upon such a people into a prevailing national custom; ambition is wanting; industry is the sport of chance; economic order and economic prosperity are impossible.

1. Political security and domestic order are crucial for saving to thrive. Since saving depends on comparing the future to the present, any uncertainty about the future makes it less appealing. People generally use a kind of probability theory in this situation,[Pg 164] valuing a benefit only half as much if there's only a 50% chance of receiving it. In countries experiencing constant revolutions and border conflicts, like in Africa and South America, or in places where robbery is widespread, such as Italy, Macedonia, and Bulgaria, the motivation to save is severely diminished. Heavy and inconsistent taxation undermines the desire to save and reduces the future's appeal. While the unfortunate citizens struggle to survive day by day, the very sources of public revenue vanish. Irresponsibility becomes a common national trait; ambition fades away; work becomes a gamble; economic stability and prosperity become unattainable.

Influence of private property on saving

2. Social institutions that give a motive to the individual are essential to saving. Among these institutions the most important are the family and, closely connected with it, the institution of private property which, in its ideal manifestation, places the responsibility for economic welfare on the individual or the family. Through it the state says to men: "Save if you will; the wealth and its fruits shall be yours. But if you spend and consume all you can, you alone will suffer the consequences." It is true that the institution of private property never is found in an ideal form. Dishonest public officials weaken and defeat its benefits. Every propertyless family marks a failure in its purpose. Private property is a favorite object of attack by social reformers, but it never can be safely abolished in a civilized state until some other incentive is provided, equally effective to make men subordinate present desires to future welfare. Unless the mass of men can be greatly changed, property creates the only motive that can induce saving regularly and on a large scale. It diffuses responsibility for present consumption. It multiplies the motives for abstinence and thus increases the welfare of all economic society.

2. Social institutions that motivate individuals are essential for saving. Among these, the family is the most important, along with the institution of private property, which ideally puts the responsibility for economic well-being on individuals or families. Through this, the state tells people: "Save if you want; the wealth and its benefits will be yours. But if you spend and use everything you have, you alone will face the consequences." It's true that private property is rarely found in its ideal form. Dishonest public officials undermine its advantages. Each family without property reflects a failure in its purpose. Private property is often targeted by social reformers, but it can't be safely eliminated in a civilized society until another equally effective incentive is provided to encourage people to prioritize future well-being over immediate desires. Unless a significant change occurs in the general population, property creates the only motivation that can lead to regular and substantial saving. It spreads responsibility for present consumption, increases the reasons for self-restraint, and thus enhances the welfare of the entire economic society.

Safe and paying investments encourage saving

3. Opportunity for the investment of small savings favors a spirit of abstinence. The institution of small property,[Pg 165] peasant proprietorship, worked powerfully in this direction in many parts of Europe, and the same effects have resulted in America from the wide diffusion of property in land. If the decline in the number of small independent farmers has somewhat weakened this influence in America, in other ways other agencies are effectively performing the same functions. Savings-banks, penny banks, building and loan associations, penny-provident funds, and other convenient means of investing small sums, encourage men to reduce their tobacco bills, their candy bills, their saloon bills, and to lay aside for the winter's coal, for the children's education, for houses, for business investments, or for old age. Probably no one thing has given a greater stimulus to saving than has the development of insurance and the endowment policies in connection with it. While the great modern corporations have destroyed many of the small business enterprises into which so much of the saving of the past was put, at the same time the increase of negotiable paper, of loans, and of stock in joint-stock companies, has opened up other large fields for investors.

3. Opportunities for investing small savings promote a mindset of saving. The establishment of small property, [Pg 165] peasant ownership, had a strong impact in many parts of Europe, and similar outcomes have occurred in America due to the widespread ownership of land. Although the decrease in the number of small independent farmers has slightly diminished this influence in America, other means are effectively serving the same role. Savings banks, penny banks, building and loan associations, penny provident funds, and other accessible ways to invest small amounts encourage people to cut back on their tobacco, candy, and bar expenses, and to save for winter coal, children's education, homes, business investments, or retirement. It's likely that nothing has motivated saving more than the growth of insurance and associated endowment policies. While large modern corporations have eliminated many small businesses where past savings were invested, the rise of negotiable notes, loans, and stock in joint-stock companies has created new opportunities for investors.

Changing interest rate in relation to saving

4. Variations in the rate of discount of the future react upon the spirit of saving in various ways. This very general proposition requires more detailed discussion. In general, a high rate of interest gives a large motive to save, for as the discount on the future is large, so is the reward for waiting. But this favoring motive may be offset by other unfavorable conditions, and is, in fact, wherever the high rate continues. In countries backward economically, where war, brigandage, and political oppression prevail, the rate of interest is frequently ten and twelve per cent. on the best secured loans. A high interest rate does not of itself insure a high degree of cumulative abstinence; it is only one of several factors. But in a new and favored country like America, a high rate of interest is a strong stimulus to saving. Again, interest may fall while saving continues at the same or a greater pace. Ordinarily a fall from six per cent. to five,[Pg 166] giving men a smaller motive for abstinence, would be expected to cause less saving, yet this is not always the case. Custom and example help to fix a habit of saving in individuals and cause them to continue saving at a lower rate of interest. With the growth of wealth, the prevailing ideas as to the amount needed for a competence change, impelling to greater saving. The tendency, however, of a fall in the rate of interest is to weaken, and that of a rise of the rate, other things being equal, is to strengthen the motive to save. But the influence of the interest rate on saving is relative to the character of men.

4. Changes in the discount rate of the future impact saving behavior in various ways. This broad statement requires more in-depth discussion. Generally, a high interest rate provides a strong incentive to save since a larger discount on the future means a greater reward for waiting. However, this incentive can be countered by other negative factors, especially when the high rate persists. In economically underdeveloped countries, where war, crime, and political oppression are common, interest rates often reach ten to twelve percent on the safest loans. A high interest rate doesn't automatically ensure a significant level of savings; it’s just one of several influencing factors. However, in a new and prosperous country like America, a high interest rate serves as a strong motivator for saving. Furthermore, interest can decrease while saving remains constant or even increases. Typically, a drop from six percent to five percent,[Pg 166] which reduces the incentive to save, would be expected to result in decreased savings, but this isn't always true. Habits of saving can be established through custom and role models, leading individuals to continue saving even at lower interest rates. As wealth grows, people's perceptions of the amount needed to feel secure change, driving them to save more. Nevertheless, falling interest rates generally weaken the saving motive, while rising rates, all else being equal, tend to strengthen it. However, the effect of interest rates on saving varies depending on individual characteristics.

§ III. INFLUENCE OF THE INTEREST RATE ON METHODS OF PRODUCTION

Saving permits improvement of agents

1. The individual saver is enabled to improve the agents that he uses. The simplest case is presented when means of enjoyment are improved and made more durable. If Crusoe on his island spends less time and fewer resources on gratifying his immediate wants, he may improve the quality of his clothing and the convenience of his house and furniture. By thus putting his consumption goods into durable instead of temporary forms, he will increase eventually the sum of utilities enjoyed. Again, abstinence permits the tools of the laborer to be made more convenient. If the farmer spends less time in the garden and he and his family live on plainer food, while he makes a plow, mends a rake, and builds a shed, he will be enabled thereafter to gather a greater crop with less effort.

1. The individual saver can enhance the tools they use. The simplest scenario occurs when enjoyment tools are improved and made more durable. If Crusoe on his island spends less time and fewer resources satisfying his immediate needs, he can enhance the quality of his clothing and the comfort of his house and furniture. By turning his consumption goods into durable rather than temporary forms, he will eventually increase the total enjoyment he experiences. Additionally, saving allows the laborer's tools to become more efficient. If the farmer spends less time in the garden and he and his family eat simpler meals while making a plow, repairing a rake, and building a shed, he will be able to harvest a larger crop with less effort afterward.

Saving of consumption goods for exchange

2. Consumption goods, when saved, may be exchanged for services, and these may be used to create durable agents. Various ways are open to one wishing to increase his stock of durable agents. He may forego seeking immediate enjoyments while he makes durable agents himself. Or he may make and save a stock of consumption goods, a surplus supply for the future, and exchange it for durable agents.[Pg 167] Finally, one who has accumulated consumption goods can always exchange them for the services of those seeking subsistence and enjoyment; and thus in control of a labor force, he can direct it toward the production of new forms of productive agents.

2. When saved, consumption goods can be traded for services, which can then be used to create durable assets. There are various strategies for someone looking to increase their stock of durable assets. They can choose to skip immediate pleasures while they create durable assets themselves. Alternatively, they can produce and save a stock of consumption goods, creating a surplus for the future, and trade it for durable assets.[Pg 167] Lastly, anyone who has accumulated consumption goods can always trade them for the services of those in need of basic living and enjoyment; by doing so, they can manage a workforce and direct it toward the production of new types of productive assets.

Money savings are converted into other wealth

3. In modern industry, saving frequently takes the form of money, which is then loaned to productive borrowers. This is the typical form of saving in modern industry. As it is more and more the case that income takes first the form of money, saving most conveniently takes the money form. The clerk on a salary of $60 a month spends $50 and saves $10 which he lends to a neighbor or deposits in a savings-bank. The borrower is thus empowered to increase his stock of productive agents in the measure that the lender has limited his consumption. The complexity of the process by which money saving becomes embodied through a money loan in new productive agents should not blind to its real nature. The money is saved as a means to the exchange of present goods for future income. Money even in our day is occasionally stored away for future use under hearthstones or in old stockings and hollow trees, but this is a primitive and wasteful method, involving the loss of all the additional rents that its exchange and investment would yield.

3. In today's industry, saving usually means money, which is then loaned to productive borrowers. This is the standard way of saving in modern industry. As it becomes more common for income to come first as money, saving most often takes the form of cash. A clerk earning $60 a month spends $50 and saves $10, which he either lends to a neighbor or deposits in a savings bank. The borrower can then increase their resources because the lender has chosen to limit their consumption. The complexity of how money saving translates into new productive resources through a loan shouldn't distract us from its true nature. The money is saved as a means to trade present goods for future income. Even today, people sometimes stash money for future use under hearthstones, in old stockings, or hollow trees, but this is a primitive and wasteful method, resulting in the loss of all the extra returns that its exchange and investment would generate.

If the money saved by the thrifty saver is loaned to a thriftless borrower, wealth is not increased, but merely changes hands. The prodigal mortgaging his wealth, spending the money, and living beyond his income, absorbs the savings of the other. One saves and adds to wealth, the other consumes it. There is no net increase of goods, but two individuals have shifted positions; each has gotten his reward of growing affluence or penury.

If the money saved by a careful saver is lent to a careless borrower, wealth doesn't actually grow; it just changes hands. The spender who borrows against his wealth, uses the money, and lives beyond his means is simply consuming what the other has saved. One person saves and increases wealth, while the other just spends it. There's no overall increase in goods, but the two people have swapped roles; each has received their reward of either growing wealth or poverty.

The "normal" end, however, of savings and loans is productive. The borrower, in getting control of purchasing power, aims to put a new machine where it will be useful, to remove obstacles, and to make economic agents more effective. Along the border-land of industry the active and[Pg 168] alert borrower seeks out opportunities to make new agents earn a rental, and having found the opening, turns to the money market for the means to profit by it.

The typical outcome of savings and loans, however, is productive. The borrower, by gaining purchasing power, aims to install a new machine where it can be useful, eliminate obstacles, and enhance the effectiveness of economic agents. Right on the edge of industry, the active and[Pg 168] alert borrower looks for opportunities to make new agents generate income, and once they identify a chance, they turn to the money market for the funds to take advantage of it.

Lower interest means higher capitalization

4. A fall in the rate of interest normally accompanies an increase in the mass, efficiency, and valuation of durable economic agents. A lower rate of interest means a higher capitalization of all incomes. It is not that either can be called the cause of the other; rather both are aspects of the same thing, the interest rate merely registering the change in capitalization. If the rate of interest has been five per cent., an income of $100 has been capitalized at $2000. When the rate falls to four per cent. the income is recapitalized at $2500. All along the line of investment there is an increase in the value of the durable economic agents.

4. A drop in interest rates usually comes with an increase in the quantity, efficiency, and value of lasting economic assets. A lower interest rate translates to a higher valuation of all incomes. It's not that one causes the other; instead, both are aspects of the same phenomenon, with the interest rate simply reflecting the change in valuation. If the interest rate has been five percent, an income of $100 is valued at $2000. When the rate drops to four percent, the income is valued at $2500. Throughout the investment landscape, there is a rise in the value of durable economic assets.

And more complex industrial processes
It encourages the increase of fixed charges to reduce cost of operation

Another phase of the change is the greater complexity of the processes of industry. Production becomes technically more complex when interest falls. Rental, product, and present goods, bear a smaller ratio to the value of capital, and therefore it becomes advantageous to apply newly formed capital to uses which before did not justify the investment. Where formerly the utility of a second tool did not justify its making, now it can be made to earn the smaller rental needed to balance its capital value. One form, therefore, which the change takes, is a multiplication of the tools already used. Things are placed wherever most convenient. Another form this change takes is the putting of new links into the chain of technical production. Cost of operation constantly is compared with fixed charges, the interest with the capital investment. Expensive improvements on railroads, the straightening of curves, the tunneling of mountains, the reducing of grades, the replacement of lighter by heavier rails, have been made possible by a fall in the rate of interest. A fall in the rate of interest disturbs the equilibrium that has been arrived at, between the cost of operation, the amount paid for wages, coal, etc., and the income on permanent investment. If the rate of interest[Pg 169] has been five per cent. and falls to four per cent. many permanent improvements before unwise become economical. One thousand dollars paid annually in wages then balanced an interest charge on a capital investment of $20,000; now it balances the interest charge on $25,000. It becomes a paying thing for the railroad to abandon or throw aside an enormous capital represented by the old, less perfect roadbed, and build a new one alongside of it. The changes of this kind one sees in traveling on the great and progressive railroads, reflect in part the growth of traffic, but in part also a change of the interest rate, making it a net saving to increase the capital investment in order to reduce the cost of operation per unit of traffic.

Another phase of the change is the increasing complexity of industrial processes. Production becomes more technically complicated when interest rates drop. Rental, products, and current goods represent a smaller proportion of capital value, making it beneficial to invest newly formed capital in areas that previously didn’t justify the expense. Where the usefulness of an additional tool didn’t warrant its production before, it can now generate enough income to cover the lower rental needed to offset its capital value. Thus, one way this change manifests is through a multiplication of existing tools. Items are placed wherever they are most convenient. Another way this change occurs is by adding new links to the production chain. Operational costs are constantly weighed against fixed charges, comparing interest with capital investments. Costly upgrades to railroads, like straightening curves, tunneling mountains, leveling grades, and replacing lighter rails with heavier ones, have become feasible due to declining interest rates. A drop in interest rates disrupts the balance that had been achieved between operating costs, including wages, coal, and other expenses, and the income generated from permanent investments. If the interest rate has been five percent and falls to four percent, many permanent improvements that once seemed impractical become cost-effective. A thousand dollars spent on wages now offsets an interest charge on a capital investment of $25,000, as opposed to the previous $20,000. It becomes financially viable for a railroad to abandon or disregard significant capital represented by the old, less efficient roadbed and build a new one alongside it. The transformations seen while traveling on major, progressive railroads reflect both the increase in traffic and the shift in interest rates, making it a worthwhile investment to raise capital to reduce per-unit operating costs.

Diffused benefits of saving

The benefits of saving viewed broadly are not confined to the owner of the wealth saved, but are diffused throughout society, in the degree that they increase and improve the industrial environment, and thus raise the efficiency of production. Such a change works the same results as would a magical increase in the fertility of the soil, an improvement in the richness and accessibility of natural mineral stores, or in the quantity and quality of artificial appliances.

The advantages of saving, when looked at widely, aren’t just limited to the person who saves the money; they spread throughout society because they enhance and improve the production environment, boosting efficiency. This kind of change produces the same effects as if there were a magical boost in soil fertility, an enhancement in the richness and accessibility of natural resources, or a rise in the quantity and quality of manufactured tools.


PART II

THE VALUE OF HUMAN SERVICES


DIVISION A—LABOR AND WAGES


CHAPTER 20

LABOR AND CLASSES OF LABORERS

§ I. RELATION OF LABOR TO WEALTH

Work and play defined and distinguished

1. Labor is any human effort having an aim or purpose outside of itself. It is difficult to define satisfactorily the term labor. No definition will quite mark off all the cases. The efforts put forth by men may be classified according as they are pleasant in themselves, and according as they have separable useful results. These two factors combine to form four groups of actions.

1. Labor is any human effort directed towards a goal beyond itself. It’s tough to define the term labor properly. No definition will fully capture all the instances. The efforts made by people can be categorized based on whether they're enjoyable in themselves and whether they have separate useful outcomes. These two factors come together to create four groups of actions.

EffortObjective result soughtName of action
1. PleasurableNot usefulPlay
2. PleasurableUsefulLabor
3. PainfulUsefulLabor
4. PainfulNot usefulNo special name

The fourth combination is not found in rational life, for no motive exists to do a painful act for a useless result. Let us consider the other three.

The fourth combination isn't found in real life, because there's no reason to go through something painful for a pointless result. Let's look at the other three.

Play

The first group comprises most of the sports, games, and pastimes found in every land and time. In the mere putting forth of the powers of mind and muscle there is a joy felt by children and men of all races, and this is heightened by companionship, emulation, and even by a spice of danger.[Pg 174] Play is not dependent on a useful objective result later to be enjoyed, but, like beauty, is its own excuse for being. The tired student goes out-of-doors to bat the tennis-ball, making no change in the material world, except to wear out his shoes and to lose the ball, but finding that hour rich in the joy of life. If properly chosen, play strengthens and vivifies both soul and body, leaving an afterglow of health and happiness. The choice of sports and temperance in their pursuit are among the surest tests of wisdom in men and in societies. A love of vigorous play no less than the power of sustained work, marks the dominant and progressive peoples of the earth.

The first group includes most of the sports, games, and activities found everywhere throughout history. Simply using one’s mind and body brings joy to both children and adults of all backgrounds, and this joy is enhanced by friendship, competition, and even a bit of risk.[Pg 174] Play doesn’t rely on achieving a useful outcome later; like beauty, it exists for its own sake. A tired student steps outside to hit a tennis ball, not changing the world in any significant way—just scuffing his shoes and losing the ball—but finding that hour full of the joy of life. If chosen wisely, play strengthens and energizes both the mind and body, leaving a lasting sense of health and happiness. The selection of sports and moderation in their pursuit are among the best indicators of wisdom in individuals and societies. A passion for active play, just like the ability to work hard, characterizes the leading and progressive peoples of the world.

Labor as pleasure

Acts in the second group give pleasure and at the same time leave an objective result. The hunter gets more pleasure if he returns with well-filled bags of game, but the distinction between the sportsman and the "pot-hunter" is not hard to find. The one has his joy in the sport, the other in the material results of the sport. This kind of action presents some puzzling cases, but in general must be classed as labor, since labor is to be judged by the objective economic results rather than by the pleasure of the act itself.

Acts in the second group provide enjoyment while also producing a tangible outcome. The hunter feels more satisfaction if he comes back with a full bag of game, but it's easy to tell the difference between a true sportsman and a "pot-hunter." One finds joy in the experience of the sport, while the other focuses on the material rewards. This type of action may raise some confusing situations, but overall, it should be classified as work, since work is evaluated based on the actual economic results rather than the enjoyment of the activity itself.

Labor as sacrifice

In a third class are the acts that are painful in themselves, that are done unwillingly, but that leave a pleasurable result. Unfortunately a large part of the actions of men are of this class, which to most minds is the typical labor.

In a third category are the actions that are inherently painful, done begrudgingly, but result in something enjoyable. Unfortunately, a significant portion of human actions falls into this category, which most people consider typical work.

Joy in work is the ideal

There is thus labor that is pleasurable in itself and labor that is painful though it leads to a desirable result. The social ideal clearly is that all human labor should be made pleasurable. Social dreamers love to picture a day when all shall find for effort a full reward in the mere doing,—the reward of the artist, of the scholar, of the saint, in addition to the objective result in economic wealth. Probably we are slowly nearing this ideal. Not only in the professions and in the esthetic arts, but in commerce, in mechanics, and in the humblest walks of life are found men free from envy,[Pg 175] rejoicing in their daily tasks. Such is the normal feeling of the healthy optimist. And yet in every serious occupation there are numberless moments and occasions when the spirit flags and only hard necessity holds men to their tasks. The dilettante does not go far or long or steadily; the real tasks of the world are done by men that labor, now with joy, now wearily.

There’s enjoyable work and work that’s tough but leads to something good. The social ideal is that all human work should be enjoyable. Visionaries love to imagine a future where everyone feels fully rewarded just by doing their job—like artists, scholars, and saints—on top of the economic benefits. We’re probably slowly moving towards this ideal. Not just in professions and the arts, but in business, mechanics, and even the simplest jobs, there are people who are free from envy, finding joy in their daily tasks. This is the typical mindset of a healthy optimist. Yet, in every serious job, there are countless moments when motivation wanes, and only sheer necessity keeps people going. The dabbler doesn’t go far, long, or steadily; the real work of the world is done by those who labor, sometimes joyfully, sometimes with fatigue.

The distinction between men and things

2. The agents of production compose two great species, material goods and human services. Our discussion of consumption goods, rent, and interest has been an analysis of the nature and uses of material goods. We now come to the other great species, human services, which comprise those acts of men (one's own or other's) that minister to the gratification of wants. There are also misdirected efforts, and evil deeds which are "disutilities" to all but the doer.

2. The agents of production consist of two main types: material goods and human services. Our discussion of consumer goods, rent, and interest has focused on the nature and functions of material goods. Now, we turn to the other major type, human services, which include the actions of people (either your own or others') that satisfy their needs. There are also misguided efforts and harmful actions that only benefit the person carrying them out, creating "disutilities" for everyone else.

The distinction between men and things is fundamental in modern economic discussion where each man is looked upon as free. It is not so clear where slavery exists and the master looks in the same way upon the services of his cattle, of his chattel slaves, and of his land. Even in the freest society, man's services are compared purely as to their utility, with the uses of other parts of the material world. It is said that the price of mules at the Pennsylvania mines has been affected by immigration, because a man and a mule sometimes represent interchangeable services. But in the study of political economy the distinction between men and other material things must never be lost sight of; they are the two fundamental classes of economic agents, the one being solely a means to an end, the other being an end in itself.

The difference between people and objects is crucial in today’s economic conversations, where each person is viewed as free. It gets murky when slavery is involved, as the owner sees the contributions of his animals, enslaved individuals, and land in the same way. Even in the most liberated societies, people's efforts are evaluated solely for their usefulness, just like other resources in the physical world. It’s noted that mule prices at the Pennsylvania mines have been influenced by immigration because sometimes a person and a mule can provide similar services. However, in studying political economy, we must always keep in mind the distinction between people and material objects; they are the two essential types of economic agents, with one being just a means to an end and the other being an end in itself.

Rent and wages mutually affect each other

3. Labor and material wealth are complementary and indispensable to each other in most of their uses. The discussion of material wealth and its value apart from the subject of labor, of the problem of rent and interest apart from that of wages, does not imply that this material wealth would have the same value in real life if labor were absent. As one field affects the value of another field, and one good,[Pg 176] by substitution, the value of another good, so does labor affect material wealth. Some material wealth can be used apart from labor, but most of it must be used in combination with some labor. Rent, therefore, is not determined in concrete cases apart from men and their services. It is allowable, however, in abstract analysis, to simplify the question by leaving out a difficult complication, and thus to set forth more clearly the logical bearing and effect of a certain factor.

3. Labor and material wealth work hand in hand and are essential to each other in most cases. Discussing material wealth and its value separately from labor, or looking at rent and interest without considering wages, doesn’t mean that material wealth would hold the same value in the real world if labor didn’t exist. Just as one field influences the value of another field and one good,[Pg 176] through substitution, the value of another good, labor similarly impacts material wealth. Some material wealth can stand alone without labor, but most of it needs to be paired with some level of labor. Therefore, rent isn't determined in specific situations without considering people and their services. However, in abstract analysis, it’s acceptable to simplify the issue by excluding a complex complication, allowing for a clearer presentation of the logical implications and effects of a particular factor.

Certain shares of the product are logically attributed to each

Each of two kinds of agents used together affects the utility of the other, and the value of the product. If neither can be credited with the whole value, how is any distribution to be made between them? It is not possible to measure their technical services in the product, but it usually is possible to gage their marginal utility under particular conditions. Flour, water, and labor are needed to make biscuits; but water being a free agent, does not enter into the combination with any marginal utility. A match also is almost indispensable to start the fire (and who has not seen the time when he would give far more for a match than for a bucket of coal), but as things usually are, the match is credited with a value of a very small fraction of a cent. Again, how is to be measured the economic service of the tree and of the labor needed for gathering its fruits? There is here suggested the superficial aspect of what is known as the problem of complementary values. Where two or more things are indispensable to a product, how much shall be credited to each?

Each of the two types of agents used together impacts the utility of the other and the value of the product. If neither can claim the entire value, how is any distribution supposed to be made between them? It's not feasible to quantify their technical contributions to the product, but it's usually possible to assess their marginal utility under specific conditions. Flour, water, and labor are needed to make biscuits; however, since water is a free resource, it doesn't contribute any marginal utility to the mix. A match is also nearly essential for starting the fire (and who hasn’t been in a situation where they would pay much more for a match than for a bucket of coal), but under normal circumstances, the match is valued at only a tiny fraction of a cent. Again, how do we measure the economic contribution of the tree and the labor required to gather its fruit? This raises the basic issue known as the problem of complementary values. When two or more things are crucial for creating a product, how should we divide the credit among them?

Labor gratifies directly and indirectly

4. Human service has the same general relation to wants that material goods have, affording gratification either directly or indirectly. It is axiomatic that to be "economic goods" human efforts like material goods must afford utilities whose importance is felt. Many services give pleasure directly and are immediately consumed. A tropical potentate has an attendant to fan him, and another to carry an umbrella; a humble citizen is shaved, doctored, sung to, and[Pg 177] played for. The gratification in such cases is directly produced in personal comfort, in the consciousness of heightened beauty, in the feeling of self-esteem. Value is thus created and consumed immediately, taking no material form apart from the consumer.

4. Human services relate to needs in the same way that physical goods do, providing satisfaction either directly or indirectly. It's clear that for something to be considered "economic goods," human efforts, like physical goods, must provide benefits that are recognized as valuable. Many services offer enjoyment right away and are used at once. A tropical ruler has someone to fan him and another to hold an umbrella; an everyday person gets shaved, receives medical care, enjoys music, and[Pg 177] is entertained. The satisfaction in these situations comes from personal comfort, a sense of beauty, and feeling good about oneself. Value is thus created and consumed immediately, without taking a physical form apart from the consumer.

Labor embodied for a time in material form

But the results of most human services may be seen to rest, at least temporarily, in some material form. Effort is put upon a material thing to be used later. The work of the waiter in spreading and arranging the table is not an immediate service, for it is embodied in material form an hour or two before the meal. The service of cook no less than that of gardener and butcher, is put into material form before it comes to the consumer. The woodman fells, cuts up and splits a tree, and piles it at the door, putting his labor into a utility to be consumed months afterward. The old economists used to class labor as productive and unproductive according as it was or was not embodied in material form. The classing of the services of cook, waiter, valet, etc., as unproductive seems, even from the old point of view, to have been inconsistent, and the attempt to distinguish services by any such test is now wholly given up. Whether the service rests in material form for a week, a month, a year, or as often happens, for a much longer period, is not essential. The test of the productiveness of services is not their embodiment in material form, but their appearance as psychic income, their ministry to wants. The most varied kinds of human activity may be unified by this thought in the concept of economic labor.

But the results of most human services can be seen to exist, at least temporarily, in some physical form. Effort is focused on a tangible item to be used later. The work of the waiter in setting and arranging the table isn’t an immediate service, since it’s completed in physical form an hour or two before the meal. The work of the cook, just like that of the gardener and butcher, is also put into a physical form before it reaches the consumer. The woodcutter chops down, cuts up, and splits a tree, stacking it by the door, putting his labor into a resource that will be used months later. The old economists used to classify labor as productive or unproductive depending on whether it was embodied in a physical form. Classifying the services of cooks, waiters, valets, etc., as unproductive seems, even from the old perspective, to have been inconsistent, and the attempt to distinguish services with any such criteria is now completely abandoned. Whether the service exists in physical form for a week, a month, a year, or often for a much longer time, is not essential. The measure of the productivity of services isn’t their embodiment in physical form, but their manifestation as psychic income, fulfilling needs. The most diverse types of human activity can be brought together with this idea in the concept of economic labor.

§ II. VARIETIES OF TALENTS AND OF ABILITIES IN MEN

Grades of labor are analogous to grades of wealth

1. As material things differ in their fitness to gratify wants, so do men differ in their powers of labor. The fields, hammers, plows, tools, and machinery of different kinds and qualities have been seen to grade off from the best to the poorest. The poorest, discarded or just about to be[Pg 178] discarded, are no-rent agents. The utility felt and recognized in the better qualities is expressed in the rents they yield. Recognizing the variety and inequality of human talent, some economists of late speak of the "rent" of ability, meaning that, like land rent, the greater utility (and corresponding reward) of some labor as compared with others, reflects the difference in the quality of agents. But this expression, though often met in contemporary economic writings, is one to be avoided because it tends to blur the essential distinction between human and other agents. Pursuing the same analogy some economists have talked of capitalizing the worker,—expressing in a lump sum the value of the man as the present worth of the series of incomes which he may be expected to earn in his working life. This, also, is to be avoided, for while possibly it is suggestive in studying some problems, it is on the whole a misleading analogy, dimming the distinction between free-workers and owned and exchangeable wealth.

1. Just as material things vary in how well they satisfy needs, people also differ in their capacity to work. The fields, hammers, plows, tools, and machinery come in different types and qualities, ranging from the best to the worst. The worst, those that are discarded or nearly discarded[Pg 178], are no-rent agents. The value recognized in the better quality items is shown by the rents they generate. Acknowledging the diversity and inequality of human talent, some recent economists refer to the "rent" of ability, suggesting that, like land rent, the greater usefulness (and corresponding reward) of some work compared to others reflects the differences in the quality of workers. However, this term, while frequently found in current economic discussions, should be avoided because it blurs the important distinction between human and other types of agents. Following the same analogy, some economists have discussed capitalizing the worker—expressing in a lump sum the value of a person as the present worth of the income they can be expected to earn throughout their working life. This approach should also be avoided; while it may be helpful for examining certain issues, it ultimately creates a misleading analogy that obscures the distinction between free workers and owned, exchangeable assets.

Physical differences among men

2. The physical strength of workers differs according to age, individual, race, and sex. Differences due to age are the most obvious. The child, at first weak, grows toward his maximum of physical strength, which he attains before his fullest intellectual capacity. The period of maximum physical working power lasts fifteen to twenty-five years according to the individual, and then gradually declines as the old worker approaches again the inefficiency of the child. Mental efficiency develops more slowly and longer, the highest qualities of judgment and wisdom being the fruits only of a life rich in experiences. Families and strains of stock differ notably in physical and mental powers; one excels in stature, another in development of muscle. The differences within families are inexplicable, sometimes one brother excelling in one thing, the other in another. The physically perfect man is a rare product. Among three thousand students are but two score endowed with the remarkable combination of lungs, heart, muscle, nerve, and character, that makes possible the finest athletes. The national and[Pg 179] racial differences in working power, even in the simplest tasks, are marked but difficult to explain, as so many influences of customs, habits of life, and varieties of diet modify the result. We cannot tell how much of the Englishman's great superiority over the East Indiaman is due to individual, native differences of mind and body, how much to the social environment in which they have lived. Certainly, though, the difference is not mainly one in size; in the Chinese War the little brown men of Japan outmarched all the others. Certainly fiber counts for more than bulk, and character for more than muscle.

2. The physical strength of workers varies based on age, individual, race, and gender. Age differences are the most noticeable. A child, initially weak, builds up to their peak physical strength before reaching their full intellectual capacity. The period of maximum physical ability lasts from fifteen to twenty-five years, depending on the person, and then gradually declines as older workers revert to a level of inefficiency similar to that of a child. Mental efficiency develops more slowly and takes longer; the highest levels of judgment and wisdom come only from a life rich in experiences. Families and genetic lineages show significant variation in physical and mental abilities; some might excel in height, while others are more muscular. The disparities within families are puzzling; sometimes one brother excels in one area, while the other stands out in something different. The perfectly fit individual is a rare find. Among three thousand students, only about forty possess the exceptional combination of lungs, heart, muscle, nerve, and character that creates the best athletes. National and racial differences in physical capabilities, even for the simplest tasks, are pronounced but hard to explain since many factors like customs, lifestyle habits, and different diets affect the outcomes. We can't pinpoint how much of the Englishman's significant advantage over the East Indiaman stems from inherent individual differences in mind and body, and how much is due to the social environment they've been in. However, it's clear that the difference isn't primarily about size; during the Chinese War, the smaller brown men of Japan outperformed everyone else. Indeed, resilience matters more than bulk, and character is more important than mere muscle.

Comparative strength of men and women

A difference in the physical strength of the sexes is found in some degree throughout the world, but it would appear to be far more marked in civilized than in savage communities. Compare the records at the Vassar field-games with that of the men in any leading college: in the hundred-yard dash, fifteen seconds as against ten and a fraction; in the high jump, forty-eight inches as against six feet and over. The muscular force of American college women as tested in the Yale and the Oberlin gymnasiums is but one third that of men, that is, taking all the students, the weaklings and the little men along with the athletes, and the women large and small. As to strength of back the average for men is 154 kilograms, for women 54 kilograms; legs, average for men 186, average for women 76.5; right forearm, average for men 56, average for women 21.4. This is an abnormal difference. The natural and possible strength is more nearly attained by men than by women under our social conditions. Women escape the physical toil which strengthens, but not the mental strain which kills. Men carry more of the wood, but the women not less of the worries. A fairer test is applied among peasants in field-work in France and Germany, where the strength of women is found to be about two thirds that of men. American women should do and will do more to attain their natural strength when we attain sounder ideas of education and saner modes of living.

A difference in physical strength between the sexes exists to some extent around the globe, but it seems much more pronounced in civilized societies than in primitive ones. For example, look at the records from the Vassar field games compared to those of the men at any top college: in the hundred-yard dash, fifteen seconds versus just over ten; in the high jump, forty-eight inches compared to six feet or more. The muscular strength of American college women, as measured in the Yale and Oberlin gymnasiums, is only about one third that of men, considering all students, including those who are less physically capable alongside the athletes, and women of all sizes. In terms of back strength, the average for men is 154 kilograms, while for women it’s 54 kilograms; for legs, men average 186 kilograms, while women average 76.5; for the right forearm, men average 56 kilograms, whereas women average 21.4. This difference is striking. Men are more likely to reach their natural strength under our social conditions than women. Women may avoid the physical labor that builds strength, but they don’t escape the mental stress that can be overwhelming. Men may handle more physical tasks, but women carry their share of worries. A more equal comparison is found among farmers in France and Germany, where women’s strength is about two thirds that of men. American women are capable of achieving more of their natural strength, and they will, as we develop better educational practices and healthier lifestyles.

Talent and training as factors of efficiency

3. Differences in intelligence are a resultant of native[Pg 180] talent and acquired ability. It is difficult to distinguish these two factors sharply. Two men sitting side by side in an examination, get the same grade; one of them has had excellent preparation from childhood, and all the opportunities that money, travel, and cultured associates can give; the other, under great difficulties, has prepared in a country district school with a little coaching now and then, and struggling against great odds, has at last entered college. The same grade does not mean that their natural ability or even their efficiency in this particular class, is equal. Yet the grade is the best expression to be had of their efficiency in the particular work. Native intelligence shortens the time needed for preparation in any calling; hastens new methods; decreases the cost of supervision; saves materials, tools, and time; diminishes loss from breakage; makes possible the use of finer machinery and better appliances, and imparts those subtler qualities that distinguish the best from the mediocre products. Education and native talent are in a degree interchangeable; one supplements the other. Education increases adaptability; the trained mind will outstrip the untrained mind of greater power. It makes direction easier, fits for higher tasks, and decreases the difficulty of coöperation. Any ability may be helped by education in the broad and true sense, though a fool cannot be made wise by training, and though many a potential genius doubtless has been dwarfed in dusty school-rooms by stupid teachers.

3. Differences in intelligence result from innate[Pg 180] talent and acquired ability. It’s hard to clearly separate these two factors. Two men sitting next to each other in an exam might get the same grade; one has had great preparation from childhood, with all the advantages that money, travel, and educated peers can provide. The other, facing significant challenges, has prepared at a rural school with occasional coaching and has fought against the odds to finally enter college. The same grade doesn't indicate that their natural ability or even their effectiveness in this specific class is equal. Yet, the grade is the best indication of their performance in this particular task. Innate intelligence shortens the time needed for preparation in any field; it speeds up the adoption of new methods; reduces the need for supervision; saves resources, tools, and time; lowers losses from damage; enables the use of better machinery and equipment, and adds those subtle qualities that set the best apart from the mediocre. Education and natural talent are somewhat interchangeable; one complements the other. Education boosts adaptability; a trained mind will surpass an untrained mind with greater abilities. It makes guidance easier, prepares for more complex tasks, and reduces the challenges of cooperation. Any skill can be enhanced by education in a broad and meaningful way, though a fool can't become wise through training, and many potential geniuses have likely been stunted in dusty classrooms by inadequate teachers.

The moral qualities required in industry

4. The moral qualities of the worker are increasingly important as society grows more complex. The need of a particular moral quality is relative to the special task in hand. Honesty is needed in the bank teller, but he need not spoil a good story. The champion broncho-buster of Arizona is not a Sunday-school superintendent. So, discipline, obedience, self-control, regularity, and punctuality are needed, for more and more in these days business is run by the watch; confidence, patience, good temper, in fact all the virtues in the calendar are necessary at some time and[Pg 181] place, and most of them are needed all the time in business. Places may be found in our developed society for those who are deficient in these qualities (it is fortunate that it is so), but these are the poorer places. Many men fail to examine the qualities necessary for success, and do not understand the causes of their own failure. Blind to their own faults, they are dropped down one notch after another in the scale of industry, and, equally blind to the virtues of their successful rivals, they rail against the unjust fates.

4. The moral qualities of workers are becoming increasingly important as society becomes more complex. The need for specific moral qualities depends on the particular task at hand. Honesty is essential for a bank teller, but that doesn't mean he should ruin a good story. The top bronco rider in Arizona isn't a Sunday-school teacher. So, qualities like discipline, obedience, self-control, regularity, and punctuality are necessary, especially now that business operates on strict schedules; confidence, patience, a good attitude, and really all the virtues you can think of are essential at various times and[Pg 181] places, and most of them are needed all the time in business. There are roles in our advanced society for those lacking in these qualities (thankfully there are), but those roles are less desirable. Many people fail to consider the qualities needed for success and don’t understand why they fail. Unaware of their own shortcomings, they get pushed down the ladder in their industry, and, equally unaware of the strengths of their successful competitors, they complain about unfair circumstances.

The union of many qualities needed

5. Skill and capacity in industrial tasks is a resultant of many qualities. The simplest task calls for a combination of force and judgment,—even the digging of a ditch, the raising of a window, or the fitting of a stovepipe. For most industrial tasks rarer combinations of qualities are required. The retail clerk must be neat, punctual, polite, and long suffering. A confidential clerk must have discretion, judgment, and other moral qualities in an unusual combination. The substitution of qualities is possible within limits; a rare quality may make amends for the lack of a commoner one, and a man may, because of peculiar fitness in some regards, continue to hold a position for which in other ways he is little fitted. The rarest and most valued worker is one uniting many good qualities and fitted to deal with emergencies. The economic efficiency of the worker often is no stronger than its weakest link. A strong motive for training is offered by the fact that supplying some one lacking quality may raise the total efficiency in a remarkable degree.

5. Skills and abilities in industrial tasks come from a mix of different qualities. Even the simplest job requires a combination of strength and judgment—like digging a ditch, raising a window, or fitting a stovepipe. For most industrial tasks, rarer combinations of qualities are needed. A retail clerk has to be neat, on time, polite, and patient. A confidential clerk must possess discretion, judgment, and other moral qualities in a unique mix. You can substitute qualities to some extent; a rare quality might compensate for a lack of a more common one, and someone might keep a position where they are not well suited in other ways due to their unique strengths. The most valuable worker is one who brings together many good qualities and is adept at handling emergencies. The worker's economic efficiency often depends on its weakest link. A strong motivation for training comes from the fact that addressing a missing quality can significantly boost overall efficiency.

Inequality of talents shown by biologic studies

6. Biologic studies have of late made clearer the existence and continuation of the inequality of talents. The political philosophy of the eighteenth century was based on the idea of natural rights and natural equality. Adam Smith, accepting the prevailing view, discussed wages on the assumption that all men had equal natural ability. It is still a favorite assumption of radical social reformers that the natural ability of all men is equal, and that all the differences in success result from political injustice. The study of[Pg 182] biology of late has made patent the unending differences that prevail throughout the animate world. No two members of the same family or species are just alike; no two pigeons have wings of just the same length. Nature by numberless devices is experimenting constantly with variations on either side of the established mean. The accepted fact of biologic evolution rests on the foundation of inequality in structure and powers, making possible selection and adaptation. Men in all their qualities of mind and body display this kaleidescopic variety. In all life there is inequality, and the whole drama of human history as well as that of biologic evolution must be meaningless or illusory to the man who does not see this truth. Accustomed now to this point of view, we as inevitably think of the natural inequalities in men as did Adam Smith of their equality.

6. Recent biological studies have made it clearer that inequality in talent exists and persists. The political philosophy of the eighteenth century was rooted in the concepts of natural rights and natural equality. Adam Smith, aligning with the common belief of his time, discussed wages based on the assumption that all men possess equal natural ability. This idea still resonates with many radical social reformers today, who assert that differences in success stem solely from political injustice. However, recent studies in biology have revealed the persistent disparities that exist throughout the animal kingdom. No two members of the same family or species are identical; no two pigeons have wings of exactly the same length. Nature is continuously experimenting with variations on either side of the established average. The widely accepted principle of biological evolution is built on the foundation of inequality in structure and abilities, allowing for selection and adaptation. Humans, in all their mental and physical qualities, exhibit this diverse variety. Inequality is present in all aspects of life, and the entirety of human history, along with biological evolution, must seem meaningless or illusory to anyone who fails to recognize this truth. Now accustomed to this perspective, we think of the natural inequalities among men as inevitably as Adam Smith thought of their equality.

This fact does not force to the conclusion that industrial inequality as it exists to-day, the great disparity of incomes, correctly or justly reflects the degree of difference in men's qualities, either native or acquired. It does not follow that a thousand-dollar income represents ten times the ability of a hundred dollar one—far from it. But to those who ignore the inequality of men, the whole problem of industrial remuneration must remain a mystery. A crude socialism is possible only to those who are blind to the enormous differences in human capacity.

This fact doesn’t lead us to conclude that the industrial inequality we see today, with its huge income gaps, accurately or fairly represents the differences in people’s qualities, whether they’re natural or developed. It’s not true that a thousand-dollar income shows someone has ten times the ability of someone earning a hundred dollars—far from it. However, for those who overlook the inequality among people, the whole issue of industrial pay will always seem confusing. A simplistic form of socialism can only appeal to those who ignore the vast differences in human capabilities.

Scarcity of labor is essential to wages
Unlimited demand for labor

7. The scarcity of human services, relative to wants, is the fundamental fact in the problem of wages. It is clearly seen that some qualities of service are scarce. Most women will confess that they cannot warble as Patti could, most men will admit that they have not the mercantile ability of John Wanamaker. The man of mediocre capacity recognizes even through the fog of his self-esteem that there is a reason for the high value of certain rare services. But it must also be recognized that the commonest services have value only because they are scarce. There are many things to be done if there were labor enough to do them. There is[Pg 183] no need to "make work," in the popular sense; it is here, but labor is lacking to do it. It is true there may be a temporary superfluity of human labor at a time of an industrial crisis. There is at all times a superfluity of "useless" human agents whose qualities are such that they have no net utility. The ignorant, insane, feeble-minded, vicious, drunken, and debauched, can give to the world only negative utilities. But services that are in any degree useful are nearly always in demand, and the higher services are so rare that they are in great demand. The proverb, "There's always room at the top," is seen to be true when conditions are thus analyzed. There is a large, though limited, supply of the commoner kinds of services at the bottom of the scale, but in every branch of human effort there is a never-ending lack of that higher qualification and training required for the best results.

7. The lack of human services compared to needs is the main issue in the wage problem. It's clear that some types of service are scarce. Most women would admit they can’t sing like Patti, and most men would acknowledge they don’t have John Wanamaker's business skills. Even an average person realizes, despite their own self-esteem, that there's a reason certain rare services are highly valued. However, it also needs to be acknowledged that the most common services only hold value because they are scarce. There’s a lot to be done if there were enough workers to do it. There’s [Pg 183] no need to "create jobs" in the usual sense; they exist, but there aren’t enough workers to handle them. It is true that there may be a temporary surplus of human labor during an industrial crisis. There is always a surplus of "useless" human agents whose qualities offer no positive benefit. The ignorant, insane, mentally challenged, immoral, drunk, and debauched can only provide negative benefits to society. However, services that are at all useful are almost always in demand, and higher-level services are so rare that they are in great demand. The saying, "There's always room at the top," proves true when conditions are analyzed this way. There’s a sizable, though limited, supply of the more common types of services at the bottom, but in every area of human effort, there is a constant shortage of that higher skill and training necessary for the best outcomes.


CHAPTER 21

THE SUPPLY OF LABOR

§ I. WHAT IS A DOCTRINE OF POPULATION?

The employer's and the social view of supply of labor

1. The supply of labor means here not the number of workers available in any one industry, but the number available in the whole field of industry. The individual employer thinks of the supply of labor as consisting of the men seeking employment in his special industry. In this view it is the demand by the employers that apportions the workers among the various occupations. The social view of the supply of labor, however, looks at the whole field. The demand for labor is then seen to be represented not by human employers, but by resources and agents presenting opportunities and demanding labor to employ them. The rich acre, the tool, the machine, all material wealth needing the human touch to give it a higher utility, represent a demand for labor in this broad sense. The thought of a supply of labor is therefore relative to that of the demand embodied in resources. A million men are a great or a small supply of labor according as they occupy a little island or a large continent, according as they are equipped with a small or a large supply of agents.

1. The labor supply here doesn't just refer to the number of workers available in a specific industry, but rather the number available across the entire industrial landscape. An individual employer tends to view the labor supply as the group of people looking for jobs in their particular industry. From this perspective, the demand from employers determines how workers are distributed among different jobs. However, the broader social view of the labor supply considers the entire landscape. In this view, the demand for labor is reflected not by individual employers, but by resources and opportunities that require labor to be fully utilized. Wealthy land, tools, machinery—all forms of material wealth that need human effort to enhance their usefulness—represent a demand for labor in this wider context. Therefore, the concept of labor supply is relative to the demand represented by these resources. A million people can be seen as either a large or small labor supply depending on whether they are on a tiny island or a vast continent, or whether they have access to a limited or extensive range of resources.

Population in relation to resources

2. "Supply of labor," as an economic problem, presents a large and complex case of diminishing returns. The population of different countries and of different sections of a country is seen to bear a general relation to their resources. An unintelligent race with little wealth and poor machinery is doomed to remain few in numbers. Mountains, districts poorly watered, the frozen regions of the North, are sparsely[Pg 185] populated because natural resources are lacking. If food production alone is thought of there are apparent exceptions to this statement, but there are no absolute contradictions of it. A favored harbor may make possible a flourishing commerce on a rocky coast; an unfertile soil may support a large population when great deposits of coal or iron insure by exchange great food-supplies. Productivity must be measured under modern conditions by the purchasing power that is possible in the environment. The connection of wealth and resources with the extent of the population is in itself a recognition of diminishing returns, of an objective limit to the number of men that can occupy a certain area and employ a given stock of agents.

2. "Supply of labor," as an economic issue, is a significant and complex case of diminishing returns. The population of various countries and different regions of a country generally relates to their available resources. A less intelligent population with minimal wealth and poor tools is likely to remain small in number. Areas with mountains, poor water supply, or the icy northern regions are sparsely[Pg 185] populated due to a lack of natural resources. If we only consider food production, there appear to be exceptions to this claim, but there are no absolute contradictions. A well-placed harbor might enable thriving trade along a rocky coastline; infertile land might support a large population if there are substantial coal or iron deposits that allow for the exchange of significant food supplies. Productivity must be assessed in modern terms by the purchasing power available in that environment. The link between wealth, resources, and population size itself acknowledges diminishing returns, indicating a definite limit to the number of people who can live in a specific area and utilize a given set of resources.

Equilibrium between numbers of animals of different species

3. Each species of the lower animals is seen to have a relatively fixed habitat limited by its food-supply and by its enemies. The rocks tell a story of a slow and steady change that has gone on in the earth and in the species of animals that inhabit it. History records some rapid changes due to convulsions of nature or to interference by man with the natural conditions. But the usual condition is an equilibrium of numbers, long maintained, though each species appears to have in itself a capacity for unlimited increase. Why this contradiction? The limit set by the food-supply is seen in a simple case when herbivorous animals are placed on an island from which they cannot escape, and where there are no dogs, wolves, weasels, or foxes. Substantially this experiment was unintentionally tried on an enormous scale with the rabbit in Australia. This peculiar and long-isolated continent contained none of the rabbit's ancient enemies. The rabbits became a pest, devastated great areas, were hunted, trapped, poisoned, and great numbers of them died of starvation outside the fences erected to stop their advance. In the imaginary island they would increase up to the point where starvation would bring about an equilibrium between the number of animals and the food supply. The destruction of one kind of animal by another limits numbers in another[Pg 186] way. The number of lions is limited by the number of their prey in the region where they roam. The number of deer, therefore, is limited in two ways, by the amount of their food and by the number of lions which catch the deer. The more numerous the lions, the fewer the deer; the fewer the deer, the greater the supply of vegetable food; as the pressure increases on one side, it decreases on the other, until an equilibrium is reached.

3. Each species of lower animals has a relatively fixed habitat limited by its food supply and its predators. The rocks reveal a story of gradual and consistent change that has occurred on Earth and among the animal species that live here. History notes some quick changes caused by natural disasters or human interference with natural conditions. However, the typical state is a balance of numbers that lasts a long time, even though each species seems to have the potential for unlimited growth. Why is there this contradiction? The limit set by the food supply is clear when herbivorous animals are put on an island where they can't escape and where there are no dogs, wolves, weasels, or foxes. This kind of experiment was unintentionally conducted on a huge scale with rabbits in Australia. This unique and isolated continent had none of the rabbits' natural enemies. The rabbits became a nuisance, devastated large areas, were hunted, trapped, poisoned, and many died from starvation outside the fences built to contain them. On the imagined island, they would multiply until starvation would create a balance between the number of animals and the food supply. The elimination of one kind of animal by another limits numbers in another[Pg 186] way. The number of lions is limited by the amount of prey available in their territory. Therefore, the population of deer is limited in two ways: by the amount of their food and by the number of lions hunting them. The more lions there are, the fewer deer there are; the fewer deer there are, the more available plant food there is; as pressure increases on one side, it decreases on the other, until a balance is reached.

The surplus of life germs

Throughout nature each species of animal keeps its customary place, changing little despite its efforts to increase and to crowd into the habitat of other species. Even the slow-breeding elephant, with a period of gestation of three years, and producing one calf at a birth, would cover the entire earth and leave no standing-room in a few centuries if every calf born could live to full age. The myriads of frogs born every spring, the swarms of insects, the countless plants, are struggling to find a foothold on the crowded earth. Of the vastly greater number of seeds and embryos, only one in a multitude ever comes or could come to maturity. Here are the undisputed facts on which rests a biologic "doctrine of population," so to speak, for the vegetable and lower animal world. Because of the limited powers of the soil, no form of life, animal or vegetable, can continue to increase even for a single generation, without meeting enormous forces of opposition, which destroy great numbers and set a limit to the increase of the species.

Throughout nature, each animal species maintains its established role, changing little despite their attempts to expand and invade the habitats of others. Even the slowly reproducing elephant, which has a three-year gestation period and typically gives birth to one calf, could populate the entire planet and leave no space in a few centuries if every calf lived to adulthood. The countless frogs born every spring, swarms of insects, and numerous plants are all competing for space on this crowded earth. Out of the far greater number of seeds and embryos, only one in many ever reaches maturity. These are the undeniable facts that underpin a sort of biological "doctrine of population" for plants and lower animals. Due to the limited capacity of the soil, no life form, whether animal or plant, can continue to grow even for a single generation without facing huge forces of opposition that kill off many and cap the population growth of the species.

These facts related to the doctrine of population

4. A doctrine of human population is a reasoned explanation of the causes determining the number of people in the world. Man in his economic life is constantly struggling with the problem of the scarcity of goods. If in any given environment men continue long to increase, they must, like the lower animals, meet limits in the capacities of the resources they use. The supply of labor force which is thus brought to be combined with the material agents must meet with diminishing returns unless these agents also continue to increase at a like rate. The relation of population to resources[Pg 187] thus presents probably the most fundamental problem in the realm of economics. It is a problem of great complexity, bristling with difficulties, and incapable of exact mathematical treatment; but it is capable of rational study. There is a great difference between a purely fatalistic view of this question and the view that is to be reached by a consideration of the motives, causes, and physical influences at work; It is possible to find some principles in the chaos of prejudices and contradictions that the subject presents. The fruit of a century of discussion of the economic, social, and biologic factors involved, is a rational, if not a final, doctrine of population.

4. A doctrine of human population is a reasoned explanation of the causes determining the number of people in the world. People in their economic lives are constantly dealing with the issue of limited resources. If, in any given environment, the population continues to grow for an extended period, they must, like other animals, face limits in the availability of the resources they use. The supply of the labor force that comes together with these resources must encounter diminishing returns unless those resources also continue to increase at a similar rate. The relationship between population and resources[Pg 187] presents probably the most fundamental issue in economics. This problem is quite complex, full of challenges, and not suited for exact mathematical solutions; however, it can be studied rationally. There is a significant difference between a purely fatalistic approach to this question and one that considers the motives, causes, and physical influences at play. It is possible to identify some principles amidst the chaos of biases and contradictions that this topic presents. The outcome of a century of discussion regarding the economic, social, and biological factors involved is a rational, albeit not final, doctrine of population.

§ II. POPULATION IN HUMAN SOCIETY

The biologic stage of human population

1. In the earlier stages of human history, population is limited mainly by biologic factors. The biologic stage continues so long as there are no artificial restraints put on the birth-rate, and no deliberate destruction of offspring for the purposes of limiting the size of the family. There the limits are all objective; they are found in scantiness of the food-supply, or in destruction by enemies, animal or human. Each species has an average or normal birth-rate, great or small. Just why this varies, why the rabbit produces a score of young in a year, and the elephant but one in three years, is a question capable of a rational answer, but it is one for the natural scientist rather than for the economist. Each species is impelled by instinct to realize this birth-rate, to bring into existence as many young as possible.

1. In the early stages of human history, the population is mainly limited by biological factors. The biological stage continues as long as there are no artificial limits on the birth rate and no intentional destruction of offspring to reduce family size. The limits are all objective; they arise from a lack of food supply or threats from enemies, whether animal or human. Each species has an average or normal birth rate, whether high or low. The reason for this variation—why a rabbit can have many young in a year while an elephant has only one every three years—is a question that can be answered rationally, but it’s more suited for natural scientists than economists. Each species is driven by instinct to achieve this birth rate, producing as many offspring as possible.

No human society known to us is so primitive that it has not passed this stage, but many societies have risen but little above it. In most savage tribes, where starvation, disease, and war are constantly at work, the difficult task is to maintain the population. Few of those born arrive at maturity. The custom of the adoption of captives from hostile tribes is widespread, because the efficiency and even the survival of the tribe depends upon keeping up its number of warriors.

No known human society is so primitive that it hasn’t gone through this stage, but many have only advanced slightly beyond it. In most primitive tribes, where hunger, illness, and conflict are always present, the challenging task is to sustain the population. Few of those born reach adulthood. The practice of adopting captives from enemy tribes is common, as the strength and even survival of the tribe rely on maintaining its number of warriors.

War among primitive societies

2. War for the possession of limited resources is the first rude social remedy for an excess of population. War is the normal condition of most primitive tribes. Its cause usually appears to be standing feuds and ancient enmities, but the deeper and abiding cause is the struggle for hunting-grounds, for pasturage, for natural resources. The rude industry and economy of hunting, fishing, or pastoral peoples, or of those in the earlier stages of agriculture, requires a large area for a small population. Distant excursions and frequent forays, when food fails, develop rival claims to favored districts, and war is the only settlement. Fighting under these conditions is an activity of such economic importance that much of the energy of the tribe must be strenuously given to it. The ceaseless loss of life in savage wars is almost incredible to modern minds. The invasion of the Roman Empire by the Teutonic tribes, the later successive inundations of medieval Europe by the fierce pastoral tribes from central Asia, are more recent and familiar examples of the economic and political effects of the increase of population and of the outgrowing of resources by barbarian peoples. When the custom arises of capturing enemies and reducing them to slavery instead of killing them, forces are set into operation to reorganize society and to create new checks on the growth of population.

2. War for control of limited resources is the first harsh social solution to an overpopulation issue. War is the usual state for most primitive tribes. Though it often seems to stem from ongoing disputes and ancient grudges, the deeper and more lasting reason is the competition for hunting grounds, grazing land, and natural resources. The basic lifestyles and economies of hunting, fishing, or herding communities, or of those in the early phases of agriculture, require a large area to support a small population. Long journeys and frequent raids, especially when food is scarce, create rival claims to desirable territories, and war becomes the only way to resolve these conflicts. Fighting in these situations is so economically vital that a significant amount of the tribe's energy must be directed toward it. The continuous loss of life in brutal wars is almost unimaginable to modern perspectives. The invasion of the Roman Empire by the Germanic tribes, along with the later waves of medieval Europe by fierce herding tribes from Central Asia, are more recent and relatable examples of the economic and political impacts of population growth and resource depletion among barbaric societies. When the practice of capturing enemies and enslaving them instead of killing them emerges, it sets off changes in society and creates new constraints on population growth.

Crude beginnings of volitional control

3. Volitional control of population begins by the destruction of offspring before or after birth. The population problem ceases to be simply biologic, and takes on its sociological aspect, when the awakening intelligence of man first grasps the mystery of birth, and when the first attempts are made in any way to regulate family relations or to interfere with the growth of numbers. The student of primitive peoples finds in the methods applied to prevent the birth of children an almost inconceivable brutality. The same methods to a large degree persist in savage communities to-day. Infanticide was generally practiced in ancient times among peoples of advanced civilization, as, for example, in Sparta and Rome,[Pg 189] where not only deformed and weak children, but unwelcome ones, commonly were destroyed. The practice, if not legalized, is at least permitted even to-day by public opinion in great portions of India, China, and other densely populated districts of the world. It is one of the dark spots on our own civilization.

3. Control over population starts with ending the lives of offspring before or after they are born. The population issue is no longer just a biological concern; it becomes a social issue when humans begin to understand the complexities of birth and make initial efforts to manage family dynamics or influence population growth. Researchers studying primitive societies discover a shocking level of violence in methods used to prevent childbirth. Many of these methods are still seen in some tribal communities today. Infanticide was commonly practiced in ancient civilizations, including advanced societies like Sparta and Rome,[Pg 189] where not just deformed or weak children, but also unwanted ones, were often killed. Even now, while it may not be formally legalized, public opinion in many regions of India, China, and other overpopulated areas tends to tolerate it. This remains one of the grim aspects of our own civilization.

Private property limits population
The problem a psychic one

4. The pressure of increase of numbers on resources is confined by individual industry and by private property to special portions of the population. A condition of communism, where all the members of the tribe or family share equally, means that all enjoy together when food and wealth are abundant, and all starve together when it becomes scarce. Along with a fierce enmity for other tribes, is found in many early societies a close approximation to tribal communism. Private property alters the nature of the struggle for subsistence and of the motives for limiting population. Society divides into a number of partially independent classes or family groups, each holding its share of wealth apart, not in common with the tribe. A society with private property is like a ship divided into a number of water-tight compartments. In communistic conditions if population increases, all sink together into want. The self-interest of those having private property keeps them from dividing their property, and starvation is confined to the propertyless members. This acts in two ways: it increases the motive for the production of wealth; it gives a motive for the limitation of the consumers of the wealth. A smaller family with larger resources means a wider margin between numbers and misery. This converts the problem of population from a material one of a balance of food and physical needs, to a psychic one of a balance of motives in the minds of men. When this stage is reached, the extreme objective limit of the birth-rate or of increase of population is no longer attained in the well-to-do classes, although it may still continue to be in the less provident.

4. The pressure from increasing population on resources is restricted by individual industry and private property to specific segments of the population. In a communist setting, where all members of a tribe or family share equally, everyone benefits together when food and wealth are plentiful, and everyone suffers together when they are scarce. Alongside a strong hostility towards other tribes, many early societies exhibit characteristics of tribal communism. Private property changes the dynamics of the struggle for survival and the motivations to control population growth. Society splits into several partially independent classes or family groups, each maintaining its wealth separately, rather than sharing it with the tribe. A society with private property resembles a ship divided into separate watertight compartments. In a communistic society, if the population grows, everyone collectively falls into hardship. The self-interest of those with private property prevents them from sharing their resources, resulting in starvation being confined to those without property. This creates two effects: it boosts the motivation to produce wealth; and it provides a reason to limit the number of people consuming that wealth. A smaller family with larger resources creates a greater gap between population and suffering. This changes the issue of population from a physical one of food and material needs to a psychological one regarding the motivations in people’s minds. Once this stage is reached, the maximum potential birth rate or population growth is no longer achieved in the wealthy classes, although it may still be apparent in those less careful with resources.

Social classes differ in volitional control

5. Volitional control is effective in very different degrees in different families and industrial classes. [Pg 190]The possession of property is both a sign of forethought and an incentive to it. Concern for the welfare of children is one of the most powerful motives, especially after social distinctions become marked. It may become abnormally strong, leading parents to sacrifice their own welfare or their own lives foolishly for their children, as is done often in the accumulation of property. Among the classes with property the provision for the children depends not only upon the amount of wealth, but upon the number among whom it is to be divided. It is simple division: wealth the dividend, number of children the divisor.

5. Volitional control works to varying degrees in different families and social classes. [Pg 190] Owning property shows foresight and motivates further planning. Caring for the well-being of children is one of the strongest drives, especially as social differences become more obvious. This concern can become excessively intense, causing parents to foolishly sacrifice their own well-being or even their lives for their children, often seen in the pursuit of wealth. In wealthier classes, the way parents provide for their children depends not only on how much money they have but also on how many children they need to support. It’s a simple calculation: wealth is the total amount, and the number of children is the divisor.

Among the poorer classes very different motives operate. After the first few years the parents' income is increased by the earnings of the children, both on the farm and in the factory districts if the laws do not prohibit child labor. Moreover, when the children are grown, their wages will depend on the general labor market, not upon the number of their brothers and sisters. So, according as the family income is from rents or from wages, the motives of the parents differ.

Among the lower-income families, different reasons come into play. After the first few years, the parents' income goes up because the children start earning money, whether on the farm or in factory areas if child labor isn’t banned. Additionally, when the children grow up, their wages will be influenced by the overall job market, not the number of siblings they have. Therefore, depending on whether the family income comes from rents or wages, the parents' motivations vary.

Motives in volitional control

Postponement of marriage must be classed as a mode of volitional control of population. The average age of marriage, both of men and women, is higher in the classes of greater wealth and ambition than in the poorer classes. The contrast in this regard between civilized and savage peoples is likewise noteworthy. The failure to marry, from whatever cause, is, in the social view of the question, volitional control. It is rare that the motive is directly and immediately the wish to avoid parenthood; now it is religious zeal, again it is disappointed sentiment; here it is conflicting duty, and there it is the individual selfish wish to retain an undivided income for one's own enjoyment. By countless strands of motive in the form of sentiments, social institutions, and interests, the primitive impulses of humanity are firmly bound; and in varying degrees, in different classes, the enormous possibilities of reproduction are controlled by human volition.

Postponing marriage can be seen as a way to consciously control population growth. On average, people tend to marry later in life, both men and women, in wealthier and more ambitious social classes compared to those in poorer classes. This difference is also notable when comparing civilized and uncivilized societies. Choosing not to marry, for any reason, is considered a form of intentional control over population in social terms. It’s uncommon for the main motivation to be the desire to avoid having children; sometimes it's driven by religious beliefs, other times by unfulfilled emotions, or conflicting responsibilities, and in other cases, by a personal desire to keep all income for one's own enjoyment. Numerous motives—through feelings, social norms, and personal interests—effectively tie down the basic human instincts, and in various ways, across different social classes, the vast potential for reproduction is managed by individual choice.

§ III. CURRENT ASPECT OF THE POPULATION PROBLEM

The many motives controlling population

1. Changes in population are resultants of many forces: those favoring a high birth-rate and low death-rate, and those limiting births or survival. Whether the population on the whole shall grow, stand still, or diminish, depends upon the relative strength of contending forces making for life or death. But this control may lose its cruder aspect and may be waged in the realm of motive. More and more it is volition that controls in human society the growth of population; less and less it is the objective limit of the food-supply. Dire need resulting in ill-health and even in starvation, is still acting in some portions of society, but less to-day than ever before. The growth of population in this stage is not "fatalistic," as there is no inevitable tendency to increase or to decrease. It depends on the interaction of a number of forces, clearly distinguishable, by which population actually is kept far within the limits of food resources. Volitional control is not by a central and unified despotism determining human action, but it is by motives of the most complex sort, diffused throughout society and acting upon every member of it.

1. Changes in population result from many factors: those encouraging a high birth rate and low death rate, and those limiting births or survival. Whether the population as a whole will grow, remain stable, or decline depends on the relative strength of competing forces for life or death. However, this control may shift from a more obvious aspect to one rooted in motives. Increasingly, it's human choice that influences population growth; less and less is it determined by the available food supply. While dire need leading to illness and even starvation still affects some parts of society, it's happening less than ever before. The growth of population in this era is not "fatalistic," as there's no unavoidable trend to increase or decrease. It relies on the interplay of various clearly identifiable forces that keep the population well within food resource limits. This control by choice doesn't come from a central, unified authority directing human actions but from a myriad of complex motives spread throughout society and impacting every individual.

The standard of life in Asiatic countries

2. The desire to maintain and raise the standard of life is the most effective motive limiting population in our society. The phrase "standard of life" expresses the complex thought of that measure of necessities, comforts, and luxuries considered by any individual to be indispensable for himself and his children; that measure which he will make great sacrifices to secure. This standard differs from land to land, and from time to time. In the Asiatic countries it is so low that it touches in large classes the minimum of subsistence. Despite adverse influences and the uninterrupted series of famines, the population of India in the last century under English rule increased from two hundred millions to three hundred millions. Such a population "lets out all the slack" of income, and never takes up any. The great public[Pg 192] works of irrigation, forestry, and transportation, and the development of industry under English rule, gave an opportunity for a higher standard of living; but it was used instead to permit the existence of a greater number of men in the same old misery. These facts have a bearing upon the question of Oriental immigration to America. The emigration of millions of Chinese from their native land would leave no void in their numbers. Peopling their own land constantly down to their own standard of living, they have the power, if they are tempted hither in great numbers, to people this continent also to the same density.

2. The desire to maintain and improve one’s quality of life is the strongest reason for limiting population in our society. The term "quality of life" reflects the complicated idea of the necessities, comforts, and luxuries that any individual considers essential for themselves and their children; it's the level they would go to great lengths to secure. This standard varies from country to country and from one period to another. In Asian countries, it is so low that it barely meets the basic needs for survival for many people. Despite difficult conditions and a continuous series of famines, India's population increased from two hundred million to three hundred million during the last century under British rule. This kind of population "uses up all the income" without contributing to it. The major public[Pg 192] projects for irrigation, forestry, transportation, and industrial development under British rule created opportunities for a better quality of life; however, it ended up just allowing for more people to endure the same old suffering. These facts are relevant to the issue of Asian immigration to America. The emigration of millions of Chinese from their homeland would not create a shortage in their population. Continuously populating their own land according to their own quality of life, they have the ability, if drawn here in large numbers, to inhabit this continent to the same extent.

The American standard

The American standard of living, while it differs in different classes, is on the whole the highest found anywhere in the world. The increasing appeal to individual selfishness in the last twenty-five years, the greater ease of travel and taste for it, the multiplied and costly pleasures and pastimes, make children a greater and greater burden. The abnormal conditions of city life increase the sacrifice required to support children, and take away a large part of the value of their services in the home. In the greater cities are whole areas larger than the city of Ithaca where children are not admitted to the apartment houses, where no one who has a child can rent rooms. Despite the increasing incomes of the masses of the population, the number of childless homes is increasing, and while the standard of comfort grows, the size of the average family dwindles.

The American standard of living, while varying across different social classes, is overall the highest anywhere in the world. Over the past twenty-five years, the rising appeal of individual self-interest, easier travel and the desire for it, and the many expensive pleasures and activities have made raising children an even bigger burden. The abnormal conditions of city life increase the sacrifices needed to support children and reduce the value of their contributions to the household. In major cities, there are entire areas larger than the city of Ithaca that don’t allow children in the apartment buildings, where anyone with a child can’t rent rooms. Despite the increasing incomes of many people, the number of childless households is growing, and while the standard of comfort improves, the average family size is getting smaller.

The decreasing death-rate

3. Great improvements in medical and in sanitary science are decreasing the death-rate and thus partly neutralizing the effects of a lower birth-rate. The death-rate in a community is a fairly good index of its general welfare. The death of a large proportion of the children before they arrive at maturity indicates poverty or ignorance. The death-rate in the Middle Ages, especially in cities, was tremendously high, but during the last hundred years has steadily decreased. The race of man which, ever since the beginnings of volitional control, probably has had a smaller death-rate relative to the[Pg 193] total number of individuals coming into existence than has any other species of living creatures, has to-day a far lower rate than ever before. Even in the most miserable industrial population where one half the children die before they are five years old, the death-rate is much less than among the young of the lion or the eagle.

3. Big advancements in medical and public health science are lowering the death rate, which is partly balancing out the effects of a declining birth rate. The death rate in a community is a pretty good indicator of its overall well-being. A high number of child deaths before they reach adulthood points to poverty or lack of knowledge. The death rate during the Middle Ages, especially in cities, was extremely high, but in the last hundred years, it has consistently gone down. Humanity, which has likely had a lower death rate compared to the[Pg 193] total number of individuals born than any other species, today has a much lower rate than ever before. Even in the poorest industrial populations where half of the children die before age five, the death rate is still less than that of young lions or eagles.

The quality of population counts

4. Volitional control is acting with the greatest force in the more capable classes and thus threatens to reduce the quality of the population. The quality of population is of more import than its quantity, alike in its economic, its social, and its ethical results. The productive force of a population is not measured merely by numbers. "Who" make up the population at any moment is no more a matter of indifference than "how many." One new-born child represents a negative addition to society, unintelligent, incapable, foredoomed to become a burden; another, with energy, thrift, inventive genius, comes to enrich and uplift his fellow-men. Quality counts for much.

4. Volitional control is operating with the strongest influence among the more capable groups, which ultimately poses a risk to diminishing the overall quality of the population. The quality of the population matters more than its quantity, affecting economic, social, and ethical outcomes alike. The productive capability of a population isn't just about how many people there are. "Who" makes up the population at any point in time is just as important as "how many." One newborn child can be a negative addition to society—unintelligent, unable, and likely to become a burden—while another, filled with energy, determination, and creativity, can contribute to and elevate those around them. Quality is very important.

Change in the American birth-rate

The average number of children reaching maturity in the families of the American colonists was six; the average number to-day in families of American descent is about two. Since many of these do not live to maturity, and of those who do survive many do not marry, the stock does not maintain itself in numbers. Much larger families are found among the poor whites of the mountains, the foreign population, the rate negroes, and, in general, in the lower ranks of labor. Forces are at work to sterilize or reduce in number the more intelligent elements of the population. The "new woman" movement, tempting into "careers," takes away from family life many of the women most worthy to become the mothers of succeeding generations, Self-interest is at war with the social interest. The individual asks, "Am I bound to sacrifice my comfort and happiness to the general good?" If this continues, the result must be a steady decline in the proportion of the population born of the successful strains of stock, and a steady increase of the descendants of the mediocre and duller-witted elements.

The average number of children reaching adulthood in the families of American colonists was six; today, the average number in families of American descent is about two. Since many of these children don’t reach adulthood, and among those who do survive, many don’t marry, the population isn't maintaining its numbers. Much larger families can be found among the poor white communities in the mountains, the immigrant population, and the Black community, as well as generally in the lower working class. Various factors are working to limit or reduce the more educated segments of the population. The "new woman" movement, which encourages women to pursue "careers," takes many of the most capable women away from family life, who would otherwise make great mothers for future generations. Self-interest clashes with the social interest. The individual wonders, "Am I obligated to sacrifice my own comfort and happiness for the greater good?" If this trend continues, the outcome will be a gradual decline in the proportion of the population coming from successful lineages and a steady rise in the descendants of those who are average or less intelligent.

Rate of increase in the nineteenth century

5. Population increased at an unprecedented rate throughout Christendom in the nineteenth century, but the pace is now slackening. The nineteenth century saw a great increase in the food-supplies available for Europe. The resources of the American continent were hardly touched until the great Western movement of population began and new agencies of transportation brought American fields thousands of miles nearer to European markets. The improvement of machinery and of other economic equipment in Europe likewise aided to increase production rapidly. Population followed, though not with equal step. Europe had a population of 200,000,000 in 1800, nearly 400,000,000 in 1900. The increase in England was from 12 to 18 per cent, each decade; it had 8,000,000 in 1800 and 30,000,000 in 1900. The United States had 5,000,000 at the beginning of the century and 75,000,000 at the close, an increase of over 30 per cent, each decade. Recently there has been a notable decline in the rate of increase in all the countries of Europe. France is already at the stationary stage, and England probably will have reached it by the middle of the century. The rate of increase by decades has fallen in America from thirty-three to twenty-four since the Civil War. Though the movement of the population is still upward, large classes are stationary or declining in numbers.

5. The population grew at an unprecedented rate across Christendom in the nineteenth century, but that pace is now slowing down. The nineteenth century experienced a significant increase in the food supplies available for Europe. The resources of the American continent remained largely untapped until the major westward migration began, and new transportation methods brought American farms thousands of miles closer to European markets. The advancement in machinery and other economic tools in Europe also contributed to a rapid increase in production. Population growth followed, but not at the same rate. Europe had a population of 200 million in 1800 and nearly 400 million in 1900. In England, the growth was from 12 to 18 percent each decade; it had 8 million in 1800 and 30 million in 1900. The United States started the century with 5 million people and ended with 75 million, an increase of over 30 percent each decade. Recently, there has been a significant decline in the rate of population growth in all European countries. France is already at a stable stage, and England will likely reach it by mid-century. The growth rate in America has dropped from thirty-three to twenty-four since the Civil War. While overall population numbers are still rising, large segments of the population are either stable or declining in numbers.

Conclusion

Population should increase more slowly than wealth and resources if progress is to go on. It has done so in the past century, and there is no probability of a too rapid increase in Christendom in the near future. A stationary or declining population, while not desirable, is not an impossibility. But this does not destroy the significance of the fact that there is inherent in humanity a great potential power of increase, the realization of which would be disastrous, the control of which is an important and ever-present condition of the social welfare.

Population should grow more slowly than wealth and resources if progress is going to continue. It has happened this way in the past century, and there’s no likelihood of a rapid increase in Christianity in the near future. While a stable or declining population isn’t ideal, it’s not impossible either. However, this doesn’t diminish the importance of the fact that humanity has a significant potential for growth, and realizing that potential could be disastrous. Controlling this growth is a crucial and ongoing aspect of social well-being.


CHAPTER 22

CONDITIONS FOR EFFICIENT LABOR

§ I. OBJECTIVE PHYSICAL CONDITIONS

Subjective and objective factors of efficiency

1. The efficiency of labor, in its broadest sense, is its ability to render services or produce things that minister to welfare. The efficiency of labor is a resultant of many influences. In part it depends on the physical and mental powers of men; in part on things outside of the worker that either stimulate and strengthen him, or give him more favorable conditions in which to work. These are respectively the subjective and the objective factors of efficiency. In its broader sense, therefore, the phrase "efficiency of labor" implies any and every influence that makes for a larger and better supply of goods.

1. The efficiency of labor, in its broadest sense, is its ability to provide services or produce things that enhance well-being. Labor efficiency is influenced by many factors. It partly depends on the physical and mental abilities of individuals; it also relies on external factors that either motivate and empower them or create better working conditions. These are known as the subjective and objective factors of efficiency. Thus, in a broader sense, the term "efficiency of labor" refers to any and all influences that contribute to a greater and improved supply of goods.

Bounty and goodness of productive agents affect the output of labor

2. The efficiency of labor is limited objectively by the abundance and quality of material resources. Material resources include both those called natural (as the field and its fertile qualities), and those called artificial (as improvements and machinery). According as these resources are more or less developed, as labor is employed in a fertile or a barren field, with a sharp tool or a dull one, with a highly developed machine or a poor one, the product is more or less. If resources were much more abundant than at present, many goods now scarce would become almost, or quite, free. In the last chapter it was shown that an increase of the labor in a limited area or with a limited supply of indirect agents results in a decline in the relative bounty of the environment. A certain part of the result is thought of as[Pg 196] due to material agents, a certain part to labor. "Efficiency of labor" is thought of in the narrower sense as the part of the product that is logically attributable to labor,—the laborer's contribution to the value of the product,—as apart from rent, the part attributable to material resources.

2. The productivity of labor is objectively limited by the availability and quality of material resources. Material resources include both those considered natural (like the land and its fertile qualities), and those considered artificial (such as improvements and machinery). Depending on how developed these resources are, whether labor is used in a fertile or barren area, with a sharp tool or a dull one, or with a highly advanced machine or a basic one, the output will vary. If resources were significantly more abundant than they are now, many currently scarce goods would become nearly, or completely, free. In the last chapter, it was demonstrated that increasing labor in a limited area or with a limited supply of indirect resources leads to a decrease in the relative benefits the environment provides. A certain portion of the outcome is attributed to[Pg 196] material resources, while another portion is attributed to labor. "Productivity of labor" is understood in a narrower sense as the part of the output logically linked to labor—the laborer's contribution to the value of the product—distinct from rent, which is attributed to material resources.

Causal relation of wages and efficiency; food

3. The laborer's efficiency is greatly affected by the quality of his food, clothing, and shelter. Usually workmen that are getting good wages enjoy abundant food and creature comforts; poorly paid workers go scantily fed. The question arises: which is cause, which effect? Some maintain that all that is needed to make workmen more efficient is to feed them well. In some cases this is probably true. The Porto Ricans enlisted in the American regular army are reported to have increased at once in strength, weight, and vigor; the Filipino recruits, thanks to the American army rations, soon outgrew their uniforms. Some employers in Europe pay their workmen an extra sum on condition that it is spent for meat. But if wages increase, it is by no means certain that more or better food will be bought or if it is that the workmen's powers will be increased. There is a limit to the benefits of increasing food. There is some reason to believe that in America great numbers of our people, perhaps even many manual laborers, would be better off if they bought simpler and less costly food. The maximum of health and vigor may be attained with moderate outlay, and beyond that point richer food doubtless does more harm than good. Poor judgment in the selection of food is shown in many workers' families, and there is no appreciation of its influence on health.

3. The efficiency of workers is heavily influenced by the quality of their food, clothing, and shelter. Typically, well-paid workers enjoy plenty of food and comforts, while those with lower wages often struggle to get enough to eat. This raises the question: which is the cause, and which is the effect? Some argue that simply providing better food for workers would make them more efficient. In some situations, this might be true. Reports suggest that Puerto Ricans enlisted in the American army quickly gained strength, weight, and energy; Filipino recruits, thanks to the army rations, soon outgrew their uniforms. Some employers in Europe offer their workers extra money as long as it’s spent on meat. However, if wages go up, it’s not guaranteed that workers will buy more or better food, or that their performance will improve as a result. There’s a limit to the benefits of simply increasing food intake. There’s reason to believe that many Americans, including quite a few manual laborers, might actually be better off if they chose simpler, less expensive food. Maximum health and energy can be achieved with moderate spending, and beyond that point, richer food likely does more harm than good. Many workers’ families show poor judgment in their food choices and often don’t recognize how it affects their health.

An experiment in feeding

A few years ago an experiment in the feeding of pigs was tried on the Cornell farm. Four groups of six pigs each were put in four different pens and fed four different rations. Though alike in breed and age; the groups began at once to differ in character. One group squealed more; another scratched more; another waxed fat faster. Every week they were weighed, and finally were butchered, hung[Pg 197] up, and photographed. At that same time, at the Elmira Reformatory Mr. Brockway was experimenting on some criminals of the lower class. They were given daily baths, special physical exercises, and were fed on a specially bountiful diet. Scientific philanthropy stopped there, but photographs "before and after," reproduced in the printed reports, show the great physical improvement that resulted, and a marked change occurred likewise in disposition and intelligence. Many laboratory experiments have been made of late to test the chemical nature and the physiological effects of foods. It is becoming more fully recognized that the quality and quantity of food, and the cooking of it, have a great influence on the economic quality of the worker.

A few years ago, an experiment on feeding pigs was conducted on the Cornell farm. Four groups of six pigs each were placed in different pens and given four different diets. Although they were the same breed and age, the groups quickly started to show different behaviors. One group squealed more, another scratched more, and another gained weight faster. They were weighed weekly and eventually were butchered, hung up, and photographed. At the same time, at the Elmira Reformatory, Mr. Brockway was conducting experiments on some lower-class criminals. They received daily baths, participated in special physical exercises, and were provided with a rich diet. Scientific philanthropy stopped there, but "before and after" photographs included in the printed reports demonstrate the significant physical improvements that occurred, along with noticeable changes in disposition and intelligence. Many laboratory experiments have recently been conducted to examine the chemical properties and physiological effects of foods. It is becoming increasingly clear that the quality and quantity of food, as well as how it's prepared, significantly affect the economic productivity of workers.

Clothing

The effect of the quality and amount of clothing, while of course varying with the climate, is in general of less practical importance. Loss of heat and energy, dulling the powers, stiffening the muscles, causing illness with many trains of evils, make ill-clad workmen inefficient. The cost of clothing enough for comfort is, however, comparatively small, the amount spent for ornament is comparatively high. Even more important in its effects on efficiency is housing. The conditions in the factory and in the home make for health or for disease.

The impact of clothing quality and quantity varies with the climate, but overall, it's generally less significant. When workers are poorly dressed, they lose heat and energy, which makes them less effective by dulling their abilities and stiffening their muscles, leading to illness and various other problems. However, the cost of having enough comfortable clothing is relatively low, while the amount spent on decoration is much higher. Even more crucial for efficiency is housing. The conditions in factories and homes contribute to either health or illness.

Physical conditions surrounding labor grow worse or better

4. The growth of society is, for the average man, making some of the conditions of efficiency more difficult, others more easy, to secure. In agricultural and sparse populations fresh air, sunshine, good water, and unbounded natural playgrounds for children, where they can grow into strong and efficient manhood, are free goods. As population grows more dense, these things become more difficult to secure; men are brought into unnatural conditions, the evils of slum and factory life develop, and the housing problem appears.

4. The growth of society means that, for the average person, some of the conditions for efficiency are becoming harder to achieve, while others are getting easier. In rural and low-density areas, fresh air, sunshine, clean water, and plenty of natural spaces for kids to play and grow into strong, capable adults are freely available. As the population becomes more dense, accessing these resources becomes more challenging; people end up in unnatural environments, the issues of living in slums and working in factories arise, and the housing crisis becomes a reality.

The character of the housing and working places could well be left to individuals in early times. If the individual chose to live and work in unsuitable places and under unsanitary conditions, it was usually his own fault and he bore[Pg 198] the consequences. When the unsanitary conditions about each family are visited upon its neighbors, society must deal with them. Engineering, sanitary science, and medicine must be directed against the evils; factory and tenement-house legislation must seek to make possible a decent life in the cities, the factories, and the homes. Indeed, in many places the development in these and other directions has enabled the mass of the workers to enjoy blessings impossible to the most favored in the past.

The character of housing and workplaces could once be left up to individuals. If someone chose to live and work in unsuitable and unsanitary conditions, it was usually their own fault, and they faced[Pg 198] the consequences. However, when unsanitary conditions in one household affect its neighbors, society must address the problem. Engineering, sanitation, and medicine need to tackle these issues; laws regarding factories and tenement housing should aim to create decent living conditions in cities, factories, and homes. In fact, in many places, advancements in these areas have allowed workers to enjoy benefits that were unattainable for even the most privileged in the past.

§ II. SOCIAL CONDITIONS FAVORING EFFICIENCY

Government to insure the reward to labor

1. The first social condition for the workers' efficiency is political security. For the same reason that this condition is favorable to the growth of capital, it is essential if men are to labor in the present and for the future. As the framers of the Constitution expressed it, the function of government is to insure domestic tranquillity, provide for the common defense, and insure the blessings of liberty to the citizen. Directness and certainty of reward are more essential than mere size of reward in insuring action and effort. There must be a close relation between work and the fruits of work. Political insecurity weakens this relation and makes the reward dependent on chance.

1. The first social condition for workers' efficiency is political security. Just as this condition promotes capital growth, it's crucial for people to work now and in the future. As the framers of the Constitution put it, the government's role is to ensure domestic peace, provide for the common defense, and secure the blessings of liberty for citizens. The clarity and reliability of rewards are more important than the size of those rewards when it comes to motivating action and effort. There needs to be a strong connection between work and its results. Political instability undermines this connection and makes rewards reliant on luck.

Common honesty as a condition to efficient labor

2. The prevalence of standards of honesty in private and public business is a condition to high efficiency. Corruption in government has the same effect as political insecurity; in fact, it is but another form of it. We are accustomed to the thought that in an Asiatic despotism a worker beginning a task is uncertain whether he will reap the reward, as public officials may at any moment seize upon the fruits of his labor. But in our own country similar evils are not entirely lacking. Assessments often are unfair, and justice sometimes is bought. Men in high executive positions are able to make or mar the fortunes of their followers. Sometimes a legislator from a country town goes[Pg 199] to the state capital poor and returns rich. Such things becoming generally known tend to break down the motives to industry. They breed the notion that wealth is more dependent on chance or jobbery than on efficient service. Dishonesty in private business means the use of energy not to produce wealth, not to add to the sum for all to enjoy, but to get it from some one else. Public corruption and commercial dishonesty alike entail on the industrious not only the immediate loss, but the far greater cost of weakened character, relaxed energy, and decreased efficiency of labor.

2. The existence of honesty standards in both private and public business is crucial for high efficiency. Corruption in government has the same impact as political instability; in fact, it's just another form of it. We often think that in an Asian despotism, a worker starting a task is unsure whether he will receive any reward since public officials might seize the fruits of his labor at any moment. However, in our own country, similar issues are not entirely absent. Assessments are often unfair, and justice can sometimes be bought. People in high executive roles can make or break the fortunes of those who follow them. Occasionally, a legislator from a small town goes[Pg 199] to the state capital poor and returns wealthy. When such things become widely known, they undermine the motivation to work hard. They create the belief that wealth relies more on luck or corruption than on efficient service. Dishonesty in private business means using energy not to create wealth or contribute to the overall good but to take it from someone else. Both public corruption and commercial dishonesty impose not only immediate losses on the diligent but also the much greater price of weakened character, decreased energy, and reduced efficiency of labor.

Effect of caste on efficiency of lower and upper classes

3. Custom and social ideals that raise or depress hope and ambition, affect efficiency. The institution called caste, which fixes the place of the worker and makes it impossible to rise out of the social position in which he is born, and disgraceful to do any work reserved to other castes, is deadening to energy. It exists in some form throughout the world, and where it is not called by that name, the same caste spirit is at work. The European peasants in the Middle Ages lived under the shadow of it. Where slavery exists the master class at times feels its hardships. "It is not so hard to live," says the hungry Creole daughter in "The Grandissimes," "but it is hard to be ladies.... We are compelled not to make a living. Look at me: I can cook, but I must not cook; I am skilful with the needle, but I must not take in sewing; I could keep accounts; I could nurse the sick; but I must not." Nowhere in the world is there less caste than in America, but it is here. The negro's low measure of industrial virtues is partly the cause of the prejudice against him, but in turn doubtless inherited class feeling is in some measure the cause of his inefficiency. To close to a worker all but the menial occupations is to take from him the most powerful motives for effort. The thought is paralyzing. The race problem in America is in part one of caste sentiment, whatever can or cannot be done about it.

3. Customs and social ideals that raise or lower hope and ambition affect efficiency. The institution known as caste, which determines a worker's place and makes it impossible to rise above the social position they are born into, and makes it shameful to do any work assigned to other castes, dulls their energy. It exists in some form around the world, and where it isn't labeled as such, the same caste mentality is still present. European peasants in the Middle Ages lived overshadowed by it. Where slavery exists, the ruling class sometimes feels its burdens. "It isn't so hard to live," says the hungry Creole daughter in "The Grandissimes," "but it's hard to be women.... We are forced to not earn a living. Look at me: I can cook, but I must not cook; I'm skilled with a needle, but I must not take in sewing; I could keep records; I could care for the sick; but I must not." Nowhere in the world is there less caste than in America, but it still exists here. The low perception of industrial skills among Black people partly contributes to the prejudice against them, but inherited class feelings also play a role in their inefficiency. Restricting a worker to only menial jobs removes their strongest motivations for effort. This thought is paralyzing. The race problem in America is partly a matter of caste sentiment, regardless of what can or cannot be done about it.

American democracy and the efficiency of labor

Democracy makes for the efficiency of American industry[Pg 200] not less than do the great natural resources. If America is to surpass the world in all the great industrial lines, it will be largely because of her ideas and institutions. They lead to greater energy and to a faster working pace in all grades of labor than is found anywhere else in the world. There is danger that as the West is closed to settlement something of the spirit of enterprise will be lost. To Western eyes already the young men in the older East seem to be trammeled by social conventions. In an older community there is less of hopeful ambition; one's position depends more on what his fathers achieved; in the new community, more on what he does himself. If it is true, as wise students declare, that the frontier has been the nursery of our democratic ideas, we may well ask what effect the closing of the frontier will have on our national sentiment and on our material prosperity.

Democracy boosts the efficiency of American industry[Pg 200] just as much as the vast natural resources do. If America is going to outshine the rest of the world in major industrial sectors, it will mainly be due to its ideas and institutions. These foster greater energy and a faster work pace across all levels of labor than is seen anywhere else globally. There is a risk that as the West becomes closed off to settlement, some of the spirit of enterprise will fade. To those in the West, the young men in the older East already seem constrained by social norms. In an older community, there's less hopeful ambition; a person's position relies more on what their parents achieved; in a new community, it's more about what they accomplish themselves. If it's true, as insightful observers suggest, that the frontier has nurtured our democratic ideals, we should seriously consider what closing the frontier will mean for our national attitude and economic prosperity.

The balance of advantage between work and leisure

4. Custom and national temperament affect the efficiency of labor by determining the normal period of labor time. After the bare necessities of life are provided for, the worker has a wide or narrow margin of productive energy to use as he pleases. If four hours' work a day would enable him to live, will he work longer or will he stop? The answer is determined by the balance of utility and disutility. Will additional hours of labor yield more gratification than idleness yields? Does the pain of toil repel more than its fruits attract? The use made of spare time differs according to climate, race, and temperament. In the tropics the margin is converted usually into loafing, in the temperate zones largely into objective forms of enjoyment. Individual differences are plainly seen when each man labors on his own field. The prudent man, in the old maxims, makes hay while the sun shines and ploughs deep while sluggards sleep. In the modern larger organization of industry, working hours are much the same for all workers in the establishment. Individual preferences are still expressed, however, in irregularity of employment. In the South some manufacturers[Pg 201] have found that on an average the negroes will work in a factory not more than five or six hours a day, working ten hours for four days and lying off two days a week. Such a standard of working hours is the mark of the primitive stage of wants and industrial qualities, although a shortening of the hours of manual labor, as incomes increase above bare subsistence, is in accord with a rational valuation of leisure. A moderate change in that direction cannot but increase rather than diminish the efficiency of labor.

4. Customs and national temperament influence how effectively labor is performed by setting the standard work hours. Once the essential needs of life are met, a worker has a certain amount of productive energy that he can choose to use however he likes. If working four hours a day is enough for him to get by, will he choose to work longer, or will he stop? The decision depends on the balance between the benefits and drawbacks of working more hours. Will the extra hours of work provide more satisfaction than the enjoyment of free time? Does the discomfort of work outweigh the rewards it brings? How free time is spent varies based on climate, ethnicity, and personality. In tropical regions, people often use this extra time for leisure, while in temperate areas, it tends to involve more active forms of enjoyment. Individual differences become evident when each worker operates on their own land. The careful person, as age-old sayings suggest, takes advantage of good weather and works hard while others are idle. In the modern large-scale industry, work hours tend to be similar for all employees within a company. However, individual choices still emerge through different work patterns. In the South, some manufacturers[Pg 201] have discovered that, on average, Black workers only tend to work in a factory for about five or six hours a day, often putting in ten-hour shifts for four days and taking two days off each week. This standard work schedule reflects a basic level of needs and industrial skills, but as incomes rise above mere survival, the reduction of manual labor hours aligns with a logical appreciation of leisure time. A moderate shift toward fewer hours is likely to enhance rather than reduce labor efficiency.

§ III. DIVISION OF LABOR

Division and exchange of labor

1. Division of labor is a term expressing that complex arrangement of industrial society whereby individual workers are enabled to apply themselves to the production of certain kinds of goods, securing others by exchange. The term "division of labor" is simple, but the thought is a complex one. Its full discussion would cover the whole field of political economy, but only its most essential aspects can here be touched upon. Division of labor and exchange are counterparts and mutually determine each other. Division of labor depends on the extent of the market, and in turn widens its limits. The number of articles that any one would care to produce at one time and place depends upon the opportunity to exchange them. These two aspects of industry thus are inseparable in thought and practice. The worker finds division of labor existing as a social institution and, according as he adapts himself to it wisely or foolishly, it increases more or less his efficiency.

1. The division of labor is a concept that describes the complex setup of industrial society where individual workers can focus on producing specific types of goods, which they obtain from others through trade. The phrase "division of labor" is straightforward, but the idea behind it is intricate. A comprehensive discussion would encompass the entire realm of political economy, but we will only touch on its most crucial aspects here. Division of labor and exchange are interconnected and influence each other. The division of labor relies on the size of the market, which in turn expands its boundaries. The quantity of items someone is willing to produce at a given time and place is influenced by the ability to trade them. Therefore, these two elements of industry are inseparable in both thought and practice. The worker encounters division of labor as a social institution, and depending on how wisely or foolishly he adapts to it, his efficiency may increase or decrease.

Division of labor between trades and territories

2. Division of labor is primarily between individuals, but appears between trades, territories, and nations. In division of labor between trades, each worker applies himself to the production of some product or group of products and secures other goods by exchange. A special form of this is territorial division of labor, arising out of differences in soil, climate, and natural products, when each community[Pg 202] develops in a high degree some one class of products to exchange in distant or foreign trade. Division of labor beginning because of such natural differences, becomes fixed by habit and training, by the advantage of a larger and regular labor supply, by the economy of nearness to related and tributary industries, and by the use of waste products where industry is conducted on a large scaled. The natural advantages in another district must be large to enable it to start successfully against these acquired economies, and territorial division of labor thus tends to continue for long periods when once established.

2. The division of labor mainly happens among individuals, but also occurs between industries, regions, and countries. In the division of labor among industries, each worker focuses on making a specific product or group of products and trades for other goods. A specific type of this is the territorial division of labor, which arises from differences in soil, climate, and natural resources, where each community[Pg 202] excels in producing a particular type of product for trade locally or internationally. The division of labor starts because of these natural differences and becomes established through habits and training, the benefit of having a larger and consistent workforce, better proximity to related industries, and the use of byproducts when production is done on a large scale. The natural advantages in another region must be significant to successfully compete against these established efficiencies, and as a result, territorial division of labor tends to persist for extended periods once it's in place.

Advantages of division of labor

3. Division of labor increases efficiency by: (a) increasing skill; (b) saving time; (c) saving tools and materials; (d) improving quality; (e) increasing knowledge; (f) stimulating invention; (g) encouraging enterprise; (h) economizing talent. There is a tradition that an ingenious lecturer in one of our universities was accustomed to give to his class eighty reasons why division of labor was of advantage. It is none too many, as every reason for the modern, as contrasted with the primitive, organization of industry should be included. The phrase division of labor is but a synonym for specialization, a word that expresses all that is most characteristic of our complex industrial society. The headings just given may serve, however, to suggest the leading phases of the subject. Repetition of the same task trains the muscles, forms a mental habit, and gives the swiftness and deftness of touch called skill. Specialization saves time by making unnecessary the physical change of place for the worker, the frequent shifting of tools, and the mental readjustment required for the undertaking of a new task. Specialization saves tools for, either each kind of work must be most ineffectively done, or there must be provided for each worker a complete set of tools which thus will be used rarely and will rust out rather than wear out. If a few tools are thoroughly used, they yield a larger income on the investment, and require less care and repairs in proportion[Pg 203] to their uses. In fact this fuller economic use of machinery and plant where a large product is turned out at one place, is a prime factor in the advantages of large production, a subject to be treated elsewhere much more fully than is here possible. By specialization is made possible a quality of goods never to be secured by the less skilled efforts of the Jack-of-all trades. The specialist steadily grows in knowledge of his materials and of the best processes, and he gains a power of delicate observation and facility in meeting new difficulties that are impossible when attention is divided among a number of tasks. By dividing and simplifying processes, specialization stimulates invention. The most complex machines have been developed gradually by combinations and adaptations of simple tools, and the more a process is subdivided, the greater is the chance of hitting upon a device to repeat mechanically the few simple movements. Division of labor increases the motives of emulation and enterprise, by making possible the more exact comparison of results. It economizes talent by giving to each the highest task of which he is capable, while fitting the less efficient workers into the minor places made possible by subdivision. In an American wagon-factory, a one-armed man operating a machine is turning out as large a product and earning as high wages as any other employee. The same advantages of specialization are found with modifying conditions in educational and professional lines. The marvelous progress of science in recent years has been made possible by each worker's doing a few things and doing them well.

3. Dividing labor boosts efficiency by: (a) enhancing skills; (b) saving time; (c) conserving tools and materials; (d) improving quality; (e) increasing knowledge; (f) inspiring innovation; (g) encouraging entrepreneurship; (h) optimizing talent. There's a tradition that a clever lecturer at one of our universities would share eighty reasons why division of labor is beneficial. That number isn’t too many, as each rationale for modern versus primitive industry organization should be included. The term division of labor is essentially a synonym for specialization, a concept that captures the essence of our complex industrial society. The points mentioned can highlight the key aspects of the topic. Doing the same task repeatedly trains muscles, develops a mental habit, and brings about the speed and skillfulness we refer to as skill. Specialization saves time by removing the need for workers to physically change locations, frequently switch tools, and mentally readjust when taking on new tasks. Specialization conserves tools because either each type of work must be done ineffectively, or every worker must be given a complete set of tools that will be used infrequently and rust out instead of being worn out. If a few tools are used extensively, they yield a greater return on investment and require less maintenance and repairs relative to their usage.[Pg 203] In fact, the more efficient use of machinery and operations in a large production setting is a key advantage of large scale production, a subject to be discussed in greater detail elsewhere. Specialization enables a quality of goods that cannot be achieved by the less skilled efforts of a generalist. The specialist continuously expands his knowledge of materials and optimal processes, developing a keen ability to observe and handle new challenges that would be difficult if attention were divided among various tasks. By breaking down and simplifying processes, specialization stimulates invention. The most intricate machines have been developed over time through the combination and adaptation of simple tools, and the more a process is divided, the higher the likelihood of finding a method to mechanically replicate simple movements. Division of labor boosts the motivation for competition and enterprise by allowing more precise comparisons of results. It optimizes talent by assigning each individual the most challenging tasks they can handle, while fitting less efficient workers into smaller roles created through subdivision. In an American wagon factory, a one-armed man operating a machine produces as much as any other employee and earns comparable wages. The same benefits of specialization are seen under changing conditions in education and professional fields. The incredible advancements in science in recent years have been made possible by each worker focusing on a few tasks and excelling at them.

Best adjustment of talent and occupation
Choice of a life career

4. The individual worker, to attain his highest economic efficiency, must select from the occupations made possible by division of labor the one for which his talents are best fitted. It seems unnecessary to state this almost axiomatic truth, yet the slight reflection given to the choice of an occupation by most young people gives to this statement a very practical bearing. The world is filled with industrial misfits,[Pg 204] "round men in square holes," good carpenters spoiled to make poor doctors. It so often happens that the natural aptitude of the youth is the thing last or, in any event, least considered. Unreasoning imitation, family traditions, parental wishes, class pride, social prejudice, childish whim, are often decisive of the life career. Happily in some cases, before too late, the man "finds himself," but too often the poverty of the family and the obstacles to education preclude the exercise of intelligent choice. It is of importance to society as well as to the individual that talent should be discovered in time, that tasks should be fitted to aptitudes, that each member of society should attain to his highest efficiency. The approach to this ideal, made possible by popular education, the decline of caste, the spread of genuine democracy, the progress of social justice, will increase not only the workers' efficiency, but society's abiding welfare.

4. To reach their highest economic efficiency, individual workers need to choose jobs suited to their skills from the options created by division of labor. While it might seem obvious to say this, the lack of thoughtful consideration about job choices by many young people makes this statement relevant. There are many people in jobs that don't fit them well, like "round pegs in square holes," with capable carpenters ending up as mediocre doctors. Often, young people's natural abilities are the last things they or others consider. Factors like blind imitation, family expectations, parental desires, class pride, social biases, and childish whims often determine career paths. Thankfully, in some cases, individuals "find themselves" before it’s too late, but too often, financial struggles and barriers to education prevent intelligent choices. It’s crucial for both society and the individual to identify talent in time, align tasks with skills, and help every member of society achieve their highest potential. Advancements toward this ideal—through accessible education, the decline of social classes, authentic democracy, and the pursuit of social justice—will not only enhance the efficiency of workers but also contribute to the lasting welfare of society.


CHAPTER 23

THE LAW OF WAGES

§ I. NATURE OF WAGES AND THE WAGES PROBLEM

Wages and rent compared and contrasted

1. Wage in the broad sense is the income due to labor, in distinction from that due to the control of material agents. The uses of material agents, studied under the subject of rent, are sometimes called "material services." The adjective refers to the source or bearer of the use, and does not imply that the service is to be thought of as a material thing. In its last analysis a service is never a material thing, but a psychic effect on men and their wants. Material services and human services are merely specific kinds of the genus services (or utilities), and it would doubtless be a better usage to speak of labor's services and wealth's uses. Wages bear the same relation to man's services that rent does to the material uses of wealth. Wages are more like rent than like interest in that neither wages nor rent are expressed as a percentage. While rent is the value of the uses of things, wages is the value of the services of men. In discussing interest, wealth is capitalized; but, in discussing wages, men are thought of as affording utilities for a time, as is wealth under the renting contract. The resemblance thus is very close between rent and wages, but not so close between wages and interest.

1. Wages, in a broad sense, are the income earned from labor, as opposed to income earned from controlling tangible assets. The use of tangible assets, studied under the topic of rent, is sometimes referred to as "material services." The adjective focuses on the source or provider of the use and doesn't suggest that the service should be viewed as a physical object. Ultimately, a service is never a physical thing but rather a psychological impact on people and their needs. Material services and human services are just specific types of the broader category of services (or utilities), and it may be more accurate to refer to labor's services and the uses of wealth. Wages have a similar relationship to human services as rent does to the tangible uses of wealth. Wages are more comparable to rent than to interest since both wages and rent aren't expressed as a percentage. While rent represents the value of utilizing things, wages represent the value of the services provided by people. When discussing interest, wealth is considered as capital; however, when talking about wages, people are seen as providing utilities temporarily, similar to how wealth is viewed under a rental agreement. Therefore, the similarity between rent and wages is quite strong, but less so between wages and interest.

Despite this interesting analogy, it is not well to speak, as some do, of "the rent of labor"—as well might one speak of the wages of wealth. Such a usage only beclouds the[Pg 206] distinction between two concepts, suggesting identity where there are important differences. The aim of scientific classification is missed when contrasts are thus concealed under a single term.

Despite this interesting analogy, it's not a good idea to refer to "the rent of labor"—just as it wouldn't make sense to talk about the wages of wealth. This kind of language only confuses the[Pg 206] distinction between two concepts, implying a similarity where there are significant differences. The purpose of scientific classification is lost when contrasts are obscured by using a single term.

Nature of the law of wages

2. A law of wages is a statement of the relation of the general causes of value to the value of human services. In real life no one agent is valued independently of other goods. The felt importance of a good depends on the degree to which other wants are gratified. If men are starving, they attach less importance to ornaments; if cold, more importance to clothing and fuel, being willing to part even with some needed food to secure them. That is, man's desire for each thing is affected by his general condition and by the existence of other goods and wants. A similar relation exists between the values of indirect agents, and must exist between wages and rent.

2. A law of wages is a statement about how the general causes of value relate to the value of human services. In reality, no single factor is valued on its own when compared to other goods. The perceived importance of a good depends on how well other needs are met. If people are starving, they care less about decorations; if they're cold, they prioritize clothing and fuel, even willing to give up some essential food to obtain them. In other words, a person's desire for anything is influenced by their overall situation and the availability of other goods and needs. A similar relationship exists between the values of indirect factors, and there must also be a connection between wages and rent.

We are to discuss the law of wages. An economic law does not state a command; it is not a political law; it states merely an observed relation. Things do not need to happen actually according to any law of wages that can be formulated, but they will happen in the measure that the assumed conditions exist. The law states a tendency of wages, just as the law of gravitation states a tendency and does not predict positively whether a given object will fall at a given moment. The "law of wages," therefore, is to be understood as a hypothetical statement of the value that will be attributed to labor under a given set of conditions.

We are going to talk about the law of wages. An economic law doesn’t issue commands; it’s not a political law; it simply describes a relationship that we’ve observed. Events don’t have to happen in accordance with any formulated law of wages, but they will occur to the extent that the assumed conditions are present. The law reflects a trend in wages, just as the law of gravitation indicates a trend without definitively predicting when a specific object will fall. Therefore, the "law of wages" should be understood as a theoretical statement about the value assigned to labor under specific conditions.

Economic wages and contract wages

3. Economic wages are the value of human services in the broad sense; contract wages are the goods paid by one wages man to another according to an agreement. In discussing rent and interest, we have become familiar with this important distinction between economic and contract values. Economic wages are fundamental, the primary subject of theoretical study. Contract wages are the wages paid by one man to another in accordance with an agreement, and may not at this moment coincide with economic wages.[Pg 207] When the contract was made, one party may have been ignorant or helpless, and have failed to get all he now could; or meantime the conditions may have changed. But contract wages are based on economic wages and tend to conform to them. If one person performs services for another without expecting to receive economic goods or services in return, it is a gift, not wages. A workman can get as contract wages the amount of his economic wage if free competition exists and he acts intelligently. Of course, these are important conditions.

3. Economic wages represent the value of human services in a broad sense; contract wages are the payments made by one worker to another based on an agreement. In our discussion of rent and interest, we've become familiar with the crucial distinction between economic and contract values. Economic wages are fundamental, forming the primary focus of theoretical study. Contract wages are the payments made by one person to another according to an agreement, and they may not currently align with economic wages.[Pg 207] When the contract was created, one party might have been unaware or powerless, resulting in them not receiving the full value they now could; or the circumstances may have changed in the meantime. However, contract wages are rooted in economic wages and usually align with them. If someone provides services to another without expecting to receive goods or services in return, it's considered a gift, not wages. A worker can receive their economic wage as contract wages if there's free competition and they make informed decisions. Of course, these are essential conditions.

Real and nominal wages must be distinguished: real wages are the reward of labor as measured in goods and enjoyments; nominal wages are the reward expressed in terms of money, whose purchasing power varies from time to time and from place to place.

Real and nominal wages need to be differentiated: real wages are the compensation for work measured in goods and experiences; nominal wages are the compensation expressed in monetary terms, which can change in value over time and across different locations.

Scarce services gratify wants

4. Human services, being one of the conditions of psychic income, bear the same relation to wants that material goods bear. As the material agents that are fitted to gratify wants are scarce, labor is applied to the outer world to change and adapt it, thus making it answer desire better. Labor, thus, in many of its applications merely supplements the bounty of nature. Men have a use to and for each other; they have a relation to other men's welfare similar to that borne by material things. The different human actions have all grades of relation to gratification, from harmful to helpful, just as things have. According to their relation to this scale services therefore become ranked either high or low in the estimation of men. Some acts are negative services, to use the term service in a paradoxical sense; they are things to be avoided and escaped. Value then is attributed to the services of men according to their rank in this scale, just as it is to the uses of agents in the case of rent.

4. Human services, which are part of our mental well-being, relate to our needs in the same way that physical goods do. Since the resources that can satisfy our needs are limited, we use labor to modify and adapt the world around us to better fulfill our desires. Labor, in many instances, simply complements what nature provides. People have a mutual need for one another; their connection to each other’s well-being is similar to how physical items interact. Different human actions have varying degrees of impact on satisfaction, ranging from harmful to beneficial, just like material goods. Based on their position on this spectrum, services are ranked as either valuable or less valuable by people. Some actions can be considered negative services, using the term service ironically; these are things we should avoid. Value is then assigned to the services provided by individuals according to their rank on this scale, similar to how we assess the value of resources in the case of rent.

Scarcity is the condition of value in labor, as it is of value in any good; but scarcity is a relative term. The commonest kinds of labor would not ordinarily be called scarce, but compared with their possible desirable uses, they are scarce,[Pg 208] and this fact is the key to a large part of the wage problem. The question is: how and in what degree does this scarcity cause value to attach to labor?

Scarcity is what gives labor its value, just like it does for any good; however, scarcity is a relative concept. The most common types of labor typically wouldn't be seen as scarce, but when compared to their potential desirable uses, they are scarce,[Pg 208] and this truth is central to much of the wage issue. The question is: how and to what extent does this scarcity create value for labor?

§ II. THE DIFFERENT MODES OF EARNING WAGES

The simplest case of economic wages

1. The self-employed laborer earns wages in the broad economic sense. In this sense the isolated workman, Robinson Crusoe on his island, earns wages, but these wages could not be measured at all exactly. They are a part of an indivisible income, and there is no way to determine how much should be attributed to the uses of the wealth employed and how much to the labor. The independent farmer, producing on his own farm nearly everything he consumes, may be said to earn wages in the broad sense. These can, moreover, be estimated, because they can be compared with what he could get by working for some one else. The farmer, therefore, attributes a certain part of his income to the farm as rent and a certain part to his own labor as wages.

1. The self-employed worker earns wages in the broad economic sense. In this way, the solitary worker, like Robinson Crusoe on his island, earns wages, but these wages can't be measured precisely. They are part of an indivisible income, and there’s no way to figure out how much should be assigned to the use of the wealth utilized and how much to the labor. The independent farmer, who produces almost everything he consumes on his own farm, can also be said to earn wages in this broad sense. Furthermore, these can be estimated, as they can be compared to what he could earn working for someone else. Therefore, the farmer attributes a certain portion of his income to the farm as rent and a certain portion to his own labor as wages.

Wages of the self-employed exchanging worker

2. The wages of self-employed labor are often simply the value of the material product it secures by exchange. Labor has value indirectly because embodied in products. The worker value of these products is reflected to the labor which secures them. The wages of the fisherman day by day, as he follows his vocation, are simply the market value of the fish he catches day by day. The gold-miner, working with simple tools in the days of placer-mining, earned wages exactly expressed by the gold he washed out.

2. The earnings of self-employed workers are typically just the value of the goods they obtain through trade. Labor has value indirectly because it's represented in products. The value of the labor that creates these products is reflected in the goods they secure. The wages of the fisherman, each day he practices his trade, are simply the market value of the fish he catches that day. The gold miner, using basic tools during the placer-mining days, earned wages exactly equivalent to the gold he extracted.

The independent worker with few tools does not think of attributing any considerable part of his income to his tools. The umbrella-mender's "kit" is so small that his true wage is little less than his total receipts. The tinker, the shoemaker, and the tailor, who went from house to house in the old days, thought only in the vaguest way of marking off from their incomes a part to be counted as the rent of their little outfit of tools. Until very recent times the capital invested[Pg 209] in tools commonly was small, and usually was owned by the handworker who thus received an undivided income, of which wages were by far the larger part. It was inevitable, therefore, that labor alone should have been thought of as the cause of the value of goods produced by the artisans in the towns and cities. This error, small at first, was magnified as the capital investment of modern industry grew, and it persists in many fallacious notions that still taint modern economic theory.

The independent worker with few tools doesn’t consider attributing any significant portion of his income to his tools. The umbrella mender's "kit" is so small that his actual earnings are just a little less than his total income. The tinker, shoemaker, and tailor who used to go from house to house back in the day only vaguely thought about setting aside a part of their earnings as the cost of their small collection of tools. Until very recently, the capital invested[Pg 209] in tools was typically minimal and usually owned by the handworker, who consequently received an undivided income, with wages being the largest part. It was inevitable, then, that labor alone would be considered the reason for the value of goods produced by artisans in towns and cities. This mistake, initially small, grew as the capital investment in modern industry increased, and it continues to influence many misleading ideas that still affect contemporary economic theory.

Both impersonal and personal causes of contract wages

3. Contract wages, paid by an employer, rest on the same cause of value, the direct or indirect effect of labor in the gratifying of wants. When contract wages come to be spoken of, the personal element of bargaining between man and man comes in to obscure somewhat the impersonal causes that are operating. If the fisher and the miner bring their products to the general markets, the impersonal part of the problem is uppermost and the wages are recognized to be the market value of the material products. But if an employer hires a number of workmen, and the labor of each becomes merged and lost to view in a complex product, the uncritical mind stops, loses all hold on a guiding principle of value, and sees only the superficial fact of a personal bargain between employer and workman. Such a view overlooks the logical cause of value, and the network of impersonal forces which enwraps and binds the personal acts.

3. Contract wages, paid by an employer, are based on the same principle of value, which is the direct or indirect impact of work in satisfying needs. When we talk about contract wages, the personal aspect of negotiation between individuals tends to overshadow the impersonal factors at play. If a fisherman and a miner bring their products to the general markets, the impersonal side of the issue takes the forefront, and wages are understood to reflect the market value of the tangible products. However, when an employer hires several workers, and the contributions of each become blended and hidden within a complex output, the uncritical observer becomes confused, losing sight of a guiding principle of value, and only perceives the superficial reality of a personal agreement between the employer and the worker. This perspective misses the underlying causes of value and the network of impersonal influences that surround and connect these personal actions.

A single direct personal service

To begin with the simplest case: workers often are temporarily employed to produce for others means of gratification at once consumed. The barber shaves his patron, the ferryman takes the traveler across the river, the boy carries a message, the surgeon sets a broken bone. Each performs a useful service, but produces no long-abiding material result outside of the beneficiary, and no separable, salable material good. When each is paid according to the value of the gratification afforded, the first step is taken toward the regular contract-wage relation between man and man.

To start with the simplest example: workers are often temporarily hired to provide services that are immediately enjoyed. The barber shaves his customer, the ferryman transports the traveler across the river, the boy delivers a message, the surgeon fixes a broken bone. Each one offers a valuable service, but creates no lasting material outcome beyond the person receiving it, and no distinct, sellable product. When each person is compensated based on the value of the service provided, the initial step is taken toward establishing a regular contract-wage relationship between individuals.

The continued wage contract for personal services

In ordinary domestic service the only condition not present[Pg 210] in the cases just given is the more abiding character of the contract relation. The employer does not hire a coachman each time he wishes to take a ride, but having summed up the advantages of a coachman's services, he buys them by the month or the year. The price is determined in the market for coachmen of the needed ability, qualities ranging from stupid to bright, from weak to strong, and from drunk to sober. Instead of buying flowers from day to day, a wealthy man hires a gardener to cultivate them in a conservatory. The average market price of flowers influences the wages paid to the gardener, his wages being but the sum of the values (or of his contribution to the values) of flowers, well-kept lawn, and garden products. According to the conditions of each household and of the general market, the one or the other mode of buying these utilities is the more advantageous.

In typical household employment, the only difference from the cases mentioned earlier[Pg 210] is the longer-term nature of the contract. The employer doesn't hire a driver every time they want to go somewhere; instead, they assess the benefits of having a driver and pay for their services monthly or yearly. The cost is set based on the market rate for drivers with the necessary skills, which can vary from average to exceptional, and from unreliable to dependable. Instead of buying flowers daily, a wealthy person might hire a gardener to grow them in a greenhouse. The average price of flowers affects what the gardener gets paid, which is essentially based on the value of the flowers, the well-maintained lawn, and other garden products they produce. Depending on each household's circumstances and the overall market, either approach to obtaining these services is more practical.

Labor employed on products exchanged

4. The payment of the laborer to produce goods for exchange is the most common modern case of wages. The relation of wages to the value of the product is in this case more complex, for the employer is directing the labor to gratifying the wants of others, not his own wants. It is the desire of prospective customers for the product, and the chance of exchanging it, that will eventually enable the employer to recover the amounts paid to laborers. Labor is only one of the elements entering into the product. Within limits it may be substituted for the other elements, fewer machines being used and more laborers, or vice versa. No more will be given for any labor than it is expected to add to the value of the product. As employers test by experience the contribution of the marginal labor to the value of the product, labor is constantly compared with the value of other things.

4. The payment to workers for producing goods to sell is the most common example of wages today. The connection between wages and the product's value is more complicated in this situation because the employer is directing labor to meet the desires of others, not his own. It's the demand from potential customers for the product, and the opportunity to sell it, that will ultimately allow the employer to recoup what they've paid to the workers. Labor is just one of the factors that contribute to the product. Within certain limits, it can be swapped for other factors, using fewer machines and hiring more workers or the other way around. No one will be paid for labor beyond what it's expected to add to the product's value. As employers learn from experience the contribution of additional labor to the product's value, they continually compare labor against the value of other resources.

When industry becomes complex, the connection between the wages and the value ultimately realized in the product may be broken for a time, but rarely for a very long time. Because of miscalculations, labor is employed on things that[Pg 211] prove to be quite valueless, and on other things that have a much greater value than was expected. When months or years intervene before the value of the labor is realized in the sale of the product, the employer must forecast the outcome as best he can, and employ labor only when the wages promise to be recovered. These are complicating facts, but in any logical view they do not falsify the principle that wages are determined by their prospective contribution to the utility of goods.

When industry gets complicated, the link between wages and the actual value of the product can break for a while, but it rarely stays broken for too long. Due to errors in judgment, workers may be hired for tasks that[Pg 211] turn out to be completely worthless, while other tasks might have much more value than expected. When there are months or years between the work done and the sale of the product, the employer has to make educated guesses about the outcome and only hire workers when there's a good chance that the wages will be recouped. These situations add complexity, but from any logical perspective, they don't undermine the idea that wages are based on their expected contribution to the usefulness of goods.

Various methods of remuneration, but one general rule

5. The wages paid by the various methods of remuneration—as, by time, by the piece, by premium for output—all conform in a general way to the economic value of the service. Many methods are employed to measure the services of wage workers. If time is used, a general or average output is assumed, and the workman must come up to that standard if he is to hold his place. If payment is by the piece, the price per piece must be enough to make possible the prevailing time-wage to workers of that grade if the supply is to be maintained in that industry. The convenience of the different methods of payment varies from industry to industry, and even from task to task within the same factory, so that now one, now another method is followed. In any case, however, the aim is to find some convenient measurement of the rate of labor, and of its contribution to the value of the product.

5. The wages paid by different compensation methods—such as hourly, per item, or bonuses for output—generally align with the economic value of the service provided. Various methods are used to assess the contributions of wage workers. When using time-based pay, an average output is expected, and the worker needs to meet that standard to keep their job. In piecework, the price per item must be set high enough to match the typical hourly wage for workers in that role to ensure there’s enough labor in that industry. The effectiveness of different payment methods varies across industries and even between tasks within the same factory, leading to a shift in methods used at different times. Regardless, the goal is to identify a useful way to measure labor rates and their contribution to the product's value.

§ III. WAGES AS EXEMPLIFYING THE GENERAL LAW OF VALUE

Ratio of exchange of services adjusted to their marginal utility

1. Each grade of labor is a potential supply of desirable things and its wage is determined in essentially the same way as if it were an actual supply. If all the various psychic goods that labor produces were spread out before men in visible form, some would be in great demand, some would exchange in a very unfavorable ratio with others. The exchange would come to equilibrium at a point where each buyer had adjusted his supply of enjoyments in the most[Pg 212] favorable way, had so distributed his purchasing power as to get those kinds and amounts of services which afford him the highest possible sum of enjoyment.

1. Every level of labor can provide valuable goods, and its pay is set in much the same way as if it were an actual supply. If all the various intangible benefits produced by labor were laid out in front of people visually, some would be highly sought after, while others would trade at a much less favorable rate. The exchange would reach balance at a point where each buyer adjusted their enjoyment in the most[Pg 212] beneficial way, distributing their spending power to obtain the types and amounts of services that give them the greatest overall satisfaction.

Differences in wages persist

In this situation the real wages of some being so much more than those of others, the low-paid workers will have a motive to change their occupations. But the various laborers have limited abilities and cannot change at will and, despite the unfavorable ratio, they may be compelled to continue at the same work. Just as apples cannot become peaches or sheep become horses when there is a change in their price, so the unskilled workman cannot become skilled quickly, if he ever can, and the possibility of changing occupations within any reasonable period is very small indeed. Labor is constantly trying to adjust itself, to get into the better-paid industries. It moves, it emigrates, it seeks training and education. Especially the workers between the ages of fifteen and twenty-five choose the callings that promise the highest reward. Within limits an adjustment is possible, but these limits are not wide and not quickly shifted, and the wages of labor continue diverse in different occupations for an indefinite time.

In this situation, some people earn significantly more than others, which gives low-paid workers a reason to change jobs. However, workers have limited skills and can't just switch jobs whenever they want. Even though the situation may not be favorable, they might have to stick with the same work. Just like apples can’t turn into peaches or sheep into horses when their prices change, unskilled workers can’t quickly become skilled, if they ever can, and the chance to switch jobs in a reasonable time frame is very small. Workers are constantly trying to adapt and move into better-paying industries. They relocate, seek training, and pursue education. Especially those between the ages of fifteen and twenty-five tend to choose careers that promise higher pay. Some adjustment is possible within limits, but those limits are narrow and don’t shift quickly, so wages for different types of labor remain varied across occupations for an indefinite time.

Various grades of labor and rates of wages

2. The term general rate of wages can be used only of a certain grade of labor and of the rate for the average worker. Every grade and kind of ability has its rate of wages. To be sure, it is sometimes convenient to speak in a broad but inexact way of "a general rate of wages," when comparing different countries and periods. When it is said that the rate of wages is higher in America than in England, in England than in France, in France than in India, the comparison is between men of the same occupation in the different countries; e.g., the unskilled laborer or the mechanic gets more here than the same grade of laborer gets in England. There is no such thing as a general rate of wages extending throughout all industries.

2. The term general rate of wages can only refer to a specific level of labor and the pay for the average worker. Every level and type of skill has its own wage rate. It can be useful to talk broadly but imprecisely about "a general rate of wages" when comparing different countries and time periods. When we say that wages are higher in America than in England, in England than in France, and in France than in India, the comparison is being made between people in the same job across different countries; e.g., an unskilled laborer or a mechanic earns more here than the same type of worker does in England. There is no such thing as a general rate of wages that applies to all industries.

The different grades of ability differ more markedly in wages than do industries compared as wholes. In[Pg 213] the manufacture of cloth all grades of ability are required, from the highly paid artist and engineer, down to the roustabout in the yard. The industries of manufacturing, commerce, and education alike require the coöperation of bookkeepers, janitors, carpenters, and superintendents. It is easy in most cases to pass from any grade of occupation in one industry to a corresponding grade in another industry; but it is difficult to pass from a lower grade to a higher grade in the same or another industry.

The different levels of skill show a bigger difference in wages compared to entire industries. In[Pg 213] the textile industry, there’s a need for all skill levels, from the well-paid artist and engineer to the laborer in the yard. Industries like manufacturing, commerce, and education all rely on a mix of roles such as bookkeepers, cleaners, carpenters, and managers. Generally, it’s straightforward to move from one level in one industry to a similar level in another industry; however, moving from a lower level to a higher one in the same or a different industry is quite challenging.

Equilibrium of services and wages

Abstractly considered, that is, wherever free competition exists, there is a constant tendency toward a state of equilibrium; each workman is moving into the industry where he earns the highest possible amount, and where he receives just what his fellow-men estimate his importance to be, judged by the service he performs. Each man's place is determined by his specific gravity, just as the place of liquids poured into a glass is determined by their density. There is much reason to believe that this condition is approached actually in a far greater degree than is thought by those who come to the question with preconceived notions of what ought to be, or of what they would like to see. This principle of the economic wage does not preclude the questioning of the justice of existing institutions, but it is a guide in the discussion of all practical problems of wages.

Abstractly speaking, wherever there's free competition, there's a constant push towards a state of balance; every worker is gravitating towards the industry where they can earn the most and where they receive exactly what their peers think they're worth, based on the service they provide. Each person's position is determined by their specific weight, just like the place of liquids poured into a glass is determined by their density. There's plenty of reason to believe that this situation is actually reached to a much greater extent than those who approach the issue with preconceived ideas of what should be, or what they wish to see, realize. This principle of economic wages doesn’t prevent questioning the fairness of existing institutions, but it serves as a guide in discussing all practical wage-related issues.

Wages follow the law of marginal valuation

3. The law of wages may be stated thus: in any state of the labor market the wages of any labor or class of labor is equal to its marginal contribution—that is, to the value of its products. Each agent in industry, whether it be a plough, a horse, or a man, is valued in connection with other agents, never apart or isolated. It is not the total service any one of them performs that can be got at; all that can be got at is the utility attributed to the last unit of supply. Their marginal contribution determines their importance. Each agent is considered in combination with other things at a given moment under existing conditions of supply.

3. The law of wages can be summed up like this: in any labor market, the wages for any type of work or worker are equal to their marginal contribution—that is, the value of what they produce. Each factor in production, whether it's a plow, a horse, or a person, is valued in relation to other factors, never on its own. It’s not about the total service that any one of them provides; it’s about the value assigned to the last unit supplied. Their marginal contribution determines their significance. Each factor is evaluated in combination with others at a specific moment under current supply conditions.

Wages exemplify the general law of value

This statement of the law of wages is broad, and appears[Pg 214] to be modified in many ways in practice: by changes in industry, by ignorance on the part of the worker, by unequal skill in bargaining; but the law of wages just stated allows for these modifications, and is a guide amid the complexity of facts, for it gives a place to the influence of trade unions, caste, and everything else that affects the labor-supply. The law of wages is but the general law of value, working itself out amid the special conditions accompanying the gratification of wants by human effort.

This statement about wages is broad and seems[Pg 214] to be influenced in various ways in real life: by changes in industry, by the worker’s lack of knowledge, and by differing levels of bargaining skills. However, the law of wages mentioned allows for these influences and serves as a guide through the complexity of the situation, as it accounts for the impact of trade unions, societal roles, and everything else that affects the supply of labor. The law of wages is essentially the overall law of value, working itself out amid the specific conditions related to meeting human needs through effort.


CHAPTER 24

THE RELATION OF LABOR TO VALUE

§ I. RELATION OF RENT TO WAGES

Concrete conditions of industry must be studied with wages

1. The law of wages must be considered in connection with other far-reaching influences. One may use the sentence, "the marginal productivity of labor determines wages," without having a true understanding of its meaning. Memorizing a definition is only the first step toward economic reasoning. Till that definition becomes a real thing in the student's thought it helps him but little. The law of wages is an abstract statement of the logical relation of wages to utility; it is not a concrete statement of the industrial conditions in which labor works, yet these are more nearly in the nature of true causes of value. The marginal utility is itself determined by forces and conditions outside of labor that are constantly changing. The more thorough is the student's knowledge of the actual conditions of industry, the more correctly he can apprehend the relations of wages to other incomes, and the more wisely he will apply the abstract law to practical life.

1. The law of wages needs to be understood alongside other important factors. One might say, "the marginal productivity of labor determines wages," without truly grasping what it means. Memorizing a definition is just the first step toward understanding economics. Until that definition becomes a real concept in the student's mind, it doesn’t help them much. The law of wages is an abstract statement about how wages relate to utility; it doesn't reflect the actual industrial conditions under which labor occurs, yet those conditions are more like the true causes of value. Marginal utility itself is influenced by external forces and conditions that are always changing. The more thoroughly a student understands the real conditions of industry, the better they can understand how wages relate to other incomes, and the more effectively they can apply this abstract law to real life.

Productivity of labor and diminishing returns of natural agents

2. The marginal productivity of labor is affected by the relative abundance and efficiency of natural resources. If land suddenly becomes more abundant through the opening up of new continents, the lower grades of agents are sooner or later abandoned. Labor having more of a choice as to the place where it is to be used, spreads itself over the better grades and takes on a greater marginal productivity. The marginal unit of labor working on better soil than before[Pg 216] produces more, and wages expressed in produce are higher. Ground rent, on the other hand, is less under these conditions. If, however, the land is fixed in area, and population increases, no other change taking place, the principle of diminishing returns applies. The marginal laborers (the last arrivals or the growing generation) being compelled to work with less efficient resources on a poorer quality of land, produce less than was the rule before, and a smaller product therefore is attributed to all the laborers of that grade. They get lower wages and more goes as rent to the owners of the land. By shifting of occupations this reduction may be somewhat moderated and equalized among the workers in other industries. In both these cases, wages vary more than does the physical amount of the total product. In the first case, wages are a larger proportion of a larger product; in the second case, the product is larger (there being more laborers) but wages are a smaller proportion of it.

2. The marginal productivity of labor is influenced by how abundant and efficient natural resources are. If land suddenly becomes more plentiful due to new continents being discovered, the lower-quality resources are eventually abandoned. With labor having more options about where to work, it spreads to better resources and achieves higher marginal productivity. The additional unit of labor working on better soil than before[Pg 216] produces more, resulting in higher wages based on output. Conversely, ground rent decreases under these conditions. However, if the amount of land is fixed and the population increases, with no other changes occurring, the principle of diminishing returns applies. The marginal laborers (those who arrive last or the younger generation) are forced to work with less efficient resources on poorer quality land, producing less than what was typical before, which means a smaller output is attributed to all workers of that grade. They receive lower wages, and more of the output goes as rent to the landowners. By changing occupations, this decrease can be somewhat balanced and spread among workers in other industries. In both cases, wages fluctuate more than the actual total output. In the first scenario, wages make up a larger portion of a bigger output; in the second scenario, the output is larger (since there are more laborers), but wages make up a smaller share of it.

The iron law of wages

3. The unwarranted assumption that a disproportionate increase in population is sure to occur, gave rise to the subsistence theory, or iron law of wages. This assumption is now seen not to correspond with what is occurring in the civilized world. A hundred years ago, however, when the poorer classes of Europe appeared to be increasing with little restraint, it was not strange that thinkers should look upon this increase as inevitable. According to the subsistence theory, the question of population was simply a question of food; it was believed that men surely would multiply up to the point where they could not further increase their numbers, and starvation wages would be the rule. It was this way of looking at things that gave to political economy the name of the dismal science. When population is limited in large measure by volitional means instead of by war, starvation, and other material means, the problem changes and the error in such a theory of wages becomes clear.

3. The unfounded belief that a huge increase in population was inevitable led to the subsistence theory, or the iron law of wages. This belief is now understood to be out of step with what’s actually happening in the developed world. A century ago, though, when the lower classes in Europe seemed to be growing without much control, it wasn't surprising that thinkers regarded this growth as unavoidable. According to the subsistence theory, the issue of population boiled down to food supply; it was thought that people would definitely reproduce until they couldn't increase any further, and that low wages would be the norm. This perspective earned political economy the label of the dismal science. When population growth is largely controlled by voluntary choices rather than by war, famine, or other harsh conditions, the issue shifts, and the flaws of this wage theory become obvious.

The standard of living, and wages

The "standard of living" theory of wages is a refined form of the subsistence theory. This theory is that wages[Pg 217] must rise to meet the cost of any standard that the laborers may set, and below which they will refuse to multiply. This is probably a fragmentary truth, but is quite inadequate as a theory. A high standard of living and all the social institutions and customs that aid in keeping the population from too rapid increase, are factors in determining ultimately the marginal productivity of labor and, hence, the height of wages. If these restraining influences suddenly were withdrawn, a reduction of wages would follow slowly because of the diminishing returns of material agents. But the standard of living is merely a partial and negative factor. No limitation of the number of workers can raise wages above their productive contribution and, in the present state of industry, a considerable falling off in population might be expected to result in a loss of enterprise, of coöperation, and of capital. The positive factor in wages is productivity.

The "standard of living" theory of wages is a more developed version of the subsistence theory. This theory suggests that wages[Pg 217] must increase to cover the cost of any standard that the workers set, and below which they will refuse to have more children. This may hold some truth, but it’s not a complete theory. A high standard of living, along with all the social institutions and customs that help prevent the population from growing too quickly, are important factors that ultimately determine the marginal productivity of labor and, as a result, wage levels. If these limiting factors were suddenly removed, wages would slowly decrease because of diminishing returns on material resources. However, the standard of living is only a partial and negative factor. No restriction on the number of workers can raise wages above what they contribute productively, and in today’s industrial context, a significant decline in population could lead to a loss of initiative, cooperation, and capital. The main factor driving wages is productivity.

If labor increases faster than wealth, wages fall

4. An increase of population more rapid than that of the artificial industrial agents would reduce marginal productivity. Labor makes use of many kinds of agents besides the so-called natural resources. If population is stationary while tools are allowed to wear out or if an increasing population, while opening up a proportionate supply of land for food, fails to accumulate a proportionate stock of other tools, the marginal productivity of labor must diminish. Labor would be more imperfectly equipped with spades, hoes, wagons, horses, cattle, machinery. These artificial agents help in getting not only manufactured products, but food products. The equipment of labor must keep pace with the number of workers or they will be forced to the lower, or less effective, uses in the tools. On the other hand, the growth of science and invention, and the growth of wealth faster than the population, equipping labor as it does with more efficient implements, cause the marginal productivity of labor to rise, and hence also the wages.

4. A population increase that is faster than the growth of artificial industrial tools would lower marginal productivity. Labor uses many types of tools beyond just natural resources. If the population stays the same while equipment wears out, or if a growing population opens up enough land for food but doesn’t build up an adequate stock of other tools, the marginal productivity of labor will decrease. Workers would have insufficient tools like shovels, hoes, wagons, horses, cattle, and machinery. These tools are essential for producing not just manufactured goods but also food. The workforce’s tools need to match the number of workers, or they’ll be stuck using their tools in less effective ways. On the flip side, advancements in science and invention, along with wealth growing faster than the population, help equip workers with better tools, which raises the marginal productivity of labor and, consequently, wages.

The wage-fund theory explained

5. The "wage-fund theory" was an imperfect perception of this truth that wages are influenced by the efficiency[Pg 218] of the industrial equipment. As the subsistence theory took a partial view, looking at agricultural land alone as the determinant of wages, so the wage-fund theory looked alone at a portion of the capital in the hands of employers which was the fund from which wages were paid. The large part played in discussion by this doctrine and the strong hold it had on thought is somewhat puzzling now; for if one begins to doubt its entire truth it is difficult to be quite just to its merits or to state it in a form that is plausible. The theory was that wages depended on the amount of capital that, in some way not clearly seen, was set apart by employers for the payment of wages. The capital making up the fund out of which wages were supposed to be paid, was only a very small part of all capital, even in the narrow sense in which that term was then used. It was assumed that this wage fund, once set aside, was necessarily paid out to laborers, wages being therefore determined by simple division: laborers were the divisor, the wage fund the dividend, and the average wage the result. When the theory is thus baldly expressed, it appears to begin and end on the surface of the facts; and the wage fund appears to be rather the arithmetic sum of variously determined payments than, in any sense, the cause of wages.

5. The "wage-fund theory" was an incomplete understanding of the fact that wages are influenced by the efficiency[Pg 218] of industrial equipment. Just as the subsistence theory looked at agricultural land alone as the key factor determining wages, the wage-fund theory focused only on a portion of the capital held by employers, which was the fund used to pay wages. It's a bit puzzling now how significant this doctrine was in discussions and how strongly it influenced thought; because once you start questioning its overall validity, it's hard to fairly assess its merits or to explain it in a believable way. The theory suggested that wages depended on how much capital was somehow reserved by employers for paying wages. The capital that made up the wage fund was just a tiny fraction of all capital, even in the limited sense that term was used at the time. It was assumed that once this wage fund was set aside, it had to be paid out to workers, with wages determined through simple division: workers were the divisor, the wage fund the dividend, and the average wage the result. When you break this theory down so straightforwardly, it seems to merely scratch the surface of the facts; the wage fund appears to be just the arithmetic total of various wage payments rather than being in any way the cause of wages.

The wage-fund theory a partial truth

The abler wage-fund theorists did not fail at times to see, though too dimly, as the determining causes behind the employers' action, certain other things, such as the material facilities, the desires of consumers, the capabilities of the workers, and the resulting value of the labor. The element of truth which still should be recognized in this theory is that the relation of labor to its equipment influences its efficiency, and determines the part of the product to be set aside for wages. In that sense, wages are related to the abstinence of capitalists and to the supply of "capital," but capital understood not as a special fund of the employers, but, in a broader sense, as labor's entire environment of indirect agents.

The more skilled wage-fund theorists sometimes recognized, though not very clearly, that other factors influence employers' actions, like the available resources, consumer demands, workers' skills, and the resulting value of their labor. The truth that still needs to be acknowledged in this theory is that the relationship between labor and its tools affects its productivity and determines the portion of the output allocated for wages. In that sense, wages are connected to the sacrifices made by capitalists and to the availability of "capital," but capital should be understood not just as a specific fund held by employers, but more broadly as the entire environment of indirect factors influencing labor.

§ II. RELATION OF TIME-VALUE TO WAGES

Labor may be near or far, in time, from gratifications

1. The services of labor, whether for one's self or others, have a more or less immediate relation in time to the gratifying of wants. While all human efforts to which the term services is applied have a relation to wants, there is much diversity in their nearness to the gratification for which they are destined. The process may be technically roundabout, to use the language of recent economists. One may break a stick from a tree, pick up a stone and drill a hole in it, catch an animal, cut thongs, tie the handle to the stone, and use it as a weapon to kill other animals for food, the first step being taken with the last object in view. But a still more essential relation we have seen to be the relation in time. Some things, some goods, are used at once, some after a long interval; some are durable, others perishable. Labor produces a song or a glass of lemonade to be consumed on the instant; it is employed on bridges, monuments, railroads, or interoceanic canals lasting for centuries. In all these cases the general object sought is the same though very different intervals of time must elapse before the gratification matures.

1. The work of labor, whether for oneself or others, is directly connected in time to satisfying needs. While all human efforts referred to as services relate to needs, there's a lot of variation in how close they are to actually fulfilling those needs. The process can be somewhat indirect, as newer economists put it. You might break a stick from a tree, pick up a stone and drill a hole in it, catch an animal, make straps, tie the handle to the stone, and use it as a tool to hunt other animals for food, starting with that final goal in mind. However, we've seen that a crucial connection is the relation in time. Some things, some goods, are used immediately, while others are used after a long wait; some last a long time, others spoil quickly. Labor can create a song or a glass of lemonade meant to be enjoyed right away; it's also used in building bridges, monuments, railroads, or interoceanic canals that last for centuries. In all these instances, the overall goal is the same, although the time before satisfaction arrives varies greatly.

All future products of labor are discounted to their present value

2. As different periods of time must elapse before services are enjoyed, the expected value of all products but those immediately available is discounted in advance. The services that afford gratification immediately, and those that afford gratification at a later time, are judged and compared at one and the same moment. All economic life centers in the present. This difference in the time of services surely cannot be ignored. If Robinson Crusoe, at work on his island with his limited supply of energy, continues to provide for next year's enjoyment, neglecting the present, present goods become scarce and their utility rises as compared with the future goods the same labor secures. To escape inconvenience, and in the extremest case to escape starvation,[Pg 220] Crusoe would be compelled to restore the equilibrium between the wants of the two periods by shifting his labor back to the present. So in each little economic group and in our complex society there is constant rivalry of present and future wants, competing for the limited present supply of labor. The present says, "Give me your labor and I will give you the fullest enjoyment." The future says, "I will give you a greater gratification, but you must wait for it." A given labor force thus making possible a wide range of choice among present and future services, labor is distributed according to the prevailing rate of time-value, which, as we have seen, is approximately expressed by the rate of interest. If the rate of interest is high, it means that the present is urgent and will not easily yield to the future. If the rate is low, it implies that the present is comparatively well provided for, and that future wants are given more consideration.

2. Since different lengths of time must pass before services can be enjoyed, the expected value of all products except those that are immediately available is adjusted in advance. Services that provide immediate satisfaction and those that offer satisfaction later are evaluated and compared all at once. All economic activity focuses on the present. This time difference in services definitely can't be overlooked. If Robinson Crusoe, working on his island with a limited amount of energy, continues to plan for next year's enjoyment while ignoring the present, immediate goods will become scarce, and their usefulness will increase compared to the future goods that the same labor can produce. To avoid trouble and, in the worst-case scenario, to avoid starvation,[Pg 220] Crusoe would have to bring back balance between the wants of the two time periods by shifting his labor back to the present. Similarly, in every small economic group and in our complex society, there is constant competition between present and future wants for the limited current supply of labor. The present demands, "Give me your labor and I will provide you with the greatest enjoyment." The future promises, "I will offer you greater satisfaction, but you need to wait for it." A specific labor force allows for a broad range of options between present and future services, and labor is allocated based on the current rate of time-value, which, as we’ve seen, is roughly reflected by the rate of interest. If the interest rate is high, it indicates that the present is urgent and won't easily yield to the future. If the rate is low, it suggests that the present is relatively well taken care of, allowing for more consideration of future wants.

The employer adjusts his labor force to the interest rate

3. The employer in hiring labor and producing goods takes account of these time differences. In the preceding paragraph has been noted the influence of time differences in the simplest problem of economic wages. Interest is likewise taken account of in the bargains between workman and employer, by which contract wages are fixed. The employer of labor works subject to a prevailing rate of interest. If he ignores it he must lose. He should direct a given amount of labor to products that mature next year only when their expected selling price is greater than that of products that can be marketed this year. This difference due to time can no more be ignored than can any other difference in the cost of products. If the employer keeps the future goods to sell later, they will normally increase in value as they approach maturity; if he markets the goods at once, he normally must pass on to the purchaser the benefit of the discount he has made on their future value. That is to say, it is not the employer of labor, the purchaser of labor as such, who gains by discounting the future value[Pg 221] of labor; it is the investor of capital (whether employer or later purchaser) who secures the rent as it matures.

3. The employer, when hiring workers and producing goods, considers these time differences. The previous paragraph pointed out the impact of time differences on the basic issue of economic wages. Interest is also taken into account in the negotiations between the worker and the employer, which determine the contract wages. The employer of labor operates under a prevailing rate of interest. If he overlooks this, he will incur losses. He should allocate a specific amount of labor to products that will be ready next year only if their expected selling price is higher than that of products that can be sold this year. This time-related difference cannot be ignored any more than any other difference in production costs. If the employer holds on to goods to sell later, those goods will typically increase in value as they near maturity; if he sells the goods immediately, he usually has to pass on the benefit of the discount he received on their future value to the buyer. In other words, it is not the employer of labor, the one who purchases labor directly, who benefits from discounting the future value[Pg 221] of labor; it is the investor of capital (whether employer or subsequent buyer) who reaps the rewards as it matures.

The discount of the future value of services is inevitable

4. Hence all wages paid for help on products that are remote are based on the present worth, or discounted value, of the future gratification to which the labor contributes. The idea is held in one form or another by all radical socialistic writers, that the laborer does not get the full value of his products. In the sense that is here discussed, he does not. He does not get what the product will sell for in the future. He gets the probable future value at its present worth, discounted at the prevailing rate. That part of the employer's gains corresponding to this discount on labor is economic time-value.

4. So, all wages paid for work on products that are far off are based on the current worth, or discounted value, of the future satisfaction that the labor helps create. This idea is shared in one way or another by all radical socialist writers, who argue that workers don’t receive the full value of what they produce. In the context we're discussing, they don’t. They don't get the future selling price of the product. Instead, they receive the estimated future value at its current worth, reduced by the current rate. The portion of the employer's profits that corresponds to this discount on labor is called economic time-value.

Nor is this discount of future services dependent on a political system or on private property or on the wage system, as some have assumed. It is a universal truth. It is in the nature of wants that present and future should differ. A communistic or socialistic state would have to take account of this difference, else the whole social economy would be irrational and there would be no principle by which to apportion in time the productive forces of the community. Contracts to pay interest and contracts to pay wages might be forbidden and made criminal by formal law, but time-value would persist.

Nor is this discounting of future services based on a political system, private property, or the wage system, as some people think. It’s a universal fact. It’s just how our wants work: present and future needs are different. A communist or socialist government would need to recognize this difference, or else the entire social structure would be illogical, and there would be no way to allocate the community’s productive resources over time. Agreements to pay interest or wages could be outlawed and treated as crimes by law, but the concept of time-value would still exist.

Relations of wages, rent, and time-value

5. Wages and rent are coördinate species of the value problem; time-value is a different kind of problem, bearing to both the other problems a similar relation. A close examination of the problems of rent and wages serves to bring out the close parallelism of these two forms of income as here defined. Rent is the value of the usufruct of wealth, wages are the value of the usufruct of labor. The bearer of the use in one case is material goods, in the other is human agents. Different in the source of use, they are in large measure alike in the form of contract, or nature of the calculation. Together rent and wages comprise the value of all currently arising uses; they are the two coördinate[Pg 222] species of the genus "value of uses." The two groups of uses are closely interrelated in practice, each acting and reacting on the value of the other.

5. Wages and rent are related aspects of the value problem; time-value is a different kind of issue, having a similar connection to both of the other problems. A detailed look at the issues of rent and wages highlights the close similarities between these two forms of income as defined here. Rent represents the value of the benefits derived from material wealth, while wages represent the value of the benefits derived from labor. The source of the benefits in one case is physical goods, and in the other, it's human agents. Although they differ in their source, they are quite similar in terms of the type of contract or the nature of the calculations involved. Together, rent and wages encompass the value of all current benefits; they are the two related[Pg 222] categories within the broader concept of "value of benefits." The two sets of benefits are closely interconnected in practice, with each influencing the value of the other.

Time-value is a different genus of the value problem. Having to do with time differences, it must be found in connection with every use that is not immediate, whatever be the bearer of that use. Its application to rent is more frequent and obvious, as only the uses of material agents are capitalized, that is, sold in perpetuity. Moreover any service of labor that is not at once consumed is fixed in material form and appears thenceforward as wealth whose uses are yielded as rent or as consumption goods.

Time-value is a different type of value issue. It relates to time differences and must be considered with any use that isn't immediate, regardless of what provides that use. Its connection to rent is more common and obvious, as only the uses of physical assets are capitalized, meaning they are sold for the long term. Additionally, any labor service that isn’t used up right away is transformed into a physical asset and from that point on appears as wealth, producing either rent or consumption goods.

§ III. THE RELATION OF LABOR TO VALUE

Several conditions of value

1. Labor is a cause, but only one of the causes of value. A cause is some one condition which is seen to be necessary to the existence of a thing, and usually that condition which brings the thing about, other things being assumed. In what sense ought a cause of value be spoken of? In one sense it is in the minds of men—it is their wants; again, looked at objectively it is in the nature of the good—it is the quality that fits it to gratify the want. But if both these causes are operative, and labor is applied to fit goods better to gratify wants, labor appears as the cause of value. Personal causes are so much more evident, an explanation through personal causation is so much more satisfying in the earlier stages of scientific inquiry, that labor long continued to be looked upon as the one source of value. This erroneous view has never quite ceased to influence economic thought, and a great deal of effort has been directed to formulating theories of value based upon it. The cruder form of the error has now almost disappeared, but in various little recognized ways it still persists.

1. Labor is a cause, but only one of the causes of value. A cause is a specific condition necessary for the existence of something, usually the condition that brings it about, assuming other factors are in place. How should we think about a cause of value? In one way, it's in people's minds—it's their desires. On the other hand, when we look at it objectively, it's in the nature of the good—it's the quality that makes it suitable to satisfy those desires. However, if both these causes are at play, and labor is used to make goods better suited to satisfy wants, then labor seems to be the cause of value. Personal causes are much more obvious, and explanations based on personal causation are more appealing in the early stages of scientific exploration, so labor was long seen as the sole source of value. This mistaken belief still influences economic thought, and a lot of effort has gone into creating theories of value based on it. The more basic form of this error has nearly vanished, but in various subtle ways, it persists.

Two phases of economic production

2. Economic production is the origin, or genesis, of value finding its source either in objective things or in services.[Pg 223] The writers of fifty years ago defined economic production as the application of labor to the creation of wealth. But as there are two factors in production, man and material things, so there are two productive sources of value. In some cases the origin of value is attributable to man's action; in other cases scarce uses arise in objective things without man's action. Broad as is this definition of production, it does not include the enjoyment of free goods, as in the case of the care-free darky basking in the sun. Anything that, causing a feeling of greater importance to attach to a thing, changes it from a free good to a scarce good or makes it more scarce, is a cause of its value. A large rainfall causing a greater crop of grain may be thought of as producing utility. The regular surplus of value attributable to the waterfall or to the railroad, is the product of the material services of wealth. Production through human action is the more obvious and is the more usually thought of; the part of material agents must be recognized if the fallacies of the labor theory of value are to be avoided.

2. Economic production is the source of value, stemming from either tangible goods or services.[Pg 223] Writers from fifty years ago described economic production as the use of labor to create wealth. However, since there are two elements in production—people and material goods—there are also two sources of value. In some instances, value originates from human actions, while in others, scarcity arises in tangible goods without human involvement. Although this definition of production is broad, it doesn't account for the enjoyment of free goods, like the carefree person soaking up the sun. Any factor that increases the perceived importance of something, shifting it from a free good to a scarce good or making it more scarce, contributes to its value. For example, a large rainfall leading to a bigger grain crop can be seen as creating utility. The consistent surplus of value from sources like waterfalls or railroads stems from the material services of wealth. Production driven by human action is the more apparent and commonly considered aspect; however, the role of material factors must be acknowledged to avoid the misconceptions of the labor theory of value.

Labor applied to creating utility

3. Human activity is directed to shaping and arranging things so as to increase their want-gratifying power. Human and non-human agents are combined in different proportions in various products. In one thing more land and machinery are used, in another more labor is used. But either of these two great classes of agents may touch the vanishing point in the production of value. While it is true that man's part is the most striking aspect of production, yet there may be value without labor. The study of rent puts this abstractly, but in a clear light. In actual life, however, a part of the value is usually attributable to rent, a part to labor.

3. Human activity focuses on shaping and organizing things to enhance their ability to satisfy our wants. Human and non-human agents are combined in different amounts in various products. In some cases, more land and machinery are used, while in others, more labor is involved. But either of these two main types of agents can become negligible in the creation of value. Although it's true that human contribution is the most noticeable part of production, there can still be value without labor. The study of rent outlines this concept abstractly, but clearly. In real life, however, part of the value is typically linked to rent, and part to labor.

Value of labor derived from its products

But in what sense is even this part attributable? Not in the sense that the labor is the original source of value which imparts that value to its products. The usufruct of wealth is the basis of rent; the need to pay rent is not the cause of value in the product. Likewise, product is the basis of[Pg 224] wages, labor is not the origin of value. Labor, like the forces and qualities of wealth, is the cause of technical changes. These changes, if favorable, cause the goods to take on a higher value which is reflected back to the labor. The labor itself has not a predetermined, ascertainable value, but only a resultant, derived value. An exception to this statement appears on a superficial view of the value of labor hired under the wage contract to make a particular product. The labor having a market value because of a large number of well-known alternate uses, can be diverted to a particular use only on condition of a definite payment. Labor here, as viewed by the employer, appears to have an original value; products, a derived value. But in the logical view, labor is seen to impart technical qualities to the goods; in turn, the goods to impart value to the labor. Man hunts throughout industry for those things to which his labor can be applied usefully. He foresees in them the changes that will increase the value. It is only as he has judged rightly that the value taken on by the things is reflected back to the labor attributed to it.

But in what way can we even attribute this part? Not in the sense that labor is the original source of value that gives that value to its products. The enjoyment of wealth is what rent is based on; the need to pay rent does not create value in the product. Similarly, the product forms the basis of[Pg 224] wages; labor is not the source of value. Labor, like the forces and characteristics of wealth, causes technical changes. If these changes are positive, they lead to goods gaining higher value, which is then reflected back to the labor. Labor itself does not have a fixed, identifiable value; it only has a resulting, derived value. At first glance, there seems to be an exception to this regarding the value of labor hired under a wage contract to produce a specific product. The labor has market value due to many well-known alternative uses and can only be directed toward a specific use if a definite payment is made. In this context, labor appears to have an original value to the employer, while products are seen as having derived value. However, from a logical perspective, labor is recognized as imparting technical qualities to the goods, which in turn bestows value on the labor. People search throughout industry for things to which they can apply their labor effectively. They anticipate changes that will enhance the value. Only when they make the right judgments does the value gained by those things get reflected back to the labor associated with it.

No unit of labor to serve as a standard of value

4. Labor being of many qualities and receiving many rates of pay, there is no unit of labor that can be used as a measure of value. The idea of finding in a "unit of labor" an objective standard of value to which the value of all other things could be reduced has been a very attractive one. This fallacious hope animates every one beginning to think of the value problem. The thought was so plausibly formulated by Ricardo that it continued for a long time to be the generally accepted doctrine of value. Although most writers reject the formal statement of the labor theory of value, use is frequently made, even now, of the phrase "unit of labor," suggesting the thought that labor is the standard by which the value of all goods may be measured. This unit of labor of the text-books may be seen to be either labor arbitrarily assumed to be of uniform quality and quantity, as a day of unskilled labor (in that form quite incomparable as[Pg 225] to amount with other qualities), or a given amount of money invested in labor of different grades at its market value. It is only by expressing labor in terms of its value that the various grades of skilled and unskilled labor can be reduced to a homogeneous unit, which is but a unit of money wages. This should not deceive us into the belief that in any peculiar sense labor can be used as a unit of value. It is equally valid and convenient to speak of units of machinery and of units of land. In terms of capital a factory site can be expressed as a multiple of a potato patch not less perfectly than can a sculptor's labor as a multiple of a ditch-digger's.

4. Labor comes in many types and pays different rates, so there isn’t a single unit of labor that can serve as a measure of value. The idea of finding an "unit of labor" as an objective standard of value to which all other things could be compared has been very appealing. This misleading hope drives everyone trying to understand the value problem. Ricardo articulated this idea so convincingly that it became the widely accepted doctrine of value for a long time. Although most writers dismiss the formal version of the labor theory of value, the term "unit of labor" is still often used, implying that labor is the standard for measuring the value of all goods. The unit of labor discussed in textbooks is usually either labor arbitrarily defined as having uniform quality and quantity, like a day of unskilled work (which is really incomparable to other types), or a specific amount of money invested in labor of different skill levels at its market value. Only by expressing labor in terms of its value can the various types of skilled and unskilled labor be combined into a single unit, which is simply a unit of money wages. This shouldn’t mislead us into thinking that labor can uniquely serve as a unit of value. It's equally valid and convenient to talk about units of machinery and units of land. In capital terms, a factory site can be compared to a potato patch just as well as a sculptor's work can be compared to that of a ditch-digger.

Scarcity and utility of labor

Scarcity of things desired is the one objective condition of value. The things that labor can produce and the labor to produce them being scarce, labor takes on a value. All things at last become comparable in terms of psychic income in each individual's judgment, but as yet neither in this comparison nor in the market values that are fixed in exchange, has any absolute standard been found by which the utility of all goods or the welfare of all men can be measured.

Scarcity of desired things is the fundamental condition for value. As the things that labor can produce and the labor itself become scarce, labor gains value. Ultimately, everything is comparable in terms of personal satisfaction in each person's judgment, but so far, neither in this comparison nor in the market values that are determined through exchange has any absolute standard been established to measure the utility of all goods or the well-being of all people.


CHAPTER 25

THE WAGE SYSTEM AND ITS RESULTS

§ I. SYSTEMS OF LABOR

The wage system defined
Never the exclusive form of organization

1. The wage system is the organization of industry wherein some men, owning and directing capital, buy at their competitive value the services of men without capital. The wage system is a method of organization never found completely realized. A community made up entirely of independent small farmers, living each on his little patch of ground, does not have any essential feature of the wage system. So long as they continue to be independent small farmers, owners of small capital, self-employing workers, the wage system does not exist in complete form. Some men with capital in every community are working for wages, while others, as independent producers, are their own employers. Society is not sharply divided into two classes, one controlling all the working capital, the other quite without resources. The wage system may be spoken of as prevailing to-day not as the exclusive, but as the typical, or dominant, form, while side by side or along with it is found independent production. It is clear that the wages here spoken of are contract wages. The wage system implies a money contract between employer and employed. The relation or bond between them is that of a wage payment.

1. The wage system is the organization of industry where some people, owning and directing capital, pay a competitive price for the services of those without capital. The wage system is a way of organizing that has never been fully realized. A community made up entirely of independent small farmers, each living on their own piece of land, doesn't really have any key characteristics of the wage system. As long as they remain independent small farmers, owning small amounts of capital and working for themselves, the wage system isn't fully present. In every community, some people with capital are earning wages, while others, as independent producers, are their own bosses. Society isn't sharply divided into two classes, one that controls all the working capital and another that has no resources at all. We can say that the wage system is prevalent today not as the only, but as the typical or dominant form, while independent production exists alongside it. It's clear that the wages being discussed here are contract wages. The wage system involves a money agreement between employer and employee. The relationship or bond between them is based on wage payments.

The wage system cannot be judged properly apart from questions to be later considered, such as private property and the enterpriser's part in industry; but some consideration of the subject properly belongs here. The wage system[Pg 227] has become of recent years in America the dominant form of industry. The theory of wages is applied most frequently in the discussion of contract wages, and there are certain practical relations between the results of the wage system and the theory of wages.

The wage system can't be properly assessed without looking at related issues that will be discussed later, like private property and the role of entrepreneurs in industry; however, some discussion of the topic is relevant here. The wage system[Pg 227] has recently become the main form of industry in America. The theory of wages is most commonly used when talking about contract wages, and there are specific practical connections between the outcomes of the wage system and wage theory.

Workers subordinate in early societies

2. The wage system, historically considered, is seen not to have displaced a system of independent labor. This question should be viewed in historical perspective. As far back as history can be traced, the masses of workers have been subordinate. Civilization began with direction, with obedience to superiors on the part of the mass of men. Within the family, in the rudest tribes, the women and children were subject to the will of the stronger, the head of the family. Among the Aryan races the family system was widened, and the patriarch of the tribe secured personal obedience and economic service from all members of the community. Chattel slavery, the typical form of industrial organization in early tropical civilization, seems to have been one of the necessary steps to progress from rude conditions; students to-day incline to view it as an essential stage in the history of the race. But as conditions changed with industrial development, chattel slavery became a hindrance to progress, a disadvantage to higher industry.

2. The wage system, when looked at historically, is seen as not having replaced a system of independent labor. This question should be considered in a historical context. As far back as we can trace history, the majority of workers have been in a subordinate position. Civilization began with leadership, requiring obedience to those in charge from the masses. Within families, in the most primitive tribes, women and children were under the control of the stronger family members. Among the Aryan races, the family structure expanded, and the patriarch of the tribe enforced obedience and economic contribution from all community members. Chattel slavery, the common form of industrial organization in early tropical civilizations, appears to have been a necessary step in moving away from primitive conditions; today’s scholars tend to view it as a crucial phase in the history of humanity. However, as industrial conditions evolved, chattel slavery became an obstacle to progress and a disadvantage to advanced industries.

Place of the workers in the Middle Ages

3. Serfdom for rural labor and many limitations on the workman's freedom in the towns, were the prevailing conditions in medieval Europe. Serfdom was both a political and an economic relation. The serf was bound to the soil; the lord could command and control him; but the serf's obligations were pretty well defined. He had to give services, but in return for them he got something definite in the form of protection and the use of land. Between the lord and the serf continued a lifelong contract, which passed by inheritance from father to son, in the case both of the master and of the serf. In the towns conditions were better for the skilled workmen, but many things bore heavily on the mass of the workers shut out from special privileges. There were[Pg 228] strict rules of apprenticeship; gild regulations forbidding the free choice of a trade or a residence; laws against immigration; settlement laws making it impossible for poor men to remove from one place to another; arbitrary regulation of wages, either by the gilds in the towns or by national councils and parliaments, forbidding the workmen to take the competitive wages that economic conditions forced the employers to pay; combination laws forbidding laborers to combine in their own interest. It is not an attractive picture, but, as far as is possible in a few words, it is a truthful picture of the conditions that existed before the coming of the modern system.

3. Serfdom for rural workers and many restrictions on the freedom of workers in towns were the common conditions in medieval Europe. Serfdom was both a political and economic relationship. The serf was tied to the land; the lord had the power to command and control him, but the serf's responsibilities were quite clear. He had to provide services, but in exchange, he received something specific in the form of protection and the right to use land. A lifelong contract existed between the lord and the serf, which was inherited from father to son for both the master and the serf. In the towns, conditions were better for skilled workers, but many burdens weighed heavily on the majority of workers who were excluded from special privileges. There were[Pg 228] strict apprenticeship rules; guild regulations that prevented free choice of trade or residence; laws against immigration; settlement laws that made it impossible for poor men to move from one place to another; arbitrary wage regulations imposed either by guilds in the towns or by national councils and parliaments, preventing workers from accepting the competitive wages that economic conditions forced employers to pay; and combination laws that prohibited laborers from organizing for their own interests. It’s not a pretty picture, but as much as possible in a few words, it accurately reflects the conditions that existed before the modern system emerged.

The wage system not the main cause of present evils

4. Many continuing limitations on the freedom of the worker are not the results of the wage system or a part of it, but are opposed to its complete workings. The worker's ignorance is a limitation, preventing the choice of an occupation for which he might naturally be fitted. Neglect of children by parents is a limitation, preventing industrial training and the development of qualities that would make it possible for the child to excel. The faults of human nature cannot be attributed to any "system"; and if they are remediable, it is by education and better social opportunity. Trade unions often forbid boys to become apprentices, and forbid the choice of a trade except under conditions so exacting that to many they are impossible. Such limitations are made by the privileged few in their own interest, but they are annoying and opposed to the interests of the many. The typical wage system would be one in which all such hindrances were lacking, in which there were no social or political limitations on free competition except such as would help in educating and training the worker. The wage system should be judged by what it is, not by things directly opposed to its spirit.

4. Many ongoing restrictions on workers' freedom aren't caused by the wage system or part of it, but actually hinder its full potential. A worker’s lack of knowledge limits their ability to choose a job they might be well-suited for. Parents neglecting their children creates a barrier to industrial training and the development of skills that could help the child succeed. Human nature's shortcomings can’t be blamed on any "system"; if they can be fixed, it’s through education and improved social opportunities. Trade unions often prevent boys from becoming apprentices and limit the choice of trade to conditions that are so stringent that they’re impossible for many. These restrictions are imposed by a privileged few for their own benefit, but they are frustrating and contrary to the interests of the majority. The ideal wage system would be one free from such obstacles, where there are no social or political restrictions on fair competition, except those that promote the education and training of workers. The wage system should be evaluated based on its true nature, not by the elements that contradict its essence.

§ II. THE WAGE SYSTEM AS IT IS

Merits and faults of the definite wage payment

1. Under the wage contract the worker gets in a definite sum at once the market value of his services. Under the wage contract the employer takes the risk as to the future selling price of the product. That he is the one best prepared to assume the risk will be made clearer in the discussion of the employer's function. Wage payment, therefore, is a form of insurance to the workingman; he gets something definite instead of taking chances he is ill prepared to take. Wage payment is a form of credit to the laborer whose labor has not yet produced the distant gratification. The employer advances to the workman the value of the future gratification, discounting it at the prevailing rate of interest. The darker side of the wage bargain is that the "cash nexus," as Carlyle expressed it, is too often the only bond between the parties. When the wages are paid, the employer considers his obligations discharged. There is a lack of fellowship and sympathy in it all. Work should be a bond of communion between men, but as it is, the laborers in some great factories and their employers live in entirely different worlds. The great inequality of their condition makes mutual understanding difficult. They are master and man, "boss" and hireling, not co-workers, each with a worthy part in the noble tasks of industry.

1. Under the wage contract, the worker receives a set amount upfront that reflects the market value of their services. In this arrangement, the employer takes on the risk of the future selling price of the product. It's clear that the employer is the one best suited to handle this risk, which will be explained further when discussing the employer's role. Wage payment, then, acts as a form of insurance for the worker; they receive something concrete instead of facing uncertainties they aren't ready to handle. Wage payment is a type of credit for the laborer whose work hasn’t yet yielded immediate rewards. The employer is essentially fronting the worker the value of future rewards, factoring in the current interest rate. The downside of the wage agreement is that the “cash nexus,” as Carlyle put it, is too often the only connection between the two parties. Once wages are paid, the employer feels their obligations have been met. There’s a lack of camaraderie and empathy in this arrangement. Work should create a sense of community among people, but instead, laborers in large factories and their employers exist in completely separate worlds. The significant imbalance in their circumstances makes it hard for them to understand each other. They become master and servant, “boss” and worker, instead of collaborators, each contributing to the important tasks of industry.

Strength and weakness of the worker in competition

2. The wage-earner gets the competitive value of his services, securing in most cases much more than a bare subsistence. At the present time competition is in a large measure active among employed as well as among employers. A believer in the subsistence theory of wages must, under these conditions, expect wages to fall to the starvation level. But according to the law of wages here presented, it is to be expected that wages can and will remain indefinitely above that level, falling or rising as conditions change. The increase in material wealth of itself tends to increase the[Pg 230] wages of the workman. The laborer, though without resources and even though not contributing to the increase of capital by saving, thus shares in the benefit of increasing capital. It is true that under some conditions the workman is at a disadvantage in making the wage contract; labor must be applied from day to day or it is lost, and the laborer must work to live. While this does not determine the rate of wages in the long run in any occupation nor to any great extent except among the lowest grades of labor, it does give an advantage for the moment to the employer, and enables him to exercise at times a harsh power over the workmen in his immediate neighborhood. A single workman is thus very often at a disadvantage, but it must not be overlooked that in a large degree the competition for good workmen is effective between employers in different trades and in distant localities.

2. The wage-earner receives the competitive value of their services, often earning much more than just enough to get by. Right now, competition is quite active among both employees and employers. Someone who believes in the subsistence theory of wages would expect that, under these circumstances, wages would drop to a level where people struggle to survive. However, based on the wage law we’re discussing, we can expect that wages can and will stay above that level for an indefinite period, rising or falling as conditions shift. The increase in material wealth tends to boost the[Pg 230] wages of workers. Even if the laborer has no resources and isn’t contributing to capital accumulation through saving, they still benefit from the growing capital. It’s true that sometimes workers are at a disadvantage when negotiating wages; they need to work day by day, or they lose their opportunity, and they must work to survive. While this doesn’t set the wage rate in the long term for any job, nor does it significantly affect most positions except the lowest-skilled jobs, it does give employers a temporary advantage. This allows them to exert control over workers in their immediate vicinity. A single worker often finds themselves at a disadvantage, but it’s important to remember that there is significant competition for skilled workers among employers across various industries and locations.

Wages as affecting the ambition of the worker

3. Increase of efficiency due to the sacrifice of parents or to personal exertion, goes to the individual worker. The most essential practical feature in any industrial system is the appeal to the ambition of each man. This appeal is made where a premium is placed on increasing efficiency, by insuring to it a higher return. This result is possible and in large measure is attained under the wage system. Little less important is the appeal to family affection to make possible by its sacrifices each worker's best preparation.

3. Improvement in efficiency through the sacrifices of parents or personal effort goes to the individual worker. The most important practical aspect of any industrial system is the appeal to each person's ambition. This appeal is made when there’s a reward for increasing efficiency, ensuring that it brings a greater return. This outcome is achievable and largely realized under the wage system. Almost as important is the appeal to family bonds, which helps enable each worker's best preparation through their sacrifices.

An offsetting disadvantage appears in the loss to the laborer in the decline of his powers. As he gains in wages if he increases in efficiency, so he loses if his strength fails from accident or in the course of years. This loss falls upon him, not, as is sometimes said to have been the case under serfdom or slavery, upon his owner (as if that secured to the slave immunity from suffering). It is true that in general under the wage system the worker has no guarantee against loss of work or, what is equally important, against sudden changes in industry. He may be, and often is, a victim of invention and of changes in machinery[Pg 231] or industrial processes, by which the masses of men are the gainers.

An offsetting disadvantage arises when a laborer loses his capabilities. While he earns more if he becomes more efficient, he also suffers a loss if his strength declines due to injury or age. This loss is his responsibility, not, as people sometimes say was the case under serfdom or slavery, the responsibility of his owner (as if that somehow spared the slave from suffering). It’s true that under the wage system, workers generally have no protection against losing their job or, equally importantly, against abrupt changes in industry. He can often be, and frequently is, a casualty of innovations and changes in machinery[Pg 231] or industrial processes, while the broader population benefits.

Large liberty of the wage-worker

4. Liberty of the worker in his choice of work and outside of working hours makes for happiness, character, and progress. Opinion is almost a unit as to the truth of this statement. The present wage system is the freest condition for the mass of men that ever has existed. Their religious, political, and personal convictions, are for the most part inviolate. There is a true but much misused maxim that liberty has its dangers. Freedom means freedom to make mistakes. Intelligence and strong industrial virtues are required to exercise properly a freedom newly acquired. Thus it is the lowest class of labor that reaps the smallest advantage from free conditions, and that suffers most from their misuse.

4. The ability of workers to choose their jobs and spend their free time as they like leads to happiness, character, and progress. Most people agree with this statement. The current wage system provides the greatest freedom for the majority of workers that has ever existed. Their religious, political, and personal beliefs are mostly respected. There's a true but often misused saying that freedom comes with risks. Freedom also means the possibility of making mistakes. It takes intelligence and strong work ethics to properly handle a newfound freedom. As a result, it's often the lowest-paid workers who benefit the least from these free conditions and suffer the most from any misuse.

Limits to the worker's liberty

The main evil in the wage system is certainly not that the liberty of the worker is too great, but that it is too small. The sale of labor involves the obeying of orders during certain hours specified in the contract. Here again the evil is greatest in the lowest grades of work, while the great majority of wage-earners are left a large measure of choice in the time and manner of their work. Where labor is severe and without joy to the worker, it appears to be little better than a form of slavery. Contrast the condition of the section hand, cursed and beaten by a brutal foreman, with that of the wage-earner in the locomotive-cab, self-respecting, self-directing, and trusted with the safety of property and lives. The wage system is manifold, it is adaptable. If it holds a portion of the laborers with a harsh hand, it gives to all a wide measure of opportunity, and to most a great degree of independence in their lives. A hasty resort to indiscriminating analogy, as in calling wage-work "slavery," does not further truth or social justice.

The main issue with the wage system isn’t that workers have too much freedom, but that they have too little. Selling labor means following orders during specific hours outlined in the contract. The biggest problems occur in the lowest-paying jobs, while most wage earners have a decent amount of choice regarding when and how they work. When work is tough and unfulfilling, it feels almost like a form of slavery. Compare the situation of a laborer who is cursed and abused by a harsh supervisor with that of a wage earner in a train cab, who is respected, in charge of their work, and trusted with the safety of people and property. The wage system is complex and flexible. While it can be quite strict for some workers, it offers many others significant opportunities and a good amount of independence in their lives. Quickly equating wage work to “slavery” doesn’t promote truth or social justice.

§ III. PROGRESS OF THE MASSES UNDER THE WAGE SYSTEM

The rise of money wages

1. The nineteenth century was a period of great progress for the masses in America, England, and throughout Europe. There are differences of opinion as to the extent of this progress, the way in which it is to be measured, and the degree to which it is an occasion for congratulation. There is no longer any dispute as to the actual fact that it has taken place. Many lines of evidence converge to confirm this one conclusion. The average money wages in the United States may be represented in 1840 by 87.7, in 1860 by 100, and in 1891 by 161.2. This was the high mark for a time and a decline followed. Again wages rose from 1897 on, and in 1899 had reached 163.2. They have continued to rise since and in 1903 attained the highest point in the history of our country and therefore in the history of the world. Another temporary decline undoubtedly will occur when industrial conditions become less prosperous.

1. The nineteenth century was a time of significant progress for ordinary people in America, England, and across Europe. There are differing opinions about how much progress was made, how to measure it, and whether it should be celebrated. However, there's no debate over the fact that it happened. Many pieces of evidence come together to support this one conclusion. Average wages in the United States can be represented as 87.7 in 1840, 100 in 1860, and 161.2 in 1891. This was the peak for a while, and then there was a decline. Wages started to rise again from 1897, reaching 163.2 in 1899. They have continued to increase since then, and by 1903 they hit the highest level in our country's history, and thus in the world’s history. Another temporary decline will likely happen when industrial conditions are less favorable.

Changes in real wages

Real wages, also, the power to purchase goods with labor, are greater than ever before so far as this can be measured in the price of leading commodities. The offsetting loss of the free health-giving pleasures of country life cannot easily be expressed. In England likewise the rise in money wages has been great. In 1860 it is represented by 100, in 1870 by 113, in 1880 by 125, in 1891 by 140, in the intervals some decline occurring. For a century in all civilized lands wages have moved in an ever-rising series of waves. The purchasing power of wages in England increased ninety per cent, in the thirty years between 1860 and 1891. Throughout Europe the same general change is seen, going always hand in hand with new industrial methods and the displacing of the old agricultural system by the wage system. As the hours of labor have at the same time been shortened, the workers have gained doubly.

Real wages, which represent the ability to buy goods with earned income, are higher than ever when looking at the prices of major commodities. It's hard to put into words the trade-off of losing the free, healthy pleasures of country life. Similarly, in England, money wages have risen significantly. In 1860, the index was 100; in 1870, it was 113; in 1880, it was 125; and in 1891, it reached 140, with some fluctuations in between. For a century, wages have steadily increased across all developed nations, moving in a continual upward trend. The purchasing power of wages in England rose by ninety percent during the thirty years from 1860 to 1891. This same shift can be observed throughout Europe, always linked with new industrial techniques and the replacement of the old agricultural system with a wage-based system. As working hours have also been reduced, workers have benefited even more.

Need of a broad explanation of rising wages

2. This progress is mainly due to the opening up of rich[Pg 233] natural resources and to the development of industrial processes. Recognized in some measure by every one, this progress is attributed by different observers to different causes: in America, by many to the protective tariff; in England, by many to the freer trade introduced about 1840; throughout the continent of Europe, to the spread of constitutional government and free institutions; by trade-unions everywhere, to the organization of labor. There is, doubtless, under certain conditions, some portion of truth in each of these claims. But, either separately or altogether, they fall short of a broad, reasonable, and sufficient explanation. The two-fold proposition just presented, the justification for which has been given in preceding chapters, points to a general and adequate cause.

2. This progress is mainly because of the opening up of rich[Pg 233] natural resources and the development of industrial processes. While everyone acknowledges this progress to some extent, different observers attribute it to various reasons: in America, many credit the protective tariff; in England, many point to the free trade introduced around 1840; throughout continental Europe, it’s linked to the spread of constitutional government and free institutions; while trade unions everywhere attribute it to the organization of labor. There is certainly some truth in each of these claims under certain conditions. However, whether considered individually or together, they don't provide a comprehensive, logical, and sufficient explanation. The two-fold proposition just presented, for which justification has been provided in earlier chapters, indicates a general and adequate cause.

The gloomy view as to the wage system was mistaken

Seventy-five years ago it was thought that, with the increase of machinery, of factories, of the concentrated control of wealth, and especially with the wage system, there must go a steady depression in the welfare of the workingman. This idea was connected with the iron law of wages. It was believed by some that, whatever the causes of advancing social income might be, the wage system would rob the wage-earners of all share in progress. In view of the facts, if it cannot now be asserted positively that the wage system is the cause of all the gain, it can be asserted negatively that it is not inconsistent with great progress on the part of the laboring classes. It might be possible to go further and to maintain that the organization of industry, under the wage system and competitive conditions, by its encouragement of enterprise, energy, and economy, has been an indispensable condition in the industrial progress which has in turn made possible the rising wages of labor.

Seventy-five years ago, people believed that with the rise of machinery, factories, the concentration of wealth, and especially the wage system, there would be a consistent decline in the well-being of workers. This idea was linked to the iron law of wages. Some thought that no matter what sparked an increase in social income, the wage system would prevent workers from benefiting from progress. Considering the evidence, while we can't definitively say that the wage system is responsible for all gains, we can assert that it doesn't contradict significant advancements for laborers. It might even be argued that the structure of industry, operating under the wage system and competitive conditions, has fostered initiative, drive, and efficiency, which have been essential for the industrial growth that has, in turn, allowed for rising wages for workers.

More workers now in better-paid callings

3. The increased proportion of workers in the higher occupations means a further rise in the average condition of the masses. A smaller proportion of workers is now engaged in the low-paid industries than fifty years ago, and a correspondingly larger proportion is in the better, or highly[Pg 234] paid, industries. Decade by decade the proportion shifts toward the upper part of the scale. Both in America and in England (doubtless also in other countries) more men are now engaged in the higher professions and skilled occupations, a smaller proportion in the lower occupations. This would raise the average of wages even if the wages of particular occupations had not risen.

3. The increased percentage of workers in higher-paying jobs means a further improvement in the overall situation for the masses. A smaller percentage of workers is now involved in low-paying industries than fifty years ago, and a larger percentage is in better or higher-paying industries. Year by year, the proportion shifts towards the upper end of the scale. Both in America and in England (and likely in other countries as well), more people are now in higher professions and skilled jobs, while fewer are in lower-paying occupations. This would raise the average wages even if the wages for specific jobs hadn’t gone up.

The masses gain by general social advance

4. The diffused advantages of progress mean relatively more to the masses than to the rich. In the olden days the poor man was bound to the spot where he lived, the rich man had his carriage; to-day poor and rich ride side by side in the trolley car. The introduction of these cheap methods of enjoyment means relatively more to the poor. Better medical care, better sanitation, more abundant food, clothing, comfort, free schools, and libraries have all a part in this movement. The enormous possibilities in these lines are just beginning to be realized. The achievements of the last twenty years read like a story from fairy-land. It tells the leveling up of the conditions enjoyed by the common man.

4. The widespread benefits of progress matter more to the masses than to the wealthy. In the past, a poor person was tied to their location, while a rich person had their carriage; today, both the poor and the rich ride together on public transport. The availability of these affordable means of enjoyment means significantly more to those with less. Improved healthcare, better sanitation, more access to food, clothing, comfort, free education, and libraries all play a role in this development. The vast potential in these areas is just beginning to be recognized. The advancements of the past twenty years read like a tale from a fairy tale. It illustrates the improvement of living conditions for the everyday person.

Better social conditions must grow out of the wage system
Improvement in the wage system

5. Any sound method of improving social conditions must grow out of experience, not break with it. Even if things were on the downward instead of the upward road there would be no excuse for wild speculation. The only rational way is to find what is good in what is, and build upon it. There can be no excuse for suggesting a method from imagination. Projects of social change must be tried by successful experiment, and gradually fitted to present needs. It is in this way that the higher forms of life have developed; it is in this way that social and political institutions have come into being. Things that work successfully first in a small way are worthy of trial on a larger scale. The wage system is a favorite object of attack for radical social reformers. It has many unlovely features and there are many individual cases of hardship. It may well be asked, What method shall be pursued to reform it? Its retention, however, is not inconsistent with very great changes in the[Pg 235] present political and economic arrangements. The impersonal economic forces are working for improvement; but further, there is a growth of sentiment, an increase in sympathy, a feeling among men that the "cash nexus" is not the only bond that should unite different classes, and this sympathy is becoming an economic force, softening and improving many of the most unlovely features of the modern wage system.

5. Any effective way to improve social conditions must come from experience, not reject it. Even if things were worsening instead of getting better, there would still be no reason for reckless speculation. The only sensible approach is to identify what's good in the current situation and build on it. There’s no justification for proposing methods based purely on imagination. Social change initiatives must be tested through successful experiments and gradually adjusted to meet current needs. This is how higher forms of life have evolved; this is how social and political institutions have developed. Ideas that prove successful on a small scale are worth trying on a larger scale. The wage system is often targeted by radical social reformers. It has many undesirable aspects, and there are numerous individual cases of hardship. One might ask, what method should be used to reform it? However, keeping it does not preclude significant changes in the [Pg 235] current political and economic systems. Impersonal economic forces are pushing for improvement; furthermore, there is a growing sentiment, an increase in empathy, and a recognition among people that the "cash nexus" isn't the only connection that should bring different classes together. This empathy is becoming an economic force, softening and improving many of the harsh realities of the modern wage system.


CHAPTER 26

MACHINERY AND LABOR

§ I. EXTENT OF THE USE OF MACHINERY

Tools, machines, and power

1. A machine is a mechanical device by which power is applied in an automatically repeated manner, to change the place or form of things. It is not easy, perhaps not important, to distinguish the machine from the tool in every case. Tools are portions of matter, such as bone, wood, iron, which man guides and directs in applying his energy to things. A machine may be used by the foot, but the hand is the great tool-using member. In many cases there is a clearly marked distinction between tool and machine. A simple, single piece that can be taken into the hand, as a spade, a hammer, a knife, is a tool; a combination of wheels, levers, pulleys, etc., is a machine. The simplest machine is but a slight adaptation of the tool, by which power may be applied in an automatically repeated manner. The drag develops into the cart, a simple machine. The spinning-stick, a tool used in ancient times, developed into the Saxon spinning-wheel of the sixteenth century, the form used when America was colonized. The use of power derived from nature, as that of wind and water and steam, while not the essential mark of machines, is the most characteristic feature of their modern development. Hand-machines, such as the hand-press and the type-writer, have had important industrial results, but it is the use of power leading to the concentration of industry and the ownership of machinery by the employers that has the greatest significance in the modern economic problem.

1. A machine is a device that uses power in a repeated way to change the position or shape of things. It's not always easy or even necessary to differentiate between a machine and a tool in every situation. Tools are physical objects, like bone, wood, or iron, which individuals control to apply their energy to tasks. A machine can be operated with the foot, but the hand is the primary tool-using part of the body. In many instances, the difference between a tool and a machine is clear. A simple item that can be held in the hand, like a spade, hammer, or knife, is a tool; while a combination of wheels, levers, pulleys, etc., is a machine. The simplest machine is just a slight modification of a tool that allows power to be applied in a repeated manner. The drag turns into the cart, a basic machine. The spinning stick, a tool from ancient times, evolved into the Saxon spinning wheel of the 16th century, which was used when America was colonized. The use of natural power sources, like wind, water, and steam, while not the defining feature of machines, is a key aspect of their modern evolution. Hand-operated machines, such as hand presses and typewriters, have had significant industrial impacts, but it's the use of power that leads to the concentration of industry and the ownership of machinery by employers that is most important in today's economic landscape.

Machinery brought in an industrial revolution

2. Machinery of many sorts has long been used, but the "age of machinery" begins with the eighteenth century. Inventions, new machines, and new processes, though not frequent, were not unknown in the Middle Ages; but no one class of machines took possession of a whole field of industry and gave rise to a great economic problem by the displacing of labor. The great industrial changes in the Middle Ages generally grew out of political changes, or of changes of routes of trade whereby large industries were disturbed, or of changes in the use of land through new methods and the bringing into use of land in other places. The industrial changes in England at the end of the eighteenth century on the contrary were due mainly to great mechanical inventions. The development of the textile machines for cotton and wool spinning and weaving mark the beginning of the movement. Here for the first time were inventions in such numbers, of such a nature, and under such conditions, that they were rapidly and widely applied, affecting the lives of a great number of workers. The steam-engine at the same time opened up the long line of mechanical inventions by which wood and iron are shaped and wrought, and the iron industry underwent notable developments. Since that time, have taken place in all Western countries that rapid expansion in the use of machines and those notable changes in industrial organization which distinguish our era from all others.

2. Machinery of various kinds has been around for a long time, but the "age of machinery" truly starts in the eighteenth century. While inventions, new machines, and new processes weren't common in the Middle Ages, they did exist; however, no specific group of machines dominated an entire industry or created a significant economic issue by displacing workers. The major industrial shifts during the Middle Ages usually stemmed from political changes, shifts in trade routes that disrupted large industries, or changes in land use due to new methods and bringing land from other areas into use. In contrast, the industrial changes in England at the end of the eighteenth century were primarily driven by major mechanical inventions. The advancement of textile machines for spinning and weaving cotton and wool marks the start of this movement. For the first time, there were inventions in such quantity and nature, and under such conditions, that they were quickly and widely implemented, impacting the lives of many workers. At the same time, the steam engine opened the door to a series of mechanical inventions that shaped wood and iron, leading to significant developments in the iron industry. Since then, all Western countries have experienced a rapid increase in the use of machines and notable changes in industrial organization that set our era apart from all others.

Increased use of power

3. Machinery is applicable in very different degrees to the different processes and industries. Machinery can save much labor in some directions, little or none in others. It is especially adapted to the application of power. In the United States, in 1870, in manufactures alone, two and one third million horse-power were used; in 1900, eleven and one third million, the increase being five-fold. It is said that in the world, in 1870, three and one half million horse-power was furnished by stationary engines, ten millions by locomotives. Probably to-day the total is four-fold as great.

3. Machinery is relevant in varying degrees across different processes and industries. It can significantly reduce labor in some areas but not much, if at all, in others. Machinery is especially suited for harnessing power. In the United States, in 1870, industries used two and one-third million horsepower; by 1900, that number rose to eleven and one-third million, marking a five-fold increase. Around the world in 1870, stationary engines provided three and a half million horsepower, while locomotives contributed ten million. Today, that total is likely quadruple.

Machines can best be used in manufactures

Machinery is applicable with especial advantage to industries that change the form of materials easily transported and widely used. There must be a large output to justify the use of machinery. In 1840 a man's work in spinning cotton was three hundred and twenty times as effective as in 1769, in 1855 it was seven hundred times; and though the rate of improvement is diminishing, to-day the productivity of such labor is still greater. Similar examples are found in the manufacture of shoes, and in all varieties of wood- and iron-work. Machinery is most applicable where there is a compact plant; not so easily where the power has to be distributed over a wide area, unless a special track can be provided.

Machinery is especially beneficial for industries that easily change the form of materials that are easy to transport and widely used. There needs to be a large output to make the use of machinery worthwhile. In 1840, a person's work in spinning cotton was three hundred and twenty times more effective than in 1769, and by 1855, it was seven hundred times more effective; even though the rate of improvement is slowing down, today, the productivity of that labor is still much higher. Similar examples can be seen in shoe manufacturing and various kinds of wood and metalwork. Machinery works best in a compact setup; it's not as effective when the power needs to be spread over a large area, unless there's a special track in place.

Not to so great an extent in agriculture

Machinery, therefore, has affected manufactures much more immediately and greatly than it has agriculture. It has not as yet, for example, been found practicable to apply steam to ploughing to any great extent. As the profitable use of most farm machinery requires a level surface and a large area given to a single crop, it cannot be used as well east of the Alleghany Mountains as in the Mississippi Valley, and it is still uneconomical in large portions of the civilized world. Despite this difficulty the methods of the farmer of to-day contrast strongly with those of one hundred or fifty years ago. Planters and seeders, reapers, harvesters, corn-shellers, hay-loaders, automatic unloading-forks, elevators, water-power-, steam-, and gasoline-engines allow great economies. The labor needed to produce food for one hundred people is a fraction of what it was one hundred years ago. In many other industries machines are usable only in a slight measure, indirectly, or not at all. They are of the least assistance in the personal services, and in the work of the thinker, the teacher, the speaker, and the artist.

Machinery has had a much more immediate and significant impact on manufacturing than it has on agriculture. For instance, we haven't found a practical way to use steam for plowing on a large scale yet. Since most farm machinery requires a flat surface and a sizable area dedicated to a single crop, it doesn't work as well east of the Alleghany Mountains as it does in the Mississippi Valley, and it's still not efficient in many parts of the developed world. Despite these challenges, today’s farming techniques are vastly different from those of a hundred or fifty years ago. Tools like planters, seeders, reapers, harvesters, corn-shellers, hay-loaders, automatic unloading forks, elevators, and water-, steam-, and gasoline-powered engines enable significant efficiencies. The amount of labor needed to grow food for a hundred people is just a fraction of what it was a century ago. In many other industries, machines can only be used to a limited extent, indirectly, or not at all. They are the least helpful in personal services and in the work of thinkers, teachers, speakers, and artists.

§ II. EFFECT OF MACHINERY ON THE WELFARE AND WAGES OF THE MASSES

Evil of sudden introduction of machinery

1. The immediate effect of improved machinery, if suddenly introduced, is almost always to throw some men out of employment. Any sudden change in industry injures men who have become adapted to the work that is affected. A well-mastered trade, a wage-earning though intangible possession, may be made suddenly valueless. Men cannot quickly change their methods of working or their place of work. This is as true of change brought about by new trade routes or by scientific discoveries (where machinery does not enter in) as in the case of labor-saving machines. If machines displace labor rapidly, men who cannot adjust themselves to the new conditions suffer, and there are always some who cannot adjust themselves, always some who suffer. It is rarely possible for a man past middle life to shift over into a new trade where his efficiency will be as great and his pay as high as in the old. New methods of puddling iron sent many old men into the poorhouses of Pennsylvania only a few years ago. Even where the total employment increases, the individual sometimes suffers. The increased demand resulting from the cheapening of a product may call for more workers than were employed before the new machinery came in, and yet some of the former workmen may be thrown out of employment. The introduction of the linotype is said to have displaced a large number of hand type-setters, but to have increased greatly the amount of printing. As the machines are expensive and cannot be worked properly by men not highly expert, men past thirty-five years of age have not been allowed to learn their use.

1. The immediate effect of improved machinery, if suddenly introduced, is almost always to put some people out of work. Any sudden change in industry harms those who have become accustomed to the affected jobs. A well-learned trade, a wage-earning yet intangible asset, can suddenly become worthless. People can’t quickly change their working methods or their workplaces. This is true for changes caused by new trade routes or scientific discoveries (where machinery isn't involved) just as much as it is for labor-saving machines. If machines rapidly replace workers, those who can't adapt to the new conditions suffer, and there will always be some who can’t adjust and some who suffer. It's rarely possible for someone past middle age to shift to a new trade where their efficiency will be as high and their pay as good as it was before. New methods of iron puddling caused many older workers to end up in Pennsylvania's poorhouses only a few years ago. Even when overall employment increases, some individuals may still suffer. The increased demand resulting from the lower cost of a product might require more workers than were employed before the new machinery was introduced, yet some of the previous workers may find themselves out of jobs. The introduction of the linotype reportedly displaced a large number of hand type-setters but greatly increased the volume of printing. Since the machines are expensive and require highly skilled operators, people over thirty-five have not been allowed to learn how to use them.

Loss falls on the less efficient workers

The least efficient men in any trade always suffer most. The change crushes hardest the man at the margin of employment. The more skilled workman can hasten his pace and still earn a living wage in competition with a machine,[Pg 240] while the less skilled can but drop out entirely, innocent victims of an economic change, sacrifices to the cause of industrial progress. Happily such pathetic incidents are relatively not numerous. Most machinery is introduced in commercial centers, and gradually spreads to other factories in such a way that most men can adapt themselves to the change. The effect of machinery must not be judged by the extreme cases. It was found that there were more hand-looms in use in England in 1850 than fifty years before, though in the meantime power-looms had displaced the hand-looms in all the great factories.

The least efficient workers in any industry always feel the impact the most. The changes hit hardest for those on the edge of employment. Skilled workers can boost their efforts and still make a living wage competing against machines, [Pg 240] while less skilled workers may have no choice but to drop out completely, becoming innocent victims of economic change and sacrifices for industrial progress. Fortunately, these sad situations are relatively rare. Most machinery is introduced in commercial hubs and gradually spreads to other factories, allowing most workers to adapt to the change. The impact of machines shouldn't be judged by extreme cases. It was found that there were more hand-looms in use in England in 1850 than fifty years earlier, even though, in the meantime, power-looms had replaced hand-looms in all the major factories.

Error of the "lump of labor" notion

2. After time for adjustment, the total sum of employment is as great as before, but the labor is differently distributed. The "lump of labor" idea, as it is called, is widely held, especially among workingmen. The notion is that there is exactly so much labor predetermined to be done; therefore, if machines are introduced, there is that much less for men to do. The logical conclusion easily drawn is that every machine reduces wages. Few, however, would go on to the further conclusion that in the aggregate the existing machinery, like an enormous vampire, is sucking the life-blood of the working-people,—though traces of such a notion frequently appear.

2. After some time for adjustment, the total amount of work available remains the same, but the way it's distributed changes. The idea of a "lump of labor," as it's known, is widely accepted, especially among workers. The belief is that there is a fixed amount of work to be done; therefore, if machines are introduced, there’s less work for people to do. The obvious conclusion people often reach is that every machine lowers wages. However, few would go so far as to say that, overall, the existing machinery, like a giant vampire, is draining the life out of the workers—although hints of such a belief often come up.

Effect of machinery varies in different industries

If extreme examples are taken, it may be made to appear either that an increase or that a decrease of employment results from machinery. Industries grade off from those that are capable of developing a greater and greater demand, to those at the other extreme that are capable of a very slight increase, as a result of a lowering of the price. There seems to be practically no limit to the consumption of textiles, provided their price falls; the demand for dress alone is indefinitely expansible. Queen Elizabeth, who had a different dress for every day in the year, has many potential imitators. There is a constant increase relatively, as well as absolutely, in the number employed in transportation, as each census shows; there are more railroad men relatively[Pg 241] than there were stage-drivers and teamsters before the day of railroads. The number of people now engaged in printing books and papers is larger by far than in the days when all the books of the world were written by the old monks in their cloisters. The proportion of workers in agriculture, on the other hand, is less than it formerly was. In part this is a change in appearance only, for the farmer once made a large part of his tools which are now made by workers employed in manufactures, yet who in a very real way are aiding in agriculture. In part the change is, however, the effect of the use of machinery and other improvements in agricultural processes. The amount of raw-food products required for each hundred persons is quite inelastic. As it becomes possible to expend more for food, the change is made in quality, variety, flavor, rather than in quantity. The greater part of the saving in the cost of food is, however, expended in other products, and the labor saved in agriculture finds employment in supplying these rising wants. In other cases also, new industries are made possible as machines liberate energy from the production of the more necessary goods. At each census it is necessary to change the schedule of occupations, because men have adopted callings unknown before.

If extreme examples are considered, it might seem that either an increase or a decrease in jobs comes from machinery. Industries range from those that can create a growing demand to those at the opposite end that can only see a slight increase as prices drop. There appears to be almost no limit to the consumption of textiles, as long as their prices decrease; the demand for clothing alone can expand indefinitely. Queen Elizabeth, who had a different outfit for every day of the year, has many potential followers. There is a constant increase, both relatively and absolutely, in the number of people working in transportation, as each census shows; there are more railroad workers than there were stagecoaches and teamsters before the advent of railroads. The number of people now working in printing books and papers is significantly larger than when all the world's books were written by monks in their cloisters. On the other hand, the proportion of workers in agriculture is less than it used to be. Part of this is just a change in appearance, since farmers once made a large portion of their tools, which are now manufactured by workers, who are, in a very real way, still supporting agriculture. However, part of this change is also due to machinery and other technological advancements in agricultural processes. The amount of raw food needed for every hundred people is quite steady. As people can spend more on food, the change tends to be in quality, variety, and flavor rather than quantity. Most of the savings from food costs, however, are spent on other products, and the labor saved in agriculture finds jobs in meeting these increasing demands. Similarly, new industries emerge as machines free up energy from producing more essential goods. With each census, it is necessary to update the list of occupations because new jobs have been created that didn't exist before.

Abnormal effect of the new machinery in England

3. In some cases the introduction of new machines injures particular workmen. The only reason for the use of machinery is to improve the quality or to lower the price of products. If the workers can do nothing but blindly pursue the same tasks, it is to be expected that the wages of hand-labor will fall in a particular trade into which machinery is suddenly introduced. When, as sometimes happens, employers introduce machines for the immediate purpose of breaking a strike, the workmen are convinced that machinery is the enemy of labor.

3. Sometimes the introduction of new machines hurts specific workers. The main goal of using machinery is to enhance product quality or reduce prices. If workers can only mindlessly repeat the same tasks, it’s likely that wages for manual labor will decrease in a trade where machines are suddenly introduced. When employers bring in machines to quickly counter a strike, workers believe that machinery is a threat to their jobs.

Because the extensive introduction of machinery in England was at first accompanied by the unhappy result of a lengthening of the hours of labor in factories, this result[Pg 242] was deemed to be necessary in all other cases. It was in fact quite abnormal, and has not been seen elsewhere. The owners of factories wished to keep their machines employed as many hours as possible; the laboring classes of England, being at the same time demoralized and depressed by industrial and social influences that had no logical connection with machinery, had no power to resist this movement. In all other countries of Europe and in America, where the introduction of machinery has been more gradual and normal, it has been followed immediately by a shortening of working hours, as eventually it was in England also.

Because the widespread introduction of machinery in England initially led to longer working hours in factories, this outcome[Pg 242] was seen as necessary in all other situations. In reality, it was quite unusual and hasn't been observed elsewhere. Factory owners wanted to keep their machines running as much as possible; meanwhile, the working class in England, being both demoralized and weighed down by industrial and social factors that weren't logically connected to the machines, had little power to resist this trend. In other European countries and in America, where the introduction of machinery happened more gradually and naturally, it was immediately followed by shorter working hours, just as it eventually was in England as well.

Higher wages logically result from the use of machinery

4. Indeed, the economic effect of improved appliances is logically and inevitably to raise wages. It has been shown above, in the discussion of wages, that if the efficiency of machines increases faster than does the number of workers who use them, the marginal application of labor stops at the higher uses or services of agents and is not forced to the lower. The more perfect the economic environment, the higher the incomes even of those who own no part of the machinery. A part of this benefit may appear in the form of higher money wages received, a part in the form of the lower price of things bought. Real wages are the essential thing, and as a consumer the laborer shares with every other member of society in the benefits of improved machinery. The benefits resulting from greater abundance are diffused, and as goods are brought from the high, or scarcity, end of the scale of value down toward the level of free goods, everybody gains by the abundance and cheapness.

4. In fact, the economic impact of better appliances naturally and inevitably leads to higher wages. It's been discussed earlier that if machines become more efficient faster than the number of workers using them increases, the added labor will focus on more skilled tasks and won't be pushed down to less valuable work. The more ideal the economic situation, the higher the earnings for those who don’t own any machinery. Some of these benefits may show up as increased money wages, while others come as lower prices for purchased goods. Real wages are what matter most, and as consumers, workers benefit along with everyone else in society from advancements in machinery. The advantages from greater abundance are spread out, and as goods move from the high, or scarce, end of the value scale toward the level of freely available goods, everyone benefits from the abundance and lower costs.

Some grades gain more than others

The general, or average, gain is not to be judged by comparing the conditions of the lowest grade of society with those of fifty years ago, for while that grade may have been bettered only a little, it has been possible for large numbers to rise to higher grades because of the use of machinery. The physical tasks are to-day much lighter than ever before, and a larger proportion of society is engaged in industries that require skill and thought rather than physical labor. That[Pg 243] portion of the work is being more and more shifted upon machines. It is important, though, to distinguish between classes of workers in judging of the benefits and evils of machines. A machine is "an iron man," it has been said, and comes into competition with other men to lower their wages by outworking and underbidding them. But this iron man can do only automatic tasks; it is not capable of exercising judgment. Every intelligent laborer who can adjust, adapt, fit himself for more intelligent action will rise above the machine and profit by its presence. But the crude physical labor which can compete only on the plane of automatic machines, must find its field of employment more and more hedged in. If the wages of unskilled labor are not depressed, it is because of the enterprise of others who rise to more skilled employments and thus reduce the competitors of the lowest rank.

The general or average gain shouldn't be judged by comparing the conditions of the lowest social class to those from fifty years ago. While that class may have seen only slight improvements, many people have been able to move up to higher classes thanks to the use of machines. Today, physical tasks are much lighter than ever before, and a larger percentage of society is involved in industries that require skill and thought rather than just physical labor. That[Pg 243] work is increasingly being handled by machines. However, it’s essential to differentiate between classes of workers when assessing the benefits and drawbacks of machines. A machine is often described as "an iron man," which competes with human workers, driving down wages by outperforming and underbidding them. But this iron man can only perform automatic tasks and lacks the ability to make judgments. Every skilled worker who can adjust, adapt, and prepare for more intelligent tasks will rise above the machine and benefit from its existence. However, unskilled labor, which can only compete on the level of automatic machines, will find its job opportunities becoming more restricted. If unskilled labor wages aren't falling, it's because of the initiative of others who are moving into more skilled jobs, thereby reducing competition at the lowest levels.

The growth of factories

5. The early effects of the factory system on the health, intelligence, and morals of the workers often have been bad; but not necessarily the abiding effects. Some kinds of machines can be more profitably used when they are grouped in great factories, and, where this is common, it is spoken of as the factory system. In the ideal modern factory (realized in few cases) each smaller machine is a part of a larger organization of machinery, so perfect that the material goes in at one end of the building and out at the other without the loss of a single motion. Factories compel great numbers of laborers to live near each other and to work together. The sudden crowding together of people into new social relations is usually bad for morals. Men are moral under the eyes of their neighbors, acquaintances, and families; habits become adjusted to right standards, and the temptations in new conditions are always great. Until of late, engineering science has not been able to deal with the problems that arise where population is densely crowded, and the early factories with their surroundings were most unsanitary. Under the degrading conditions that resulted in some places,[Pg 244] especially in England, the effect of machinery on the intelligence of the workers was bad. Whether this is its natural result is debatable, but the factory worker in general does not appear to be less intelligent than the agricultural worker. The alertness of the city dweller is due doubtless to social contact more than to the immediate work he does. This work may or may not be less thought-awakening than work with simple tools. There is a general improvement along all the lines of intelligence, morals, and health. The conditions in the cities as regards health and morals are approaching those of agricultural communities. While many factory districts are forlorn, there may be seen around many factories more happy conditions, better buildings, better sanitation, increased leisure for workers, workmen's clubs, educational agencies, and many other evidences of civic and social progress.

5. The early effects of the factory system on the health, intelligence, and morals of workers have often been negative; however, those effects don’t have to last. Certain machines can be used more effectively when grouped in large factories, and when this happens, it’s referred to as the factory system. In the ideal modern factory (which is rarely seen), each smaller machine is part of a larger organization of machinery, so seamless that the materials enter one end of the building and exit the other without a single wasted motion. Factories force large numbers of workers to live close to one another and to collaborate. This sudden mingling of people into new social settings is typically harmful to morals. People tend to behave better when their neighbors, friends, and families are watching; habits align with appropriate standards, and the temptations in new situations are always significant. Until recently, engineering had not effectively addressed the challenges posed by densely populated areas, and the early factories and their environments were often quite unsanitary. Under the degrading conditions that arose in some places,[Pg 244] especially in England, machinery had a negative impact on the intelligence of the workers. Whether this is an inherent outcome is a matter of debate, but in general, factory workers do not seem to be less intelligent than agricultural workers. The quickness of city dwellers is likely more related to social interactions than to the tasks they perform. This work might be less stimulating than using simple tools, but there is a general improvement in intelligence, morals, and health across the board. The health and moral conditions in cities are starting to resemble those of farming communities. While many factory areas are bleak, around numerous factories, you can see happier conditions, better buildings, improved sanitation, more leisure time for workers, workers' clubs, educational programs, and many other signs of civic and social progress.

Problems of large industry

6. The great social consequences flowing from the concentration of industry and wealth are the most serious problems in the relation of machinery to labor. The ownership of tools was widely diffused in medieval times. It is not yet evident how many can own a share in great factories, but the control drifts into few hands. It is not yet clear what social effects great corporations will have on our democratic institutions. Many problems of large industry remain to be solved in the near future. The question in the old form, as to the effect of machinery on labor, is no longer open. It has been clearly answered by experience and explained by theory: the economic effect of machinery is to lift the productiveness and efficiency of the average man. The benefits are unequally distributed, but nearly all share in them to some degree. The question which the future will have to answer is, What will be the social and political effects of the great fortunes that have been made possible by the enormous development of machinery?

6. The significant social issues arising from the concentration of industry and wealth are the most serious challenges related to machinery and labor. In medieval times, the ownership of tools was widespread. It’s not yet clear how many people can own a stake in large factories, but the control is shifting into fewer hands. The social impact of large corporations on our democratic institutions is still uncertain. Many challenges associated with large industry need to be addressed in the near future. The longstanding question about the impact of machinery on labor is no longer up for debate. Experience has provided a clear answer, and theory has explained it: the economic impact of machinery is to enhance the productivity and efficiency of the average worker. While the benefits are unevenly distributed, almost everyone experiences them to some extent. The question for the future will be: What will be the social and political implications of the vast fortunes made possible by the massive advancement of machinery?


CHAPTER 27

TRADE-UNIONS

§ I. THE OBJECTS OF TRADE-UNIONS

Definition and purposes of trade-unions

1. A trade-union is an association of wage-workers for purposes of mutual information, mutual help, and for the raising of wages. The term trade-union is used in a general sense both of combinations of workers in the same trade, and of men in different trades, though usually the latter are called labor-unions. The "Knights of Labor" is a good example of the labor-union, the "American Federation of Labor" of a combination of trade-unions. The Knights of Labor is composed of local branches to which workers of every class except lawyers and saloon-keepers are admitted. The Federation of Labor, however, is composed of chapters, or lodges, that are homogeneous, all the men of each lodge being in the same trade.

1. A trade union is a group of wage workers that comes together for sharing information, providing support, and increasing wages. The term trade union refers to both workers in the same profession and those in different professions, although the latter are usually referred to as labor unions. The "Knights of Labor" is a good example of a labor union, while the "American Federation of Labor" represents a collection of trade unions. The Knights of Labor consists of local branches that accept workers from all classes except for lawyers and bar owners. In contrast, the Federation of Labor is made up of chapters or lodges that are uniform, with all members of each lodge being in the same trade.

The definition given is broad enough to include the various degrees of help given and the various methods adopted by trade-unions to accomplish their objects. Trade-unions are mutual-benefit associations: insurance against accident, sickness, death, or lack of employment, forms an important part, and in some cases almost the whole of their work. All unions in a measure serve their members as employment bureaus, while in some unions this is a most important feature. Through trade-papers, correspondence, and personal meetings, information is exchanged regarding trade conditions, and great mutual service is thus rendered. But a great deal of the help given is in the more impersonal economic[Pg 246] ways: help to get from the employers better wages, to secure shorter hours, to improve in various ways the conditions of employment.

The definition provided is broad enough to cover the different levels of support and various methods used by labor unions to achieve their goals. Labor unions are mutual-aid organizations: providing insurance against accidents, illness, death, or unemployment is a significant part of their function, and in some cases, almost all of their work. All unions somewhat operate as employment agencies for their members, while this function is particularly important in some unions. Through trade publications, correspondence, and personal meetings, information on trade conditions is shared, providing significant mutual benefit. However, a large portion of the assistance offered is in more impersonal economic ways: helping members negotiate better wages, secure shorter hours, and enhance the overall conditions of employment.[Pg 246]

Lack of personal touch between employers and workmen

2. The organization of workers has resulted from the separation of the economic and personal interests of employers and workmen. The control of industry has become more concentrated during the age of machinery, and this has reduced the feeling of economic unity among the different ranks of industry. There is now to the average workman no possibility of becoming a master, an employer. The largeness of industry forbids, moreover, the meeting and personal acquaintance of employer and workman which were before possible. Misunderstandings grow when men cannot talk over their differences. The social chasm has widened between the workmen and the responsible director of industry. As a result of these changes, the attitude of the employer very often has become that of the buyer of labor as a mere ware. He has with the mass of his employees no personal relations whatever. Under these conditions, when the employer feels the presence of competition, he is more likely to force the lowest wage that is possible. It is not unusual for the immediate direction of factories to be intrusted to paid managers, who are responsible to the stockholders and whose work is judged only by the dividends they succeed in earning. Many examples might be found where the managers or the resident owners have wished to pursue a more liberal policy than the absentee shareholders would permit.

2. The organization of workers has come about due to the separation of the economic and personal interests of employers and employees. Control of industry has become more centralized during the age of machinery, and this has diminished the sense of economic unity among the various levels of industry. For the average worker, there’s now no chance of becoming a master or an employer. Additionally, the size of industries prevents the meetings and personal connections between employers and employees that used to be possible. Misunderstandings arise when people can't discuss their differences. The social gap has widened between workers and the executives in charge of industry. Because of these changes, employers often view workers simply as a means to an end, like a commodity. They have no personal connection with their large number of employees. In this environment, when employers sense competition, they tend to push for the lowest possible wages. It’s common for factory management to be handed over to paid managers who answer to shareholders and whose performance is judged only by the profits they can generate. There are many instances where managers or local owners have wanted to adopt a more progressive approach than the absentee shareholders would allow.

Lack of personal acquaintance among workers

3. The need of organization of labor has grown with the growth of factories and with the loss of personal touch among the workers. This is another aspect of the point just mentioned. The smaller the number of employers, the easier is it by an understanding to suppress competition on their side. If there is only one factory of a kind in a town or city, the employer is able to drive a harder bargain with the worker. Especially in times of industrial depression is a[Pg 247] change of employment difficult for the laborer; it involves much risk, and loss of time and money in moving. In the long run competition must be felt even in such cases. The unfair employer will find his workmen drifting away, his force reduced in number and quality, and his evil reputation going abroad among workmen. But there is a great deal of friction in this adjustment and the loss falls largely upon the workman. In a large industry, especially, the workers have no personal acquaintance with each other, nothing to give them a sense of unity and power. In the old-fashioned shop, with its close association and its interchange of views, could grow up a strong public opinion; but in the wilderness of a modern factory the worker may be unknown in name and character to the man who touches elbows with him. Moreover, in America differences in nationality and in speech among immigrant workers is often an effective factor in preventing the assertion of their interests. There is an analogy (though it is only an analogy) between these conditions and the political conditions that have led pure democracies to give way to representative governments. So long as a community is small and men know each other personally, there may be popular government, but when the number becomes larger the only way in which public opinion can be concentrated and made effective is by delegating the functions of government to representatives.

3. The need for organized labor has increased with the rise of factories and the loss of personal connections among workers. This is another aspect of the previous point. The fewer employers there are, the easier it is for them to conspire to suppress competition on their side. If there's only one factory of its kind in a town or city, the employer can negotiate harder with the workers. Especially during times of industrial downturn, changing jobs is tough for laborers; it involves significant risk, as well as time and money spent on relocating. Over time, competition will become apparent even in these situations. An unfair employer will see his workers leaving, reducing both the number and quality of his workforce, and his negative reputation will spread among laborers. However, there is a lot of friction in this adjustment, and much of the burden falls on the worker. In large industries, particularly, workers have no personal relationships with one another, leading to a lack of unity and power. In the traditional shop, with its close-knit environment and exchange of ideas, strong public opinion could form; but in the chaos of a modern factory, a worker may be completely unknown to the person working right next to him. Additionally, in America, the differences in nationality and language among immigrant workers often play a significant role in hindering their ability to advocate for their interests. There’s an analogy (though it’s only an analogy) between these conditions and the political situations that have caused pure democracies to transition to representative governments. As long as a community is small and individuals know each other personally, there may be popular governance, but when the group grows larger, the only way to concentrate and make public opinion effective is to delegate government functions to representatives.

Main objects of trade-unions to-day

4. The main objects of labor-unions to-day are to improve conditions in their working places, to maintain or increase wages, and to shorten working hours. Better conditions of safety and sanitation in their work were not the first thought of the unions. The workers, as a result of habit and ignorance, were strangely unconcerned about this matter. Reforms in this direction at the outset had to come largely from sympathetic observers. But since better ideals have been developed, organized laborers strive to improve the sanitary, moral, and other conditions in the places of work. Their main object, however, was for a long time to raise[Pg 248] wages, or to resist any decrease. Shorter hours have been a prime object of recent years, and almost coördinate with that of higher wages. The eight-hour movement has declined somewhat of late, but a few years ago it seemed possible that the eight-hour day would become the rule. This aim has never been lost sight of, however, and now and then another step is taken toward it. Labor leaders have repeatedly asserted in recent years, when the two demands have been made together, that shorter hours were more desirable than increased wages.

4. The main goals of labor unions today are to improve working conditions, maintain or raise wages, and reduce working hours. Initially, better safety and sanitation conditions in the workplace weren't a top priority for unions. Workers, due to habit and lack of awareness, were surprisingly indifferent about this issue. Early reforms mostly came from sympathetic observers. However, as better values have emerged, organized laborers now aim to enhance sanitary, moral, and other workplace conditions. For a long time, their primary focus was on raising[Pg 248] wages or opposing any cuts. In recent years, shorter hours have become a major goal, almost on par with the push for higher wages. The eight-hour movement has slowed down somewhat recently, but a few years ago, it seemed likely the eight-hour workday would become standard. This objective has never been completely forgotten, and occasionally progress is still made toward it. Labor leaders have repeatedly emphasized in recent years, when both demands are made, that shorter hours are more desirable than higher wages.

§ II. THE METHODS OF TRADE-UNIONS

Organized labor seeks to prevent competition among workers

1. The union's first aim is to get control of all the labor force in the market, and to minimize competition among workers. Every labor federation aims to extend its control to every branch of its trade. A sense of wrong is one of the strongest forces to bring the workers into the organization. The appeal to a common interest is effective in times of great grievance, as it was effective in the dangerous times of the American Revolution, though failing during the Confederation. The unwilling are first persuaded, then coerced by threats, by petty persecutions, by the most cruel of all peaceful weapons, social ostracism, and finally by personal violence. The "public opinion" and class feeling fostered among workers by their organization are analogous to the sense of patriotism and loyalty in the country at large, and at times displace it, as is seen in the opposition to the militia and to the maintenance of public order at times of strikes. The individual who declines to enter the union is denounced as a traitor and made to feel the scorn of his associates. When all these measures fail, pressure is brought to bear upon the employer to get him to force the unwilling workers into the union.

1. The union's main goal is to gain control over the entire workforce in the market and reduce competition among workers. Every labor federation seeks to expand its control to all areas of its trade. A sense of injustice is one of the strongest motivators for workers to join the organization. Appeal to shared interests works well during times of significant grievances, just as it did during the tumultuous times of the American Revolution, even though it faltered during the Confederation. Those who are reluctant are initially persuaded, then pressured through threats, minor harassment, the harshest peaceful tactic—social ostracism—and eventually through physical violence. The "public opinion" and class consciousness developed among workers by their organization is similar to the sense of patriotism and loyalty felt by society as a whole and can sometimes take precedence, as seen in the resistance to the militia and maintaining public order during strikes. Individuals who refuse to join the union are labeled as traitors and made to feel the disdain of their peers. When all these strategies fail, pressure is applied to the employer to compel the unwilling workers to join the union.

The union seeks to secure the full competitive wage
And as much more as possible

2. Its next aim is to use collective in the place of individual bargaining, to force as much as the competitive wage, and more if possible.[Pg 249] The term collective bargaining has been much used to describe bargaining between a group of labor leaders, the delegated representatives of the workingmen, and a group of employers or directors. It is sometimes claimed that all the trade-union seeks is to put the workman on an equality with the employer in bargaining, enabling him to get all he would if competition were free on both sides. It is said that organized labor simply prevents the employer from following the maxim of Napoleon to "divide and conquer," from meeting his employees one by one and forcing his own terms upon them. But the most effective argument in organizing the trade-union is that it forces a higher wage, more than the market would warrant. It is sometimes assumed by labor leaders that competitive wages would be very low, almost starvation wages, and anything above that level is credited to the work of the union; while in other cases where the wages are already large, the purpose frankly avowed is to limit the labor supply in the particular trade and to force a monopoly wage by any means possible. One's opinion of trade-unions is likely to differ according as they work in one or the other of these ways. The impartial onlooker sympathizes with the efforts of the trade-unions in so far as they serve merely to put the workers on an equality with the employers in bargaining. The public wants to see "fair play," and up to a certain point the union is merely a device to get fair play. But if the union is a device to defeat competition, to force artificially high wages, it will be judged differently. The public readily sees that if the unions force more than a fair and open market affords, it is rarely at the expense of the employer; that in the long run it is at the expense of the purchasing public itself, including the unprivileged workmen shut out from the monopoly of labor.

2. Its next goal is to replace individual bargaining with collective bargaining, aiming to secure competitive wages, and even more if possible.[Pg 249] The term collective bargaining is often used to describe negotiations between a group of labor leaders, who are the chosen representatives of the workers, and a group of employers or directors. It's sometimes argued that all a trade union wants is to level the playing field for workers in negotiations, allowing them to earn what they would if competition was fair on both sides. It's said that organized labor just stops the employer from following Napoleon's strategy to "divide and conquer," which means negotiating with employees individually to impose their own terms. However, the strongest argument for forming a trade union is that it pushes for higher wages than the market would typically allow. Labor leaders sometimes assume that competitive wages would be very low—almost starvation wages—and anything above that is credited to the union’s efforts; conversely, in situations where wages are already high, the clear goal is to limit the labor supply in that specific trade and to achieve a monopoly wage by any means necessary. People’s opinions about trade unions tend to vary depending on whether they operate in one way or the other. Impartial observers typically sympathize with the unions to the extent that they help to equalize bargaining power between workers and employers. The public seeks "fair play," and to a certain degree, the union functions simply as a tool for achieving fair play. But if the union is used to undermine competition and force artificially high wages, it will be viewed differently. The public easily understands that if unions demand more than what a fair and open market would provide, it rarely affects the employer directly; rather, in the long term, it impacts the purchasing public itself, including the lower-wage workers excluded from the labor monopoly.

The issue of the closed shop vs. the open shop

3. In order to accomplish their ends, the trade-unions seek to control their employers' business in various ways. They demand, first, that no non-union men shall be employed[Pg 250] even at union wages; they demand that the employer shall help them to force his employees into the unions. In this very usual demand for the "closed shop" or "union shop" the public can see very little justice. On this point, nearly always, unions forfeit in a strike the sympathy of the public; yet the unions assert that it is almost absolutely necessary to gain this point in order to carry out their objects. If a union and a non-union man work side by side there are many ways in which the employer may make the union man suffer. If business slackens, it is likely to be the union man that is discharged; if any preference is given, it is to the non-union man. Certainly all will agree that if the unions are to get the strength to enforce all their demands it is essential that they make good this claim which leaves the employer almost helpless. Yet it certainly is not essential to the accomplishing of valuable services for the members of the union. The educational and mutual-benefit features are attained without this means; and much experience shows that, if their cause is strong, the organized men can carry with them a large proportion of the workers and the sympathy of the public in a contest for higher wages. It never has seemed to any considerable portion of the public any more desirable that organized labor through its officers should be able to dictate to employees, than that employers should crush the workmen. It is by just this assumption that union advocates beg the question of the "union shop."

3. To achieve their goals, trade unions try to control their employers' businesses in various ways. They first demand that no non-union workers are hired[Pg 250], even at union wages; they insist that the employer help pressure his employees to join the unions. In this common demand for the "closed shop" or "union shop," the public sees very little fairness. Because of this, unions often lose public sympathy during strikes; however, unions claim that securing this demand is almost essential to achieve their objectives. If a union worker and a non-union worker are employed side by side, there are many ways the employer can disadvantage the union worker. If business slows down, it’s likely the union worker will be let go first; if there’s any favoritism, it usually goes to the non-union worker. Everyone can agree that for unions to gain the power to enforce all their demands, it’s crucial they support this claim, which leaves the employer nearly powerless. Yet, this isn’t necessary for providing valuable services to union members. The educational and mutual-benefit aspects can be achieved without this tactic; and many experiences show that if their cause is strong, organized workers can win over a large portion of their peers and public support in the fight for higher wages. It has never seemed desirable to a significant part of the public that organized labor, through its leaders, should be able to dictate terms to workers any more than it is for employers to oppress the laborers. It is precisely this assumption that union advocates use to justify the "union shop."

Other limitations put upon industry by unions

Further, the unions direct and control the employment of labor, often limit the number of apprentices in a trade, and assume to determine who shall enjoy the privilege of learning it. They limit the output, fix the maximum amount, and forbid the use of labor-saving machinery. Whenever the unions are charged with these acts, labor leaders either deny the facts or avoid giving a direct answer, but there is no doubt that the charge is true in many ways and in many cases. The requirement that each special kind of work shall be controlled by a special trade, and disputes between[Pg 251] rival trades, for which their jealousies are responsible, give rise to great annoyance, expense, and loss to employers and to the entire public.

Furthermore, unions manage and oversee the employment of workers, often restricting the number of apprentices in a particular trade and deciding who gets to learn it. They control the output, set limits on production, and prohibit the use of labor-saving machines. When unions are accused of these practices, labor leaders either deny the allegations or dodge giving a straight answer, but it’s clear that these accusations are valid in many instances. The rule that each specific type of work must be handled by a distinct trade, along with conflicts between rival trades fueled by their rivalries, causes significant frustration, costs, and losses for employers and the public at large.

The strike and the boycott

4. The strike is a threat and a mode of attack to enforce the demands of the union. To most newly organized laborers the union appeals mainly as an instrument for striking, for threatening the employer or for making him suffer. When a new union is formed, it is nearly always dedicated by a strike, which is the simultaneous stopping of work by a number of workers. A strike is intended to force the employer to grant the wages and conditions demanded. Its effectiveness lies in the injury which it occasions or threatens in the stopping of machinery, the ruin of material, the loss of custom, and the failure to complete contracts undertaken. Its success being dependent on the inability of the employer to fill the places of the strikers, their energies are bent on persuading or coercing other workers from taking employment. There are many ways of coercing workers without personal violence. Public opinion does much, and probably the severest of all coercive measures is the social ostracism of the worker. What may be called the endless-chain boycott is an excommunication, without measure or limit, of the non-union worker and of every one in any way befriending him or the employer. So far as in their power lies, the enraged strikers dissolve the very bonds of society, brother casts off brother, and mother disowns son. The unhappy conditions in the coal regions in 1902 rivaled the tragedies of civil war. A reasonable use of the boycott, refusal to maintain social relations with the person who offends one, is doubtless a part of personal liberty; but the boycott, as experience shows, has moral limits, and it should have strict legal limits. Its use beyond the moderate limit of the first degree of personal relations is antisocial to the degree of criminality, whether it be used as the weapon of organized workers or of organized wealth.

4. The strike is a threat and a way to push for the union's demands. For most newly organized workers, the union primarily serves as a tool for striking, intimidating the employer, or causing him difficulties. When a new union is established, it's almost always launched with a strike, which involves multiple workers stopping work at the same time. A strike aims to pressure the employer into conceding to the requested wages and conditions. Its effectiveness comes from the disruption it causes or threatens by halting machinery, damaging materials, losing customers, and failing to fulfill contracts. Success relies on the employer's inability to replace the strikers, so the workers focus on convincing or pressuring others not to take their jobs. There are many ways to pressure workers without resorting to violence. Public opinion plays a major role, and probably the harshest form of pressure is social ostracism of the workers. The so-called endless-chain boycott is a complete excommunication of non-union workers and everyone who supports them or their employer. As much as they can, the angry strikers break down the very fabric of society, with brother turning against brother and mother disowning son. The dire conditions in the coal regions in 1902 were comparable to the tragedies of a civil war. While a reasonable boycott—refusing to maintain social ties with those who offend us—can be seen as part of personal freedom, as experience shows, the boycott has moral limits, and it should have strict legal boundaries. Its use beyond a moderate level of personal relations becomes antisocial to a degree that could be criminal, whether used by organized labor or organized wealth.

Violence in strikes is mob law

When peaceable means fail, often there is a recourse to[Pg 252] violence both against the employer and his property and against the non-union men. The evils of violence in strikes often are tardily recognized by the public, whose sympathy up to a certain point is with the striker as "the under dog." It is slow to realize that strike violence is mob-law. Whenever men of one group assume the right to coerce forcibly and to wreak their hatred against one of their fellow-workers, it is a blow at political liberty. No free society can safely go the first step in permitting one group of men to usurp control over others in this way.

When peaceful methods fail, there's often a shift to[Pg 252] violence aimed at both the employer and his property, as well as at non-union workers. The negative consequences of violence during strikes are often slow to be recognized by the public, whose sympathy initially lies with the striker as the "underdog." It takes time for them to understand that strike violence is a form of mob rule. Whenever members of one group assume the right to forcibly coerce and unleash their hatred on a fellow worker, it undermines political freedom. No free society can safely allow one group of people to take control over others in this way.

Costliness of strikes

5. The great losses caused by strikes are the penalty of an unsolved industrial problem. The losses to workers in wages, to employers and to investors in income and property, and to the public in interruption of business, aggregate an enormous sum. It is, however, impossible to estimate it at all exactly, as the losses are in many cases indirect and intangible. The strikers are concerned not with the balance of total losses and total gains to society as a whole, but with the net gain that in the long run accrues to them. It is true that there are indirect gains not easily calculable, as the advance of wages made to avoid a strike while the lesson of the consequences is still fresh. Opinion among workingmen is not a unit as to the value of strikes. A few years ago it seemed safe to say that strikes were declining as compared with the period of the early eighties. It is probably true, as is often said, that as laborers become educated they put less faith in strikes. The epidemic of labor troubles, marking the years from 1899 to 1903, gave no evidence of a decrease in the use of strikes, yet many of these were due to the recent organization in various trades. The coal strike of 1902, though doubtless due to real grievances, was opposed by the officers of the union, an unusually capable set of men, but the more violent and discordant elements overruled the more pacific counsels. The public is perhaps as favorable as it has ever been to the cause of labor, but it appears to have less patience with strikes than[Pg 253] it had fifteen years ago, and strikes usually fail if not backed by public opinion. The public has not as yet thought out consistent conclusions on the question of the rights of the union. It is just now much impressed with the value of arbitration. As experience destroys the unsound sentiments, and divides the wise from the unwise measures, a peaceable solution of industrial differences must and will be found.

5. The huge losses caused by strikes are the consequence of an unresolved industrial issue. The losses to workers in wages, to employers and investors in income and property, and to the public in business disruptions add up to a significant total. However, it's challenging to estimate the exact amount, as many of the losses are indirect and hard to quantify. Strikers focus not on the overall balance of losses and gains for society, but on the net benefit that ultimately comes to them. While it's true there are indirect gains that are hard to measure, such as wage increases to prevent strikes while the impacts are still fresh, worker opinion on the value of strikes is not uniform. A few years ago, it seemed safe to say that strikes were declining compared to the early 1880s. It's likely true, as often stated, that as workers become more educated, they trust strikes less. The wave of labor disputes from 1899 to 1903 showed no signs of reducing the number of strikes, although many were spurred by recent organization in various trades. The coal strike of 1902, undoubtedly driven by genuine grievances, was opposed by the union's leadership, who were a notably capable group, yet the more extreme and disruptive factions prevailed over the more conciliatory approaches. The public is likely more supportive of labor causes than ever, but it seems to have less tolerance for strikes than[Pg 253] it did fifteen years ago, and strikes typically fail without public backing. The public has not yet come to a consistent position on the rights of unions. Right now, there is a strong emphasis on the importance of arbitration. As experience sheds light on flawed beliefs and distinguishes wise actions from unwise ones, a peaceful resolution to industrial conflicts must and will be achieved.

§ III. COMBINATION AND WAGES

Wages are raised by a labor monopoly

1. Wages in particular industries often are maintained above the competitive rate. The older economic writers were somewhat unsympathetic with trade-unions, and were even inclined to deny that organization could be helpful in any way in raising wages. This view, it must now be recognized, was mistaken, and overlooked the hindrances to competition and the effective economic forces that organization can bring into play. The sympathies of most men favor the wage-earner so strongly that they hesitate to express an opinion in any way unfavorable to his efforts to raise wages. But the view of the economic theorist as to the services of the union cannot be as roseate as is that of the union labor leader. The general proposition, however, is applicable, that wherever it is possible to limit supply, prices may be raised. If men fitted to do a certain work are not permitted to do it, labor in the special industry becomes more scarce and consequently more highly valued. This involves the result that some men are forced to remain where they get lower wages than they could earn if free to act. The temporary need of the employer may enable the union to force from him a division of his profits. If the trade-union watches its opportunity and takes occasion to strike when a failure to fill orders would cause him great loss, it may compel him to pay for a time more than the normal value of the labor. It may well be doubted whether such action on the part of[Pg 254] labor is generous, fair, honest, or in the long run wise; but that it may be immediately effective cannot be denied. By the principle of complementary goods an essential kind of labor can be given an artificially high value, if its supply can be controlled. If only the labor that is ready and willing to come in to take the place of the strikers can for a time be kept out, wages may be fixed practically according to monopoly principles, later to be discussed in connection with capitalistic organization.

1. Wages in certain industries are often kept above the competitive rate. Older economic writers were generally unsupportive of trade unions, and many even believed that organization couldn't really help in raising wages. This perspective was, in hindsight, misguided, as it ignored the barriers to competition and the powerful economic forces that organization can activate. Most people sympathize with wage-earners so much that they're reluctant to voice any opinion that might be negative towards their efforts to increase wages. However, the view of an economic theorist on the benefits of a union cannot be as optimistic as that of a union leader. The general idea, though, remains that wherever it’s possible to restrict supply, prices can be increased. If qualified individuals for a specific job are not allowed to work, labor in that particular industry becomes scarcer and, therefore, more valuable. This often results in some people having to stay in positions that pay less than what they could earn if they had the freedom to choose. The employer’s short-term needs might allow the union to demand a share of his profits. If the union seizes the chance to strike when the employer would suffer significant losses from unfilled orders, they may compel him to pay more than the usual value of labor for a while. It may be questionable whether such actions by labor are generous, fair, honest, or wise in the long run, but it’s undeniable that they can be immediately effective. Through the principle of complementary goods, a vital type of labor can be given an artificially inflated value if its supply is controlled. If only the workers willing to fill in for the strikers can be kept out for a period, wages may be set almost in line with monopoly principles, which will be further discussed in relation to capitalist organization.

Exaggerated claims made for trade-unions

2. Trade-unions can, in various but limited ways, set in motion economic forces to increase the productiveness of labor. It is difficult to take a moderate view of trade-unions; it is easier to go to one extreme or the other. In a book by Trant, reprinted from the English edition and circulated by the American Federation of Labor as representing its theory and claims, all the advances in wages that have been made are said to be due to the trade-unions. This claim is believed by many besides the members of trade-unions. The thought is sometimes expressed even by social students that but for the trade-unions wages in America would be the same as in 1850. Many well-known facts should cause such an opinion to be accepted with hesitation, to say the least. Only about one tenth of the workers in England are unionists and of the twenty-two million workers in the United States, far less than ten per cent. are organized. Can it be maintained that one tenth of the labor supply fixes the value of all? In many lines where labor is not organized, as in teaching, clerical positions, professional and domestic service, wages have risen even more than in organized trade. The evidence advanced to support the extreme claim is that wages are higher in some organized trades than in other unorganized trades requiring the same grade of laborers. Trant says that "where there are no unions wages should be lower. This is exactly the case"; and he quotes: "Wherever we find union principles ignored, a low rate of wages prevails and the reverse where organization is perfect." But he later[Pg 255] explains in part this difference: "The union men are the best workmen and often employers pay a man more than union wages. This is not surprising as no man can be a union carpenter unless he be in good health, have worked a certain number of years at his trade, be a good workman, of steady habits and good moral character."

2. Trade unions can, in various but limited ways, activate economic forces to enhance the productivity of labor. It's tough to have a balanced view of trade unions; it's easier to swing to one side or the other. In a book by Trant, reprinted from the English edition and distributed by the American Federation of Labor as a representation of its theory and claims, it is stated that all wage increases have been attributed to trade unions. Many people, not just union members, believe this claim. Some social researchers even suggest that without trade unions, wages in America would be the same as they were in 1850. Many well-known facts should lead us to be cautious about accepting such a view, at the very least. Only about ten percent of workers in England are union members, and in the United States, far less than ten percent of the twenty-two million workers are organized. Can we really say that one-tenth of the labor force determines the value for all? In many fields where labor isn't organized, such as teaching, office jobs, professional services, and domestic work, wages have increased even more than in organized trades. The evidence cited to support the extreme claim is that wages are higher in some organized trades than in unorganized trades that require the same level of workers. Trant states that "where there are no unions, wages should be lower. This is exactly the case"; and he quotes: "Wherever we find union principles ignored, a low rate of wages prevails and the opposite where organization is strong." However, he later[Pg 255] clarifies this difference: "The union workers are the top craftsmen, and often employers pay more than union wages. This isn't surprising since no one can be a union carpenter unless they are in good health, have worked a certain number of years in their trade, are skilled workers, have steady habits, and possess good moral character."

Certain unquestionable reasons why union wages should be higher

If this be true, it is in accordance with strict competitive principles that, as the elite of the trade, they should get higher wages than those outside. Moreover the unions exist mainly in the more populated places where cost of living, wages, and all prices range higher than in the towns. A much higher standard of work prevails in the cities, both among union and non-union men, and the old men and the inefficient drift away to the smaller towns and the places where wages are lower. Many of the differences are explicable without taking any account of the union. So far as unions tend toward intelligence, education, sobriety, efficiency, fuller and fairer competition, they are economic factors in all branches of industry, and it cannot be doubted that they do work in some measure in all these ways. So far also as they strengthen the bargaining power of the laborers, or as they can enforce a monopoly of labor in a particular trade and locality, they can secure the full competitive or even a monopoly price.

If this is true, it aligns with strict competitive principles that, as the top players in the industry, they should earn higher wages than those outside. Additionally, unions mainly exist in more populated areas where the cost of living, wages, and all prices are higher than in smaller towns. A much higher standard of work is found in the cities, among both union and non-union workers, while older and less efficient workers tend to move to smaller towns where wages are lower. Many of the differences can be explained without considering the union. To the extent that unions promote intelligence, education, sobriety, efficiency, and fairer competition, they serve as economic factors in all areas of industry, and it’s clear that they contribute in various ways. Likewise, as they enhance the bargaining power of workers, or can create a labor monopoly in a specific trade and location, they can achieve full competitive or even monopoly prices.

Labor organizations a minor factor in lifting the mass of the workers
The chief factors determining wages

3. Wages viewed in general industry, and in the long run, are determined mainly by impersonal economic forces. That implies the converse, that they are not determined mainly by the trade-unions. This statement, in fact, is admitted in calmer moments by the extreme partisans of the unions. Even the book before quoted says somewhat vaguely that "it is an error to think that the trade-union seeks to determine the rate of wages. It cannot do that. It can do no more than affect them." Again it says: "Capital is increasing faster than population.... It seems therefore merely in obedience to natural laws that wages should rise." Men can easily see personal and immediate results.[Pg 256] They cannot follow out the impersonal and ultimate workings of economic forces. The leaders make exaggerated claims; laborers believe them and pay their dues more readily; the public believes them and is the more inclined to pardon the excesses of so important an institution. That wages in a number of special trades are raised in a considerable degree cannot be questioned. The open or secret use of violence and other antisocial forces make much of this boasted service to some of the workers, an injury to others, and an occasion of reproach from the citizen who condemns the spirit of lawlessness thus encouraged. The chief factors tending to raise the general standard of wages are the productiveness of industry, peace, order, and security to wealth, honesty in man and master, in lawmaker and in judge, the efficiency and intelligence of the workers, and an earnest effort on their part to get the share that competition would accord them. Chiefly, though not exclusively, because of their bearing on this last factor, trade-unions have a useful, even though subordinate, part in the regulating of wages over the whole field of employment.

3. Wages in general industry, in the long run, are mainly determined by impersonal economic forces. This indicates the opposite, that they are not primarily determined by trade unions. Even the most extreme supporters of the unions acknowledge this in calmer moments. The previously cited book somewhat vaguely states that "it is a mistake to think that the trade union can set the wage rate. It cannot do that; it can only influence them." It also mentions: "Capital is growing faster than the population.... It seems, therefore, that wages should rise simply in accordance with natural laws." People can easily see personal and immediate results.[Pg 256] They struggle to understand the impersonal and ultimate effects of economic forces. Leaders tend to make exaggerated claims; workers believe them and pay their dues more willingly; the public believes them and is more inclined to overlook the excesses of such an important institution. It's undeniable that wages in certain specialized trades have significantly increased. However, the open or secret use of violence and other antisocial tactics makes much of this claimed benefit to some workers a detriment to others, while also provoking criticism from citizens who condemn the lawlessness it encourages. The main factors that raise the overall standard of wages are the productivity of industry, stability, order, security for wealth, honesty among individuals and authorities, and the efficiency and intelligence of the workforce, along with their sincere effort to obtain the share that competition would allow them. Primarily, although not exclusively, due to their influence on this last factor, trade unions play a helpful, albeit secondary, role in regulating wages across the entire job market.


DIVISION B—ENTERPRISE AND PROFITS


CHAPTER 28

PRODUCTION AND THE COMBINATION OF THE FACTORS

§ I. THE NATURE OF PRODUCTION

Man's active intervention in production here to be studied

1. The aim of industrial effort is the increase of the quantity and quality of scarce goods; this is economic production. The thought has become familiar to the student that the supply of economic resources of whatever sort is limited, while the wants are practically unlimited. A supply of consumption goods meets a perennial stream of wants, the result being that value is attributed to things. The aim of production is to add to scarce things, to make the supply of goods as large as possible. There is occasion here to recall the thought of the two aspects of production noticed in Chapter 24. Man's part in production is passive when goods come into existence without his effort. One can imagine the indolent savage of the tropics, lying under the banana-tree, letting the fruit drop into his mouth. One can conceive of a tribe living upon manna, where every day the people awoke to discover a certain amount of food provided to each person's hand. Though no effort could increase that amount, still, if the food differed in flavor and the better qualities were rare, value would come into existence and exchange[Pg 258] would arise. Now there is something very analogous to that in daily experience. There are some goods which effort can do little to, increase. Usually, however, there is a possibility of change and adaptation to make them better suited to needs, and there is required the use of intelligence to choose among the goods and to employ them in the best way. Further, man can intervene and direct the course of industry; he does not merely gather what is provided. It is this active intervention and effort that is here to be considered.

1. The goal of industrial effort is to increase both the quantity and quality of limited resources; this is economic production. Students have come to understand that the supply of economic resources is limited while the wants are virtually unlimited. A supply of consumer goods addresses an ongoing stream of desires, which leads to value being assigned to things. The purpose of production is to increase the availability of limited resources and to make the supply of goods as extensive as possible. It's worth recalling the two aspects of production mentioned in Chapter 24. Man's role in production is passive when goods come into existence without his effort. One can picture a lazy savage in the tropics, lying under a banana tree, letting fruit fall into his mouth. You can imagine a tribe living off manna, where each day people wake up to find a certain amount of food provided for each individual. Even though no effort could increase that amount, if the food had different flavors and the better qualities were rare, value would emerge, and trading[Pg 258] would occur. There are some goods in daily life that can't be easily increased with effort. However, there's usually a chance for change and adaptation to better meet needs, requiring intelligence to choose the right goods and use them effectively. Furthermore, individuals can intervene and steer the course of industry; they don’t just collect what's available. It's this active intervention and effort that we need to focus on.

The four essential characteristics of value

2. To have value, a thing must be of the right stuff, in the right form, at the right time, and at the right place to gratify wants. A distinction is sometimes made between elemental, form, time, and place value. It is a mistake to say that the value of anything is due to any one of these features, for to have value all must be united in a single thing. But the distinction is useful in emphasizing the missing characteristics, which if supplied, cause value to emerge. Ice may be considered to have form value when produced artificially by a machine, time value when stored from winter to summer, and place value when brought from the north to the south. But not less essential is the psychological condition of a hungry and thirsty population ready to consume the ice. Any act or agent is said to be productive which works in any one of these respects: puts things in better form, or in a more fitting place, or provides them at a more fitting time to serve human wants.

2. For something to have value, it needs to be made of the right materials, in the right shape, at the right time, and in the right location to satisfy desires. People sometimes distinguish between elemental, form, time, and place value. It's a mistake to say that the value of anything comes from just one of these aspects; for something to have value, all must be combined in one item. However, making this distinction can help highlight the missing characteristics, which, when provided, allow value to appear. Ice can be seen as having form value when it’s made by a machine, time value when it’s stored from winter to summer, and place value when it’s moved from the north to the south. But just as important is the psychological state of a hungry and thirsty population ready to consume the ice. Any action or agent is considered productive if it enhances things in any of these ways: it puts items in better shape, relocates them more appropriately, or delivers them at the right time to meet human needs.

Economic vs. technical changes in goods

3. Economic production (in contrast with technical or merely formal production) is such a change in goods as is attended by an increase in value. It is often well to contrast form, appearance, imitation, with the thing itself, the reality. Men sometimes go through the forms of study when their eyes and thoughts are wandering; through the form of getting a college education when they are simply having a good time. Likewise in production there is the form and the reality. The young lady just out of boarding-school rarely produces a masterpiece with the tubes and brushes[Pg 259] that Raphael might have used. The justification for amateur work is to be found in the doing and not in the market value of the result. Blue rosebuds, painted with loving if unskilled touch on red velvet slippers, may bloom into a romance and happiness; but to the economist this appears to be a consumption of good pigment for amusement, not a creation of value. The difference between the form and value of productive effort becomes, in the study of business organization, a most essential question. The significance of leadership and control of industry is found in this fact that economic goods may be united to produce results having either a less or a greater value than the materials that are used.

3. Economic production (unlike just technical or formal production) is a change in goods that increases their value. It's often important to distinguish between form, appearance, imitation, and the actual reality of things. People sometimes go through the motions of studying while their minds are elsewhere, or pursue a college education simply to have fun. The same applies to production; there's a difference between the form and the reality. A young woman fresh out of boarding school rarely creates a masterpiece using the tubes and brushes[Pg 259] that Raphael might have used. The value of amateur work lies in the experience rather than its market price. Blue rosebuds painted with a loving but untrained touch on red velvet slippers may lead to romance and happiness; however, to an economist, that looks like a waste of good paint for fun, not a creation of value. The distinction between the form and value of productive effort becomes crucial in studying business organization. The importance of leadership and control in industry lies in the fact that economic goods can be combined to produce outcomes that may have either lesser or greater value than the materials used.

Acquisition vs. social production

4. Individual acquisition may be contrasted with social production in cases where the individual increases his wealth at the expense of others, without adding to value. Most economic efforts increase the income of the individual and the income of society at the same time. The fruits of the field and the uses of machines are net additions to current income; they are not merely subtracted from the income of one and added to that of another. The increase of products by labor may depress somewhat the exchange value of competing labor, but the general welfare is furthered by the greater abundance. With very slight qualification it is true that in these cases the good of each is the good of all. But in some forms of human effort, social and individual interests clash. When two men bet, one gains and the other loses. The gambler's gain is a loss not only directly to his beaten opponent but indirectly to society. Certain forms of speculation approach dangerously near to the appropriation of the goods of others, and others become outright stealing, or cheating so nearly like stealing that it would be treated as a crime if discovered. But many a man prowls along the border-line of crime all his life and succeeds in making large gains without falling into the clutches of the law. Cheating that can be detected, and outright stealing, are prohibited by the law not because the burglar is an[Pg 260] idler; he loses sleep; he has his trials too. The pursuit of burglary requires courage, effort, and ingenuity, but society does not reward these as virtues nor recognize as production the transfer of wealth from the bank-vault to the pocket of the burglar. It is the aim of social institutions to harmonize individual and social interests in the pursuit of wealth, to force men into lines of action where individual acquisition adds to the sum of social utilities. But there are many marginal cases where human justice discriminates only in a bungling way, and many controverted questions arise at the meeting-point of ethics, economics, and law.

4. Individual acquisition can be compared to social production when a person increases their wealth at the expense of others without creating new value. Most economic activities boost both individual income and social income simultaneously. The products from the land and the uses of machinery contribute positively to overall income; they aren't just taken from one person and given to another. The increase in goods from labor might slightly lower the exchange value of competing labor, but the overall welfare improves due to the higher abundance. With only slight exceptions, it's true that in these cases, what benefits one person benefits everyone. However, in some situations, individual and social interests conflict. When two people gamble, one wins while the other loses. The winner's gain directly harms their opponent and indirectly impacts society as well. Certain types of speculation come dangerously close to taking advantage of others' goods, while others are outright theft or cheating so similar to stealing that it would be treated as a crime if caught. Yet many people spend their lives walking the fine line of crime and manage to gain a lot without facing legal consequences. Detectable cheating and outright theft are outlawed not because the thief is a [Pg 260] slacker; they lose sleep and face their own challenges. Committing burglary requires bravery, effort, and cleverness, but society doesn't reward these traits as virtues nor recognizes the transfer of wealth from a bank vault to a burglar's pocket as productive. Social institutions aim to align individual and social interests in the pursuit of wealth, guiding people toward actions where personal gain contributes positively to the overall social good. Yet, there are many borderline cases where justice seems to distinguish only clumsily, and numerous contentious issues arise at the intersection of ethics, economics, and law.

Industries are socially more or less productive

5. In this sense, productive industries may be distinguished from unproductive ones. The old distinction between productive and unproductive labor rested on the idea that production must be embodied in material and lasting form. We have rejected this for the thought that the tests of production are to be found in feeling, not in outward things. The distinction, therefore, between productive and unproductive labor must now be of a very different kind. Viewed from the social standpoint, the efforts of men may be seen to be directed along more or less productive lines. Enterprise and effort shade off from the more to the less productive, from the extreme where the value is a net addition to wealth, through other cases where one's gain is partly at the cost of others, to fraud and crime where there is merely a transfer of ownership.

5. In this sense, we can distinguish between productive and unproductive industries. The traditional distinction between productive and unproductive labor was based on the idea that production had to result in material and lasting goods. We have moved away from this and now believe that the true measures of production are found in emotions, not just physical items. Consequently, the difference between productive and unproductive labor must be understood in a new way. From a social perspective, we can see that people's efforts are directed towards varying levels of productivity. Business ventures and hard work can range from highly productive, where value contributes directly to wealth, to less productive activities where someone's gain comes at the expense of others, and even to fraud and crime, where there is only a shift in ownership.

§ II. COMBINATION OF THE FACTORS

The factors of production defined

1. The various parts, materials, and agents that unite to form products are called the factors of production. In a general sense every separate thing that enters into industry is a factor; as, in agriculture, for example, the seed, plows, fields, fences, barns, cattle, labor. But usually in economic discussion, these numerous factors are grouped in large classes. The main factors are two, variously named as man[Pg 261] and nature, or labor and material agents, or humanity and wealth. Rejecting, as we have, the old view as to the nature of consumption goods and as to the nature and possibility of the distinction between "land" and artificial capital, we class under wealth all material economic agents whatsoever. The discussion of labor and wages has broadly laid down the principles that apply to the value of human effort, but the factor of directing energy presents in modern society so many important features that it calls for special and fuller consideration.

1. The different parts, materials, and agents that come together to create products are referred to as the factors of production. Generally speaking, anything that plays a role in industry is a factor; for example, in agriculture, you have seeds, plows, fields, fences, barns, cattle, and labor. However, in economic discussions, these many factors are usually organized into larger categories. The main factors are two, referred to in different ways as people[Pg 261] and nature, or labor and material agents, or humanity and wealth. By rejecting the old perspective on the nature of consumption goods and the possible distinction between "land" and artificial capital, we categorize all material economic agents under wealth. The exploration of labor and wages has broadly established principles that relate to the value of human effort, but the factor of directing energy has so many critical aspects in modern society that it deserves special and more comprehensive attention.

Progressive stages of control over natural conditions

2. The economic progress of society has been marked by decreasing dependence on the bounties and chances of nature and by increasing control of natural forces by man. Various stages of progress in human history have been recognized. First is the stage of appropriation—the stage of hunting, or of fishing, or of gathering fruits. Man in this stage is still an animal in his economic methods, not guiding and controlling nature, but merely gathering what nature chances to bring forth. The limitations to man's powers in this stage are marked. There is excess of supply and waste at one season, scarcity and great suffering at another. With such crude utilization of the bounties of nature, a vast area will support but a small population. When sheep and cattle have been domesticated, and where there is a large area for grazing, industry rises to the pastoral stage. While still dependent on nature's bounties for the feeding of his cattle, man is hourly intervening to increase, regulate, and improve the supply of food and materials. Famines are more rare, economic welfare is greater, a greater population is nourished on the same area. The agricultural stage begins whenever man plants seeds, trims, tends, and increases by his care the supply of vegetable food. This is a still greater intervention in the course of nature. Man anticipates the future, directs forces, and groups materials to his purpose of getting a regular food-supply. He is thus himself forced into settled life, begins hand-production, and[Pg 262] makes the first steps in commerce. Then gradually comes the industrial stage, in which control over nature grows, supplies increase, machinery and motive forces are utilized, and humanity is in the full tide of industrial development. These are not sharply marked changes, but throughout all there is a growth of security, of certainty, and of productivity. With man's increasing power and foresight, chance is lessened, for directing energy takes its place.

2. Society's economic progress has been characterized by a decreasing reliance on the gifts and randomness of nature, along with an increasing mastery of natural forces by humans. Different stages of progress in human history have been identified. The first stage is appropriation—the stage of hunting, fishing, or gathering fruits. At this stage, humans are still acting like animals in their economic practices, simply collecting what nature provides without guiding or controlling it. The limitations on human capabilities in this stage are clear. There are times of excess supply and waste in one season, followed by scarcity and severe suffering in another. With such basic use of nature's resources, a vast area can only support a small population. Once sheep and cattle are domesticated, and there is ample space for grazing, society enters the pastoral stage. Although still reliant on nature's resources for feeding livestock, humans actively work to increase, manage, and improve the availability of food and materials. Famines become less frequent, economic conditions improve, and a larger population can thrive in the same area. The agricultural stage begins when humans plant seeds, cultivate, care for, and enhance the supply of plant-based food through their efforts. This marks a significant intervention in the natural order. Humans start to anticipate future needs, direct energies, and organize resources to ensure a steady food supply. This forces them into a settled lifestyle, sparks hand-production, and[Pg 262] initiates the first steps in trade. Gradually, the industrial stage emerges, where mastery over nature increases, supplies grow, machinery and energy sources are employed, and humanity fully engages in industrial growth. These shifts are not sharply defined, but throughout all these phases, there is an increase in security, certainty, and productivity. As humans gain more power and foresight, randomness diminishes, replaced by directed energy.

Increasing importance of skilled organization and direction
The source of American enterprise

3. For a high efficiency of production, as a whole, conditions must favor the best organization and direction of industry. Industry is dependent primarily upon natural resources. Climate, rainfall, iron deposits, fuel, supply of wood or coal, predetermine in large measure the limits within, and the direction in which, the industry of any community can move. The progress of production depends also on an increasing efficiency of labor as embodied in individual men, and upon social and political conditions making possible an increase of capital. But—a condition as important as any of these—production is dependent also on a wise combination of the factors. Social, political, and economic conditions must be such as to call forth the factor of direction and control of industry, to make possible industrial progress. This is one of the greatest sources of America's superiority to-day. It has been strikingly said that it is now no longer "young America and old Europe," but "old America and young Europe." America is older in industrial experience; Europe, with undeveloped resources, awaits the touch of American methods and machinery. There are dynamic forces in American society not present in equal degree in any other. It is therefore not alone the great resources of coal and iron,—equal resources may be found in unexplored parts of the world,—it is the dynamic social forces, invention, enterprise, and organization, which have brought America to the forefront in industry. Her natural resources have thus yielded an incentive and a premium to enterprise as a sort of by-product. Absence of caste, political liberty, the[Pg 263] democracy following the spread of the frontier, have not made it possible for every one to succeed, but they have made it possible, as nowhere else in the world, for real ability to scale the barriers of birth, poverty, and hardship. A conservative population never can equal a progressive population in industrial efficiency. It has been remarked that America has little to fear from Oriental competition so long as the avenues of education and enterprise are open to her young men, insuring her the highest capacity in the organization and direction of industry.

3. For high production efficiency overall, conditions must support the best organization and management of industry. Industry mainly relies on natural resources. Factors like climate, rainfall, iron deposits, and the availability of wood or coal largely determine the extent and direction in which any community's industry can develop. The advancement of production also depends on the growing efficiency of labor, represented by individuals, and on social and political conditions that allow for an increase in capital. However, an equally important condition is that production also relies on a smart combination of these factors. Social, political, and economic conditions must be structured to facilitate the direction and management of industry, enabling industrial progress. This is one of the biggest reasons for America's current advantage. It has been famously stated that it's no longer "young America and old Europe," but "old America and young Europe." America is more advanced in industrial experience; Europe, with its untapped resources, is waiting for the influence of American methods and machinery. There are dynamic forces in American society that aren't as prevalent elsewhere. Thus, it's not just the abundant resources of coal and iron—similar resources can be found in unexplored areas around the world—it's the dynamic social forces, innovation, initiative, and organization that have propelled America to the top in industry. Her natural resources have thus provided an incentive and advantage for entrepreneurship as a sort of bonus. The lack of caste, political freedom, and the democracy that followed the expansion of the frontier have not guaranteed success for everyone, but they have allowed genuine talent to overcome the challenges of birth, poverty, and hardship more than anywhere else. A conservative population can never match a progressive one in industrial efficiency. It has been noted that America has little to fear from competition with Asia as long as the pathways to education and enterprise remain open for her young men, ensuring her a high level of capability in organizing and managing industry.

Growing specialization of industry

4. A high efficiency of industry is dependent on many social causes making possible a great specialization. It was said in another connection that division of labor is dependent upon the size of the market. With a large population massed at one spot, so that the demand for even the less important products is large, there may be a high specialization of industry. An increase of transportation, such as railways and telegraphs, is equivalent for many economic purposes to growth of population on one spot. In colonial days it took ten days to go from Boston to Philadelphia, and two weeks to go to Washington. San Francisco is now for many economic purposes but one fourth as far from Boston as Washington was at that time. California and the eastern states are distant only thirty minutes by telegraph and three days and a fraction by railroad, and are thus in many respects in the same market. The great development during the past century in the means of communication and of carriage has made possible, as never before, the massing of population to secure the advantages of division of labor in most lines, without meeting the hitherto insurmountable difficulty in the securing of food for such large numbers in a limited space. The population draws its food from the whole vast area; whereas it is massed at the points more favorable for other products and can make use of the most highly specialized machinery. These several conditions thus have favored the growth of large industry under a single control and direction,[Pg 264] on a scale never before approached. These changes have brought in their train social problems connected with the concentration of economic power. It remains to be seen whether the unquestioned economies of this new organization can be retained and improved while it is divested of its evils.

4. A high level of industrial efficiency relies on various social factors that enable significant specialization. It's been noted elsewhere that the division of labor depends on market size. When a large population is concentrated in one location, there can be a strong demand for even less crucial products, leading to high industrial specialization. Improved transportation, like railroads and telegraphs, essentially serves the same purpose as an increased population in one area for many economic reasons. Back in colonial times, traveling from Boston to Philadelphia took ten days, and getting to Washington took two weeks. Now, for many economic purposes, San Francisco is only a quarter as far from Boston as Washington was back then. California and the eastern states are just thirty minutes apart by telegraph and a little over three days by train, placing them in many ways within the same market. The significant advancements over the past century in communication and transportation have made it possible, like never before, to gather large populations to take advantage of the division of labor across most sectors, without facing the previously insurmountable challenge of securing food for such large groups in a confined area. The population sources its food from a vast region, while being concentrated in areas more suited for other products, allowing for the use of highly specialized machinery. These various circumstances have thus supported the expansion of large industries under a single control and management,[Pg 264] on an unprecedented scale. These changes have also led to social issues related to the concentration of economic power. It remains to be seen whether the clear efficiencies of this new organization can be maintained and improved while addressing its negative aspects.

Growing importance of directive ability

5. With the growing division of labor, grows the need of the highest ability for the directing of industry. Ability may be judged by various standards. From one point of view, the scientific mind, grouping facts in the cold light of reason to arrive at truth, is the highest type. But supreme, each in his own sphere, are also the artist expressing, through painting, poetry, dramatic action, and music, the subtleties and complexities of feeling, the moral philosopher, the prophet, the preacher, in the best sense of the term the teacher, all aiding to guide the spiritual forces of humanity along lines that make for social welfare. Not least is the business enterpriser, whose function is to direct the economic forces for production. It is vain to assign a mean place to the organizing intelligence and its social work. Its importance grows apace with the growing magnitude and complexity of industry. Misjudgment now will destroy more wealth, and wise judgment can produce larger results, than ever before. The captain of industry also may work as an artist or as a gambler; he may, by the methods he pursues, uplift the moral plane of his society or he may help to corrupt and degrade it. No citizen is in control of more potent influence for good or ill than the successful business organizer. On the attitude of society toward him, and on the standards to which he is held, depend in large measure the use that will be made of his exceptional powers.

5. As the division of labor increases, so does the need for top-tier skills to manage industry. Ability can be assessed by different criteria. From one perspective, the scientific mind, which organizes facts logically to uncover truth, is considered the highest form. However, equally important in their own fields are the artist who conveys the nuances and complexities of emotions through painting, poetry, drama, and music, the moral philosopher, the prophet, the preacher, and, in the best sense, the teacher—all contributing to guide humanity's spiritual forces toward social well-being. Also significant is the business entrepreneur, whose role is to manage economic forces for production. It’s misguided to downplay the role of organizing intelligence and its social impact. Its significance increases with the growing size and complexity of industry. Miscalculations now can destroy more wealth, while wise decisions can yield greater outcomes than ever before. The industrial leader may act as an artist or a risk-taker; depending on their methods, they can either elevate the moral standards of society or contribute to its corruption and decay. No one has more powerful influence for good or bad than the successful business organizer. The way society views them, and the standards they are held to, significantly shape how their exceptional abilities will be utilized.


CHAPTER 29

BUSINESS ORGANIZATION AND THE ENTERPRISER'S FUNCTION

§ I. THE DIRECTION OF INDUSTRY

Judgment and self-direction as elements in personal skill

1. In the simplest kinds of individual production the value of the results depends largely on intelligent choice. Even for the solitary worker the choice of the right time to do work is most important. The first thing Robinson Crusoe did was to turn to the ship to save as much as possible of the cargo before it was dashed in pieces by the waves. If he had begun first to till the soil to provide a future supply of food it would have shown one kind of foresight, but it would have shown very poor judgment. Every moment of delay in recovering the cargo of the wrecked vessel cost him many useful materials. The humblest farmer has a great range of choice and a need of good judgment in fixing the time to sow, to reap, to do each simple task. There is the same need to-day for the small shopkeepers, for the blacksmiths, for the small producers of all kinds to make wise choice of time in the use of their own labor. There is also a wide range of choice in the distributing and combining of labor, agents, and materials. A limited supply of agents can be used to secure a variety of goods, more or less desirable. There are many chances for mistake, but in the long run it is judgment, not chance, that determines the success of one man as compared with another. There is a choice in ways and methods by which a thing can be done. There are many wrong ways, there is but one[Pg 266] best way, at any stage of industrial progress. While most work is done in customary ways and little independent judgment is required, yet in every business from time to time new problems arise and call for an exercise of choice as to methods. Moral qualities are continually called for, such as control of impulse, and the giving up of the comfort of the moment. The wisdom of our fathers is embodied in a multitude of proverbs that suggest the wise course. Men must "make hay while the sun shines," not lie in the shade. But virtue fails less often from lack of knowledge than from lack of will. As men differ in judgment, character, and will-power, their products differ, even in the simplest circumstances. The ability to choose and to do wisely is an element in personal skill.

1. In the simplest forms of individual production, the value of the outcomes largely relies on smart choices. Even for a lone worker, picking the right time to get things done is crucial. The first thing Robinson Crusoe did was to head to the ship to save as much of the cargo as he could before the waves destroyed it. If he had started by farming to ensure future food supplies, it might have shown one type of foresight, but it would have been a poor decision. Every moment wasted in recovering the cargo from the wrecked ship cost him many valuable resources. Even the most basic farmer needs to make good decisions about when to plant, harvest, and tackle each simple task. Today, small shopkeepers, blacksmiths, and small producers of all kinds also need to wisely choose when to use their labor. There are also many options in how to distribute and combine labor, agents, and materials. A limited number of agents can be used to secure a variety of goods, some more desirable than others. There are plenty of chances for mistakes, but in the long run, it's judgment, not luck, that defines one person's success compared to another's. There are different ways and methods to accomplish tasks. Many methods are wrong, but there’s usually one[Pg 266] best way at any stage of industrial development. While most work is done in traditional ways with little need for independent judgment, new challenges in every business occasionally arise, requiring thoughtful choices about methods. Moral qualities like self-control and sacrificing immediate comfort are always necessary. The wisdom of our ancestors is reflected in countless proverbs that suggest wise paths. People must "make hay while the sun shines," instead of lounging in the shade. But often, virtue falters not due to a lack of knowledge but because of a lack of will. As people vary in judgment, character, and willpower, their products will also differ, even in the simplest situations. The ability to choose wisely and act is a key part of personal skill.

Direction of a group of workers

2. When men work in an associated group, the direction of effort becomes relatively more important. The first and simplest advantage of association is working in unison. Men unite their muscular efforts for a single task, and accomplish what is impossible to them working singly. But when many work in unison, the right selection of time and way is of greater importance; a mistake will waste more materials and agents. If association is to yield its advantages, there must be division of labor; hence harmony of effort, hence agreement or direction. While the gain of well-directed association is large, the waste of ill-directed effort is greater, when specialization has taken place, than with isolated workers. Most communal societies have failed because of the lack of a good head. The few exceptional successes have been due to the presence of a man of superior ability, such as George Rapp of the Harmonist Community, who, had he lived in this day, could have become easily the head of a great business corporation.

2. When people work in a group, how that effort is directed becomes even more important. The first and simplest benefit of working together is the ability to act in harmony. People combine their physical efforts for a single purpose and achieve what would be impossible individually. However, when many are working together, choosing the right timing and approach becomes more crucial; a mistake can lead to a lot more wasted materials and resources. For group work to be effective, there needs to be a division of tasks; this creates a coordinated effort and clear direction. While the benefits of well-organized teamwork are significant, the waste from poorly directed efforts is even greater, especially when specialization is involved, compared to when individuals work alone. Most communal societies have failed due to a lack of strong leadership. The few that have succeeded were led by individuals with exceptional talent, like George Rapp of the Harmonist Community, who, if he lived today, could easily have become the head of a large business corporation.

Direction of interrelated groups

3. Where various industrial groups are associated, direction becomes still more important. In the single group it is an internal harmony alone that is needed. The work of a dozen men must be so arranged that each is in his fitting[Pg 267] place. But as this group comes into contact with others, the relationship becomes two-fold, and there must be both internal and external harmony. The more complex the economic organization of society, the more the chance of mistake and the more injurious are the mistakes to a wide range of interests. Large amounts of capital and labor can be rapidly lost through lack of wise direction of associated groups.

3. When different industrial groups are connected, leadership becomes even more crucial. In a single group, all that's needed is internal harmony. The work of a dozen people has to be arranged so that each one is in their appropriate[Pg 267] role. But when this group interacts with others, the relationship becomes two-fold, requiring both internal and external harmony. The more complicated the economic structure of society, the higher the risk of errors, which can harm a wide range of interests. Large amounts of capital and labor can quickly be wasted if there's a lack of effective leadership among connected groups.

Greatest need now of capable direction of industry

4. The increased efficiency of industry has been accompanied by the specialization of control. The crude, early methods of enforcing harmony in industry were slavery and political subordination. Under division of labor, with free workmen, industry is ruled by impersonal economic forces that bring the less capable under the direction of the more capable. This work is rudely done, no doubt, but the penalties of bad direction of labor and capital are so great that blundering cannot be permitted. The man who shovels dirt must do it at the right time and place if, in this complex society, it counts for something and gives the effort value. If he cannot choose well for himself, he comes under direction. The average man cannot decide nearly as well here as he could on a desert island where and when to put in his spade. There it would be to raise food for the current year; here it may be to dig a canal or a tunnel whose uses will not become actual for many years. The more distant the end sought, the more difficult is the choice. To every worker, according to his personal skill, is left some degree of choice in the method of his work, but in a large part of industry the range of choice is very narrow. The man with the shovel and the man with the hoe come under direction.

4. The increased efficiency of industry has come with specialized control. The rough, early ways of maintaining order in industry were slavery and political dominance. With the division of labor and free workers, industry is now guided by impersonal economic forces that place the less skilled under the supervision of the more skilled. This process might be clumsy, but the consequences of poor management of labor and capital are so severe that mistakes can't be tolerated. The person shoveling dirt has to do it at the right time and place if, in this complex society, it has any significance and gives their effort value. If they can't make good choices for themselves, they fall under supervision. The average person can't make decisions nearly as effectively here as they could on a deserted island regarding when and where to use their spade. On the island, it would be about growing food for that year; here, it might be about digging a canal or a tunnel whose benefits won't be seen for many years. The more distant the goal, the harder the choice becomes. Each worker is given some degree of choice in how they do their work based on their personal skills, but in many parts of the industry, that range of choice is quite limited. The person with the shovel and the person with the hoe are both subject to direction.

§ II. QUALITIES OF A BUSINESS ORGANIZER

Technical knowledge and skill

1. The organizer and director of industry must first have technical knowledge of methods, processes, and materials. The qualities required in the direction of industry are implied[Pg 268] in the foregoing section, but they may be more specifically enumerated. Knowledge of technical processes is relatively more important in the direction of industry in the earlier stage. In the single independent producer it is the quality most desirable. He must know the quality of the materials with which he works and the best modes of combining them. But, as industrial organization becomes more complex, only a broad knowledge and ability to judge of the results of different processes and to compare plans are necessary in the organizer. He can hire the technical knowledge of details required in the larger management of business. Draftsmen, engineers, pattern-makers, men with far more education and capacity in certain lines than the business manager, work under his direction.

1. The organizer and director of industry must first have a solid understanding of methods, processes, and materials. The qualities needed to lead in industry are hinted at[Pg 268] in the previous section, but they can be outlined more clearly. Understanding technical processes is particularly important for industry leaders at the early stages. For an independent producer, this knowledge is the most crucial. They must know the quality of the materials they're working with and the best ways to combine them. However, as industrial organization grows more complicated, what’s needed from the organizer is a broad understanding and the ability to evaluate the outcomes of various processes and compare plans. They can hire specialists for the detailed technical knowledge required in larger business operations. Draftsmen, engineers, pattern-makers, and others with greater education and expertise in specific areas work under their direction.

Judgment of men

2. The organizer requires ability to judge men and tact in relations with them. In the small group, ability to get on well in personal contact with workmen is of great importance. Especially rare is the genial manner that wins the confidence and even the affection of the men. A sense of humor and the ability to turn a joke are said to have obviated many a strike and thus to have prevented losses both to the employer and to the men. In large affairs much of this managing tact can be hired in good foremen; but the organizer must still have a knowledge of men, ability to judge of human nature, to select his subordinates, and to animate them with his own purposes and plans. Mr. Carnegie has said that an appropriate epitaph for himself would be, "He was a man who knew how to surround himself with men abler than he was himself." That seems too modest; but in a sense it is not, because he claims for himself, and justly, the highest of all industrial qualities. A great administrator in political or industrial affairs can dispense with everything else rather than with this, the supreme quality of the great organizer.

2. The organizer needs to be good at judging people and handling relationships. In a small group, getting along well with workers is really important. It's especially rare to have a friendly demeanor that earns the trust and even affection of the team. Having a sense of humor and the ability to make jokes is said to have prevented many strikes, saving both the employer and the workers from losses. In larger settings, a lot of this management skill can be found in capable foremen, but the organizer still needs to understand people, judge human nature, choose the right subordinates, and inspire them with his own goals and plans. Mr. Carnegie once stated that an appropriate epitaph for himself would be, "He was a man who knew how to surround himself with people more capable than he was." That may seem too humble; however, it isn’t entirely, as he rightfully claims the highest industrial quality for himself. A great leader in politics or business can do without everything else, but not this supreme quality of the exceptional organizer.

Foresight in commercial affairs

3. The organizer must have unusual foresight and the ability to form a large commercial policy. This proposition[Pg 269] is to be interpreted relatively to the task before the organizer, and to the size of the business. Modern industry anticipates demand far more than did primitive industry. Large amounts of materials and energy are embarked in directions from which they cannot be recalled. With the progress of electrical engineering it soon may become possible to recall at any moment a cargo embarked for a distant port. But no wireless telegraphy is able to recall the great masses of capital that are embarked on distant and definite journeys in modern business. The organizer anticipates future demand, and prepares for it. The process has been figuratively expressed somewhat as follows: the enterpriser throws into the crucible great quantities of material; they melt, and an industrial result is secured, but whether the deposit is greater in value than the material is a question that cannot be answered for years. The need of anticipating demand is greater to-day than ever before, and this requires large investments months and even years in advance. The losses are proportionally large if there is miscalculation of demand. A large commercial policy is one that takes into account the more distant factors, and anticipates the new conditions. The rare ability to do this is rightly called statemanship in economic affairs.

3. The organizer must have exceptional foresight and the ability to develop a broad commercial strategy. This statement[Pg 269] should be understood in relation to the organizer's responsibilities and the scale of the business. Modern industries predict demand much better than primitive industries did. Significant amounts of materials and energy are invested in pursuits that cannot be reversed. With advancements in electrical engineering, it may soon be possible to call back a shipment headed to a distant port at any time. However, no form of wireless communication can retrieve the vast amounts of capital that are committed to specific, far-off ventures in contemporary business. The organizer anticipates future demand and makes preparations accordingly. This process has been metaphorically described as follows: the entrepreneur pours large quantities of material into a crucible; they melt down, resulting in industrial output, but whether the final product is worth more than the original material is a question that may take years to answer. The need to forecast demand is more pressing today than ever, requiring substantial investments months and even years ahead of time. The potential losses are significantly greater if there's a miscalculation of demand. A broad commercial strategy considers more distant factors and foresees new conditions. The rare skill to do this is rightly referred to as statesmanship in economic matters.

Command of financial resources

4. The organizer need not himself have great wealth, but he must have ability to command financial resources. Business to-day is done in many cases with borrowed capital. Even a subscription to stock is frequently as much in the nature of a loan, made in reliance on the reputation of the organizer, as an investment for profits. There are many temporary needs that require sudden loans. The confidence of investors, whether banks, trust companies, individual shareholders or investors in bonds, must be secured by the organizer. Good judgment of the money market often is as vital as judgment of the market for the particular product. In some of the largest corporate enterprises this quality becomes the most essential.

4. The organizer doesn't need to be wealthy, but they must be able to access financial resources. These days, business is often done with borrowed money. Even buying stock can frequently feel more like a loan, relying on the organizer's reputation, rather than a straightforward investment for profits. There are many short-term needs that require quick loans. The organizer must earn the trust of investors, whether they are banks, trust companies, individual shareholders, or bond investors. Being good at understanding the money market is often just as important as knowing the market for the specific product. In some of the largest corporate ventures, this ability becomes the most crucial.

Scarcity of great organizing ability
The industrial leaders

5. Organizing ability of the highest order is rarely found. This is almost a superfluous statement after the foregoing. According to the theory of chances, such a combination and balancing of qualities is likely to occur in very few cases. Even where it exists, it may not be discovered or developed. The man may not find his opportunity, nor the task the man. There are many misfits in the world. On the occasion of the visit of Prince Henry of Prussia to America, in 1902, he was entertained at luncheon in New York with one hundred of the leaders in invention, finance, and industry, wherein have been the most characteristic achievements of America. In jocular reference to the French Academy, whose members are the forty most noted literary men of France, the newspapers called this the meeting of America's one hundred immortals. There were J. P. Morgan, the great financier; Vanderbilt, Hill, and Harriman, the railroad kings; Carnegie, the iron magnate; Irving Scott, "the man who built the Oregon"—nearly all the company deserving a place at the table mainly by reason of excellence as business organizers. Such a gathering has a dramatic interest as presenting the greatest leaders of industry, but about other tables might be gathered thousands of other less notable figures worthy to be accounted captains of industry in their several fields. One may well ask, How did they come into the important places they occupy?

5. Top-notch organizing skills are a rare find. This almost goes without saying after what we've discussed. According to probability theory, such a combination and balance of qualities is likely to happen in very few cases. Even when it does exist, it might not be noticed or nurtured. A person may not come across their chance, nor may the task find the right person. There are many misfits in the world. When Prince Henry of Prussia visited America in 1902, he was treated to lunch in New York with one hundred of the leaders in invention, finance, and industry, showcasing America's most significant achievements. In a playful nod to the French Academy, which consists of the forty most prominent literary figures in France, the newspapers dubbed this gathering America's one hundred immortals. Among them were J. P. Morgan, the great financier; Vanderbilt, Hill, and Harriman, the railroad moguls; Carnegie, the steel titan; and Irving Scott, "the man who built the Oregon"—nearly all of them deserving a place at the table mainly due to their excellence as business organizers. Such a gathering is dramatically interesting as it highlights the greatest industrial leaders, but at other tables, thousands of other less famous individuals could also be considered captains of industry in their respective fields. One might wonder, how did they attain the important positions they hold?

§ III. THE SELECTION OF ABILITY

Various roads to industrial leadership

1. The men actually in control of industry have been selected in manifold ways. Skill develops a small industry into a large one. A small factory owner gradually adds machine to machine, building to building, till he finds himself at the head of a great industry. Or an employee develops ability and becomes an employer. Who does not know of some one who, as a small boy, went into a store to do chores, worked up to a clerkship and, enlisting the confidence[Pg 271] of men of wealth, was enabled to establish a business of his own and become an employer? Others have won promotion from the ranks to the head of a large industry in which they secured at last a controlling interest. Employees that have proved their ability may be selected by the directors of a stock company. Men that have worked their way up from the ranks may bequeath their business positions to their sons and grandsons, as in the case of the Vanderbilts and the Goulds. And finally, but rarely, there may be selection by fellow-workmen in the case of coöperative business.

1. The men who actually run industry have been chosen in various ways. Talent turns a small business into a large one. A small factory owner gradually adds machines and buildings until he finds himself leading a major industry. Or an employee shows their skills and becomes an employer. Who hasn’t heard of someone who, as a young boy, started doing chores in a store, worked up to being a clerk, and, by gaining the trust[Pg 271] of wealthy individuals, was able to start their own business and become an employer? Others have climbed the ranks to the top of a large industry where they eventually gained a controlling stake. Employees who have demonstrated their capabilities may be chosen by the board of a stock company. Those who have worked their way up may pass their business roles to their sons and grandsons, like the Vanderbilts and the Goulds. And finally, though rarely, there can be selection by fellow workers in the case of cooperative businesses.

Success as the evidence of ability

2. There is a constant selective process: dropping out the weak and advancing the efficient organizer. There is, to be sure, an element of chance in this selection. The process in general is a rude one. Accidents and unforeseen changes, industrial crises, failure of health at a critical moment, fraud and crime, may defeat men of ability and they may never regain their foothold. Lack of experience may lead to disaster a naturally able but youthful heir, too suddenly burdened with the responsibilities of a fortune. On the other hand, men of limited ability may inherit fortunes and preserve them by caution, without enterprise. It is not always true, even in America, that "It is but three generations from shirt-sleeves to shirt-sleeves," although many fortunes slip away from the sons of rich fathers. In general, success in retaining the control of a business is an evidence of considerable ability. By loss of fortune unwisely risked, through unforeseen changes in methods, and after manifold blunders, the less capable drop out. Thus, by the ceaseless working of competition, the higher places are taken by those most capable of filling them, and the efficiency both of the employers and of the workmen is increased.

2. There's a constant process of selection: getting rid of the weak and promoting the efficient organizer. There’s definitely an element of chance in this selection. Overall, the process is tough. Accidents, unexpected changes, industrial crises, health failures at critical times, fraud, and crime can bring down capable people, and they may never get back on their feet. Lack of experience can lead to disaster for a naturally talented but young heir suddenly overwhelmed by the responsibilities of wealth. On the flip side, people with limited ability can inherit fortunes and keep them through caution, without taking any risks. It’s not always true, even in America, that "It only takes three generations to go from riches to rags," although many fortunes do slip away from the sons of wealthy fathers. Generally, being successful at maintaining control of a business shows a significant level of ability. Through the loss of wealth due to unwise risks, unexpected changes in methods, and numerous mistakes, the less capable fall away. As a result, through the ongoing process of competition, higher positions are filled by those most qualified for them, and the effectiveness of both employers and workers improves.

Various modes of business organization

3. In the various kinds of business organization the merits of men and of methods are tested. The independent producer working entirely alone, directing his own industry, is analogous to the animal organism of a single cell. More complex is the family partnership found often in early stages[Pg 272] of industry but more rarely now, where the father directs the work of his children and all share in common. The simplest form of the wage system is the single employer with a few assistants. When the employer is in danger of losing valuable assistants, he sometimes gives them a share in the business. In the ordinary partnership, two or more men divide the ownership and duties, agreeing as to the division of control. Coöperation among workmen, though rare, gives an unusual opportunity for the discovery of special talent. The dominant form of organization to-day is that of the stock company, or corporation, the ownership of which is divided among the holders of shares of stock, or of certificates of membership.

3. In the various types of business organization, the skills of people and methods are assessed. The independent producer working entirely alone, managing his own business, is like a single-celled organism. More complex is the family partnership, often seen in the early stages[Pg 272] of industry but less common now, where the father manages the work of his children, and they all share their resources. The simplest version of the wage system is the single employer employing a few assistants. When the employer risks losing valuable assistants, he sometimes offers them a stake in the business. In a typical partnership, two or more individuals share ownership and responsibilities, agreeing on how to divide control. Cooperation among workers, though infrequent, provides a unique opportunity to discover special talents. The most common form of organization today is the stock company, or corporation, where ownership is divided among shareholders or members with certificates.

Many chances to try ability

This variety of organization affords opportunity for a two-fold test: that of the ability of men and of the merits, in varying circumstances, of the different forms of organization. Methods of organization are constantly tested by their results. Men having money to invest are asking whether they would be better off to go into business by themselves, or to join with a partner, or to buy stock in some large corporation. Each of these forms of organization has its peculiar advantages. A stock company can better enlist large amounts of capital, while the individual employer is generally more free from dictation and can adapt his business more quickly to changing conditions. At the same time this variety of organization offers better opportunities for managing ability to show its metal. On the watch towers of industry are many observers sweeping the horizon for the appearance of men of business talent. Some characters develop better under direction; others prove that nowhere does native ability count for more, and mere book-schooling for less, than in business administration. There is some ground for the belief that a college education does not increase executive capacity in business. Such ability often seems to be a freak of nature and a product of practical experience, rather than the result of college training.

This variety of organization provides a chance for a two-fold test: the ability of individuals and the advantages of different organizational forms in various situations. Organizational methods are constantly evaluated based on their results. People looking to invest money want to know whether they would be better off starting their own business, partnering with someone, or buying shares in a large corporation. Each of these organizational forms has its unique benefits. A stock company can attract large amounts of capital more easily, while an individual business owner is usually more independent and can adapt their business quicker to changing conditions. At the same time, this variety of organization provides better opportunities for management skills to shine. There are many observers in the industry keeping an eye out for talented business people. Some individuals thrive under guidance, while others demonstrate that natural talent matters more and formal education matters less in business management. There is some belief that a college education doesn't enhance executive ability in business. This ability often appears to be a rare trait and a result of practical experience rather than something gained through college training.


CHAPTER 30

COST OF PRODUCTION

§ 1. COST OF PRODUCTION FROM THE ENTERPRISER'S POINT OF VIEW

The enterpriser's cost

1. The task of the enterpriser is to get together the essential factors to secure valuable products. The enterpriser must first decide what product he will endeavor to secure, and the kind, the place, the time, the quantity, and the quality. He must then select in the right proportion the materials, labor, plant, and machinery necessary for that product. He must purchase these factors in the market at the lowest price he can, unite them and sell the product to recover the expenses in the selling price. A thousand items enter into the cost and perhaps a single product emerges. What the business man thus pays out, expressed in money form, are the costs that are here to be considered.

1. The job of the entrepreneur is to bring together the key elements needed to create valuable products. The entrepreneur must first decide what product they will aim to create, along with the type, location, timing, quantity, and quality. Next, they need to choose the right mix of materials, labor, equipment, and machinery required for that product. They should buy these elements in the market at the lowest possible price, combine them, and sell the final product to recover the expenses through the selling price. Numerous factors contribute to the cost, and often only one product results. The monetary amounts the businessperson spends are the costs that should be taken into account.

Several meanings of cost

2. The term cost of production is used in several senses, the chief of which are money cost, psychic cost, and alternative cost. The ambiguity of this term is a source of much confusion. Psychic cost is the pain, fatigue, irksomeness of labor. This is not definitely measured except at rare points. When the pain of work more than offsets the value of the product, the worker who is free to determine the length of his own working-day, stops. At that point the psychic cost and the utility of the marginal unit are almost equal in intensity—the one as a positive, the other as a negative quantity. But the value of the product as a whole cannot be related to the psychic cost or sacrifice, and therefore it cannot[Pg 274] serve as a measure of cost in every-day business. Alternative cost is any good or gratification that must be given up when any other good is chosen. One may stay at home and read a book or go on a picnic; the pleasure of reading the book will cost the pleasure of the picnic. A good dress may cost a happy vacation that must be given up for it. In this sense, each thing is a cost of every other thing that might be chosen in the place of it. Alternative cost is therefore manifold and indefinite. The thought is significant at the moment of a choice, but it is not constantly measurable for practical purposes. The money cost is the practical cost generally implied in the term cost of production. It expresses not the pain of the laborer in doing the work, not the sacrifice of the owner of the capital in saving the money, but merely the sum of money paid out by the producer. There is frequent confusion of these ideas in economic discussion, few even of the leading economists of the nineteenth century having quite escaped it.

2. The term cost of production is used in several ways, primarily referring to money cost, psychic cost, and alternative cost. The ambiguity of this term causes a lot of confusion. Psychic cost refers to the discomfort, fatigue, and annoyance of labor. This isn’t easily measured except in rare instances. When the pain of work outweighs the value of the product, the worker, if able to choose their working hours, will stop. At that moment, psychic cost and the utility of the last unit produced are nearly equal in intensity—one is positive, the other negative. However, the overall value of the product can't be directly related to psychic cost or sacrifice, which is why it can't[Pg 274] serve as a measure of cost in everyday business. Alternative cost is any benefit or enjoyment that must be sacrificed when choosing one good over another. For example, you might choose to stay home and read a book instead of going on a picnic; the enjoyment of reading comes at the cost of the enjoyment of the picnic. A nice dress might mean giving up a happy vacation that you could have taken instead. In this way, each option incurs a cost in relation to every other possible choice. Alternative cost is therefore varied and indefinite. It's a key consideration at the time of a choice, but it isn’t consistently measurable for practical purposes. The money cost represents the practical cost generally associated with the term cost of production. It doesn’t reflect the discomfort of the worker or the sacrifice of the capital owner in saving the money; it simply represents the total amount of money spent by the producer. This confusion among these concepts is common in economic discussions, and even leading economists of the nineteenth century often struggled to differentiate them.

The cost of the factors is their market price

3. The enterpriser, looking upon the cost of most of the factors as fixed, seeks to combine them as economically as possible. Whether the enterpriser is running a factory or a farm, is engaged in a retail or a wholesale store, is conducting a school, or a railroad, he has to solve much the same problem. By close attention, good judgment, skilful bargaining, he may be able to buy slightly cheaper than his competitors, and thus have an advantage over them at the outset. When he does this, it is usually by searching out a better market in which to buy, buying at a better time, and judging better than his competitors the quality of goods. If, in a given market at a given time, goods are sold to one more cheaply than to others, it is an act of generosity. Even the best buyers pay nearly the prevailing market price for agents. The most successful enterprisers are not found to be those paying lower wages or lower ground-rent than their competitors. It must not be forgotten that the main forces fixing the prices of agents are impersonal, and can be only[Pg 275] slightly modified in most cases by a particular buyer. He looks therefore upon the cost of the elements as an ultimate fact which he can change little, if at all, and he shows his judgment chiefly in the selection of quality. Cost determines and limits the extent of his business and determines the price at which he sells.

3. The entrepreneur, viewing the cost of most factors as fixed, aims to combine them as efficiently as possible. Whether the entrepreneur is operating a factory or a farm, running a retail or wholesale store, managing a school, or a railroad, they face nearly the same challenges. With careful attention, good judgment, and skilled negotiation, they might be able to purchase goods slightly cheaper than their competitors, giving them an edge right from the start. They achieve this by finding a better market to buy from, purchasing at a more favorable time, and assessing the quality of goods more accurately than their rivals. In a specific market at a certain time, if goods are sold to one buyer at a lower price than to others, it's typically an act of generosity. Even the best buyers generally pay close to the prevailing market price for goods. The most successful entrepreneurs are usually not the ones paying lower wages or less rent than their competitors. It’s important to remember that the main factors determining prices are impersonal and can only be slightly altered by any individual buyer. Therefore, they view the cost of the elements as a fundamental fact that they can change very little, if at all, and their judgment primarily reflects in the quality selection. Costs determine and limit the scope of their business and influence the prices at which they sell.

The right proportioning of the factors

4. The right proportioning and skilful substitution of the factors is a delicate technical task for the enterpriser. Good buying and good selling must precede and follow the central part of the enterpriser's task, that is, the combining of the various factors. Each factor is applied, subject to diminishing returns, up to a point where its addition will not secure the value attributed to it in its cost. The enterpriser is constantly studying the question whether the application of another unit of any one factor at the price will add to the value of the product as much or more than the cost. This calculation is made for every one of the minor factors entering into the business, and for the business as a whole. The proper proportion varies at different prices, or costs. If wages rise, "it pays" to get machinery; if wages fall, it pays to let the machinery deteriorate and to do more by hand-labor. Likewise there is constant substitution of the various materials. The right proportions change constantly with inventions. A model factory is so proportioned that the buildings hold the right number of machines, with the right amount of space for the workmen, and the right amount of power. If there is more of a single factor than the ideal proportion, it is an unnecessary cost. Even the model factory begins to be out of date almost as soon as the walls are dry, and the latest method is to build as nearly as possible on the unit system, so that new parts may be added without the loss of harmony and proportion.

4. Finding the right balance and skillfully swapping out the factors is a tricky technical job for the entrepreneur. Good buying and good selling need to come before and after the main part of the entrepreneur's work, which is bringing together different factors. Each factor is used, with decreasing returns, until a point is reached where adding more of it won't deliver the value expected for its cost. The entrepreneur is always assessing whether applying another unit of any factor at its price will increase the product's value as much or more than its cost. This assessment is made for each of the minor factors in the business and for the business overall. The right balance shifts with different prices or costs. If wages go up, "it pays" to invest in machinery; if wages go down, it makes sense to let the machinery wear out and to rely more on manual labor. Similarly, there's constant swapping of different materials. The right balances change frequently with new inventions. An ideal factory is designed so that the buildings accommodate the right number of machines, sufficient space for workers, and adequate power. If there's too much of a single factor beyond the ideal balance, it becomes wasted cost. Even the ideal factory starts to become outdated almost as soon as it’s built, and the latest approach is to construct as closely as possible to a modular system, allowing new parts to be added without disrupting the overall balance and proportion.

Pressure of price toward cost at certain points
The enterpriser in contact with costs

5. The enterpriser's costs determine the lowest price at which he can continue to sell, but if successful he may have a wide margin of profits. New factories are constantly arising with new and better adjustments. In industries of[Pg 276] competing products, also, the processes are changing. Hence there is always a pressure of competition on some enterprisers who constantly complain that they must sell below the cost of production. The organizers of a trust always declare, some no doubt truly, that they have been selling below the cost of production. Business men say that competition is destructive, and it certainly does destroy the less favorably situated enterprises. Each enterpriser's price is the highest he can get in the market for his product; it may far exceed his costs; it may even fall below them, but only temporarily, for if sales continue to encroach on capital, the sheriff soon closes the doors. Successful competitors are constantly pressing upon the marginal enterpriser, fixing a price that leaves themselves a profit, but is below his cost. Even the most successful enterpriser comes into contact with cost, and seems to be compelled by it. He reaches out for trade, and sells some (not all) goods at a price which leaves him no profit. He enlarges his factory and ships goods farther, paying the freight, which means a lower price at the factory. The expanding business, therefore, comes at length to the point where it cannot go farther at the prevailing prices. Hence the business man's view of the costs is that they determine value. It is true in the sense that the supply of a particular product in any market is at last limited by cost of marginal producers or of marginal portions of supply. But it is not true of all the units of product that costs determine, or equal, market price. There is a margin above costs to the successful enterpriser on a large portion of his output. The margin may be narrow or wide, according to the business. The margin is "profit," or the gain of the enterpriser.

5. The entrepreneur's costs set the lowest price at which they can keep selling, but if they succeed, they might enjoy a substantial profit margin. New factories are always popping up with better setups. In industries with[Pg 276] competing products, the processes are also evolving. Thus, there's constant competition putting pressure on some entrepreneurs, who often say they have to sell below the cost of production. Organizers of a trust often claim, some likely truthfully, that they've been selling below production costs. Businesspeople argue that competition is harmful, and it undoubtedly wipes out less competitive enterprises. Each entrepreneur's price is the highest they can charge in the market for their product; it may be much higher than their costs or even temporarily lower, but if sales keep cutting into capital, the sheriff will soon shut them down. Successful competitors continually pressure marginal entrepreneurs, setting a price that allows them to profit while being below the entrepreneur's costs. Even the most successful entrepreneur has to deal with costs and seems bound by them. They reach out for sales and sell some (not all) goods at prices that yield no profit. They expand their factory and ship goods further, covering the freight, which means lower prices at the factory. Eventually, the growing business hits a point where it can’t push further at the current prices. Therefore, the business person's understanding of costs is that they determine value. This is true in that the supply of a specific product in any market is ultimately limited by the costs of marginal producers or marginal supplies. However, it's not accurate to say that costs determine or equal market prices for all units of product. There is often a margin above costs for the successful entrepreneur on a large part of their output. The width of this margin varies with the business. The margin represents "profit," or the gain for the entrepreneur.

§ II. COST OF PRODUCTION FROM THE ECONOMIST'S STANDPOINT

Money cost not the ultimate explanation of value

1. The economist should view money cost as an intermediate and not as an ultimate explanation of value. The[Pg 277] value of all things must be traced back to gratification, to the relation of goods with psychic income. This being true, the value of the factors which the enterpriser uses must be derived from the value of the products, and not the reverse. This does not mean that the business man is deceived into the belief that he has in cost of production a final explanation of value. He simply is not interested in that question. He knows that there are many influences determining the cost of the factors he buys, but they are distant; he cannot influence them, and in the single stage of his production they seem to fix the price. In some purchases, and on the stock exchange, a marvelous recognition and analysis of the most distant influences is necessary; but in general a superficial view of value is taken in business; it does not pay to do other. The logical treatment, however, must go deeper into the question and trace the cost of agents back to the ultimate cause of value, that is, to want-gratifying power. To say that the price of a product is determined by the money cost, or price, of the factors is simply to postpone the answer to the question of value; one has still to ask, What determines the money cost, or price, of those factors themselves?

1. The economist should see money cost as a middle-ground factor and not as the final explanation of value. The[Pg 277] value of everything must be traced back to satisfaction, to the connection between goods and personal income. Since this is true, the value of the resources that the entrepreneur uses must come from the value of the products, not the other way around. This doesn’t mean that the businessperson is misled into thinking that production costs provide a conclusive explanation of value. They simply aren’t focused on that issue. They know that many factors influence the cost of the resources they purchase, but these are far removed; they can’t control them, and in this single stage of production, those costs seem to set the price. In some transactions, especially on the stock exchange, an amazing understanding and analysis of the most distant influences are required; however, generally speaking, businesses take a superficial view of value as it’s not worth it to do otherwise. The logical analysis, though, must dig deeper and trace the cost of resources back to the ultimate source of value, which is the ability to satisfy wants. To claim that the price of a product is determined by the money cost or price of the factors is merely to delay answering the question of value; one still needs to ask, What determines the money cost or price of those factors themselves?

The cost of agents is fixed by their marginal utility in alternative uses

2. The demand for any factor entering into products is reflected, in an increased price, to its cost in all competing products. Figuratively speaking, products compete with each other for the factors that enter into them. According to location, quality of the soil, and improvements, a certain area of land has various rival uses. These uses bid for the land, or put in an economic claim for it. Products of a higher value outbid and exclude those of a lower. If fine wine can be raised on a piece of land, potatoes ordinarily will not be planted in it. But if there is such a supply of that quality of land that it continues to be used side by side for both products, it will have the same value and yield the same rental in both uses. The least utility yielded by any portion of the supply fixes the value of all the units.[Pg 278] Machines are usually made for some product determined in advance, but often they are only partially specialized and within limits they can be adapted. Sewing-machine factories were readily turned to the making of bicycles at the time of greatest demand, and bicycle factories later were used for the making of automobiles. Thus, in general, machinery is used for the product to which it contributes the most value. Any enterpriser seeking it for any other use finds its "cost" affected by its various alternative uses. The same is true of all the materials and of all the grades of labor entering into products. The enterpriser's cost is therefore the reflection of the want-gratifying power of the productive agent in all its other uses as well as in the particular product he desires. To the enterpriser, cost seems the cause of the value of a product. To the economist it should be clear that the utility found in the various products is the basis of value in the factors, i. e., of the costs.

2. The demand for any factor involved in products is shown, in a higher price, to its cost in all competing products. In a way, products compete with each other for the factors that make them. Depending on location, soil quality, and improvements, a specific piece of land has different competing uses. These uses bid for the land or claim it economically. Higher-value products outbid and exclude those of lower value. If high-quality wine can be produced on a piece of land, potatoes typically won’t be grown there. However, if there's such an abundance of that quality land that it's used simultaneously for both products, it will hold the same value and generate the same rental in both uses. The least utility provided by any part of the supply sets the value for all the units.[Pg 278] Machines are usually designed for a specific product in advance, but they are often only partially specialized and can be adapted to some extent. During times of high demand, sewing-machine factories could easily switch to making bicycles, and bicycle factories later transitioned to producing automobiles. Thus, generally, machinery is used for the product that it adds the most value to. Any entrepreneur looking to use it for a different purpose finds its "cost" affected by its various alternative uses. This is also true for all the materials and all the different types of labor that go into products. The entrepreneur's cost is therefore a reflection of the want-satisfying power of the productive agent in all its other applications as well as in the specific product he wants. To the entrepreneur, cost appears to be the cause of a product's value. To an economist, it should be clear that the utility found in various products is the basis of value in the factors, i.e., of the costs.

A single source of a single product

3. The genealogy of value may thus be traced through the various intermediate products to consumption goods. A single product having a single source of supply shows most clearly the reflection of value directly from the product. The discovery of a mineral spring or of a good quality of building-stone on worthless land, will cause a value to attach at once to the source of supply. When a great singer like Adelina Patti commands several thousand dollars for each appearance in concert, the source is the magical throat of the singer, and the salary reflects the utility of the music in the minds of delighted hearers.

3. The genealogy of value can be traced through the various intermediate products to consumer goods. A single product with a single source of supply clearly shows how value is reflected directly from the product. Discovering a mineral spring or high-quality building stone on previously worthless land will immediately add value to the source of supply. When a famous singer like Adelina Patti earns several thousand dollars for each concert appearance, the source is the singer's extraordinary voice, and the salary reflects how valuable the music is to the thrilled audience.

One source of several products

When the one source of supply yields several different kinds of products there is just one new condition which confuses the thought and suggests the error that value begins in the source (with costs therefore) and not in the product. Looking at the products severally, no one of them explains the value of the source, and, on the contrary, each one is seen to have a value independent of the particular use to which it is put. To make the illustration most simple: a savage finds[Pg 279] in a wreck on the coast a number of bars of iron. His fellows wish them for various purposes: to make arrow heads, spears, knives, hatchets, hoes, ornaments, nails, needles, etc. Value is in this case derived in part, through the source, from the alternate uses. Taken jointly and considered as one sum, the value of the various products accounts as completely and exclusively for the value of the source as if they were merged into one product. The source (S) is distributed to each of the products in accordance with their marginal utility, and therefore the value of the various products from any source of supply constantly tends to equality. Any unit of product sought for any purpose must be paid for according to a marginal utility determined in all the applications. The genesis of the value is in the utility of the product; the value of the source is derived.

When one supply source produces several different types of products, it creates a situation that can confuse people's understanding and leads to the mistake of thinking that value starts with the source (and thus with costs) instead of the product. If we examine the products individually, none of them explains the value of the source. In fact, each product has a value independent of its specific use. To simplify the example: imagine a primitive person finds a number of iron bars in a shipwreck on the beach. His peers want them for various purposes: making arrowheads, spears, knives, hatchets, hoes, ornaments, nails, needles, and so on. In this case, value partly comes from the source and the alternative uses. When considered together as a single group, the total value of these various products explains the value of the source just as completely as if they were one single product. The source (S) is allocated to each product based on its marginal utility, which is why the value of different products from any supply source tends to equalize. Any unit of product sought for any purpose must be compensated based on a marginal utility assessed across all uses. The origin of the value lies in the product's utility; the value of the source comes from this relationship.

1. One Product 2. Multiple Products from a single Source
Complex conditions with intermediate products

In actual life the problem is far more complex, and yet, through its settlement runs just the same principle. There is constant bidding for materials, and through their price the claims of rival products are adjusted. A point is reached where it does not pay to use any more of an agent in a certain industry; the production of another unit results[Pg 280] in a loss. There is a most complex relation among many different industries using the same factors, the value of a unit of product (at a) being reflected up to the source, and through successive links to the most distant product (z). The effect of this is to reduce the sale (of z) and correspondingly the use made of the agent in question. A higher price of leather, due to the increased use of shoes, raises the value of hides and cattle (this increasing the extent of cattle raising) and raises thus the cost of carriage-trimmings, pocket-books, foot-balls, leather belts, and every other leather product. As the price rises, substitutes for leather, and imitations of it, are used for such of the products as cannot bear the increased cost of leather.

In real life, the situation is much more complicated, but the same principle still applies to how it gets resolved. There's ongoing competition for materials, and the prices determine the claims of competing products. There comes a point where using more of a resource in a specific industry is not profitable; producing another unit leads to a loss. There's a very intricate relationship among various industries that use the same resources, where the value of a product (at a) influences everything back to the source, cascading through links all the way to the most distant product (z). This effect reduces the sales of product z and consequently decreases the use of the resource in question. For example, a higher price for leather, resulting from increased shoe sales, raises the value of hides and cattle (which expands cattle farming) and thus increases the cost of leather goods like carriage trims, wallets, footballs, leather belts, and any other leather products. As prices go up, alternatives to leather and imitations are adopted for products that can’t handle the higher costs of leather.

3. Complicated Relationships Through Intermediate Products
The enterpriser the medium of price movements
Costs are an expression of consumers' estimates

4. The enterpriser does not fix the value of products or of agents, but is the medium through which consumers express their estimates. The enterpriser who anticipates aright and satisfies the public taste is the good medium. He readily transmits and accurately focuses the rays of public judgment. One that misjudges is a poor medium. The enterpriser is himself the servant of costs. Laborers sometimes[Pg 281] assume that the employer can dictate wages, prices, and markets, can rule things with a lordly hand. With rare exceptions the ultimate control in these matters by business men is very slight. In the main the enterpriser masters the situation only by bowing to it, just as the scientist and the engineer gain mastery over nature because they know when to bend and how to obey. The consumer, by deciding to buy this or that product, sets in motion waves of value. The consumers of products are the true purchasers of labor, materials, and uses of agents. The enterpriser must conform closely to cost, to the price prevailing for the moment, or his competitors in this day of narrow margins will seize the opportunity. The enterpriser is merely the distributor or equalizer of cost among all the different products for which different agents can be used. If he acts efficiently, profits arise.

4. The entrepreneur doesn’t set the value of products or agents; instead, they're the channel through which consumers express their opinions. The entrepreneur who correctly anticipates and meets public demand is an effective channel. They easily convey and accurately reflect public judgment. Someone who misjudges is an ineffective channel. The entrepreneur is ultimately subject to costs. Workers sometimes[Pg 281] believe that employers can dictate wages, prices, and markets, and control everything with an iron fist. In most cases, business leaders have very limited control over these matters. Generally, the entrepreneur navigates the situation by adapting to it, just like scientists and engineers gain control over nature by knowing when to adjust and obey. When consumers decide to buy a particular product, they create waves of value. The true buyers of labor, materials, and the services of agents are the consumers of products. The entrepreneur must closely adhere to costs and the current market price, or their competitors will quickly take advantage. The entrepreneur is essentially the distributor or equalizer of costs across all the different products for which various agents can be utilized. If they operate effectively, profits will follow.


CHAPTER 31

THE LAW OF PROFITS

§ I. MEANING OF TERMS

Broadest use of the term profit

1. The term profit is popularly used as any gain or advantage secured by any means in business. The terms used in economics, being taken from popular language, vary in meaning according to the context. It is necessary to clear thinking to reject some words entirely and when using others to define them more strictly. The broad usage of the term profits just noted includes every kind of return to industry: such as interest on capital, and wages or services of the man owning the industry. Precise thinking requires its use in a much narrower sense.

1. The term profit is commonly used to describe any gain or advantage achieved in business. The terms used in economics, derived from everyday language, can change in meaning based on the context. It's important for clear thinking to eliminate certain words entirely and to define others more precisely when using them. The wide-ranging use of the term profits mentioned includes all types of returns from industry, like interest on capital and the wages or services of the person running the industry. Accurate thinking requires that it be used in a much more specific sense.

Used of gross gains on sales

2. A common meaning of profits in retail business is the gross gain on a given sale. Buying an article for one dollar and selling it for two dollars, is said by the merchant to be selling at one hundred per cent. profit, jocularly called, "The Dutchman's one per cent." The cost price is considered to be that paid to the manufacturer or wholesaler. In different lines of goods there is added regularly to this cost twenty, thirty, or fifty per cent., as the case may be, as the merchant's profit on the sale. This is of course a gross profit, and not net, or true profit. It leaves out of account rent, interest on capital, clerk hire, freight, and many other minor items that enter into the cost of running a store. It often happens that the Dutchman's way of reckoning is nearer the truth, and that the gross profit of one hundred per cent. proves at the end of the year to be only a net[Pg 283] profit of one per cent. This evidently is a loose meaning, impossible in the discussion of theoretical questions. This meaning is sometimes developed, making profits the sum of all the gross profits on separate sales within a year, or the difference between the wholesale and retail prices of goods sold within the year.

2. A common meaning of profits in retail business is the total gain from a specific sale. If a merchant buys an item for one dollar and sells it for two dollars, they refer to this as making a one hundred percent profit, humorously called, "The Dutchman's one percent." The cost price is what was paid to the manufacturer or wholesaler. In various lines of goods, a markup of twenty, thirty, or fifty percent is typically added to this cost as the merchant's profit on the sale. This represents gross profit, not net or actual profit, as it does not account for expenses like rent, interest on capital, employee salaries, shipping, and other minor costs associated with running a store. Often, the Dutchman's method of calculation is closer to reality, as the gross profit of one hundred percent may actually result in a net[Pg 283] profit of just one percent by the end of the year. Clearly, this is a vague definition, unsuitable for serious theoretical discussions. Sometimes, this definition expands to consider profits as the total of all gross profits from separate sales within a year, or as the difference between wholesale and retail prices of goods sold throughout the year.

Another meaning given to the term is gross profit (as above) compared with the capital invested. The "profit" in this case varies partly with the rate of the turnover. To illustrate: if the amount invested in a printing-office is $100,000, and the annual business done is $300,000, the capital is said to be turned over three times; if the gross profits on sales averaged twenty per cent., they would be sixty per cent. on the investment; but, if the capital had been turned over four times, the gross profit would have been eighty per cent. on the investment.

Another meaning of the term is gross profit (as mentioned above) in relation to the capital invested. The "profit" in this context varies partly with the turnover rate. For example: if the amount invested in a printing business is $100,000, and the annual revenue is $300,000, the capital is said to be turned over three times; if the gross profits on sales average twenty percent, that would equate to sixty percent on the investment; however, if the capital had been turned over four times, the gross profit would be eighty percent on the investment.

Of net gains as a percentage of invested capital

3. Another meaning of profits is the annual net gain of the business, as compared with the average investment of capital. This is a long step toward greater definiteness. If at the end of a year it were found that after paying all outside expenses there were $10,000 to set aside, this would be accounted a profit of ten per cent. on $100,000 invested. But confusion still reigns because of wide variation in the methods of estimating costs before fixing net profits. In one case the enterpriser rents lands and buildings, in another he owns them; in one case he has borrowed money and counts interest as a cost, in another he is free from debt; in one case he counts as a part of cost an estimated fair salary for himself and his partners, in another (usually in a small business) no such allowance is made Such a variation in business usage is most perplexing. In all these cases one must have the exact conditions in mind before it is possible to make any comparisons and draw any conclusions as to the relative profits of different industries.

3. Another way to define profits is the annual net gain of a business, compared to the average capital investment. This moves us closer to clarity. If at the end of a year it turns out there’s $10,000 left after paying all expenses, that would be seen as a profit of ten percent on a $100,000 investment. However, confusion still exists because of the significant differences in how costs are estimated before determining net profits. In some cases, the business owner rents land and buildings, while in others, they own them; sometimes they have borrowed money and include interest as a cost, while in other cases, there is no debt; in some instances, they factor in a fair salary for themselves and their partners as part of the costs, while in other cases (usually in small businesses) no such salary is accounted for. This variety in business practices can be quite confusing. In all these situations, one must understand the specific conditions before making any comparisons or drawing conclusions about the relative profits of different industries.

Profits in economic theory

4. In the narrower and exacter sense profits are the net gain of the enterpriser after counting the rent of material agents and contract wages of employees at the prevailing rates. [Pg 284]Into the practical problem of cost and profit many factors enter, and the theoretical problem is to determine just how much ought to be attributed to each. In a large business usually the practical bookkeeping problem is not unlike that of economic analysis. A stock company counts as cost, as a part of fixed charges, interest on capital borrowed either from banks or bondholders. Its managers are paid salaries, counted as a part of cost. The net balance, after deducting these and all other expenses, is counted profits and paid in dividends to stockholders. The economic student is not attempting to get a theory of profits that is in contrast with practice. Rather, he is trying to analyze profits generally, just as they are analyzed in the few cases where the books are properly kept. In economic theory, therefore, profits are the part of the gain of any business that is logically attributable to fortunate investment and good management; profits are the income attributable to the enterpriser's services.

4. In a more precise sense, profits are the net earnings of the entrepreneur after accounting for the cost of materials and the wages of employees at the current rates. [Pg 284]Multiple factors influence the practical issues of cost and profit, and the theoretical challenge is to determine how much should be assigned to each factor. In a large business, the bookkeeping challenges often resemble those in economic analysis. A corporation considers interest on borrowed capital, whether from banks or bondholders, as a cost and part of fixed expenses. The salaries of the managers are also included as a cost. The remaining balance, after subtracting these and all other expenses, is considered profits and distributed as dividends to shareholders. The economic student isn't trying to create a profit theory that goes against practical reality. Instead, he aims to analyze profits in general, similar to how they are examined in the few cases where accounting is accurately maintained. In economic theory, therefore, profits are the portion of a business's earnings that can logically be attributed to successful investment and effective management; profits are the income related to the entrepreneur's contributions.

Profits a species of wages

5. Typical economic profits are thus a species of wages but are marked by peculiar features. In some of the older treatises on political economy, profits are treated merely as a combination of "wages of management," and of interest on capital invested. A man hired at a fixed sum to manage a business is receiving simply contract wages. Economic profits are not contract wages, not being paid by agreement, but being yielded impersonally by the industry. Profits are, however, economic wages or the earnings of services. As business has developed, it has been seen that the enterpriser's work has its peculiar character and deserves special attention. The old English word "enterpriser," used of the "adventurer" who embarked in foreign trade, may fittingly apply to the organizer and director of business to-day. Foreign trade then, more often than now, was most uncertain, and there were many chances that the ship would be lost, or the venture prove a losing one. In the simplest[Pg 285] business to-day there is this element of enterprise, or undertaking, combined with ordinary capital and labor. As industry develops, this special service stands out more clearly. In the corner-grocer and in the manager of the little news-stand, the elements of enterprise and labor are not apart. In the large wholesale house, the enterpriser is seen to be not merely an abstractly thinkable function, but a separate and concrete person. The typical enterpriser is the man who gives his time and energies to the launching and guiding of business.

5. Typical economic profits are a type of wages but have unique characteristics. In some older writings on political economy, profits are seen simply as a mix of "management wages" and interest on invested capital. A person hired for a set salary to run a business is just earning contract wages. Economic profits are not contract wages; they aren’t paid by agreement but are generated impersonally by the industry. However, profits are considered economic wages or the earnings from services. As business has evolved, it’s become clear that the work of an entrepreneur has its own distinct nature and requires special focus. The old English term "enterpriser," once used to describe the "adventurer" involved in foreign trade, can now appropriately refer to the organizer and manager of businesses today. Back then, foreign trade was often very unpredictable, with many risks that ships could be lost or ventures could fail. Even in the simplest[Pg 285] business today, there is an element of enterprise or endeavor, combined with regular capital and labor. As industry continues to grow, this special service becomes more evident. In the small grocery store and the manager of the local newsstand, the aspects of enterprise and labor are intertwined. In a large wholesale company, the entrepreneur is no longer just an abstract function; they are a distinct and tangible person. The typical entrepreneur is someone who dedicates their time and energy to starting and leading a business.

§ II. THE TYPICAL ENTERPRISER'S SERVICES REVIEWED

The enterpriser's skilful use of capital

1. The enterpriser guarantees to the capitalist-lender a fixed return. Agents will yield the highest economic rent of which they are capable only in the hands of those who can use them with exceptional skill. Owners of capital who for any reason, such as youth, inexperience, ill health, incapacity, or conflicting duties, are not able to make agents yield the average rent, seek out, or are sought out by, those who in general can make the agents yield more than the average. The interest contract between them is one of mutual advantage, in that the enterpriser pays a definite sum to the investor unable himself to apply his productive agents. Immense sums of capital are now put into the hands of small enterprisers, such as Western farmers improving their lands, builders of city homes and business blocks, and small manufacturers. But stocks and bonds of corporations give a wide variety of investments which shade off from the safer or capitalistic type, to the more uncertain, or enterpriser's type. First-mortgage bonds, being a first claim on the income and property, have the highest security and yield generally the lowest interest. Even national bonds are not absolutely safe, and for that reason as well as because of their fluctuation in price, even their purchase has something of the nature of an enterprise. Stocks are the enterpriser's type of investment,[Pg 286] the dividends being more uncertain, but giving the chance of a higher return than the average. It is because some stand ready to assume the risk of making goods yield average returns or more, that others can sit and enjoy a fixed income with little effort and in comparative security.

1. The entrepreneur guarantees a fixed return to the capitalist-lender. Agents will generate the highest economic rent they're capable of only when they're managed by those who possess exceptional skill. Capital owners, who due to reasons like youth, inexperience, ill health, incapacity, or conflicting responsibilities, can't make agents yield the average rent, either seek out or are sought out by those who can generally achieve more than average returns with the agents. The interest contract between them is mutually beneficial, as the entrepreneur pays a specific amount to the investor who cannot apply his productive agents himself. A large amount of capital is currently in the hands of small entrepreneurs, such as farmers in the West improving their land, builders of homes and business blocks in cities, and small manufacturers. However, stocks and bonds from corporations offer a wide range of investments that vary from safer, capitalistic types to the more uncertain, entrepreneur's types. First-mortgage bonds, which hold the first claim on income and property, provide the highest security and usually yield the lowest interest. Even government bonds aren't completely safe, and for that reason, as well as their price fluctuation, purchasing them carries a degree of risk. Stocks represent the entrepreneur's type of investment,[Pg 286] with dividends being less certain but offering the potential for higher returns than the average. It is because some are willing to take the risk to ensure goods yield average returns or more that others can relax and enjoy a fixed income with minimal effort and relative security.

The enterpriser's insurance of the lender's capital

2. The enterpriser gives up the certain income to be got by lending his own capital, and, becoming a borrower, offers his capital as insurance to the lender. Every business has an element of uncertainty in it, and some one must meet the risk. A man with marked ability as an organizer of industry is rarely found long without capital of his own. But even a penniless man who can gain the confidence of investors is able to get backing and to secure the necessary funds to engage in business. The lenders in such a case, however, run a greater risk than when the enterpriser is a man of some means, and they therefore ask a higher rate of interest than if they were loaning to a wealthy man or to a wealthy company. They are in part the enterprisers. When, as usually, the enterpriser invests some of his own capital, it is a guarantee of his good faith, a sort of insurance reserve to protect the lender from loss. The first loss falls on the enterpriser, and the chance of loss to the lender is in large part, though not entirely, eliminated. It is characteristic of modern loans that the borrower may be rich, not poor,—often richer than the lender. The mortgage on real estate and the creditor's claim on a merchant's property usually give security of far greater value than the loan.

2. The entrepreneur gives up the guaranteed income they could earn by lending their own money and, by becoming a borrower, offers their capital as a form of insurance to the lender. Every business carries some level of uncertainty, and someone has to take on the risk. A person with a strong talent for organizing industry rarely goes long without their own capital. However, even someone with no money who can earn the trust of investors can secure backing and obtain the funds needed to start a business. In such cases, lenders take on a greater risk than when the entrepreneur has some means, so they typically demand a higher interest rate than if they were lending to a wealthy individual or company. They are partly the entrepreneurs themselves. When, as is often the case, the entrepreneur invests some of their own capital, it serves as proof of their integrity, a sort of insurance reserve to protect the lender from losses. The first loss is absorbed by the entrepreneur, greatly reducing, though not completely eliminating, the lender's risk. A common feature of modern loans is that the borrower may be wealthy, not poor—often even wealthier than the lender. Mortgages on real estate and a creditor's claim on a merchant's assets usually provide security worth much more than the loan.

The enterpriser's insurance of the laborer's production

3. The enterpriser gives to other workers a definite amount for services applied to distant ends. In discussing the wage system it was pointed out that most labor at the present time is put upon future goods. It is not known what they will be worth a month or a year later when they mature as consumption goods; their present worth can merely be estimated. If they prove to be worth little, the profits may be nothing or less than nothing. The enterpriser, however, buys the services for ready money, embodies[Pg 287] them in goods, and assumes the risk; the goods may sell for more or less than the wages. It is sometimes said with a certain irony that if the enterpriser assumes the risk he is very careful to pay so little for labor that he does not lose. In this naive view the enterpriser is so independent of the market that he can pay much or little as he pleases. In fact in many cases he gains little, and in many he loses and loses largely.

3. The entrepreneur pays workers a set amount for their services directed toward distant goals. When discussing the wage system, it's noted that most labor today is invested in goods that will benefit the future. It's uncertain what those goods will be worth a month or a year from now when they become consumer products; their current value can only be approximated. If they turn out to be worth very little, the profits could be nonexistent or even negative. The entrepreneur, however, purchases services upfront, incorporates[Pg 287] them into products, and takes on the risk; the products might sell for more or less than the wages paid. It's sometimes said with a hint of irony that if the entrepreneur takes on the risk, he's very careful to pay workers so little that he doesn't suffer a loss. This simplistic view suggests that the entrepreneur is so detached from the market that he can choose to pay whatever amount he wants. In reality, in many situations, he hardly profits, and in many cases, he incurs significant losses.

The risk of the enterpriser's services

4. The enterpriser risks his own services and accepts an indefinite chance instead of a definite amount for them. Assuming the risk for the right conduct of industry, he backs himself, expresses his faith in himself as a manager who can make labor earn more than the prevailing wages and make capital yield more than the prevailing rate of interest. If it were otherwise, he would loan what capital he has instead of borrowing more; instead of employing others, he would himself seek employment in some other industry. Men are constantly shifting from the class of hired workers to that of enterprisers. It is a rude and often tragic process of adjustment and selection that enables men having ability as enterprisers to continue in that work, and forces others into the class of employees.

4. The entrepreneur risks his own efforts and accepts an uncertain outcome instead of a guaranteed payment for them. By taking on the risk of successfully running a business, he bets on himself, showing his confidence as a manager who can make labor produce more than the average wages and make capital earn more than the usual interest rate. If it were different, he would lend the capital he has instead of borrowing more; instead of hiring others, he would look for a job in another industry himself. People are constantly moving from being hired workers to becoming entrepreneurs. It’s a tough and often painful process of adjustment and selection that allows those with entrepreneurial skills to stay in that role, while pushing others into the employee category.

The enterpriser the intermediary in industry

5. The enterpriser is the economic buffer; economic forces are transmitted through him. In a more primitive industry each man is wage-earner, capitalist, and enterpriser combined in one. As industry develops, some of the factors of cost become distinguishable, and relatively stable and calculable. A low rate of interest, ranging from three to four per cent., can be secured with practical certainty by putting one's money into good corporation securities, into the savings-bank, or into national bonds. Contract wages in each class of labor also are fixed by competition at a point where they are a medium or average of gains and losses. The enterpriser is the most movable element. As the specialized risk-taker, he is the spring or buffer, which takes up and distributes the strain of industry. He feels[Pg 288] first the influence of changing conditions. If the prices of his products fall, the first loss comes upon him, and he avoids further loss as best he can by paying less for materials and labor. At such times the wage-earners look upon him as their evil genius, and usually blame him for lowering their wages, not the public for refusing to buy the product at the former high prices. Again, if prices rise, he gains from the increased value of the stock in his hand that has been produced at low cost. If the employer often appears to be a hard man, his disposition is the result of "natural selection." He is placed between the powerful, selfish forces of competition, and his economic survival is conditioned on vigilance, strength, and self-assertion. Weak generosity cannot endure.

5. The entrepreneur acts as the economic buffer; economic forces flow through him. In simpler industries, each person is a wage-earner, capitalist, and entrepreneur all rolled into one. As industries grow, some cost factors become identifiable, relatively stable, and predictable. A low-interest rate, typically between three and four percent, can be reliably obtained by investing in good corporate securities, savings accounts, or government bonds. Contract wages in each labor category are set by competition at a level that reflects a balance of gains and losses. The entrepreneur is the most flexible component. As the specialized risk-taker, he is the spring or buffer that absorbs and distributes the pressures of industry. He feels[Pg 288] the effects of changing conditions first. If the prices of his products drop, he incurs the initial loss and tries to minimize further losses by cutting costs on materials and labor. During such times, wage-earners often see him as their nemesis and typically blame him for reducing their wages, rather than holding the public accountable for not buying the product at the previous higher prices. Conversely, if prices rise, he benefits from the increased value of the inventory produced at a lower cost. If the employer often seems tough, it's a result of "natural selection." He operates between the powerful, selfish pressures of competition, and his economic survival relies on vigilance, strength, and self-assertion. Weak generosity cannot last.

Fluctuation of profits

6. Profits therefore fluctuate more from industry to industry and from man to man than do other incomes. As a somewhat exceptional case, small employers in industries such as baking and tailoring, may for long periods get less for their work than their employees get in wages. The pride in being an employer and occasional chances of greater gains perhaps explain the fact. The fluctuations of the market may sweep away from the enterpriser not only all his "profits," but all his accumulated wealth. As a consequence, profits may be at other times very high, for men will not take the risk of great losses unless there is a chance of large gains. While the income of the salaried man is occasionally advanced, and then for long periods remains unchanged, the profits of enterprise come in waves. In seasons of prosperity the income of the employer swells with a dramatic swiftness while rents and wages move tardily upward. But for years again the employer earns a return hardly exceeding a low interest on the capital invested in the enterprise, or runs the business for a time at a loss. Profits of this kind should not be spoken of as a percentage. Greater or less, they are the net result attributable to the enterpriser's skill, and bear no fixed or calculable relation to any capital investment.

6. Profits vary more from industry to industry and from person to person than other incomes do. In some unique cases, small employers in fields like baking and tailoring may earn less for their work than what they pay their employees in wages for extended periods. The pride of being an employer and the occasional potential for higher earnings might explain this situation. Market fluctuations can wipe out not only all of the enterpriser's "profits" but also all their accumulated wealth. As a result, profits can sometimes be very high because people won't take the risk of significant losses unless there's a chance for substantial gains. While a salaried employee's income might see occasional raises and then remain stable for long periods, profits from entrepreneurship come in waves. During prosperous times, the employer's income can dramatically surge, while rents and wages increase slowly. However, there can be years when the employer earns a return that barely exceeds a low interest rate on the capital put into the business, or even operates at a loss for a time. Profits like these shouldn't be referred to as a percentage. Whether greater or lesser, they are the net result of the enterpriser's skill and don't have a fixed or predictable relationship to any capital investment.

§ III. STATEMENT OF THE LAW OF PROFITS

Antisocial or pseudo-profits

1. Some apparent profits are due to antisocial or criminal acts. Cheating, lying, breaking of contracts, bribery of public officials, and many similar acts may greatly increase individual incomes. These are not profits, as the term is here understood, but they are hard to distinguish from profits in practical life. One man gains a temporary success by acts that are later punished as crimes; another, guilty of like deeds, escapes conviction for lack of evidence or on technicalities, and enjoys ill-gotten wealth. More fortunes, however, are due to actions on the border-line of ethics, which society is not yet honest enough to condemn or wise enough to prevent. No code of laws can be framed that will make possible the punishment of all antisocial acts. Any law that would catch all the guilty would injure many of the innocent. Economic analysis may exclude from the concept of profits the gains made by such means, but only omniscience could distinguish them in every actual case from "swag and boodle."

1. Some apparent profits come from antisocial or criminal acts. Cheating, lying, breaking contracts, bribing public officials, and many similar actions can significantly boost individual incomes. These aren't profits in the way we understand the term here, but they can be hard to separate from profits in real life. One person achieves temporary success through actions that are later punished as crimes; another, who commits similar acts, avoids conviction due to lack of evidence or legal loopholes, and enjoys ill-gotten gains. However, a lot of wealth comes from actions that skirt the edge of ethics, which society isn’t honest enough to condemn or smart enough to prevent. No set of laws can be created that will ensure the punishment of all antisocial acts. Any law aiming to catch all the guilty would also hurt many innocent people. Economic analysis might exclude from the idea of profits the earnings made through such means, but only someone all-knowing could tell them apart in every real case from "swag and boodle."

Chance profits

2. Some profits are the result of pure chance or luck. What is luck? A result that is not calculable, coming to pass in conditions where a rational choice is not possible, is called luck, for lack of another name. Now pure luck often brings temporary profit to the individual, but chance does not in the least account for the average and abiding profits. There is bad luck as well as good luck. According to the law of chance, in the tossing of a coin for "heads and tails," one side is as likely to come up as the other, and in the long run the number of heads and tails will be equal. Where cases are numerous, losses and gains distribute themselves about a general average, and may be eliminated by insurance, as that against fire, flood, lightning, against sickness of the employer, which would cripple the business, or against his death, which would check it. But many factors evade all[Pg 290] attempts to reduce them to rule, and chance remains a considerable factor in the success of many individuals. It still sometimes appears better to be born lucky than rich.

2. Some profits come from pure chance or luck. What is luck? It’s an outcome that can’t be calculated, happening in situations where a rational decision isn’t possible, and we call it luck for lack of a better term. Now, pure luck often brings short-term benefits to individuals, but chance doesn’t account for the average and lasting profits. There's bad luck as well as good luck. According to the law of chance, when you flip a coin for "heads and tails," either side has an equal chance of coming up, and over time, the number of heads and tails will balance out. In large numbers, losses and gains generally even out, and can be managed through insurance, such as for fire, flood, lightning, the illness of the employer, which could disrupt the business, or against his death, which would halt it. However, many factors can't be neatly defined, and chance remains a significant component in the success of many individuals. Sometimes, it seems better to be born lucky than wealthy.

Profits due to a union of chance and choice

3. Some profits are temporary gains from happy but not entirely accidental choice of the best course. Many cases of profit said to be due to chance are found on closer knowledge to be due to superior judgment. A slight advantage in choice will give now and then apparently chance gains. The adventurer who, on the discovery of gold, goes at once to California or to Alaska, may stumble upon a gold-mine. It is luck; but if he stays at home it is more likely, according to the theory of chances, that he will stumble over an ash-heap. In places where gold-mines are comparatively plentiful, one takes chances between a load of lead and a bag of money. Throughout life there is constant opportunity, but it must be sought. One who has the good judgment to be ever at the right time at the place where he has the best chance of stumbling upon a good thing, usually gets the advantage, and men call it luck. The more the causes of success in general are studied, the larger is found the element of choice, the smaller that of luck. Some writers make these temporary gains the essence of profits. Considering that profits are always due to the introduction of new and better methods, and not to the continued use of better ones, they argue that as the knowledge of these becomes common property profits will disappear. But this in our view is a partial truth.

3. Some profits are short-term rewards from happy but not completely random decisions about the best path to take. Many instances of profit claimed to be due to luck are found, upon closer examination, to be the result of better judgment. A small advantage in decision-making can occasionally lead to seemingly random gains. The adventurer who, upon discovering gold, immediately heads to California or Alaska might stumble upon a gold mine. That’s luck; but if he stays at home, it’s more likely, based on the theory of chance, that he will trip over an ash pile. In areas where gold mines are relatively common, one weighs the odds between a load of lead and a bag of money. Throughout life, opportunities are constantly available, but they must be pursued. Someone with the good sense to always be in the right place at the right time, where they have the best chance of finding something valuable, usually gains the upper hand, and people call that luck. The more we study the factors that lead to success in general, the more we see that choice plays a significant role, while luck plays a smaller part. Some writers consider these temporary gains to be the essence of profits. They argue that since profits always arise from introducing new and improved methods, and not from continually using better ones, they will disappear as this knowledge becomes widely known. But we think this is only a partial truth.

Skill the essential condition of continuing profits

4. Continuing profits arise from the continued exercise of superior judgment. After all the chance elements are taken into account, there remain differences in the abilities of men, and a continued and ever-renewed need of organizing power. Profits, being recognized as due to these differences in the abilities just as rent is due to differences in the fertility and efficiency of goods, have therefore been called differential gains. There would be no objection to the term were it not intended to emphasize a supposed difference between[Pg 291] profits and rents on the one hand and interest wages on the other.

4. Ongoing profits come from consistently using better judgment. Once all the chance factors are considered, there are still differences in people's abilities, along with a constant and renewed need for organizational skills. Profits, like rent, are recognized as arising from these differences in ability, which is why they've been referred to as differential gains. The term wouldn't be a problem if it didn't imply a supposed distinction between[Pg 291] profits and rents versus interest and wages.

Risk of loss reduced by skill

Some writers have so magnified the thought that the enterpriser's function is to assume risk, as to make it a denial of the view that profits are the earnings of ability. The risks of business are not those of the throwing of dice in which (if it is fair) skill plays no part, and gains in the long run offset losses. Business risks are rather those of the rope-walker in crossing Niagara; the task is easily undertaken by the skilful Blondin, it is fatally dangerous to the man of unsteady nerve and limb. Profits are due not to risks, but to superior skill in taking risks. They are not subtracted from the gains of labor but are earned, in the same sense in which the wages of skilled labor are earned. So long as some men have better organizing ability than others, have better judgment, are better able to take the risks, there is reason to believe that profits will continue.

Some writers have exaggerated the idea that a business person's main job is to take risks, which downplays the notion that profits come from skill. The risks in business aren't like rolling dice where, if it's fair, skill doesn't matter and overall gains balance out losses. Instead, business risks resemble the tightrope walker's challenge of crossing Niagara; it can be easily managed by a skilled performer like Blondin, but it's incredibly dangerous for someone who isn’t steady and sure. Profits come not from the risks themselves but from the superior skill involved in managing those risks. They're not deducted from workers' earnings but are earned in the same way skilled labor is compensated. As long as some people have better organizational skills, judgment, and the ability to take risks, it's likely that profits will persist.

Profits are the share, or income, of the enterpriser for his skill in directing industry and in assuming the risks. Despite the complex influences, they are determined by his contribution to industry essentially as is the value of any skilled service.

Profits are the portion of income that the business owner earns for their expertise in managing operations and taking on risks. Although many factors come into play, they are fundamentally decided by their contribution to the industry, just like the value of any skilled service.


CHAPTER 32

PROFIT-SHARING, PRODUCERS' AND CONSUMERS' COÖPERATION

§ I. PROFIT-SHARING

Nature and definition of profit-sharing

1. Profit-sharing is rewarding labor with a share of the profits in addition to contract wages. The essential mark of profit-sharing is that the additional payment depends on the net profits of the whole business at the end of the year. It is not to be confused with a free gift, or with special privileges granted by the employer, such as lunch-rooms, bathrooms or houses at a low rent. Profit-sharing is a contract made in advance, not a free gift. Nor is it the same as a bonus or premium for a larger output, made contingent on the physical product, on the increased number of pieces turned out by the workmen, individually or in groups. Premium for output is given for something directly under the influence of the worker. The amount of profits is affected by the amount of output, but also by a number of other things that are quite outside the control of the workmen.

1. Profit-sharing is about giving employees a share of the profits in addition to their regular wages. The key aspect of profit-sharing is that this extra payment relies on the net profits of the entire business at the end of the year. It shouldn’t be confused with a free gift or special perks granted by the employer, like lunchrooms, bathrooms, or affordable housing. Profit-sharing is a prearranged contract, not a free gift. It also differs from a bonus or incentive for increased production, which depends on the worker's direct output, whether individually or in teams. A production bonus is awarded for something directly influenced by the worker. While profit amounts are impacted by output levels, they are also affected by various other factors that are beyond the workers' control.

The possibilities of profit-sharing

2. The purpose of the employer in adopting profit-sharing is to stimulate the industry of the workers, thus reducing waste and cost of labor and supervision. The employer adopting the plan does not intend to lose by it; he believes that if he can get his workmen to take an interest in the business his costs will be reduced. He offers to divide with them the resulting savings. There is, in every factory, greater or less waste of materials, destruction of tools, and[Pg 293] loss of time, that no rules or penalties can prevent. If the worker can be made to take a strong enough personal interest he will use care when the eye of the foreman is not upon him. The product also can be slightly increased in many ways by the workmen's exertions or suggestions. In some cases the quality of the work cannot be insured by the closest inspection as well as it can be by a small degree of personal interest. Either responsibility for the fault cannot be fixed, or the defect is one not measurable by any easily applied standard. Strikes are averted, good feeling is promoted, and contentment is furthered if the interest of the worker can be made to approach, and actually to be in harmony with, that of the employer. The economic result of the plan, if it can be made to work, must be to reduce the costs of these establishments below what they are. The crucial question is whether this alone insures that the costs will be less than those of competitors, thus giving a source out of which an increased amount, really a wage, can be paid to the laborer. This additional wage is made conditional on the employer's success in gaining a net profit on the year's business.

2. The goal of the employer in implementing profit-sharing is to motivate workers, which helps reduce waste and lower labor and supervision costs. The employer who adopts this plan doesn’t intend to lose money; he believes that encouraging his workers to be invested in the business will lower costs. He proposes to share the savings that result. In every factory, there is always some waste of materials, damage to tools, and[Pg 293] time lost that rules or punishments can’t fully prevent. If workers can develop a strong personal interest, they'll be more careful even when the foreman's not watching. Additionally, workers can often improve production in various ways through their efforts or ideas. Sometimes, maintaining quality can't be guaranteed by strict inspections as effectively as it can be achieved through a bit of personal investment. Either it’s hard to assign blame for a mistake, or the problem isn't easily measurable. Strikes can be avoided, positive relationships can be fostered, and satisfaction can be increased if workers' interests can align with those of the employer. The economic outcome of the plan, if successful, should lead to lower operating costs compared to current levels. The key question is whether this alone ensures that these costs will be less than those of competitors, providing a means to offer workers a higher salary. This additional pay depends on the employer achieving a net profit from the business over the year.

Its successes and failures

3. The profit-sharing plan is now successfully working in over one hundred firms in America and Europe. The plan was first tried in Paris by Leclaire, a house-painter. In house-painting there is often a great waste of materials and time by men working singly or in small groups in different parts of the city. By this new method Leclaire enlisted the aid of the workmen, reduced the costs, and increased the profits. It is a remarkable fact that the plan has been continued successfully by the same firm to the present time. The most important examples of profit-sharing in the United States are the Pillsbury Mills in Minneapolis, Procter and Gamble's soap-factories at Ivorydale, O., and the Nelson Mfg. Co. at Leclaire, Ill. In some cases both manufacturer and workman value the system highly. N. P. Gilman, the author of "Profit Sharing," puts the ratio of[Pg 294] successes very high. Others declare that the failures are mostly lost sight of and are very many. The proportion of business done in this way is not large. One hundred firms is a very small fraction of one per cent. of the total number of firms in Germany, France, England, and America. A still more important fact is that this method of remuneration did not spread in the ten years preceding 1900.

3. The profit-sharing plan is now successfully implemented in over one hundred companies in the U.S. and Europe. The plan was first tried in Paris by Leclaire, a house painter. In house painting, there's often a lot of waste in materials and time when workers operate alone or in small groups across different parts of the city. With this new approach, Leclaire got the workers involved, cut costs, and boosted profits. It's noteworthy that the plan has been successfully continued by the same company to this day. Some of the key examples of profit-sharing in the United States are the Pillsbury Mills in Minneapolis, Procter and Gamble's soap factories in Ivorydale, Ohio, and the Nelson Manufacturing Company in Leclaire, Illinois. In some cases, both manufacturers and workers highly appreciate the system. N. P. Gilman, the author of "Profit Sharing," rates the success ratio as[Pg 294] very high. Others argue that many failures are overlooked and actually quite numerous. The portion of business operating this way is not substantial. One hundred firms represent a very small fraction of one percent of the total number of firms in Germany, France, England, and the U.S. An even more significant point is that this method of compensation did not expand in the ten years leading up to 1900.

Objections to and difficulties in profit-sharing in practice

4. The failure of profit-sharing to grow is due to objections on the side both of the employer and of the workman. On the side of the workman there is the bookkeeping difficulty. He is suspicious, and he lacks knowledge of the business. If at the end of the year the books show no profits, the workman loses confidence, considers the plan to be mere deception, and rejects it. Moreover, the plan puts a limitation upon the workman's freedom to compete for better wages by changing his place of work. It is almost indispensable to make length of service a condition to the sharing of profits. Workmen coming and going, working only a few months, cannot be allowed to share; the percentage given to the others increases with length of employment. Whenever men are thus practically subject to a fine (equal to the amount of shared profits) if they accept a better position, there is danger of a covert lowering of wages. The plan tends to break up the trade-unions, which is one of the reasons that the employers like it, and is the reason that organized labor opposes it. The employer on his part objects to the interference with his management, the troublesome inspection of the books, and the constant grumbling and complaint of the workmen. It makes known the amount of his profits; if they are large, the advertising of his success invites competition; if they are small, publicity injures his credit and depresses the value of his property. In view of all these difficulties it is not surprising that while the plan often starts promisingly, it usually loses its efficiency after a short trial. Business methods are severely subject to the principle of the survival of the fittest.[Pg 295] Through competition and the survival of the firms that adopt improvements, better methods must eventually supplant poorer ones. If a method fails to spread when it has been tried for fifty years and all are free to adopt it, there must be some defects inherent in it. That must be our conclusion as to profit-sharing.

4. The reason profit-sharing hasn't expanded is due to objections from both employers and workers. Workers face bookkeeping issues. They’re skeptical and don’t have a good grasp of how the business works. If, at the end of the year, the books show no profits, workers lose trust, view the plan as a scam, and dismiss it. Plus, the plan limits workers' ability to seek better-paying jobs elsewhere. It's almost essential to make length of service a requirement for sharing profits. Workers who come and go, staying only a few months, shouldn’t be allowed to share; the percentage given to others grows with their time on the job. Whenever workers are practically penalized (by losing shared profits) for taking a better position, there’s a risk of secretly lowering wages. The plan also tends to undermine trade unions, which is one reason employers support it, while organized labor opposes it. On the employer's side, they dislike how it interferes with their management, the hassle of auditing the books, and the ongoing complaints from workers. It reveals how much profit they make; if profits are high, promoting success invites competition; if profits are low, the publicity harms their reputation and decreases the value of their business. Given all these challenges, it's no wonder that while the plan often starts off strong, it usually loses its effectiveness after a short period. Business practices are heavily influenced by the principle of survival of the fittest.[Pg 295] Through competition and the survival of firms that embrace improvements, better methods will eventually replace inferior ones. If a method hasn't gained traction after being tried for fifty years with everyone free to adopt it, there must be some inherent flaws. That should be our conclusion regarding profit-sharing.

Defective character of profit-sharing

5. It is usually better to make wages depend on the worker's efficiency rather than on the profits of the whole business. The strongest motive to efficiency is present when reward is connected immediately and directly with effort, not with some result only slightly under the worker's control. In profit-sharing the added share is only partially due to increased effort of the worker. Labor is but one of the groups of costs. Profits are the net result of many influences. Chief among these is the wisdom of the enterpriser in planning and conducting the business. The "profits" may be nothing, though the worker may be exerting himself to the utmost. The plan is, therefore, reactionary, not in accord with the general progress of the wage system, which is tending constantly to centralize responsibility, to put the risk into the hands of competent managers, and to secure to the worker a definite amount in advance, as high as conditions make possible. The system of premiums, or bonus payments, for output, gives in most cases better results and is rapidly spreading. It is sounder in conception and works better in practice. This premium depends on the increase by the laborer of the output of his particular machine or process as compared with a standard based on the experience of some definite period.

5. It's usually better for wages to be based on a worker's efficiency rather than on the overall profits of the business. The strongest motivation for efficiency comes when rewards are directly linked to effort, rather than tied to results that are only slightly under the worker’s control. In profit-sharing, the extra share is only partially due to the worker's increased effort. Labor is just one of the many costs involved. Profits are the end result of various factors. The most significant of these is the entrepreneur's skill in planning and managing the business. The "profits" might be non-existent, even if the worker is working as hard as possible. This plan is, therefore, outdated and doesn't align with the overall development of the wage system, which is increasingly focused on centralizing responsibility, placing risk in the hands of capable managers, and ensuring that workers receive a guaranteed amount up front, as high as conditions allow. The system of bonuses for output often yields better results and is growing in popularity. It’s fundamentally sound and performs better in practice. This bonus is based on the worker's increase in output from their specific machine or process compared to a standard established during a specific time frame.

§ II. PRODUCERS' COÖPERATION

Purpose of producers' coöperation

1. Producers' coöperation is the union of workers in a self-employing group to do away with any other enterpriser than themselves, and to secure for themselves the profits. Its object is not to do away with any return on the capital[Pg 296] investment. Capital may be borrowed either from outsiders or from the individual coöperators, and is paid a stipulated interest apart from the profits. The source of the gain is to be found in the saving of what the worker looks upon as the needless drain of profits into the pockets of the employer. The hope is that the enterpriser's function (if it is admitted that he has any useful function) will be performed by the workers collectively or through their representatives. They undertake to furnish brain as well as muscle, management as well as hand-work. The hope is even to increase the profits through increasing the stimulus to the workers and by saving in friction, disputes, and strikes.

1. Producers' cooperation is the coming together of workers in a self-managing group to eliminate any other business owner but themselves and to secure the profits for themselves. Its goal isn't to remove any return on the capital[Pg 296] investment. Capital can be borrowed from outsiders or from the individual cooperators and earns a predetermined interest separate from the profits. The source of profit comes from reducing what the worker sees as the unnecessary loss of profits to the employer. The hope is that the entrepreneur's role (if it is acknowledged that he has any useful role) will be fulfilled by the workers collectively or through their representatives. They promise to provide both intellectual and physical labor, management as well as hands-on work. There is even the hope of increasing profits by boosting motivation among workers and reducing friction, disputes, and strikes.

Its limited success

2. Practically the plan has been made to work in a comparatively few simple industries. The most notable examples of successful coöperation in America have been the cooper-shops in Minneapolis. There were a simple problem of costs, few and uniform materials, patterns, and qualities of product, few machines and much hand-labor, simple well-known processes, a sure local market. Mr. Lloyd, in a recent book, describes many successful societies in England, but they are all of a simple sort of industry, as agriculture and dairy-farming. Within the whole field of industry, this method of organization makes little if any progress. Most experiments have failed and the successful ones often become ordinary stock companies with the most able men in control. Therefore, whether losing or making money, they nearly all cease to exist as coöperative enterprises. This result has disappointed the prophecies of many wise men of seventy-five years ago. In the time of John Stuart Mill, great expectations were entertained of the future of productive coöperation, which was thought to be a solution of the whole social problem.

2. Basically, the plan has been implemented in a relatively small number of straightforward industries. The most noteworthy examples of successful cooperation in America have been the cooperatives in Minneapolis. There was a simple issue of costs, with few consistent materials, patterns, and product qualities, minimal machinery, and a lot of hand-labor, straightforward well-known processes, and a reliable local market. Mr. Lloyd, in a recent book, describes many successful societies in England, but they all belong to simple industries like agriculture and dairy farming. Across the entire industrial landscape, this method of organization makes little to no progress. Most experiments have failed, and the successful ones often turn into regular stock companies with the most capable individuals in charge. As a result, whether losing or making money, nearly all of them stop existing as cooperative enterprises. This outcome has disappointed the predictions of many wise thinkers from seventy-five years ago. During John Stuart Mill's time, there were high hopes for the future of productive cooperation, which was seen as a solution to the entire social problem.

Its main difficulty

3. The main difficulty in productive coöperation is to secure managing ability of a high order. There is no touchstone for business talent, no way of selecting it with any certainty in advance of trial. This selection is made hard[Pg 297] in coöperative shops by the jealousies and rivalries, and by the politics among the workmen. A man thus selected by his fellows finds it almost impossible to enforce discipline. In coöperation there is occasionally developed good business ability that might have remained dormant under the wage system; some workmen showing unusual capacity cease to be handicraftsmen. But the unwillingness on the part of the workers to pay high salaries results in the loss of able managers. Having demonstrated their ability, the leaders go to competing industries where their function is not in such bad repute, and where higher salaries can be earned; or they go into business independently, being able easily to get control of the necessary capital.

3. The main challenge in effective cooperation is finding top-notch management skills. There’s no reliable way to identify business talent ahead of time without testing it first. This selection process is made tougher[Pg 297] in cooperative workplaces due to jealousy, rivalry, and workplace politics among the employees. A person chosen by their peers finds it nearly impossible to maintain discipline. In cooperative settings, good business skills can sometimes emerge that might have stayed hidden under traditional wage systems; some workers with exceptional talent move beyond just being craftsmen. However, the workers' reluctance to offer high salaries often leads to the departure of capable managers. Once they prove their skills, these leaders often leave for competing industries where their role is more respected and where they can earn better pay; or they might start their own businesses, easily securing the necessary funding.

Coöperators under-value the enterpriser's function

4. Most coöperative schemes have suffered from a lack of good theory, an inability of the workers to see the importance of the enterpriser's service. Most men make a very imperfect analysis of the productive process. They see that a large part of the product does not go to the workmen; they see the gross amount going to the enterpriser, and they ignore the fact that this contains the cost of materials, interest on capital, and incidental expenses. They ignore further that the enterpriser's function is a productive and essential one. The theory of exploitation, or robbery, as explaining the employer's profits, is very commonly held in a more or less vague way by workmen. With a body of intelligent and thoroughly honest workmen, keenly alive to the truth, the dangers, and the risks of the enterprise, coöperation would be possible in many industries where now it is not. The producers' coöperative schemes usually stumble into an unsuspected pitfall. When a heedless and over-confident army ventures into an enemy's country without a knowledge of its geography, without a map, and without leaders that have been tested on the field of battle, the result can easily be foreseen.

4. Most cooperative initiatives have struggled due to a lack of solid theory and the workers' inability to recognize the importance of the entrepreneur's role. Most people do a very incomplete analysis of the production process. They notice that a large portion of the product does not go to the workers; they see the total amount going to the entrepreneur, but overlook the fact that this also includes the cost of materials, interest on capital, and additional expenses. They further ignore that the entrepreneur's role is productive and essential. The theory of exploitation, or robbery, as a way to explain the employer's profits, is often held more or less vaguely by workers. With a group of intelligent and genuinely honest workers, well aware of the truths, dangers, and risks of the enterprise, cooperation would be feasible in many industries where it currently is not. Producers' cooperative schemes often fall into an unexpected trap. When an overconfident group ventures into enemy territory without understanding the geography, lacking a map, and without leaders that have been proven on the battlefield, the outcome can be easily predicted.

§ III. CONSUMERS' COÖPERATION

Nature and kinds of consumers' coöperation

1. Consumers' coöperation is the union of a number of buyers to save for themselves the profits of the merchants or agents. There are many classes of consumers' coöperation, but the chief ones are: (1) to sell goods (retail stores); (2) to provide insurance (coöperative insurance companies); (3) to provide credit or capital (coöperative banks). These are also productive enterprises, for the merchant's work adds value to the goods, the insurance company and its agent do a real service, the profits of the small bank are, ordinarily, earned fairly under existing conditions. The terms producers' and consumers' coöperation merely set in contrast the part of the productive process that is undertaken. Producers' coöperation is concerned with the earlier steps, usually stopping when the product is disposed of to wholesale or retail merchants. Consumers' coöperation (often called distributive coöperation) is concerned with the later steps, the placing of a consumption good (rarely also productive agents) into the hands of the final user. It imparts the same value to goods that the retail merchant does. The one thing this class of coöperators is sure of when they begin is a number of consumers to make use of the service or products they purpose to supply; hence the name.

1. Consumer cooperation is the joining together of several buyers to save the profits that would go to merchants or agents. There are various types of consumer cooperation, but the main ones include: (1) selling goods (retail stores); (2) providing insurance (cooperative insurance companies); (3) offering credit or capital (cooperative banks). These are also productive enterprises, as the merchant's efforts add value to the goods, the insurance company and its agent provide a genuine service, and the profits of small banks are generally earned fairly under current conditions. The terms producers' and consumers' cooperation simply highlight the part of the production process they focus on. Producers' cooperation deals with the earlier stages and typically stops once the product is sold to wholesale or retail merchants. Consumer cooperation (often called distributive cooperation) focuses on the later stages, getting a consumer good (rarely also productive agents) into the hands of the end user. It adds the same value to goods as the retail merchant does. The one thing this group of cooperators knows for sure when they start is that there are enough consumers to use the services or products they aim to provide; hence the name.

Costliness of competitive mercantile business

2. The waste of competitive mercantile business is the source from which it is expected that the savings of the coöperative enterprise will come. It is a great expense to the retail dealer to secure a body of customers. Rent of store-room, clerk hire, interest on invested capital are fixed charges, which can be met only on condition of a regular and frequent turnover of the stock. To attract customers the dealer must have a well-located store, must advertise, keep open long hours, and pay idle clerks. Frequently he must give credit, raising the price enough to cover[Pg 299] the expense of bookkeeping, collection, bad accounts, and loss of interest. The public's likings, whims, lack of judgment, and lack of business analysis make these charges necessary. There are many communities where it would be impossible to carry on a cash business even at considerably lower prices. Customers are exacting and require the costly delivery of small packages; two horses and a driver must travel two miles to deliver a spool of thread or a half-dozen oranges. Frequent changes of fashion and the shifting of customers from one store to another keep the merchant always insecure in his trade. A number of buyers mutually agreeing to pay cash, to buy at certain times, to place all their orders with one store, to go to a cheaper location, down an alley or into a basement, can save much of this cost on one condition: that the management approaches in its efficiency that of ordinary competitive business. In spite of all these advantages, if there is inefficient management the final cost will be no less than that of ordinary business.

2. The inefficiency of competitive retail businesses is where the savings of cooperative enterprises are expected to come from. Retailers face significant costs to build a customer base. Store rent, employee salaries, and interest on invested capital are fixed expenses that can only be covered through consistent and frequent sales. To draw in customers, retailers need a well-placed store, must advertise, maintain long hours, and pay staff who may not be busy. Often, they also have to extend credit, which means raising prices enough to cover[Pg 299] expenses related to bookkeeping, collections, bad debts, and lost interest. The public’s preferences, fancies, lack of judgment, and little business insight make these costs unavoidable. In many places, it would be impossible to run a cash-only business even with significantly lower prices. Customers are demanding and expect the expensive delivery of small items; for example, two horses and a driver might have to travel two miles just to deliver a spool of thread or a few oranges. Constant changes in fashion and customers switching from one store to another leave retailers in a vulnerable position. If a group of buyers agrees to pay cash, shop at specific times, place all their orders with one store, and choose a less expensive location, like down an alley or in a basement, they can save on some of these costs, but only if the management is nearly as efficient as that of standard competitive businesses. Despite these potential benefits, if the management is inefficient, the overall cost will be no lower than that of typical retail operations.

The more successful coöperative stores

3. Despite the possibilities of saving, most coöperative stores fail through a lack of good management. Note first the greater successes. Since 1842, from which time it dates, the coöperative-store movement has progressed steadily in England, where the scores of retail societies are federated and own large wholesale stores. The long experience has developed good methods and a conservatism almost inconceivable to an American mind. They are practically great stock companies in which one can buy a share at a small cost and become a purchaser at usual prices, receiving a dividend later according to the amount of his purchases. Coöperative stores in American universities are generally successful, apparently because they don't coöperate. Some get into politics and go the way of the wicked. The survivors gravitate into the hands of a committee of the faculty, which tries to employ an efficient manager, and administers the business as a public[Pg 300] trust without private profit. The wastefulness of multiplying orders for text-books to be used by a class whose number is definitely known in advance, and the comparatively uniform character of the supplies, make economy peculiarly easy in this case. A large part of the services of the coöperative store, however, are indirect; it reduces and regulates the charges in the stores near by.

3. Even though there are opportunities for savings, most cooperative stores fail due to poor management. First, let’s look at the greater successes. Since 1842, when it started, the cooperative store movement has steadily advanced in England, where numerous retail societies are joined together and own large wholesale stores. Their long experience has led to effective methods and a conservatism that seems almost unimaginable to an American perspective. They essentially function like large stock companies, allowing individuals to buy a small share and shop at regular prices, later receiving a dividend based on how much they purchased. Cooperative stores at American universities tend to do well, likely because they don’t actually cooperate. Some get involved in politics and fall into disarray. The ones that survive usually end up managed by a faculty committee, which tries to hire an efficient manager and runs the business as a public[Pg 300] trust without any private profit. The inefficiency of placing multiple orders for textbooks needed by a class with a set number of students makes saving particularly easy in this case. However, a significant portion of the cooperative store's benefits is indirect; it lowers and regulates prices in nearby stores.

The failures and their causes

Nearly all the Granger stores, started thirty years ago in great numbers, and most of the coöperative stores among American workmen, have failed. The failure is easily explained by the ignorance of danger, by lack of harmony, by credit sales, and by inefficient management. The wastes of competitive business are partly a tax imposed upon men (taken collectively) by their lack of business method; the community is not intelligent enough, honest enough, or self-sacrificing enough to do business in the most economical way. Partly they are the price paid for variety and change, and for the cherished American right "to kick"—something difficult for the members of a coöperative store to do without hurting themselves.

Nearly all the Granger stores, which started in large numbers thirty years ago, along with most of the cooperative stores among American workers, have failed. The reasons for this failure are clear: ignorance of risks, lack of teamwork, reliance on credit sales, and poor management. The inefficiencies of competitive business represent a cost that people (collectively) bear due to their lack of business acumen; the community isn’t informed enough, honest enough, or willing to sacrifice enough to do business in the most efficient way. Some of these inefficiencies are also the cost of diversity and change, as well as the valued American right to complain—something that’s hard for members of a cooperative store to do without negatively impacting themselves.

Profit-sharing and coöperation in relation to the enterpriser
Continued need of the enterpriser

4. The experience with these plans verifies the analysis of the enterpriser's function: pure profits are the earnings of a productive service. Comparing these three plans, they are seen to be alike in seeking to make workers share some of the profits, to change the destination to which profits would go. The first would create profits by the effort of the workers, and give them a part of the saving. The second would have collective workers perform the enterpriser's work in the factory and get his reward. The third would have collective buyers do the work of the merchant and save his profits and other costs. The last is the easiest to do. Profit-sharing is next in difficulty, and producers' coöperation is the hardest of all to put into practice. In some cases, under some conditions, the enterpriser's services may be more economically performed than at present, for the waste is great. But taking men as they are and things as they are, in most[Pg 301] places the enterpriser's service is necessary and must be paid for. His contribution to the success of the industry depends on his nature and ability, and it can be distinguished theoretically and practically from the contribution made by the workmen. Nothing but changes in human nature, in education, and in morality can diminish the necessity for his service.

4. The experience with these plans confirms the analysis of the entrepreneur's role: pure profits are the earnings from providing a productive service. Comparing these three plans, they are similar in attempting to allow workers to share some of the profits, altering where those profits would go. The first would generate profits through the efforts of the workers and give them a portion of the savings. The second would have collective workers carry out the entrepreneur's tasks in the factory and receive his rewards. The third would have collective buyers take on the work of the merchant and save his profits and other costs. The last option is the easiest to implement. Profit-sharing comes next in terms of difficulty, while producers' cooperation is the hardest to put into practice. In some cases, under certain conditions, the entrepreneur's services could potentially be performed more economically than they are now, as there is a lot of waste. However, considering people as they are and situations as they are, in most[Pg 301] cases, the entrepreneur's service remains essential and must be compensated. His contribution to the success of the industry relies on his character and skills, and it can be theoretically and practically distinguished from the contributions made by the workers. Only changes in human nature, education, and morality can reduce the need for his service.


CHAPTER 33

MONOPOLY PROFITS

§ I. NATURE OF MONOPOLY

Difficulty of fixing the meaning of monopoly

1. The term monopoly is used loosely and in many senses. In popular discussion monopoly means almost any wealthy corporation or the power the corporation possesses, a power which is usually thought of as oppressive. Even economists have held the vaguest ideas regarding monopoly. The recent rise of trusts and monopolies has given a large new body of facts bearing upon the subject, but all the resulting discussion by the public and by economists has not brought agreement upon a definition entirely satisfactory. When usage has not settled upon any one meaning, the selection of a definition is in a measure arbitrary, though it may be guided by logic and considerations of expediency. Let us state the various meanings and indicate the one adopted in this discussion.

1. The term monopoly is used loosely and in many ways. In everyday conversations, monopoly often refers to almost any wealthy corporation or the power that corporation holds, which is typically seen as oppressive. Even economists have had very vague ideas about monopoly. The recent increase in trusts and monopolies has provided a significant amount of new information on the subject, but all the discussions from the public and economists have not led to a universally accepted definition. When there isn’t an agreed meaning, choosing a definition can be somewhat arbitrary, though it might be influenced by reason and practical considerations. Let’s outline the different meanings and clarify the one used in this discussion.

Monopoly is not merely scarcity

2. Monopoly should not be used as synonymous with scarcity. Scarcity is the essential condition of all value. The simplest things—bricks, sand, the commonest unskilled labor—would have no value were there not a degree of scarcity relative to the wants that may be gratified. "Monopoly," whatever else it means, always conveys the idea of some exceptional kind of scarcity, scarcity due in part to some source or cause not ordinarily present. It is a bad practice in definition to apply two words to one idea, leaving the other idea unnamed, as is done when monopoly is made synonymous with scarcity. Both words are needed. Such a[Pg 303] usage unfortunately is common in economic literature. Many economic writers, for example, have called landownership monopoly, saying that land being the work of nature cannot be increased by men, and therefore must always be scarce. Even if it were true that in the economic sense land could be produced by man, there still would be confusion here between a general class of goods and a special thing. The fact that a particular field cannot be duplicated does not make a monopoly of land as a whole, any more than the existence of desert land in Arizona makes land valueless or a free good. Nor is a land-owner a monopolist any more than is the owner of a valuable machine. The owner of forty acres of land worth four hundred dollars, or the owner of a village lot worth a hundred dollars, can hardly be called a monopolist. It leads to absurdity to use the word monopoly with reference to landownership indiscriminately. Neither mere scarcity nor the limitation of natural stores should be called monopoly when ownership is scattered and combination between owners does not exist.

2. Monopoly shouldn't be used interchangeably with scarcity. Scarcity is the fundamental condition for all value. The simplest things—bricks, sand, the most basic unskilled labor—would hold no value if there wasn't some level of scarcity relative to the needs that can be satisfied. "Monopoly," whatever else it means, always implies a specific type of scarcity, one that comes partly from a source or cause that isn't typically present. It's not good practice to use two words to describe one idea while leaving the other idea unnamed, as is done when monopoly is equated with scarcity. Both terms are necessary. Such a[Pg 303] usage is unfortunately common in economic literature. Many economic writers, for instance, have referred to landownership as monopoly, claiming that since land is a natural resource and can't be increased by humans, it must always be scarce. Even if it were true that land could be produced by humans in an economic sense, there would still be confusion between a general category of goods and a specific item. The fact that a particular plot of land can't be duplicated doesn't create a monopoly over land as a whole, just as the existence of barren land in Arizona doesn't render land worthless or a free good. Moreover, a landowner isn't a monopolist any more than the owner of a valuable machine is. The owner of forty acres of land worth four hundred dollars or the owner of a village lot worth a hundred dollars can hardly be labeled a monopolist. It's absurd to use the term monopoly in relation to landownership without distinction. Neither simple scarcity nor the limitation of natural resources should be referred to as monopoly when ownership is dispersed, and there is no combination between owners.

Monopoly is not merely superior economic power

3. The ability of superior material agents and of skilled workers to secure higher returns than do poor ones does not constitute monopoly. The free competition assumed in abstract discussions of value, does not mean equal capacity or efficiency, but the legal freedom and personal willingness to move a productive agent into the highest industrial place it is capable of holding. The rocky field does not compete with the fertile one in the sense that it can yield the same uses. The field fit only for potatoes does not compete with those rare and favored localities that can raise the best wines. The gardener earning two dollars a day does not compete with the skilled physician with an income of twenty thousand dollars a year, for he has not the economic capacity to do so; but he is free to compete (as is the owner of the rocky field) unless law, caste, class legislation, social prejudice, or some other objective factor forbids. Anything, however, that prevents the labor or capital of[Pg 304] buyers or sellers from application for which they are fitted, defeats free competition. To use the term monopoly of any and every limitation of economic ability is to extend it to every case of value. To use it of the high wages of skilled workmen, where no union to suppress competition exists among them, is to make it a colorless synonym of scarcity. It should be confined to a narrower and more exclusive use. Some special kinds of limitation should be connected with the idea of monopoly.

3. The fact that more skilled workers and better resources can earn more than less skilled workers and poor resources doesn't mean there's a monopoly. Free competition in discussions about value doesn't imply everyone has the same skills or efficiency, but rather that individuals have the legal freedom and personal desire to move their resources to the best possible position in the industry. A rocky field doesn’t compete with a fertile one in terms of producing the same crops. A field only suitable for potatoes isn't in competition with those unique locations that can produce the finest wines. A gardener making two dollars a day isn't competing with a skilled doctor earning twenty thousand dollars a year because he doesn't have the economic means to do so; however, he is free to compete (just like the owner of the rocky field) unless laws, social classes, or other external factors prevent it. Anything that stops workers or investors from pursuing the opportunities they're suited for undermines free competition. Calling every limitation on economic ability a monopoly broadens the term to almost every instance of value. Using it to describe the high earnings of skilled workers, where there's no union to limit competition among them, turns it into a vague synonym for scarcity. The term should be used more specifically and reserved for particular kinds of restrictions related to the idea of monopoly.

Monopoly consists in unified control

4. The limitation connected with monopoly is not that of economic capacity but that of ownership and control. The derivation of the word from the Greek points to the general thought: monos, alone, poléo, to sell, a single seller, the sole source of supply in a given market. The term was first used in England of special grants or patents of monopoly from the crown to make or deal in specified articles, such as soap, candles, etc. The political power of the state created and defended the monopoly. This policy is pursued in a limited degree to-day for the encouragement of invention, in the granting of patents and copyrights. In the current definition, "The exclusive right, power, or privilege of dealing in some article or trading in some market," the term "dealing in" is well chosen, for it is broad enough to cover cases of buying as well as selling, and includes power derived from political as well as from other sources. But the term "exclusive" is too absolute, allows of no gradations, and makes the definition applicable only in the rarest cases.

4. The limitation associated with a monopoly isn't about economic capability but about ownership and control. The origin of the word comes from Greek, pointing to the general idea: monos, meaning alone, and poléo, to sell; it refers to a single seller, the only source of supply in a specific market. The term was first used in England to describe special grants or patents of monopoly from the crown for making or dealing in specified items, like soap, candles, and so on. The political power of the state established and protected the monopoly. Today, this policy is still pursued to a limited degree to encourage innovation, through the granting of patents and copyrights. In the current definition, "The exclusive right, power, or privilege to deal in a particular item or trade in a specific market," the phrase "dealing in" is appropriately chosen, as it is broad enough to include both buying and selling, and encompasses power derived from political as well as other sources. However, the term "exclusive" is too absolute, does not allow for variations, and makes the definition relevant only in the rarest situations.

Definition of monopoly
Monopoly limits supply

5. Monopoly is such a degree of control over the supply of goods in a given market that a net gain will result to the seller if a portion is withheld. Every producer has control over some agents and some portion of the supply of products; but ordinarily the portion controlled by any one is so small that withholding it entirely from sale would not cause the market price to rise in any appreciable degree. The producer in such a case regulates his action as if the market price were fixed beyond his control, and he uses his productive[Pg 305] agents fully up to the point where costs equal price on the marginal unit of product. A skilled worker getting five dollars a day loses that sum every day he is idle. A landowner whose land can command a competitive rent of ten dollars an acre must take that sum or less, or nothing; he cannot get more. How can a net gain ever result from a smaller sale? As a reduction of supply results in a higher price, it is possible, as is seen in the paradox of value, for a situation to arise in the case of some goods, where a smaller number of units yield a larger sum in the market than a larger number of units. But the seller's interest lies not in the increase of total sales, but in that of net gains. Net gains, being the product of the number of units sold multiplied by the gain on each unit, increase at a much faster rate than do total sales. The existence of monopoly power in any degree depends therefore on several factors: the effect of contraction of supply in raising prices, the effect on costs, the number of units remaining in the ownership of the one contracting supply, and the possibility of preventing others from increasing supply later to profit by the higher prices.

5. A monopoly is when someone has so much control over the supply of goods in a specific market that the seller benefits financially by holding back some of that supply. Every producer has control over certain resources and some share of the product supply; however, typically, the amount controlled by any individual is so small that completely withholding it from the market doesn’t significantly raise the market price. In such cases, the producer acts as if the market price is set beyond their influence, and they utilize their productive[Pg 305] resources fully up until the point where costs equal the price for the last unit produced. A skilled worker earning five dollars a day loses that amount for every day they don’t work. A landowner whose land can rent for a competitive price of ten dollars an acre must accept that amount or less, or nothing at all; they can’t charge more. How can holding back sales ever result in a net gain? When the supply decreases, the price can rise, which demonstrates the paradox of value: for certain goods, having fewer units can result in a higher overall revenue than having more units. However, a seller's focus is not on boosting total sales but on increasing net gains. Net gains, calculated as the number of units sold multiplied by the profit on each unit, grow at a much quicker pace than total sales. Therefore, the existence of monopoly power to any degree depends on several factors: how reducing supply raises prices, the impact on costs, the number of units still owned by the one limiting the supply, and the ability to prevent others from increasing supply later to take advantage of the higher prices.

§ II. KINDS OF MONOPOLY

The sources of monopoly power
Political monopoly

1. Monopoly gets its power from political, economic, and commercial sources. A political monopoly derives its power of control from a special grant from the government, forbidding others to engage in that business. The typical political monopoly is that conferred by a crown patent bestowing the exclusive right to carry on a certain business. A second kind is that conferred by a patent for invention, or the copyright on books, the object of which is to stimulate invention, research, and writing by giving the full control and protection of the government to the inventor and writer or their assignees. In this case the privilege is socially earned by the monopolist; it is not gotten for nothing. Moreover, the patent is limited in time, expires and becomes a social possession.[Pg 306] A third kind is a government monopoly for purposes of revenue. In France, the government controls the tobacco trade, and the high price charged for tobacco makes the monopoly yield a large income. A fourth kind are public franchises for public service, as street-railways, lights, gas, waterworks, etc. These are granted to private capitalists to induce them to invest capital in something which has public utility.

1. Monopoly gets its power from political, economic, and commercial sources. A political monopoly gets its control from a special government grant that prevents others from participating in that business. The most common type of political monopoly is a crown patent, which gives exclusive rights to conduct a specific business. Another type is granted by a patent for inventions or a copyright on books, aimed at encouraging invention, research, and writing by providing full government control and protection to inventors and authors or their assignees. In this case, the privilege is earned by the monopolist; it's not handed out for free. Also, the patent has a time limit, eventually expires, and becomes a public asset.[Pg 306] A third type is a government monopoly aimed at generating revenue. In France, the government manages the tobacco industry, and the high prices for tobacco result in significant income from the monopoly. A fourth type includes public franchises for public services, like streetcars, lighting, gas, water systems, etc. These are given to private investors to encourage them to put money into ventures that benefit the public.

Economic monopoly

Economic monopoly arises when the ownership of scarce natural agents, as mines, land, water-power, comes under the control of one man or one group of men who agree on a price. Economic monopoly is a result of private property that is undesigned by the government or by society. It is exceptional, considering the whole range of private property, but it is important. The oil-wells embracing the main sources of the world's supply have come under one control. One corporation may control so many of the richest iron-mines of the country as to be able to fix a price different from that which would result under competition. Coal-mines, especially those of some peculiar and limited kind, such as anthracite, appear to become easily an object of monopolization. Economic monopoly merges into political monopolies, such as patents and franchises. Private property is a political institution designed to further social welfare, and only rarely is any particular property a monopoly. Private control of great natural resources doubtless would have been prohibited had it been foreseen.

Economic monopoly happens when a single person or group of people controls valuable natural resources like mines, land, or water power and agrees on a price. It's an outcome of private property that isn't regulated by the government or society. While it's uncommon in the broader context of private property, it holds significant importance. The oil reserves that account for most of the world’s supply are controlled by one entity. One company might control enough of the richest iron mines in the country to set a price that's different from what would occur in a competitive market. Coal mines, especially specific types like anthracite, are particularly susceptible to monopolization. Economic monopoly overlaps with political monopolies, like patents and franchises. Private property is a political system intended to promote social well-being, and only occasionally does any specific piece of property turn into a monopoly. It's likely that private control of major natural resources would have been banned if it had been anticipated.

Commercial monopoly

Commercial monopoly, variously called contractual, organized, or capitalistic monopoly, arises where men unite their wealth to control a market, to overpower or intimidate opposition, and to keep out or limit competition by the mere magnitude of their wealth. These various kinds so merge into each other that they cannot always be distinguished in practice. A patent may help a capitalistic monopoly in getting control of a market; great wealth may enable a company to get control of rare natural resources.

Commercial monopoly, also known as contractual, organized, or capitalistic monopoly, occurs when people combine their wealth to dominate a market, overpower or intimidate competitors, and exclude or restrict competition simply by the sheer size of their wealth. These different types often blend into one another to the point that they can’t always be easily identified in practice. A patent might assist a capitalistic monopoly in taking control of a market; substantial wealth may allow a company to acquire rare natural resources.

Special classes of monopoly

2. Monopolies may, for special purposes, be classified also as selling and buying, producing and trading, lasting and temporary, general and local. The terms selling and buying monopoly explain themselves, though the latter conflicts with the etymology. Under conditions of barter the selling and the buying monopoly would be the same thing in two aspects. A selling monopoly is by far the more common, but a buying monopoly may be connected with it. A large oil-refining corporation that sells most of the product may by various methods succeed in driving out the competitors who would buy the crude oil. It thus becomes practically the only outlet for the oil product, and the owners of the land thus must share their ownership with the buying monopoly by accepting, within certain limits, the price it fixes. The Hudson Bay Company, dealing in furs, had practically this sort of power in North America. Many instances can be found, yet, relatively to the selling monopolies, those of the buying kind are rare. A producing monopoly is one controlling the manufacture or the source of supply of an article; a trading monopoly is one controlling the avenues of commerce between the source and the consumers. Monopolies are lasting or temporary, according to the duration of control. By far the larger number are of the temporary sort, because high prices strongly stimulate efforts to develop other sources of supply. Yet the average profits of a monopoly may be large throughout a succession of periods of high and low prices. Monopolies are general or local, according to the extent of territory where their power is felt. At its maximum where transportation and other costs most effectually shut out competition, monopoly power shades off to zero on the border-line of competitive territory.

2. Monopolies can be categorized for specific purposes as selling and buying, producing and trading, lasting and temporary, and general and local. The terms selling and buying monopoly are straightforward, though the latter contradicts its origin. In a barter system, selling and buying monopolies are essentially the same in two aspects. A selling monopoly is much more common, but it can be linked to a buying monopoly. A large oil-refining company that sells most of its products may use various tactics to drive out competitors that would purchase crude oil. This way, it effectively becomes the only outlet for oil products, and landowners must accept, within certain limits, the prices set by the buying monopoly. The Hudson Bay Company, which traded in furs, had this kind of power in North America. While there are many examples, buying monopolies are relatively rare compared to selling monopolies. A producing monopoly controls the manufacture or source of supply of a product, while a trading monopoly controls the pathways of commerce between the source and consumers. Monopolies can be lasting or temporary, depending on how long they maintain control. Most are temporary since high prices encourage efforts to find alternative sources of supply. However, the average profits of a monopoly can remain substantial throughout various periods of high and low prices. Monopolies can be general or local, based on how broad their influence is. Their power peaks where transportation and other costs effectively block competition, fading to zero at the edge of competitive territories.

Relativity of monopoly
The test of monopoly

3. Degrees of power to affect price result from varying extent of control; monopoly is a relative term. The term monopoly by its derivation has reference to a single seller; but there are other thoughts in the concept. Monopoly has reference also to the amount of the supply controlled. The[Pg 308] frequent use of the adjectives partial, limited, and virtual are implied but usually superfluous recognitions of the relative character of monopoly. Ownership of a particular knife, pencil, book, makes one the unique seller of it, but confers no monopoly power, as the power of substitution is practically absolute; the welfare of no one depends in any appreciable measure on that particular pencil. Ownership of an important fraction of an entire species of goods gives more power to affect value. One owning a large part of the desirable building sites or houses in town may gain by occasionally letting one stand vacant in order to drive better bargains with tenants. A trade-union may control most of the labor-supply of one kind in a town. But the test of monopoly is that a gain results from a higher price and fewer sales. It begins at the point where there is a motive to limit the supply in accordance with the paradox of value. The control of an entire species of goods gives price-fixing power, limited only by substitution of goods. Even though one person controlled all the coal and wood in any market, their prices still would be limited. If there were but one possible source of meat-supply, most people could live without meat. The monopoly of great species of goods can thus be seen gradually to merge from one grade into another. It is a matter of quality as well as quantity. There is more or less of it in the different industries, and, as noted in the preceding paragraph, it varies over time and territory.

3. Degrees of power to affect price come from different levels of control; monopoly is a relative term. By definition, monopoly means a single seller; however, there are other aspects involved. Monopoly also relates to the amount of supply that is controlled. The[Pg 308] frequent use of terms like partial, limited, and virtual are often implied but usually unnecessary acknowledgments of the relative nature of monopoly. Owning a specific knife, pencil, or book makes someone the sole seller of that item, but it doesn't grant any real monopoly power because the power to substitute it is nearly limitless; no one's well-being significantly relies on that particular pencil. Owning a significant portion of an entire category of goods gives more influence over value. Someone who owns a large share of desirable building lots or houses in town can benefit by occasionally leaving one vacant to negotiate better deals with tenants. A trade union might control most of the labor supply of a certain type in a town. However, the true test of monopoly is that a higher price leads to fewer sales. It starts where there’s a motivation to restrict supply according to the paradox of value. Controlling an entire category of goods provides price-setting power, constrained only by the substitution of goods. Even if one person controlled all the coal and wood in a market, their prices would still be limited. If there were only one supplier of meat, most people could go without it. The monopoly of large categories of goods can thus be seen as gradually merging from one level into another. It involves both quality and quantity. Different industries exhibit varying degrees of it, and as mentioned in the previous paragraph, it changes over time and location.

§ III. THE FIXING OF A MONOPOLY PRICE

Forces governing competitive prices

1. A competitive producer gets the highest price that will permit him to dispose of his product. The enterpriser seeks to get the highest price for his product that the market will afford. His ability to continue making a profit at a lower price does not induce him to reduce the price unless the reduction is to his interest. The ordinary competing manufacturer is limited in his price by two things: first,[Pg 309] his customers may cease to buy such articles entirely and may substitute other goods if the price is too high; secondly, they may buy of other sellers. Between his wish to keep the price up, and the customer's wish to buy as cheaply as he can, the price is fixed at a point where there is no inducement for others to come in and reduce his sales, or for him to seek a better market. There may be under these conditions a potential but very limited monopoly power. The sole druggist in a small town might occasionally get extortionate prices from particular customers in times of dire need, but he would thus drive away much of his custom, and would tempt a fairer and less grasping competitor to come in. Thus, when men and capital are free to come and go, there results an average or normal return for ability and agents of a certain grade. Prices come to equilibrium where each is selling his total product.

1. A competitive producer aims to get the highest price that will allow him to sell his product. The entrepreneur tries to maximize the price for his product based on market conditions. His ability to continue earning a profit at a lower price doesn't lead him to lower the price unless it benefits him. A typical competing manufacturer has two main limits on his pricing: first,[Pg 309] if the price is too high, customers might stop buying those items altogether and choose different products; second, they might purchase from other sellers. The balance between his desire to keep prices high and the customer's desire to buy for less establishes a price point that discourages others from entering the market and undercutting his sales or motivates him to find better market opportunities. Under these conditions, there may be limited monopoly power. For example, the only pharmacist in a small town might occasionally charge inflated prices to certain customers during urgent situations, but doing so could alienate a lot of his business and attract a more reasonable competitor. Therefore, when people and capital are free to move, an average or normal return results for individuals and resources of a certain level. Prices reach an equilibrium where each seller is able to sell their entire product.

Monopoly's greater control of price

2. Where a monopoly exists to a greater or less degree, there is less reason to fear loss of custom to competitors. The degree of control determines the fear of competitors. If the control is slight, a very small rise of price will bring in competitors. The monopoly profits in this case either must be very small or they will be very brief. Those outside, controlling a large supply, will be tempted by large profits to market it at once and to increase it as fast as possible. Even where a large part of the supply is under one control, the fear of substitution puts a limit on the price demanded. If the control were extended to all wealth, the monopolist would be the absolute despot of the lives of his fellows. But as things are, the monopolist aims, just as the competitor does, to get the price that gives the maximum gain. The monopolist, however, is in a more or less favored position, as he can raise his price considerably before losing the most of his customers. Much depends on whether the costs increase or decrease as output grows. Where a large increase in output greatly decreases the cost, lower price may leave a larger margin between the cost and the selling price. A[Pg 310] general monopoly price is therefore not an unlimited price. It is higher than the competitive price if the same cost of production is maintained. It may conceivably be lower than the former competitive price if the economies of combination greatly reduce the cost and justify a large increase of the output.

2. Where a monopoly exists to a greater or lesser extent, there's less reason to worry about losing customers to competitors. The level of control affects how much competitors are feared. If the control is weak, even a small increase in price will attract competitors. In this case, the monopoly profits must either be very small or will only last a short time. Those on the outside, who control a large supply, will be tempted by big profits to sell it immediately and increase it as quickly as possible. Even if a large portion of the supply is controlled by one entity, the fear of customers switching to alternatives keeps the price in check. If control extended to all wealth, the monopolist would have absolute power over the lives of others. But as it stands, the monopolist aims, like the competitor, to set a price that maximizes profit. However, the monopolist is in a relatively better position, as they can raise their price significantly before losing most of their customers. Much depends on whether costs rise or fall as production increases. When a significant increase in output greatly lowers costs, a lower price can leave a bigger gap between cost and selling price. A[Pg 310] general monopoly price is therefore not an unlimited price. It is higher than the competitive price if the same production costs are kept. It could even be lower than the previous competitive price if the efficiencies from combining resources significantly reduce costs and justify a large increase in output.

Discriminating monopoly rates

3. A monopoly often seeks to avoid a general market price, and it adjusts its charge in each small market separately. This is a most important aspect of the monopoly problem and a most important modification of the principle just stated. A market price is the expression of the least urgent demand that aids in carrying off a given supply. It is a maxim that there can be but one price at a time in a given market. The baker ordinarily sells the loaf at the same price to every one buying a given quantity. If he had a monopoly of the bread-supply, however, he might deal with each customer separately, ascertain, by personal inquiry into the lives of the citizens and by the aid of a force of detectives, just how much each could or would pay rather than do without bread. The policy of varying prices is thus followed by monopolies, though usually in a less inquisitorial way, to enable them to get the highest possible returns. Under the name of "charging what the traffic will bear," it is practiced by the railroads as local and personal discrimination. The endurance of some communities and of some individuals being greater than that of others, the burden is adjusted to the back, being made not as light but as heavy as each can be forced to bear.

3. A monopoly often tries to avoid a general market price and adjusts its charges in each smaller market separately. This is a crucial aspect of the monopoly issue and an important modification of the principle just mentioned. A market price reflects the least urgent demand that helps absorb a certain supply. It’s a rule that there can only be one price at a time in a given market. Typically, a baker sells a loaf of bread at the same price to everyone buying a specific amount. However, if he had a monopoly on the bread supply, he could negotiate with each customer individually, finding out through inquiries into the lives of local residents and with the help of detectives exactly how much each person could or would pay instead of going without bread. Monopolies often follow the strategy of varying prices—though typically in a less intrusive manner—to achieve the highest possible profits. This practice, known as "charging what the traffic will bear," is used by railroads as local and personal discrimination. The capacity of different communities and individuals varies, so the burden is adjusted according to their ability to pay, becoming not lighter but as heavy as each can be made to endure.

Low rates to destroy competitors

Large monopolies dealing in commodities use an adaptation of this method to kill off small competitors who, within a certain district, sell at less than the monopoly price. Prices are suddenly reduced in that community below cost until, the small competitor being ruined, the monopoly rate is reëstablished perhaps higher than before. Fear of suffering a like fate prevents others from attempting competition even when prices offer a great attraction and give a high monopoly profit.

Large monopolies that deal in commodities use a variation of this strategy to eliminate small competitors who sell for less than the monopoly price in a specific area. They suddenly drop prices in that community below cost until the small competitor is driven out of business, after which the monopoly price is reestablished, possibly even higher than before. The fear of experiencing a similar fate deters others from trying to compete, even when prices seem very appealing and promise a significant monopoly profit.

The source of monopolistic profits

The profits of monopoly can be explained by the ordinary laws of value, yet evidently they form a peculiar economic and social problem. They appear to be due not to the services of the enterpriser in increasing production, but to his success in limiting it. There is, therefore, an antisocial element in them not found in the profits of ordinary industry. This deserves further and closer study.

The profits from a monopoly can be understood through the usual laws of value, but clearly, they present a unique economic and social issue. These profits seem to arise not from the entrepreneur's efforts to boost production, but from their ability to restrict it. Consequently, there is an antisocial aspect to these profits that isn't present in the profits of normal industry. This warrants deeper and more detailed examination.


CHAPTER 34

GROWTH OF TRUSTS AND COMBINATIONS IN THE UNITED STATES

§ I. GROWTH OF LARGE INDUSTRY IN THE UNITED STATES

Distinction between large capital
Large production
And monopoly

1. In the discussion of the so-called trust problem three things must be distinguished: large individual capital, large production, and monopoly power. Capital, in the sense of valuable agents, is found in the smallest as well as the largest industry, and every owner, from the small shop-keeper to the wealthiest bondholder, is a capitalist. In popular discussion, however, the word frequently implies great wealth in a single hand, though this wealth may be invested in a large number of small industries. Large production is the concentration of capital into large units of industry. The capital may be the same as before, the ownership may or may not be widely diffused, but the control and management are unified. Large factories may or may not have monopoly power; as factories grow in size, competition among them often becomes more, not less, complete and severe. On the contrary, monopoly, as before defined, may exist where the industry is small, as the waterworks in a small town, or a small factory for making patented articles. In periods of depression a business with a capital of ten thousand dollars may go on and prosper, while one with millions may be forced into bankruptcy. These three ideas—great individual wealth, large industry, and monopoly power—are often hopelessly confused in the discussion of present-day questions.

1. When talking about the so-called trust problem, three things need to be clarified: individual wealth, large-scale production, and monopoly power. Capital, meaning valuable resources, exists in both small and large businesses, and every owner, from a small shopkeeper to a rich bondholder, is a capitalist. In everyday conversations, however, the term often suggests significant wealth concentrated in one person, even if that wealth is spread across many small businesses. Large-scale production is about bringing capital together into big units of industry. The capital might remain unchanged, and ownership could be widespread or not, but the management and control are consolidated. Large factories might or might not possess monopoly power; as factories expand, competition among them can actually become more intense, not less. Conversely, monopoly, as defined earlier, can exist in smaller industries, like the water supply in a small town or a small factory producing patented products. During economic downturns, a business with $10,000 in capital can thrive, while one with millions may go bankrupt. These three concepts—significant individual wealth, large industries, and monopoly power—are frequently mixed up in discussions about current issues.

Stages of tools and household industries
Of simple machines
And of large industry

2. Three industrial stages may be broadly distinguished: that of tools, that of machines and small factories, and that of large production. Men are prone to forget that all the world is not doing just as they are. Over two thirds of the people on the globe are still in the first industrial stage. One billion people use only tools, and have no better source and means of power than domestic animals. This is true in the most of Asia and Africa, in the greater part of South America, and in many portions of North America. About two hundred million people live in the stage of simple machines and small factories. These are found in eastern and southern Europe, small portions of South America, some parts even of the United States. In this stage there is not enough manufacturing power in the community to supply much more than its own needs. About two hundred million people in the United States and western Europe have reached the third and highest industrial plane, where the highest mechanical devices are employed and industry becomes highly specialized. These differences are broadly stated; there are contrasts within every nation. Three hundred miles from here, in the Alleghanies, people still can be found spinning and weaving and wearing homespun as in colonial days. In a trip of twenty miles in Tyrol or Switzerland one can observe every one of these industrial stages. The most striking development, if not the typical form, in America to-day is large or concentrated industry.

2. Three industrial stages can generally be identified: the stage of tools, the stage of machines and small factories, and the stage of large-scale production. People often forget that not everyone around the world is experiencing things the same way they are. Over two-thirds of the global population is still in the first industrial stage. One billion people rely solely on tools and have no better source of power than domesticated animals. This is common in much of Asia and Africa, the majority of South America, and many areas of North America. About two hundred million people live in the stage of simple machines and small factories, found in Eastern and Southern Europe, parts of South America, and some areas in the United States. In this stage, there isn’t enough manufacturing capability in the community to meet much more than its own basic needs. Around two hundred million people in the United States and Western Europe have reached the third and highest industrial stage, where advanced mechanical devices are used and industries become highly specialized. These distinctions are broad; there are variations within every country. Three hundred miles from here, in the Alleghenies, you can still find people spinning and weaving and wearing homespun fabric, just like in colonial times. A short trip of twenty miles in Tyrol or Switzerland allows you to see all of these industrial stages in action. The most notable development, if not the standard form, in America today is large or concentrated industry.

Household industry in America
Recent changes in number of factories

3. In the last half century the unit of organization in leading industries has tended to grow larger. Seventy-five years ago a tool-using household industry, on farms and in homes where the greater part of the things used were produced in the family, was still the typical organization in the United States. The early factories growing out of the household industry were small. A family specialized in producing cloth and exchanged with its neighbors; so with shoes, candles, soap, canned goods, cured meats, etc. Since that time two counter forces have been at work to affect the ratio[Pg 314] of manufacturing establishments to population. The number of establishments has been increased by specialization of farming which has called for many industries to produce the things once made on farms, and by increasing wealth and invention, which has made possible many small industries supplying things before almost unknown. The number of establishments has been diminished as the staple products that can be transported have come to be made in larger factories. The resultant of these movements during the thirty years ending in 1900 is somewhat surprising: the ratio of factories (with an output worth five hundred dollars) to population has somewhat increased. In 1870 there were two hundred and fifty-two thousand establishments; in 1890, three hundred and fifty-five thousand, and in 1900, five hundred and twelve thousand, a ratio to population of one to one hundred and sixty-two, one hundred and seventy-seven, and one hundred and forty-four respectively. The last date was one of great industrial prosperity, and doubtless many ephemeral enterprises had been called into existence, thus giving a somewhat abnormal result. Moreover, there has been a large increase in the number of things made in factories which were formerly made in the homes, and which then did not appear at all in the census of manufactures.

3. In the last fifty years, the way industries are organized has become larger. Seventy-five years ago, small household industries—where most of the goods used were produced by the family—were still the norm in the United States. The early factories that emerged from these household industries were small. A family would specialize in making cloth and trade with their neighbors, just like with shoes, candles, soap, canned goods, cured meats, and so on. Since then, two opposing forces have influenced the ratio[Pg 314] of manufacturing establishments to the population. On one hand, the rise of specialized farming has increased the number of businesses that produce items once made on farms. On the other hand, growing wealth and innovation have led to many small industries that supply goods that were previously rare. However, the number of establishments has decreased as staple products that can be transported started being produced in larger factories. The outcome of these changes over the thirty years leading to 1900 is quite surprising: the ratio of factories (with an output worth five hundred dollars) to population has somewhat increased. In 1870, there were two hundred and fifty-two thousand establishments; by 1890, that number grew to three hundred and fifty-five thousand, and by 1900, it reached five hundred and twelve thousand, resulting in population ratios of one to one hundred and sixty-two, one hundred and seventy-seven, and one hundred and forty-four, respectively. The last date marked a period of significant industrial prosperity, and likely many short-lived enterprises had been created, producing a somewhat unusual result. Additionally, there has been a significant rise in the number of products made in factories that were previously made at home, which didn’t appear in the census of manufacturing at all.

Large production in some industries

In cotton-weaving, however, the unit of industry is growing, factories in 1870 numbering nine hundred and fifty-six; in 1890, nine hundred and five; in 1900, one thousand and fifty-five, the later increase being due to the fact that many new factories in the South have been started in the last decade. The population meantime doubled. This movement has been going on for seventy years, there being about the same number of mills in 1900 as in 1830, though population had multiplied six-fold. Iron- and steel-mills numbered one thousand three hundred in 1880, one thousand in 1890, and nine hundred and sixty-five in 1900. In industries having local markets and sources of supply for materials, the change has been less rapid. There were twenty-four thousand grist-mills in 1880, eighteen thousand in 1890, and twenty-five[Pg 315] thousand in 1900, a change of ratio from two thousand one hundred to three thousand population per grist-mill. There were twenty-six thousand sawmills in 1880, twenty-two thousand in 1890, and thirty-three thousand in 1900, a change from about one thousand nine hundred and twenty to two thousand two hundred and seventy persons per sawmill.

In cotton weaving, though, the scale of the industry is expanding, with factories numbering nine hundred and fifty-six in 1870, nine hundred and five in 1890, and one thousand and fifty-five in 1900. The increase in the last decade is due to many new factories opening in the South. Meanwhile, the population doubled. This trend has been happening for seventy years, with about the same number of mills in 1900 as in 1830, even though the population had multiplied six times. Iron and steel mills numbered one thousand three hundred in 1880, one thousand in 1890, and nine hundred and sixty-five in 1900. In industries with local markets and sources of materials, the change has been slower. There were twenty-four thousand grist mills in 1880, eighteen thousand in 1890, and twenty-five[Pg 315] thousand in 1900, changing the ratio from two thousand one hundred to three thousand people per grist mill. There were twenty-six thousand sawmills in 1880, twenty-two thousand in 1890, and thirty-three thousand in 1900, shifting from about one thousand nine hundred and twenty to two thousand two hundred and seventy people per sawmill.

But while the number of establishments in these staple industries was decreasing, the number of employees per establishment in most cases was increasing. The average in all industries, in 1870, was eight; in 1890, twelve; in 1900, ten and four tenths. In cotton-mills, in 1870, the average was one hundred and eighty-four; in 1890, two hundred and forty-four; in 1900, two hundred and eighty-seven. The grist-mills, in 1880, had two and four tenths persons per establishment; in 1890, three and four tenths. The sawmills, in 1880, averaged six employees each; in 1890, fourteen; iron- and steel-mills in 1880, one hundred and twenty-one each; in 1890, one hundred and ninety-six.

But while the number of businesses in these main industries was decreasing, the number of employees per business in most cases was increasing. The average across all industries in 1870 was eight; in 1890, it was twelve; and in 1900, it was ten point four. In cotton mills, the average was one hundred eighty-four in 1870; two hundred forty-four in 1890; and two hundred eighty-seven in 1900. The grist mills had an average of two point four employees per establishment in 1880, which increased to three point four in 1890. Sawmills averaged six employees each in 1880; fourteen in 1890. Iron and steel mills had an average of one hundred twenty-one employees each in 1880, which grew to one hundred ninety-six in 1890.

Growing concentration of capital into large industries

4. The amount of capital per establishment is tending to increase in the leading lines of industry. The amount of capital is not so easy to determine as the number of employees, and it is recognized that the census figures on this subject are only approximately correct. We are told that in cotton-mills, in 1830, the average capital invested was fifty thousand dollars; in 1890, nearly four hundred thousand dollars; in 1900, four hundred and forty thousand dollars. It is easy to observe the large increase in investment of capital in flouring-mills since the new processes came into use. The average capital of all industries does not grow as in the staple ones, for many smaller industries have come into existence. In 1880, the average capital was eleven thousand dollars; in 1900, it was eighteen thousand dollars.

4. The amount of capital per establishment is increasing in the leading industries. It's not as easy to figure out the amount of capital as it is to count the number of employees, and it's acknowledged that the census data on this topic is only roughly accurate. We're told that in cotton mills, in 1830, the average capital invested was fifty thousand dollars; in 1890, it was nearly four hundred thousand dollars; and in 1900, four hundred and forty thousand dollars. It's clear to see the significant rise in capital investment in flour mills since the new processes were introduced. The average capital across all industries isn't growing as much as in the major ones, because many smaller industries have emerged. In 1880, the average capital was eleven thousand dollars; by 1900, it rose to eighteen thousand dollars.

Recent formation of combinations

The years between 1890 and 1900 saw the rapid formation of trusts and combinations, and of larger industries. Consolidation took place on a great scale in railroads and in manufactures. Much of this has been of such a kind that it does not appear at all in the figures showing the number of establishments[Pg 316] and of employees. Many discrepancies appear in the data regarding this movement given by different authorities, as there is no generally accepted rule by which to determine the selection of the companies to be included in the lists, and as the conditions are changing from day to day. A competent financial authority[1] gives the following figures regarding the "industrial" trusts (manufacturing and commercial) and gas trusts, organized in the United States between 1860 and 1899, not including combinations in such businesses as banking, shipping, railroad transportation, etc. The figures refer to the reorganization and consolidation of industries into larger units, some of which have much and others little or no monopoly power.

The years between 1890 and 1900 saw a rapid rise in trusts, combinations, and larger industries. There was a significant consolidation in railroads and manufacturing. Much of this activity isn’t reflected in the statistics on the number of establishments[Pg 316] and employees. Various sources report inconsistent data on this trend, as there isn't a widely accepted method to determine which companies should be included in the lists, and the situation is constantly changing. A knowledgeable financial expert[1] provides the following statistics on the "industrial" trusts (manufacturing and commercial) and gas trusts formed in the United States between 1860 and 1899, excluding combinations in sectors like banking, shipping, and railroad transportation. These figures relate to the reorganization and consolidation of industries into larger entities, some of which hold significant monopoly power while others have little or none.

DecadeNumber OrganizedTotal Nominal Capital
1860-692$13,000,000
1870-794135,000,000
1880-8918288,000,000
1890-991573,150,000,000
———————————————
Total, 40 years181$3,586,000,000

The number organized and the capital represented by this movement in the last of these decades are eight times as great as in the thirty years preceding. In the last ten years can be traced the influence of general industrial conditions.

The number of people organized and the capital represented by this movement in the last decade is eight times greater than in the thirty years before that. In the past ten years, you can see the impact of overall industrial conditions.

YearNumber OrganizedTotal Nominal Capital
18906$82,000,000
189113168,000,000
189213140,000,000
18935226,000,000
1894235,000,000
18957104,000,000
1896340,000,000
1897693,000,000
189822574,000,000
1899801,688,000,000
———————————————
Total, 10 years157$3,150,000,000

The first three years enjoyed great prosperity and the number of combinations were six, thirteen, thirteen. In 1893, the number was less, but the total nominal capital (preferred and common stocks and bonds) was still the greatest it had ever been in any year. Then came the period of depression, 1894-97, when both the numbers and the capital were comparatively small. Then followed the period of the greatest formation of trust companies the world has ever seen, which extended from 1898 to 1901, and ended in 1902.

The first three years saw significant prosperity, with the number of combinations being six, thirteen, thirteen. In 1893, the number decreased, but the total nominal capital (preferred and common stocks and bonds) was still the highest it had ever reached in any year. Then came the depression period from 1894 to 1897, when both the numbers and the capital were relatively low. This was followed by the greatest formation of trust companies the world has ever experienced, which lasted from 1898 to 1901 and ended in 1902.

Trust statistics for 1904

In a list recently revised by another authority[2] it appears that the data for all "industrial trusts" (nearly, but not quite, comparable with the foregoing figures), are in round numbers as follows:

In a list recently updated by another authority[2] it seems that the data for all "industrial trusts" (almost, but not entirely, comparable to the previous figures) are approximately as follows:

DateNumberNumber of Plants
Acquired or Controlled
Total
Nominal Capital
Jan. 1, 19043185288$7,246,000,000

These figures would indicate that the industrial trusts more than doubled within four years, most of the growth being within three years. The same authority, in a more comprehensive list, classifies in six groups all so-called "trusts" of the United States, at the date of January 1, 1904, as follows (the figures just given above are the totals of the first three groups):

These figures suggest that the industrial trusts more than doubled in just four years, with most of the growth happening within three years. The same source, in a more detailed list, categorizes all the so-called "trusts" in the United States as of January 1, 1904, into six groups, as follows (the figures mentioned above are the totals of the first three groups):

DateNumberNumber of Plants
Acquired or Controlled
Total
Nominal Capital
1. Greater industrial trusts71528$2,660,000,000
2. Lesser industrial trusts29834264,055,000,000
3. Other industrial trusts in process
of reorganization or readjustment
13334528,000,000
4. Franchise trusts11113363,735,000,000
5. Great steam railroad groups67909,017,000,000
6. Allied independent railroad groups10250380,000,000
———————————-
Total,4458664$20,000,000,000

§ II. ADVANTAGES OF LARGE PRODUCTION

Economical use of machinery in large production

1. A great technical advantage of large production is the better and fuller use of machinery. A large factory with a large output can keep a special machine adjusted for each pattern and process, whereas in a small factory much time and energy are wasted in adjusting one machine for various processes. The machinery in a large factory is thus more fully utilized. Compare the machinery used in a large ax-factory with that used in twenty-five small ax-factories having the same total output: the one hundred and fifty workmen in twenty-five small factories would use twenty-five shears, one hundred trip-hammers, fifty grindstone-pits, fifty polishing-frames, a total of two hundred and twenty-five machines; the same one hundred and fifty men in one large factory would require three shears, a saving of twenty-two; twenty trip-hammers, a saving of eighty; thirty-seven grindstone-pits, a saving of thirteen; thirty polishing-frames, a saving of twenty; a total of ninety machines, a saving of one hundred and thirty-five machines. The difference in cost due to machinery is not so great as these figures indicate, as the unused machines last longer; but in the small factory there is more depreciation from rust and decay, and a larger proportionate investment of capital for which interest must be earned. The average amount of stock and materials required in a large factory is not so great in proportion to the output.

1. A major technical advantage of large-scale production is the better and more efficient use of machinery. A big factory with high output can keep specialized machines set up for each design and process, while a smaller factory wastes a lot of time and energy adjusting one machine for different tasks. Therefore, the machinery in a large factory is utilized more effectively. Take, for example, the machinery used in a large ax factory compared to that in twenty-five smaller ax factories with the same total output: the one hundred and fifty workers in those twenty-five small factories would use twenty-five shears, one hundred trip-hammers, fifty grindstone pits, and fifty polishing frames—a total of two hundred and twenty-five machines. In contrast, the same one hundred and fifty workers in one large factory would need only three shears, saving twenty-two; twenty trip-hammers, saving eighty; thirty-seven grindstone pits, saving thirteen; and thirty polishing frames, saving twenty; resulting in a total of ninety machines, which means a savings of one hundred and thirty-five machines. The difference in costs due to machinery isn't as significant as these numbers suggest, since the unused machines tend to last longer; however, in small factories, there's more depreciation from rust and decay, along with a larger proportionate investment of capital that needs to earn interest. The average amount of stock and materials needed in a large factory

Economy in labor power

2. In a large factory the division of labor may be more complete and effective. The technical economies of the division of labor can be realized in large measure only when a number of men work together. Partly because of the advantages in the use of machinery, but partly from other causes, labor in a large group is proportionately more effective than in a small group, especially in producing form-value. In making plows, nine men working separately will[Pg 319] average sixty-six plows each per year, while one hundred and eighty men working together will average one hundred and ten each per year, the output per man being increased sixty-six and two thirds per cent. In a rifle-factory with a daily output of fifty, eight men are needed for the same product that can be supplied by three men in a factory with an output of one thousand daily.

2. In a large factory, the division of labor can be more complete and effective. The benefits of dividing work can really only be achieved when many people work together. This is partly due to the advantages of using machinery, but also for other reasons; labor in a large group is generally more effective than in a small group, especially when it comes to producing goods. For example, when making plows, nine men working individually will[Pg 319] average sixty-six plows each per year, while one hundred and eighty men working together will average one hundred and ten each per year, increasing the output per man by sixty-six and two-thirds percent. In a rifle factory with a daily output of fifty, eight men are needed for the same product that three men can produce in a factory with a daily output of one thousand.

Miscellaneous economies

3. In the larger industry the costs of management, supervision, and marketing are relatively less. Division of labor decreases the difficulty of supervision in larger factories, where the processes are divided, systematized, and made a matter of routine. The necessary inspection of the results is more rapid and easy. The advertising of certain kinds of goods involves a large and inevitable outlay, which is relatively less for a larger business, as the greater the output the smaller the burden on each unit of the product. Combination effects a great saving in the number of commercial travelers, a result partly due to the decrease in competition, but partly also to better organization. Each of twenty different factories must send its drummers into every part of the country to seek business. In combination they can divide the territory, visit every merchant and get larger orders at smaller cost. Supplies can be purchased more cheaply in large amounts, and shipments in car-load and train-load lots make possible special (sometimes illegal) concessions from railroads and from carriers on waterways.

3. In larger industries, the costs of management, oversight, and marketing are relatively lower. Dividing tasks makes it easier to supervise in bigger factories, where processes are split up, organized, and turned into routines. Necessary inspections of results happen more quickly and effortlessly. Marketing for certain types of products requires a significant and unavoidable investment, which is less burdensome for larger businesses since as production increases, the cost per unit goes down. Collaborating leads to significant savings on the number of sales representatives, partly due to reduced competition but also due to improved organization. Each of twenty different factories would have to send their salespeople to every part of the country to find business. When they work together, they can share territory, visit every merchant, and secure bigger orders at a lower cost. They can buy supplies more cheaply in bulk, and freight shipments in car-load and train-load quantities allow for special (sometimes illegal) discounts from railroads and waterway carriers.

Limits to the growth of a single factory

4. There are some disadvantages in a large industry which put a limit to the growth of a single local establishment. There is practically a limit to the advantages of size in a factory. When each man is working on the smallest possible subdivision of the product, doubling the number of employees will not increase his skill. When the finest machinery can be kept constantly in use, economy in its use has reached the maximum. As large factories tend to create cities around them, land rises in value and higher wages[Pg 320] must be paid the workmen. Small factories are constantly seeking out lower rents, taxes, wages, salaries, cheaper local sources of materials, cheap though limited sources of power, and thus they compete successfully in many markets. The point is reached in the growth of establishments where oversight cannot be as perfect and complete; the eye of the master cannot be over all. The market that can be reached by one factory is limited by distance, as the cost of transportation finally offsets all the other advantages of large industry.

4. There are some downsides to a large industry that limit the growth of a single local business. There's practically a cap on the benefits of size in a factory. When each worker is focused on the smallest part of the product, adding more employees won’t boost anyone's skills. When the best machinery is kept running all the time, the efficiency gained from using it has hit its peak. As large factories attract cities around them, land prices go up, and higher wages[Pg 320] must be paid to the workers. Small factories consistently look for lower rents, taxes, wages, salaries, cheaper local materials, and inexpensive yet limited power sources, which allows them to compete effectively in various markets. There's a point in the expansion of businesses where management can't be as thorough and complete; the master’s eye can’t oversee everything. The market that one factory can reach is limited by distance, as transportation costs eventually outweigh the other benefits of large industry.

Do not necessarily limit consolidation

It is evident that most of these reasons apply to a single local factory with far greater force than to a federation of locally scattered plants. It was once believed that the growing disadvantages of large industry would set an early limit to consolidation. While there is a truth in this thought not to be overlooked, the effects must now be recognized to be more distant than was supposed. The limits to the advantages of combination have been removed by the application of the federative plan which makes possible under one management the maximum of advantages with the minimum of the disadvantages in large industry. That was the discovery of the early promoters of the trust movement.

It’s clear that most of these reasons are much stronger for a single local factory than for a collection of scattered plants. People used to think that the growing downsides of large industry would soon put a stop to consolidation. While there’s some truth in that idea that shouldn’t be ignored, the reality is that the effects are now recognized as being further away than we initially thought. The limits on the benefits of combining operations have been lifted by the use of a federative approach, which allows for maximum advantages and minimum downsides in large industry under a single management. This was the insight of the early leaders of the trust movement.

§ III. CAUSES OF INDUSTRIAL COMBINATIONS

Trusts in the legal and the popular sense

1. Trusts are large combinations of capital with some degree of monopoly power. The original, legal meaning of the term trust does not include the idea of monopoly. The old legal idea of a trust is the confidence imposed in a trustee. The method that was adopted by the early combinations was the trust method, that is, they made use of this legal device: the stock of the separate companies was put into the hands of a board of trustees to whom was thus given the right to control. As it has been found possible to accomplish the same end without the use of this legal method, the popular meaning of the word trust, as applied to[Pg 321] a monopoly, no longer agrees with the legal meaning. The word trust is popularly used of any large industry, though usually there is connected with it the idea of some evil power to raise prices to the consumers. A large number of the corporations called trusts have, however, little monopoly power, and some have none at all. They are simply large establishments.

1. Trusts are large pools of capital with some level of monopoly power. The original legal definition of a trust doesn’t include the concept of monopoly. The historical legal meaning of a trust is the confidence placed in a trustee. The early groups that formed these combinations used the trust method, meaning they utilized this legal tool: the stock of the individual companies was placed in the hands of a board of trustees, which gave them the right to control. Since it has been shown that the same outcome can be achieved without using this legal method, the common interpretation of the term trust, as it relates to [Pg 321] a monopoly, no longer aligns with the legal definition. The term trust is now typically used to refer to any large industry, although it usually carries the implication of an undesirable ability to increase prices for consumers. However, many corporations labeled as trusts have little to no monopoly power, and some have none at all. They are merely large businesses.

Economies of combination

2. A strong reason for combination of competing plants is found in the legitimate economies of large production. The economies that are possible within a single factory may be still greater in a number of combined or federated industries. The cost of management, amount of stock carried, advertising, cost of selling the product, may all be smaller per unit of product. A large aggregation can control credit better and escape loss from bad debts. By regulating and equalizing the output in the different localities, it can run more nearly full time. Being acquainted with the entire situation, it can reduce the friction. A strong combination has advantages in shipment. It can have a clearing-house for orders and ship from the nearest source of supply. The least efficient factories can be first closed when demand falls off. Factories can be specialized to produce that for which each is best fitted. The magnitude of the industry and its presence in different localities strengthens its influence with the railroads. Its political as well as its economic power is increased.

2. A strong reason for combining competing plants is found in the genuine cost savings of large-scale production. The savings that can be achieved within a single factory may be even greater when multiple industries come together. The costs of management, inventory, advertising, and selling the product can all be lower per unit produced. A large organization can manage credit more effectively and reduce losses from bad debts. By coordinating and balancing output across different locations, it can operate closer to full capacity. Being aware of the overall situation helps minimize inefficiencies. A strong coalition has advantages in shipping. It can create a centralized order system and ship from the nearest supply point. The least efficient factories can be the first to shut down when demand decreases. Factories can be specialized to produce what each one is best suited for. The size of the industry and its distribution across various locations enhances its leverage with the railroads. Its political as well as its economic influence is heightened.

Integration of industry

A recent phase of corporate growth is the "integration of industry," that is, the grouping under one control of a whole series of industries. One company may carry the iron ore through all the processes from the mine to the finished product. A railroad line across the continent owns its own steamers for shipping goods to Asia or Europe. Large wholesale houses own or control the output of entire factories. The possibilities in this direction have only begun to be realized.

A recent trend in corporate growth is the "integration of industry," which means bringing together a whole range of industries under a single control. One company might manage everything from mining iron ore to producing the final product. A railroad company that spans the continent might own its own ships for transporting goods to Asia or Europe. Big wholesale companies often own or control the production of entire factories. The potential in this area has only just started to be explored.

Combination prevents competition

3. The men uniting to form a trust always declare that[Pg 322] its formation is the necessary result of excessive competition. The statement is often true in the sense that a hard fight and lower prices have preceded the formation of the trust. But as this excessive competition usually is for the very purpose of forcing the combination, this explanation is a begging of the question. It is fallacious also in that it ignores the marginal principle in the problem of profits. Profits are never homogeneous from factory to factory, and to those that are on the margin competition may appear excessive. It is generally the largest and strongest factories, in the more favored situations, that, in order to get rid of troublesome competitors, force the smaller, weaker, industries to come into the trust. When, therefore, it is said that competition is destructive, it may be a partial truth, but more likely it is a pleasantry reflecting the happy humor of the prosperous promoters of the combination.

3. The men coming together to create a trust always claim that[Pg 322] its creation is the inevitable outcome of too much competition. This statement is often accurate in that a tough struggle and lower prices typically precede the establishment of the trust. However, since this excess competition usually aims to push for the merger, this reasoning is circular. It's also misleading because it overlooks the marginal principle in profit discussions. Profits aren't uniform from one factory to another, and for those on the edge, competition may seem excessive. Typically, the largest and strongest factories, located in better positions, are the ones that pressure smaller, weaker industries to join the trust in order to eliminate bothersome competitors. So, when it's said that competition is destructive, it may hold some truth, but more likely it reflects the satisfied mood of the successful promoters of the merger.

Financial gains of combination

4. Another strong motive for the combination is the profit to promoters and organizers. There are indirect as well as direct gains to the managers of a large business. There is the gain from the production and sale of goods to consumers, and there is the gain from the financial management, from the rise and fall in the value of stock. The promoters of a combination often expect to make from sales to the investing public far more than from sales to the consumer of the product. A season of prosperity and confidence, when trusts and their enormous profits are constantly discussed, has an effect on the public mind like that of the discovery of a new El Dorado, a California, or a Klondike. Then is the time for the wily promoter to offer shares without limit to investors.

4. Another strong reason for the merger is the profit for promoters and organizers. There are both indirect and direct benefits for the managers of a large business. There's profit from producing and selling goods to consumers, as well as from financial management and changes in stock value. The promoters of a merger often expect to earn much more from sales to investors than from sales to the product's consumers. A time of prosperity and confidence, when trusts and their huge profits are frequently talked about, impacts public perception like the discovery of a new El Dorado, California, or Klondike. It's during this time that the clever promoter can offer unlimited shares to investors.

These considerations show that the trust is not simple in its cause, nor in its nature. In a sense the most artificial of industrial arrangements, in another sense it is a natural evolution of industry. More and more it is being recognized that though it has in it something of evil, it has as well something of good, and certainly much of the inevitable.

These points demonstrate that the trust is complex both in its origins and in its characteristics. In one way, it's one of the most artificial setups in industry; in another, it's a natural progression of industry. It's increasingly acknowledged that although it has its drawbacks, it also has its benefits and, undeniably, a lot of the unavoidable.


CHAPTER 35

EFFECT OF TRUSTS ON PRICES

§ I. HOW TRUSTS MIGHT AFFECT PRICES

Economics of the trust problem

1. The economist's task, strictly confined, is to explain the relation of trusts to prices, not to solve the problem of their political control. The question of trusts is such a large one that its discussion here must be confined to those aspects having close relation to the central subject of economic study,—the laws of value. These laws were by the older economists thought to be true only within the limits of free competition. Seeing that in various ways this freedom is interfered with not only by caste, custom, organized labor, but by patents, political privileges, and the power of large aggregations of capital (in short by all things that check the flow of ability and of agents from one industry to another), the question occurs: Are the abstract laws of rents, profits, and wages of any significance or of any help in discussing the great practical questions of to-day? Are not prices determined by the personal whim of industrial despots who can bid defiance to the laws of price? The control of trusts by legislative action is largely a political problem, but it must be guided by a correct economic analysis. Proposed legislative measures often assume or imply that in no way, directly or indirectly, is competition found in the problem. It should be the aim of economic study to make clear the true bearing and force of monopoly power in practical problems of value.

1. The economist's job, clearly defined, is to explain how trusts affect prices, not to figure out how to control them politically. The issue of trusts is so vast that we must focus on the aspects that closely relate to the main topic of economic study—the laws of value. Older economists believed these laws only held true in a system of free competition. However, this freedom is often disrupted not just by social classes, traditions, and organized labor, but also by patents, government privileges, and the influence of large capital groups (basically by anything that prevents the movement of skills and resources between industries). This raises the question: Do the abstract laws of rents, profits, and wages really matter or help us understand today’s major issues? Aren’t prices influenced by the personal preferences of industrial leaders who can ignore the laws of pricing? While regulating trusts through legislation is mainly a political challenge, it needs to be informed by accurate economic analysis. Proposed laws often assume or suggest that competition is absent from the equation. Economic study should aim to clarify the real impact and significance of monopoly power in practical value-related issues.

Limited power of trusts
Monopoly and supply

2. The fundamental principles of market value cannot be[Pg 324] changed by a trust; a selling monopoly can affect price only as it affects supply or demand. The strongest "trust" yet seen has not been omnipotent. Many careless expressions on the subject are heard even from ordinarily careful writers and speakers: "The trust can fix its own prices," "has unlimited control," "can determine what it will pay and for what it will sell." This implies that trusts are benevolent, seeing that the prices they charge are usually not far in excess of competitive prices in the past. Such a view overlooks the forces that limit the price a monopoly can charge. The law according to which the value of products on the market is determined, is as valid where there is a trust as anywhere else. The marginal utility of goods to the consumer determines the price of any given supply. If the supply remains the same, no trust can make the price go higher. What it gets in exchange are the services or the wealth of the rest of the public. At what rate can it exchange its products for the products of others (including other trusts)? The monopoly usually directs its efforts to affecting the supply, leaving the price to adjust itself. (This is the case of the selling monopoly; the statement must be adjusted where it is a buying monopoly.) It can affect the supply either by lessening its own output or by intimidating and forcing out its competitors. It is true that this logical order is not always the order of events. The trust does not first limit the supply, and then wait for prices to adjust themselves; it first raises its prices, but unless it is prepared to limit the supply in accordance with the new resulting conditions of demand, such action would be vain. The control of the sources of supply is the logical explanation of the higher price, even though the limitation of supply is effected later by successive acts found necessary to maintain the higher price.

2. The basic principles of market value can’t be[Pg 324] altered by a trust; a selling monopoly can only influence price by affecting supply or demand. The most powerful "trust" seen to date has not been all-powerful. Many careless comments on the topic are made even by normally precise writers and speakers: "The trust can set its own prices," "has unlimited control," "can decide what it will pay and what it will sell." This suggests that trusts are generous, considering that the prices they charge are typically not far above the competitive prices of the past. Such a perspective ignores the factors that limit the price a monopoly can set. The principle that determines the market value of products holds true for trusts just as it does elsewhere. The marginal utility of goods to consumers sets the price for any given supply. If the supply stays the same, no trust can raise the price. What they receive in return is the services or wealth of the rest of the public. At what rate can they trade their products for those of others (including other trusts)? The monopoly usually focuses its efforts on influencing supply, letting the price adjust on its own. (This applies to selling monopolies; the statement should be modified when it’s a buying monopoly.) They can affect supply by either reducing their output or intimidating and driving out competitors. It’s true that this logical sequence doesn’t always reflect the order of events. The trust doesn’t first restrict supply and then wait for prices to adapt; it initially raises its prices, but unless it’s ready to limit supply according to the new demand conditions, that action would be pointless. Controlling the sources of supply is the logical reason for the higher price, even if the supply limitation happens later through a series of actions deemed necessary to maintain the higher price.

Monopoly price is therefore a rational thing, not a mystery entirely out of harmony with the simple law of value laid down for consumption goods. The trust works as the magician[Pg 325] does, not as was thought of old, in defiance of natural laws, but in harmony with them and by their aid. The view the public took of the trusts was at first medieval. That should not be the view to-day.

Monopoly pricing is a logical concept, not something mysterious that contradicts the basic principle of value for consumer goods. The trust operates like a magician[Pg 325] does, not as people used to think, by going against natural laws, but in alignment with them and with their support. The public's perception of trusts was initially outdated. That should not be the perspective today.

Monopolistic gains from successful combination

3. The economies of large production after a successful combination may be divided in varying proportions among monopolists, workmen, and consumers. If the great economies of large production are effected by a new combination which makes no attempt to fix a higher price and limit production, where will the fruits of these economies go? They will go first to the owners of the trust, because, unless inspired by motives of philanthropy, they have no need to lower prices. Though they are in possession of special facilities, they will try to secure as high a price as before. A wider margin permits greater profits on each unit without limiting the output or the sales. They may retain this so long as they do not yield to the temptation to increase the output in proportion to their new facilities.

3. The benefits of large-scale production after a successful merger can be split in different ways among monopolists, workers, and consumers. If the significant efficiencies of large-scale production come from a new merger that doesn't try to raise prices or limit production, where will these benefits go? They will primarily go to the owners of the trust because, unless motivated by charitable intentions, they have no reason to drop prices. Even with unique advantages, they will aim to keep prices as high as before. A wider profit margin allows for greater profits on each unit without restricting output or sales. They can maintain this as long as they resist the temptation to increase production in line with their new capabilities.

Gains to workmen

These economies, may, however, at times inure to the benefit of the workmen in higher wages if they succeed by any means whatever in squeezing the employers at this time of exceptional gains. The suggestion has even come from employers that in order to allay labor troubles there should be a union of capital and labor to squeeze the consumer, by doing away with all competition in fixing prices. This proposition to divide the plunder of monopoly has been viewed approvingly by some leaders of organized labor, but it does not look especially alluring to the general public, to which is assigned the humble part of paying the bill.

These economies, however, can sometimes benefit workers with higher wages if they manage to pressure employers during these times of exceptional profits. Some employers have even suggested that to reduce labor issues, there should be a partnership between capital and labor to squeeze the consumer by eliminating competition in setting prices. This idea of sharing the profits from monopoly has been seen favorably by some leaders of organized labor, but it doesn't appear particularly appealing to the general public, who are left with the task of footing the bill.

Gains to consumers

Part of the advantages will go to the consumer whenever there is a motive on the part of the large establishment to increase supply in order to get a larger profit or to forestall new competition. As the improvements become matters of public knowledge, most of the new economic methods can and will be adopted by new enterprisers, and other large aggregations of capital will be induced to come in to reap[Pg 326] the benefits. The effect, of course, is an increase in supply and a lowering of prices. The fiat of the trust to prices to remain fixed while supply increases is as vain as a mortal's commands to the waves to be still. The undesigned result of the economies of large production, therefore, where control is not great, is to lower the prices and to diffuse the benefits among the public.

Part of the benefits will go to consumers whenever large companies want to increase supply to make more profit or to prevent new competition. As these improvements become known to the public, most of the new economic methods will be adopted by new businesses, and other large groups of capital will be encouraged to join in and take advantage of the perks. The result, of course, is an increase in supply and a decrease in prices. The demand from the trusts for prices to stay fixed while supply rises is as pointless as telling the waves to be calm. The unintended consequence of the efficiencies from large-scale production, therefore, when control isn’t too tight, is to lower prices and spread the benefits among the public.

Social burden of monopoly profits

4. If the trust succeeds in raising its prices it gains at the expense of the community. If a producer has some monopoly power, recognizes and uses it, his gain does not correspond with an increase in production. It is taken from those who buy these products, it is deducted from the psychic incomes of other members of society. This raising of prices actually reduces technical production, for the output is limited in order to secure the higher price. The probably less urgent wants of the receivers of monopoly incomes are gratified in place of the probably more urgent wants of the average purchaser. The result is a decreased social income, with an increase of the inequality of distribution. There is an analogy here with the effects of trade-unions. If the trade-union succeeds in forcing prices higher than the competitive prices, it gains at the expense of the other portion of the community. But while its gains appear to be more largely at the expense of the richer elements of society, the gains of the trust are more likely at the expense of the poorer elements. If the success of organized labor means to some extent a leveling up of income, the success of the trust means a still further inequality. Hence a difference in public sympathy in the two cases.

4. If the trust manages to increase its prices, it benefits at the expense of the community. When a producer has some monopoly power and chooses to exploit it, their profit does not lead to an increase in production. Instead, it comes at the cost of those purchasing these products and reduces the overall well-being of other members of society. This price hike actually lowers technical production because output is restricted to maintain the higher prices. The needs of those receiving monopoly profits, which are likely less urgent, are prioritized over the more pressing needs of the average consumer. The outcome is a decrease in social income combined with a rise in inequality of distribution. There is a similar effect with trade unions. If a trade union successfully pushes prices above competitive levels, it benefits at the expense of another segment of the community. However, while its benefits seem to come more from the wealthier parts of society, the gains from the trust are more often at the expense of the poorer groups. If organized labor's success leads to a degree of income leveling, the success of the trust results in even greater inequality. This creates a difference in public sympathy between the two situations.

The praise and blame for trust prices

5. The responsibility for either the rise or the decline of trust prices cannot always be determined. Prices are changing constantly under competitive conditions. In this active, moving world, changes of demand, the exhaustion of sources of supply, new processes, expiration of patents, opening up of new lines of transportation, affect prices in a multitude of ways entirely independent of organization. Trust-controlled[Pg 327] industries are open to all these influences. Economic forces cannot be isolated as can elements in a chemical laboratory, and, therefore, trusts claim the credit for all the reductions of price that have occurred. By such a calculation the trusts usually make a showing of progress, as, until 1896, for twenty years the tendency of prices in most lines was downward. Always getting the highest price they can under the market conditions, they yet pose as benefactors. They would claim that the economies possible only under trust organization cause even a monopoly price to be less than a competitive price would be. Critics of the trusts, on the other hand, charge them with causing all the increase that occurs, and with checking the decline in prices. The critics compare the percentages of decline in price during the decades before and after the combination was formed, and as it is impossible for a geometric rate of decrease in price, as a result of improvements, to be long maintained, this showing is very unfavorable to the trusts. A method has been found, however, of testing, in the case of a few leading industries, the effects they have had on the price of their portion of the productive process.

5. The responsibility for the rise or fall of trust prices isn't always clear. Prices are constantly changing in a competitive environment. In this dynamic world, shifts in demand, depletion of supply sources, new technologies, expiration of patents, and the development of new transportation methods all influence prices in numerous ways that are completely independent of organization. Industries controlled by trusts are subject to all these factors. Economic forces can’t be isolated like elements in a chemistry lab, which is why trusts take credit for all the price reductions that occur. This often allows them to present a facade of progress, as prices in most sectors had been declining for twenty years until 1896. They always aim to charge the highest price possible given market conditions, yet they portray themselves as benefactors. They argue that the efficiencies achievable only through trust organization make even monopoly prices lower than what competitive pricing would yield. Meanwhile, trust critics accuse them of causing all price increases and halting price declines. Critics compare the percentage decreases in price from the decades before and after the trusts formed, and since it’s impossible to maintain a geometric rate of price decline due to improvements for long, this analysis tends to paint an unfavorable picture of the trusts. However, a method has been discovered to assess, in a few major industries, the impact they’ve had on the prices within their segment of the production process.

§ II. HOW TRUSTS HAVE AFFECTED PRICES

Trusts raise prices
The oil trust

1. Examination of the course of prices in the case of some notable trusts shows that, wherever effective, they raise prices above the competitive rate possible to smaller production. The most instructive study in the subject is that undertaken by J. W. Jenks a number of years ago, and later developed by him when working with the Industrial Commission from 1898 to 1900. Its results are embodied in a series of charts. It appears that the price of refined petroleum, in 1871, was twenty-five and seven tenths cents per gallon; in 1880, eight and six tenths cents; in 1887, seven and eight tenths cents; in 1900, seven and eight tenths cents. A writer in the "North American Review" claims that this[Pg 328] decline was due to the economies accomplished by the Standard Oil Trust. It will be noticed, however, that prices fell most rapidly (from twenty-five and seven tenths cents to eight and six tenths cents) between 1871 to 1880, a period of intense competition, when the industry was new, and when the independent companies, fighting for their existence, introduced many improvements and began the construction of the pipe-lines that were later secured by the Standard Oil Co. Despite this rapid decline, the smaller companies still could have maintained a profitable business had it not been for the ruinous discrimination of the railroads against them. Because of this, the Standard Oil Co., in 1880, obtained almost complete control. The price twenty years later than that date was less than a cent cheaper. In the meantime the price for a time continued to fall. Competition was never quite stilled. The small competitor, wherever he saw a chance, has nibbled off a bit of the tempting profits. The rise from 1898 to 1900 was in accord with that occurring in other lines. A much lower cost of production is now possible to the great monopoly with its larger sales and more economical methods. The by-products, unknown at the beginning of the period, now yield large sums, yet the price remains much the same as a quarter of a century ago. The trust has succeeded in retaining a large part of the increasing margin of price over cost.

1. Looking at how prices have changed in the case of some major trusts indicates that, where they are able to operate effectively, they raise prices above what smaller producers could competitively offer. The most insightful analysis on this topic was conducted by J. W. Jenks several years ago, and he expanded on it while working with the Industrial Commission from 1898 to 1900. The findings are shown in a series of charts. It turns out that the price of refined petroleum in 1871 was twenty-five point seven cents per gallon; in 1880, it dropped to eight point six cents; in 1887, it was seven point eight cents; and in 1900, it remained at seven point eight cents. A writer in the "North American Review" argues that this[Pg 328] decrease resulted from the efficiencies achieved by the Standard Oil Trust. However, it's important to note that prices fell most significantly (from twenty-five point seven cents to eight point six cents) between 1871 and 1880, a time of fierce competition when the industry was still emerging, and independent companies, struggling to survive, introduced numerous improvements and began constructing the pipelines that would later be acquired by Standard Oil Co. Despite the swift price drop, smaller companies could have still run a profitable business if it weren't for the destructive discrimination from the railroads against them. As a result, by 1880, the Standard Oil Co. gained almost total control. Twenty years later, the price was less than a cent lower. Meanwhile, prices continued to decline for a time. Competition never completely disappeared. Smaller competitors, wherever they saw an opportunity, managed to bite off some of the attractive profits. The increase from 1898 to 1900 was in line with trends in other sectors. Now, the large monopoly benefits from significantly lower production costs due to its larger sales and more efficient methods. The by-products, which weren’t even considered at the start of this period, now generate substantial income, yet prices remain largely unchanged compared to a quarter-century ago. The trust has managed to keep a large portion of the growing price margin over costs.

The sugar trust

The influence of the sugar trust may be studied by what is known as the method of differentials. The differential in sugar is the difference between the cost of the raw sugar and the refined granulated sugar. Raw sugar is the main material and the principal fluctuating item of cost beyond the control of the trust. Changes in the differential reflect the changes in profits except as modified by a cheapening of the process. The period from 1880 to 1887 was one of great competition. In 1880, the differential was one and ninety-two hundredths cents on each pound of refined sugar, but it fell steadily till, in 1887, it had reached sixty-four hundredths[Pg 329] cents. In the fall of that year the trust was formed; and the next year the differential had risen to one and twenty-five hundredths cents, in 1889 to one and thirty-two hundredths cents. Tempted by the enormous profits, the rival refineries of Claus Spreckel were started, and with competition the differential fell, in 1890, to seventy hundredths cents. The rival factories were then bought up and under the new combination the differential went sailing up to one and three hundredths in 1892, and to one and fifteen hundredths in 1893. Rival factories again arose and competition grew stronger, reducing the differential to ninety-four hundredths in 1894. It was in that year that the firm of Arbuckle Brothers and Claus Doscher each opened a great refinery, and in the next year the differential fell to fifty hundredths cents. In 1900, some agreement, the terms of which were unknown to the public, was entered into by the rivals and the differential had risen, in March, 1901, to ninety-five hundredths cents. In every case the differential fell when competition was effective and went up when monopoly power was regained.

The impact of the sugar trust can be analyzed using a method called differentials. The differential in sugar refers to the difference between the cost of raw sugar and refined granulated sugar. Raw sugar is the primary material and the main fluctuating cost factor that the trust cannot control. Changes in the differential indicate changes in profits, except when influenced by a reduction in processing costs. The years from 1880 to 1887 were marked by intense competition. In 1880, the differential was 1.92 cents per pound of refined sugar, but it steadily decreased until it reached 0.64[Pg 329] cents by 1887. In the fall of that year, the trust was established, and the following year the differential rose to 1.25 cents, increasing to 1.32 cents in 1889. Lured by the massive profits, rival refineries, like those of Claus Spreckels, were launched, and with the rise in competition, the differential dropped to 0.70 cents in 1890. The competing factories were then acquired, and under the new collaboration, the differential soared to 1.03 cents in 1892 and 1.15 cents in 1893. Once again, rival factories emerged and competition intensified, bringing the differential down to 0.94 cents in 1894. That year, the firms of Arbuckle Brothers and Claus Doscher each opened a large refinery, and the next year, the differential fell to 0.50 cents. In 1900, an agreement was made, the details of which were not public, and the differential had risen to 0.95 cents by March 1901. In every instance, the differential decreased when competition was strong and increased when monopolistic power was restored.

The nail trust

The differential of steel-wire nails is the difference between the cost of the steel billets and the price of the wire. Between 1890 and 1895 there was a steady decline in the differential. In 1895 was formed the nail pool, an agreement to share the profits, a form of combination. A rapid advance took place, both in the price and in the differential. In the fall of 1896 the pool was broken and then occurred a fall in prices and in the differential during 1896-97. In January, 1899, the nail trust was formed, controlling sixty-five to ninety-five per cent. of the output of wire nails, and a rapid advance occurred in the price and also in the differential.

The differential of steel-wire nails is the difference between the cost of the steel billets and the price of the wire. Between 1890 and 1895, there was a consistent decrease in the differential. In 1895, the nail pool was created, which was an agreement to share profits, a type of partnership. This led to a significant increase in both the price and the differential. In the fall of 1896, the pool collapsed, resulting in a drop in prices and the differential during 1896-97. In January 1899, the nail trust was established, controlling sixty-five to ninety-five percent of the output of wire nails, and there was a significant increase in both the price and the differential.

The tin-plate trust

The tin-plate industry practically had its origin in the United States, in 1892, under the McKinley tariff. As competition increased, prices and the differential fluctuated and declined. At the end of 1898 the tin-plate company was[Pg 330] formed and prices at once started upward with a rapid increase in the differential. Cause may, in a measure, be mistaken here for effect. In these cases the part of the rise in price due to the rise of materials is not brought about by the trust. The differential represents its part of the productive process and its source of profits. The power to make the differential high is due in part to the general conditions of business in the last three years considered. The profits of all industries in those years increased. While prices may have risen partly because the trust was formed, it may have been possible to form the trust because prices were rising. The general conclusion is that trust prices are always raised when, and to the extent that, control is secured. They are lowered below normal prices when competition becomes troublesome. Fluctuation of prices probably has been more rapid and more spasmodic under trusts than it has been under ordinary competitive conditions.

The tin-plate industry basically started in the United States in 1892, thanks to the McKinley tariff. As competition grew, prices and the differentials changed and dropped. By the end of 1898, the tin-plate company was[Pg 330] established, and prices immediately began to rise with a sharp increase in the differential. It can sometimes be confusing to tell cause from effect here. In these situations, the price rise due to increasing material costs isn't necessarily caused by the trust. The differential reflects its role in the production process and its profit source. The ability to maintain a high differential is partly influenced by the overall business conditions over the last three years. Profits across all industries increased during that time. While prices might have gone up partly because the trust was formed, it’s also possible that the trust could be formed because prices were already rising. The main takeaway is that trust prices tend to rise whenever they can secure control, and they drop below normal prices when competition becomes a problem. Price fluctuations have likely been more rapid and erratic under trusts than in standard competitive markets.

Effective trusts injure various producers

2. A large degree of monopoly control may lower the incomes of producers of materials, the value of competitive plants, and prices in special local markets. A strong selling monopoly tends to become also a buying monopoly. A great industry using great quantities of materials may either own the sources or purchase from small producers. The steel trust owns mines, and ships and railroads to bring the ore to the furnaces; but the tobacco trust buys from the farmers. If the packing, refining, and marketing of a product is monopolized, the sellers of the raw or partly finished product are subject to one-sided competition. The small producers of tobacco, of crude oil, and of anthracite coal claim that the effect of the trusts is to give them lower prices for their products. Some have been severely punished by the monopolies for refusing to take the first offer made. Monopoly is thus likewise able to purchase competing plants at ridiculously small sums, by first making them valueless through fierce price-cutting, or by threats of it. "Rich" is often a relative term, and it is said that many a small millionaire[Pg 331] producer has anxiously waited to see whether the great trust would next turn its attention to him.

2. A significant amount of monopoly control can decrease the incomes of material producers, the value of competing companies, and prices in specific local markets. A strong selling monopoly often becomes a buying monopoly as well. A large industry that uses vast amounts of materials might either own the sources or buy from smaller producers. The steel company owns mines and has ships and railroads to transport the ore to the furnaces, while the tobacco company purchases from farmers. If the packing, refining, and marketing of a product is monopolized, the sellers of the raw or partially finished product face unfair competition. Small producers of tobacco, crude oil, and anthracite coal argue that the trusts lead to lower prices for their products. Some have faced harsh consequences from the monopolies for refusing the initial offer they receive. Monopoly can also acquire competing companies for unbelievably low prices by first making them worthless through aggressive price reductions or threats to do so. "Rich" is often a relative term, and it's said that many small millionaire[Pg 331] producers have anxiously awaited to see if the large trust would target them next.

The persistence of competition reducing prices

3. Competition of less capable producers works in most cases to prevent the great or continued rise of trust prices. Early trusts overestimated their power. The persistence of competition in industries where the trusts have had great advantages in position and resources has been astonishing. The wall-paper trust, though for many years it kept prices above competitive rates, was repeatedly undermined by competition. The whisky trust, while it frequently raised prices, was as often forced by the growth of small distilleries to lower them below competitive rates. Competition in the oil industry has persisted under the greatest difficulties. The smaller companies have hauled the product by wagon when the trust was moving it by pipe-lines. The continuance of high prices by a trust depends on a high degree of control of supply. A recognition of the limits of their power has led trusts in some cases to a policy of moderate prices, affording a good profit, but not encouraging competition.

3. Competition from less capable producers usually helps keep trust prices from rising too much or for too long. Early trusts overestimated their influence. The ongoing competition in industries where trusts have held significant advantages in position and resources has been surprising. The wallpaper trust, even though it maintained prices above competitive levels for many years, was continually challenged by competition. The whisky trust, while it often increased prices, was just as frequently compelled by the growth of small distilleries to reduce them below competitive rates. Competition in the oil industry has persisted despite significant challenges. Smaller companies have transported the product by wagon while the trust was using pipelines. For a trust to sustain high prices, it needs a strong control over supply. Recognizing the limits of their influence has led some trusts to adopt a strategy of moderate pricing, allowing for a decent profit without encouraging competition.

Supply as the condition of low prices

The limits of the power of the trust to control prices are strikingly shown by the fact that it cannot even insure low prices if the market conditions do not justify them. The steel trust, in 1902-3, declared that it would not advance the price of steel rails above twenty-eight dollars, and this was hailed as a beneficent effect of trust control, which, by equalizing production, could prevent excessive fluctuations of price. But the trust's declaration was a bit of inexpensive humor on the part of the managers; the trust had nothing to sell at the price quoted, as its entire product had been sold out months in advance. While, therefore, the trust continued calmly to quote steel rails at twenty-eight dollars, competition raised the market price to thirty-three dollars a ton; twenty-eight dollars or more was paid for second-hand rails, and a proportionate price for other iron products. Such exceptional conditions, raising prices to abnormal levels, are[Pg 332] followed by a decline disastrous not only to the small producer, but to the trusts as well.

The limitations of the trust's power to control prices are clearly illustrated by the fact that it can't guarantee low prices if the market conditions don't support them. The steel trust, in 1902-3, claimed it wouldn't raise the price of steel rails above twenty-eight dollars, which was praised as a positive result of trust control that could stabilize production and prevent wild price swings. However, this statement was more of a cheap joke from the managers; the trust had nothing available for sale at that price since its entire output had been sold months earlier. So, while the trust continued to confidently quote steel rails at twenty-eight dollars, competition pushed the market price up to thirty-three dollars a ton; more than twenty-eight dollars was being paid for used rails, and there were comparable prices for other iron products. Such unusual conditions, pushing prices to extreme levels, are[Pg 332] followed by a decline that is disastrous not just for the small producer but for the trusts as well.

Modes of controlling trusts

4. The control of the trusts must be sought in the direction of maintaining potential competition through fair and free conditions of industry. Many of the remedies suggested are reactionary and would give up the benefits of large production. Measures must be sought in harmony with the economic principles of price. Since many of the trusts have grown wealthy by special shipping privileges from the great quasi-public corporations, the railroads, and by special favors from public or corporation officers, who have been false to their duties, the solution must be a political and moral one; it must be sought in the development of honest citizenship and of a more efficient social regulation of quasi-public industries. The conditions of competition may be made fairer by requiring publicity of accounts, and by making it impossible for great corporations to strangle their local competitors by special and temporary prices. The state here has the same duty to perform that it has to protect the weak man from personal violence at the hands of the strong. This will not prevent competition, but it will determine the ways in which the rivalries of men can be manifested. Any measures for controlling the great combinations must start from a right understanding of the law of value, neither underestimating nor overestimating their economic power. Public sentiment toward the trust question has changed somewhat in recent years, because the nature of trusts and the extent of their power are better understood. There is now less fear of them, and more confidence that they can be tamed and made to serve the welfare of society.

4. The control of trusts should focus on maintaining potential competition through fair and open industry conditions. Many of the proposed solutions are backward-looking and would sacrifice the advantages of large-scale production. We need to find solutions that align with the economic principles of pricing. Since many trusts have become wealthy due to special shipping privileges from large quasi-public corporations like railroads, and due to special favors from public officials or corporate officers who have neglected their responsibilities, the solution needs to be political and moral. It should involve fostering honest citizenship and creating more effective social regulations for quasi-public industries. We can make competition fairer by requiring transparency in financial accounts and preventing large corporations from undermining local competitors with special temporary pricing. The state has the same responsibility here as it does in protecting vulnerable individuals from personal harm by the powerful. This won't stop competition, but it will shape how rivalries are expressed. Any efforts to regulate large combinations must begin with a proper understanding of value law, avoiding both underestimating and overestimating their economic influence. Public opinion about the trust issue has shifted in recent years because people now have a better understanding of the nature of trusts and the scope of their power. There's less fear of them now and more belief that they can be controlled to benefit society.


CHAPTER 36

GAMBLING, SPECULATION, AND PROMOTERS' PROFITS

§ I. GAMBLING VS. INSURANCE

Unavoidable chances

1. Many forms of chance are inseparable from the individual enterprise. There are what may be called natural chances chances, arising from the uncertainties of the seasons, from rainfall, heat, hail, storm, flood, lightning, land-slides. Such chances must be taken both by the small enterpriser and by the large. In an earlier condition of society natural chance almost dominated industry, and it still remains and must always remain an important factor to deal with. There are political chances, as war and riot; as legislation on money, tariffs, credit, and business relations. These are caused, it is true, by the action of men, but it is a collective action out of the control, to a greater or less degree, of the individual—absolutely out of the control of most individuals. Men of greater political influence can to some extent control these chances, possibly in their own favor. There are chances of carelessness causing fire, explosions, wrecks on misplaced switches, and involving penalties and losses that must be met. There is the chance of physical or mental collapse, as the sudden insanity or the sudden death, unforeseen and unpreventable, of one performing responsible duties. Sickness often wrecks the plans and the fortune of a whole family. There are economic changes, such as those in methods of production, in machinery, in methods of transportation; such as the growth of fashions or the growth of population changing demand in some directions and for some materials.

1. Many forms of chance are inseparable from individual enterprise. There are what could be called natural chances, arising from the uncertainties of the seasons, like rainfall, heat, hail, storms, floods, lightning, and landslides. Both small and large business owners must deal with these risks. In earlier times, natural chance almost completely dictated industry, and it still remains— and will always remain—an important factor to consider. There are political chances, like war and riots; like legislation on money, tariffs, credit, and business relations. These are caused, true, by human actions, but they result from collective actions that are largely beyond the control of any individual—completely out of reach for most people. Those with greater political influence can somewhat control these chances, possibly for their own benefit. There are risks from carelessness leading to fires, explosions, accidents from misaligned switches, and resulting penalties and losses that must be faced. There’s also the risk of physical or mental breakdown, such as sudden insanity or unexpected death, unforeseen and unavoidable, of someone carrying out important duties. Illness often disrupts the plans and fortunes of an entire family. Economic changes happen too, such as those in production methods, machinery, transportation practices; trends in fashion or population growth changing demand in certain areas and for specific materials.

Average of chances in each industry

Some of these chances are more connected with money-lending, others with manufacturing; some with agriculture, others with commerce; but all are present in some degree in every industry. In the broadest view they are not chances, for on the basis of experience it can be foretold that they will occur to some one; but no individual can tell when and how they will occur to him. A general average of chances in different lines of business causes some to be called safe, others extra-hazardous. The chance is averaged and added to the profit or gain of that industry, for an extra-hazardous industry must in general afford a higher average of profit in order to induce men to engage in it. It is folly to take a risk without ascertaining its degree, so far as general experience enables one to choose. But inasmuch and in as far as the gains and losses fall unequally upon different individuals, income depends on chance.

Some of these opportunities are more related to lending money, some to manufacturing; some to farming, others to trade; but all are present to some extent in every industry. From a broad perspective, they aren’t really chances, since past experience suggests they will happen to someone; however, no one can predict when or how they will happen to them. A general average of opportunities in different areas of business leads some to be labeled as safe, while others are seen as high-risk. The opportunity is averaged and added to the profit or gain of that industry, because a high-risk industry typically needs to offer a higher average profit to attract people to participate in it. It’s foolish to take a risk without understanding its level, based on what general experience allows one to determine. But because gains and losses impact different individuals unevenly, income relies on chance.

Other chances artificial and avoidable

2. The essence of gambling is the attempt to gain by taking chances that are not the unavoidable incidents of productive enterprise. The chances just enumerated are not sought, but avoided as far as possible; yet they must be borne by some one, and the burden must be distributed throughout society. There are unquestionably many kinds of chance-taking which differ from these in economic, and therefore in moral quality; but it has taxed the ingenuity of philosophers to lay down an abstract definition of gambling that would permit ready and certain distinction in practice between gambling and legitimate chance-taking. Typical gambling is the transfer of wealth on the outcome of events absolutely unpredictable, so far as the two gamblers are concerned. Examples are the shaking of unloaded dice or the honest dealing of a pack of cards. There can be no doubt of the entire lack of a productive economic basis in the betting on prices carried on in so-called bucket-shops by ignorant persons having no connection with the market of real things, and seeking to get something for nothing as a result of mere chance.

2. The essence of gambling is trying to win by taking risks that aren't normal parts of productive work. The risks mentioned aren’t sought after; people try to avoid them as much as possible. However, someone has to deal with them, and the consequences must be spread across society. There are definitely many types of risk-taking that are different in economic and moral terms; yet it has challenged philosophers to come up with a clear definition of gambling that would easily distinguish it from legitimate risk-taking. Typical gambling involves the transfer of wealth based on the outcomes of events that are completely unpredictable for both gamblers. Examples include rolling fair dice or dealing a deck of cards honestly. There's no doubt that betting on prices in so-called bucket shops by uninformed individuals, who have no connection to the real market, is entirely lacking a productive economic foundation, as they aim to get something for nothing through mere chance.

Cheating and gambling

Cheating is not a necessary mark of gambling, although the cruder kinds of dishonesty, such as the loading of dice or the collusion of horse-owners or of horse-jockeys to deceive the betting public, are so common that they seem often to be its essential feature. Gamblers recognize fair as opposed to unfair methods. Fair gambling is a kind of minor morality within the immoral field of gambling, like the honor found among thieves. Gambling bears somewhat the same relation to legitimate chance-taking that play does to labor. The chance-taking in gambling has no useful purpose or result outside itself. The gamblers constitute themselves a little fictitious economic circle, and they transfer gains and losses on the turn of events that have no practical objective result within their circle except to determine the direction of the transfer.

Cheating isn't a fundamental part of gambling, although blatant forms of dishonesty, like rigging dice or horse owners and jockeys teaming up to trick bettors, are so prevalent that they often seem like a core aspect. Gamblers can tell the difference between fair and unfair practices. Fair gambling represents a sort of minor ethics within the overall immoral realm of gambling, similar to the code of honor among thieves. Gambling is somewhat like play compared to work; the risks taken in gambling don't serve any beneficial purpose outside of the activity itself. Gamblers create a small, fictional economic system, transferring wins and losses based on events that have no practical outcome within their circle, aside from determining where the money goes.

Various cases of a mixed nature; partisan bets

3. Legitimate forms of chance, or risk-taking, shade off into illegitimate forms, or gambling. Ranging between the extremes of legitimate risk-taking and of gambling are a number of cases of a mixed nature. The bets made on college games, races, and contests differ from ordinary bets only in the added feature of so-called college loyalty (a travesty on the real sentiment). These college gambling contracts are supposed (according to a mode of reasoning found also among primitive peoples) to exercise a subtle and irresistible influence upon the result. A crew that enters the race with the odds against it is unnerved and undone, thinks the patriotic collegian.

3. Legitimate forms of chance, or risk-taking, fade into illegitimate forms, or gambling. Between the two extremes of legitimate risk-taking and gambling are several cases that are a mix of both. The bets placed on college games, races, and competitions are different from regular bets mainly because of the added element of so-called college loyalty (which is a mockery of the true sentiment). These college gambling agreements are believed (following a line of thinking also seen in primitive cultures) to have a subtle and powerful impact on the outcome. A team entering a race as the underdog feels anxious and defeated, thinks the loyal college fan.

Knowledge and skill affecting the result

In nearly all wagers, judgment in some degree influences the choice of sides. One man bets on a horse whose pedigree and performances he knows thoroughly; another judges by the horse's appearance as it comes upon the track. The professional book-makers have the latest possible and most exact information on which to base their bids.

In almost all bets, some level of judgment affects the choice of sides. One person bets on a horse whose lineage and past performances he knows inside and out; another makes his decision based on how the horse looks as it enters the track. The professional bookmakers have the most up-to-date and accurate information available to inform their odds.

In the bets made on one's own prowess, as on speed in running or rowing, or in playing cards (wherein also the element of pure chance is mingled) the chance-taking is[Pg 336] still far over on the uneconomic side of the border-line. The running is for the sake of the wager, not for a useful purpose. A premium won by a runner for speed in delivering a message of economic importance is in striking contrast to the winnings in a wager.

In bets based on personal skill, like running, rowing, or playing cards (which also includes the element of pure chance), the risk-taking is[Pg 336] clearly on the unproductive side of the line. The race is for the sake of the bet, not for any practical reason. A reward earned by a runner for quickly delivering an important message is a stark contrast to the payouts from a wager.

Finally, the very border-line of difficulty is reached in the purchase and sale of goods in the market with a view of profiting by chance changes in price. Land speculation, the purchasing and holding of lumber, grain, cattle, and other tangible and useful things, must be judged liberally. The quality of gambling depends somewhat on the motive as well as on the ability of the actor. The enterpriser dealing with real wealth, and fitted to take the risks, both because of his resources and of his exceptional knowledge, needs the motive of gain, and in a sense can be said to earn socially what he gets. The motive of the uninformed must be a blind trust in luck, and a hope to gain from a rise in prices which they are quite unable to foresee or rationally to explain.

Finally, we've reached the edge of difficulty when it comes to buying and selling goods in the market to profit from sudden changes in price. Speculating on land, buying and holding lumber, grain, cattle, and other tangible and useful items should be viewed in a broad sense. The essence of gambling depends partly on the motive as well as on the person's ability. The entrepreneur who deals with real assets and is equipped to take risks—thanks to their resources and exceptional knowledge—requires a motive for gain and can be seen as earning socially what they receive. In contrast, the uninformed must rely on blind luck, hoping to profit from price increases that they cannot foresee or logically explain.

Gambling an economic loss to society

4. In its relation to value, a bet, or wager, is the exchange of the chance of loss for the chance of gain, involving a social loss. Even when fairest, the average results of such an exchange must be unfavorable to society. One person loses a part of his income that gratifies relatively urgent wants; another gains something that gratifies only less urgent wants than were represented by the sum he risked. The area that is subtracted from the loser's psychic income is larger than the area added to the winner's psychic income. The result would be different on the impossible condition that it were always the poorer man that gained and the richer one that lost. Betting, then, does not produce wealth; it merely transfers ownership in a way that reduces the total want-gratifying power of wealth.

4. In terms of value, a bet or wager is the trade-off between the chance of losing something and the chance of gaining something, which involves a social loss. Even when it's as fair as it can be, the overall results of this exchange will always be bad for society. One person loses part of their income, which they could have spent on urgent needs, while another person gains something that satisfies less urgent needs than what they risked. The loss in the loser’s overall satisfaction is greater than the gain in the winner’s overall satisfaction. The outcome would change only under the unrealistic scenario where the poorer person always wins and the richer one always loses. So, betting doesn’t create wealth; it simply shifts ownership in a way that reduces the overall ability of wealth to satisfy wants.

The effects that gambling and betting have upon character are still more important and dangerous than their effects upon income. Motives of economic activity are reduced; energy is diverted from productive enterprise; society is[Pg 337] demoralized through dishonesty of men intoxicated by gambling; speculation and embezzlement occur; and there is a reduction both of production and of enjoyment in society. These things can be reasoned out with mathematical certainty by means of the law of marginal utility.

The impact of gambling and betting on a person's character is even more significant and risky than their impact on income. Economic motivation decreases; energy shifts away from productive activities; society is[Pg 337] undermined by the dishonesty of those consumed by gambling; speculation and theft happen; and there is a decline in both production and enjoyment in society. These consequences can be logically deduced with mathematical certainty through the law of marginal utility.

Insurance as a wager

5. Insurance is, in outer form, a bet; but its essential purpose is the useful one of equalizing and eliminating chance. In its early form insurance was a bet made by a ship-owner to protect his cargo from loss. The chance of loss in shipping was even greater in the Middle Ages than now, and it became customary for the ship-owner to bet with a wealthy man that the ship would not return. If it did come back, the owner could afford to pay the bet; if it did not, he won his bet and thus recovered a part of his loss. It was what is called to-day "a hedge," that is, one bet made to neutralize, or offset, another. This gave to the smaller merchant the advantage of distributing his losses over a number of voyages, as was done by the owner of many vessels. Antonio, the wealthy merchant, is made thus to express his security:

5. Insurance looks like a gamble on the surface; however, its main purpose is to balance out and reduce risk. In its early days, insurance was essentially a bet taken by a ship owner to safeguard his cargo from potential loss. The risk of loss during shipping was even higher in the Middle Ages than it is today, and it became common for the ship owner to wager with a wealthy individual that the ship would not return. If the ship did return, the owner could afford to pay the bet; if it didn't, he won his bet and partially recovered his losses. This is what's known today as "a hedge," which is a bet made to counterbalance another. This allowed smaller merchants to spread their risks over multiple voyages, similar to what a fleet owner would do. Antonio, the wealthy merchant, expresses his confidence this way:

"I'm not putting all my investments in one place." Not to just one place; nor is all my property With the luck of this current year.
So my products don't make me unhappy.__A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Gradually there came about a specialization of risk-taking by the men most able to bear it. They could tell by experience about what was the degree of uncertainty, and could lay their wagers accordingly. When several insurers were in the same business, competition forced them to insure the vessel and cargo of the ordinary trader for something near the percentage of risk involved. The insurance thus tended to become a mutual protection to the ship-owners; what had to be paid in premiums to cover risk came to be counted as part of the cost of carrying on that business.

Slowly, those who were best equipped to take on risks became more specialized in it. They learned from experience how much uncertainty there was and adjusted their bets accordingly. When multiple insurers operated in the same market, competition pushed them to insure the ships and cargo of regular traders for a price that reflected the actual risk involved. As a result, insurance turned into a form of mutual protection for ship owners; the premiums paid to cover risks began to be seen as just another cost of running their business.

Insurance as mutual protection

Modern insurance is mutual in nearly every case: the total[Pg 338] premiums equal the total losses plus operating expenses, the interest on the reserve of premiums counting as part of the premium. Each one gets protection for the loss of his property in return for the payment of a sum that will cover the losses on others' property. Such an exchange is a profitable one. The premium comes from marginal income; the loss of house or property would fall upon the parts of income having higher marginal utility. The less urgent wants of the present are sacrificed in order to protect the income that gratifies the more urgent wants of the future. In insurance each party gives a smaller utility for a greater; each has a margin of advantage; while the greater certainty in business stimulates effort and rewards it. This is quite the opposite of the working of betting and gambling.

Modern insurance is almost always mutual: the total[Pg 338] premiums match the total losses plus operating expenses, with the interest from the reserve of premiums considered part of the premium. Each person gets protection against the loss of their property in exchange for paying an amount that helps cover the losses of others' property. This exchange is beneficial. The premium comes from extra income; losing a house or property would impact parts of income that are more valuable. Less urgent wants today are sacrificed to safeguard the income that fulfills more pressing wants in the future. In insurance, each party gives up a smaller benefit for a larger one; both have an advantage; and the greater certainty in business encourages effort and rewards it. This is completely different from the way betting and gambling operate.

Conditions of sound insurance

6. To be economically sound, insurance must have to do with real productive agents, and with somewhat regular, ascertainable events beyond the control of the insured. The difficulties that arise in case of fire-insurance are due largely to the failure to meet these requirements. When the insured sets fire to his own buildings, fire insurance ceases to be a legitimate thing. Constant efforts are made by insurance companies to guard against these "moral risks," the least calculable of any. Merchants whose stocks have been mysteriously burned two or three times find difficulty in getting insured. In life-insurance it was the custom formerly to refuse to pay death-losses in case of suicide; but now that condition is attached only for the first two or three years. It being reasonable to suppose that no man would plan suicide years in advance, death by one's own hand some years after taking life-insurance is regarded as coming under the ordinary rule of chance.

6. To be financially viable, insurance needs to relate to real productive resources and to somewhat regular, predictable events that are beyond the insured's control. The challenges that come up with fire insurance largely stem from not meeting these criteria. When the insured sets their own buildings on fire, fire insurance stops being legitimate. Insurance companies consistently work to protect against these "moral hazards," which are the hardest to predict. Merchants whose stock has mysteriously burned down two or three times find it hard to get insured. In life insurance, it used to be standard practice to deny death benefits in cases of suicide; however, now that restriction only applies for the first two or three years. It’s reasonable to assume that no one would plan for suicide years in advance, so death by one’s own hand after having life insurance is considered to fall under the normal rules of chance.

§ II. THE SPECULATOR AS A RISK-TAKER

An element of speculation in all business

1. Every enterpriser is to some extent specializing as a risk-taker. This familiar idea may be taken as a starting[Pg 339] point in discussing speculation. In its broadest sense speculation means to look into things, to examine attentively, study deeply, contemplate, meditate. In a business sense the speculator is one who studies carefully the conditions and the chances of a change of prices; hence arises the thought that speculation is connected with chance. The enterpriser can estimate these chances better than most men. He stands on a hilltop sweeping the horizon, and can see farther than the workingman can. He relieves the other agents of part of the risk, and he insures both laborer and capitalist against future fluctuations of prices. Some of the profits of successful enterprise in countries where no system of regular insurance has grown up, and in certain lines here where no insurance is possible, are speculative gains of this sort. Offsetting them, however, in large measure, are the speculative losses, by which in many cases the investment has been swept away altogether. The cautious business man tries to reduce chance as much as possible by insurance, and to confine his thought and worry to the parts of the productive process where his ability counts in the result. The wise have found out that it is better to shift the risk to some specialist who can take it better than they. For a man who has his thought and effort concentrated on running a flour-mill, it is foolish to take the risks of fire, of loss in shipment, of a rise in the price of grain needed to fill outstanding orders—it is as foolish as it would be for him to make his own machinery. Insurance being the economical way to cover risk, the reckless will, in the long run, be eliminated from the ranks of enterprisers.

1. Every entrepreneur is, to some degree, a specialist in taking risks. This well-known idea can serve as a starting[Pg 339] point for discussing speculation. In its broadest sense, speculation means to investigate things, examine them closely, study deeply, contemplate, and meditate. In business, a speculator is someone who carefully studies the conditions and potential price changes; this leads to the idea that speculation is linked to chance. The entrepreneur can assess these chances better than most. He stands on a hilltop, surveying the horizon, and can see farther than the average worker. He takes on part of the risk for others and protects both laborers and investors against future price fluctuations. Some of the profits from successful business ventures in places without a regular insurance system, and in certain areas here where insurance isn’t feasible, come from these speculative gains. However, these are largely offset by speculative losses, which can completely wipe out investments. Cautious businesspeople try to minimize risk as much as possible through insurance and focus their thoughts and worries on the aspects of the production process where their skills are most effective. The wise have learned that it’s better to transfer the risk to a specialist who can manage it more effectively than they can. For someone focused on running a flour mill, it’s unwise to take on the risks of fire, shipping losses, or increasing grain prices needed to fulfill orders—it's as foolish as it would be to build their own machinery. Insurance is the most economical way to mitigate risk, so, in the long run, the reckless will be weeded out of the entrepreneur ranks.

Specialization of risk taking

2. In some lines the risk of marketing and carrying large stocks becomes highly specialized, so that ordinary enterprisers shift it to a small group of risk-takers. In buying and selling large quantities of produce there is required the closest and most exclusive attention of a small group of men. The marketing of some staple products requires the most minute acquaintance with world conditions. To foretell[Pg 340] the price of wheat one must know the rainfall in India, the condition of the crop in Argentina, must be in touch as nearly as possible with every unit of supply that will come into the market. Such knowledge is sought by the great produce speculators in the central markets. If all means of communication—telegraph, cables, mails—are open to all, competition among these speculators becomes intense, and the result is the extremest efficiency. Their survival depends on the development of acute insight into market conditions. It is the testimony of expert witnesses and of writers in the report of the Industrial Commission that the margin at which farm produce is sold has fallen greatly in the last few years. These products are marketed along the lines of the least resistance, that is, of the greatest economy. The function of the commercial specialists is to foresee the markets, and to ship to the best place, at the right time, in the right quantities. If a product shipped to Liverpool will, by the time it arrives there, be worth more in Hamburg, there is a loss. Such difficult decisions can be made best by a small group of men selected by competition. When handling actual products they perform a real economic service.

2. In some areas, the risk of marketing and managing large inventories becomes highly specialized, so ordinary business people pass it on to a small group of risk-takers. Buying and selling large quantities of goods requires the focused and exclusive attention of a small team. Marketing certain staple products demands a deep understanding of global conditions. To predict[Pg 340] the price of wheat, one must be aware of the rainfall in India, the state of crops in Argentina, and stay as informed as possible about every source of supply entering the market. This knowledge is pursued by major produce speculators in the central markets. When all communication methods—telegraph, cables, mails—are available to everyone, competition among these speculators becomes fierce, resulting in extreme efficiency. Their survival hinges on developing a sharp insight into market conditions. Expert witnesses and writers in the report of the Industrial Commission note that the margin for selling farm products has significantly decreased in recent years. These products are marketed along the path of least resistance, meaning the greatest efficiency. The role of commercial specialists is to anticipate market trends and ship products to the right location, at the right time, and in the right amounts. If a product sent to Liverpool will be worth more in Hamburg by the time it arrives, that results in a loss. Such complex decisions are best made by a small group of individuals chosen through competition. When dealing with actual products, they provide a valuable economic service.

Produce speculators as insurers
Source of legitimate speculators' gain

3. Even some mere speculators on the produce markets may and do at times perform a productive service as risk-takers. Many of the speculators in staples, wheat, corn, wool, rarely handle the material things, the real products. They make it their business to study the world conditions, to foresee prices, and in a sense to bet upon them. Regular merchants buy and sell fictitious products of these men. When a miller buys ten thousand bushels of wheat that will remain in the mill three months before they are marketed as actual flour, he at the same time sells that number of bushels to a speculator for future delivery; or selling flour for future delivery the miller buys a future in wheat. In either case he cancels the chance of loss or gain, giving up the chance of profit in the rise of wheat in exchange for[Pg 341] protection from the loss of the product on his hands. To him this is legitimate insurance, for he is striving not to create an artificial risk, but like the medieval ship-owners, to neutralize one that is inseparable from the ordinary conditions of his business.

3. Even some simple speculators in the produce markets can and do occasionally provide a valuable service as risk-takers. Many speculators dealing in staples like wheat, corn, and wool hardly ever handle the actual products themselves. They focus on studying global conditions, predicting prices, and essentially placing bets on them. Regular merchants trade in the fictional products created by these speculators. When a miller buys ten thousand bushels of wheat that will stay in the mill for three months before being sold as flour, he also sells that same amount to a speculator for future delivery; or when selling flour for future delivery, the miller is effectively buying a futures contract in wheat. In both scenarios, he eliminates the possibility of loss or gain, trading the potential profit from rising wheat prices for[Pg 341] protection against the loss of the product he has on hand. To him, this is legitimate insurance, as he aims not to create an artificial risk, but rather to mitigate one that is inherent to his business, similar to how medieval shipowners operated.

One may ask, How, if the miller in the long run benefits, can the speculator gain? He does not intend to perform this service for nothing. Yet as the sales in the whole market equal the purchases, some say that there can be no profits to the speculator. There are unsuccessful speculators and at any rate their losses go to the successful as a sort of gambling profit. Speculators do not dine entirely on "lambs"; they are anthropophagous. But, further, the sales to legitimate purchasers should net a gain to the abler speculator. In proportion as his estimates are correct, there will remain a regular slight margin of profit to him. If he agrees to sell wheat at eighty-five cents to be delivered in three months, he expects it to be a little less at that time. In the long run the ablest speculator probably buys at a little less and sells at a little more than the price really proves to be. This means that the merchants in the long run pay something for protection against changes in prices, just as they pay something for insurance. And yet this is the cheapest way to eliminate risk, and a man engaged on a large scale in milling is, it is said, at a disadvantage if he neglects this method of marginal buying.

One might wonder, if the miller ultimately benefits, how does the speculator make money? He doesn't plan to provide this service for free. However, since the total sales in the entire market match the total purchases, some argue that speculators can’t make a profit. There are unsuccessful speculators, and their losses create gains for the successful ones, similar to gambling profits. Speculators don’t solely feed on "lambs"; they are predatory. Additionally, the sales to legitimate buyers should yield a profit for the more skilled speculator. To the extent that his predictions are accurate, there will be a consistent small profit margin for him. If he agrees to sell wheat for eighty-five cents to be delivered in three months, he anticipates the price will be slightly lower by that time. Over time, the most capable speculator likely buys for a bit less and sells for a bit more than the actual price. This implies that merchants, in the long run, pay something for protection against price fluctuations, just as they pay for insurance. Still, this is the most cost-effective way to mitigate risk, and it’s said that a large-scale miller is at a disadvantage if he ignores this approach to marginal buying.

Ignorant and dishonest speculation

4. The buying of margins by the "lambs" is simple betting, and much manipulation of the market is dishonest. What has just been described is the more legitimate phase of marginal buying, not its darker aspect. One who, having no special opportunities to know the market, buys or sells wheat, or other commodities or securities, on margin, is called a lamb. He is simply betting. He has no unusual skill; he cannot foresee the result. The commission paid to brokers "loads the dice" slightly; the opportunities of the larger dealer of anticipating information load the dice heavily[Pg 342] against the lambs. Secret combinations and all kinds of false rumors cause fluctuations large enough to use up the margins of the small speculator. At times a number of powerful dealers unite to cause an artificially high or low price, a situation called "a corner." But this is little other than gambling between betters. The general public gains and loses little if any by these operations, except in the evil effects they entail socially.

4. The buying on margin by inexperienced traders is just a form of betting, and a lot of market manipulation is dishonest. What has just been described is the more legitimate side of buying on margin, not its shady side. Someone who doesn’t have special insight into the market and buys or sells wheat or other commodities or securities on margin is called a lamb. They are just betting. They don’t have any special skills and can’t predict the outcome. The commissions paid to brokers slightly "loaded the dice"; the larger dealers who have access to insider information heavily load the dice[Pg 342] against the lambs. Secret alliances and all kinds of false rumors create price swings big enough to wipe out the margins of small traders. Sometimes, several powerful dealers team up to create an artificially high or low price, a situation known as "a corner." But this is really just gambling among bettors. The general public gains and loses little, if anything, from these activities, aside from the negative social consequences they bring.

§ III. PROMOTER'S AND TRUSTEE'S PROFITS

The promoter's service to the owners

1. The promoter of trusts performs in some ways a substantial economic service. A promoter is one who undertakes to convert a number of unrelated factories, or establishments, into a trust, or combination. He gets options on different factories, that is, the right to buy them at an agreed price within certain time limits. He gets some banking house to underwrite the combination, that is, to agree to dispose of a number of shares to the investing public. A certain number of shares go to the owners, a certain number to the banking house for its services in underwriting, and a substantial number, it may be ten or twenty per cent, of the enormous capitalization, to the promoter himself. This is payment for his ability to water the stock successfully, to capitalize it for more than its former value. Evidently the owners think he earns the money or they would not pay him. So far as there are economic advantages in large production, and inasmuch as there is always friction in the forming of new industrial arrangements, there is a real social service performed by the promoter. The gains of the promoter are in part the legitimate price of progress.

1. The promoter of trusts provides a significant economic service. A promoter is someone who takes on the job of transforming a set of unrelated factories or businesses into a trust or a combination. They secure options on different factories, which means they have the right to buy them at an agreed price within a certain timeframe. They arrange for a bank to underwrite the combination, which means the bank agrees to sell a number of shares to the investing public. A portion of the shares goes to the owners, another portion goes to the bank for its underwriting services, and a significant portion—possibly ten or twenty percent of the total capitalization—goes to the promoter as compensation. This payment rewards the promoter for their ability to successfully inflate the stock’s value and capitalize it beyond its former worth. Clearly, the owners believe he is earning this money; otherwise, they wouldn’t be willing to pay him. Given the economic advantages of large-scale production and the inevitable challenges in establishing new industrial arrangements, the promoter does perform a genuine social service. The promoter’s profits are partly the rightful reward for progress.

The loss of the investors

2. A large part of the profits of promoter and of owners is unfairly taken from the investor. The larger modern business is less and less attached to particular neighborhoods. A much smaller proportion of investments is made in industries which the investor himself can control or even see in[Pg 343] operation. Business, therefore, in these days is done largely on faith in other men. Especially the investor takes great chances. The prospectus announcing a reorganization is frequently misleading. It frequently misrepresents the sources of income and the probable dividends, conceals essential facts, and makes misleading statements. The capitalization often is absurdly high, compared with the value of the different establishments. In one case eight million dollars of stock were issued to represent factories whose combined value had been five hundred thousand dollars. So far as the capitalization is based on the increased profits due to the monopoly power, the profits of reorganization are taken out of the pockets of the public. But in fact even monopoly earnings cannot support such valuations, and from the outset if fair dividends are paid, they are falsely paid out of capital, not out of earnings. With the approach of bad times there must be a suspension of dividends, a fall in the value of securities, and a loss falling upon the investors. Such practices are a serious evil, for the stability of industry depends on the opening up of opportunities for safe investment to the average man.

2. A significant portion of the profits for promoters and owners is unfairly taken from the investor. Modern businesses are becoming less connected to specific neighborhoods. A much smaller percentage of investments are made in industries that the investor can control or even observe in[Pg 343] operation. Today, business is largely conducted based on trust in others. Investors especially take on substantial risks. The prospectus announcing a reorganization is often misleading. It frequently misrepresents income sources and expected dividends, hides essential facts, and makes deceptive statements. The capitalization is often ridiculously high compared to the actual value of the different establishments. In one instance, eight million dollars worth of stock was issued to represent factories whose total value was only five hundred thousand dollars. The way capitalization is based on increased profits from monopoly power means that the profits from reorganization are taken out of the public's pockets. However, even monopoly earnings can't sustain such valuations, and right from the start, if fair dividends are paid, they are misleadingly paid out of capital, not out of real earnings. As bad times approach, dividends must be suspended, the value of securities will drop, and investors will suffer losses. These practices are a serious problem, because the stability of industry relies on creating safe investment opportunities for the average person.

The speculating trustee

3. Corporation officers and trustees, speculating in the stocks of their own companies, are reaping illegitimate gains. It is recognized by public sentiment and in law that for public officials to let contracts to themselves is bad morals and bad public policy. It is the duty of legislators not to make laws for companies in which they are interested. One of the greatest scandals in American public life, "the Credit Mobilier affair," was caused by the acceptance by members of Congress, virtually as a gift, of shares in a company that was seeking favoring legislation. Such action must be looked upon as a sort of industrial treason, comparable to the old form of political treason. Corporation officers are in a position of public trust toward the investors quite comparable to that of government officers toward the citizens. The power of directors and of other officers to manipulate[Pg 344] earnings and dividends, and thus to affect the market value of the stock, leaves the investing public helpless. The practice by officials in great corporations of speculating in their own stocks, whose prices they can manipulate, is so common as scarcely to attract comment. Large fortunes result from this betrayal of the trust imposed by the shareholders. This is not legitimate speculation; it is like loading the dice, pulling the horse, drugging the pugilist—things despised and condemned even in gambling and sporting circles.

3. Corporation officers and trustees who gamble on their own companies’ stocks are making unfair profits. Public opinion and the law recognize that it's unethical and bad public policy for public officials to award contracts to themselves. Legislators have a responsibility not to create laws for companies they have a stake in. One of the major scandals in American politics, "the Credit Mobilier affair," occurred when members of Congress accepted shares in a company that was looking for favorable legislation, essentially as a gift. Such actions should be seen as a form of industrial treason, similar to traditional political treason. Corporation officers hold a position of trust toward investors that is similar to that of government officials toward citizens. Their ability to influence earnings and dividends and, in turn, the market value of stock leaves investors vulnerable. It's incredibly common for officials in large corporations to speculate on their own stocks, which they can manipulate, and this hardly raises eyebrows anymore. Huge fortunes come from this violation of the trust shareholders place in them. This isn't legitimate speculation; it's like cheating at dice, rigging races, or doping athletes—things that are looked down upon even in gambling and sports.

Two types of speculation

It appears, therefore, that in the complex conditions of modern business there is a legitimate concentration of risk in the more capable hands, but also a growth of opportunities for illegitimate speculation and for large dishonest gains that were not possible before. These two types of speculation should be distinguished, as far as possible, in thought and in practice; but this it not easy in concrete instances, which vary almost indistinguishably from the clear case of honest earnings to the other extreme of illegitimate gains.

It seems that in today’s complex business environment, there’s a valid concentration of risk in the more skilled hands. However, there’s also an increase in chances for unethical speculation and substantial dishonest profits that weren’t possible before. It’s essential to differentiate between these two kinds of speculation, as much as we can, both in theory and in practice. Yet, this is not straightforward in real situations, which often blur the lines between legitimate earnings and outright dishonest profits.


CHAPTER 37

CRISES AND INDUSTRIAL DEPRESSIONS

§ I. DEFINITION AND DESCRIPTION OF CRISES

Broader definition of a crisis

1. In a broad sense, a crisis is a decisive moment or turning point; hence, in industry, a collapse of prosperity. In the course of a fever the crisis is the point where there is a turn for the better or for the worse. The figure of speech as applied to industrial conditions would seem to fail, in that what precedes is apparently exuberant health, not disease. Business conditions do not move along uniformly. There are waves of prosperity. Profits are apparently great, then may be suddenly swept away. The profits of the prosperous time are partly illusory, or exist only on paper. The situation has all the unhealthiness of the fever-patient. Men trade in promises and when the crisis comes, they have only promises for profits. The discussion of business management and profits is not complete without a consideration of this rhythmic movement of confidence and prices.

1. In a general sense, a crisis is a crucial moment or turning point; therefore, in industry, it refers to a collapse of prosperity. During a fever, the crisis marks the moment when the situation either improves or worsens. The analogy applied to industrial conditions seems to break down, as what comes before appears to be robust health, not illness. Business conditions don't progress steadily. There are cycles of prosperity. Profits can seem substantial and then suddenly disappear. The profits during prosperous times are partly misleading or exist only on paper. The situation has all the unhealthy traits of a feverish patient. People trade in promises and when the crisis hits, they are left with only promises instead of real profits. The discussion about business management and profits isn't complete without considering this rhythmic fluctuation of confidence and prices.

A crisis in the business affairs of an individual, in the sense of a collapse of prosperity, may occur from many mischances. A local crisis may be felt in some one neighborhood as a result of flood, of fire, or of other accidents. Such a case was that which occurred in 1864, in Manchester, England, when the cotton factories were compelled to close because the supply of cotton was cut off by the blockade of the ports of the South in the Civil War. Such a local crisis sometimes results from a change of transportation,[Pg 346] throwing a town out of the line of trade. These have been mentioned in discussing chance and risk; but the phenomenon known generally as an industrial crisis is of wider extent and of a more peculiar nature.

A crisis in a person's business affairs, meaning a complete loss of prosperity, can happen for many unexpected reasons. A local crisis might hit a specific neighborhood due to a flood, fire, or other accidents. One example occurred in 1864 in Manchester, England, when cotton factories had to shut down because the supply of cotton was cut off by the Southern ports being blockaded during the Civil War. A local crisis can also occur due to a change in transportation, which can exclude a town from the trading routes.[Pg 346] These instances have been discussed in relation to chance and risk; however, the phenomenon known as an industrial crisis is broader in scope and has unique characteristics.

Various types of crises

2. In a more special sense a financial crisis is the confusion and loss that mark the end of a period of rising prices; an industrial depression is the period of hard times that follows. The word crisis suggests a brief period, a moment, something that is severe, sudden, and soon over. The term financial panic is frequently used as a synonym for financial crisis. A crisis in the narrower sense has to do with prices—is always connected with money in some way. While, therefore, crises may be divided into industrial, speculative, and financial, according to their immediate occasion, all of them are financial in the sense that they have to do with a change in the general price level. A crisis is a jolt to prices which shatters the credit of some banks, brokers, merchants, and manufacturers. Crises are thus peculiar to the money economy and to a developed industry. Not every business misfortune is to be called an industrial crisis, but only those where prices and credit are generally depressed. A long period of hard times is sometimes called a crisis, but it is better to distinguish it by the term industrial depression.

2. In a more specific sense, a financial crisis is the confusion and loss that signal the end of a period of rising prices; an industrial depression is the tough times that come afterward. The word crisis implies a short duration, a moment, something serious, sudden, and over quickly. The term financial panic is often used as a synonym for financial crisis. A crisis, in this narrower sense, relates to prices—it's always connected to money in some way. Therefore, while crises can be categorized into industrial, speculative, and financial based on their immediate causes, they are all financial in the sense that they involve changes in the general price level. A crisis is a shock to prices that destabilizes the credit of certain banks, brokers, merchants, and manufacturers. Crises are therefore unique to the money economy and a developed industry. Not every business setback qualifies as an industrial crisis, but only those where prices and credit are widely depressed. A prolonged period of difficult times is sometimes called a crisis, but it's better to refer to it as an industrial depression.

Industrial conditions preceding a crisis

3. The period leading up to a crisis is one of general prosperity. Industry in successive decades does not pass through an unvarying series of changes, but history repeats itself with sufficient regularity to justify the view that a certain series of changes is typical in modern industry. When prices are at the lowest point many factories are closed, and much labor is unemployed. Conditions are worse in some industries than in others. General economy and great caution prevail; few new enterprises are undertaken. To those having available money this is a good time to buy, and property begins to change hands. Then hoarded money begins to come out of its hiding-places. Money flows in from other countries, particularly if business conditions[Pg 347] are better abroad than here, for low prices make a country a good place in which to buy. At the same time that the money in circulation thus increases, there is a general return of confidence that increases credit. Not only are there more dollars, but each does more work. Then old enterprises are resumed and new ones are undertaken. The purchase of materials in larger quantities causes a rise in prices and an increase in costs. The surplus labor on the margin of efficiency gets employment, and wages begin to increase. The only classes not sharing in this improvement are the receivers of fixed incomes. As prices rise, the purchasing power of their incomes gradually falls.

3. The time before a crisis is typically a period of overall prosperity. Industry doesn’t go through a consistent series of changes over the decades; instead, history tends to repeat itself enough to support the idea that certain changes are common in modern industry. When prices hit rock bottom, many factories shut down, and a lot of workers are left without jobs. Some industries face worse conditions than others. There’s a general atmosphere of frugality and caution; few new ventures are started. For those with available cash, this is a good time to make purchases, and property starts exchanging hands. Then, money that’s been hoarded starts to come back into circulation. Capital flows in from other countries, especially if business conditions[Pg 347] are better elsewhere than here, since low prices make a country an attractive place to buy. Simultaneously, as the cash flow increases, there’s a return of confidence that boosts credit. Not only are there more dollars in circulation, but each dollar is able to do more work. Old businesses resume operations, and new ones are launched. Purchasing materials in larger amounts drives prices up and increases costs. The excess labor that’s on the edge of efficiency finds work, and wages begin to rise. The only groups not benefiting from this improvement are those with fixed incomes. As prices rise, the purchasing power of their incomes slowly diminishes.

The crisis and its results

4. The crisis is a moment of widespread loss, which is followed by a long period of small profits to most enterprises, and of enforced economy. As prices cease to go up rapidly, the question arises in many minds whether the movement can continue, and if not, when it will cease. Men wish to hold on for the last profits, and are willing to risk something to gain them. When foreign prices do not rise in as great proportion as domestic prices, foreign imports are stimulated and the quantity of exports falls. This disturbs the equilibrium of money and requires at length large and continued exportation of specie. This checks prices, and, reducing the specie reserves of the banks, compels them to be more cautious. The fall in the value of many stocks and securities held by the banks forces many brokers and speculators to convert their resources into ready money. This is the moment of danger; weak enterprises find their foundations crumbling, and there are many failures. The falling prices, the shattered credit, and the financial losses force many factories to close; many workmen are thrown out of employment, and business must again enter upon a period of retrenchment, for it has completed the cycle of changing prices.

4. The crisis is a time of widespread loss, which is followed by a long stretch of small profits for most businesses, and enforced saving. As prices stop rising quickly, many people start wondering whether the trend can keep going, and if not, when it will end. People want to hang on for the last profits and are willing to take some risks to get them. When foreign prices don’t increase as much as domestic prices, foreign imports go up and the amount of exports drops. This disrupts the balance of money and eventually leads to a significant and ongoing export of precious metals. This slows down prices and lowers the banks' reserves of these metals, forcing them to be more careful. The decline in the value of many stocks and securities held by the banks pushes many brokers and speculators to turn their assets into cash. This is the moment of danger; weak businesses find their foundations crumbling, leading to many failures. The falling prices, damaged credit, and financial losses force many factories to shut down; many workers are laid off, and business must once again go through a period of cutbacks, having completed the cycle of shifting prices.

§ II. CRISES IN THE NINETEENTH CENTURY

No financial crises in the Middle Ages

1. The periods of industrial hardship in the Middle Ages were connected with adverse conditions of production, not with the collapse of prices. Periods of exceptional hardship in medieval times were mostly due to political oppression, famine, wars, pestilence, and scourges of nature. There being very little of the money economy, there was no development of credit and of credit prices. The money economy began, as has been noted, in the cities. As the use of money spread, as larger commercial enterprises were undertaken, as borrowing and the payment of interest became common, there began to appear in city trading circles, on a small scale, the phenomena of the modern crisis.

1. The tough times in the Middle Ages were linked to poor production conditions, not falling prices. Periods of extreme hardship during medieval times were mainly caused by political oppression, famine, wars, disease, and natural disasters. With very little money economy, there was no development of credit or credit prices. The money economy started, as mentioned, in the cities. As money use expanded, larger businesses were launched, and borrowing and interest payments became common, the early signs of modern economic crises began to show in city trading circles, even if on a small scale.

European crises of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries

2. In Europe general industrial crises date from 1763 and have occurred at more or less regular intervals since. It frequently is said that the cycle, or period, of crises is ten years, but it takes an elastic imagination to find support for this in history. The crises of the eighteenth century occurred in 1763, 1783, 1793, these dates marking the close of wars of some magnitude. The crises were not widespread or general, but were more marked in England, which was most developed industrially and in its money economy. Likewise in the nineteenth century, the crises were of unequal force in the various countries, usually being severer in England. The English crises may be roughly dated 1803, 1825, 1838, 1847, 1857, 1864, 1875, 1890. These were attributed to various causes; that of 1825 to over-trading abroad; that of 1847 to railroad-building; that of 1864 to the interruption of the cotton trade and of commerce, as a result of the Civil War in America. While in many parts of England the crisis of 1864 was unusually severe, in other countries it was of little moment. Germany, after several years of great speculative prosperity, had a most severe crisis in 1875; while France (a somewhat significant fact),[Pg 349] although prostrated by the war of 1870-71, losing a large amount of wealth, and paying a thousand millions of dollars to Germany as a war indemnity, escaped a commercial crisis almost entirely at that time.

2. In Europe, major industrial crises started around 1763 and have happened at pretty regular intervals since then. People often say that these crises occur every ten years, but it takes a bit of a stretch of the imagination to really support that with history. The crises in the eighteenth century happened in 1763, 1783, and 1793, which coincided with the end of some significant wars. These crises weren't widespread or general, but were more noticeable in England, which was the most industrially advanced and financially developed at the time. Similarly, in the nineteenth century, the intensity of the crises varied across different countries, often being more severe in England. The English crises can be roughly dated to 1803, 1825, 1838, 1847, 1857, 1864, 1875, and 1890. These were caused by various factors; for example, the crisis of 1825 was due to overtrading abroad, the crisis of 1847 was linked to railroad construction, and the crisis of 1864 was triggered by disruptions in the cotton trade and commerce because of the Civil War in America. While the crisis of 1864 was particularly harsh in many parts of England, it barely registered elsewhere. Germany experienced its worst crisis in 1875 after several years of speculative prosperity, whereas France (notably) [Pg 349] managed to avoid a commercial crisis despite being devastated by the war of 1870-71, losing a significant amount of wealth and paying a billion dollars to Germany as a war indemnity.

Crises in the United States

3. In the United States there have been five marked crises: the first in 1817, the last in 1893. These crises were of date 1817-20, 1837-39, 1857, 1873, 1893. Major crises thus occurred about twenty years apart, and minor crises in several instances alternated with them, notably in 1866, 1884, and we might add, 1903. These crises were the culmination of different kinds of speculation, usually spoken of as their causes. The crisis of 1817 was due to over-trading and to the immense importation following the war of 1812 and the resumption of commerce with Europe in 1816. In 1837-39 came in quick succession two crises, not quite distinct from each other, the second similar to the relapse of a fever patient. The immediate occasions were over-speculation in lands, a great issue of bank money, national expansion, and over-confidence, possibly in some degree the heedless financial measures of Andrew Jackson. The crisis of 1857 followed a period of great prosperity marked by the discovery of gold in California in 1848, by great expansion of commerce, by the building of railroads, and by a great increase in foreign trade. The crisis of 1873, probably the severest in our history, is attributable to great speculation, especially to railroad-building on an unexampled scale following the war. The blow, when it fell, was intensified by the contraction of currency leading to the return to a specie basis and lower prices. The crisis of 1884, a comparatively slight one, occasioned (rather than caused) by the discussion of the money question, was followed by some years of noticeable depression. The years 1889 to 1892 witnessed a prosperity that culminated in a crisis in September, 1893, (likewise generally explained as due to the unsettled state of our monetary system) followed by a period of depression lasting until 1897.

3. In the United States, there have been five significant crises: the first in 1817, and the last in 1893. These crises occurred in the years 1817-20, 1837-39, 1857, 1873, and 1893. Major crises happened roughly every twenty years, with minor crises often occurring in between, notably in 1866, 1884, and we might add 1903. These crises were the result of various types of speculation, typically referred to as their causes. The crisis of 1817 was caused by excessive trading and the massive importation that followed the War of 1812, along with the resumption of trade with Europe in 1816. In 1837-39, two crises hit in quick succession that weren't entirely separate from each other, with the second resembling a relapse in a fever patient. The immediate causes were over-speculation in land, a huge increase in bank money, national expansion, and an overabundance of confidence, possibly influenced by the reckless financial policies of Andrew Jackson. The crisis of 1857 came after a period of significant prosperity, marked by the discovery of gold in California in 1848, extensive growth in trade, the building of railroads, and a substantial increase in foreign trade. The crisis of 1873, likely the worst in our history, can be traced to major speculation, especially related to railroad construction on an unprecedented scale following the war. The impact was worsened by a contraction of currency that led to a return to a gold standard and falling prices. The crisis of 1884 was relatively minor and was triggered (rather than caused) by debates over the monetary question, followed by several years of noticeable economic downturn. The years from 1889 to 1892 saw a boom that culminated in a crisis in September 1893, which is generally explained as being due to the unstable state of our monetary system, resulting in a period of recession lasting until 1897.

The period from 1897 to 1903 has been marked by great prosperity and by rising prices. The over-hasty prophecies of collapse in the last two years have thus far been falsified,[3] but there is now a general feeling of distrust in investing circles. Already there has been a reduction of dividends in leading industries, and here and there a fall in the value of stocks. High prices have greatly checked building. The great credit advances made on "industrials," the stocks of manufacturing corporations, are one of the main sources of danger. Caution, however, has been learned by experience; the banking interests are more closely coördinated and give better mutual support than in the past, and a considerable decline in stocks has already occurred without as yet affecting general prices of commodities. Various novel features in the situation make prophecy difficult, but a period of liquidation and lower prices appears to be at hand.

The years from 1897 to 1903 have been characterized by significant prosperity and rising prices. The overly optimistic predictions of a collapse in the last two years have so far proven to be unfounded,[3] but there’s now a general sense of distrust in investment circles. Dividends in major industries have already been cut, and there’s been a decline in stock values here and there. High prices have significantly slowed down construction. The large credit extensions made on "industrials," the stocks of manufacturing companies, are a major source of risk. However, caution has been learned through experience; banking interests are now more coordinated and provide better mutual support than before, and a notable drop in stocks has already happened without yet impacting the overall prices of commodities. Various new elements in the situation make predictions challenging, but a period of sell-offs and decreasing prices seems to be on the horizon.

General features of crises

4. Irregular in time, and unlike in their immediate occasions, crises show some general features. The chief of these are told in the brief story of the course of prices. Crises are less severe in countries with less developed money and credit systems. They are harder in the United States and England than in Germany, harder in Germany than in France, harder in western Europe than in eastern Europe, harder in Christendom than in heathendom. They are less severe in rural districts, where prosperity depends more on crop conditions, and business has in it less of financial speculation. Their effects are least felt in the staple industries, for when hard times come, people economize on the less essential things. The glove-factory, the silk-factory, the golf-club-factory are more likely to close than the flouring-mill. They are felt less by classes with fixed incomes than[Pg 351] by those with variable ones. They affect wages and salaries less than profits. The rate of wages is affected only in a moderate degree, but laborers suffer in the loss of employment. The money-lender who has eliminated chance as far as possible and has taken a low rate of interest loses little; the risk-taker who draws his income from dividends on stock probably loses much.

4. Irregular over time and different in their immediate situations, crises have some common features. The main ones are highlighted in the brief overview of price movements. Crises tend to be less severe in countries with less developed monetary and credit systems. They're tougher in the United States and England than in Germany, tougher in Germany than in France, tougher in Western Europe than in Eastern Europe, and tougher in Christian countries than in non-Christian ones. They hit rural areas less hard, where prosperity relies more on crop conditions and business involves less financial speculation. Their impact is least felt in essential industries; when tough times arrive, people cut back on less essential items. The glove factory, silk factory, and golf club factory are more likely to shut down than the flour mill. People with fixed incomes feel the effects less[Pg 351] than those with variable incomes. Crises impact wages and salaries less than profits. Wage rates are only moderately affected, but workers do suffer from job losses. The money lender who has minimized risk and charges low interest loses little; however, the risk-taker who earns from stock dividends probably loses a lot.

§ III. VARIOUS EXPLANATIONS OF CRISES

Glut theories of crises

1. Over-production and under-consumption theories are those most widely held. In the first annual report of the United States Commissioner of Labor (1886) is given a long list of theories, more or less wild, that have been advanced in explanation of crises. It is simply a catalogue, not a logical grouping. Most of the views can be classed as under-consumption or over-production theories, which are but two aspects of the same idea. One view is that too many things are produced, another that too few are consumed. The over-production theorist, seeing that warehouses are filled with goods that cannot be disposed of for what they cost, that factories are shut down and men are out of employment for lack of demand, declares that productive power has grown too great. The under-consumption theorist, seeing the same facts, says that the trouble is lack of purchasing power. He admits that there are people who would like to buy these things, but he asserts that such people lack money because production grows faster than wages, wages being fixed, as he believes, by the minimum of subsistence—a theory akin to the iron law of wages. In both over-production and under-consumption theories the inequality of demand and supply is looked upon as a general one. There is supposed to be not merely an unequal and mistaken distribution of production, but a general excess of productive power.

1. Theories of over-production and under-consumption are the most commonly accepted. In the first annual report of the United States Commissioner of Labor (1886), there's a long list of theories, some quite far-fetched, put forward to explain economic crises. It’s simply a catalog, not a logical arrangement. Most of these views can be categorized as either under-consumption or over-production theories, which are just two sides of the same coin. One perspective is that too many goods are being produced, while the other argues that too few goods are being consumed. The over-production theorist, noticing that warehouses are full of products that can’t be sold for their original cost, that factories are closed, and that people are unemployed due to lack of demand, claims that production capacity has become too large. The under-consumption theorist, observing the same situation, argues that the issue is a lack of purchasing power. He acknowledges that there are people who want to buy these goods, but he insists these individuals lack the money because production is increasing faster than wages, which he believes are set by the minimum necessary for survival—a concept similar to the iron law of wages. In both over-production and under-consumption theories, the mismatch between demand and supply is viewed as a widespread issue. It’s believed there’s not only an unequal and misguided distribution of production but also a general surplus of productive capacity.

Defects of glut theories

The wide vogue held by these views would justify a fuller discussion and disproof of them here, did space permit. It[Pg 352] must suffice to indicate merely that they have the same taint of illogicalness as the "fallacy of waste," the "fallacy of saving" and, still closer likeness, the "fallacy of luxury." They overlook the fact that an income, either of money or of other goods, coming even to the wealthiest, will be used in some way. It may be used either for immediate consumption or for further indirect use in durable form. Through miscalculation there may be, at a given moment, too many consumption goods of a particular kind, but the durable applications can find no limit until the inconceivable day when the material world is no longer capable of improvement. At the time of a crisis, there is unquestionably a bad apportionment of productive agents, and a still worse adjustment of their valuations, but these in no wise negative the basic economic fact of the scarcity of wealth.

The widespread popularity of these views would justify a more detailed discussion and rebuttal here if there were enough space. It[Pg 352] is enough to simply point out that they share the same flaws in logic as the "fallacy of waste," the "fallacy of saving," and, even more similarly, the "fallacy of luxury." They ignore the fact that any income, whether from money or other goods, will be used in some way, even by the wealthiest. It may be spent on immediate consumption or invested for future use in a durable form. There might be, at a given moment, an overabundance of specific consumption goods due to miscalculations, but the potential for durable applications is limitless until an unimaginable day when the material world can no longer be improved. During a crisis, there is undoubtedly a poor distribution of productive resources and an even worse adjustment of their values, but these do not negate the fundamental economic reality of wealth scarcity.

Money theories of crises

2. Another group of theories explains the crises as being due to money, either too much or too little. The unregulated issue of bank-notes has been assigned as the cause of crises, especially under the circumstances accompanying such crises as those of 1837 and 1857 in America, when bank-note issues chanced to be the agency most marked in the undue and unsound expansion of credit. The issue of government paper money, leading to inflation and speculation, is assigned as a cause leading up to such a crisis as that of 1873, following our Civil War. The reverse view is taken by the advocates of a cheap and plentiful money. They say that these crises were caused, not by the expansion, but by the reduction of bank-notes; for example, not by the inflation of prices through the issue of greenbacks in 1862 to 1865, but by the contraction of the currency from 1866 to 1873.

2. Another group of theories explains the crises as being due to money, either too much or too little. The unregulated issuance of banknotes has been identified as a cause of crises, especially during events like those of 1837 and 1857 in America, when banknote issuance was particularly prominent in the unhealthy expansion of credit. The issuance of government paper money, which led to inflation and speculation, is cited as a cause leading up to the crisis of 1873, following our Civil War. In contrast, proponents of cheap and abundant money argue that these crises were caused not by expansion but by the reduction of banknotes; for instance, not by the price inflation from the issuance of greenbacks between 1862 and 1865, but by the contraction of the currency from 1866 to 1873.

Their inadequacy

There is only a fragment of truth in these various views. It is always lack of money at the moment of the crisis that causes any particular failure, and in that sense it is always lack of money that causes a crisis. But the question is, whether in any reasonable sense it can be said that it was[Pg 353] lack of a circulating medium before the crisis that brought it on. There is no support for this view, except in the rare case when the money standard is undergoing a rapid change, as in the United States from 1866 to 1873, and the statement then needs much modification and explanation. The money theories of crises are nearer to the truth than are the over-production type, for the crisis is always connected with money and prices. But it cannot be said that the absolute amount of money in circulation in the period preceding crises gives occasion to them. In a few instances a rapid change in the amount has had an important effect, but this fact does not explain crises in general.

There’s only a small piece of truth in these different opinions. It’s always a lack of money at the time of the crisis that leads to any particular failure, which means a lack of money is what triggers a crisis. But the question is whether it can reasonably be said that it was[Pg 353] the lack of a circulating medium before the crisis that caused it. There’s no evidence to support this view, except in rare cases when the money standard is changing rapidly, like in the United States from 1866 to 1873, and even then, that claim needs a lot of modification and explanation. The monetary theories of crises are closer to the truth than the overproduction theories because crises are always tied to money and prices. However, it can't be said that the total amount of money in circulation in the period leading up to crises is what causes them. In a few cases, a rapid change in the amount of money has had a significant impact, but this doesn’t explain crises in general.

Lack of confidence is said to be a cause of crises. This is a truism, but the lack of confidence is not without reason and cause. Over-confidence in the period of expanding prices is succeeded by extreme depression when many false hopes are shattered.

Lack of confidence is considered a cause of crises. This is a given, but the lack of confidence isn’t without reason and cause. Overconfidence during times of rising prices is followed by severe depression when many false hopes are crushed.

Capitalization theory of crises

3. Crises must be explained essentially as the forcible and sudden movement of readjustment in the mistaken capitalization of productive agents. Capitalization runs through all industry. The value of everything that lasts for more than a moment is built in part upon rents that are not actual, but expectative, whose amount, therefore, is a matter of guesswork, or "speculation." Many unknown factors enter into the estimate of future rents. The universal tendency to rhythm in motion (material or psychic) manifests itself in an overestimate or underestimate of rent and of every other factor in value. This is emphasized by a psychological factor called the "hypnotism of the crowd," Most men follow a leader in investment as in other things. The spirit of speculation grows till it becomes almost a frenzy, and people rush toward this or that investment, throwing capitalization in some industries far out of equilibrium with that in others.

3. Crises should be understood as the sudden and forceful need to adjust the misallocation of productive resources. Capitalization is a part of all industries. The value of anything that lasts for more than a moment is partly based on rents that are expectation-based rather than actual, making their value largely speculative. Many unknown factors play into estimating future rents. The universal tendency for rhythm in motion (whether material or psychological) leads to overestimating or underestimating rents and other value factors. This is highlighted by a psychological aspect known as the "hypnotism of the crowd." Most people tend to follow a leader when it comes to investments, just like in other areas. The spirit of speculation builds up until it reaches a frenzy, causing people to rush toward various investments, resulting in capitalization in some industries being far out of balance with others.

The use of credit enhances the rhythm of price. A large part of business is done practically on margins. If the value[Pg 354] of a thing fully paid for falls in the hands of the owner, he alone loses; but if the value of a thing only partly paid for falls so much that the owner is forced to default in his payment, the loss may be transmitted along the line of credit to every one in the series of transactions. A credit system, highly developed, is a house of cards at a time of financial stress. There is an element of credit in all modern business. Enterprisers enter into strenuous rivalry to secure the profits of a rise, ever hoping to get out whole before the crisis comes.

The use of credit influences pricing significantly. A big chunk of business operates on margins. If the value[Pg 354] of an item that’s fully paid for drops, only the owner suffers; but if the value of something that’s only partially paid for decreases to the point where the owner has to default on payment, the loss can spread through the entire credit chain affecting everyone involved in the transactions. A well-developed credit system is like a house of cards during financial trouble. There’s an element of credit in all modern business. Entrepreneurs compete fiercely to capture the profits from a price increase, always hoping to exit unscathed before a crisis hits.

Psychological nature and objective conditions of crises

The fundamental cause of crises thus is seen to be psychological; it is the rhythmic miscalculation of rents and of capital value, occurring to some degree throughout industry, but particularly in certain lines. But this subjective cause in men is given full opportunity for action only when certain favoring objective conditions are present. Most noteworthy of these besides the credit system is a dynamic condition of industry. The past century has opened up new fields for investment on an unexampled scale. Investment has advanced both intensively and extensively in a series of great waves. New machinery and processes have given undreamed of opportunities for enterprise in the older countries, and the physical frontier of investment has moved outward with the march of millions of immigrants to people the fertile wilderness. Such factors disturb the equilibrium of prices both in time and space, give a powerful impulse toward higher values in the older lands, and stimulate the hopes of all investors. When the balance between the capitalizations of various industries and between the rents of the various periods proves to be false, the inevitable readjustment causes suffering and loss to many, but particularly in the inflated industries. But, because of the mutual relations of men in business, few even of those who have kept freest from speculation can quite escape the evils.

The main cause of crises is seen as psychological; it’s the ongoing miscalculation of rents and capital value, which happens to some extent across all industries, but especially in certain areas. However, this subjective cause in people only has a chance to manifest when specific favorable objective conditions are in place. One of the most important of these, aside from the credit system, is a dynamic condition in industry. The past century has opened up new investment opportunities on an unprecedented scale. Investment has surged both intensively and extensively in a series of significant waves. New machinery and processes have created incredible opportunities for business in older countries, and the physical frontier of investment has expanded with millions of immigrants populating the fertile wilderness. These factors disrupt the balance of prices over time and across regions, driving up values in older areas and fueling the hopes of all investors. When the balance between the capitalizations of different industries and the rents across various periods turns out to be incorrect, the inevitable adjustment leads to suffering and loss for many, particularly in the overinflated industries. However, due to the interconnectedness of people in business, even those who have avoided speculation may still be affected by these issues.

Widespread effects on incomes

4. Crises must be discussed in connection with other subjects than profits. In the text-books the subject of the[Pg 355] crisis is variously classified. It may well be discussed with money, credit, and banking. It has its bearings on wages, justice in distribution, the theory of interest, and the consumption of wealth. But the reasons for taking it up in connection with the subject of profits are strongest. In no other connection is the presence of the element of speculation and of chance profit and loss in business so forcibly seen.

4. We need to talk about crises in relation to more than just profits. In textbooks, the topic of the[Pg 355] crisis is classified in different ways. It can definitely be addressed alongside money, credit, and banking. It also relates to wages, fairness in distribution, interest theory, and wealth consumption. However, the case for discussing it in connection with profits is the strongest. In no other context is the impact of speculation and the risks of profit and loss in business more clearly evident.

Their probable mitigation

The income of every class of society is to some extent affected by these more or less periodic fluctuations. They are in part the price paid for progress under the constantly shifting conditions of our dynamic industry. In part they are the proof of industrial maladjustment. The force of the shocks will no doubt be much reduced by better banking and business methods, and by a sound currency system. More important still, the development of moderation, conservatism, and a less speculative spirit among the leaders of business will do much toward softening the asperity of these scourges of industry.

The income of every social class is somewhat influenced by these periodic fluctuations. They are partly the cost of progress in our constantly changing industry. They also indicate issues within the industrial system. The impact of these shocks will likely lessen with improved banking and business practices, as well as a stable currency system. Even more crucial, fostering moderation, conservatism, and a less speculative attitude among business leaders will greatly help to ease the harshness of these challenges in the industry.


PART III

THE SOCIAL ASPECTS OF VALUE


DIVISION A—RELATION OF PRIVATE INCOME TO SOCIAL WELFARE


CHAPTER 38

PRIVATE PROPERTY AND INHERITANCE

§ I. IMPERSONAL AND PERSONAL SHARES OF INCOME

Functional vs. personal distribution

1. Under the title "the social aspects of value" are to be considered the influences exerted upon incomes by various social acts, ideals, and institutions. The incomes from the wages of free labor and those from the rent of wealth, as studied in the abstract theory of value, are alike in their impersonal aspect, their relation to utility. But while wage flows from a personal source—is an income appearing to reward the personal effort of the laborer, the income of the wealth-owner is due to the uses of goods. In the abstract theory of value we do not seek to get behind this impersonal phase of rent. The income arising from goods goes to the de facto owner of the goods. We do not ask how the goods first came into his possession, whether through labor or as a gift, whether stolen or inherited. Indeed, the economic theory of competitive rent may be said not to recognize the personal fact of ownership; it is concerned with the impersonal fact of usufruct. The theory of economic rent, of time-value and capital, and of wages, as measured by efficiency, is impersonal, is a study of functional distribution. In the problem of monopoly[Pg 360] the personal factor is more prominent, but the economic study of rent cannot well stop there.

1. Under the title "the social aspects of value," we need to consider the effects that different social actions, ideals, and institutions have on incomes. Incomes from wages for free labor and from the rent of wealth, as discussed in the abstract theory of value, are similar in their impersonal nature and their relation to utility. However, while wages originate from a personal source—an income that seems to reward the individual efforts of the worker—the income of the wealth owner comes from the use of goods. In the abstract theory of value, we don’t delve into the impersonal nature of rent. The income generated from goods goes to the actual owner of those goods. We don’t inquire how the goods came into their possession, whether through labor, as a gift, or if they were stolen or inherited. In fact, the economic theory of competitive rent can be said to overlook the personal aspect of ownership; it focuses on the impersonal reality of usufruct. The theories of economic rent, time-value and capital, and wages based on efficiency are all impersonal, studying functional distribution. In the issue of monopoly[Pg 360], the personal factor becomes more evident, but the economic study of rent can’t simply stop there.

Social institutions and personal incomes

An answer, at least in broad outline, must now be given to the question why some men are permitted to hold wealth as their "own," that is, as "property," while other men are propertyless. Why do the owners exact payment for the use of goods, and why are they allowed by their fellows to do so? Back of these facts is a great system of social institutions that helps to determine what men will do. Market value is a social fact; price is determined by the bidding of men under the existing social and political conditions. These broader social aspects of value remain for consideration. The influence of lawmaking, of collective action, and of social institutions on value must be noted. Incidentally, this has been done in speaking of patents, political monopolies, and related questions; but mainly the subject has been viewed from the individual standpoint; now it must be looked at more fully from the social side.

An answer, at least in general terms, must now be given to the question of why some people are allowed to own wealth as their "own," meaning as "property," while others do not have any property. Why do owners require payment for the use of goods, and why do others allow them to do so? Behind these facts is a large system of social institutions that shapes what people will do. Market value is a social reality; price is determined by what people are willing to pay under the current social and political conditions. These wider social aspects of value still need to be examined. The impact of lawmaking, collective action, and social institutions on value should be acknowledged. This has been touched on when discussing patents, political monopolies, and related issues; however, the focus has mainly been on the individual perspective. Now, it should be explored more thoroughly from the social angle.

Harmony of the studies of impersonal and of personal distribution

2. The study of personal distribution should include a further explanation of the various elements that unite to form the individual's income. "Distribution" in economics is the reasoned explanation of the way in which the total product of a society is divided among its members. It is a logical question and not an ethical one. The economist first asks, What is the effect of utility on value? and, next, What is the relation of these goods to the personal incomes of the members of society? It is not his peculiar part to say whether this is the best distribution in an ethical sense, yet in pursuing the question of distribution one comes to the border of certain moral questions.

2. The study of personal distribution should provide a deeper look into the different factors that come together to shape an individual’s income. "Distribution" in economics is the clear explanation of how a society's total output is shared among its members. It's a practical question, not an ethical one. The economist first asks, What impact does utility have on value? and then, What is the connection between these goods and the personal incomes of society's members? It's not his role to determine whether this is the best distribution from an ethical standpoint, but exploring the topic of distribution inevitably leads to some moral considerations.

The impersonal and the personal views of distribution are not, however, contradictory; they are different aspects of the same question. It cannot be said that the analysis of economic rent is a purely abstract piece of work. In fact, the impersonal view of distribution is essential to an understanding of the personal view of it. The one gives general[Pg 361] principles, the other the special cases. In the practical economic issues of the day, the most urgent need is a better popular understanding of the abstracter theory of value. It is a guiding thread through otherwise bewildering mazes.

The impersonal and personal views on distribution aren't contradictory; they're two different sides of the same coin. You can't say that analyzing economic rent is just some abstract exercise. In fact, the impersonal view of distribution is crucial for understanding the personal perspective. One provides general principles, while the other focuses on specific cases. In the pressing economic issues we face today, there's a strong need for a better public understanding of the more abstract theory of value. It's a guiding thread through otherwise confusing complexities.

Composition of personal incomes

The actual incomes of individuals are made up of different elements. The wage-earner and the salaried man are rarely quite without material wealth. The enterpriser gets some income also in the form of contract interest, or as rent from machinery. Actual personal incomes are therefore a sum of various functional or impersonal incomes. The earnings of every agent may be thought of as always going either to some individual or to some group. By social convention the receiver of incomes that are not personal gifts is supposed to have produced them. This involves the great assumption that the owner of a piece of land has produced or contributed in some way to society an amount equal to the rent. This may be true in many cases, but in many cases this view cannot be accepted without close scrutiny.

The actual incomes of individuals consist of different components. Wage earners and salaried workers rarely lack material wealth. Entrepreneurs also earn income through contract interests or rental payments from machinery. Therefore, actual personal incomes are a mix of various functional or impersonal earnings. We can think of the income generated by each contributor as always going to either an individual or a group. By social standards, the person receiving income that isn’t a personal gift is assumed to have created it. This leads to the significant assumption that the owner of a piece of land has produced or somehow contributed to society an amount equal to the rent. While this may be true in many situations, in numerous cases, this perspective cannot be accepted without careful examination.

Law in relation to wealth

3. Property and wealth are respectively the personal and the impersonal, the legal and the economic, aspects of productive agents. Law holds an important place in the discussion of actual economic questions. This fact was not overlooked by John Stuart Mill, and it has been far more clearly recognized in the last few years, especially by the German economists. Political law in the broadest sense, as embodied in the state, is, in the first place, a set of rules to guide the conduct and regulate the relations of men in society—a legal code; it is, in the next place, a governmental machine to determine disputes between men—a judicial system; and it is, finally, physical power to bring contestants into court and to secure and protect their rights—a police force. Whether acting through legislature, courts, or police, in all its dealings with wealth the law is predominantly personal. The question the law asks and answers regarding wealth is not What, but Who? Who is the owner, who should control, receive, enjoy the income? Economic wealth[Pg 362] consists of scarce things, of valuable agents, and because they are scarce, men quarrel over them. Because of the impersonal economic fact that a field and a machine produce scarce goods, arises the legal question as to which man is entitled to enjoy them.

3. Property and wealth are the personal and impersonal, legal and economic, aspects of productive agents. Law plays a crucial role in discussions about real economic issues. John Stuart Mill recognized this, and it's been even more clearly acknowledged in recent years, particularly by German economists. Political law, in the broadest sense, as represented by the state, is primarily a set of rules that guides behavior and regulates relationships among people in society—a legal code. It is also a governmental system for resolving disputes between individuals—a judicial system. Finally, it involves the physical power needed to bring parties into court and to secure and protect their rights—a police force. Whether through legislation, courts, or police, the law predominantly focuses on personal aspects when dealing with wealth. The question the law asks and answers about wealth isn't What, but Who? Who owns it, who should control or benefit from the income? Economic wealth[Pg 362] consists of scarce resources, valuable agents, and because they are limited, people argue over them. The impersonal economic reality that a field and a machine produce scarce goods raises the legal question of which person is entitled to enjoy them.

Property and wealth

In the case of material things, property value and capital value must be exactly equal. Property rights cover the ownership of a material thing. Material property consists of things viewed with reference to ownership; capital consists of the same things viewed with reference to their economic services. There are other property rights besides those in material things, various immaterial rights controlling the action of the individual and thus giving a sort of ownership of the individual's actions. Such are patents which forbid other men making a particular kind of machine; copyrights which forbid other men printing certain writings; legal contracts that limit the action of men in various ways, and thus appear to abridge their liberty.

In terms of physical items, property value and capital value must be exactly the same. Property rights refer to the ownership of a physical item. Material property includes items considered in relation to their ownership; capital represents those same items viewed in terms of their economic utility. In addition to rights related to physical items, there are various immaterial rights that regulate individual actions, essentially granting a form of ownership over those actions. Examples include patents that prevent others from manufacturing a specific type of machine; copyrights that prohibit others from publishing certain written works; legal contracts that restrict individuals' actions in various ways, which can seem to limit their freedom.

§ II. THE ORIGIN OF PRIVATE PROPERTY

Property and income

1. Property is ownership, the legal control over the sources of economic income. The Latin word property means ownership, and hence that which pertains to the individual, that which is a man's own. The control of property is greater or less. The law makes between property rights and equity rights certain subtle distinctions which have their reason in the history, if not in the logic, of the law, but which are not essential to economic discussion. What we are interested in are the equitable claims of men to wealth rather than the technical property rights. With that thought let us consider the value of the control of wealth. If a farm worth ten thousand dollars is mortgaged for five thousand dollars, its economic worth is ten thousand dollars after as before the mortgage, but the equitable claim is divided into two shares of five thousand dollars each. The value of the property[Pg 363] right cannot, in a reasonable view, be greater than the value of the economic wealth it covers. There is much confusion in the law of taxation on this point. The law treats the farm as property and the debt upon it, whether secured by a mortgage or not, as another body of property. Needless to say, this leads to absurd conclusions in reasoning, and to gross injustice.

1. Property is ownership, the legal control over sources of economic income. The Latin word for property means ownership, referring to what belongs to an individual, what is a person’s own. The level of control over property can vary. The law draws some subtle distinctions between property rights and equity rights based on history, if not logic, but these distinctions aren't crucial for our economic discussion. What we’re focused on are the fair claims of individuals to wealth rather than the technical property rights. Keeping that in mind, let’s look at the value of controlling wealth. If a farm valued at ten thousand dollars is mortgaged for five thousand dollars, its economic worth remains ten thousand dollars, just like before the mortgage, but the equitable claim is split into two shares of five thousand dollars each. The value of the property[Pg 363] right cannot reasonably be considered greater than the value of the economic wealth it represents. There’s a lot of confusion in tax law regarding this issue. The law considers the farm as property and the debt on it, whether secured by a mortgage or not, as a separate piece of property. This obviously leads to absurd reasoning and significant injustice.

Forms and modes of ownership

There are different forms of ownership: first, private, as that of individuals, families, partnerships, or corporations; second, public or state, as the ownership of the state house, the highway, the Adirondack forest-reserve or the Erie Canal. These are equally effective as against the claims of outsiders, but the rights of those inside the circle of ownership differ. For example, the rights of one shareholder against another, or the rights of one member of a family as against another, are not the same as the rights against outsiders. Private property is the characteristic feature of our present industrial society, but it exists side by side with state property and with many intermediate grades between private and common property. Private property, while attacked on some sides, is usually accepted without question; but in this age of inquiry its origin should be examined, its limits and the reasons for them should be noted, and its purpose, faults, and effects should be set clearly before the judgment.

There are different types of ownership: first, private, which includes individuals, families, partnerships, or corporations; second, public or state, like the ownership of government buildings, highways, the Adirondack forest reserve, or the Erie Canal. Both types are equally valid against claims from outsiders, but the rights of those within the ownership circle differ. For instance, the rights of one shareholder against another, or the rights of one family member against another, are not the same as the rights against outsiders. Private property is a key feature of our modern industrial society, but it coexists with state property and various forms between private and common ownership. While private property is challenged by some, it is generally accepted without question; however, in this era of inquiry, its origin should be examined, its limits and the reasons for them should be noted, and its purpose, flaws, and impacts should be clearly presented for judgment.

Various theories of property: Occupation

2. The older theories of the origin of private property are those of occupation, conquest, labor, natural rights, and law. The theory of occupation is that property is based upon the priority of claim of one who finds wealth without an owner and appropriates it. This, to be sure, is a statement of what happens in the settlement of new countries, but it is not an explanation of the property rights that are arising every moment, nor does it give a logical reason for the continuance of ancient property rights.

2. The earlier theories about how private property originated include occupation, conquest, labor, natural rights, and law. The occupation theory suggests that property arises when someone claims something they find that has no owner and takes it for themselves. This certainly describes what occurs when new territories are settled, but it doesn’t explain the property rights that emerge continuously, nor does it provide a logical reason for the persistence of traditional property rights.

Conquest

The same can be said of the conquest theory, the theory that property is based on force. It applies to the invasion of[Pg 364] the Roman provinces by the barbarian tribes who divided the country and enslaved the population. But it rarely applies to present-day happenings and at its best it cannot, to modern minds, "justify" present property rights.

The same goes for the conquest theory, which suggests that property is based on force. This applies to the invasion of[Pg 364] the Roman provinces by barbarian tribes who took control of the land and enslaved the people. However, it hardly relates to current events, and at best, it cannot, in the eyes of modern thinkers, "justify" today's property rights.

Labor

The labor theory, meeting some queries where others fail, is that ownership is based on production, on the right of a man to that to which his brain and his muscle have imparted value. It is evident that this test leaves without explanation or justification a great number of things that do exist and have existed as property.

The labor theory, addressing certain questions where others fall short, is that ownership is grounded in production, specifically the right of a person to what their intellect and effort have added value to. Clearly, this standard leaves many things that exist and have existed as property without explanation or justification.

Natural rights

The natural-rights theory is that property is necessary for the realization of the dignity of human nature. This, if true, would be not so much an explanation as a condemnation of private property as it has existed in most cases, as millions of men are in every land all but lacking in property, and inequality of possession is everywhere marked. This theory expresses, however, one of the worthy ideals of modern democracy. Although, in common with the various other "natural rights" theories, it must to-day be deemed too absolute and too individualistic, it contains a far-reaching truth, of which due account must be taken in our social philosophy.

The natural-rights theory suggests that property is essential for achieving the dignity of human nature. If this is true, it would largely serve as a critique of private property as it has typically existed, since millions of people around the world have very little property, and inequality in ownership is clearly evident everywhere. However, this theory reflects one of the important ideals of modern democracy. Although, like many other "natural rights" theories, it is now seen as too extreme and too focused on the individual, it holds a significant truth that must be considered in our thinking about society.

Law

The legal theory is that property exists because the law says it shall. This expresses a truth, but is no more than a truism. The law determines the limits of property, but what determines the limits of the law? What practical or social justification is there for passing and continuing such law? The legal theory does not explain anything finally. Each of these theories has its defects, but each points to some fact important and significant, at certain times and places, in the explanation of this widespread institution.

The legal theory suggests that property exists because the law declares it to be so. This is true, but it's just a basic observation. The law sets the boundaries of property, but what defines the boundaries of the law? What practical or social reasons exist for creating and upholding such laws? The legal theory doesn’t provide a complete explanation. Each of these theories has its shortcomings, but each highlights some important and meaningful fact at specific times and places that helps explain this widespread institution.

Property in early societies

3. The institution of private property has evolved under diverse conditions; the question of its origin is not the same as that of its present justification. In early societies individual property rights were not very clearly marked. Every tribe asserted against other tribes, and tried to uphold, by[Pg 365] war, its claims upon its customary hunting-grounds; but the claims of the individual hunter and fisher within the tribe did not often come into conflict. Private property at the outset was in personal possessions, ornaments, weapons, utensils, which were very meager in that primitive society where it was the custom "to go calling with a club instead of a card-case." Only later came individual property in land. A few years ago it was generally believed that the organization of the old German tribes was politically an almost perfect democracy, and economically a communism wherein all had equal claims on the land. To-day this opinion is very seriously questioned. It seems probable that the so-called communism was really an oligarchy of the favored, and that the masses lived in subjection, cut off from all but a meager share in the public property.

3. The concept of private property has changed under various conditions; the question of where it comes from is different from the question of how it's justified today. In early societies, individual property rights weren't very clearly defined. Each tribe claimed their hunting grounds against others and fought to defend those claims, but the rights of individual hunters and fishers within a tribe rarely clashed. Private property initially referred to personal belongings, like ornaments, weapons, and utensils, which were quite limited in that primitive society where it was common "to visit with a club instead of a business card." It wasn't until later that individual property in land developed. A few years ago, it was widely believed that the organization of the old German tribes was politically almost a perfect democracy and economically communistic, where everyone had equal rights to the land. Today, this view is being seriously challenged. It seems likely that this so-called communism was actually an oligarchy of the privileged few, while the majority lived in subjugation, with access to only a small share of the public property.

Origin vs. present justification of property

However that may have been, strong forces within historic times have put an end to the common ownership and tillage of land as it existed among the serfs of Europe. The common tillage of land was shown by experience to be wasteful. Not only did competition tend to bring the economic agents into more efficient hands, but the movement was furthered by many acts of injustice and violence on the part of those in power. Inquiries into the origin and development of this social institution are interesting and helpful in forming an estimate of its present significance, but the problems of the past are not those of to-day. Whether or not the ancient beginning of property in Europe was in violence and evil has but a remote bearing on the question as to the present working of it. Social conditions and needs have not changed more than have the forms and limits of property itself. Each generation has its own problems to solve, and each must test existing institutions by their present results, ignoring for the most part the evils of the past.

However that may have been, strong forces throughout history have ended the common ownership and cultivation of land as it existed among the serfs of Europe. The shared farming of land was proven to be inefficient. Not only did competition lead to more effective management of economic resources, but this change was also driven by numerous acts of injustice and violence by those in power. Investigating the origin and development of this social system is interesting and useful for understanding its current significance, but the issues of the past are not the same as those we face today. Whether the ancient roots of property in Europe were based in violence and wrongdoing has little relevance to how it operates now. Social conditions and needs have changed just as much as the forms and boundaries of property itself. Each generation has its own challenges to address, and each must evaluate existing systems based on their current outcomes, largely overlooking the wrongdoings of the past.

Social expediency the ground of private property
Shifting limits of the law of property

4. Private property may now be justified mainly on the grounds of social expediency. This is a broad explanation under which can be brought the many varying conditions;[Pg 366] but it has the fault of a broad explanation, that it needs be further explained. Conceding that private property works hardship to the individual in many cases, it must be justified on the ground that, on the whole, it furthers the progress of society. Private property is looked upon by some as merely reflecting or expressing the economic inequalities of men; the man poor in ability is the man poor in property. It is looked upon by others as exaggerating, indeed at times reversing, the economic abilities of men. In general, it must be judged by this test: Does it further the welfare of society better than would any alternative plan for the control of economic wealth? The question is not whether it is faultless, for no human institution is so. Nor must it be assumed that property is a fixed and uniform mode of control; there are many kinds of property. Different parts of wealth may be treated in different ways: there may be private property in wagons, and public property in roads; private property in houses, and public property in forests; private property in automobiles, and, in some countries, public property in railway-carriages. But any rule of property, like any other workable human law, must be applicable to all individuals that meet the conditions. Hence any human institution must be judged by its average working, not by exceptional cases.

4. Private property can now mainly be justified on the basis of social practicality. This is a broad explanation that encompasses various conditions;[Pg 366] however, its broad nature means it requires further clarification. While it's true that private property can create difficulties for individuals in many instances, it needs to be justified by the fact that, overall, it contributes to societal progress. Some view private property as simply reflecting or representing the economic inequalities among people; those who lack abilities are often the ones who lack property. Others see it as amplifying or even reversing the economic capabilities of individuals. In general, it should be assessed by this standard: Does it benefit society more than any alternative method of managing economic wealth? The concern isn't whether it’s perfect, since no human system is. Additionally, we shouldn't assume that property is a fixed and uniform means of control; there are various types of property. Different elements of wealth may be managed in different ways: there can be private ownership of vehicles while roads are publicly owned; private ownership of homes versus public ownership of forests; private ownership of cars, and, in some countries, public ownership of train carriages. However, any property rule, like any effective human law, must apply to all individuals meeting the necessary conditions. Therefore, any human system should be evaluated based on its overall function, not on exceptional circumstances.

The very acceptance of the theory of social expediency implies the need of a readjustment of the institution of private property; for private property, as it is found to-day, is complicated by many historical accidents. Survivals of ancient injustice and relics of feudal institutions that rest on no vital reason remain in our new country as well as in the older ones. The limits of property in many respects are determined, not according to the logic of expediency, but by the social inertia which often governs succeeding generations.

The acceptance of the theory of social expediency requires us to rethink the institution of private property. Today, private property is affected by many historical factors. There are remnants of past injustices and traces of feudal systems that lack any solid justification, existing in both our new country and the older ones. The boundaries of property are often defined not by logical reasoning for the greater good, but by the social resistance that frequently influences later generations.

§ III. LIMITATIONS OF THE RIGHT OF PRIVATE PROPERTY

Public interests limiting property rights

1. Unmodified private control of property is unknown: the public makes many reservations in its own interest. Few realize the manifold ways in which property rights are limited. There is, first, a whole set of limitations to prevent nuisances. An owner in many situations is not free to build a slaughter-house or to start a glue-factory on his land. Property is governed by general public utility, and anything that threatens to become a nuisance or a danger is excluded. When, under the right of eminent domain, the state or the railroad takes the old homestead from its owner who would live and die there, the payment of money damages to him does not make this the less a limitation of his property rights. Rights of way on property exist either through contract or by prescription permitting its public use. Most important of all limitations is the right of taxation, by which society takes more or less of private incomes for purposes of which the individual owners may in no way approve.

1. Unrestricted private ownership of property is rare: the public places many limitations for its own benefit. Few people understand the many ways in which property rights are restricted. First, there are numerous limitations to prevent nuisances. An owner often can't freely build a slaughterhouse or start a glue factory on their land. Property is regulated by general public welfare, and anything that poses a risk of becoming a nuisance or danger is not allowed. When the state or a railroad exercises eminent domain to take away a long-time family home from its owner, the compensation paid doesn’t change the fact that it limits their property rights. Rights of way on property exist either through contracts or historical use that allows public access. The most significant limitation is the right of taxation, where society takes a portion of private incomes for purposes that individual owners may not agree with.

Private claims limiting property rights

2. The law enforces a multitude of private claims against private owners. A variety of rights called easements or servitudes may attach to private property, modifying its exclusive use. Leases for any period are a virtual limitation of the control and division of the ownership. Both the holder of the lease and the owner of the property have certain rights before the law. The lender of money secured by mortgage has a legally recognized and enforceable interest in the mortgaged wealth. Property is left in trust for the benefit of persons or of institutions or of the public, and is administered by trustees who are strictly bound to the execution of the terms of their instructions. Contracts of many sorts are entered into by owners, limiting their control in manifold ways, and the law enforces these contracts. These all form a complex of equitable claims, which together equal in value one undivided property right, which in turn equals[Pg 368] the value of the wealth. These claims mutually limit each other (whether they be called equitable claims, or liens, or property rights), and wealth is not multiplied by multiplying the claims, as the lawmakers unfortunately sometimes assume to be the case.

2. The law enforces a range of private claims against private owners. Various rights, known as easements or servitudes, can be attached to private property, changing its exclusive use. Leases of any duration effectively limit the control and division of ownership. Both the leaseholder and the property owner have specific rights under the law. A lender who provides money secured by a mortgage has a legally recognized and enforceable interest in the mortgaged asset. Property can be held in trust for the benefit of individuals, institutions, or the public, and is managed by trustees who are strictly required to follow the terms of their instructions. Owners enter into many types of contracts, which limit their control in various ways, and the law enforces these contracts. All of these create a complex of equitable claims that together represent one undivided property right, which in turn equals [Pg 368] the value of the asset. These claims limit each other (whether referred to as equitable claims, liens, or property rights), and wealth is not increased by simply multiplying the claims, as lawmakers unfortunately sometimes believe.

Limitation of bequest

3. The right of bequest, or of gift at death, is limited in various ways in different countries. The term bequest implies a will, usually a written will in which the person, foreseeing death, has expressed his wishes as to the disposition of his property. It is said sometimes that bequest is a "logical" result of private property, but the law does not treat it as such. In countries where hereditary aristocracies exist, primogeniture is in some cases required by law, in others so strongly favored by public opinion that it is practically always followed. Custom limits bequests in England to members of the family, and wills giving outside the family are rare, and are almost always broken in the courts. John Stuart Mill contrasts this with the frequent practice by rich men in America of giving for public purposes. In France the right of bequest outside the family is legally limited; only the share of one child can be willed away by the father, and the rest must be equally divided among the children. Settlements and fidei commissa are limited in many countries, because of the recognized social evils resulting from the tying up of estates for generations. Throughout the history of England, Parliament has given attention to the question of mortmain, which chiefly concerned the drifting of great estates into the hands of the church or of corporations, as a result of bequests by the pious. Only recently in England, and to a less extent in this country, has been seriously discussed the policy of permitting unlimited endowments to charitable institutions, and new legislation has diverted from their original purposes some of the old endowments. These varied and often strict limitations of the right of private property are all determined by some thought, wise or foolish, of social expediency.

3. The right to leave a will or give gifts after death is restricted in different ways depending on the country. The term "bequest" refers to a will, typically a written document where a person, anticipating death, outlines their wishes for how to distribute their property. It's often said that bequest is a "logical" outcome of private property, but the law doesn't see it that way. In countries with hereditary aristocracies, firstborn inheritance is sometimes mandated by law, while in other cases, it's so strongly supported by public sentiment that it is almost always practiced. In England, customs often limit bequests to family members, and wills leaving property to anyone outside the family are uncommon and usually contested in court. John Stuart Mill highlights this by noting that wealthy individuals in America frequently donate to public causes. In France, the ability to bequeath outside the family is legally restricted; a father is only allowed to will away the share of one child, while the remaining portion must be equally divided among all children. Settlements and fidei commissa are also restricted in many countries due to recognized social issues caused by holding estates for generations. Throughout England's history, Parliament has focused on the issue of mortmain, mainly concerning the accumulation of large estates by churches or corporations due to bequests from the devout. Only recently has England, and to a lesser extent the U.S., started to seriously address the idea of allowing unlimited endowments to charitable organizations, leading to new laws that have redirected some older endowments from their original purposes. These various and often strict limitations on the right of private property all stem from some perception, whether wise or foolish, of social convenience.

Limitation of right of inheritance

4. The law of inheritance varies greatly with time and place. Inheritance, in contrast with bequest, usually means succession to the property of one who has died intestate, that is, has made no will. The old idea of family unity survives in great measure in modern laws of inheritance. The nearest living relatives, no matter how distant they may be, inherit property when there is no will. When a miser dies in solitude and neglect, the world must be searched over to find a remote cousin to take the hoarded wealth. Inheritance is limited largely at present by the power of taxation. The view is growing that the claims of the society in which wealth has been acquired are stronger than those of relatives distant alike in space, in blood, and in affectionate interest. This view is reflected in many recent inheritance-tax laws which take from the shares of distant relatives a goodly portion for public purposes.

4. The law of inheritance varies significantly over time and location. Inheritance, unlike bequest, typically refers to taking over the property of someone who has died without a will. The old concept of family unity still influences modern inheritance laws. The closest living relatives, regardless of how far removed they might be, inherit property when there’s no will. When a miser passes away in isolation and neglect, the world must be searched to find a distant cousin to claim the accumulated wealth. Currently, inheritance is heavily influenced by tax laws. There is a growing belief that society’s claims to the wealth that has been accumulated are stronger than those of relatives who are distant in geography, blood, and emotional connection. This belief is evident in many recent inheritance tax laws that take a significant portion from the shares of distant relatives for public use.

The question is raised in many minds, If private property is not an absolute right, what shall be its limits? What changes should be made in it? The essential thought in the various attacks on the institution of private property is that, because it occasions inequality in incomes, it is not socially expedient. The conviction is growing that, in some general way, incomes should correspond to, and reflect, social service. It is well to consider more closely what the terms social expediency and social service imply.

The question arises in many people's minds: If private property isn't an absolute right, what should its limits be? What changes should we make to it? The main idea behind the various critiques of private property is that, because it leads to income inequality, it's not beneficial for society. There's a growing belief that, in some general sense, incomes should align with and reflect social contributions. It's important to take a closer look at what the terms social expediency and social service really mean.


CHAPTER 39

INCOME AND SOCIAL SERVICE

§ I. INCOME FROM PROPERTY

The justice of property questioned

1. Property rights must meet the test of social expediency. If private property is defended on the ground of social expediency, it must show good social results. It is not a sacred thing; it is open to examination, and must be judged by its fruits. Of all the forms of income, that from property has been most strongly attacked. The thought is that enjoyment of wealth should not be found apart from labor, and that it should bear some proportion to services performed. The enjoyment of an ample income by one who does no more than to draw checks or to sign coupons seems to many minds to be unjust; and it is often questioned whether there is any social service performed by the receivers of the rent from land. Property seems in many cases to be distributed without rule or reason. It does not correspond with beauty, strength, wit, wisdom, temperance, gentleness, or charity. Since the beginning of the Christian era, reformers have assailed and preached against the prevailing inequality of wealth. The idea that incomes, if not equal, should correspond to social service has always been present in some vague way in the minds of men.

1. Property rights need to pass the test of social usefulness. If private property is justified on the basis of social usefulness, it must demonstrate positive social outcomes. It’s not an untouchable thing; it’s subject to scrutiny and should be evaluated by its results. Out of all the types of income, income from property has faced the most criticism. The belief is that wealth should not be enjoyed without effort, and it should relate to the services provided. The idea of someone enjoying a substantial income just by cashing checks or collecting dividends seems unfair to many; it’s often questioned whether those collecting rent from land are contributing anything to society. Property appears to be allocated without clear rationale. It doesn’t align with qualities like beauty, strength, intelligence, wisdom, moderation, kindness, or generosity. Since the start of the Christian era, reformers have criticized and spoken out against the existing wealth inequality. The notion that incomes, if not equal, should relate to social contributions has always been vaguely present in people’s minds.

Social effect of the right to give

2. The right to transmit property by inheritance or by gift may be judged with reference to its effect on the giver, on the receiver, and on society at large. It is well to take these three points of view. The right to dispose of property either during life or at death has undoubtedly in many[Pg 371] ways a good effect on the character of men. It stimulates the father to provide for his children, the husband to provide for his wife. There is a joy in giving, a joy in the power to bestow one's wealth on those one loves. The right to give stimulates industry, frugality, ingenuity, and yields productive results. Much of the existing wealth probably never would have been created if men did not have this right of gift. But there is a limit to the working of this motive, and other motives often are much more effective. Many men after gaining a competence continue to work for love of wealth and power in their own lifetime, as the miser continues to toil for love of gold. When men without families die wealthy, when men that have not the slightest interest in their nearest relatives labor and amass wealth till their dying day, it is evident that the right to bequeath property has little to do with their efforts. Love of accumulation and love of power in these cases supply the motive. A more limited liberty to dispose of property at death might still suffice, therefore, to call out the greater part of the efforts now made to accumulate property.

2. The right to pass on property through inheritance or as a gift can be evaluated based on its impact on the giver, the receiver, and society as a whole. It’s useful to consider these three perspectives. The ability to manage property during one's life or at death has certainly fostered many[Pg 371] positive effects on people's character. It motivates fathers to take care of their children and husbands to support their wives. There’s a joy in giving and in the ability to share one's wealth with loved ones. The freedom to give encourages hard work, saving, creativity, and leads to fruitful outcomes. Much of the wealth we see today probably wouldn't exist if people didn't have the right to give. However, there are limits to this motivational factor, and other motivations often play a bigger role. Many individuals, after achieving financial stability, continue to work for the sake of wealth and power during their lifetime, just as a miser toils endlessly for gold. When wealthy individuals die without families or those who have no real connection to their closest relatives work hard to accumulate wealth until the end of their lives, it becomes clear that the desire to inherit property is not the main driver of their efforts. In these situations, the desire for accumulation and power takes precedence. Therefore, a more restricted ability to distribute property upon death might still be enough to inspire most of the current efforts to gather wealth.

Effect of the right to receive

That the effects on the receiver of the property are good is somewhat more doubtful. It is true that children raised in great comfort or luxury would be more than ordinarily unhappy if plunged into poverty or even into humble circumstances on the death of their parents. There is much social justification for permitting families to maintain an accustomed standard of comfort. Few would deny that a moderate provision by parents to provide education and opportunity for their children is commendable and desirable. But the evil effects of waiting for dead men's shoes are proverbial. Many a boy's greatest curse has been his father's fortune. Men of native ability wait idly for fortune to come, and opportunities for self-help slip by unheeded. The world often exclaims over the failure of the sons of noted men to achieve great things, for, despite confusing evidence, men still have faith in heredity. A too easy fortune saps[Pg 372] ambition and relaxes energy; and thus rich men's sons, if not most carefully and wisely trained, are made pitiable paupers in spirit, while the self-made fathers think their boys have chances they themselves did not enjoy. The greater social loss is not the dissipated fortunes, but the ruined characters.

That the impact on the person receiving the property is good is somewhat more questionable. It's true that kids raised in luxury would likely be extremely unhappy if they were suddenly thrown into poverty or even modest living after their parents pass away. There’s a good social reason for allowing families to keep a certain level of comfort. Few would argue that parents providing a reasonable education and opportunities for their children is a good and desirable thing. But the negative effects of waiting for inherited wealth are well-known. Many boys have been burdened by their father's wealth. Capable men often wait passively for fortune to arrive, missing out on chances for self-improvement. People often wonder why the sons of famous men fail to achieve greatness, as, despite mixed signals, there remains a belief in hereditary influence. An easy fortune can drain ambition and deplete energy, causing rich men's sons, if not raised very carefully and wisely, to become spiritually impoverished, while the self-made fathers assume their sons have opportunities they never had. The bigger social loss isn’t the squandered wealth, but the damaged character.

Broader social effects of inheritance

The effects of inheritance on the community are good in so far as it secures efficient management of wealth. If the son or relative has been in business with the deceased, there is a reason that he should inherit the property, and his succession to it makes the least disturbance to existing business conditions. But every profligate son is an argument against inheritance; every incompetent heir is an argument in the hands of the enemies of the existing order of society. It is to society's interest that no able-bodied member shall stand idle. Every child should have presented to him the motive to devote his powers to the social welfare in economic or other directions. Moreover, many feel that the great fortunes now accumulating through successive generations in the hands of a few families are endangering our free society, even if these fortunes should continue to be well administered. There is a widespread feeling that the heredity of great wealth is, like the heredity of political power, out of harmony with the democratic spirit—though this may easily become a misleading comparison. Still, democracy wishes to see men as individuals put to the test, not profiting forever by the deeds of their forebears. This feeling is shared by those who cannot be charged with radical prejudices. A few years ago the Illinois Bar Association passed a somewhat startling resolution favoring moderate limits to inherited fortunes. Every year sees bills of this purport introduced in the legislatures and in Congress. Andrew Carnegie says it would be a good thing if every boy had to start in poverty and make his own way. Cecil Rhodes recorded in his will his contempt for the idle, expectant heir.

The impact of inheritance on the community is positive as long as it ensures effective management of wealth. If the son or relative has been involved in the business with the deceased, there's a valid reason for him to inherit the property, and his taking over makes the least disruption to the current business environment. However, every wayward son is a counterargument against inheritance; every unqualified heir is an argument used by those opposed to the existing social order. It's in society's best interest for no able-bodied member to remain idle. Every child should be motivated to contribute his skills to the social good in economic or other ways. Furthermore, many believe that the massive fortunes building up over generations in the hands of a few families threaten our free society, even if these fortunes are well managed. There's a widespread sentiment that inheriting great wealth, like inheriting political power, clashes with the democratic spirit—although this comparison can be misleading. Still, democracy prefers to see individuals challenged on their own merits rather than benefiting indefinitely from their ancestors' achievements. This view is held by many who cannot be labeled as radicals. A few years ago, the Illinois Bar Association passed a somewhat surprising resolution advocating for reasonable limits on inherited wealth. Each year, similar bills are introduced in state legislatures and Congress. Andrew Carnegie suggested that it would be beneficial if every boy had to start out in poverty and carve his own path. Cecil Rhodes expressed in his will his disdain for the lazy, entitled heir.

The test of wise inheritance laws

3. Social expediency will limit the right of intestate[Pg 373] inheritance to persons in essential economic and social relations. Public opinion is not yet crystallized in favor of this formal proposition, but tends strongly toward it. The foregoing considerations show that the right of gift in the lifetime of the giver should be the freest. The right of bequest, that is, of gift by will, should be liberal. The man who has acquired wealth may well be trusted to decide who bear to him a close social or personal relation, and to say whose lives have in a measure furnished the motives of his activity. But the right of intestate inheritance by distant relatives is one that stands on weak social foundations to-day. It appears to be an unreasonable survival from more patriarchal conditions. The true test is whether the wish to provide for these heirs has furnished the motive for the producing and preserving of the wealth. The claims of those nearest in blood and closest in personal relations are strongest. Family affection and friendship form the strongest of social ties, and it is socially expedient to cultivate them. Motives for abstinence and industry must be strengthened. But the same test shows that the zealous regard of the American law for the rights of grandnephews in Australia, or even of brothers long absent in distant quarters of this country, is irrational, and is unjust to the community where the fortune lies.

3. Social convenience will restrict the right of intestate[Pg 373] inheritance to people in essential economic and social relationships. Public opinion hasn't fully formed in support of this proposal yet, but it's leaning toward it. The points made earlier suggest that the right to give while alive should be as unrestricted as possible. The right to bequeath, or give through a will, should also be generous. A person who has acquired wealth can be trusted to determine who has a close social or personal connection with them and to recognize whose lives have influenced their work. However, the right of intestate inheritance for distant relatives is built on shaky social grounds today. It seems to be an outdated remnant from more patriarchal times. The real measure is whether the desire to support these heirs motivated the creation and preservation of the wealth. The claims of those closest in blood and personal ties are the strongest. Family bonds and friendship are the most powerful social connections, and it's beneficial to nurture them. The motivations for restraint and hard work need to be reinforced. But this perspective also reveals that the American legal system's protection of the rights of grandnephews in Australia or brothers who have been absent for long periods in distant parts of the country is unreasonable and unfair to the community where the wealth is situated.

Social services of favored classes

4. Many fortunes built on favoring legislation are defended as due to social service. In the Middle Ages kings often granted great estates to nobles as rewards for past merit and as a payment for expected public actions. The great landlords were the magistrates, military leaders, and supporters of social order, and thus, in the judgment both of the king and of the commonalty, the nobles earned their incomes by their social service. While this practice has disappeared under constitutional government, large grants are still made to royal families. Many Englishmen who are democratic at heart uphold such grants as the price of social stability. Regard for royalty is so deep-rooted in the minds of the people of any long-established monarchy that there is always[Pg 374] danger in change. England must pay many millions annually as the price of loyal and conservative sentiment. So long as this is true, a family of royal figureheads and idlers performs a social service.

4. Many fortunes built on favorable legislation are justified as social service. In the Middle Ages, kings often granted large estates to nobles as rewards for past achievements and as payment for expected public duties. The major landowners were the magistrates, military leaders, and supporters of social order, and so, in the eyes of both the king and the common people, the nobles earned their income through their social contributions. While this practice has faded under constitutional government, significant grants are still given to royal families. Many English people who believe in democracy at heart support such grants as a cost of social stability. The respect for royalty is so deeply ingrained in the minds of the citizens of any long-established monarchy that change always carries a risk. England must pay millions annually as the cost of loyalty and conservative sentiment. As long as this remains true, a family of royal figureheads and idlers provides a social service.

Possible social service of protected industries

Protective tariffs sought by wealthy manufacturers are granted, not ostensibly to help them, but to help the country. The argument is that the benefits are diffused. Aid to enterprises in private hands, such as ship subsidies or as the grants to the Pacific railroads, are defended on the ground that, as a whole, society benefits by thus increasing the income of one class. The promise of social service is most urged by those who get the immediate benefit. Their eyes are keenest. The manufacturer sees clearly the benefits that will come to his factory from a protective tariff, but before he can get it he must convince many others that they too will gain. The majority of the American electorate is not voting a special favor at the polls, but is recognizing what it believes to be in its own interest. Most students of social questions doubt the wisdom of most of these grants to the wealthy on grounds of social service. The burden of proof is on their advocates, but few to-day are so rash as to say that such a claim of social service is never sound.

Protective tariffs pushed for by wealthy manufacturers are approved, not just to assist them, but to benefit the country as a whole. The argument is that the advantages are widespread. Support for private business initiatives, like ship subsidies or grants to the Pacific railroads, is justified by the idea that society as a whole gains from boosting the income of one group. Those who stand to gain the most are often the loudest proponents of social benefits. The manufacturer clearly sees how a protective tariff will benefit his factory, but to secure it, he must persuade others that they will also benefit. Most American voters aren’t simply granting special favors at the polls; they believe they are acting in their own best interests. Many social issue scholars question the wisdom of these subsidies for the wealthy based on the argument of social service. Advocates of these measures bear the burden of proof, yet few today are bold enough to claim that the idea of social service can never be valid.

Private property in land questioned

5. Property in natural agents is the most strongly attacked. In the case of great natural deposits, such as those of coal or iron, the social service that is performed by the mine-owner is hard to see. Great incomes are drawn in the form of royalty or rent by those who never lift a pick or direct a stroke of work. Agricultural land in the hands of absentee landlords yields an income not very clearly due to social service, and this phase of property has been especially assailed during the past century. The modern form of this discussion is concerning "the unearned increment," the rise in the value of lands as a result of social growth. It is proposed to appropriate by "the single tax" the entire rental value of the land for the use of the public.

5. Ownership of natural resources is the most heavily criticized. In the case of large natural deposits, like coal or iron, it's hard to see the social contribution made by mine owners. Huge profits come in the form of royalties or rents from those who never do any actual mining or work. Agricultural land owned by absentee landlords generates income that isn't clearly linked to social contribution, and this aspect of property has been particularly attacked over the past century. The modern version of this debate focuses on "unearned increment," which refers to the increase in land value due to social development. The proposal is to use "the single tax" to capture the full rental value of the land for public benefit.

The defense of property in land is first positive: taking[Pg 375] not the extreme but the usual case, private property secures the discovery and development of natural resources and their thorough use and good management (not necessarily by personal labor with the hands). If this is true, it is well for the individual and for the community to have this wealth in private hands. But in other cases there is merely a negative argument for property in land: no other better method of employing it has been devised and found practicable The experience with state ownership of mines, forests, and estates has not definitely answered in every case the question whether the social results of state ownership are more favorable than those of private ownership. In some cases they clearly are not, in others they may be; and as the balance of opinion inclines in the direction of public ownership, other reforms will doubtless be undertaken.

The defense of property in land is primarily positive: taking[Pg 375] not the extreme but the typical case, private property enables the discovery and development of natural resources and their effective use and management (not necessarily through personal manual labor). If this is true, it's beneficial for both individuals and the community to have this wealth in private hands. However, in other cases, there is only a negative argument for property in land: no better method of utilizing it has been developed and proven practical. The experience with state ownership of mines, forests, and estates has not definitively resolved whether the social outcomes of state ownership are better than those of private ownership. In some cases, they clearly aren’t, while in others they might be; and as the overall opinion leans toward public ownership, other reforms will likely be pursued.

Inequality of fortunes

6. The present inequality of wealth, not private property as such, is often attacked. It is estimated that in the United Kingdom two per cent. of the families own seventy-five per cent. of all the wealth, while ninety-three per cent. own less than eight per cent. In the United States it is estimated that one per cent. of all the families own more than the remaining ninety-nine per cent.; and at the other part of the scale eighty-seven per cent. of all the families own less than twelve per cent. of all the wealth. The trend has been toward concentration of fortunes and a larger proportion of the growing income from property is in a few hands. Many feel that the law of property is defective when this is possible, although at the same time the average income of the wage-earner is increasing. Yet, it is not the institution as a whole that is attacked, but its details. The custom of equal division of property among children in the United States has not been as effective in keeping fortunes small as was expected. The wealthy American families have averaged small, and in some of the most prominent the rule of equal division has not been followed. Opportunities for the investment of small savings at low interest are not lacking, but[Pg 376] the great fortunes overtower the little ones, securing the great profits and great political and economic power. The farms and the villages are refuges for the small industry and for the small fortunes, and this fact has a great influence on our national character. The whole social atmosphere in the cities, with their extremes of wealth, differs from that in the country, and this contrast promises to become greater as the years go on.

6. People often criticize the current inequality of wealth, rather than private property itself. It's estimated that in the United Kingdom, two percent of families own seventy-five percent of all wealth, while ninety-three percent own less than eight percent. In the United States, it's estimated that one percent of families own more than the remaining ninety-nine percent; and at the other end of the scale, eighty-seven percent of families own less than twelve percent of all the wealth. The trend has been toward the concentration of wealth, with a larger portion of growing income from property held by a few. Many believe there's something wrong with property laws when this happens, even though the average income for workers is rising. However, it's not the institution itself that’s being challenged, but its specifics. The practice of evenly dividing property among children in the U.S. hasn't been as effective in keeping fortunes small as expected. Wealthy American families tend to be small, but in some of the most prominent cases, the equal division rule has not been followed. Opportunities to invest small savings at low interest rates are available, but[Pg 376] the large fortunes overshadow the small ones, securing significant profits and substantial political and economic power. Farms and villages serve as havens for small businesses and modest fortunes, which heavily influences our national character. The overall social climate in cities, marked by extreme wealth, is very different from that in rural areas, and this gap is likely to widen in the coming years.

Private property vs. socialism

7. The ideal of property rights is that they shall furnish the highest motives for efficient social service. Private property furnishes such a motive in a broad way, but its most ardent defenders will recognize that it does so imperfectly. It is an institution that has been tried and that does the work, while other methods suggested to do away with it are found to be dreams. The ideal of socialism is the abolition of private property, the centralizing under the control of the state of all wealth, except the simple personal belongings, clothing and other consumption goods. But history and human nature unite to testify that extreme socialism is an unworkable plan, excepting under special conditions, as in barbarous times and under a political despotism. The modern ideal for the control of wealth is the best attainable harmony of liberty and efficiency. If private property as it is, falls short of that ideal, at any rate it works either on a small or on a large scale, and socialism does not work at all. Property rights as they exist are not a product of pure reason. They are the result of social evolution, of historical accidents, of class legislation, and of selfish interest in many cases. Changing social conditions and ideas are bringing many changes in law, and further change must be expected to come.

7. The ideal of property rights is that they should provide the strongest motivations for effective social service. Private property does offer such motivation broadly, but even its most passionate supporters will admit that it does so imperfectly. It’s an institution that's been tested and does serve a purpose, while other proposed alternatives to eliminate it are largely unrealistic. The socialist ideal advocates for the elimination of private property, centralizing all wealth under state control, except for basic personal belongings, clothing, and other consumer goods. However, both history and human nature indicate that extreme socialism is not a viable approach, except under certain conditions, like in primitive times or under a tyrannical government. The modern ideal for managing wealth is to find the best balance between freedom and efficiency. While private property may not fully achieve that ideal, it does function on both small and large scales, whereas socialism fails to work at all. Property rights, as they currently exist, are not the outcome of pure logic. They arise from social evolution, historical events, class-based laws, and often from self-interest. Changing social conditions and ideas are leading to many legal changes, and we should expect more changes to come.

§ II. INCOME FROM PERSONAL SERVICES

Some anti-social speculative gains

1. Incomes from legitimate enterprise and speculation correspond roughly to social service. It has been recognized[Pg 377] above that there are many grades of chance, of speculation, and of enterprise. The extreme cases are bald crimes and are punished as such. Over some men that never directly break the law there always hangs a suspicion of guilt. It is the purpose of the law to make dishonesty unprofitable, but how imperfectly it does so! There are many cases of chance gains where the lucky man without social service legally enjoys his fortune. The law must be framed in broad terms, and cannot provide for every case. It may broadly forbid lotteries whose evils clearly exceed their benefits. But what would be the effect of taking away reward for the discovery of a gold-mine, even though sometimes it is awkward stumbling, not industry, that reveals the veins of metal? Society has studied that question in the past; even now changes are being made in the laws; and in their turn the citizens and legislators of the next generation must decide the question. It is always under consideration.

1. Income from legitimate business and speculation is roughly equivalent to social service. It has been noted[Pg 377] above that there are many levels of chance, speculation, and enterprise. The extreme cases are clear crimes and are punished accordingly. For some people who never directly break the law, there is always an air of suspicion around them. The goal of the law is to make dishonesty unprofitable, but it does this imperfectly! There are many instances of chance gains where the lucky individual, without any social contribution, enjoys their fortune legally. The law must be written in broad terms and cannot account for every situation. It may generally prohibit lotteries where the harms clearly outweigh the benefits. But what would happen if we removed the rewards for discovering a gold mine, even if sometimes it’s simply a stroke of luck, not hard work, that uncovers the metal veins? Society has pondered this question in the past; even now, changes are being made to the laws; and in turn, the citizens and lawmakers of the next generation will have to tackle this issue. It's always a topic of discussion.

Reward and enterprise

Are the rewards of the successful enterpriser greater than he deserves? How shall it be judged what he deserves? The answer is in the form of a question, Could society have the service without the reward? Society may be thought of as hiring the services of the efficient business man at the lowest price. Does it wish the services of Cornelius Vanderbilt in organizing a great system of railroads, of Andrew Carnegie, of Pierpont Morgan? What can it get them for? It must appeal not only to their love of money but to their love of power. Large services and large results can be bought only with large rewards. The shrewd enterpriser is not to be paid with abstract social gratitude. He is not to be tricked, as is a Chinese god, with tissue-paper gold.

Are the rewards of a successful entrepreneur greater than they deserve? How do we determine what they deserve? The answer comes in the form of a question: Could society enjoy the service without the reward? You can think of society as hiring the efficient businessman at the lowest possible cost. Does it want the skills of Cornelius Vanderbilt in organizing a massive railroad system, Andrew Carnegie, or Pierpont Morgan? What can society offer to get their services? It has to appeal not only to their desire for money but also to their desire for power. Significant services and big results can only be bought with substantial rewards. The savvy entrepreneur shouldn’t expect to be compensated with mere social gratitude. They shouldn’t be deceived, like a Chinese god, with paper-thin gold.

Unmeasured gains of vast wealth

But in many ways fortunes appear to grow without social services, and sometimes with social harm. Russell Sage, the noted capitalist (who should know something of Wall Street), in speaking of the greatest of American corporations, said: "They dominate wherever they choose to go. They can make and unmake any property, no matter how vast. They[Pg 378] can almost compel any man to sell out anything, at any price." Henry Clews, the well-known New York banker, said of a certain group of financiers: "Their resources are so vast that they need only to concentrate on any given property in order to do with it what they please.... There is an utter absence of chance that is terrible to contemplate. This combination controls Wall Street almost absolutely. With such power and facilities it is easily conceivable that these men must make enormous sums on either side of the market."

But in many ways, fortunes seem to grow without social services, and sometimes at a social cost. Russell Sage, the well-known capitalist (who certainly understands Wall Street), noted about the largest American corporations: "They dominate wherever they choose to go. They can create and destroy any property, no matter how extensive. They[Pg 378] can practically force anyone to sell anything, at any price." Henry Clews, the famous New York banker, commented on a specific group of financiers: "Their resources are so vast that they just need to focus on any given property to do whatever they want with it.... The complete lack of chance is frightening to think about. This combination has almost total control over Wall Street. With such power and resources, it’s easy to see that these individuals must make huge profits on either side of the market."

Antisocial use of rare ability

2. The high pay of rare ability and skilled labor reflects in general a high social service. The large income of some men reflects service to a narrow class, not to society as a whole. Lawyers as a class aid in maintaining right, but a corporation lawyer may get enormous fees for defeating just public claims; a skilful criminal lawyer may grow rich aiding the guilty to escape justice. Other service ministers to the whims, follies, and vices of the men who pay the bill. Such a service is "social" in a mean sense, corresponding to the low standards of desire in that social group. But what of the high rewards of skilled service ministering to worthy ends? Such favorites of fortune as Jenny Lind and Patti have received five thousand dollars for a single concert. Is this because they are the lucky possessors of a rare gift, or because they perform a social service deserving such reward? Certainly many of their auditors get what they want and believe they are getting the worth of their money.

2. The high pay for rare talent and skilled labor generally indicates a significant social contribution. The substantial income of certain individuals reflects their service to a specific group rather than to society at large. Lawyers, in general, help uphold justice, but a corporate lawyer can rake in huge fees by undermining public interests; a well-paid criminal lawyer might amass wealth by helping the guilty evade justice. Other professions cater to the whims, mistakes, and vices of those who pay for their services. Such work is "social" in a narrow sense, reflecting the low standards of desire within that social group. But what about the generous compensation for skilled services that serve worthy purposes? People like Jenny Lind and Patti have earned five thousand dollars for a single concert. Is this due to their extraordinary talent or because they provide a social service that merits such pay? Undoubtedly, many of their audience members get what they want and feel they are receiving good value for their money.

General social result of rewarding talent

In general the legal right of everyone to get the highest pay he can in a free and open market is essential to the calling forth of ability. In a particular instance it is possible that the service would continue if one half or more of the income were confiscated by the public; but such a personal discrimination would introduce an arbitrary and demoralizing uncertainty into the problem. Who can tell how far the exceptional money rewards have inspired to the highest cultivation of great genius and[Pg 379] of many minor talents? In a broad but very true sense, therefore, it appears that high personal achievement, large economic reward, and large social service are connected.

In general, everyone’s legal right to earn as much as possible in a free and open market is crucial for encouraging talent. In some cases, a service might continue even if half or more of the income were taken by the government; however, this kind of personal treatment would create an arbitrary and discouraging uncertainty in the situation. Who knows how much extraordinary financial rewards have motivated the greatest talents and many lesser abilities? In a broad but very real sense, it seems that high personal achievement, significant financial rewards, and substantial social contribution are all linked.

Social service of manual workers

3. The low income of unskilled labor seems to fall short of its social service. This does not refer to the feeble-minded or utterly inefficient, but rather to honest, industrious, "day-laborers," and to the low-paid manual workers in field, on railroad, and in factory. Their service is essential to the existence of society as it is, to all the higher arts, to the sciences, and to the amenities of life; their tasks are the roughest, most painful, most dangerous; yet their pecuniary rewards are the lowest. There is such a unity in society that each more fortunate man is dependent on the services of the humbler laborers who make up a large part of society. According to the breadth of social sympathy their claims seem more or less urgent.

3. The low income of unskilled workers falls short of what their social contribution deserves. This doesn't refer to those who are incapable or completely ineffective, but instead to honest, hardworking "day laborers" and low-paid manual workers in fields, on railroads, and in factories. Their work is crucial for the functioning of society, for all higher arts, sciences, and the comforts of life; their jobs are the toughest, most painful, and most dangerous; yet their financial rewards are the lowest. There is such a connection in society that each more privileged individual relies on the services of the less fortunate workers who make up a large segment of society. Depending on the level of social empathy, their needs seem more or less urgent.

The problem of increasing their reward

There is a vaguely recognized and growing conviction that these hewers of wood and drawers of water should enjoy a larger income. But how are they to get it? How is society to grant it to them? They get what they can under the competitive conditions, they get what their service is worth in the market. Are the conditions of the competition fair? If not, what will be the effect of a change? If they get more, others will get less; and with what result? However great the wish for better things, the attempt to change conditions fundamentally in a forcible and artificial way is both dangerous and foolish. Improvement must come through the coöperation of many indirect agencies gradually changing the nature and direction of the deeper economic forces.

There’s a growing belief that those who do the tough, manual work should earn a better income. But how can they achieve this? How can society make it happen? They earn what they can under the current competitive conditions; their compensation reflects what their work is worth in the market. Are the competitive conditions fair? If not, what would be the impact of changing them? If they earn more, others will earn less; what would the outcome be? No matter how much we desire better circumstances, trying to change things dramatically and artificially is both risky and unwise. Improvement should come through the collaboration of many indirect factors that gradually shift the deeper economic forces.

Imperfect social and individual estimates of service

4. The services of each are being measured and paid for by each and all. In two ways society is putting its valuation on the economic services of other members of society: first, by law, or formal social convention; secondly, by individual estimates. By formal law is determined what institutions shall be continued. If the class of property owners is considered[Pg 380] worthy of this reward, the institution of property will be continued; if not, it will be altered or destroyed. These decisions are made imperfectly, but as well as men of limited intelligence and honesty can make them. If men were more capable in both these ways they would enact better laws. Again, individuals are putting their estimates on others in bidding for services to minister to wisdom and virtue or to ignorance and vice. If there is to be a much juster estimate of social service, there must be wiser men in society.

4. The services of each person are being measured and compensated by everyone. Society values the economic contributions of its members in two ways: first, through laws or formal social agreements; second, through personal judgments. Formal laws determine which institutions will remain in place. If property owners are deemed[Pg 380] deserving of this reward, the institution of property will persist; if not, it will be changed or eliminated. These decisions are made imperfectly, but as well as people with limited intelligence and integrity can manage. If people were more capable in both areas, they would create better laws. Additionally, individuals express their opinions about others by bidding for services aimed at promoting wisdom and virtue or, conversely, ignorance and vice. For there to be a much fairer assessment of social service, society needs wiser individuals.

The ideal of social service

Does the world owe each man a living? No; on the contrary, each man owes the world his services in exchange for his living. The pauperism of spirit that consists in taking something for nothing is found in every rank of society that enjoys the blessings of progress without giving its best services in return. The ideal of a better adjustment of reward and service grows in the minds of men. Social evolution, shaped by this changing ideal and by accumulating experience, will bring into closer relation the social services and the economic rewards of men.

Does the world owe everyone a living? No; on the contrary, each person owes the world their services in exchange for their living. The entitlement mentality of getting something for nothing is present in every part of society that benefits from progress without contributing its best efforts in return. The vision of a fairer balance between reward and service is developing in people's minds. Social evolution, driven by this changing vision and by growing experiences, will bring social services and economic rewards closer together.


CHAPTER 40

WASTE AND LUXURY

§ I. WASTE OF WEALTH

Loss of wealth in an isolated or an exchanging economy

1. The accidental destruction of wealth is a loss to the owner, rarely with benefit, on the whole, to others. In the consumption of wealth the loss of its utility is accompanied by the gratifying of wants; in the destruction of wealth utility is lost without the gratifying of wants. In a simple society, without exchange, the result of such a loss is evident. If food is destroyed, men suffer from hunger or gratify appetite less perfectly; if clothing is destroyed, they are cold; if houses are destroyed, they have no shelter. Likewise, if the self-sufficing family on a farm loses wealth by fire or storm or blight, its economic environment is made less fitted to gratify wants. In the conditions of our society, where goods are exchanged, the result appears to be different. The need to replace the lost goods makes a demand for special kinds of labor or goods. There may be, therefore, an immediate benefit to some, which obscures the corresponding loss to others. If a part of the income of the loser must be diverted from other uses to replace the wealth destroyed, those from whom he would have bought suffer an unexpected falling off of their sales, and he has himself gained nothing. The net result is a loss of wealth and gratification to the community as a whole.

1. The accidental destruction of wealth is a loss for the owner, rarely benefiting others overall. When wealth is consumed, its utility is lost but it also satisfies wants; in contrast, when wealth is destroyed, utility is gone without fulfilling any wants. In a simple society without trade, the consequences of such a loss are clear. If food is destroyed, people go hungry or can't satisfy their hunger as well; if clothing is lost, they feel cold; if houses are destroyed, they lack shelter. Similarly, if a self-sufficient family on a farm loses wealth due to fire, storm, or blight, their economic circumstances become less capable of satisfying their needs. In our society, where goods are traded, the situation seems different. The need to replace lost goods creates a demand for specific types of labor or products. As a result, some may experience immediate benefits, obscuring the corresponding losses for others. If part of the income of the person who lost wealth has to be redirected to replace what was destroyed, those from whom they would have purchased goods experience an unexpected drop in sales, leaving the loser without any real gain. The overall result is a loss of wealth and satisfaction for the community as a whole.

There is a real exception where the accidental destruction removes some social difficulty. The great fire in London and the great fire in Chicago resulted in wonderful improvement.[Pg 382] When an old city is built almost entirely of wood, each owner may think it to his interest to keep the old buildings. A great fire sweeps them all down and compels the rebuilding of the city on a new and higher standard. But the usual social result of accidental destruction is a loss. It is a use of wealth without a fulfilling of the purpose of production, the gratifying of wants.

There is a real exception where accidental destruction alleviates some social issues. The great fire in London and the great fire in Chicago led to significant improvement.[Pg 382] When an old city is mostly made of wood, each owner might believe that it’s in their best interest to maintain the old buildings. A large fire wipes them all out and forces the city to be rebuilt to a new and better standard. However, the typical social outcome of accidental destruction is a loss. It represents a use of wealth without achieving the true purpose of production, which is to satisfy wants.

Intentional destruction of wealth by the owner

2. The intentional destruction of wealth by the owner, to make trade good, benefits neither himself nor others. The case in mind is one where there is full choice between keeping or losing the good, not such a case as the throwing overboard of a part of the cargo when the ship is in danger of sinking, in the hope thereby of saving the rest, or as the blowing up of buildings to prevent the spread of a fire. In such cases the destruction is inevitable without man's action; he merely tries to minimize it. The case in mind is the deliberate destruction of wealth that might be kept for use. One labor leader, for example, boasted that when he drank pop he always broke the bottle "to make trade good" by helping the glass industry. The refuting of this fallacy is one of the time-honored tasks in political economy. There is, it is true, an increase in the demand for glass and glass-blowers' labor, but without an increase in gratification; but at the same time there is a decrease in the demand for other goods which would afford additional gratification. The proverb, old in Shakespeare's time, runs, "Nothing can come of nothing." What is spent for one purpose cannot be for another; "you cannot eat your cake and have it too." A given income can be spent in one of many ways, but not in all ways or even in two ways at once. It is a question of this or that. At the same moment that the demand for pop-bottles is increased, the demand for other things is decreased, possibly that for pop-corn or pop-guns or Populist papers—who can tell? Such a form of benevolence is a mistaken, uneconomic attempt to provide labor for one man by taking it from another.

2. The intentional destruction of wealth by the owner, to stimulate trade, benefits neither himself nor others. The situation we're talking about is one where there is a full choice between keeping or losing something valuable, not like throwing part of the cargo overboard when a ship is sinking in the hope of saving the rest, or blowing up buildings to stop a fire from spreading. In those scenarios, destruction is unavoidable without human intervention; they’re just trying to minimize losses. What we’re discussing is the intentional destruction of wealth that could be preserved for use. One labor leader, for instance, claimed that when he drank soda, he always broke the bottle "to stimulate trade" by supporting the glass industry. Debunking this misconception is a classic task in political economy. True, there’s an increase in demand for glass and the labor of glassblowers, but it doesn’t come with an increase in satisfaction; meanwhile, there’s a decrease in demand for other goods that could offer additional satisfaction. There's an old saying, dating back to Shakespeare's time: "Nothing can come of nothing." What is spent on one thing can't be spent on another; "you can't eat your cake and have it too." A certain income can only be spent in one of many ways, but not in all ways or even in two at the same time. It's a choice of this or that. At the same time that the demand for soda bottles goes up, the demand for other things goes down, perhaps for popcorn, toy guns, or Populist newspapers—who knows? This kind of well-meaning is a wrong and uneconomic attempt to create work for one person by taking it from another.

If the advocate of wealth-destruction would be consistent, he should break, not merely the pop-bottle, but the water-pitcher and the table as well; he should make a bonfire at least once daily of his clothing, his house, and its furnishings; he should advise blowing up the steamboat and ripping up the railroad when they have carried a single load of passengers. Thus, when all men were naked and starving, and civilization had sunk to savagery, trade would have been made as "good" as, by the policy of destruction, he could ever hope to make it.

If the supporter of destroying wealth were to be consistent, he shouldn’t just break the pop bottle but also the water pitcher and the table; he should set fire to his clothes, his house, and its furniture at least once a day; he should suggest blowing up the steamboat and tearing up the railroad after they’ve carried even one load of passengers. That way, when everyone is naked and starving, and civilization has fallen into chaos, trade would have been made as "good" as he could ever hope to achieve through his policy of destruction.

Intentional destruction of others' wealth

3. The intentional destruction of wealth owned by other persons is falsely thought to benefit trade in general. The cases referred to are not acts done with criminal motives, but those done with a view to the public interest. If one sets fire to the property of another, seeking revenge or plunder, he is guilty of the crime of arson. But what shall be said of volunteer firemen that let an old house burn down to provide labor for carpenters and "to make business good"? The duty of firemen is to put out fires, no matter what the building is; but they choose sometimes to be ministers to the social interest as they interpret it. The more spent for carpenters' work out of any income, the less can be spent for other objects. It is true, however, that if in a small town the money to rebuild is borrowed from a distant loan or insurance company, there is an increase in employment in that town for one season; and that is as far as most men try to carry their economic analysis. Let the student carry it further.

3. The intentional destruction of someone else's wealth is mistakenly believed to benefit trade overall. The situations mentioned aren’t actions driven by criminal motives, but rather actions taken for the public good. If someone sets another person's property on fire out of revenge or to steal, they commit the crime of arson. But what about volunteer firefighters who allow an old house to burn down to provide work for carpenters and "to boost the economy"? Firefighters' duty is to extinguish fires, regardless of the building involved; however, they sometimes choose to act according to their interpretation of societal benefit. The more spent on carpenters' jobs from any income, the less can be allocated for other needs. It is true, though, that if a small town borrows money to rebuild from a distant lender or insurance company, there is a temporary increase in jobs in that town for one season; and that's as far as most people take their economic analysis. Let the student explore it further.

The seen and the unseen

Servants sometimes excuse the breaking of dishes and furniture on the ground that it makes work, and that the employer can afford it. But income is thus diverted from other expenditure, either for production or for consumption. In the light of the theory of wages, it would appear that carelessness reduces the servant's own efficiency, and in the long run the loss comes, in part at least, off the wages of that particular servant. Bastiat's discussion of the broken window-pane[Pg 384] is often and deservedly quoted. What is seen is a certain immediate benefit that the glass-maker and glazier get; what is not seen is that the power to expend an equal amount for other things is thereby lost by the owner of the house.

Servants sometimes justify breaking dishes and furniture by saying it creates work and that the employer can afford it. However, income is taken away from other spending, whether for production or consumption. According to wage theory, it seems that being careless lowers the servant's own efficiency, and over time, the loss partly affects that servant's wages. Bastiat's discussion of the broken window-pane[Pg 384] is often and rightly referenced. The immediate benefit goes to the glass-maker and glazier, but what's overlooked is that the homeowner loses the ability to spend the same amount on other things.

The wasteful use of wealth

4. The destruction of unnecessarily large value to secure a given gratification is not economically sound. The careless use of wealth to secure an inadequate result is likewise justified as "making trade good." The blunder that compels the rebuilding of a wall in a rich man's garden is an occasion for congratulation to those who see in it a happy provision of work for the unemployed. It is easy to forget that the proper use of goods is the final step in production. According as goods are well or poorly used, the production—that is, the real income or gratification they afford—is large or small. Differences in skill in the use of wealth are great. A French cook, we are often told, can make a palatable soup from what goes from the average American kitchen into the swill-pail. Waste in the use of goods is more likely to be found in new countries where wealth comes more easily and necessity does not enforce frugality.

4. Wasting a lot of value to achieve a small reward isn't smart from an economic standpoint. Using wealth carelessly to get a meager result is often claimed to be "good for business." When a wealthy man's wall needs to be rebuilt, some see it as a positive chance to create jobs for the unemployed. It's easy to overlook that using goods properly is the final step in production. Depending on whether goods are used well or poorly, the production—that is, the actual income or satisfaction they provide—can vary greatly. The difference in skills when it comes to managing wealth is significant. We often hear that a French chef can turn leftovers from a typical American kitchen into a delicious soup. Waste in using goods is more likely to occur in new countries where wealth is easier to come by, and necessity doesn't require saving.

The praise of waste implies the error noted in the preceding propositions. Deliberately securing less than the maximum result from wealth is merely a minor degree of the intentional destruction of wealth. The mistaken view is essentially that of the opponents of labor-saving machinery. It may be true, if the interests of a small class of workers or of tradesmen for the moment are looked at; it is false, if the interests of society as a whole be considered. Far more of wisdom lies in the proverb, "A penny saved is two earned." The economic use of wealth as surely adds to wealth (and, ultimately, to the income of society) as any other mode of production.

The praise of waste highlights the mistake mentioned in the earlier points. Intentionally getting less than the maximum benefit from wealth is just a slight version of willfully wasting wealth. This flawed perspective is similar to that of those who oppose labor-saving machines. It might hold true for the short-term interests of a small group of workers or tradespeople, but it’s wrong when considering the interests of society as a whole. There’s much more wisdom in the saying, "A penny saved is two earned." The smart use of wealth definitely contributes to increasing wealth (and, eventually, to society's overall income) just like any other production method does.

Waste in public outlay

Some government expenditures, as for river and harbor improvements, are sometimes favored, not because their immediate purposes are good, but because they "make work"[Pg 385] and "distribute money" throughout the country. This money comes from taxation, and no matter what the system of taxation, the burden falls on some one, reducing the incomes at the disposal of the people to expend for objects of their own choice. If the work is not worth doing for itself, the collection of money in small amounts from many taxpayers and its expenditure as a large sum in one locality results in a net loss to society as a whole. Where the result is worth something, but not enough by itself to justify the expenditure, the fallacy of the destruction of wealth is present in a smaller degree. Examples are seen in the extreme use of pensions and in some public subsidies.

Some government spending, like improvements to rivers and harbors, is sometimes supported, not because the immediate goals are beneficial, but because they "create jobs" and "spread money" around the country.[Pg 385] This money comes from taxes, and regardless of the tax system in place, the burden falls on someone, reducing the amount of income that people can spend on their own choices. If the work isn’t worth doing for its own sake, collecting money in small amounts from many taxpayers and spending it as a large sum in one place ultimately leads to a net loss for society as a whole. When the outcome has some value, but not enough to justify the spending, the issue of wealth destruction is still present, though to a lesser extent. Examples can be seen in the excessive use of pensions and some public subsidies.

The fallacy of waste

5. The supposed benefits of destruction and waste are due to a narrow and incomplete view of the question. Let us restate the ideas that have been touched upon. In many cases it is possible that one person may benefit by another's mishap or folly in the use of wealth. The complex interrelations of men in society make this inevitable. But, to appreciate the final effects of such action upon society, one needs but to go back to the essential thought of wealth and its purposes. As the average efficiency and bounty of the world fall, so fall the income and welfare of men. As it rises, the social and economic levels rise also. Every kind of economic wealth has potentially two kinds of uses: to gratify wants—thus fulfilling its destiny—or to be converted into higher and more efficient agents—consumption or production. That the possibilities of the latter are boundless is overlooked in the fallacies here criticized. An efficient world would be the result of "economy" and saving; a wasted and used-up world, the result of the fallacy of the destruction and waste of wealth.

5. The supposed benefits of destruction and waste come from a narrow and incomplete view of the issue. Let's restate the ideas we've discussed. In many cases, one person might benefit from another's mistake or poor judgment in using their wealth. The complex interactions among people in society make this unavoidable. However, to understand the overall effects of such actions on society, one only needs to revisit the basic idea of wealth and its purposes. As the average efficiency and abundance of the world decrease, so do people's income and well-being. As it increases, social and economic levels rise too. Every type of economic wealth can potentially be used in two ways: to satisfy wants—thus fulfilling its intended purpose—or to be transformed into higher and more efficient outputs—consumption or production. The limitless potential of the latter is often overlooked in the misconceptions being criticized here. An efficient world would result from "economy" and saving; a wasted and depleted world would be the outcome of the misconception surrounding destruction and waste of wealth.

§ II. LUXURY

Luxury defined

1. Luxury, while variously defined, involves always the thought of great consumption of wealth for unessential pleasures. [Pg 386]It is not possible to define luxury absolutely; it is a relative term. Those opposed to it condemn it in their definition of it, as, for example: "an excessive consumption of wealth," or "devoting a relatively large amount of wealth to the satisfaction of a relatively superfluous want." Those who take a more moderate and favorable view say: "It is the enjoyment of forms of wealth not obtainable by the mass of men." The difficulty in the definition as well as in the problem of luxury is that it involves a mixture of economic and of ethical questions.

1. Luxury, though defined in many ways, always involves the idea of spending a lot of money on non-essential pleasures. [Pg 386] It's impossible to define luxury in absolute terms; it's a relative concept. Those who oppose it criticize it in their definitions, for instance: "an excessive use of wealth," or "spending a comparatively large amount of money to satisfy a relatively unnecessary desire." Meanwhile, those with a more moderate and positive perspective say: "It's the enjoyment of kinds of wealth that most people can't access." The challenge in defining luxury, as well as the issue itself, arises from the intertwining of economic and ethical questions.

Extravagance "to give employment"

2. Luxury is erroneously justified by some as giving employment to labor. Typical instances are extravagant dress and elaborate balls where fine and costly flowers, decorations, music, coaches, require the expenditure of a large amount of money. It is said of the Empress Eugenie, wife of Napoleon III, that, in order to help the glove industry of France, she wore no pair of gloves more than once; in order to help other French industries, she purchased many silks and laces. It is a very comfortable doctrine to some people that the oftener they change their dress, the greater benefactors to society they are. A few years ago the "Bradley-Martin ball" was given in New York city. It was possibly little more elaborate and expensive than many another ball, but it chanced to be a dull time for news and the papers all over the land gave columns to its discussion. In the many interviews with ministers and business men, the thought appeared over and over that the ball had at least the merit of giving employment to labor.

2. Some people mistakenly justify luxury as a way to provide jobs. Typical examples are fancy outfits and grand balls where expensive flowers, decorations, music, and coaches require spending a lot of money. It’s said that Empress Eugenie, the wife of Napoleon III, helped the glove industry in France by only wearing each pair of gloves once; to support other French industries, she bought numerous silks and laces. It’s a comforting belief for some that the more they change their outfits, the more they are benefiting society. A few years ago, the "Bradley-Martin ball" took place in New York City. It was probably just as elaborate and costly as many other balls, but it happened to be a slow news period, and newspapers across the country devoted columns to discussing it. In numerous interviews with ministers and business leaders, the idea repeatedly came up that the ball at least had the advantage of creating jobs.

The fallacy of luxury

The fallacy of this is essentially the same as that in the argument for waste and destruction. From the fact that these particular tailors, musicians, and florists would have less employment if this ball were not given, it is falsely concluded that, but for this ball, this particular income, or capital, would not be used at all. The average of employment in those special industries which minister to luxury is the result of and is determined by the average level of[Pg 387] demand. There are more caterers and florists in Ithaca than in Hayt's Corners. A more than ordinarily gay season gives unusual profits to these enterprises, and it is true that an abrupt and extreme falling off in demand would cause them large losses, and leave many workers lacking employment for that one season. But, if this limited demand became usual, capital and labor would shift to the other industries to which expenditure had shifted. Other modes of expenditure than twenty-five thousand-dollar balls are possible, as, for example, twenty-five thousand-dollar public libraries. Mr. Carnegie takes his dissipation in that form. That gives employment also; not less does investment in new houses, in new railroads, and in new factories. More employment of a particular kind of labor is caused in one case than in another, but not more employment of labor as a whole and on the average.

The flaw here is pretty much the same as in the argument for waste and destruction. Just because these specific tailors, musicians, and florists would have less work if this ball didn’t happen, it doesn’t mean that without this ball, this income or capital wouldn't be used at all. The average level of employment in those luxury-related industries is a result of and depends on the average demand. There are more caterers and florists in Ithaca than in Hayt's Corners. A particularly vibrant season brings in unusual profits for these businesses, and it’s true that a sudden and sharp drop in demand would lead to significant losses and leave many workers without jobs for that season. However, if that limited demand became the norm, capital and labor would shift to other industries where spending went instead. There are plenty of ways to spend money besides throwing twenty-five thousand-dollar balls, like creating twenty-five thousand-dollar public libraries. Mr. Carnegie prefers to spend his money that way. That also creates jobs; likewise, investments in new houses, railroads, and factories create jobs too. More of a certain type of work may be created in one scenario compared to another, but the overall level of employment doesn’t increase on average.

Results of a sudden change in standards of living

3. If all extreme luxury ceased, men of means would improve durable agents more or would give more or would take more leisure while producing less. The question of luxury is most difficult when put thus: What would happen if everybody began suddenly to live on the simplest food and to confine himself to the bare necessities of life? A sudden change of this sort is almost unthinkable, but if it took place, all the factories and agents used for non-essentials would lose their value at once. A great industrial crisis would follow, as industry would have to adjust itself abruptly to an unprecedented standard of desires. What would happen if that standard continued would vary as human nature varies. There might follow increase of population, or a heightening of the efficiency of such agents as were of use, or, more probable than all else, a progressive lightening of labor, a use of the surplus of energy in study, rest, and recreation. It is, of course, illogical to suppose that with limited desires for the objective goods of the world there would continue undiminished efforts to produce goods and to save for future superfluities. In actual life[Pg 388] changes of standard occur gradually. Economizing in material things by simpler living makes possible not only the increased efficiency of productive agents but the increased enjoyment of immaterial goods.

3. If all extreme luxury came to an end, wealthy individuals would either enhance long-lasting resources more, give more, or take more leisure while producing less. The question of luxury is particularly challenging when framed this way: What would happen if everyone suddenly started living on the simplest foods and limited themselves to just the basics of life? A sudden shift like this is almost unimaginable, but if it occurred, all the factories and resources used for non-essentials would instantly lose their worth. A major industrial crisis would ensue, as industry would need to rapidly adapt to an unprecedented standard of wants. What would happen if that standard continued would depend on the variability of human nature. There might be a rise in population, or an increase in the efficiency of useful resources, or, more likely than anything else, a gradual reduction in labor, with the extra energy being used for study, rest, and leisure. It is, of course, illogical to think that with limited desires for material goods, there would still be unyielding efforts to produce and save for future luxuries. In real life[Pg 388], changes in standards happen gradually. Cutting back on material things through simpler living not only allows for greater efficiency of productive resources but also enhances the enjoyment of non-material goods.

Luxury as an incentive to progress

4. The defenders of luxury claim that it is the great incentive to progress. It is undoubtedly true that a dead level of conditions is unfavorable to the progress of society. There must be in society some motive for emulation and ambition after the bare necessities of life are provided. There is therefore much strength in the defense of luxury. Necessities, strictly understood, are things absolutely essential to life and health. No hard line can be drawn between necessities and comforts, between comforts and luxuries. The level rises; it is a trite and true saying that the luxuries of one age become the necessities of the next. The rise of the bath-tub in the nineteenth century is an epitome of the progress of civilization in that period. The free baths in our cities surpass the hopes of the wealthy of a century ago. Even the meaner motives of envy may have their social function. The lower social grades, emulous of the higher standard held before them, labor with greater energy. The successful and capable, not content with necessities, continue to give their efforts to production. The destruction of the motive of luxury before the development of a substitute in a higher social conscience, would be paralyzing to industry. Luxury in a moderate measure may be defended by the same arguments as those for private property. True as this view may be in many cases, in others it seems directly opposed to the facts. Let us look at the economico-moral questions involved from the side of the individual who is indulging in luxury, and from that of the society in which he lives.

4. The supporters of luxury argue that it is the main driving force for progress. It's definitely true that a stagnant state of society is not good for progress. There has to be some motivation for individuals to aspire and be ambitious once the basic needs of life are taken care of. So, there is a lot of merit in the argument for luxury. Necessities, in the strictest sense, are what we absolutely need for life and health. There’s no clear line between necessities and comforts, and between comforts and luxuries. Standards keep rising; it's a common saying that the luxuries of one generation become the necessities of the next. The introduction of the bathtub in the nineteenth century is a symbol of the advances in civilization during that time. The public baths in our cities exceed what the wealthy dreamed of a century ago. Even the less noble feelings of envy can serve a purpose in society. Those in lower social classes, inspired by the higher standards set before them, work harder. The successful and capable, not satisfied with just the essentials, keep striving to produce more. Removing the motivation of luxury without having developed an alternative higher social awareness would significantly hinder industry. Luxury, in moderation, can be justified using the same arguments made for private property. While this perspective may hold true in many instances, in others it seems to contradict reality. Let’s examine the economic and moral questions involved from both the standpoint of the individual indulging in luxury, and from that of the society in which they live.

Happiness and the simple life

5. As a question of consumption luxury involves for the individual both an economic and a moral problem. The economic question is, Does luxury enhance the man's real income? Does a greater expenditure on himself give him a[Pg 389] larger sum of gratification in life than a moderate expenditure would give? Ostentation has its penalties. Undue striving after effect defeats its own purpose. This is the cold fact of experience, not a speculative proposition. To get back to the fundamental principle: gratification results from a harmonious relation between man's nature and the world. Life loaded with too much luggage staggers under the burden. The tired faculties of the Sybarite cease at length to respond to natural pleasures. When the senses are robbed of their fineness, youth grows blasé, mature manhood is ennuied, life is empty. The praise of "the simple life" has lately been heard in a quarter whence such counsel does not usually come. In gay Paris, a wise pastor has made one of the most beautiful and rational pleas for plain and sincere living that society has heard since the time of the stoic philosophers. The word is needed. With the growth of incomes grows the strain to reach the self-imposed standards of frivolity. Insanity and suicide are on the increase. The stress of modern life makes men yearn for the simpler joys. Happiness dwells not outside of men; they must seek it within.

5. When it comes to consumption, luxury presents both an economic and a moral dilemma for individuals. The economic question is, Does luxury actually increase a person's real income? Does spending more on oneself provide a[Pg 389] greater amount of satisfaction in life compared to spending moderately? Showiness comes with consequences. Excessive attempts to impress can backfire. This is a straightforward fact based on experience, not just a theoretical idea. Returning to the core principle: satisfaction comes from a balanced connection between a person's nature and the world around them. Life that's bogged down by too much baggage struggles under the weight. The weary senses of someone who overindulges eventually stop appreciating natural pleasures. When feelings lose their sensitivity, youth becomes indifferent, adulthood feels bored, and life feels unfulfilling. Recently, the idea of "the simple life" has been echoed from an unexpected source. In vibrant Paris, a wise pastor has made one of the most beautiful and sensible arguments for living simply and sincerely that society has heard since the time of the Stoics. This message is important. As incomes rise, the pressure to meet self-imposed standards of superficiality intensifies. Cases of mental breakdown and suicide are on the rise. The pressures of modern existence make people crave more straightforward joys. Happiness isn't found outside of ourselves; we must search for it within.

Luxury vs. social welfare

An economic failure, luxury is likewise in most cases a moral failure. Morality has to do with others; the social aspect of luxury is its effect on other people. The mere spending of a large income in selfish indulgence absorbs all the energies and interests of some men and women. Not only happiness in the narrow sense, but self-realization, is to such lives impossible. Those absorbed in display can give no due measure of thought to social obligations. A society made up of self-absorbed and self-centered individuals is a selfish society, foredoomed to decay.

An economic failure, luxury is also often a moral failure. Morality involves other people; the social aspect of luxury is how it affects others. Simply spending a large income on personal indulgence consumes all the energy and interests of some individuals. Not only is happiness in a narrow sense unattainable, but so is self-realization for such people. Those focused on showing off cannot adequately consider their social responsibilities. A society filled with self-absorbed and self-centered individuals is a selfish society, destined to decline.

Luxury generally condemned

6. The larger moral problem involved in luxury is connected with distribution or the justice of the income, rather than with consumption or the spending of the income. The individual effects of luxury broaden thus into the larger social effects. Most of the enemies of luxury condemn all[Pg 390] expenditure of wealth above a very moderate sum, declaring that it is "unjust" for one man to have much while others are in poverty. This communistic doctrine pervades the teaching of many moral teachers, pagan and Christian. In many ways a public opinion can be developed to disapprove and condemn ostentation. Frivolous display becomes bad taste. Flaunting riches meet the public frown. The spending of income for dress and display has never been successfully forbidden by law. The Middle Ages are full of futile sumptuary laws which sprang from the envy of the nobles for the wealthy merchants. The growth of good taste may do what formal law found impossible.

6. The bigger moral issue with luxury is more about how income is distributed and whether it’s fair, rather than just how it’s spent. The individual impacts of luxury expand into broader social effects. Many critics of luxury denounce any spending of wealth beyond a reasonable amount, claiming it's "unfair" for one person to have so much while others live in poverty. This communist idea is common among numerous moral teachers, both pagan and Christian. In many ways, public opinion can develop to disapprove of and criticize showiness. Excessive display becomes a sign of bad taste. Showing off wealth tends to get a negative reaction from the public. The law has never successfully prohibited spending on clothing and showiness. The Middle Ages were filled with ineffective sumptuary laws that came from the envy of nobles toward rich merchants. The rise of good taste might achieve what formal laws could not.

Increasing social uses of wealth

The use of wealth in these days is taking more social directions. It turns from dress toward education, art, music, and travel; then ceases to be applied merely to self and family, and benefits the community. Nowhere and never before has this movement gone so far as in America. Andrew Carnegie, with his gifts of millions annually to public libraries; Peter Cooper, founder of the People's Institute; Ezra Cornell, the patron and prophet of the modern type of higher education—are citizens of a kind better known in this country than in any other.

The way wealth is used these days is becoming more socially focused. It shifts from being all about clothing to supporting education, art, music, and travel; it no longer just benefits individuals and their families, but also the community. Nowhere and at no other time has this movement advanced as much as it has in America. Andrew Carnegie, with his millions given each year to public libraries; Peter Cooper, who started the People's Institute; Ezra Cornell, a supporter and visionary of modern higher education—these are citizens whose contributions are better recognized in this country than anywhere else.

Justice of the large income
Legal repression of luxury inadvisable

The immorality of luxury rests in most minds on the conviction that it is unjust that any one should have so large an income to use. The question of luxury leads back to the question of distribution: Has the man honestly gained his wealth? If so, he may spend it with good judgment or poor, with good taste or bad, but, so long as he does not injure others in the spending of it, there is much vagueness and confusion in the talk of "justice" or "injustice." Each must in large measure be his own judge of the wisdom of expenditure. Luxury is not always a question of wealth. Every person of moderate income has relatively superfluous and expensive tastes. One spends more for music than many a millionaire does; another more for books. How many college students' budgets could pass the censorship of Hetty[Pg 391] Green, reputed to be the richest woman in America? If expenditures were regulated by the public, few persons would be within the law. But whatever the goods that are bought, if income is unjustly acquired, if its distribution is by rules that do not give the best possible approach to social service, there may well be talk of injustice. There is need of better standards of taste and judgment in expenditure, but not of sumptuary laws. If there is any legal change, it should be rather in the law of property.

The immorality of luxury often comes down to the belief that it’s unfair for anyone to have such a large income to spend. The discussion around luxury connects back to how wealth is distributed: Did the person earn their money honestly? If they did, they can spend it wisely or poorly, tastefully or not, but as long as their spending doesn’t harm others, there’s a lot of ambiguity in the talk about "justice" or "injustice." Each person should largely be their own judge about how wisely to spend. Luxury isn’t just about being rich. Everyone with a moderate income has relatively unnecessary and expensive tastes. Some people spend more on music than many millionaires do; others spend more on books. How many college students' budgets would pass the scrutiny of Hetty[Pg 391] Green, who was known as the richest woman in America? If the public regulated spending, few people would be compliant. But regardless of what goods are purchased, if the income is unfairly acquired, and if its distribution doesn’t prioritize the best approach to social service, then discussions about injustice are valid. We need better standards of taste and judgment in spending, but not laws that dictate what we can buy. If there should be any legal changes, they should focus more on property laws.


CHAPTER 41

REACTION OF CONSUMPTION ON PRODUCTION

§ I. REACTION UPON MATERIAL PRODUCTIVE AGENTS

Essential mark of the consumption of goods

1. Economic consumption is the enjoyment of the utilities which wealth is capable of affording. All wealth looks toward consumption. To take away the prospect of the enjoyment of goods is to take away all their value. Consumption involves generally the using up of a thing. Food is consumed quickly, clothing more slowly, and houses wear out after many years. The using up is, in some cases, due to the forces of nature, and is not hastened by enjoyment. A house goes to ruin more rapidly if uninhabited than with a careful tenant; clothing is destroyed more quickly by moths than by wear. The use of many goods that give esthetic pleasures, as art, painting, sculpture, and the enjoyment of fine scenery or of beautiful building sites, does not destroy the things that afford the pleasure. The idea that all value originates in labor has led to false views on this question. The essential mark of consumption is the using of the income as it arises, not necessarily the using up of the material agents that afford it, though this frequently occurs as well.

1. Economic consumption is the enjoyment of the benefits that wealth can provide. All wealth is aimed at consumption. Removing the possibility of enjoying goods takes away all their value. Consumption usually means using something up. Food is consumed quickly, clothing more slowly, and houses deteriorate after many years. In some cases, the wear and tear happens due to natural forces and isn't sped up by enjoyment. A house falls into disrepair more quickly if it's empty than if there's a careful tenant; clothing is damaged more by moths than by actual use. The enjoyment of many goods that provide aesthetic pleasure, like art, paintings, sculptures, and the beauty of scenic views or stunning locations, doesn’t ruin the items that bring pleasure. The idea that all value comes from labor has led to misconceptions about this topic. The key aspect of consumption is using the income as it comes in, not necessarily depleting the material resources that provide it, although that often happens too.

Consumers' choice as influencing value

2. The kind of consumption affects the value of material agents. Each buyer helps to determine the use of productive agents. The control of purchasing power means the potential control of industry to that degree. It was necessary in discussing the enterpriser to recognize that the buyer eventually dictates the direction of industry; the[Pg 393] enterpriser seeks to produce that for which there is most demand. A change of taste affects the value of natural agents. An increase in the demand for meat affects the value of wheat and potatoes, and also the land used for producing them. A change in the national diet may be equivalent to the discovery or to the destruction of half a continent. If one chooses to drink wine instead of buying statuary, he increases the value of vineyards and decreases that of marble quarries: If one drinks beer, he bids for barley; if he eats candy, he may be offering a bounty for beets. Therefore, choosing vines or violets, pictures or pretzels, each with his nickel helps to determine what shall be produced.

2. The type of consumption impacts the value of material resources. Each buyer plays a role in determining how productive resources are used. The control of purchasing power means having potential control over industry to that extent. When discussing the entrepreneur, it's important to recognize that the buyer ultimately dictates the direction of industry; the [Pg 393] entrepreneur aims to produce what is in greatest demand. A shift in preferences changes the value of natural resources. An increase in demand for meat raises the value of wheat and potatoes, as well as the land used for their production. A shift in the national diet could be as impactful as discovering or losing half a continent. If someone chooses to drink wine instead of buying sculptures, they increase the value of vineyards and decrease that of marble quarries. If they drink beer, they drive up the demand for barley; if they eat candy, they might be increasing the demand for beets. Thus, whether choosing wine or flowers, art or snacks, every small purchase influences what gets produced.

Inventions influencing value

The distribution of wealth thus affects the value of agents. The wealthy spend relatively more for luxuries, the poor for food and other essentials. Where wealth and incomes are very nearly equally distributed, the demand of different families will be for much the same kinds of goods. If there were no rich men, the demand for vineyards producing fine wines would be less. The very best qualities of goods take on the highest prices when there is a small, but very wealthy, class of purchasers.

The distribution of wealth affects the value of people in the market. Wealthy individuals tend to spend more on luxuries, while those with less money prioritize food and basic necessities. When wealth and income are more evenly distributed, different families will tend to want the same types of goods. If there were no wealthy individuals, the demand for vineyards that produce fine wines would decrease. The highest quality goods tend to have the highest prices when there is a small, but very affluent, group of buyers.

Inventions often shift demand, and value follows. The invention of the bicycle with pneumatic tires, coincident with the adoption of electric traction for street cars, reduced the price of horses between 1890 and 1895. This doubtless was a factor in agricultural land values at that time. This change was sudden, extreme, and temporary, and there has since been a gradual adjustment and a return to the former values.

Inventions frequently change demand, and value adjusts accordingly. The creation of the bicycle with inflatable tires, along with the rise of electric streetcars, lowered the price of horses between 1890 and 1895. This was certainly a contributing factor to agricultural land values during that period. This shift was abrupt, significant, and short-lived, and since then, there has been a gradual adjustment back to the previous values.

Consumers' choice as affecting productive forces

3. The production of the next period may be radically affected by the use now made of agents. Some consumption takes the form of using up and reducing the stock of wealth. The demand for lumber causes the disappearance of the forests, whereas the demand for oranges stimulates the planting of orange trees. The reckless exploitation of natural[Pg 394] resources leaves society poorer. Great herds of buffalo were slaughtered to get the hides, which were of comparatively slight value. Rich land has been exhausted to get a few harvests.

3. The way we use agents now could greatly impact production in the next period. Some consumption means using up and depleting our wealth. The demand for lumber leads to the destruction of forests, while the demand for oranges encourages the planting of orange trees. The careless overuse of natural[Pg 394] resources makes society poorer. Huge numbers of buffalo were killed just for their hides, which were worth very little. Fertile land has been drained to yield only a few harvests.

War is a use of wealth for ends believed at the time to be necessary and believed to forward social welfare better in the long run than would dishonorable submission; but it causes misery and leaves industry prostrate. The forms taken by saving are affected by the choice of expenditure. In war the savings of individuals are given to the government and used for destructive purposes. The lender parts with his wealth and society uses it up. While the lender has a claim on the industry and on the remaining property of the community, society as a whole is the poorer. If the savings had taken the form of public buildings, libraries, railroads, and factories, the wealth and income of society as a whole would have been enhanced.

War is a way of using wealth for what people believe at the time to be necessary and to promote social welfare more effectively in the long run than simply giving in; however, it brings suffering and leaves industries in ruins. How savings are used is influenced by spending choices. During war, individual savings are given to the government and spent on destructive actions. The lender gives up their wealth, and society consumes it. While the lender has a claim on the remaining resources and industry of the community, society as a whole ends up worse off. If those savings had been invested in public buildings, libraries, railroads, and factories, the overall wealth and income of society would have increased.

Consumers' choice as affecting wages

4. The kind of consumption affects the wages of the various classes of labor. That an increase in the supply of a given grade of labor reduces its wages and encourages its use, and vice versa, is a truth that became familiar in the study of wages. An influence also is exerted from the side of goods upon the price of labor. A shift of demand from one kind of goods to another depresses the wage of the one kind of labor and raises that of the other. A low grade of labor that performs only simple tasks, and those but badly, is injured if demand shifts to better products. Back of the sweat-shop shirt is the problem of the inefficient worker. Progress takes place by the effort of labor to increase its efficiency and to move into higher paid callings, and at the same time by the desire of the purchaser to buy as good a quality as he can.

4. The way we consume impacts the pay of different classes of workers. It's a well-known fact that when there's an increase in the availability of a specific type of labor, it lowers the wages for that labor and encourages its usage, and the opposite is also true. The demand for goods also influences labor prices. If demand shifts from one type of goods to another, it reduces the wage for the first type of labor and increases it for the second. A low-skilled worker who only does simple tasks poorly is negatively affected if demand moves toward higher-quality products. Behind the low-cost shirt made in sweatshops is the issue of the less efficient worker. Progress happens through the efforts of workers to improve their efficiency and move into better-paying jobs, while at the same time, buyers want to purchase the best quality they can find.

The consumer's responsibility

Every buyer then determines in some degree the direction of industry. The market is a democracy where every penny gives a right of vote. It is the thought of the society called "The Consumers' League" that through purchases, pressure[Pg 395] may be brought to bear upon the employer to provide better conditions of work. The members of The Consumers' League refuse to buy goods not made under sanitary conditions. Undoubtedly there is here a great economic force which an enlightened public opinion, even without a formal association, can make in large measure effective. Every individual may organize a consumer's league, leaguing himself with the powers of righteousness. Will he read a yellow journal or a pink or a white one? A nickel or two will buy either. He has a dollar; will he go to the theater or buy ten dishes of ice-cream? He decides to buy a book, and more type and paper are made, and more printers are employed; he subscribes to foreign missions and Christian workers penetrate farther into Africa. Every purchase has far-reaching consequences. You may spend your monthly allowance as an agent of iniquity or of truth. You cannot escape a choice even by burying the money, for that is either a demand for gold or a gift to the issuer of paper currency.

Every buyer plays a role in shaping the direction of industry. The market is like a democracy where every cent counts as a vote. It's the belief of the group known as "The Consumers' League" that through purchases, pressure[Pg 395] can be applied to employers to improve working conditions. Members of The Consumers' League refuse to buy products that aren't made under sanitary conditions. There is certainly a powerful economic force here that an informed public, even without a formal organization, can effectively harness. Anyone can create their own consumer league, aligning themselves with the forces of good. Will they read a sensationalist tabloid, a gossip magazine, or a serious publication? A nickel or two can buy any of them. If they have a dollar, will they go to the movies or buy ten ice cream dishes? If they choose to buy a book, that means more type and paper are produced, and more printers get hired; if they donate to foreign missions, it allows Christian workers to reach further into Africa. Every purchase has significant consequences. You can spend your monthly budget as a supporter of wrongdoing or of truth. You can’t avoid making a choice, even by hiding the money, because that either demands gold or gives a gift to the issuer of paper currency.

§ II. REACTION UPON THE EFFICIENCY OF THE WORKERS

Instinctive choice as related to welfare

1. All consumption works some temporary change in the consumer, making him a more or less efficient producer. Most consumption goods are used to gratify a wish of the moment. Many actions are governed by impulse rather than by reason; but in general this impulse is in harmony with the interests of efficiency. In primitive society instinct and appetite must generally have been safe guides. Food not merely appeased hunger and gratified the palate, but it gave strength. Sensations of cold, hunger, and thirst were developed by nature to stimulate men to do the things that helped them to survive. In primitive societies there are few chances to seek pleasures that are not favorable to efficiency. In the struggle for existence the more efficient tribes survive, and those that develop many abnormal tastes must perish.[Pg 396] But the conditions of modern life are more complex, and temptations beset men on every side. Tastes are pampered and appetite is gratified at the expense of later welfare.

1. All consumption causes some temporary change in the consumer, making them a more or less efficient producer. Most consumer goods are used to satisfy a fleeting desire. Many actions are driven by impulse rather than reason; however, this impulse generally aligns with efficiency. In early societies, instinct and appetite were probably reliable guides. Food not only satisfied hunger and pleased the taste buds, but it also provided strength. Sensations of cold, hunger, and thirst were developed by nature to encourage people to do what was necessary for survival. In primitive societies, there were few opportunities to seek pleasures that didn't contribute to efficiency. In the struggle for survival, the more efficient tribes thrive, while those that develop many unusual tastes tend to perish.[Pg 396] But modern life is more complicated, and temptations surround people on all sides. Tastes are indulged, and appetites are satisfied at the cost of future well-being.

Choice of foods

2. The physical efficiency of the worker is conditioned on wise consumption. Chemists and physiologists are telling now in accurate terms how the nutritive values of foods differ. Food values are not measured by the pleasure afforded the palate. The wide variety and greater choice now possible, even to the modest purse, make the chance of error much greater than in simpler conditions. This subject, already touched upon in the sections on the efficiency of labor, deserves further notice. From youth to age, the foolish choice of goods yields its harvest of ultimate misery. When babies are fed on crackers dipped in coffee, or, as among the Italian immigrants, on stale bread dipped in sour wine, there is a poor foundation laid for a vigorous manhood. Rich and poor cook too much for taste and too little for nutrition or digestion. Much cooking is still done in ways fit only for our grandfathers who had cast-iron stomachs and worked in the open air. Culinary methods have not been adapted as yet to a sedentary life.

2. The physical efficiency of the worker depends on smart consumption. Chemists and physiologists are now accurately explaining how the nutritional values of foods vary. Food values aren’t determined by how good they taste. The wider variety and greater options available today, even for those on a budget, increase the chances of making poor choices much more than in simpler times. This topic, which has already been discussed in the sections about labor efficiency, deserves more attention. From youth to old age, making poor food choices leads to long-term misery. When babies are fed crackers dipped in coffee, or, like some Italian immigrants, stale bread dipped in sour wine, they’re not set up for a healthy adulthood. Both rich and poor families often cook too much for flavor and too little for nutrition or digestion. Many cooking methods are still suited more for our grandfathers, who had strong stomachs and worked outdoors. Cooking techniques haven’t yet been adjusted for a more sedentary lifestyle.

Of drinks

Drinking tempts some men not only by taste, but by the appeal to sociability; to other coarser natures the joys of Bacchus offer the one hope of exhilaration. The pleasure from alcoholic liquor may at the moment outweigh the cost in money, but a diseased appetite forbids any reckoning of the vast psychic cost that follows. The coin paid for the drink is the beginning of the expense; misery, disgrace, degeneracy, and bestialty too often are the unreckoned items.

Drinking appeals to some guys not just because of the taste, but also because of the social aspect; for others with rougher edges, the joys of alcohol offer their only chance for a good time. At the moment, the pleasure from drinking might seem worth the price, but an unhealthy craving prevents any consideration of the huge mental toll that comes after. The money spent on the drink is just the start of the costs; sadness, shame, decline, and animalistic behavior are often the hidden consequences.

Of clothing

Clothing is primarily for ornament, secondly for physical comfort. That was the historical order, and it is the logical order in most minds to-day. How badly the two needs are harmonized! No wonder that the savage suffers in adopting civilized dress. Travelers describe the African potentate, attired in a high hat and a bracelet, striving to outshine[Pg 397] his rival resplendent in full-dress coat and a palm-leaf fan. Civilization is making headway there; but the student of primitive peoples finds one of the important causes of their decay to be their bad judgment in adopting civilized dress, unsuited to their customs and climate. A mistake is made likewise by workers in physical tasks in imitating the dress of the wealthy and professional classes. The dress of the higher classes often is chosen because of its unsuitableness for an active worker. It serves thus to mark its wearer as one engaged in delicate tasks or as a person of leisure. Possibly, therefore, because of their strong social ambitions, the manual workers in America more than elsewhere adopt a costume that is not sensible or sanitary.

Clothing is mainly for decoration and secondarily for comfort. That was the historical order, and it still makes sense to most people today. It's surprising how poorly these two needs are balanced! No wonder that people struggle with adapting to civilized clothing. Travelers describe an African leader wearing a tall hat and a bracelet, trying to outshine his rival who is decked out in a formal coat and holding a palm-leaf fan. Civilization is progressing there, but those studying primitive cultures find that one major reason for their decline is their poor choice in adopting civilized clothing, which doesn't fit their customs and climate. Similarly, workers in hands-on jobs make a mistake by mimicking the clothing of the rich and professional classes. The attire of the upper classes is often chosen because it's not practical for someone who works hard. It serves to identify the wearer as someone involved in delicate tasks or someone who doesn’t work at all. Therefore, possibly due to their strong social aspirations, manual workers in America tend more than others to wear clothing that isn’t sensible or hygienic.

Reactions of enjoyment upon the intelligence

3. The intelligence of the worker is affected by the form of his enjoyments. This does not refer to the use made of spare time for regular study in night schools, correspondence schools, vacation work, but to the use of time when seeking recreation. The choice of recreation reacts upon the nature of the man. Will he read a book or play billiards? In proper proportions both may be good, in excess both are evil. Liking realism, does he read Howells or the blood-curdling serial entitled "Piping the Mystery"? Does he devote his spare hours to the "Scientific American" or to the "Police Gazette"? At the moment there may be as much pleasure in one as in the other (and one might add, in Hibernian phrase, "Yes, and more too."). Does he enjoy music, the theater, or the cheaper attractions of Coney Island and the Bowery? Is his recreation permeated with a certain intellectual ambition? There may be just as much momentary joy in one choice as in another, and life is shaped by the direction of one's enjoyments. Much depends on the natural bent; some natures incline to the healthy as the plant grows toward the sun. With most characters much depends on the influences of neighborhood life; thus the boy's clubs and college settlements of the cities, the schools and playgrounds of the villages, are tending to surround[Pg 398] child life with healthier conditions, that will mould it into better social habits.

3. The intelligence of the worker is influenced by how he finds enjoyment. This isn't about using free time for regular study in evening classes, correspondence courses, or summer jobs, but rather how he spends time when looking for fun. The kind of recreation he chooses affects his character. Will he read a book or play billiards? Both can be good in moderation, but too much of either can be harmful. If he likes realism, does he read Howells or the thrilling serial titled "Piping the Mystery"? Does he spend his free hours reading the "Scientific American" or the "Police Gazette"? At any given moment, both may offer the same level of enjoyment (and one could add, as the Irish might say, "Yes, and even more."). Does he appreciate music, the theater, or the cheaper entertainment at Coney Island and the Bowery? Is his leisure time infused with a certain intellectual ambition? There can be as much instant pleasure in one option as in another, and the course of one's life is shaped by the direction of one's pleasures. Much depends on personal inclinations; some individuals naturally gravitate toward healthier options like plants growing toward the sun. For most people, the influences of their neighborhood play a significant role; hence, boys' clubs and college settlements in cities, along with the schools and playgrounds in villages, aim to surround child life with healthier conditions that will encourage better social habits.

Reaction upon the character

4. The form of the worker's expenditures affects his industrial virtues. This is not a moral lecture; it is a look at the economic side of the subject. There are some moral qualities, however, that are closely connected with efficiency, while others are not. Some individuals are corrupt in private personal relations, but "square" in business dealings. But usually there is some connection between the two, and under modern conditions this is becoming closer. Fitness for daily tasks is affected by the daily thoughts of the worker. Sordid and foul thoughts, like an internal malady, sap the economic efficiency of the worker; clean, bright thoughts act as a tonic. Drink, gambling, fast living, unfit men for positions of trust, while many pastimes leave the moral nature cleaner and stronger. Few can live a double life—honorable, conscientious, and exact in one part of the day, and corrupt in another. Dr. Jekylls and Mr. Hydes are not often found in real life. The habitual train of thought in leisure hours possesses and controls the man throughout his work. It is said that "A man is what his work makes him," but it is equally true that a man's work tends to become what he is. A man fit for a higher kind of work rises to it in the usual order of things; but no matter how humble the task, it partakes of the worth and wholesomeness of its doer.

4. The way a worker spends their money impacts their work ethic. This isn’t a moral lesson; it’s an examination of the economic aspect of the topic. There are some ethical qualities that are closely tied to efficiency, while others are not. Some people may be dishonest in personal relationships but "straightforward" in business. However, there’s usually a link between the two, and in today’s world, that connection is getting stronger. A worker’s effectiveness in daily tasks is influenced by their thoughts throughout the day. Negative and dirty thoughts, like an internal sickness, drain a worker's economic efficiency; positive, uplifting thoughts serve as a boost. Drinking, gambling, and living recklessly make people unfit for positions of trust, whereas many hobbies can leave one’s moral character cleaner and stronger. Few can maintain a double life—honest, responsible, and meticulous during part of the day, while being corrupt at another time. Dr. Jekylls and Mr. Hydes aren’t commonly found in real life. The patterns of thought during leisure time dominate and control a person during work hours. It’s said that "A man is what his work makes him," but it's equally true that a man's work tends to reflect who he is. A person suited for a higher level of work typically rises to it in the usual course of events; but regardless of how menial the task may be, it carries the value and integrity of the person doing it.

§ III. EFFECTS ON THE ABIDING WELFARE OF THE CONSUMER

Production vs. welfare

1. Man and his welfare are the end and aim of the economic process. The starting point of industry is wants; the goal is welfare. Momentary gratification is only a way-station, not the journey's end. Too often, in economic reasoning, things are looked at from the employer's point of view. The older writers, such as Ricardo and Mill, were inclined to take what John B. Clark has called the "feed[Pg 399] and work" view,—the view that the workman is merely an agent of production, a means to an end; that his food, the same as coal for an engine, is to be thought of rather as employer's cost than as consumer's gratification. But, in the broader view, the welfare of men as men is the subject most worthy of economic study. The workman's food is to gratify his hunger, primarily; not merely to make him a better working machine. This reverses the order of the older reasoning. The use made of the income is itself a kind of production—its last stage. Is the process, on the whole, worth while? This can only be judged by finding whether, on the whole, the welfare of man has been furthered.

1. People and their well-being are the ultimate goal of the economic process. The starting point of industry is needs; the aim is well-being. Short-term satisfaction is just a pit stop, not the final destination. Too often, economic discussions focus on the employer's perspective. Older writers, like Ricardo and Mill, tended to adopt what John B. Clark described as the "feed[Pg 399] and work" view—the idea that the worker is simply a production tool, a means to an end; that their sustenance, like coal for a machine, is more about the employer's expenses than the consumer's satisfaction. However, from a broader perspective, the well-being of individuals as human beings is the most important subject for economic analysis. A worker's food is meant to satisfy their hunger first; it’s not just about making them a more efficient machine. This shifts the priority from the older viewpoints. How the income is used is also a form of production—its final stage. Is the whole process worthwhile? This can be determined only by assessing whether, overall, people's well-being has improved.

The marginal application of income

2. An income yields the maximum gratification when it is apportioned among goods so that their marginal utilities, as nearly as possible, are equal. Even a small income is income capable of many applications. The choice lies among many thousands of articles. Utility varies not only according to the kinds of good, but according to the varying quantities of each. Every moment, therefore, the conditions of a choice are changing. The best use of income forbids the purchase of an additional unit of any good unless it affords the highest gratification obtainable, at the moment, at an equal price. Various circumstances prevent the exact application of this rule. Expenditure is a matter of habit, in large measure, rather than a matter of judgment. The knowledge needed for a rational choice very often is lacking. Appetites change, making unwise the old purchases, yet men go on buying the same things in the same proportions simply because a readjustment that would give greater gratification requires thought. Finally, the best economic adjustment must conform to the abiding physical and moral welfare of the user, not to a temporary impulse; and such a choice is far more difficult than that of the temporary good.

2. An income provides the most satisfaction when it is distributed among goods in a way that their additional benefits are as equal as possible. Even a small income can be used in many ways. The options include thousands of items. The value of these items changes not only based on their type but also according to the different amounts of each. Therefore, the conditions for making a choice are constantly shifting. The best way to use income prevents buying an extra unit of any good unless it offers the highest satisfaction available at that price at that moment. Various factors hinder the precise application of this principle. Spending is often more about habit than judgment. People often lack the knowledge needed for a rational choice. Desires change, making past purchases unwise, yet people continue to buy the same things in the same amounts simply because adjusting for greater satisfaction takes effort. Lastly, the best economic choice must align with the lasting physical and moral well-being of the user, not just a momentary desire; and making such a choice is much harder than opting for short-term satisfaction.

Progress and the refinement of desires

3. Progress takes place where new wealth gratifies marginal wants as intense as those of the preceding period. If the utility of every kind of goods decreased uniformly as[Pg 400] wealth increased, desire would steadily decline in intensity. But old wants vary and new wants develop with prosperity. Desire grows by what it feeds on. Ambition passes on to other and higher peaks. The direction of the individual man's life thus is determined by the expenditure of his increasing income. Wealth makes possible a new adjustment of life, a new character, both in the individual and in the society.

3. Progress happens when new wealth satisfies marginal wants as strongly as those from the previous period. If the usefulness of all types of goods decreased uniformly as [Pg 400] wealth increased, desire would consistently diminish in intensity. However, old wants change and new wants emerge with prosperity. Desire grows by what it consumes. Ambition shifts to other and higher goals. The course of an individual’s life is shaped by how he spends his increasing income. Wealth enables a new way of living and a new character for both the individual and society.

Wealth a means to living

The thought that needs emphasis in this connection is that, while production and consumption are separable in thought and distinguishable in practice, they are not opposed in their ultimate purpose. The highest fruits of production are in the lessons of sacrifice and discipline, and in its opportunities for experience and self-expression. The best result of the consumption of wealth is not the gratification of appetite, but the strengthening of the spiritual forces within men. The world is to rise to a higher social stage not by banishing labor and by multiplying sensual enjoyments of the commoner sort. Wealth, even in an economic view, is not the end of life, but merely the means to its realization.

The key point to consider here is that, although we can think of production and consumption as separate and treat them differently in practice, they ultimately serve the same purpose. The greatest benefits of production lie in the lessons of sacrifice and discipline, as well as in the opportunities for learning and self-expression it provides. The true value of consuming wealth isn’t just about satisfying desires; it’s about enhancing the inner strengths of individuals. The world can progress to a higher social level not by eliminating work or by simply increasing basic pleasures. Wealth, from an economic perspective, isn’t the goal of life; it’s just a tool to achieve it.

Variety and harmony in the choice of goods

4. Enjoyment is increased by a proper variety and harmony of goods. As the old kinds of goods increase in amount and fall in value, there must be a substitution of new goods. An element added to the dress or to the diet heightens greatly the total gratification. The result is a unit. Think of a dinner without butter, or a cranberry-pie without sugar, or a dress-suit without a linen collar. Certain combinations are essential to the requirements of developed taste and present a problem of complementary goods. Combinations of complementary goods enhance the enjoyment; inharmonious combinations decrease it. That certain things "go together" is a fact that rests often in the nature of things. Complementary colors please the eye; well-seasoned dishes please the palate.

4. Enjoyment is enhanced by having the right mix and balance of items. As older types of items become more common and lose value, new items need to take their place. Adding something to your outfit or your meals significantly boosts overall satisfaction. The outcome is a whole. Imagine a dinner without butter, a cranberry pie without sugar, or a formal suit without a linen collar. Some combinations are vital for refined taste and create a challenge of complementary items. Pairing complementary items increases enjoyment; mismatched combinations reduce it. The idea that certain things "go together" is often based on their inherent qualities. Complementary colors are pleasing to the eye; well-seasoned dishes are delightful to the palate.

Again, the harmony of goods is affected by the special nature of the occupation. A farmer with his out-of-door[Pg 401] life can use tobacco with far less danger than the sedentary worker. A piano player cannot be a base-ball player: the one requires soft and supple hands, the other hard and callous ones. The young man must give up the piano or the game, or play both badly. The harmony may rest on a still more complex social adjustment. The loss to the man whose life is in the main on a higher plane is greater if he descends occasionally to a lower. A ditch-digger, looking at the question short-sightedly, may deem "a good drunk" a very desirable form of enjoyment. But a brain-worker, whose joy as well as efficiency depends on the clearness of his intellectual processes, must see that in his case the perils and the costs are much greater.

Again, the balance of goods is influenced by the specific nature of the job. A farmer, with his outdoor lifestyle, can use tobacco with far less risk than someone who works a desk job. A piano player can’t also be a baseball player: the former needs soft, flexible hands, while the latter requires tough, calloused ones. The young man must choose between the piano or the game, or he’ll end up being mediocre at both. The balance may depend on an even more complex social adjustment. The loss for someone whose life is mostly on a higher level is greater if they occasionally drop to a lower one. A ditch-digger, thinking short-term, may see "a good drunk" as a desirable way to enjoy himself. But a brain-worker, whose happiness and effectiveness rely on clear thinking, must recognize that for him, the risks and consequences are much higher.

Unity of choice in happiness and in character

Wise consumption depends not alone on physical pleasures, but on the spiritual unity of the uses made of goods. Happiness and character are akin in the qualities of simplicity and unity. Happiness, so far as it depends on wealth, is a harmony of gratifications. Character is a harmony of actions, a group of complementary deeds. There can be no harmony, without a central, simple, guiding principle. The wise and moral use of goods and the economic use of them are therefore for the individual essentially the same. Life is a unity. The results of the choice of goods are reflected in the health, intelligence, happiness, morality, and progress of society. It is vain for the economist to ignore the ultimate relations between economic choice and morality; it is folly for the moralist to ignore the economic bases of right and wrong in human conduct.

Wise consumption isn't just about physical pleasures; it's also about the spiritual connection we create through how we use goods. Happiness and character share qualities like simplicity and unity. Happiness, when linked to wealth, is a balance of satisfactions. Character is a balance of actions, a collection of complementary deeds. There can't be true harmony without a central, simple guiding principle. Therefore, the wise and moral use of goods is essentially the same as their economic use for an individual. Life is unified. The outcomes of our choices regarding goods show up in the health, intelligence, happiness, morality, and progress of society. It's pointless for economists to overlook the connections between economic choices and morality; it's foolish for moralists to neglect the economic foundations of right and wrong in human behavior.


CHAPTER 42

DISTRIBUTION OF THE SOCIAL INCOME

§ I. THE NATURE OF PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION

Definition of personal distribution reviewed

1. Personal distribution, in economics, is the reasoned explanation of the ways in which income is divided among the members of the community. Before noting more exactly the ways in which distribution can and does take place, it may be well to review briefly some definitions that have been given in other connections. Distribution is bound up in practice with production, but it can be thought of as a more or less distinct problem. Functional distribution is the attribution of value to agents or classes of producers, to land, machinery, and labor considered impersonally as groups of productive agents. Personal distribution is the actual apportioning of income to living persons. This theme now to be dealt with is the more important practically, for the abstract discussion of rent and interest is of use only as it helps to an understanding of this vital human problem. It is well to recall also the distinction between wealth income, money income, and psychic income. The first is the objective aspect, the last is the subjective aspect, of income; the second, money income, may be an expression, in money form, of either of the others, but commonly of the former. The money expression of psychic income can be only approximately attained.

1. Personal distribution, in economics, refers to how income is shared among the members of a community. Before looking more closely at how distribution happens in practice, it’s helpful to briefly review some definitions that have been provided in other contexts. Distribution is closely linked to production, but it can also be seen as a somewhat separate issue. Functional distribution assigns value to different types of producers, such as land, machinery, and labor, considered as groups of productive agents. Personal distribution involves the actual sharing of income among individuals. This topic is particularly important in practice because the theoretical discussions about rent and interest only help us understand this crucial human issue. It's also important to remember the differences between wealth income, money income, and psychic income. Wealth income represents the objective side, while psychic income represents the subjective side of income; money income can generally be seen as a monetary expression of wealth income, though it can also reflect psychic income, albeit only to a limited extent.

Personal affection and distribution

2. The individual's income is determined by a number of forces, only part of which are primarily economic. Many persons derive income directly neither from property nor[Pg 403] from labor. They neither toil nor clip coupons, but they flourish in the favor of others—parent, husband, wife, friends, patrons. So long as the good-will continues these persons may be as well off as if they drew a salary or owned a bank. If a person in control of goods shares them with another, it is a matter that economists must recognize, but cannot well reduce to rules of value. It is not the task of economists to explain why the impulses of generosity arise, but only how they affect distribution. The economic problem of distribution really ends where owner or worker secures his income. Giving a part of it to some one else is essentially a form of consumption, and only secondarily a mode of distribution; it is the way chosen to spend the wealth income.

2. An individual's income is influenced by various factors, not all of which are purely economic. Many people earn income not directly from property or[Pg 403] from work. They don’t labor or collect interest, but instead thrive on the support of others—parents, spouses, friends, patrons. As long as this goodwill continues, these individuals can be just as well off as if they earned a regular salary or owned a bank. When someone in possession of goods shares them with another, it's something that economists need to acknowledge, but it can't easily be simplified into rules of value. It’s not the economists' job to explain why acts of generosity happen, but rather how they impact distribution. The economic issue of distribution effectively concludes when the owner or worker receives their income. Giving part of that income to someone else is fundamentally a type of consumption, and only secondarily a way of distributing wealth; it’s simply a choice of how to spend that income.

Complex source of psychic incomes

The psychic income of individuals, therefore, is often made up of many elements. Some parts are due to services performed by the person himself. When one combs his own hair he is adding to his income. Benjamin Franklin said it was better to teach a boy to shave himself than to give him a thousand dollars. Other goods are the uses and fruits of legally controlled wealth: chance finds, as gifts of value or lost and abandoned goods; goods assigned to one by authority; wealth inherited; illegal gains by robbery; goods secured on credit; gifts either of things or of services. The uses of this university are a gift forming a part, first, of the student's income, and, finally, of the social income. Such gifts can be traced back to large-hearted, public-spirited men like Ezra Cornell, but they must be looked upon as coming from some one. This list, incomplete as it is, suggests that the real income of most individuals has manifold sources. Let us undertake to examine and analyze the various methods in actual use in the distribution of income to the persons making up society.

The psychic income of individuals is often made up of various elements. Some parts come from services performed by the person themselves. When someone combs their own hair, they are contributing to their income. Benjamin Franklin said it’s better to teach a boy to shave himself than to give him a thousand dollars. Other goods come from the uses and benefits of legally controlled wealth: unexpected discoveries, gifts of value, or lost and abandoned items; goods given to someone by authority; inherited wealth; illegal profits from robbery; goods obtained on credit; gifts of either items or services. The benefits of this university are a gift that makes up part of the student’s income and, ultimately, of the social income. Such gifts can be traced back to generous, community-minded individuals like Ezra Cornell, but they should be viewed as coming from someone. This list, though incomplete, suggests that the real income of most individuals has many sources. Let’s take a closer look at the various methods currently used in the distribution of income among the people that make up society.

§ II. METHODS OF PERSONAL DISTRIBUTION

Compulsory distribution; violence

1. Distribution is sometimes compulsory, by force or fraud. This crude and primitive mode of distribution, the negation of personal liberty, never has been quite eliminated. In every country an unhappily large number of men from time to time break over into crime, from violence and highway robbery down to sneak-thieving, pocket-picking, and bunco games. Not more than ten per cent. of this criminal element is at any one time in prison. This method of personal distribution, not hinted at in most theories of distribution, determines a large part of the income of tens of thousands of men in this country and concerns the distribution of millions of dollars. These enemies of society appropriate whatever they can, and the law stops them if it is able.

1. Distribution can sometimes be enforced through violence or deception. This harsh and primitive method of distribution, which denies personal freedom, has never been completely eradicated. In every country, a sadly large number of people occasionally turn to crime, ranging from violence and robbery to petty theft, pickpocketing, and con games. No more than ten percent of this criminal group is in prison at any given time. This type of personal distribution, which most distribution theories ignore, significantly impacts the income of tens of thousands of people in this country and involves the distribution of millions of dollars. These societal outcasts take whatever they can, and the law intervenes when it can.

Chattel slavery

Slavery is distribution by legalized force, but the force is not legalized by the consent of the victims. The evolution of the harsher slavery may be traced through various forms of milder serfdom. There is found an element of this in the freest existing societies; men unwilling are forced to do things. A patent example is the convict on a chain-gang, a slave to society as a penalty for his violation of its commands. But some radical reformers to-day claim that present society is wholly based on legalized force, and that the workingman is essentially a slave. Their ideal cannot be realized without dissolving social bonds and destroying civilization; yet the presence, even in our society, of this forced, unwilling submission on the part of some of its members cannot be ignored.

Slavery is the distribution of power through legalized force, but that force isn’t legitimized by the victims’ consent. The development of harsher forms of slavery can be traced back to various types of milder serfdom. This concept exists even in the freest societies; people who are unwilling are compelled to do things. A clear example is the convict in a chain gang, a slave to society as punishment for breaking its laws. However, some radical reformers today argue that modern society is entirely built on legalized force, and that the working class is fundamentally enslaved. Their ideal cannot be achieved without dismantling social structures and destroying civilization; yet, the fact that some individuals in our society experience this forced, unwilling submission cannot be overlooked.

War indemnities

A similar example of forcible taking is seen in case of war. Savage tribes plunder and take captive their weaker neighbors. Conquering modern nations usually exact tribute from defeated enemies. Germany got a billion dollars from France, Japan a quarter of a billion from China. The[Pg 405] terms of peace at the close of our great Civil War were the most liberal ever granted by conqueror to vanquished; and yet the federal pensions granted to Northern soldiers are a form of tribute, being paid by taxes falling alike upon the North and the South. In all these cases the distribution by force is unwillingly suffered. In none of them is it reducible to economic rules or capable of a strict economic explanation.

A similar example of forcible taking can be seen in wartime. Savage tribes loot and capture their weaker neighbors. Modern conquering nations typically demand tribute from defeated enemies. Germany received a billion dollars from France, while Japan got a quarter of a billion from China. The[Pg 405] terms of peace at the end of our great Civil War were the most generous ever given by a conqueror to the defeated; and yet the federal pensions paid to Northern soldiers are a form of tribute, funded by taxes that affect both the North and the South. In all these cases, the distribution by force is reluctantly accepted. None of them can be reduced to economic rules or explained strictly through economics.

Charitable distribution within the family

2. Distribution may be charitable, that is, determined by considerations of benevolence and affection. Charitable is here used in its original sense, as synonymous with love or affection. First to be mentioned is the love of parents, the root and type of all the forms of charity. The lack of economic equivalence in the relation of parent and child is complete in early years. The helpless infant gives nothing economic to the parent, the parent gives all to the child. Gradually, however, the balance is regained; as the years go on, not only does the child repay in affection but in many cases he repays in material ways. In the factory districts and on the farm the child in early years begins to reëstablish the balance, becomes a worker, and contributes as much as the cost of his support, and finally more. A student of modern English town life has traced the curve of poverty traversed by the average child of the poor, as the family moves, now below, again above, the level of minimum income required for physical efficiency. In the middle or propertied classes the children do not for many years take the burden from the parents, and it is doubtful whether in most cases the economic balance is ever reëstablished. It is not to the parents, but to the succeeding generation, that the debt is vicariously paid.

2. Distribution can be charitable, meaning driven by feelings of kindness and affection. Charitable is used here in its original sense, as synonymous with love or affection. First, we should talk about the love of parents, which is the foundation and model for all forms of charity. In early years, the economic imbalance in the relationship between parent and child is complete. The helpless infant contributes nothing financially to the parent, while the parent gives everything to the child. However, over time, the balance is restored; as the child grows, they not only repay with affection but often also in tangible ways. In factory areas and on farms, children start contributing as workers at an early age, helping to balance out the cost of their upbringing and eventually contributing even more. A researcher studying modern urban life has documented the cycle of poverty experienced by the average child in poor families, as the family fluctuates above and below the minimum income needed for physical well-being. In middle or upper-class families, children do not relieve their parents of financial burdens for many years, and it’s uncertain whether in most cases the economic balance is ever really restored. The debt is not repaid to the parents but rather to the next generation.

And in larger circles

Friendship widens the range of generosity and multiplies the mass of gifts. Broad sentiments of humanity lead to gifts outside the range of personal affection and personal interest, to the beggar on the street, to institutions devoted to charity. In New York state about twenty million dollars[Pg 406] a year is given to charity, and in the country at large many times as much. In the year 1901 over one hundred million dollars was given to education in the United States by private donors; and that high mark will no doubt soon be passed. Gifts in cases of great disasters, as the Irish and Indian famines, the Chicago fire, the Galveston flood, the eruption of Mount Pelée, bespeak a widening generosity. Religion impels to the building of churches, to the support of priests, missions, and manifold religious undertakings. Charity in this connection is the expression of a sentiment that varies from the broadest and most general humanitarian sentiment to the most intense and ardent personal affection.

Friendship expands the scope of generosity and increases the number of gifts. Broad feelings of humanity lead to giving beyond personal connections and interests, reaching out to the beggar on the street and to organizations focused on charity. In New York state, about twenty million dollars[Pg 406] a year is donated to charity, and across the country, that amount is much higher. In 1901, private donors contributed over one hundred million dollars to education in the United States, and that peak will likely be surpassed soon. Donations in response to major disasters, like the Irish and Indian famines, the Chicago fire, the Galveston flood, and the eruption of Mount Pelée, demonstrate a growing generosity. Religion drives the construction of churches, the support of priests, missions, and various religious initiatives. Charity in this context expresses a feeling that ranges from the broadest humanitarian impulse to deep personal affection.

Authoritative distribution in the despotic state

3. Distribution may be by an authority willingly acknowledged. The two preceding forms of distribution, force and love, shade off into this form. In them the ones from whom goods are taken or to whom they are given have no power to change the conditions; here is to be considered the case where the person bows willingly to the superior power and takes what that power accords him. There are few despotisms in which the government is not based on the wishes and average capacities of the governed. If the citizens as a body really desired and were deserving of better government, in most cases they could get it. Much is heard, for example, of despotism in Russia, and of the abject condition of the people; but travelers testify that while many in the educated student classes are filled with the greatest discontent, and the intelligent subject peoples, such as the Finns, detest their rulers, such sentiments are far from general throughout the empire. The power of the Czar could not exist for a single moment if the mass of the people did not look to him as the great father whom they venerate and love. If this is true, the despotism in Russia, though abhorrent to our ideals of freedom, is fitted to the aspirations of the mass of the people. So far as government determines income, the authority distributing income there, as elsewhere, is one willingly acknowledged.

3. Distribution can occur through an authority that is willingly recognized. The two previous forms of distribution, coercion and affection, lead into this form. In those cases, the individuals from whom goods are taken or to whom they are given have no power to change the situation; here we consider a scenario where a person voluntarily submits to a higher authority and accepts what that authority grants them. There are few oppressive regimes where the government doesn't rely on the desires and general capabilities of the populace. If the citizens, as a whole, truly wanted and deserved better governance, in most cases they could attain it. For instance, there’s a lot of talk about despotism in Russia and the miserable state of the people; however, travelers report that while many in the educated student groups feel greatly dissatisfied, and the informed minority, like the Finns, despise their rulers, such feelings are far from being widespread across the empire. The Czar's power couldn't survive for a moment if the majority of the people didn't view him as the great father figure they respect and admire. If this is accurate, then despotism in Russia, although contrary to our ideals of freedom, aligns with the aspirations of the majority. As far as government influences income, the authority governing income there, as elsewhere, is one that is willingly accepted.

In communities and families

In patriarchal tribes, in communal societies, in monastic and other religious orders distribution is by an accepted authority. Each person works at what he is commanded to do, and some one in authority (the patriarch, head of the community, the father of the monastic order) portions out the work and the reward. In the family this rule largely prevails, and even after the children have come to years of discretion they not infrequently accept, from habit or affection, the will of the parents, and give up their entire wages to receive back a portion. The method of charitable distribution while the child is young gradually changes to authoritative distribution after the child becomes a worker. The untrained and indocile youth, however, is made the subject of compulsory distribution.

In patriarchal tribes, communal societies, and religious orders like monastic groups, distribution happens through an accepted authority. Each person does the work they are assigned, and someone in charge (the patriarch, community leader, or head of the monastic order) divides the work and the rewards. This rule largely applies to families as well, and even when children reach adulthood, they often still go along with their parents’ wishes out of habit or love, giving up their entire earnings in exchange for a portion back. As children grow, the way resources are distributed shifts from charitable to more authoritative. However, untrained and disobedient youth may be subjected to compulsory distribution.

In much governmental action

The collection and distribution of taxes is by public authority. No attempt is made to give back an exact equivalent to the tax-payer. The money is taken and spent by authority for the public good. This method is exemplified in the work of certain commissions appointed by law to fix rates or settle disputes, as boards of conciliation and arbitration and railway commissions. The courts sometimes find themselves obliged to enter this field, although they do so most unwillingly. They try to confine their efforts to interpreting the contracts men have voluntarily entered into, and they avoid, so far as possible, the making of contracts or the fixing of rates.

The collection and distribution of taxes is handled by public authorities. There’s no effort to return an exact equivalent to the taxpayer. The money is collected and used by authorities for the public good. This approach is illustrated by the work of various commissions established by law to set rates or resolve disputes, such as boards of conciliation and arbitration and railway commissions. Courts sometimes find themselves needing to get involved in this area, although they do so very reluctantly. They try to focus on interpreting the contracts that people have voluntarily agreed to and avoid, as much as possible, creating contracts or setting rates.

In various contests

In many cases, little thought of as economic distribution, the authoritative method is followed. Literary and oratorical contests are passed upon by a set of judges whose opinion of merit determines the award. It is a poor method, often resulting in injustice (as every defeated candidate will admit); but it is the only way practicable for deciding such contests. Yet there are literary and oratorical contests decided very differently. If a man advertises himself as an orator and charges fifty cents admission to his lecture, everyone who goes to hear the man votes that he is an orator;[Pg 408] everyone having money but staying away votes that he is not of such value. The one is judgment by the authoritative, the other by the competitive, method. The essence of the method of distributing by authority is that one individual (or group of individuals) judges of the deserts or duties of others, decides what others must get or must pay, not what he himself is willing to pay. Authoritative distribution is necessary in many cases, but it is fraught with dangers. It is the essence of socialism that it would make this plan universal.

In many instances, the authoritative method is used for economic distribution. Literary and speaking competitions are judged by a panel whose opinions on merit determine the winners. This method is flawed and often leads to unfairness (as every losing contestant will agree), but it’s the only feasible way to settle these contests. However, some literary and speaking competitions are judged quite differently. When someone promotes themselves as a speaker and charges fifty cents for admission to their lecture, everyone who attends effectively votes that they're a good speaker; anyone who has the money but chooses not to go is voting that the speaker isn’t worth it. One method is based on authority, while the other relies on competition. The core of authoritative distribution is that one individual (or group of individuals) evaluates the worth or responsibilities of others and decides what others should receive or pay, regardless of what they personally are willing to pay. Authoritative distribution is needed in many situations, but it carries significant risks. The essence of socialism is that it aims to make this approach universal.[Pg 408]

4. Distribution of psychic income may be in part by the collective use of social wealth. By collective use in the full sense is meant the continuing enjoyment at the same time by all caring to partake and without limit as to amount.

4. The sharing of psychic income may partly come from the shared use of social wealth. By collective use in the full sense, it means that everyone who wants to participate can enjoy it at the same time, without any limits on the amount.

Distribution by collective enjoyment

Now it is evident that, because of difficulties that arise, not all things are capable of this kind of enjoyment. Free water for private use from public waterworks is wasted; free meals and clothing to school-children are open to still greater abuses. Men cannot thus collectively enjoy rare wines or good confectionery; they cannot partake without limit of a limited supply. But libraries and schools may practically be managed in this way. They require both certain qualifications and certain sacrifices on the part of the user. Collective enjoyment is most completely possible where the use of a permanent form of wealth, such as a park, can be made free to the public. All individuals may enjoy equal privileges, though general rules may limit the kind of use; for example: no one may be permitted to pull flowers or to walk on the grass, but all who make use of the park enjoy equal privileges. Henry van Dyke in one of his essays puts into the mouth of his boy the question, "Father, who owns the mountains?" and the answer is, He who can enjoy them. Every man without covetousness, as he stands on this hilltop, owns the mountains, the lake, and this beautiful valley.

Now it’s clear that due to various challenges, not everything can be enjoyed in this way. Free water for personal use from public systems is often wasted; free meals and clothing for school kids can be misused even more. People can’t collectively enjoy luxury items like fine wines or gourmet treats; they can’t indulge in a limited supply without constraints. However, libraries and schools can be managed this way. They require certain qualifications and sacrifices from the users. Collective enjoyment works best where a permanent resource, like a park, can be freely accessed by the public. Everyone can enjoy equal rights, though general rules may restrict how it’s used; for instance, no one is allowed to pick flowers or walk on the grass, but everyone using the park has the same privileges. In one of his essays, Henry van Dyke presents a boy asking his father, "Who owns the mountains?" and the answer is, “He who can enjoy them.” Every person, free from greed, as they stand on that hilltop, owns the mountains, the lake, and this beautiful valley.

In some ways the amount of public enjoyment is decreasing,[Pg 409] as by the growing density of population, by the loss of open spaces and commons for playgrounds, by the destruction or fencing in of natural scenery; but in other ways it is growing and must grow rapidly. The spirit of civic improvement spreads. The streets are better paved than formerly; there are more public buildings, art galleries, and noble monuments. Every cross-road in the land will some day have its fountain and its statue. The coöperation of the whole community gives to collective use many of the advantages of large production, and the maximum of enjoyment.

In some ways, the amount of public enjoyment is decreasing,[Pg 409] due to the increasing population density, the loss of open spaces and parks for recreation, and the destruction or fencing off of natural scenery. However, in other ways, it is growing and will continue to grow quickly. The spirit of civic improvement is spreading. Streets are better paved than they used to be; there are more public buildings, art galleries, and impressive monuments. Every intersection in the country will eventually have its fountain and statue. The cooperation of the entire community provides to collective use many of the benefits of large-scale production and maximizes enjoyment.

Distribution by custom and status

5. Distribution may be by status or set rules and customs. Distribution by status fixes the shares of men independently of their effort and without their control. It is guided neither by their personal merit nor by the economic value of their services, but by the merits and acts of men not living. This method has prevailed and still prevails to a great extent, though in our society this is hardly realized. Feudal society was built on status. Men were born to certain privileges and positions; they inherited property which could neither be bought nor sold; they followed trades which could rarely be entered by any outside of favored families. Caste in India and in other Oriental countries regulates by status a large part of the life. In western countries to-day inheritance of property is the main legal form of status and it shades off into other forms of distribution. While in some cases inheritance may be looked upon as a gift to the heir, in other cases, elsewhere noted, it is partly earned by the heir who has helped to produce it. By public opinion and by prejudices, status is still maintained even where the law has formally abolished it, as is seen in modern race problems.

5. Distribution can be based on status or established rules and customs. When distribution is based on status, the shares people receive are determined independently of their efforts and without their control. It’s not guided by their personal worth or the economic value of their contributions but rather by the merits and actions of those who are no longer living. This method has dominated and continues to do so to a great extent, though this is often unrecognized in our society. Feudal society was built on status. People were born into specific privileges and positions; they inherited property that couldn’t be bought or sold; they pursued trades that were rarely open to anyone outside of preferred families. Caste systems in India and other Eastern countries regulate a significant part of life based on status. In today’s Western countries, inheriting property remains the primary legal form of status, which transitions into other forms of distribution. While sometimes inheritance might be seen as a gift to the heir, in other instances, as noted elsewhere, it is also partly earned by the heir who contributed to its production. Public opinion and biases still uphold status even where the law has formally abolished it, as demonstrated in modern race issues.

Competitive distribution the dominant form

6. Distribution is usually competitive in accordance with the value of the product. This is the dominant form of distribution in modern society. It is the essentially economic form, as contrasted with the legal and personal forms just described, because it is impersonal and reducible to a rule of value. Distribution under competition is made not[Pg 410] with reference to abstract ethical principles or to personal affection, but to the value of the product so far as it is honestly controlled. Monopoly, it may be noted, never has ceased to rest under the ban of Anglo-Saxon law, hence to exemplify compulsory, as opposed to competitive, distribution. A striking feature of the competitive method is its decentralization. Each helps to value the economic services of each. If one pays more for the services of the singer than for those of the cook, it is not because he would rather listen to the singing than to eat, but because by apportioning his income he can get the singing and the eating too. In the existing circumstances, the singer's services seem to him worth paying for, and he backs his opinion with his money. So each is measuring the services of all others, and all are valuing each. It is the democracy of valuation, while the method of authority is an oligarchy or monarchy.

6. Distribution is usually competitive based on the product's value. This is the main type of distribution in today's society. It's fundamentally economic, unlike the legal and personal forms previously mentioned, because it's impersonal and can be defined by a value rule. Distribution through competition is determined[Pg 410] by the product's value as long as it's honestly regulated, not by abstract ethical principles or personal feelings. It's worth noting that monopoly has always been frowned upon by Anglo-Saxon law, representing compulsory rather than competitive distribution. A notable aspect of the competitive approach is its decentralization. Each person's preferences help assess the economic value of others’ services. If someone pays more for a singer's services than for a cook’s, it's not because they prefer listening to singing over eating, but because by allocating their income wisely, they can enjoy both. In the current situation, the singer's services are valuable to them, and they affirm this value with their money. So everyone is evaluating each other's services, and all are assigning value to one another. It's a democracy of valuation, while authority-based methods tend to be oligarchic or monarchical.

Various ideals of distribution

7. The best distribution in practice must be sought in union and harmony of these various methods. Various social reforms propose simply the extreme application of one kind to the exclusion of the others. There are two opposing views of competition: one, that it is the ideal to be sought; the other, that it is inherently bad, and therefore should be abolished. Extreme individualists, believing that everything would be settled for the best by free competition, wish to make it universal. They ignore the many cases where it does not, should not, and cannot exist.

7. The best way to distribute resources in practice must be found through the combination and balance of these different methods. Various social reforms simply advocate for an extreme focus on one method at the expense of the others. There are two opposing views on competition: one sees it as the ultimate goal to achieve, while the other views it as inherently negative and deserving of elimination. Extreme individualists, who believe that free competition would lead to the best outcomes, want to make it universal. They overlook the numerous situations where competition does not, should not, and cannot happen.

Socialists, ill content with the share secured by the less skilled laborer, say that the competitive plan is unsound at the core. They say that distribution should be not in proportion to value, but in proportion either to needs or to deserts (they are not agreed which), judged by a vague ethical standard. But this involves the principle of authority in its extremest form. It intrusts to some men the function of passing upon the economic merits or desires of all others. Yet that alone is not a conclusive argument against all use of authoritative distribution. In many practical cases the[Pg 411] intrusting of power and authority to men to judge of the value of others cannot be avoided. Whatever is indispensable, whatever is the best possible, is, humanly speaking, just. Assessors, judges, jurors, must be employed. Interstate commerce commissioners determine whether rates are reasonable, boards of arbitration settle disputes, the strike commission adjudicates difficulties in the coal regions. Doubtless these methods will be increasingly used.

Socialists, unhappy with the share received by less skilled workers, argue that the competitive system is fundamentally flawed. They believe that distribution should be based not on value, but on either needs or merits (they can't agree which), assessed by a vague moral standard. However, this introduces the principle of authority in its most extreme form. It gives some individuals the power to judge the economic worth or needs of everyone else. Still, that by itself isn't a definitive argument against all forms of authoritative distribution. In many real-world situations, the delegation of power to people to evaluate the value of others is unavoidable. Whatever is necessary, whatever is the best possible, is, from a human perspective, just. Assessors, judges, and jurors must be used. Interstate commerce commissioners decide whether rates are fair, arbitration boards resolve disputes, and the strike commission mediates issues in the coal regions. These methods will surely be used more often.

Need of a wise blending of methods

There is no other kind of distribution than those enumerated. The strongest contrast is between the competitive and the authoritative principles; the others are minor and modifying. None of them alone is sufficient; each has its merits and each has its defects; they must supplement each other. Actually they are employed in modern society side by side; each seems essential and best in some special application. But it does not follow that exactly the proper use is now made of each. No two generations have followed the same rule, and the proportions in which use has been made of them has constantly shifted. It must be recognized that the principle of diminishing utility applies to each method of distribution as it does to the productive processes. Each may be best under certain conditions and circumstances, but, extended in application, each reveals its weaknesses. In any productive process the best method depends upon the proper proportion and combination of elements. Progress toward the best possible distribution is to be sought in the wise adjustment of the various methods to human nature and to human needs.

There’s no type of distribution other than the ones listed. The biggest contrast is between competitive and authoritative principles; the others are less significant and more flexible. None of them is enough on its own; each has its strengths and weaknesses, and they need to work together. In modern society, they are used side by side; each seems essential and optimal for specific situations. However, this doesn’t mean that each is being used appropriately. No two generations have followed the same approach, and the ways they’ve been utilized have constantly changed. It’s important to recognize that the principle of diminishing utility applies to each distribution method just like it does to production processes. Each method can be the best in certain conditions and circumstances, but when applied broadly, each shows its flaws. In any production process, the best method relies on the right balance and combination of elements. Progress toward the best possible distribution should focus on wisely adjusting the various methods to align with human nature and needs.


CHAPTER 43

SURVEY OF THE THEORY OF VALUE

§ I. REVIEW OF THE PLAN FOLLOWED

The cycle and order of economic study

1. The beginning and end of economic study is man. Before leaving the more theoretical and abstracter part of the theory of value, it may be well, at the cost of some repetition, to restate and review the relations of the various parts of the argument. Intent on details of the theory of value the student is in danger of losing its broader perspective.

1. The starting point and conclusion of economic study is people. Before moving away from the more theoretical and abstract aspects of value theory, it might be worthwhile, even if it means repeating some points, to restate and review how the different parts of the argument connect. Focused on the details of value theory, the student risks losing sight of the bigger picture.

The proposition with which this section opens was accepted as our axiomatic starting-point. It was not so in the older political economy; men too often were looked upon rather as a means to an end, namely, the creation of wealth. This proposition refers to all classes, not to a small group of men. The aim of economic study is democratic, being the welfare of all men. Economics does not purpose, however, to explain man's action with reference to all things. It asks and attempts to answer the question: "Why does man attach value to certain things and actions; why does he measure them in certain ratios as expressed in terms of each other; and why do these ratios change with changing conditions?" This purpose has determined the order of our study. Beginning with an analysis of the nature of wants, and of the mental process of valuing consumption goods, the circle of inquiry widened to the problem of valuing things whose relation to wants is more remote and indirect (though not less important).

The idea that starts this section is accepted as our basic principle. This wasn’t the case in older political economy; people were often seen mainly as a way to generate wealth. This idea applies to all classes, not just a select few. The goal of economic study is democratic, aiming for the wellbeing of everyone. However, economics doesn’t intend to explain human actions in relation to everything. It seeks to ask and answer the question: "Why does a person value certain things and actions; why do they measure them in specific proportions as compared to one another; and why do these proportions change with different conditions?" This objective has shaped our study's structure. We start with an analysis of the nature of wants and the mental process of valuing consumer goods, then expand our inquiry to include the problem of valuing things that are more indirectly related to wants (but are still important).

The problem of future uses, the major part of the theory[Pg 413] of value, leads back to the question of the use man makes of things—a field claimed by the moralist, but one that cannot be neglected by the economist. Economics is not the whole science of social relations. It is a restricted part of the field. But it comes into relation with great practical questions that touch all sides of life. Thus economics broadens and unites with the general stream of sociology. In the pursuit of our study one comes back to the starting-point and cause of value—human wants and the use made of wealth to gratify them. The circle is completed. We have surveyed, rapidly and imperfectly it is true, the whole range of economic inquiry.

The issue of future uses, a key aspect of the theory[Pg 413] of value, brings us back to how people utilize things—a domain often explored by moralists, but one that economists cannot overlook. Economics isn't the entirety of social science; it's just one segment. However, it connects with significant real-world questions that impact every aspect of life. In this way, economics expands and merges with the broader scope of sociology. As we delve into our study, we circle back to the foundation and cause of value—human needs and how wealth is used to satisfy them. The cycle is complete. We have quickly and imperfectly examined the full spectrum of economic inquiry.

The unit in value problems

2. The central point in economic study is the simplest problem of exchange value. The first look at the economic world reveals so many things that have relation to wants, and relations so complex, that the mind is confused. The object of science is to simplify; it seeks unity in the midst of chaos. Relations exist between wants and things that certainly never can gratify them directly. Where is the simplest aspect of the problem to be found? Evidently in the exchange of consumption goods, for these are in closest touch with wants. Out of the complex of direct and indirect goods, those few which are at the moment gratifying wants must be somewhat abstractly, but logically, set apart and studied. In the simplest problem, the exchange of the most typical consumption goods, is the key to the larger problem of value. If one could follow it step by step into its complexer relations, he might hope to understand everything in economics.

2. The main focus of economic study is the simplest issue of exchange value. A first look at the economic world reveals a multitude of factors related to wants, and the connections are so intricate that it can be overwhelming. The goal of science is to simplify; it aims to find unity amidst the chaos. There are relationships between wants and things that can't directly satisfy them. Where can we find the simplest aspect of the problem? Clearly, it's in the exchange of consumer goods, as these are most closely related to wants. From the mix of direct and indirect goods, the few that currently satisfy wants must be somewhat abstractly but logically identified and analyzed. The simplest issue—the exchange of the most typical consumer goods—holds the key to the broader issue of value. If one could trace it step by step into its more complex relationships, they might hope to grasp everything in economics.

Former or conventional conceptions of rent and interest

3. The problems of rent and of time-value are successive steps in the explanation of the exchange value of indirect agents. The term rent has been so variously defined that no caution to the student as to its use can be deemed superfluous. Until recently economists sought to confine the term to the income from natural resources (or land). Rent, in their conception, was the income from one group of goods, physically distinguishable from another group of goods, called[Pg 414] capital, which were supposed to yield interest. That is, rent and interest was each supposed to bear much the same relation to a particular set of durable agents; the difference between them was primarily in the agent that yielded them (though there were other complicating thoughts) rather than in the aspect of value they represented.

3. The issues of rent and time value are steps toward understanding the exchange value of indirect agents. The term rent has been defined in so many ways that students should be careful about how they use it. Until recently, economists tried to limit the term to income from natural resources (or land). In their view, rent was the income from one category of goods, which was physically distinct from another category of goods, called[Pg 414] capital, that was believed to generate interest. In other words, rent and interest were thought to have similar relationships to a specific set of durable agents; the main difference between them was the type of agent that produced them (although there were other complicating factors) rather than in the type of value they represented.

Rent and time-value as here used

Rent as defined in this volume has the much broader meaning of the usufruct of any material agent as contrasted with the use-bearer. Usufruct is a conception most intimately related to that of consumption goods, but is logically one step further removed from want. Time-value, as here considered, is a broader conception than that of contract interest, for it has to do with the all-pervading element of time in its influence on value. Some rents are logically, and in practical business as well, not measured over periods of time, but at the moment of their accrual. The measurement of time differences is mainly required in setting a valuation upon a more or less permanent use-bearer. This process, which is capitalization, has only recently been recognized to be the discounting of all the future uses to their present worth. While in its essence this is merely a problem in exchange value, it is the highest, subtlest, and most difficult of such problems. Its understanding presupposes rent, just as rent presupposes the analysis of wants and marginal utility. It is the outer zone of the value problem, carrying the thought of value years away (all but an eternity away) from present enjoyment.

Rent, as defined in this volume, has a much broader meaning that encompasses the right to use any material resource as opposed to just the user. Usufruct is a concept closely tied to consumption goods, but it is logically one step removed from immediate desire. The time-value discussed here is a broader concept than just contract interest, as it pertains to the pervasive influence of time on value. Some rents are measured not over time periods, but at the moment they are earned. Time measurement is mainly necessary when evaluating a more or less permanent user. This process, known as capitalization, has only recently been recognized as the act of discounting future uses to their present value. While essentially a question of exchange value, this is the most complex and subtle of such issues. Understanding it requires a grasp of rent, just as rent requires an understanding of wants and marginal utility. It represents the outer edge of the value problem, extending the concept of value far beyond immediate enjoyment.

Different stages in value

While both rent and time value are widened so that each applies in some manner to all durable agents, it is a grave error to conclude hastily that the intention is to make synonymous the old terms rent and interest. Rent and time-discount remain essentially different stages in the value problem. Actual concrete net economic incomes as they arise are always rents. Interest never accrues in a concrete form except under the interest contract for a money loan (a contract income, not an economic income), and this evidently is a species of contract rent. Time-value is a phase of value connected[Pg 415] logically with investment, or the calculation of future earning power; rents are both actual and expectative, or future, but as realized incomes they always express present earning power. Together, rent and capitalization embrace the whole problem of valuing durable material agents.

While both rent and time value are expanded so that they apply in some way to all durable assets, it’s a serious mistake to quickly conclude that the intention is to make the old terms rent and interest interchangeable. Rent and time-discount are essentially different aspects of the value issue. Actual net economic incomes as they occur are always rents. Interest only materializes in a concrete form under a loan agreement (which is a contractual income, not an economic income), and this is clearly a type of contract rent. Time value is a phase of value connected[Pg 415] logically with investment, or the estimation of future earning potential; rents are both actual and expected, or future, but as realized incomes, they always indicate present earning potential. Together, rent and capitalization cover the entire issue of valuing durable material assets.

Wages and profits related

4. Wages and profits are of the same genus, the value of human services of different grades. The attempt has been made in the foregoing treatment to show the unity between the problems of wages and profits, and to point out the difference between the conditions that surround them. Through the common characteristic, social utility, the employer's service can be compared with the most ordinary or the most artistic labor. Profits and wages, therefore, are simply different aspects of the same question. A common power, or principle, is found in all objects of value, a power to gratify human wants. In the variety of human services and in material goods must be sought this unity.

4. Wages and profits are essentially the same, representing the value of different types of human services. The earlier discussion aimed to highlight the connection between the issues of wages and profits, as well as the differences in the conditions that affect them. By focusing on the shared characteristic of social utility, the employer's service can be compared to both ordinary and artistic work. Therefore, profits and wages are just different sides of the same issue. A common force or principle exists in all valuable items, a force that satisfies human needs. This unity can be found in the variety of human services and material goods.

The different kinds of services range from direct to most indirect goods. The commonest labor may serve welfare at the moment or may be embodied in a form to be used years later. In that light, wages seems a more complex problem than either rent or capitalization. But the moment the service embodies itself in a material good with future uses the general theory of capitalization applies to it.

The various types of services range from direct to very indirect goods. The most common labor might benefit welfare right now or could be transformed into a form that will be used years down the line. From that perspective, wages appear to be a more complicated issue than rent or capitalization. However, once the service takes shape in a physical good with future applications, the general theory of capitalization applies to it.

§ II. RELATION OF VALUE THEORIES TO SOCIAL REFORMS

"Orthodox" political economy

1. The earlier theories of political economy implied a dismal view of the future of the masses. The theory of value one holds is sure to affect his view of economic progress and of social reform. The theories from the middle of the eighteenth to the middle of the nineteenth centuries, however varied they were in other respects, nearly all gave a gloomy view of the condition of the laboring-men. The physiocratic school in France, the so-called "orthodox" economists in England (that is, the writers from about 1800 to 1850 that were in[Pg 416] sympathy with the landholding or commercial classes), and the socialistic or laboring-class theorists, all inclined to this view. It was while this view prevailed that Carlyle characterized political economy by the term still sometimes heard—"the dismal science." The thinkers of that time started their study of value at wages, and assumed that population would always increase so fast as to force labor to a bare subsistence. The other shares (or the other classes of society) were supposed then to absorb all the surplus income. Economics to-day is not especially lugubrious, and its more cheerful note is due as well to its changed theory of value as to the evidence of advancing welfare among the masses.

1. The earlier theories of political economy presented a bleak outlook for the future of the masses. The value theory you believe in definitely influences your perspective on economic progress and social reform. The theories from the mid-eighteenth century to the mid-nineteenth century, despite their differences, almost all portrayed a grim picture of the conditions faced by laborers. The physiocrats in France, the so-called "orthodox" economists in England (the writers around 1800 to 1850 who were in [Pg 416] support of the landholding or commercial classes), and the socialistic or labor-class theorists all tended to share this view. During this time, Carlyle famously referred to political economy as "the dismal science." The thinkers of that era began their analysis of value with wages, assuming that population growth would always outpace resources, forcing laborers to live on only the bare minimum. Other social classes were thought to absorb all the surplus income. Today's economics is not particularly gloomy, and its more optimistic tone reflects both its updated value theory and the evidence of improving conditions for the masses.

The gloomy socialistic theory

2. The socialistic theory of value, akin to the other, holds that capitalists absorb all the benefits of progress. The socialists (of the radical school) claim that their theory is merely the logical conclusion to be drawn from the old "orthodox" theory, stated in its extremest form. Usually, however, the orthodox theorists softened and modified greatly the statement of their harsher views. The socialists have not been willing to recognize any ameliorating conditions. They say: economic theory shows that under a competitive condition of society the laboring-man must be forever ground down in helpless misery; therefore the only hope of the laboring masses is to do away with competitive society and to substitute for it central, governmental control of all industry. They did not and do not attempt to distinguish carefully the part of production, due to brains and effort, from the part due to ownership of capital. The socialist theory is a plan for political agitation rather than a scientific theory of value. It was originated or elaborated by men such as Karl Marx, Frederick Engels, and Ferdinand Lasalle, as labor leaders and political agitators, who found a ready weapon in the bungling economic analysis of the time. The claim of a scientific basis for socialism has continued to be proudly made by their followers, but it has a tottering support in their defective theory of value.

2. The socialist theory of value, similar to others, argues that capitalists reap all the benefits of progress. Socialists (from the radical camp) assert that their theory is simply the logical conclusion drawn from the old "orthodox" theory, taken to its extremes. However, orthodox theorists typically softened and modified their tougher views significantly. The socialists haven’t been willing to acknowledge any improving conditions. They argue that economic theory indicates that in a competitive society, working-class people will always be trapped in helpless misery; thus, the only hope for the working masses is to eliminate competitive society and replace it with centralized, governmental control of all industries. They have not made a clear distinction between the contributions of intellect and effort in production and those due to capital ownership. The socialist theory serves more as a political agenda than a scientific theory of value. It was developed or refined by figures like Karl Marx, Frederick Engels, and Ferdinand Lasalle, who were labor leaders and political activists that found a useful tool in the flawed economic analysis of their time. Their followers have continued to make the claim of a scientific foundation for socialism, but it rests on shaky ground due to their flawed theory of value.

George's single-tax theory

3. The single-tax theory of value is that ground-rent automatically absorbs all benefits of progress. This is the most notable example of a plan of social reform growing out of an abstract theory of value. While the socialists first had their plan of social reform (or revolution), in whose support Marx's fanciful theory of value was invented, Henry George appears first to have got hold of a theory of value that suggested his plan of social reform. Studying the political economy of Ricardo and Mill, he accepted their ideas regarding the hopeless outlook of the laboring classes, and their conception of the theory of ground-rent with its false implication that landowners get all the surplus in society. George thus came to believe that, with private ownership in land, competition steadily robbed all but landlords, even the non-landholding capitalist, of any share in the benefits of progress. This theory of value is thought to explain all the poverty in the world. It calls, in the single-taxer's opinion, for a radical measure of reform, namely, the taking of all rent of land for public purposes as a common instead of an individual income. If the theory of value on which it is based were sound, the doctrine would have irresistible reasons in its favor; if it is false, most of the argument falls to the ground, though there may still be substantial reasons of a different nature for the exceptional treatment of ground-rents for purposes of taxation.

3. The single-tax theory of value suggests that ground rent automatically absorbs all the benefits of progress. This is a notable example of a social reform plan that emerges from an abstract theory of value. While socialists initially had their plans for social reform (or revolution), which inspired Marx's imaginative theory of value, Henry George seems to have been the first to adopt a theory of value that led to his social reform plan. By studying the political economy of Ricardo and Mill, he agreed with their views on the bleak future of the working class and their ideas about ground rent, which incorrectly implies that landowners receive all the excess wealth in society. As a result, George believed that, with private land ownership, competition continuously deprived everyone except landlords, including non-landholding capitalists, of any share in the benefits of progress. This theory of value is thought to explain all the poverty in the world. According to the single-tax advocates, it calls for an urgent reform measure: taking all land rent for public use as a common income rather than an individual one. If the theory of value it's based on is accurate, the doctrine has compelling reasons in its favor; if it's incorrect, most of the argument collapses, although there may still be significant reasons of another kind for the special treatment of ground rents in taxation.

Recent hopeful theories of wages; Walker's

4. Recent theories of value assign to labor a more hopeful position. A most optimistic theory of wages is "the residual claimant theory," presented by Francis A. Walker. His view was that the various shares of production, such as land-rent, the income from machinery, etc., and the enterpriser's profits, were fixed by forces independent of wages, and any increase in the product must therefore fall to the laborer as the residual claimant. This conclusion has the one merit of explaining somehow the rise in wages in the past century, but the fallacy of its method is too evident to call for exposure. Not to enter into the details of the method, it is[Pg 418] enough to note that it involves the circular reasoning that land-rent is a surplus over cost of production, and is fixed regardless of wages, whereas the cost of production itself is made up of money wages.

4. Recent theories of value give labor a more positive role. A very optimistic view of wages is the "residual claimant theory," introduced by Francis A. Walker. He believed that different shares of production, like land rent, income from machinery, and the profits of entrepreneurs, are determined by factors separate from wages, meaning that any increase in production must go to the laborer as the residual claimant. This idea does explain the rise in wages over the past century, but the flaw in its reasoning is obvious and doesn't need much elaboration. Without going into the details of the reasoning, it is [Pg 418] enough to point out that it relies on the circular logic that land rent is a surplus over production costs and is set regardless of wages, while production costs themselves are determined by money wages.

Clark's wage theory

Another American economist, John B. Clark, is led by his theory of profits to a most hopeful conclusion as to the future of wages. Profits he considers to be essentially the reward for improvements in productive processes, which gradually accrue to the general benefit. As profits thus disappear, the average wage-earner is correspondingly uplifted, a conclusion quite as hopeful as that of Walker. In discussing profits above, dissent from the narrow conception of their source has been expressed.

Another American economist, John B. Clark, draws a very optimistic conclusion about the future of wages based on his theory of profits. He believes that profits are basically the reward for advancements in production methods, which ultimately benefit everyone. As profits fade away, the average wage worker is correspondingly uplifted, making his conclusion as hopeful as Walker's. In the discussion of profits earlier, there has been a disagreement with the limited view of where they come from.

Some facts lend support to every one of these theories of social progress, but other facts refuse to be harmonized. The temptation to get a simple, dogmatic explanation of value should be resisted. When the interrelation of the factors is recognized there is little likelihood of concluding that some one of them will absorb all the benefits of progress. One is not driven to the extreme either of optimism or of pessimism. While the theory of value is not in itself a theory of society, it greatly influences social conclusions. Clear economic analysis is a condition to sound thinking on practical questions.

Some facts support each of these theories of social progress, but other facts just don't fit in. We should resist the urge to find a simple, dogmatic explanation of value. When we recognize how the different factors are interconnected, it's unlikely that any one of them will gain all the benefits of progress. This means we won't be pushed to extremes of optimism or pessimism. Although the theory of value isn't a theory of society itself, it has a big impact on social conclusions. A clear economic analysis is essential for sound thinking on practical issues.

§ III. INTERRELATION OF ECONOMIC AGENTS

Organic nature of the productive process

1. The industrial process is a unity and the different agents bear an organic relation to each other. The problem of value is not one of physical division; it is one of logical analysis, and this is not possible in isolation or without the competition of men. Production as now carried on is a social process; the determination of market price is a social process. The different agents are complementary goods, each necessary to the best use of the various other agents. The value of seed is not to be found apart from the use of the ground; or the value of the leather apart from the shoemaker or the[Pg 419] thread he uses. When these things are brought together in society their value is found by the comparison and measurement of marginal utilities. Economic forces, like other classes of forces, act and react upon each other. Two bodies attract each other in space; two chemicals uniting are both transformed into a substance differing from either. The economic result of materials and men coöperating is something differing from either factor, yet dependent on both.

1. The industrial process is a whole, and the different agents are interconnected. The issue of value isn't about physical separation; it's about logical analysis, which can't happen in isolation or without competition among people. Production as it's currently done is a social process; determining market price is also a social process. The different agents are complementary goods, each essential for making the best use of the other agents. The value of seed can't be seen apart from the use of land, just as the value of leather can't be separated from the shoemaker or the[Pg 419] thread he uses. When these elements come together in society, their value is determined through the comparison and measurement of marginal utilities. Economic forces, like other types of forces, influence and respond to each other. Two objects attract one another in space; when two chemicals combine, both are transformed into a new substance that's different from either. The economic outcome of materials and people working together is something different from either factor alone, but it relies on both.

The conventional divisions of economics

2. The divisions of the older political economy are aspects of the general problem of value. The divisions conventional in the text-books on political economy, namely, "production, exchange, distribution, and consumption," have not been observed in the plan of this work. It has not seemed possible to accept the view that each of these phases of the vital economic process could be discussed completely apart from the others. Consumption must be studied at the beginning, as the basis of exchange value, and again at the end, when the circle of thought has returned to the use man makes of wealth; and it pervades the whole subject of value, for back of every price is the potential utility of the good. Exchange is coextensive with the whole process of associated industry; for wherever there is a price, there is exchange. Subjective value outside a market forms a small, though not negligible, part of the problem for the student of to-day. Production is implied in every exchange, as exchange is in all social production. They are, indeed, but different phases of the larger phenomenon, the economic process. Nor is distribution, considered in its impersonal or economic form, any other than the logical valuing of the shares of the factors in economic production. Impersonal distribution is coextensive with economic production. Whatever a good, logically considered, contributes to value in production, that is its share of the product. Personal distribution, it is true, brings in other great influences which have been partly considered, but which will be treated more fully in the division to follow, on the influence of the state in the distribution of income.

2. The divisions of older political economy are aspects of the general problem of value. The divisions commonly found in textbooks on political economy, such as "production, exchange, distribution, and consumption," haven't been followed in this work. It hasn't seemed feasible to treat each of these stages of the vital economic process as entirely separate from the others. Consumption has to be studied at the beginning since it forms the basis of exchange value, and again at the end when the discussion comes full circle back to how people use wealth; and it influences the entire subject of value, because behind every price is the potential utility of the good. Exchange is interconnected with the whole process of associated industry; wherever there is a price, there is exchange. Subjective value outside of a market is a small, though not insignificant, aspect of the issue for today's student. Production is implied in every exchange, just as exchange is intrinsic to all social production. They are, in fact, just different aspects of the larger phenomenon—the economic process. Likewise, distribution, when looked at from an impersonal or economic perspective, is essentially the logical assessment of the shares of the factors in economic production. Impersonal distribution coincides with economic production. Whatever a good contributes to value in production, that becomes its share of the product. Personal distribution, however, introduces significant influences that have been partly discussed, but will be explored in more depth in the next section, regarding the influence of the state on income distribution.

The broadest principle of value

3. The law of diminishing returns is the broadest principle of value. The one character common to all goods is that their importance varies with their quantity in any given connection. This is true of direct goods whose power to gratify wants falls as the supply grows; it is true of indirect goods, whose technical importance diminishes as the quantity increases, and which when taken at any given cost can be applied, after a point, only with diminishing advantage. The gradual extension of the marginal principle from land used in agriculture to every conceivable economic agent is the most important development of the last century of economic theory.

3. The law of diminishing returns is the broadest principle of value. The common characteristic of all goods is that their importance changes with the amount available in any situation. This applies to direct goods, where the ability to satisfy needs decreases as the supply increases; it also applies to indirect goods, whose practical value decreases as the quantity rises, and which, when considered at a certain cost, can only be used with less benefit after a certain point. The gradual expansion of the marginal principle from agricultural land to all types of economic resources is the most significant advancement in economic theory over the last century.

Generality of the law of value

It being true that things are measured by the utility of the unit used last, logically considered, the least change in the combination alters the value of all the factors. Practical economic problems, therefore, are dynamic, not static. The view that the shares of the different factors are fixed by quite separate laws has not been accepted here. The law of rent is the same as the law of wages in its essential point and principle. It is a general law of value applied to a particular kind of want-gratifier. The law of substitution likewise is a general law, for within limits some substitution of factors is always possible along the margin. That being true, every movement of price creates its own resistance; substitutes will be found for materials, demand will decline, and a new equilibrium of price will be attained.

It’s true that the value of things is determined by the usefulness of the most recently used unit. Therefore, even the slightest change in the combination affects the value of all the factors. Practical economic issues are dynamic, not static. The idea that the shares of different factors are determined by entirely separate rules isn’t accepted here. The law of rent and the law of wages are essentially the same in their principles. They represent a general principle of value applied to a specific type of want-satisfier. The law of substitution is also a general principle since, within limits, some substitution of factors is always possible at the margins. Because of this, every price movement creates its own resistance; substitutes will emerge for materials, demand will drop, and a new price equilibrium will be reached.

Mutual employment of the factors
An ever changing problem

4. The factors and agents of production mutually furnish the field of employment for each other. Each factor is dependent for its technical efficiency on the presence of the other factors. If labor is plentiful and machines are scarce, machines bear a high rent. In accordance with the law of diminishing returns, the last unit of labor in that case contributes little to the product, and labor gets low wages, while more is attributed to the machine. Each machine thus may be considered to offer a field for the employment of labor. If population increases and land remains fixed, the need for[Pg 421] food raises the rental value of land. But if population increases slowly, and capital and science progress, the field for the employment of labor is enlarged; and if new lands are opened up or new resources are discovered beneath the surface of the land, the field for labor is still more enlarged and a greater share is attributed to labor. This changing character of the problem must be recognized; no share is foreordained in size.

4. The factors and agents of production create job opportunities for each other. Each factor relies on the presence of the other factors to be technically efficient. When there’s plenty of labor but few machines, machines become expensive. Following the law of diminishing returns, the last addition of labor contributes little to the overall product, resulting in low wages for labor, while more value is given to the machine. Each machine can be seen as creating job opportunities for labor. If the population grows and the amount of land stays the same, the demand for[Pg 421] food increases the rental value of land. However, if the population grows slowly, and capital and technology improve, the opportunities for labor also increase; and if new lands are opened up or new resources are found beneath the land, the job market for labor expands even further, leading to a greater share being attributed to labor. This evolving nature of the issue needs to be acknowledged; no share is predetermined in size.

The pursuit of the analysis of value along the lines of marginal utility thus leads to conclusions far less mechanical, and, to the superficial student, less simple than were the doctrines prevailing in the older economics. But the conclusions are, let us hope, more exact and more applicable to the real world, enabling the student to arrive at juster views of the present interests and of the future welfare of society.

The pursuit of analyzing value through marginal utility leads to conclusions that are much less mechanical and, to a casual learner, less straightforward than the theories that dominated older economics. However, we hope these conclusions are more precise and more relevant to the real world, helping students develop a clearer understanding of current interests and future societal well-being.


DIVISION B—RELATION OF THE STATE TO INDUSTRY


CHAPTER 44

FREE COMPETITION AND STATE ACTION

§ I. COMPETITION AND CUSTOM

Definition of economic freedom

1. Economic freedom exists when men's goods or their own services may be exchanged as they choose, without hindrance. Competition is but another expression for economic freedom. Where men are free to exchange their goods and to get the best price they can, and actually do so, they are said to compete. The action of men in the mass follows pretty regular lines, corresponding to certain abiding motives. If one man dictated all industry, a very fragmentary science of economics would be possible; but the mass of men act according to some rule and are free so to act. When men are free to bring their goods to a market and get the best price possible, a single market price results.

1. Economic freedom exists when people can exchange their goods or services as they wish, without any obstacles. Competition is just another way of describing economic freedom. When individuals are free to trade their goods and seek the best price they can get—and actually do so—they are considered to be competing. The behavior of people as a group tends to follow consistent patterns based on certain enduring motivations. If one person controlled all industry, only a limited understanding of economics would be possible; however, most people act according to some principles and are free to do so. When individuals are free to bring their goods to a marketplace and secure the best price available, a single market price emerges.

When cost of production was believed to be the regulator of value, it was said that the law of value laid down was true "within the limit of free competition." Market price varied ceaselessly from cost of production, and whenever it did "the law of value" as then formulated was admittedly invalid or inapplicable. The law of monopoly price was supposed to be in marked contrast to the law of competitive prices. The law of prices, as followed in our study, stated in[Pg 423] terms of marginal utility, is equally valid in competitive and in monopolistic conditions if there is merely one-sided, or buyers', competition. Two-sided competition is not the sole, though it is the usual condition, which the economist takes account of in reasoning on the problem of price. Anything that keeps men from exchanging what they have for the best price, interferes with competition. Some of these hindrances have been noted, others are now to be.

When it was thought that the cost of production determined value, people said that the law of value was only true "within the limits of free competition." Market prices constantly fluctuated from the cost of production, and whenever they did, "the law of value" as it was then defined was clearly invalid or not applicable. The law of monopoly pricing was supposed to be very different from the law of competitive pricing. The law of prices, as discussed in our study, stated in[Pg 423] terms of marginal utility, is just as valid under competitive conditions as it is under monopolistic ones if there's only one-sided competition, or buyers’ competition. Two-sided competition is not the only condition that economists consider when analyzing price issues, even though it's the most common scenario. Anything that prevents people from exchanging what they possess for the best price disrupts competition. Some of these obstacles have been noted, and others will now be discussed.

Economic freedom vs. equality of efficiency

2. Economic freedom does not mean equality of power or of efficiency. It was said in discussing monopoly that it was not to be understood to be merely either scarcity or superiority. To speak of the class of laborers of ability above that of the average day laborer as having a monopoly is certainly a confusion of monopoly with the scarcity of efficiency. The term competition is not easy to define in practice; for it is not easy to see just what part of a man's inability to exchange is due to his own lack of efficiency, and what to things outside of himself which prevent him from exchanging his labor. But the thought is clear that free competition—economic freedom—is limited whenever men are hindered by any power outside themselves from using their economic power as they prefer. The limitations of competition, thus understood, are essentially social limitations, imposed by other men either unconsciously by custom, convention, tradition, or consciously by force or by laws. When, among Polynesian tribes, the custom of taboo prevailed, by which certain things were reserved to the rulers and were forbidden to the common man, there was a limitation on his economic freedom. Contrast such limits with those set by the penury of nature. The savage may like best to hunt, but if there is no game, he must fish; he may like best to make arrowheads, but in need of food he must dig roots. Economic action is limited by lack of knowledge and skill; the resources of nature lie unused under the feet of savages who are suffering from their lack. These are limitations not of economic freedom but of economic efficiency.

2. Economic freedom doesn't mean everyone has the same power or efficiency. When discussing monopoly, it's important to clarify that it isn't just about scarcity or superiority. Referring to skilled workers as having a monopoly compared to the average day laborer mixes up the idea of monopoly with the scarcity of efficiency. Defining competition in real life can be tricky; it’s hard to pinpoint how much of a person's inability to trade is due to their own inefficiency versus external factors that stop them from exchanging their labor. However, the concept is clear: free competition—economic freedom—is restricted whenever individuals are prevented by external forces from using their economic power as they wish. These limitations on competition are essentially social restrictions, imposed by others either unknowingly through customs, conventions, and traditions, or knowingly through force or laws. For example, in certain Polynesian tribes, the practice of taboo kept certain resources reserved for rulers, limiting the economic freedom of common people. In contrast, limits set by nature's scarcity are different. A hunter may prefer hunting, but if there’s no game, they must fish; they might prefer making arrowheads, but in need of food, they must gather roots. Economic activities are limited by a lack of knowledge and skills; the resources of nature are left untapped at the feet of those lacking these abilities. These limitations are not about economic freedom but about economic efficiency.

Limitation by custom in early society

3. In early society custom limits economic freedom in many ways. The savage is not a man without law; he is bound in many ways to prescribed lines of conduct. Primitive custom usually takes on a religious sanction, and every member of the tribe is compelled to do as his fathers have done and as his neighbors are doing. He is not free to choose. Custom in some ways is favorable to the welfare of society, for it limits the power of masters and rulers, preserves the rights of individuals to common property, and is in the interest of the weak as well as of the strong. In an age of force if it were not for custom, he who had might on his side could take all. So in early society even economic relations were complex and yet almost fixed—changing only slowly from generation to generation. Every such social custom that limits the choice of men limits economic freedom.

3. In early society, tradition restricts economic freedom in many ways. The savage isn’t a person without laws; he is bound in many ways to prescribed behaviors. Primitive tradition often has a religious basis, and every member of the tribe is expected to do what their ancestors did and what their neighbors are doing. They aren’t free to choose. Tradition can be beneficial to society because it limits the power of masters and rulers, protects individuals' rights to shared resources, and serves the interests of both the weak and the strong. In a time of force, if it weren’t for tradition, those with power could take everything. So in early society, even economic relationships were complex yet somewhat stable—only changing slowly from generation to generation. Every social custom that restricts people's choices also limits economic freedom.

Limitation by custom in the Middle Ages

4. Custom ruled a large share of the industrial life of the Middle Ages. Political and economic interests were not clearly divided in the Middle Ages. Land was the all-important kind of wealth. Military and other public services were performed by the vassal, who thus at the same time paid his taxes and the rent of the land. The landlord was at once the ruler, the receiver of rents, and the collector of taxes. The rent, however, was not a competitive price, but consisted of the dues and services the forefathers had been accustomed to pay. This limited slavery, like all other slavery, was wasteful, as it did not give to the individual the strongest motive to increase the quantity and to improve the quality of his service. Trade became limited in almost every direction. Crafts and gilds arrogated to themselves the right of employment in their industries. No matter what talent the son of a peasant might show, he usually found it impossible and always found it difficult to follow the occupation of his choice. Privilege pervaded all the life of that time. In such conditions economic friction is great. Men are kept in trades below their ability, while others gain command of monopolistic and unearned returns.

4. Custom played a major role in the industrial life of the Middle Ages. Political and economic interests weren't clearly separated during this time. Land was the most important form of wealth. Military and other public services were carried out by vassals, who simultaneously paid their taxes and the rent for the land. The landlord was both the ruler, the recipient of rents, and the tax collector. However, rent wasn't determined by competition but was made up of the dues and services that ancestors had traditionally paid. This type of limited slavery, like all forms of slavery, was inefficient, as it did not provide individuals with a strong motivation to increase the quantity or improve the quality of their work. Trade was constrained in almost every way. Crafts and guilds claimed the exclusive right to employ in their industries. Regardless of the talent shown by a peasant's son, he usually found it impossible and always found it difficult to pursue the occupation of his choice. Privilege was everywhere in life at that time. Under such conditions, economic friction is high. People are stuck in trades below their ability, while others gain control of monopolistic and unearned profits.

Yet through all the Middle Ages ran the forces of competition. The inefficiency of customary services was a constant invitation to competitors. Men were striving to break over the barriers of custom and prejudice. The strife for freedom was the vital economic force even of the Middle Ages. The industrial history of that time is largely the story of the struggle of the forces of competition against the bounds of custom.

Yet throughout the Middle Ages, competition was a driving force. The inefficiency of traditional services constantly invited competitors. People were trying to push past the limits of custom and bias. The fight for freedom was the essential economic force even during the Middle Ages. The industrial history of that era is mainly about the struggle of competitive forces against the constraints of tradition.

§ II. ECONOMIC HARMONY THROUGH COMPETITION

Effect of modern forces on custom

1. The industrial events following the discovery of America strengthened the forces making for economic freedom. Discoveries in the Western hemisphere opened up a wide field for the adventure and enterprise of Europe. Commerce is the strongest enemy of custom, and new opportunities gave a rude shock to the conservatism both of the manor and of the village. With the rapid growth of industry and manufactures, old methods broke down. In an open market custom declines; it flourishes best in sheltered places. Further, the movement of thought in the Reformation and the spirit of the time, expressing the principle of personal liberty, allowing the individual to follow his own opinions and take the consequences, were favorable to competition. Despite these facts the restraints of the national governments on trade continued great, in some respects increasing during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, in France, Holland, and England. The regulation before attempted by towns and villages was employed on a larger scale by national governments with their commercial systems. The colonies in America were used for the economic ends of the "mother countries" and for the selfish interests of the home merchants in Europe. The American Revolution was one of the bitter fruits of the English policy of trade restriction.

1. The industrial developments after the discovery of America boosted the push for economic freedom. Discoveries in the Western hemisphere opened up vast opportunities for European adventure and enterprise. Trade is the biggest challenge to tradition, and new possibilities provided a significant shock to the conservatism of both the manor and the village. With the rapid growth of industry and manufacturing, old practices fell apart. In an open market, tradition fades; it thrives best in protected environments. Additionally, the ideas emerging from the Reformation and the prevailing spirit of the time, which championed personal liberty, allowed individuals to follow their own beliefs and face the consequences, were supportive of competition. Despite this, the restrictions imposed by national governments on trade remained significant, and in some cases increased during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, especially in France, Holland, and England. The regulations once implemented by towns and villages were taken to a larger scale by national governments through their commercial systems. The American colonies were exploited for the economic benefit of the "mother countries" and for the selfish interests of home merchants in Europe. The American Revolution was one of the harsh outcomes of English trade restriction policies.

Adam Smith's influence
The philosophy of natural law

2. Adam Smith's work advocating greater economic freedom had a profound influence upon public thought. "The[Pg 426] Wealth of Nations," the first great work on political economy, was published in the year 1776. That was the "psychological moment," as public thought was so prepared for it that it had its maximum possible influence. The year of the American Declaration of Independence gave the most striking object lesson on the evils of a selfish colonial policy that interfered on a grand scale with economic freedom. The old customs had become ill fitted to life, ill adapted to the rapid industrial changes that were going on. What was needed in many directions, both in politics and in industry, was negative action by the government, the repeal of the old laws, the overthrow of old abuses. The French Revolution, following a few years later, emphasized this thought in the political field. The philosophers of the time believed in a "natural law" in industry and politics. The reformers of the time wished to throw off the trammels of the past and to give men opportunity to exert themselves "naturally." In America the old abuses never had taken deep root, as the conditions of a new continent were not favorable to monopoly and privilege. Although the movement for the repeal of medieval laws has continued in Europe from 1776 till the present time, yet to-day custom is stronger in Europe than in America. Serfdom was not abolished until the nineteenth century in Austria and southeastern Europe, and not until a few years ago in Russia. Many economic and cultural forces furthered this movement, but the most powerful intellectual force in its favor was the work of Adam Smith. So strong an impression did Smith's book make, that in the minds of men "free trade" became almost identical in thought with political economy, whereas that was but the temporary economic problem of the eighteenth century.

2. Adam Smith's work promoting increased economic freedom had a significant impact on public opinion. "The[Pg 426] Wealth of Nations," the first major book on political economy, was published in 1776. It was the "psychological moment," as public thought was so ready for it that it had its maximum influence. The year of the American Declaration of Independence provided the most striking example of the harms of a self-serving colonial policy that widely obstructed economic freedom. The old customs had become outdated and misaligned with the rapid industrial changes occurring. What was needed in many areas, both politically and industrially, was for the government to take a step back, repeal the old laws, and eliminate old abuses. The French Revolution, occurring shortly after, highlighted this idea in the political arena. The philosophers of that era believed in a "natural law" in both industry and politics. The reformers of the time wanted to shed the constraints of the past and give individuals the chance to act "naturally." In America, the old abuses never took deep root, as the conditions of a new continent were not conducive to monopoly and privilege. Although the push to repeal medieval laws has continued in Europe from 1776 to today, customs are still stronger in Europe than in America. Serfdom wasn’t abolished until the nineteenth century in Austria and southeastern Europe, and just a few years ago in Russia. Various economic and cultural forces supported this movement, but the most influential intellectual force in its favor was Adam Smith's work. Smith's book made such a strong impression that in people's minds, "free trade" became almost synonymous with political economy, even though it was merely a temporary economic issue of the eighteenth century.

The doctrine of the economic harmonies

3. The doctrine of the "economic harmonies" is the extremest form of belief in the virtues of competition. Every truth in political philosophy finds some exaggerated expression. The main task of the student is to determine what shade of gray things are, rather than whether they are white[Pg 427] or black. The belief in the benefits of competition and the virtues of economic freedom found expression in the doctrine of "the economic harmonies." This is the faith that if men are left entirely free to do as their interest dictates, the highest and best efficiency for all will follow; it is the belief that the economic interests of all men are in harmony. The most striking evidence in support of this thought is the stimulating effect of self-interest freely working in the field of competition. Each strives to do what will bring him the largest return, and the price others pay measures their estimate of the service. Each seeking his own interest is led to make himself more useful to others. Thus are men stimulated to sacrifice, to invention, to preparation; thus is zeal animated and are efforts sustained.

3. The idea of "economic harmonies" is the most extreme belief in the advantages of competition. Every truth in political philosophy tends to be expressed in an exaggerated way. The main task of students is to figure out the nuanced realities instead of simply classifying them as white[Pg 427] or black. The belief in the advantages of competition and the benefits of economic freedom is reflected in the concept of "economic harmonies." This idea suggests that if people are completely free to pursue their own interests, the best outcomes for everyone will emerge; it's the belief that everyone's economic interests align. Strong evidence supporting this idea is the energizing effect of self-interest functioning within competition. Each person aims to do what generates the greatest return for them, and the prices that others pay reflect their assessment of the value of the service. By pursuing their own interests, individuals are motivated to be more helpful to others. This drives people to make sacrifices, innovate, and prepare; it fuels enthusiasm and sustains efforts.

Good social effects of self-interest

Through self-interest the working force is distributed over the field of industry wherever it is most needed. The remarkable adjustment of industry to the needs of each neighborhood is brought about by individual motives, not by centralized authority. It is not mere chance that produces this harmony. Wherever consumers settle, stores are started and factories are built. Wherever work is to be done, men come in about the right number to do it. Skill is adjusted to needs by the delicate measurement of the market rate of wages. Competition gives a definite rule of price—certainly the only definite impersonal rule; some say the only just rule. The competitive price must be appealed to even in arbitration. It is the standard to which things tend constantly to adjust themselves in an open market.

Through self-interest, the workforce is spread across various industries wherever it's most needed. This remarkable adaptation of industry to the needs of each community is driven by individual motives, not by a centralized authority. It’s not just coincidence that creates this balance. Wherever consumers settle, stores pop up and factories are built. Wherever there’s work to be done, people come in about the right numbers to get it done. Skills are aligned with needs by the precise measurement of the market wage rates. Competition establishes a clear pricing rule—certainly the only definite impersonal rule; some argue it’s the only fair rule. The competitive price must be referenced even in arbitration. It’s the standard to which things consistently try to align in an open market.

Conflicting interests in the business world

4. Experience shows that the economic interests of men are only partly, not wholly, in harmony. That there is a great measure of truth in the statements just made, all must admit; but their application is limited. They are partial truths, never to be ignored, but quite false if taken, without modification, as practical rules of conduct. There are three species of competition in every market: that between sellers, that between buyers, and that between sellers on the one hand[Pg 428] and buyers on the other. It is to the interest of the buyers that the sellers shall be numerous, eager, and freely competing. It is to the interest of the seller that supply shall be small, that sellers shall be united, and that buyers shall compete sharply. If at any point free competition is hindered, even the disciple of economic harmony must expect a discordant result. But in reality competition is rarely quite complete on both sides, and when it is not, the weak suffer. Men do not start with fair and equal opportunities. All that they may be entitled to under competition may be so little that social sympathy seeks to better the result; hence poor relief, public and private. Society as a whole has an interest in the outcome of the individual's economic struggle. It cannot see men starving or driven into crime. But the argument need not be confined to such crude and extreme cases, for wherever economic interests are not in harmony and it is possible to further the social welfare, will not society be justified in acting?

4. Experience shows that the economic interests of people are only partly, not entirely, aligned. Everyone has to admit that there's a lot of truth in these statements, but their application is limited. They represent partial truths that should never be overlooked, but they can be misleading if taken as absolute rules for behavior without any adjustments. There are three types of competition in every market: competition among sellers, competition among buyers, and competition between sellers on one side[Pg 428] and buyers on the other. Buyers benefit when there are many sellers who are eager and competing freely. Conversely, sellers benefit when supply is limited, when they stand together, and when buyers compete rigorously. If free competition is restricted at any point, even someone who believes in economic harmony should expect a discordant outcome. However, in reality, competition is seldom fully balanced on both sides, and whenever it's not, the weaker parties suffer. People don’t start out with fair and equal opportunities. What they might gain from competition can be so minimal that social compassion seeks to improve the situation; this is the reason for public and private assistance. Society as a whole has a stake in the results of individual economic struggles. It can't just stand by and watch people starve or turn to crime. But this argument goes beyond just the most extreme situations; whenever economic interests are misaligned and there's a chance to promote social well-being, shouldn’t society feel justified in taking action?

§ III. SOCIAL LIMITING OF COMPETITION

Imperfections of economic freedom

1. Undoubted evils result from some forms of competition under the conditions actually existing. Complete freedom must remain a somewhat abstract ideal, and actual conditions must be recognized. Entire freedom of choice means freedom to make mistakes, a privilege whose enjoyment society cannot always permit. The child should be raised to good citizenship, and entire freedom of choice makes that impossible or improbable. The freedom of choice of the insane, the feeble-minded, and the criminal, cannot be recognized. Even where competition is the ideal of sound adult humanity, it is not to be too suddenly or extremely applied. The inequality of faculties, the prevailing dishonesty, the mass of inherited abuses, cannot be either ignored or at once ended. The immigrant from Europe, plunged into the trying conditions of city life, suffers in health and in morals, and often becomes[Pg 429] a burden upon society. One of many competitors may drive competition to an evil extreme. The "problem of the twentieth man" is presented when nineteen men desire to limit competition in ways not socially harmful, as by closing shops on Sunday or in the evening, and the one man refuses. The appeal to economic harmony often is the cry of "peace, peace, where there is no peace." The highest social result may be attained now by limiting, again by directing, in other cases possibly by fostering, competition.

1. Some types of competition definitely lead to negative outcomes given the current conditions. True freedom will always be a somewhat abstract concept, and we must acknowledge reality as it is. Complete freedom of choice allows for the possibility of making mistakes, a luxury that society can’t always afford. Children should be raised to be responsible citizens, and having total freedom of choice makes that difficult, if not impossible. The freedom of choice for those who are insane, intellectually disabled, or criminals cannot be accepted. Even when competition is ideally suited for responsible adults, it shouldn't be implemented too quickly or drastically. We cannot ignore the disparities in abilities, the widespread dishonesty, or the many inherited problems that exist; these can't just be resolved overnight. Immigrants from Europe, thrown into the challenges of urban life, often suffer in terms of health and morality, and frequently become[Pg 429] a burden on society. A single competitor can push competition to a harmful extreme. The "problem of the twentieth man" arises when nineteen people want to restrict competition in socially responsible ways, such as closing shops on Sundays or in the evenings, while one person refuses. The call for economic harmony often equates to a plea for "peace, peace, where there is no peace." The best social outcomes may now be achieved by limiting, redirecting, or in some cases possibly encouraging competition.

Forces opposing competition

2. The main rivals of competition are custom, religion, morality, combination, and state action. The first three of these were the strongest forces in the past and they are still operating; but combination and state action are more characteristic of the present. The influence of custom, of morality, and of religion on value, has been touched upon at several points in our study; that of combination has been recently and more fully discussed. But state action, one of the most important of all the limitations, has been reserved for the concluding portion of our work.

2. The main rivals to competition are customs, religion, morality, collective action, and government intervention. The first three have been the strongest forces in the past and still have an impact today; however, collective action and government intervention are more typical of the present. The influence of customs, morality, and religion on value has been mentioned at several points in our study; the impact of collective action has been discussed more thoroughly recently. But government intervention, one of the most significant limitations, has been saved for the final part of our work.

The state's part in directing competition

3. It is a function of the state to determine in part the ways in which men shall exert their powers. This is not the sole function of the state, nor is its influence toward this end exclusive. The state puts limits to the physical rivalry of men. In the distant past no doubt physical rivalry between men was an agent of progress. The strong drove out the weak; physical contest developed more vigorous limbs, keener senses, and higher sagacity. To-day it is one of the principal functions of the state to suppress the physical contest between men. The citizen is surrounded with a network of rules and regulations of which he is hardly conscious. Most men easily avoid coming into contact with the police and feel no irksomeness in the control of the civil courts. The state regulates economic interests in many other ways; it controls the building of streets; it inspects the material and construction of houses; it forbids acts injurious to the public welfare; it regulates the issue of money; it determines the[Pg 430] manner in which credit may be extended, the forms of taxation, and the direction which trade may legally take. The state has a part in shaping great industries of a public or semi-public nature, such as waterworks, railroads, and the postal system.

3. It's the state's role to partly decide how people use their powers. This isn’t the only role of the state, nor is its influence on this matter exclusive. The state sets limits on the physical competition among people. In the distant past, physical competition among individuals was likely a driver of progress. The strong pushed out the weak; physical contests led to stronger bodies, sharper senses, and greater intelligence. Today, one of the main roles of the state is to prevent physical competition among individuals. Citizens are surrounded by a web of rules and regulations that they are often unaware of. Most people easily avoid interactions with the police and don’t feel burdened by the control of civil courts. The state also regulates economic interests in many other ways; it oversees the construction of streets, inspects building materials and construction methods, prohibits actions that harm public welfare, regulates the money supply, dictates how[Pg 430] credit can be extended, establishes tax structures, and controls the legal direction of trade. The state plays a role in shaping major industries that are public or semi-public, like water systems, railroads, and postal services.

Aim and failings of state action

The state is as wise as the men who constitute it. Men make mistakes, therefore men collectively will make them. The state regulates and limits—now wisely, now foolishly; but its aim is to preserve the benefits of competition without its evils, to lift the competition to a higher plane, and, by determining the direction in which men shall put forth their efforts, to give a higher and truer economic freedom.

The government is as smart as the people who make it up. People make mistakes, so collectively they will too. The government regulates and restricts—sometimes wisely, sometimes not; but its goal is to maintain the advantages of competition while minimizing its downsides, to raise competition to a better level, and, by guiding where people focus their efforts, to provide a more genuine and elevated economic freedom.


CHAPTER 45

USE, COINAGE, AND VALUE OF MONEY

§ I. THE PRECIOUS METALS AS MONEY

Money defined and reviewed

1. Money we have defined as a material means of payment and medium of exchange, generally accepted and passing from hand to hand. The origin and function of money were set forth in the study of capital. The subject must now be approached from a different side and with the two-fold purpose of seeing whether there is anything peculiar in the relation of money to the general problem of value, and what is the influence of the action of the state on the value of money. The definition of money implies several ideas. First, the words "generally accepted means of payment" imply that money, as something bearing the stamp of social approval, has a peculiar social character, is not an ordinary good. Second, the definition implies that money itself must be a thing having value, otherwise it could not serve as a medium of exchange. Exchange means the taking and giving of things of value. Money is, therefore, not merely an order for goods, as a card or paper requesting payment; it is itself a thing of value, though this value may be due solely to its possessing the money function. This point is one of the most difficult in the subject. Third, the definition implies that money is a material thing. The telegram when transferring an order for the payment of money, the spoken word, the promise to pay, etc., are not money. Fourth, it implies that money passes from hand to hand, is a thing that can be handled, and is or can be bodily transported.

1. We define money as a tangible means of payment and a medium of exchange that is generally accepted and goes from person to person. The origin and function of money were discussed in the study of capital. Now, we need to approach the topic from a different angle, focusing on two main questions: Is there anything unique about the relationship between money and the broader issue of value? And how does government action influence the value of money? The definition of money contains several ideas. First, the phrase "generally accepted means of payment" indicates that money, as something recognized by society, has a distinct social character; it’s not just a regular commodity. Second, this definition suggests that money itself must have value; otherwise, it couldn't act as a medium of exchange. Exchange involves giving and receiving things of value. Therefore, money is more than just an order for goods, like a card or a paper requesting payment; it is itself valuable, even if that value arises solely from its role as money. This aspect is one of the most complex in the topic. Third, the definition indicates that money is a physical item. A telegram transferring payment instructions, a spoken word, or a promise to pay, etc., are not considered money. Fourth, it implies that money is something that changes hands, is tangible, and can be physically moved.

Difficulty in applying the definition

The application of the definition is not always easy, for money shades off into other things that serve the same purpose and are related in nature. Even special students differ as to the border-line of the concept, but as to the general nature of money there is essential agreement. In many problems it appears to be at the same time like and unlike other things of value, and just wherein lies the difference often is difficult to determine. The use of money is of such social importance, and it touches so many practical interests, that it raises many questions of a political and ethical nature. There are perhaps more popular errors on this than on any other one subject in economics. Yet the general principles of money are as fully understood and as firmly established as any parts of economics.

The application of the definition isn’t always straightforward, as money overlaps with other things that serve similar purposes and are related in nature. Even experts disagree on the boundaries of the concept, but there is a fundamental agreement on the general nature of money. In many cases, it seems both similar to and different from other valuable things, and pinpointing exactly where the difference lies can be tough. The use of money is so socially significant and intersects with many practical interests that it brings up numerous political and ethical questions. There are probably more misconceptions about this topic than any other in economics. Still, the basic principles of money are well understood and as firmly established as any other areas within economics.

Standard, or primary, money
Gold-using countries

2. The precious metals, gold and silver, are the standard, or primary, moneys in the world to-day. Primary, typical, standard money is the unit in which the value of the money of a country is expressed, no matter what its form is; the standard is a certain weight and fineness of a particular metal. Coins of this standard are called full, or real, money by some writers who deny the title of money to everything else. It has been shown before that there has been an evolution in the use of money. The more efficient forms, gold and silver, have competed with copper, iron, tin, cattle, salt, tobacco. In this contest silver had proved itself a few centuries ago to be the fittest medium of exchange, but in the last century gold has, among the leading nations, been displacing silver rapidly. In a higher degree than any other material, gold has the qualities of a good standard money in rich and industrially developed communities. The gold-using countries to-day are those of the western world. England for perhaps two centuries practically has had gold as its standard money; the United States since 1834 (except for the period of paper money from 1862 to 1879); France since about the year 1855, at which time she shifted from silver under the working of the bimetallic law; and Germany, then[Pg 433] more backward industrially, since 1873. Australia and Japan have reached that result only within the last few years, and Italy, Russia, India, Mexico—even China and other Oriental countries—are striving to attain it.

2. Gold and silver are the primary forms of money in the world today. Primary or standard money is the unit in which a country's money is valued, regardless of its form; the standard represents a specific weight and purity of a certain metal. Some writers refer to coins of this standard as full or real money, denying the title of money to everything else. It has been previously established that money has evolved over time. The more effective forms, gold and silver, have competed against copper, iron, tin, cattle, salt, and tobacco. A few centuries ago, silver was recognized as the best medium of exchange, but in the last century, gold has quickly replaced silver among leading nations. Gold possesses qualities that make it an excellent standard for money in wealthy, industrially advanced societies. Today, the countries using gold as their standard are primarily in the western world. England has relied on gold as its standard money for about two centuries; the United States since 1834 (except for the period of paper money from 1862 to 1879); France since around 1855, when it switched from silver due to the bimetallic law; and Germany, which was less industrialized at that time, since 1873. Australia and Japan have only achieved this in the last few years, while Italy, Russia, India, Mexico—along with China and other Eastern countries—are working towards this goal.

Subordinate kinds of money

In all these countries other kinds of money are used side by side with gold and silver. The actual money consists of a wide and confusing variety: silver, nickel, copper, paper in various forms and issued by various authorities. But among all the kinds, either gold or silver is found standing preëminent and in a peculiar position. The difficulties of the money problem must be attacked at the point of standard money where it is nearest to ordinary value problems and is less complicated than when the various money substitutes are included. Most of the fallacies regarding money have arisen not about standard money, but about paper and light-weight silver.

In all these countries, other types of money are used alongside gold and silver. The actual currency consists of a wide and confusing mix: silver, nickel, copper, and several forms of paper issued by different authorities. However, among all these types, either gold or silver holds a special status. The challenges of the money issue should be approached from the angle of standard money, where it is closest to regular value issues and is simpler than when all the different money substitutes are considered. Most of the misconceptions about money have not come from standard money, but from paper and lightweight silver.

Coinage defined

3. Coinage is the act of shaping and marking a piece of metal to be used as money so as to indicate its weight and fineness. The precious metals can and do circulate as money without coinage. Any other mark equally plain and equally recognizable serves for many purposes just as well as the government stamp on the standard metal. The use of metals in antiquity was without coinage, by weight and test of fineness. In backward countries to-day most payments are made by weight. International payments are made by means of gold ingots that bear the mark of some well-known banking-house, and for that purpose gold bullion is money without the coiner's stamp. But for most uses government coinage has marked advantages. It is far more convenient for the average citizen to handle coins uniform in size and design than the diverse coins that would be put out by private enterprisers.

3. Coinage is the process of shaping and marking a piece of metal to be used as money to indicate its weight and purity. Precious metals can and do act as money without being coined. Any other clear and recognizable mark works just as well for various purposes as the government's stamp on standard metal. In ancient times, metals were used without coinage, based on weight and purity tests. In less developed countries today, most transactions are done by weight. International payments are made with gold bars that have the mark of a reputable bank, meaning gold bullion acts as money even without a coin maker's stamp. However, for everyday use, government coinage has significant advantages. It's much more convenient for the average person to deal with coins that have a uniform size and design rather than a mix of coins produced by private companies.

Technical features of coinage

An established rate of fineness insuring uniform quality is a great convenience. In the United States all gold and silver coins are nine tenths fine; in Great Britain, eleven twelfths. The established weight of the gold dollar in the[Pg 434] United States is twenty-three and twenty-two hundredths grains of fine gold or twenty-five and eight tenths grains of standard gold. The limit of tolerance is the variation either above or below the standard weight or fineness that a coin is allowed to have when it leaves the mint. The par of exchange between standard coins of different countries is the expression of the ratio of fine gold in them. Thus the par of exchange between the American dollar and the English sovereign (the "pound") is four and eighty-six and two third hundredths, that is, four and eighty-six and two third hundredths dollars contain the same amount of gold as an English gold sovereign. The embossed design, milled or lettered edges, and other similar devices are merely to make the coins easily recognizable and difficult to counterfeit.

An established level of purity that ensures consistent quality is really helpful. In the United States, all gold and silver coins are 90% pure; in Great Britain, they are 92% pure. The designated weight of the gold dollar in the [Pg 434] United States is 23.22 grains of pure gold or 25.8 grains of standard gold. The tolerance limit is the acceptable variation above or below the standard weight or purity that a coin can have when it leaves the mint. The exchange rate between standard coins from different countries reflects the ratio of pure gold they contain. So, the exchange rate between the American dollar and the British sovereign (the "pound") is 4.86 and two-thirds, meaning that 4.86 and two-thirds dollars contain the same amount of gold as a British gold sovereign. The embossed designs, milled edges, and other similar features are just to make the coins easy to recognize and hard to counterfeit.

Seigniorage defined

4. Seigniorage is the right the ruler or state has to charge for coinage, or it is the charge made for coinage. Coinage as a function of great importance politically as well as economically was early exercised by governments or rulers. The prince, king, or emperor stamped his own device or portrait upon the coin; hence the term seigniorage from seignior (meaning lord or ruler). The right to issue money came to be one of the most essential prerogatives of sovereignty. Coinage is rarely without charge, and often has been a source of revenue to the ruler. In the Middle Ages this right was frequently exercised by princes for their selfish advantage to the injury and unsettling of trade.

4. Seigniorage is the right that a ruler or state has to charge for coin production, or it’s the fee imposed for creating coins. Coin production, which is significant both politically and economically, has historically been managed by governments or rulers. The prince, king, or emperor would put their personal emblem or portrait on the coins; this is where the term seigniorage comes from, derived from seignior (which means lord or ruler). The authority to create money became one of the most crucial powers of sovereignty. Coin production is rarely free, and it has often served as a source of income for the ruler. In the Middle Ages, this right was often exploited by princes for their own benefit, leading to negative impacts and disruption in trade.

Free or gratuitous coinage

When no charge is made for coinage, the coinage is said to be gratuitous. Coinage is said to be free if the subject or citizen can take bullion to the mint whenever he pleases, paying the usual seigniorage. Coinage is limited if the government or ruler determines when coinage is to take place. Thus, coinage may be both free and gratuitous, when citizens are allowed to bring bullion whenever they please and have it converted into coins without charge or deduction. But coinage is free without being gratuitous when any citizen[Pg 435] may bring metal to the mint, whenever he chooses, to be coined subject to the seigniorage charge.

When there’s no fee for coinage, it’s called gratuitous. Coinage is considered free if a person can bring gold or silver to the mint whenever they want, paying the usual seigniorage fee. Coinage is limited if the government decides when it’s done. Therefore, coinage can be both free and gratuitous when citizens can bring their metal anytime and have it turned into coins at no cost. However, coinage can be free without being gratuitous when any citizen[Pg 435] can bring metal to the mint whenever they want, but must pay the seigniorage fee.

Money value under free coinage

5. Where coinage is free and gratuitous the coin is worth the same as the bullion that is in it. This evidently and necessarily must be near the truth if the citizens exercise their right. They will not long keep metal uncoined in their possession when it is worth more in the form of money, nor will they long keep money from the melting-pot when it is worth more as bullion. Yet there may be a slight disparity between the bullion and the money values before the metal is converted into coin or the coin melted down into metal. A motive for action must exist before either change will be made; but a thing cannot have considerably different values in two different uses at the same moment.

5. When coinage is free and without charge, the coin is worth the same as the metal it contains. This must be pretty close to the truth if people exercise their right. They won't hold onto uncoined metal for long if it's worth more as money, and they won't keep money instead of melting it down if it's worth more as raw metal. However, there might be a small difference between the values of the metal and the money before the metal is turned into coins or the coins are melted back down. There needs to be a reason for action before either change occurs; but something can't have significantly different values for two different purposes at the same time.

Adjustment of supply to value

There is here no special problem of value. The value of gold as bullion and money is fixed by marginal demand. The several uses of gold are constantly competing for it: its uses for rings, pens, ornaments, championship cups, photography, dentistry, delicate instruments, and as a circulating medium. If the metal becomes worth more in one use, its amount there is increased and correspondingly diminished in the others. The supply likewise is influenced by changes in price. Gold-mining is one among various industries to which men may apply their labor and capital. Some mines are superior, others average, others marginal which it barely pays to work. There is, therefore, a rise and fall of the margin of production with change in price and change in cost of production. If at a given moment, when it barely pays to work a mine, gold becomes worth less, that mine will go out of use. As gold rises, some mines that did not pay before, come into use. A similar variation has been noted in the case of marginal land, marginal factories, marginal forges, and marginal agents of every kind.

There isn't a specific issue of value here. The value of gold as bullion and money is determined by marginal demand. Its various uses—like for rings, pens, jewelry, trophies, photography, dentistry, delicate instruments, and as currency—are constantly competing for it. If gold becomes more valuable for one use, the amount used for that purpose increases, while it decreases in others. The supply is also affected by price changes. Gold mining is just one of the many industries where people can invest their labor and capital. Some mines are high-quality, some are average, and others are marginal, where it's barely profitable to operate. Therefore, the profitability of production fluctuates with changes in price and production costs. If, at any given time, a mine is barely operating and gold prices drop, that mine will be shut down. Conversely, as gold prices rise, some mines that were previously unprofitable start being worked. A similar trend has been observed with marginal land, marginal factories, marginal forges, and marginal resources of all types.

"What is a dollar?"

The question was once asked in Parliament, "What is a pound?" and a good question to ask in beginning the study of money is, "What is a dollar?" The answer, so far as it[Pg 436] refers to the standard money, is: a dollar is a convenient name applied to twenty-three and twenty-two hundredths grains of fine gold or twenty-five and eight tenths grains of standard fineness. The exchange value of gold varies in different places and conditions, but the name remains the same. A dollar exchanges for more wheat in Dakota than in New York or for more iron in Pittsburg than in Oregon, yet it is sometimes asserted that the value is always the same because the name is always the same. The fallacy of this may be seen in the equivalent expression that twenty-three and twenty-two hundredths grains of gold have the same value always and under all circumstances.

The question was once asked in Parliament, "What is a pound?" and a good question to start studying money is, "What is a dollar?" The answer, as far as the standard money is concerned, is: a dollar is a convenient name for twenty-three point twenty-two grains of fine gold or twenty-five point eight grains of standard fineness. The exchange value of gold changes depending on location and conditions, but the name stays the same. A dollar buys more wheat in Dakota than in New York or more iron in Pittsburgh than in Oregon, yet it’s sometimes said that the value is always the same just because the name is the same. The flaw in this idea is clear when we say that twenty-three point twenty-two grains of gold have the same value always and in all situations.

The problem of the bullion value of money metal, under gratuitous coinage, presents no special difficulties. The ordinary theory of value applies to it. The difficulties of the money question begin at the point where the money value is seen to diverge from, and depend on, something else than the value of the bullion. Yet in the principles just discussed are found a firm foundation for any further study of the question.

The issue of the bullion value of money metal, when it comes to free coinage, isn't really complicated. The standard theory of value applies here. The challenges related to money arise when we notice that the money value differs from and relies on factors other than the bullion value. However, the principles we've just talked about provide a solid basis for any further exploration of the topic.

§ II. THE QUANTITY THEORY OF MONEY

The money use

1. The fundamental use that money serves is to apportion incomes of goods so as to make them yield the maximum gratification. Money first increases utility by increasing the ease with which exchange takes place. Like any tool or agent, it is valued for what it does or helps to do. But further, it enhances the sum of enjoyments by the division of goods into proper quantities, making them available at the best time. It follows from the principle of diminishing utility that the particular time at which goods are available for wants has an essential bearing on their value. A hundred loaves of bread in the hands of a single individual would mold long before they could be consumed. Money enables men in society to acquire these hundred loaves in a series so that they[Pg 437] can be used when most needed. Money is the most successful device man has ever discovered for distributing the supplies of a journey along its course, and the goods of daily need over a period of time. The use of money as a storehouse of value is merely an extreme case of keeping things for the future when they will have a greater gratifying power.

1. The main purpose of money is to distribute the income from goods in a way that maximizes satisfaction. Money first increases utility by making exchanges easier. Like any tool, its value comes from what it does or helps to accomplish. Additionally, it boosts overall enjoyment by dividing goods into appropriate amounts, making them available at the right time. According to the principle of diminishing utility, the timing of when goods are available for needs significantly affects their value. A hundred loaves of bread in the hands of one person would spoil before they could be eaten. Money allows people in society to acquire those hundred loaves gradually so that they[Pg 437] can be used when they're most needed. Money is the most effective method humans have ever created for distributing resources along a journey and managing everyday goods over time. Using money as a way to store value is simply an extreme example of saving for the future when those resources will provide more satisfaction.

Concept of the money demand
Variation in the average

The fact that money is essentially a valuable good kept on hand as the best possible provision against emergencies points to the essential nature of the money demand. Money is sought, in order to form a cash reserve, up to a point where the loss from keeping it balances the probable gain. The money use is subject to the law of diminishing utility; beyond a certain point its added convenience is purchased at too great cost. Every man may be thought of as having an average, or usual, money demand, which is that proportion of his income that gives him more utility retained in money form than if at once expended. A man with an income and expenditure of fifty dollars a month paid monthly has use ordinarily for no more than fifty dollars as his cash reserve. While under ordinary circumstances this is his maximum demand, various circumstances may diminish it. If his expenses are distributed in two equal parts (the one on pay-day, the other thirty days later) his average money demand is twenty-five dollars, not fifty dollars. If most of his purchasing is done at the beginning of the month, his average money demand may be perhaps ten dollars. Many a workman purchases on credit, spends his fifty dollars within an hour after he receives it, and goes without money for the rest of the month. The average demand of a community for money required as a reserve is affected by the methods of doing business. With a given method of use a reduction in the supply of money results in loss of time and waste of effort; an increase in the supply results in a lowering of its value relative to other things. In either case the equilibrium of the marginal utilities of income must be restored. The[Pg 438] thought of an average, rational, money demand relative to money income is the fundamental requisite for clear thinking on the question of money, but to grasp this thought there is needed a certain power of scientific imagination lacking in some minds.

The idea that money is basically a valuable asset we keep on hand as the best safeguard against emergencies highlights the core nature of money demand. People seek money to build a cash reserve until the loss from holding it outweighs the potential benefits. The usefulness of money follows the principle of diminishing returns; after a certain point, the extra convenience it provides comes at too high a cost. Each person can be seen as having an average, or typical, money demand, which is the portion of their income that gives them more satisfaction when kept in cash rather than spent immediately. For example, someone with a monthly income and expenses of fifty dollars, paid every month, typically has no more need for cash than that amount in reserve. While this is usually the maximum, various situations can lower it. If their expenses are split into two equal parts (one on payday and the other thirty days later), their average money demand is twenty-five dollars, not fifty. If most of their shopping happens at the beginning of the month, their average demand might even drop to around ten dollars. Many workers buy on credit, spend their fifty dollars within an hour of getting it, and then go without any money for the rest of the month. The overall demand in a community for money held as a reserve is influenced by the way business is conducted. With a specific method of use, a decrease in money supply leads to lost time and wasted effort, while an increase lowers its value compared to other goods. In both cases, the balance of marginal utilities from income needs to be restored. The thought of an average, rational money demand in relation to money income is essential for clear understanding of monetary issues, but grasping this concept requires a certain level of scientific imagination that some individuals may lack.

The quantity theory of money

2. The quantity theory of money is that, other things being equal, the value of money falls as its quantity increases, and vice versa. This is an abstract statement of a concrete and difficult problem. The phrase "other things being equal" betokens the statement of a tendency where there are several unknown factors. In recent discussion the quantity theory of money has been questioned by some critics; yet it is held by most economists to be merely the general law of value as applied to money. There are three sets of facts to be brought into relationship with each other in the quantity theory: (1) amount of business or exchanges to be effected; (2) the methods by which this is done; (3) the amount of money available to do it. According to the quantity theory we must expect that when conditions (1) and (2) remain fixed, the value of money will vary inversely as its quantity. This conclusion follows from the conception of the money demand as the value of circulating medium that bears an average proportion to the value of goods exchanged.

2. The quantity theory of money states that, all other things being equal, the value of money decreases as its quantity increases, and vice versa. This is an abstract statement about a concrete and complex issue. The phrase "all other things being equal" indicates a tendency where there are multiple unknown factors. In recent discussions, some critics have questioned the quantity theory of money; however, most economists still consider it to be simply the general law of value as it applies to money. There are three sets of facts that need to be related to each other in the quantity theory: (1) the amount of business or exchanges that need to be made; (2) the methods used to make these exchanges; (3) the amount of money available to facilitate them. According to the quantity theory, we should expect that when conditions (1) and (2) remain constant, the value of money will vary inversely with its quantity. This conclusion stems from the idea that the demand for money is the value of the circulating medium that maintains an average relationship to the value of goods exchanged.

Example of its application

Let us consider various conditions. When a number of men, by reason of increasing gold supplies, get larger stocks of money than they have had, the former proportion between their money incomes and their money is altered. In reducing their stock of money by buying goods they bid up the prices of goods until the total value of goods exchanged again bears the same ratio as before to the total value of money. Taking an extreme case: if twice as many dollars get into circulation in a community, either some few men must have several times as many dollars as before, while others have the same; or every man will have his due proportion, just twice as much as before. The latter, "other[Pg 439] things being equal," must be the logical result after equilibrium has been restored. Is any other result thinkable? Now if prices of goods remained the same as before, there would be twice as great a value of money available to effect exchanges. There is no reason why each should tie up twice as large a proportion of his income in a supply of the medium of exchange. If, however, there is a concerted movement to spend the surplus money, there results a general bidding down of the exchange value of money, a general bidding up of prices of goods. At what point will this movement stop? The rational conclusion must be that "other things being equal" equilibrium will be reëstablished only when the ratio between the value of money and the price of goods becomes the same as before. The money being doubled, prices must be double, and likewise for any other change in quantity.

Let’s look at different circumstances. When a group of people, due to increasing amounts of gold, end up with more cash than they’ve had before, the previous relationship between their money incomes and their cash is changed. As they reduce their amount of cash by purchasing items, they drive up the prices of those goods until the total value of goods exchanged is once again in the same relationship to the total value of money as it was before. In an extreme example: if twice as many dollars circulate in a community, either a few people must have several times more dollars than they did before while others have the same amount, or everyone will have their fair share, just twice as much as before. The latter, "other things being equal," should logically happen once equilibrium is restored. Is there any other possible outcome? If the prices of goods stayed the same as before, there would be twice as much money available for transactions. There’s no reason for each person to keep twice as much of their income in cash for transactions. However, if there’s a coordinated effort to spend the extra money, it would lead to a general decrease in the value of money and a general increase in prices of goods. At what point will this trend end? The logical conclusion must be that "other things being equal," equilibrium will only be restored when the relationship between the value of money and the price of goods returns to what it was before. With the money doubled, prices must also be doubled, and this holds for any other change in quantity.

Objections made to the quantity theory

3. The quantity theory is misunderstood, and is criticized on the ground that the facts oppose it. If but one kind of metal were used as money, and this were coined of uniform weight and fineness, the problem would be comparatively simple. But in fact gold and silver, full-weight and light-weight coins, circulate side by side. More mysterious still, the money in circulation is partly coin and partly paper. How can the quantity theory hold in these conditions? Several objections to the quantity theory are presented. It is said, first, that prices do not vary exactly with the per capita circulation of different countries at a given moment. The per capita circulation in Mexico may be five dollars and in the United States twenty-five dollars, while prices are much less than five times as great here as in Mexico. Secondly, it is said that prices do not vary directly with changes in the amount of money in a given country. There is now perhaps five times as much money per capita in the United States as fifty years ago and yet prices are not five times as high. Thirdly, it is said that credit methods change, and therefore that money does not fix prices. Fourthly, it is said that even if true of primary money the theory fails to apply to actual[Pg 440] conditions with many forms of money in circulation side by side. Fifthly, it is said that there are too many unknown quantities to permit the rule to be used.

3. The quantity theory is often misunderstood and criticized because the facts seem to contradict it. If only one type of metal were used as money, and if it were all minted with a consistent weight and quality, the situation would be relatively straightforward. However, in reality, gold and silver, along with full-weight and light-weight coins, are used simultaneously. Even more confusing, the money in circulation is both coins and paper. How can the quantity theory apply under these circumstances? Several objections to the quantity theory are raised. First, it is claimed that prices do not change in direct correlation with the money supply per person in different countries at the same time. For instance, the per capita money supply in Mexico might be five dollars, while in the United States it's twenty-five dollars, yet prices here are not nearly five times higher than in Mexico. Second, it is argued that prices do not change in direct relation to the amount of money in a country at a given time. Currently, there may be about five times as much money per person in the United States as there was fifty years ago, but prices are not five times as high. Third, it is pointed out that methods of credit change, which means money does not dictate prices. Fourth, even if the theory is accurate for primary money, it fails to apply to actual[Pg 440] situations where various forms of money circulate concurrently. Fifth, it is argued that there are too many unknown variables for the theory to be reliably applied.

The objections examined

4. A reasonable interpretation of the quantity theory makes it a statement of the effect of a change in a single factor. The objections to the quantity theory assume that it is a statement of what occurs under all conditions, instead of what it is, an index to the working of one condition at a time. The foregoing objections need but to be further analyzed to show that in each of them it is not merely the quantity of money, but a number of other factors that differ in each of the propositions. We may note briefly in turn the defects in the arguments of the preceding paragraph.

4. A clear understanding of the quantity theory sees it as a statement about the impact of a change in one single factor. The criticisms of the quantity theory treat it as if it explains what happens under all circumstances, rather than what it actually is: a measure of how one specific condition operates at a time. A deeper analysis of these criticisms reveals that in each case, it’s not just the amount of money that's different, but several other factors that vary in each situation. Let's briefly look at the flaws in the arguments from the previous paragraph.

Not a per capita rule

First, the quantity theory does not remotely imply that prices in different countries differ at a given moment according to the per capita money. In the case of the United States and Mexico not only the amount of exchange per capita but the method of exchange, and the rapidity of the circulation of money differ quite as much, doubtless, as does the per capita circulation. The quantity theory would lead any fairly careful student to a conclusion the exact opposite of that which its critics have twisted from it.

First, the quantity theory doesn’t suggest that prices in different countries are different at any given time based on the per capita money. In the cases of the United States and Mexico, not only the amount of currency exchanged per person but also the method of exchange and the speed of money circulation vary just as much, likely, as the per capita circulation itself. The quantity theory would guide any reasonably attentive student to a conclusion that's the complete opposite of what its critics have misinterpreted from it.

Recognizes the growth of trade

Second, the quantity theory does not imply that during a period of years when a country is changing in a multitude of ways, as in population, methods of industry, modes of exchange and transportation, and in wealth and income, the prices will vary directly either as the absolute or per capita amount of money does. In the light of the quantity theory the inquirer must be led to just the opposite of the ridiculous conclusion imputed to it.

Second, the quantity theory doesn’t suggest that over a number of years, when a country is undergoing numerous changes—like shifts in population, industrial methods, ways of trading and transporting goods, as well as changes in wealth and income—the prices will directly fluctuate in line with either the total or per person amount of money. Based on the quantity theory, the investigator should arrive at the exact opposite of the absurd conclusion attributed to it.

Recognizes use of credit

Third, the theory does not overlook the effect of an increased use of credit, for it fully implies that any such a change, by economizing the use of money, would enable the same amount of money to support a higher scale of prices.

Third, the theory doesn’t ignore the impact of increased credit use; it clearly suggests that any change like this, by reducing the need for cash, would allow the same amount of money to sustain higher price levels.

Not confined to primary money

Fourth, the theory does not overlook the variety of forms, and is not true merely of primary money. However great[Pg 441] this variety, the money demand of individuals and of communities still represents a pretty definite ratio of the value of exchanges effected. If the primary money alone were doubled in quantity, while the various forms of substitute money (smaller coins, bank-notes, government notes, etc.) remained unchanged, the quantity of money as a whole would not be doubled, and according to the theory, prices would not be expected to double. Indeed, in such a case, the method of exchange would be very greatly altered, and the case is fully covered by the statement of the theory.

Fourth, the theory acknowledges the different forms of money and doesn’t only apply to primary money. No matter how significant[Pg 441] this variety is, the money demand from individuals and communities still reflects a pretty clear ratio of the value of the exchanges made. If only the primary money were doubled in amount, while the various forms of substitute money (like smaller coins, banknotes, government notes, etc.) remained the same, the overall quantity of money wouldn’t be doubled, and based on the theory, prices wouldn’t be expected to double either. In fact, in this scenario, the method of exchange would change significantly, which is fully addressed by the theory's statement.

Is a practical rule

Fifth, despite the number of changing factors affecting the methods of exchange, the method of business, etc., the quantity theory is a rule usable at any moment. These various factors change slowly, and the quantity theory answers the question, What change occurs in prices as a result of an increase or decrease of the money in a given community at a given moment? Like the law of gravitation, the law of projectiles, and the statement of the chemical reaction to be expected when adding some substance to a given compound, the theory must be interpreted with practical limitations. When the quantity theory is thus stated and understood, its negation is unthinkable, as is evidenced by the involuntary use made of it constantly by every one of its few critics in explaining the simplest monetary phenomena.

Fifth, even with all the changing factors that affect exchange methods and business practices, the quantity theory is a rule that can be applied at any time. These various factors change slowly, and the quantity theory addresses the question: What changes occur in prices due to an increase or decrease in the amount of money in a community at a specific time? Just like the laws of gravity, projectile motion, and the expected outcomes of adding a substance to a compound, this theory needs to be interpreted with practical limits. Once the quantity theory is clearly stated and understood, it's unimaginable to deny it, as shown by how even its few critics involuntarily rely on it when explaining basic monetary phenomena.

Practical application of the quantity theory
Recent price changes

5. The quantity theory makes intelligible the great and rapid changes in price that have followed sudden changes in the money supply. Inductive demonstration of broadly stated economic principles is difficult, but in no other economic problem is laboratory experiment so nearly possible as in that of money. Many inflations and contractions of the circulating medium have occurred, now in a single country, again in the entire world, and the local or general results have served to exemplify richly the working of the quantity principle. With the scanty yield of silver- and gold-mines in the Middle Ages, prices were low. After the discovery of America, especially in the sixteenth century, quantities of[Pg 442] silver flowed into Europe. The great rise of prices that occurred was explained by the keenest thinkers of that day along the essential lines of the quantity theory, though there were many monetary fallacies current at the time. The experience in England during the Napoleonic wars, when the money of England was inflated and prices rose above those of the Continent, led to the modern formulation of the theory by Ricardo and others. The discovery of gold in California and Australia, in 1848-50, increased the gold supply marvelously, and gold prices rose throughout the world. Between 1870 and 1890 the production of gold fell off greatly while its use as money increased and prices fell. A great increase of gold production has occurred in the period since 1890. In part the rising prices from 1897 to 1902 are explicable as the periodic upswing of confidence and credit, but in part doubtless they are due to the stimulus of increasing gold supplies. These are but a few of many instances in monetary history which, taken together, make an argument of probability in favor of the quantity theory so strong as to constitute practically its inductive proof.

5. The quantity theory explains the large and rapid price changes that follow sudden shifts in the money supply. It's tough to demonstrate broad economic principles through induction, but no other economic issue is as close to being tested in a lab as money is. There have been many instances of inflation and deflation in the money supply, whether in a single country or globally, and the local or global outcomes have vividly illustrated the quantity principle. With the limited output of silver and gold mines in the Middle Ages, prices were low. After America was discovered, especially in the sixteenth century, large amounts of[Pg 442] silver poured into Europe. The significant price increase that followed was explained by the sharpest minds of that time based on the quantity theory, despite many monetary misconceptions that existed then. England's experience during the Napoleonic wars, when the money supply was inflated and prices surpassed those on the Continent, led to the modern formulation of the theory by Ricardo and others. The discovery of gold in California and Australia between 1848 and 1850 greatly boosted the gold supply, causing gold prices to rise worldwide. From 1870 to 1890, gold production significantly declined while its use as money increased, leading to falling prices. A significant increase in gold production has occurred since 1890. The rising prices from 1897 to 1902 can partly be attributed to a periodic surge in confidence and credit, but they are likely also influenced by the rising gold supply. These examples are just a few from monetary history, which together make a compelling argument supporting the quantity theory strong enough to serve as its practical inductive proof.


CHAPTER 46

TOKEN COINAGE AND GOVERNMENT PAPER MONEY

§ I. LIGHT-WEIGHT COINS

Seigniorage and the value of coins
Saturation point for coinage

1. When the number of coins issued is limited properly, a seigniorage charge does not reduce their money value; they are worth more as money than as bullion. The coinage thus far considered has been that of full-weight coins without seigniorage. The question now is, What is the effect of a seigniorage charge on the value of the coin as compared with the bullion that is in it? This is one of the most difficult phases of monetary theory. Two values must be thought of: one the value of the coin as money, the other the value of the bullion in it. When coinage is free and gratuitous, these two values are the same. How can they ever be different? The answer to the question is found in the theory of monopoly value. If the supply of coin is limited by the sole agency of issue, the value can be kept above the cost of production (i.e., in this case the bullion value), the seigniorage being the profit of the government. The limit within which the coinage must be kept is the number of coins that would circulate freely if they were made full weight without a seigniorage charge. This is the "saturation point" of the money demand of the country; it is a certain number of pieces of full-weight metal. If more than that amount gets into circulation it becomes worth less as money than as bullion, and it is melted or exported.

1. When the number of coins issued is kept under control, a seigniorage fee doesn't reduce their monetary value; they're more valuable as currency than as metal. So far, we've discussed full-weight coins without any seigniorage. The question now is: What impact does a seigniorage fee have on the value of the coin compared to the value of the metal it contains? This is one of the toughest areas in monetary theory. We need to consider two values: the value of the coin as currency and the value of the metal inside it. When coinage is freely available and cost-free, these two values are identical. How can they ever differ? The answer lies in the monopoly value theory. If the supply of coins is limited by the exclusive issuing authority, their value can be maintained above the production cost (i.e., in this case, the metal value), with the seigniorage being the profit for the government. The limit for coinage must be the number of coins that would circulate freely if they were made full weight without a seigniorage fee. This is the "saturation point" for the country's money demand; it represents a specific number of full-weight pieces. If more than that amount circulates, it becomes worth less as currency than as metal, leading to it being melted down or sent abroad.

Example of seigniorage value in coins

If this full supply of money at a given moment is 100,000[Pg 444] pieces or dollars, a seigniorage charge of ten per cent. could be made if the number of pieces were not increased above 100,000. The government alone having the right of coinage, the need of money would give the circulating medium a monopoly value. The value of the money would rise until the coin would buy one ninth more bullion than was in it, but if there were any further rise the citizens would begin to take coins to the mint. After the ten per cent. charge was taken out they would receive a coin which, though containing one tenth less bullion, would be worth very nearly the same as the metal taken to the mint. No considerable depreciation could take place unless the volume of business fell off so that less money was needed than at the old standard. In that case there would be no outlet for the excess of coins until they fell to their bullion value, i.e., till they lost the entire value of the seigniorage, the monopoly element in them. Melting or exporting them before that point was reached would cause the loss of whatever element of seigniorage value they contained.

If the total amount of money at a specific time is 100,000[Pg 444] pieces or dollars, a seigniorage fee of ten percent could be applied as long as the number of pieces doesn't increase beyond 100,000. Since only the government has the right to mint coins, the demand for money would give the circulating currency a monopoly value. The value of the money would rise until a coin could buy one-ninth more bullion than it contains, but if the value continued to rise, people would start taking coins to the mint. After the ten percent fee was deducted, they would receive a coin that, while containing one-tenth less bullion, would still be worth nearly the same as the metal they brought to the mint. Significant depreciation wouldn't happen unless the volume of business dropped, meaning less money was needed than before. In that case, there would be no way to use the excess coins until they dropped to their bullion value, meaning they would lose their entire seigniorage value, which is the monopoly aspect of them. Melting or exporting them before reaching that point would result in the loss of whatever seigniorage value they still had.

Example of excess and depreciation of coins

Assuming that the volume of business, or sum of exchanges, remains unchanged, let us consider what will result if the government begins to issue "on its own account." The number of coins might be increased until at the bullion price the total money value were equal to the original 100,000 full-weight coins, at which point exportation would take place. There being nine tenths as much precious metal as before, it would require ten ninths as many pieces, or 111,111 pieces, to have as great a value as the 100,000 had before. At this point there is no further profit to the government in issuing coins of that weight. To make a further profit it must again reduce the amount of pure metal in the coin.

Assuming that the volume of business, or total exchanges, stays the same, let’s look at what happens if the government starts issuing money on its own. The number of coins might be increased until, at the bullion price, the total money value equals the original 100,000 full-weight coins, leading to exports. With only 90% of the precious metal compared to before, it would require 111,111 pieces, or ten-ninths as many, to have the same value as the 100,000 had previously. At this point, there’s no extra profit for the government in issuing coins of that weight. To make more profit, it would have to reduce the amount of pure metal in the coins again.

Medieval examples of depreciation

This is essentially what occurred often throughout the Middle Ages. A ruler debased the quality or reduced the weight of money, but for a time the new coin, having the same money use, circulated as freely as the old coin. If,[Pg 445] as so often happened, the ruler yielded to the temptation to issue more in order to get the profit, the older, heavier coins at once began to go abroad or into the melting-pot. Then occurred a fall in value, mystifying alike to the prince and the people. The reason is now perfectly plain: the number of pieces issued had not been kept within the proper limits, and the coins went down to their bullion value.

This is basically what often happened during the Middle Ages. A ruler would lower the quality or decrease the weight of money, but for a while, the new coins, which served the same purpose, circulated just as easily as the old ones. If, [Pg 445] as frequently occurred, the ruler gave in to the urge to mint more coins for profit, the older, heavier coins quickly left circulation or were melted down. This led to a drop in value, which confused both the ruler and the people. The reason is now quite clear: the number of coins produced was not kept within appropriate limits, causing their value to fall to their bullion value.

Difficulties with full-weight subsidiary coins

2. Subsidiary coins of lighter weight than the standard, if properly limited, will remain in circulation at par. Money to serve all of its purposes must be of different denominations. The amount required of each denomination is determined by the volume of exchanges for which each is most convenient. Each kind of money, as the penny, nickel, dime, has its own peculiar demand and its saturation point. For the smaller denominations the standard metal is not suitable. A gold dollar cannot well be cut into twenty or a hundred pieces. Thus copper, nickel, silver remain in restricted use. When these are issued at their bullion value, difficulties arise; not only are they too heavy, but as they vary in bullion value, some of them become worth more as bullion than as coin, and suddenly disappear from circulation.

2. Coins that are lighter than the standard weight, if properly managed, will stay in circulation at their face value. Money needs to come in different denominations to meet all its purposes. The amount needed for each denomination is based on how often it’s used in transactions. Each type of money, like pennies, nickels, and dimes, has its own specific demand and saturation point. For smaller denominations, standard metal isn't suitable. You can't easily cut a gold dollar into twenty or a hundred pieces. So, copper, nickel, and silver are kept in limited use. When these are issued at their metal value, problems arise; not only are they too heavy, but as their metal value changes, some become worth more as metal than as coins and suddenly drop out of circulation.

Adoption of light-weight minor coins
Theory of light-weight coins

This happened often throughout the Middle Ages and until the nineteenth century. Gold and silver generally were coined at a ratio of weight corresponding exactly to their market ratio at a given moment, and every time the market conditions varied, one kind of the money went out of circulation, and the country was left either without the larger gold coins, or without subsidiary coin, or "small change." At length the plan was hit upon of issuing a limited number of subsidiary coins of less than full bullion value, that is, as "token coins." By this plan there is given to the minor coins a value greater than that of the bullion in them. The small profit made by the government on every penny, nickel, or dime issued, is a seigniorage charge. These minor coins, in somewhat confusing variety,[Pg 446] circulate side by side with full-weight money, their value depending on the monopoly principle. The result of a large issue of any one denomination would be a lowering of its value. In practice their issue is determined by the needs of business and by the requests of citizens for small coins in exchange for standard money. One needing "change" gets it at the bank; when the bank finds its supply falling short it gets more from the government mints. As business increased in 1898, the demand for nickels, dimes, and quarters became unprecedented, and the mints worked night and day to supply them.

This happened often throughout the Middle Ages and lasted until the nineteenth century. Gold and silver were usually minted at a weight ratio that reflected their market value at the time, and whenever market conditions changed, one type of currency would go out of circulation. This left the country either without larger gold coins or without smaller change. Eventually, the idea was developed to issue a limited number of smaller coins that were worth less than their full bullion value, known as "token coins." This meant that these smaller coins had a value greater than the metal in them. The small profit made by the government on each penny, nickel, or dime issued is called a seigniorage charge. These smaller coins, in a somewhat confusing variety,[Pg 446] circulate alongside full-weight money, with their value determined by monopoly principles. If a large amount of any one denomination is issued, its value decreases. In practice, their issuance depends on business needs and citizens’ requests for small change in exchange for standard money. If someone needs change, they get it from the bank; when the bank runs low, it gets more from the government mints. As business increased in 1898, the demand for nickels, dimes, and quarters became unprecedented, and the mints operated around the clock to meet this demand.

Gresham's law

3. Gresham's law of the circulation of coins of different bullion value is: bad money drives out good money. This so-called "law" was stated in these circumstances: England had two kinds of metal money, silver and gold, which were coined at a fixed ratio in weight; and as the market value of the bullion changed, the new full-weight coins of the metal rising in value went out of circulation. The coining of the cheaper metal caused the melting or exporting of the one becoming dearer, and for those purposes the coins containing the most bullion were picked. Likewise full-weight coins disappear whenever money of less bullion value (either because containing more alloy, or because made of a cheaper metal or of paper) is poured into the circulation in large quantities.

3. Gresham's law regarding the circulation of coins with different bullion values is: bad money drives out good money. This so-called "law" was defined in these circumstances: England used two types of metal coins, silver and gold, which were minted at a fixed weight ratio. As the market value of the bullion changed, the new full-weight coins of the metal that was increasing in value went out of circulation. The minting of the cheaper metal led to the melting down or exporting of the one that was becoming more valuable, and for these purposes, the coins with the most bullion were selected. Similarly, full-weight coins vanish whenever money with less bullion value (either because they contain more alloy, are made from a cheaper metal, or are made of paper) is introduced into circulation in large amounts.

Proper interpretation of Gresham's law

Gresham's law needs some explanation, for it is frequently misunderstood. "Bad" money means money that has not the bullion value equal to its money value, money that is either debased in quality or light in weight. But not every piece of bad money will drive out every piece of good money. If that were so, a single bad penny would drive out of circulation all the gold. The law applies only under certain conditions. The "good" will leave the country only if the total amount of money in circulation is in excess of what would be needed if all were of full weight or best quality. Paradoxically speaking, if there is not too much of the bad[Pg 447] money, it is just as good as the good money. The good money may not leave the country. It may be hoarded, or be picked out by banks and savings-institutions to retain as their reserve, or it may be melted for use in the arts. Gresham's "law" is thus a practical precept: keep the amount of token or light-weight coin limited to the field of its peculiar use, or it will cause the other forms, the fuller weight money, to leave for a better market. That better market may be the melting-pot or it may be a foreign country.

Gresham's law needs some clarification because it's often misunderstood. "Bad" money refers to currency that doesn't have a bullion value equal to its face value, meaning it’s either of lower quality or lighter in weight. However, not every piece of bad money will push out every piece of good money. If that were the case, a single bad penny could eliminate all the gold from circulation. The law only applies under specific conditions. Good money will leave the country only if the total amount of money in circulation exceeds what would be necessary if everything had full weight or top quality. Ironically, if there isn’t too much bad money, it’s just as acceptable as good money. Good money might stay in the country, be hoarded, be chosen by banks and savings institutions to hold as reserves, or be melted down for artistic use. Gresham's "law" is essentially a practical guideline: keep the amount of token or lightweight coins limited to their specific purpose, or they will drive out the other forms of money, the heavier coins, seeking a better market. That better market could be a melting pot or a foreign country.

§ II. PAPER MONEY EXPERIMENTS

Nature of paper money
The legal-tender quality

1. Government paper money may be defined as money for which a seigniorage of one hundred per cent. is charged. The order in the study of the money question is from seigniorage to paper money, because paper money embodies the principle of seigniorage in its extremest form. The issue of paper money grew out of the practice of debasing metal. The gain of seigniorage from paper money is greater and is just as easily secured. Government paper money is sometimes called "political money," in contrast with money whose value rests on the value of its material. In this sense, however, all coins containing an element of seigniorage, or monopoly value, are to that degree "political" money. The typical paper money is irredeemable, that is, it cannot be turned into bullion money on demand. It was simply put into circulation with the legal-tender quality. The "legal-tender" quality is the declaration of the government that the paper money must be accepted by citizens as a legal discharge for debts due them. The object of this is to compel people to use it as money whether they will or not. The purpose of the government in thus employing its power over the circulating medium is usually to profit, that is, to secure the value of the seigniorage for public purposes. Paper money differs from bank-notes in that it does not depend for its redemption on the credit of the issuer. It[Pg 448] differs from bonds in that its value is not based on the interest it yields, but solely on its money uses. The issue of paper money may save the government the payment of interest on an equal amount of bonds. The promise to receive paper money in payment for taxes or for public lands, may help to maintain the value of the notes by reducing their quantity, but nothing short of prompt exchange for standard coins makes them truly redeemable.

1. Government paper money can be defined as money with a seigniorage of one hundred percent. In studying the money issue, we start with seigniorage and move to paper money because paper money represents the idea of seigniorage in its most extreme form. The creation of paper money came from the practice of reducing the value of metal currency. The profit from seigniorage with paper money is higher and is just as easily obtained. Government paper money is sometimes referred to as "political money," in contrast to money that derives its value from the value of its material. In this sense, however, all coins that have an element of seigniorage or monopoly value can be considered "political" money to some extent. Typical paper money is irredeemable, meaning it cannot be exchanged for bullion money on demand. It was simply released into circulation with legal-tender status. The "legal-tender" status is the government’s declaration that citizens must accept the paper money as a valid payment for debts owed to them. The goal of this is to force people to use it as money whether they want to or not. The government uses its power over the circulating medium primarily to profit, specifically to secure the value of the seigniorage for public purposes. Paper money is different from banknotes in that it does not rely on the creditworthiness of the issuer for its redemption. It[Pg 448] differs from bonds in that its value is not based on the interest it generates, but solely on its use as money. Issuing paper money may spare the government from paying interest on an equivalent amount of bonds. Promising to accept paper money for taxes or public lands may help maintain the value of the notes by reducing their supply, but nothing short of immediate exchange for standard coins makes them truly redeemable.

Examples of paper money in the eighteenth century

2. The most notable examples of paper money in the eighteenth century were the American colonial currencies, the continental notes, and the French assignats. In all the American colonies before the Revolution notes or bills of credit were issued which were in most cases legal tender. Without exception they were issued in large amounts and without exception they depreciated. Parliament forbade the issues, but to no effect. The continental notes were issued by the Continental Congress in the first year of the war (1775), and for the next five years. The object at first was to anticipate taxes, and it was expected that the states would redeem and destroy the notes, but this was not done. The notes passed at par for a time, but depreciated rapidly as their number increased. The country had less than $10,000,000 of coin before the war, and when, in 1780, over $200,000,000 of notes were in circulation they were completely discredited; hence the phrase "not worth a continental." Specie quickly came back into use. A few years later the leaders of the French Revolution, failing to learn the lesson of the American experience, issued, on the security of land, notes called assignats in such enormous quantities that they became worth no more than the paper on which they were printed. In a figurative sense they may be said to have fallen to their "bullion" value.

2. The most famous examples of paper money in the eighteenth century were the American colonial currencies, the Continental notes, and the French assignats. In all the American colonies before the Revolution, notes or bills of credit were issued that were mostly legal tender. They were all issued in large amounts and they all lost value. Parliament tried to stop the issues, but it didn’t work. The Continental notes were issued by the Continental Congress in the first year of the war (1775) and for the next five years. The initial goal was to advance taxes, and it was expected that the states would redeem and destroy the notes, but that didn’t happen. The notes were worth their full value for a time but rapidly lost value as their quantity increased. The country had less than $10 million in coins before the war, and when, in 1780, over $200 million in notes were in circulation, they completely lost credibility; hence the phrase "not worth a continental." Specie quickly returned to use. A few years later, the leaders of the French Revolution, not learning from the American experience, issued notes called assignats backed by land in such massive quantities that they became worth no more than the paper they were printed on. In a figurative sense, they may be said to have dropped to their "bullion" value.

More recent examples of paper money

3. Notable examples of paper money in the nineteenth century were the English bank-notes in the years 1797-1820, and the American greenbacks, 1862-79. There have been many other examples. During the Franco-Prussian[Pg 449] War, France, through the medium of its great state bank, issued notes which only slightly depreciated. At the present time many countries—Russia, Austria, Portugal, Italy, all the South American republics—have depreciated paper currencies. But the English bank restriction of 1797-1820 is notable because it gave rise to the controversy which did most to develop the modern theory of the subject. The Bank of England was forbidden to redeem its notes in coin because the government wished to borrow all the coin the bank had. The result was the issue of a large amount of bank money not subject to the ordinary rule of redemption on demand. It was virtually government paper money. The notes depreciated and drove gold out of circulation, and not until 1820 was there a return to specie payments.

3. Notable examples of paper money in the nineteenth century were the English banknotes from 1797 to 1820, and the American greenbacks from 1862 to 1879. There have been many other examples. During the Franco-Prussian[Pg 449] War, France, through its major state bank, issued notes that only slightly lost value. Today, many countries—Russia, Austria, Portugal, Italy, and all the South American republics—have seen their paper currencies depreciate. However, the English bank restriction from 1797 to 1820 is significant because it sparked the debate that contributed most to the development of modern economic theory on the topic. The Bank of England was prevented from exchanging its notes for coins because the government needed to borrow all the coins the bank had. As a result, a large amount of bank money was issued that didn’t follow the usual rule of being redeemable on demand. It was basically government paper money. The notes lost value and caused gold to disappear from circulation, and it wasn’t until 1820 that they returned to coin payments.

The greenbacks

The United States under the constitution did not try paper money till 1862 when paper notes (called greenbacks, because of the color of ink with which the reverse side was printed) were issued as a war measure to the amount of about $450,000,000. Other interest-bearing notes were issued with legal-tender quality and circulated as money to some extent. Greenbacks depreciated in terms of gold, and gold rose in price until, in June, 1864, it sold at two hundred and eighty a hundred. Fourteen years elapsed after the war before these notes rose to par, in terms of gold.

The United States didn't experiment with paper money under the constitution until 1862, when paper notes (called greenbacks because of the ink color on the back) were issued as a war measure totaling about $450 million. Other interest-bearing notes were also issued with legal-tender status and circulated as money to some degree. Greenbacks lost value compared to gold, and gold prices increased until, in June 1864, it reached $280 per hundred. It took fourteen years after the war for these notes to regain their value relative to gold.

Evil effects of political money

4. Paper-money issues usually have had injurious effects on general industry. The purpose of the issue of paper money is generally to relieve the financial necessities of the government. It is a costly expedient, resorted to only in desperate extremities. A result usually unintended is the derangement of business and of the existing distribution of incomes. The rapid and unpredictable changes in prices give opportunity for speculative profits, but most legitimate business is injured. This incidental effect on debts and industry becomes the main motive of some citizens in advocating the issue. It is peculiarly liable to be the subject of political intrigue and of popular misunderstanding.

4. Paper money usually has harmful effects on overall industry. The main goal of issuing paper money is typically to address the financial needs of the government. It's an expensive solution, used only in dire situations. An often unintended consequence is the disruption of business and the current distribution of incomes. The rapid and unpredictable shifts in prices create opportunities for speculative profits, but most legitimate businesses suffer. This side effect on debts and industry becomes the primary reason some people support the issuance. It is particularly prone to being a topic of political manipulation and public misunderstanding.

§ III. THEORIES OF POLITICAL MONEY

Commodity-money theory

1. The commodity-money theorists declare that government is powerless to influence value, or to impart value to paper by law. There are two extreme views regarding the nature of paper money, and a third which endeavors to find the truth between these two. First is that of the commodity-money theorists, or the cost-of-production theorists, who will not admit that there is any other basis for the value of money than the cost of the material that is in it. Money made of paper, on a printing press, has a cost almost negligibly small, and, therefore, they say it can have no value. The fact that it does circulate, and is treated as if it had value, is explained by the commodity theorists as follows: While the paper note is a mere promise to pay, with no value in itself, it is accepted because of the hope of its redemption, just as is any private note. Depreciation in this view is due to loss of confidence; the rise toward par measures the hope of repayment. Such a view overlooks the feature in which paper money differs from ordinary credit paper. The value of one's promise to pay depends on his reputation and his resources; the resources constitute the basis of value. Bonds have value because they yield interest and are payable at a definite time in standard money. But paper money, lacking this basis for its value, has another basis in its money use, in its power to buy goods. The money demand in connection with the monopoly power of government over the money supply, furnishes a satisfactory logical explanation of the value of paper money.

1. Commodity-money theorists argue that the government can't affect value or give value to paper through legislation. There are two extreme opinions on paper money, plus a third that seeks to find a middle ground. The first is from the commodity-money theorists, or cost-of-production theorists, who assert that the only basis for money's value is the cost of the material it contains. Paper money, printed on a press, costs almost nothing to produce, so they argue it must have no value. They explain its use and acceptance as circulating currency by saying that while a paper note is just a promise to pay and has no intrinsic value, it’s accepted because people hope it can be redeemed, similar to any personal note. In this view, depreciation happens because of a loss of confidence, while the climb back to face value reflects the hope of repayment. This perspective neglects how paper money is different from regular credit notes. The value of someone’s promise to pay relies on their reputation and resources; those resources form the foundation of value. Bonds hold value because they earn interest and are payable at a specific time in standard currency. However, paper money, which doesn’t have that kind of backing for its value, has another source of value tied to its use as money and its ability to purchase goods. The demand for money, combined with the government’s control over the money supply, provides a convincing logical explanation for the value of paper money.

Fiat-money theory

2. The fiat-money advocates assert that government has unlimited power to maintain the value of paper money by conferring upon it the legal-tender quality. The meaning of fiat is "let there be," and the fiat-money advocates believe that the government has but to say, "let it be money," to invest paper with value. The typical fiat advocates in the[Pg 451] United States were the "Greenbackers," those voters who wished to retain the paper money issued in the Civil War, and to increase its amount greatly. They saw in paper money an unlimited source of income to the government. They proposed the payment of the national debt, the support of the government without taxes, and the loan of unlimited money without interest to citizens. All might live in luxury if the extreme fiat-money theorists could realize their dream. There are still some survivors of this faith in the power of the government fiat. The depreciation that has taken place in every case where government notes have been issued, they declare to be due to a too mild enforcement of the law of legal tender. To them the fact that paper money may circulate for a time at par appears a reason why it always should. They do not admit that there is a saturation point in the use of money, and that its use is still further limited by the fear of larger issues. They do not see that the ultimate basis of the value of paper money is economic,—is in its money use, not in the fiat of the government.

2. The supporters of fiat money argue that the government has unlimited power to maintain the value of paper money by giving it the status of legal tender. The term fiat means "let there be," and these advocates believe that the government just needs to say, "let it be money," to give paper its value. The typical supporters of fiat money in the[Pg 451] United States were the "Greenbackers," those voters who wanted to keep the paper money issued during the Civil War and to greatly increase its supply. They viewed paper money as an endless source of income for the government. They suggested paying off the national debt, supporting the government without taxes, and lending unlimited money without interest to citizens. Everyone could enjoy a life of luxury if the extreme fiat-money theorists could achieve their vision. There are still some who hold on to this belief in the government's fiat power. They claim that the depreciation seen every time government notes are issued is due to a too lenient enforcement of the law of legal tender. To them, the fact that paper money can circulate at par for a time seems like a reason why it should always do so. They refuse to accept that there's a saturation point in the use of money and that its use is further limited by the fear of larger issuances. They don't recognize that the real basis for the value of paper money is economic—it lies in its utility as money, not in the government’s fiat.

Theoretical possibility of a good paper money

3. A sound theory of paper money makes it a special case of monopoly value. It has been seen that the power of almost every monopoly over price is relative, not absolute. As the power of a great private corporation over the price of its product is limited, so is that of the government over the value of political money. The money use is the source of value to the paper notes. Business conditions remaining unchanged, the limit of possible issue without depreciation is the number of units in circulation before the paper money was issued, the saturation point of full-weight and full-value coins. Because governments generally have not stopped at that point, paper money has depreciated. Popular error and selfish interests force legislation beyond the reasonable limit. In a few cases only have there been public integrity and courage enough to retrace the steps before great harm resulted. It is principally this lack of control that prevents paper money from being a good circulating medium.

3. A solid theory of paper money treats it as a specific example of monopoly value. It's understood that the control of almost any monopoly over pricing is relative rather than absolute. Just as a large private corporation's control over the price of its product has limits, so does the government's control over the value of political money. The value of paper notes comes from their use as money. If business conditions remain the same, the maximum amount of paper money that can be issued without losing value is the number of units in circulation before the paper money was introduced, which is the saturation point of full-weight and full-value coins. Because governments often go beyond that limit, paper money has depreciated. Common misconceptions and self-interest push legislation past reasonable limits. In only a few instances have there been enough public integrity and courage to reverse decisions before significant damage was done. It's mainly this lack of oversight that stops paper money from being an effective medium of exchange.

Influence of law on value

It is sometimes said that government cannot affect value in any way, but it can do so in many ways. Certainly one of the most remarkable is by the use of its monopoly power over the medium of exchange, whereby it can, under certain conditions, cause a piece of paper to have the value of a piece of gold. Thereby at the same time it affects the interests of nearly every member of society, raising or lowering the value of many kinds of property, and of many incomes.

It’s often claimed that government can’t influence value, but it actually can in several ways. One of the most significant is through its monopoly control over the currency, which allows it, under certain conditions, to make a piece of paper worth the same as a piece of gold. This simultaneously impacts the interests of almost everyone in society, either increasing or decreasing the value of various types of property and incomes.


CHAPTER 47

THE STANDARD OF DEFERRED PAYMENTS

§ I. FUNCTION OF THE STANDARD

Definition of the standard

1. The standard of deferred payments is the thing of value in which, by the law or by contract, the amount of a debt is expressed. A credit transaction is a lengthened exchange; one party fulfils his part of the contract, the other party promises to give an equivalent at a later date. The equivalent may be in any kind of goods; for example, in barter one may part with a horse on the promise of a cow to be received later; or a small horse on the promise of a large one; or a flock of sheep on the promise of its return at the end of the year with a part of the increase of the flock. A simple standard in which to express the debt is the thing borrowed, as horse, sheep, wheat, house, etc. This involves the use of the renting contract. Again, the thing to which the value of debts is referred may be a thing quite different from the goods borrowed, and with the growth of the money economy and the use of the interest contract, money comes more and more to be used as the standard. The parties express the debt in terms of the standard unit established by law.

1. The standard for deferred payments is the item of value that, according to law or contract, specifies the amount of a debt. A credit transaction is an extended exchange; one party fulfills their part of the contract, while the other party agrees to provide something of equal value later. The equivalent can be any type of goods; for instance, in barter, someone might give a horse with the promise of receiving a cow later; or offer a small horse in exchange for a larger one; or trade a flock of sheep with the understanding that it will be returned at the end of the year along with some of the offspring. A straightforward standard to express the debt is the item borrowed, like a horse, sheep, wheat, house, etc. This involves using a rental agreement. Additionally, the item that determines the value of debts may be something completely different from the actual goods borrowed, and as the money economy grows and the use of interest contracts increases, money increasingly becomes the standard. The parties express the debt in terms of the standard unit set by law.

Increasing use of the interest contract

2. The importance of the standard of deferred payments increases with the use of money and with the amount of outstanding debts. Until the use of money develops, the use of credit is difficult and limited; it becomes easy when the value of all things is expressed in terms of a common circulating medium. If all business were done for cash there would be no great interests affected when a change in the value of[Pg 454] money occurred. Every dollar would change in value in the hands of the holder, but there the effect would cease. But the volume of outstanding debts expressed in terms of money now exceeds many fold the total value of the circulating medium. The value of all these debts changes in the same proportion as does that of the standard unit of money; when this is cheapened either by law or as a result of increasing supplies, a creditor to whom a thousand dollars are due loses the same as if he had a thousand metal dollars locked up in a strong chest.

2. The importance of the standard for deferred payments increases with the use of money and the amount of outstanding debts. Until money is widely used, credit is difficult and limited; it becomes easier when the value of everything is represented by a common currency. If all business transactions were done in cash, a change in the value of [Pg 454] money wouldn’t significantly affect major interests. Each dollar would change in value for the person holding it, but that would be the end of the impact. However, the total amount of outstanding debts measured in money now far exceeds the total value of the money in circulation. The value of all these debts changes in the same way as the value of the standard unit of money; when money loses value, whether due to laws or increased supply, a creditor owed a thousand dollars loses the same amount as if they had a thousand metal dollars stored away in a secure place.

Great effects of money changes

Outstanding contract debts may be roughly divided into three classes: short-time loans, running less than a year; medium-time, running from one to five years; long-time, running over five years. Fluctuations are rarely rapid and great enough to affect appreciably the debtors and creditors in the case of short-time loans. The results are greater in the case of long-time loans, such as national, state, and city debts, bonds of corporations, mortgages given by farmers on their land or by owners of city real estate. A multitude of interests are affected by a change in the value of money. When, as in the years 1873-96, money gains in purchasing power (prices fall) receivers of fixed incomes are gainers. When, as in the years 1896-1903, the value of money falls, the revenues from educational and charitable endowments, the salaries of public officials, and all fixed incomes, lose purchasing power. In a capitalistic age, therefore, almost every individual is affected in some way by a change in the value of money. In most cases the change escapes recognition; people do not trace out the relation that an industrial change bears to their own interests. In a few notable cases, however, the change has been revolutionary as in the period following the discovery of America, when the feudal dues had come to be expressed in terms of money instead of labor services. In modern times, the mass of debts being greater than ever before, such changes as those following the discovery of gold in California or the decrease in gold[Pg 455] production between 1873 and 1890 have the gravest economic results.

Outstanding contract debts can be roughly divided into three categories: short-term loans, lasting less than a year; medium-term loans, lasting from one to five years; and long-term loans, lasting over five years. Fluctuations are rarely rapid or significant enough to noticeably impact debtors and creditors in the case of short-term loans. The effects are more significant with long-term loans, such as national, state, and city debts, corporate bonds, and mortgages taken out by farmers on their land or by owners of urban real estate. A wide range of interests are influenced by changes in the value of money. When, as happened from 1873 to 1896, money increases in purchasing power (prices decrease), those with fixed incomes benefit. Conversely, when, as happened from 1896 to 1903, the value of money decreases, the revenues from educational and charitable endowments, public officials' salaries, and all fixed incomes lose purchasing power. In a capitalist economy, nearly everyone is influenced in some way by changes in the value of money. Most of the time, these changes go unnoticed; people don't connect how industrial changes impact their own interests. However, in a few significant cases, the changes have been revolutionary, such as in the period following the discovery of America, when feudal dues shifted from being paid in labor services to being expressed in monetary terms. In modern times, with the total amount of debt being greater than ever, changes like those after the discovery of gold in California or the decrease in gold production between 1873 and 1890 have serious economic implications.

Merits of gold and of silver as standards

3. The best standards of deferred payments available—the precious metals, gold and silver—are still imperfect. The good that is most convenient as a standard of deferred payments is the one used as money. Gold to-day is constantly expressing the value of all other things. Borrowers prefer to make loans in the form of the general medium of exchange. From the usage of speaking of all things in terms of money, the false idea arises that the value of other things changes, but that the value of gold is always the same. Money is no such a fixed objective standard as a foot-rule or a pound weight. The value of gold rests on the estimates made by men, and is constantly changing according to conditions. A fixed objective standard of value is not possible of attainment. The value of the precious metals is stable as compared with most things. The current new supply is comparatively regular. For generations at a time there may be no radical changes in the output of gold and silver. For centuries there was no change in the methods of extraction. Recent inventions, however, have considerably altered these conditions. The nature of the use of gold and silver, likewise, is such as to make the demand for them, under ordinary conditions, most stable. The precious metals are but slowly worn out; only a portion of the annual output is used in the arts; there is, therefore, a large reservoir into which flows steadily a small stream; the existing stock is twenty or thirty times the annual output. Yet the value of the standard metals is never quite stable, and sometimes several influences combine, as in the last century, to affect their value greatly and suddenly.

3. The best standards for deferred payments available—the precious metals, gold and silver—are still not perfect. The most convenient good used as a standard for deferred payments is the one that's used as money. Gold today is constantly reflecting the value of everything else. Borrowers prefer to take out loans in the form of the common medium of exchange. By referring to everything in terms of money, the misleading notion arises that the value of other things changes, but the value of gold remains constant. Money is not a fixed objective standard like a ruler or a weight. The value of gold depends on human assessments and is constantly fluctuating based on conditions. A fixed objective standard of value is unattainable. The value of precious metals is stable compared to most things. The current supply is relatively consistent. For long periods, there might be no significant changes in gold and silver production. For centuries, the methods of extraction remained unchanged. However, recent inventions have significantly changed these conditions. The way gold and silver are used also makes their demand, under normal circumstances, quite stable. The precious metals deteriorate slowly; only a portion of the annual output is used in industry; thus, there's a large reservoir receiving a small, steady inflow; the existing stock is twenty to thirty times the annual output. Yet, the value of standard metals is never completely stable, and sometimes multiple factors combine, as seen last century, to greatly and suddenly affect their value.

Various standards suggested
Enjoyment
Sacrifice
Labor
Tabular standard

4. Various ideals for a standard of deferred payments have been suggested—as return of equal enjoyment, of equal sacrifice, social expediency; and various standards—as labor, commodities, and the tabular standard. The ideal standard of deferred payments is one that will insure justice between borrower and lender. Different views have been taken as to what constitutes justice in this matter. The suggestion is attractive that the sum when returned should represent the same amount of enjoyment as it did when it was borrowed. Such a standard is impossible of realization in any general way, for men's circumstances are constantly changing. To insure even to the average man the same amount of enjoyment is only roughly possible. The same goods do not afford the same enjoyment when conditions have changed. Another suggestion is that the goods returned should represent the same sacrifice as those loaned. Here again the difficulty is in the lack of an objective standard. Whose sacrifice? That of the lender, who may be rich, or that of the borrower, who may be poor? Some have supposed the conditions of equal sacrifice were met by the labor standard, according to which the sum returned should purchase the same number of days of labor as when borrowed. But what kind of labor is to be taken, that of the lender or that of the borrower, or that of some one else? Labor is of many different qualities, which can be exactly compared only through their objective value in terms of some one good. The ideal of equal enjoyment has been supposed to be realized by the tabular standard, which consists of a number of leading commodities in fixed proportions. The money returned is to be enough to purchase the same goods at the expiration as at the making of the loan, and thus may be a larger or smaller sum than was borrowed. While this does not, as is sometimes claimed, insure equality of enjoyment, it averages the fluctuations of many goods, and thus prevents great extremes. This standard has been favored by notable monetary authorities, but the difficulties of its practical application are prohibitive.

4. Various ideals for a standard of deferred payments have been suggested—like the return of equal enjoyment, equal sacrifice, and social expediency; as well as different standards—such as labor, commodities, and the tabular standard. The ideal standard of deferred payments is one that ensures fairness between the borrower and the lender. There are different opinions on what constitutes fairness in this situation. It’s an appealing idea that the amount paid back should represent the same level of enjoyment as when it was borrowed. However, this standard is practically impossible to achieve in a general sense because people's circumstances are always changing. Even ensuring the average person has the same amount of enjoyment is only roughly feasible. The same items don’t provide the same enjoyment when conditions have shifted. Another suggestion is that the goods returned should show the same sacrifice as those loaned. Again, the problem lies in the lack of an objective standard. Whose sacrifice do we consider? That of the lender, who might be wealthy, or that of the borrower, who might be struggling? Some believe that equal sacrifice can be addressed by the labor standard, suggesting that the amount returned should buy the same number of days of labor as when it was borrowed. But what kind of labor should be considered? The lender's, the borrower's, or someone else's? Labor varies widely, and can only be accurately compared through its objective value in relation to a specific good. The ideal of equal enjoyment has been thought to be realized through the tabular standard, which consists of a set of key commodities in fixed ratios. The money paid back should be enough to buy the same goods at the end of the loan as it was when the loan was taken out, which could result in a larger or smaller amount than was borrowed. While this doesn’t necessarily guarantee equal enjoyment, as some claim, it averages out fluctuations across many goods, helping to prevent extreme disparities. This standard has been supported by prominent monetary experts, but the challenges of practical implementation are prohibitive.

It must be recognized that any possible concrete standard of deferred payments will sometimes work hardship to individuals. The best average results for justice and social welfare will be secured by measuring debts in goods that[Pg 457] change least often, least rapidly, and in the least unpredictable manner. Gold thus far has proved itself worthy to serve as the standard.

It should be acknowledged that any potential concrete standard for deferred payments can sometimes cause difficulties for individuals. The best overall outcomes for justice and social welfare will come from evaluating debts in goods that[Pg 457] change the least often, the slowest, and in the most predictable way. So far, gold has shown to be a suitable standard.

§ II. INTERNATIONAL BIMETALLISM

Examples of price fluctuations

1. The fall of prices in 1873 and the following years meant a great change in the standard of deferred payments. The monetary changes following the discovery of America were due to the inflow to Europe of great quantities of silver taken by force from the native American rulers, and from the rich mines. Silver, at that time throughout Europe the main standard of deferred payments, was thus greatly lowered in value. This change lightened all outstanding obligations, lowered the money rents of the peasants, and the customary dues of labor wherever they had come to be expressed in money form. By the third quarter of the nineteenth century gold had become in Europe and America the main standard, though silver still served as such in some countries. The output of gold in 1849-57 caused the greatest money inflation that has occurred since the sixteenth century, favoring in a similar manner the debtor classes. The substitution of gold for silver by some countries at that time, by making a great additional market for gold, helped in some degree to check the fall in its value.

1. The drop in prices in 1873 and the years that followed brought a significant change in the standard for delayed payments. The monetary shifts after the discovery of America were due to the large amounts of silver taken by force from indigenous American leaders and from rich mines flowing into Europe. Silver, which was the primary standard for delayed payments in Europe at that time, lost a lot of its value. This change eased all existing debts, reduced the monetary rents for peasants, and lowered the customary labor dues wherever they had been expressed in money. By the third quarter of the nineteenth century, gold had become the main standard in Europe and America, although silver still served that purpose in some countries. The gold output from 1849 to 1857 led to the biggest money inflation seen since the sixteenth century, similarly benefiting debtors. The switch from silver to gold in some countries during that time created a larger market for gold, which helped to somewhat stabilize its value.

The recent great fall of prices

The decline in the output of gold was a change of the opposite character, causing a fall of prices and increasing the burden of debts. From 1873 to 1896 there was almost constant decline of the prosperity of the agricultural classes, due in part to this money influence, but in part to influences which cannot be dwelt upon here, as they had nothing to do with the money question. There was complaint, agitation, and demand for relief on the part of many interests in France, Germany, England, and the United States.

The decrease in gold production was a shift in the opposite direction, leading to falling prices and a heavier debt load. From 1873 to 1896, the prosperity of farming communities consistently declined, partly due to this monetary impact and partly due to factors that can't be discussed here since they didn’t relate to the money issue. There were complaints, protests, and calls for help from various groups in France, Germany, England, and the United States.

Bitmetallism defined

2. Bimetallism, the use of two metals as standard moneys, was the remedy proposed. Bimetallism is legally complete[Pg 458] when both metals are admitted to the mints for free coinage at an established ratio of weight; it is halting or limping when one of the metals is not freely coined. Bimetallism may be legally authorized, but not actually working. As soon as the legal ratio varies appreciably from the market value, only one of the metals will in fact be brought to the mint. National bimetallism is confined to a single country, as that in the United States before the Civil War, or in France before 1867. International bimetallism is an agreement among several nations to use two metals on the same terms, the only case in history being that of the Latin Union, which included France, Italy, Switzerland, and other countries. The discussion of international bimetallism in recent years has been on the proposal to make a much larger league of states than the Latin Union, embracing all the leading countries.

2. Bimetallism, the use of two metals as standard currencies, was the solution that was proposed. Bimetallism is legally complete[Pg 458] when both metals can be minted freely at an established weight ratio; it is incomplete when one of the metals isn’t minted freely. Bimetallism may be legally authorized, but that doesn’t mean it’s functioning in practice. If the legal ratio significantly diverges from the market value, only one of the metals will actually be taken to the mint. National bimetallism exists within a single country, as was the case in the United States before the Civil War, or in France before 1867. International bimetallism involves an agreement among multiple nations to use two metals under the same conditions, with the only historical example being the Latin Union, which included France, Italy, Switzerland, and other countries. Recent discussions about international bimetallism have focused on the idea of forming a much larger coalition of states than the Latin Union, covering all the major countries.

Object of international bimetallism

3. The main object of international bimetallism is to prevent the fluctuations of the standard of deferred payments. Commercial dealings between gold-using and silver-using countries are of great magnitude, and the use of different standards leads to many difficulties. Fluctuations in the ratio of the two metals occasion much uncertainty and loss to individual traders. The rise in the value of gold meant an increase in the burden of the public debts of silver-using countries which collect their revenues in silver, but which must pay their debts, principal and interest, in gold.

3. The main goal of international bimetallism is to stop fluctuations in the standard of deferred payments. The commercial exchanges between countries that use gold and those that use silver are significant, and using different standards creates various challenges. Changes in the ratio of the two metals often result in uncertainty and loss for individual traders. The increase in gold's value has raised the burden of public debts for silver-using countries that collect their revenues in silver but have to pay their debts, including interest, in gold.

Its theory

The theory of bimetallism is that the government can act on the value of the two metals through the principle of substitution. The metal tending to become dearer will not be coined, the other will be coined in greater quantities. The degree of influence that can thus be exerted on the value of the two metals depends on the size of the reservoir of the metal that is rising in price. When it all leaves circulation, the law on the statute book permitting it to be coined becomes a mere sounding phrase. In such a case there is bimetallism de jure, but monometallism de facto. The greater the league[Pg 459] of states, the greater is the likelihood that the scheme will work. The economic theory of bimetallism was recognized by a majority of economists to be abstractly sound, but the political difficulties in the way of international agreements are great, and have proved to be insurmountable.

The theory of bimetallism suggests that the government can influence the value of two metals through substitution. When one metal becomes more expensive, it won't be minted, while the other will be minted more frequently. The extent to which the value of these metals can be influenced depends on the amount of the metal that is increasing in price. Once that metal leaves circulation, the law allowing it to be minted becomes just empty words. In this situation, there's bimetallism de jure, but monometallism de facto. The larger the coalition of states, the higher the chance that the plan will succeed. Most economists agree that the economic theory of bimetallism is fundamentally sound, but the political challenges of reaching international agreements are significant and have proven to be impossible to overcome.

§ III. THE FREE-SILVER MOVEMENT IN AMERICA

Conditions leading to the demand for free-silver

1. International bimetallism, despite many efforts, failed of adoption. This brief proposition sums up the history of the movement, from 1878 to 1892, to form a league of states and an agreement for international bimetallism. International conferences were held, and taken part in by the leading financiers of the world. France at first favored the policy, and the United States was always foremost in advocating it, while England in the main was opposed. Some of the advocates of bimetallism argued that the fall of prices was due not alone to economic forces, but also to a money conspiracy which had influenced legislation to introduce and continue the gold standard. This, of course, was strenuously denied. It is true that the commercial classes found gold the form of money most suitable to large business, and no doubt class interests entered into the question in some measure. The difficulties of the debtor class in America were peculiarly great, owing to the inflated paper currency, from 1862 to 1879, which had made our conditions quite abnormal. In the period of speculation following the Civil War an enormous mass of debts had been accumulated. The hopes of thousands of tillers of the soil suffering from a fall in prices, and of the great debtor class, clamoring for relief, were centered upon the success of this movement. Banking and other large business interests in general opposed it.

1. International bimetallism, despite many attempts, failed to gain traction. This simple statement summarizes the history of the movement, from 1878 to 1892, aimed at creating a coalition of states and an agreement for international bimetallism. International conferences took place, involving the leading financial figures from around the globe. Initially, France supported the policy, while the United States consistently championed it, and England largely opposed it. Some bimetallism supporters argued that the decline in prices was caused not just by economic factors, but also by a monetary conspiracy that influenced legislation to establish and maintain the gold standard. This was, of course, strongly denied. It's true that the business sector found gold to be the most suitable form of currency for large transactions, and class interests likely played a role in the debate. The challenges faced by America's debtor class were particularly severe, due to the inflated paper currency issued from 1862 to 1879, which had created very unusual conditions. In the speculative period following the Civil War, an enormous amount of debt had piled up. The hopes of thousands of struggling farmers facing falling prices, along with the larger debtor class seeking relief, were pinned on the success of this movement. Banking and other major business interests, in general, opposed it.

Purpose of the free-silver movement

2. The plan of the free-silver advocates was to legalize national bimetallism in the United States at a ratio between gold and silver very different from the market ratio. Gold had become, long before 1860, the real standard of our[Pg 460] money system, and after 1873 it was the only metal admitted to free coinage. Silver, little by little, was losing purchasing power in terms of gold, until from being worth, in 1873, one sixteenth as much, ounce for ounce, it became, in 1896, worth but one thirtieth as much as gold. It must be recognized that the power of silver to purchase general commodities fell much less than the change in its ratio to gold would indicate, gold having risen in terms of most other goods as well as of silver. Nevertheless, the proposal to open the mints to free silver at sixteen to one in the year 1896 meant a sudden and marked cheapening of money. The prime purpose was to lighten the burden of debts by making the standard of deferred payments cheaper. It was at first a debtors' movement, but to succeed it had to enlist the support of other large classes of voters. And thus, by force of political necessity, but doubtless in large part naïvely, it developed into the more sweeping theory that wages, welfare, and prosperity called for a larger supply of money independently of the effect on debts.

2. The plan of the free-silver supporters was to make national bimetallism legal in the United States at a ratio between gold and silver very different from the market rate. Gold had already become the real standard of our[Pg 460] money system long before 1860, and after 1873, it was the only metal allowed for free coinage. Slowly, silver was losing its purchasing power in relation to gold, decreasing from being worth one sixteenth as much in 1873 to just one thirtieth as much in 1896. It's important to note that silver's purchasing power for general goods fell much less than what the change in its ratio to gold would suggest, since gold also increased in value compared to most other products as well as silver. Still, the proposal to open the mints for free silver at a sixteen to one ratio in 1896 meant a sudden and significant decrease in the value of money. The main goal was to ease the burden of debt by making the standard for paying back debts cheaper. It started as a movement for debtors, but to succeed, it needed the backing of other large groups of voters. Therefore, out of political necessity, and probably in part due to naivety, it grew into a broader idea that wages, welfare, and prosperity required a larger money supply regardless of its impact on debts.

The free-silver theory

In its extreme form the free-silver plan was a fiat scheme, for some of its supporters believed that by the mere passage of the law the two metals could be made to bear to each other any ratio desired. But its most intelligent and high-minded advocates (who were moved to its support by a sincere sympathy and concern for the distressed agriculturalists) recognized fully that the force of the law was limited by economic conditions. The extreme opponents of the plan, ignoring the evident fact that the adoption of a metal as a standard money is one of the most essential of the market conditions, denied that government action could in any way affect the value. Most of the arguments presented on either side in the political campaigns showed little evidence of a sound theory of money. The victory of the gold standard in 1896 and 1900, it would seem, was due more to the well-founded fear that a sudden change of the money standard would cause a panic, than to a thorough understanding of the question.

In its most extreme form, the free-silver plan was a fiat scheme because some of its supporters thought that simply passing the law could set any desired ratio between the two metals. However, its most thoughtful and principled supporters (who truly cared about the struggling farmers) fully understood that the law's power was limited by economic conditions. The strongest critics of the plan, overlooking the obvious fact that choosing a metal as a standard currency is one of the key market conditions, argued that government actions couldn't influence value at all. Most of the arguments shared during the political campaigns on either side lacked a solid understanding of monetary theory. The success of the gold standard in 1896 and 1900 seems to have stemmed more from a justified fear that a sudden shift in the monetary standard would lead to a crisis, rather than from a deep comprehension of the issues involved.

Increase of gold production

3. The increase of the gold output has for the present checked the fall of prices. Before 1890, for a number of years, the average output of gold was shrinking till it reached a scant hundred million per year. At the same time, nations which recently had gone over to the gold standard were striving to secure large stocks for their banks and general circulation, and those great reservoirs, as a result, became better filled than they ever were before. After the opening of new gold-yielding territory in South Africa and in the Klondike, the annual output of gold became greater than it had ever been, being at the opening of the South African War in 1898 nearly three times that of ten years earlier. The present methods of extracting gold resemble those of fifty years ago as civilized industry resembles that of savages. Intricate machinery has taken the place of crude tools, chemical processes have been introduced, and the principal product results from the regular and certain working of deep mines rather than from chance surface discoveries. Great masses of debris can now be reworked profitably. In many parts of the world are enormous deposits of low-grade ores, before useless, that can be worked economically by present methods. For a generation at least the world's supply of gold is likely to continue larger than ever before in history, and prices in terms of gold probably will rise.

3. The increase in gold production has currently slowed down the drop in prices. Before 1890, for several years, the average gold output was decreasing until it hit a low of around a hundred million per year. At the same time, countries that had recently adopted the gold standard were trying to get large reserves for their banks and general circulation, leading these reserves to become better stocked than ever before. After new gold-rich areas opened up in South Africa and the Klondike, the annual gold output soared to levels never seen before, reaching nearly three times what it was a decade earlier by the start of the South African War in 1898. Today's gold extraction methods are vastly different from those used fifty years ago, just as modern industry is more advanced than that of primitive societies. Complex machinery has replaced simple tools, chemical processes have been introduced, and the main output now comes from consistent deep mining operations rather than random surface finds. Huge amounts of material can now be mined profitably. In many parts of the world, there are large deposits of low-grade ores that were once considered worthless, but can now be mined economically using current methods. For at least a generation, the world's gold supply is expected to remain larger than ever in history, and prices in terms of gold will likely rise.

Rising prices the temporary solution

Though no change seems likely or possible at the present time, the free-silver advocate has been justified by events against those gold advocates who said that the amount of money has nothing to do with prices. Prices have gone up as gold has increased. The free-silver advocates have gotten what they wanted through a change for which neither party can claim the credit. Yet the present situation is unsatisfactory and undeveloped. A standard better than a single metal, more stable than a single commodity, is desirable if it can be found. The money question must arise again and in a new form before many years. The difficulty has not been finally settled; it is but postponed.

Though change doesn’t seem likely or possible right now, free-silver supporters have been proven right by events against gold supporters who claimed that the amount of money doesn’t affect prices. Prices have risen as gold has increased. Free-silver advocates have achieved what they wanted through a shift that neither side can take credit for. However, the current situation is unsatisfactory and undeveloped. A standard better than a single metal, more stable than a single commodity, is desirable if possible. The money issue will come up again in a new form in a few years. The problem has not been finally resolved; it has just been postponed.


CHAPTER 48

BANKING AND CREDIT

§ I. FUNCTIONS OF A BANK

The essential banking function

1. A bank is a business whose income is derived chiefly from lending its promises to pay. Banks have passed through many changes in the past three centuries. Originating on the street corner for exchange of money, they have evolved into great institutions of many forms, and performing many functions. The definition seems paradoxical, but it expresses what in modern thought is the essential feature of a bank: the lending of its credit. A reserve of money is needed by the man of business. But for the banks each man would have to keep his reserve in his own till. Except the small sum needed for current uses, a bank can keep this reserve more economically than individuals can. It has the advantages of large production similar to those of a large factory. The process of lending credit is called deposit and discount. It grew out of the deposit of actual money for safe keeping and the loaning to borrowers by the method of discounting their notes. The term now has a somewhat different meaning, for a merchant may obtain a deposit to-day without putting any money in the bank. He gets the bank to discount his notes or collateral security, and to enter the sum to his credit as a deposit. He becomes a depositor by borrowing, not by lending to the bank. The sum is under the borrower's control; he can check it out when he wishes; but he usually keeps a certain balance to his credit. The bank's gain is larger than ordinary interest, because it[Pg 463] gets a discount on the large sums left in its possession. The bank increases its funds also by attracting deposits from those who do not care to borrow.

1. A bank is a business that primarily makes money by lending out its ability to pay. Banks have undergone many changes over the past three hundred years. They started at street corners for exchanging money and have transformed into large institutions with various forms and functions. This definition may seem contradictory, but it captures what is crucial in modern understanding: the lending of credit. Businesspeople need a reserve of money. Without banks, each person would have to keep their own reserves at home. Besides the small amount needed for daily expenses, banks can manage these reserves more efficiently than individuals can. They benefit from economies of scale similar to those in large factories. The process of lending credit is referred to as deposit and discount. This emerged from depositing actual cash for safekeeping and then lending to borrowers by discounting their notes. The meaning has shifted somewhat; now a merchant can obtain a deposit today without putting any money in the bank. Instead, he gets the bank to discount his notes or collateral and adds the amount to his credit as a deposit. He becomes a depositor by borrowing, not by depositing money in the bank. This amount is under the borrower's control; he can withdraw it whenever he wants, but he usually maintains a certain balance. The bank's earnings are higher than ordinary interest because it[Pg 463] receives a discount on the large amounts kept in its care. The bank also increases its funds by attracting deposits from those who do not wish to borrow.

Other functions usually performed

2. Functions not essential to banking are ordinary money-lending, money-changing, exchange to distant points, safe deposit, and issue of bank-notes. Banks often lend in the ordinary way, allowing borrowers to draw the money out at once, but this is not the business they prefer. Many individuals and corporations, such as endowed charities, colleges, insurance companies, lend great sums of their own money without thereby partaking in any degree of the peculiar character of banking. Money-changing (the exchange of coins of different countries) is done by banks, but likewise by many other agencies not sharing the essential banking character. Foreign and domestic exchange is the issue and cashing of "drafts" for money payments between distant places. Most banks are well fitted to perform this function, but some banks do not undertake it, and it is performed also by some business houses that are not banks. Safe deposit is the keeping of things to be returned in identical form, as silverware, notes, and papers. By banks in small towns this is sometimes done freely, sometimes for a slight charge; but in large cities safe-deposit vaults are generally quite unconnected with banks. Even bank-note issue is not essential to banking; most banks in the United States issue no notes, others issue very few. All these functions may be united under one management, but the essential banking function is deposit and discount.

2. Functions that aren't central to banking include regular money-lending, currency exchange, transferring money to distant places, safe deposit services, and issuing bank notes. Banks often lend money in a straightforward way, allowing borrowers to take out the cash immediately, but this isn't their preferred method. Many individuals and organizations, like charitable foundations, universities, and insurance companies, lend large amounts of their own money without necessarily taking on the distinct nature of banking. Currency exchange (the swapping of coins from different countries) is handled by banks, but also by many other entities that don't fit the essential banking mold. Foreign and domestic exchange involves issuing and cashing "drafts" for monetary payments between far-off locations. While most banks are well-suited to handle this, some do not offer this service, and certain businesses that are not banks also provide it. Safe deposit services involve storing items to be returned in the same condition, such as silverware, contracts, and important documents. In smaller towns, banks may offer this service freely or for a small fee, but in larger cities, safe deposit vaults are typically separate from banks. Even the issuance of banknotes is not vital to banking; many banks in the United States do not issue any notes, while others issue very few. All these functions can be managed under one roof, but the key banking functions are taking deposits and providing loans.

Sources of the income of banks

3. The income of banks is derived from discounts, interest on their own capital, charges for exchange and collection, rents on investments, and profit from the loan of their bank-notes. The income of banks is drawn from different sources, according to the size of the community, and the nature of the banks. While in the villages and smaller cities they perform a number of functions, in the larger cities they usually specialize in a far greater degree. Like every other enterprise,[Pg 464] a bank must start in business with some paid-up capital as a guarantee of credit. Further security is afforded by the limited liability of shareholders for losses, in proportion to their capital stock. The same amount of money could be loaned with less trouble and more cheaply without starting a bank, but used as a banking capital a part of it can be loaned while still serving to attract money deposits. Charges to smaller customers for exchange are a source of income to some banks, but in many cases this service is freely performed for regular customers and becomes a considerable expense. Banks make few investments in real estate or other physical property; it is, in fact, their duty to keep out of ordinary enterprises, but they are forced sometimes to take for unpaid debts things that have been held as security. Profits on bank-notes have at times been the main, possibly the sole, motive for starting banks; but that is not the case to-day when the right of issue is so strictly limited.

3. Banks generate income from discounts, interest on their own capital, fees for exchanges and collections, rental income from investments, and profits from loaning out their banknotes. The income of banks comes from various sources, depending on the size of the community and the type of banks. In villages and smaller cities, they offer a range of services, whereas in larger cities, they tend to specialize much more. Like any other business,[Pg 464] a bank needs to start with some paid-up capital to ensure creditworthiness. Limited liability of shareholders for losses based on their capital stock provides additional security. The same funds could be lent more easily and cheaply without establishing a bank, but when used as banking capital, part of it can be loaned out while still attracting money deposits. Some banks earn income by charging small customers for exchanges, but often, this service is offered for free to regular customers and can become a significant expense. Banks rarely invest in real estate or other physical assets; in fact, they should avoid engaging in regular businesses, although they sometimes have to accept collateral for unpaid debts. At times, profits from banknotes have been the primary, if not the only, reason for starting banks; however, this is no longer true today when the right to issue them is heavily regulated.

Productive services of banks

4. Banks are productive economic agents performing important industrial services. False ideas have long been entertained about the magic power of banks to produce wealth from nothing. To many, banks are a mystery much like paper money. Their opponents sometimes have pictured them as vampires fattening on the blood of industry. That they have shown abuses at times is undeniable, but, like other economic agents, they are to be judged by their net efficiency. The bank is a tool performing services similar to those of money. For some purposes money is an awkward and costly agent in comparison with banks. For remitting payments from New York to San Francisco or Hong Kong, money is a medieval device. Money can more safely be entrusted to a bank than to a strong chest in one's own house. The man who refused to make use of banks in this day would isolate himself economically, and would soon find himself out of any but the smallest business. He could no more get along without the banks than without the post, the telegraph, or the telephone.

4. Banks are productive economic agents providing essential industrial services. Misconceptions have persisted about the ability of banks to create wealth out of nothing. For many, banks are as enigmatic as paper money. Critics sometimes portray them as vampires feeding on the lifeblood of industry. While it's undeniable they have committed abuses at times, like other economic agents, they should be evaluated based on their overall efficiency. A bank is a tool that offers services similar to those of money. In some cases, money is a cumbersome and expensive option compared to banks. Sending payments from New York to San Francisco or Hong Kong makes money seem outdated. It's generally safer to trust money to a bank rather than to a safe in one's home. Anyone who refuses to utilize banks today would economically isolate themselves and quickly find it difficult to engage in anything beyond the smallest ventures. They would struggle to operate without banks just as much as they would without the post office, telegraph, or telephone.

The bank as a labor-saving device

The gathering of loanable funds by the banks, making them available at once, reduces hoarding, makes money move more rapidly, and creates a central market between borrowers and lenders for the sale of credit. While not creating more physical wealth directly, it adds to the efficiency of wealth; it oils the bearings of the industrial machine. To abolish banks would be to destroy labor-saving machinery. Banks perform incidentally a further service in developing better business methods in the community. In supplying credit to active business, banks are constantly passing judgment on the collateral security presented to them and on the solidity of the enterprises that are seeking support. They enforce promptness and exactitude in business dealings.

The collection of loanable funds by banks, making them available right away, cuts down on hoarding, speeds up the flow of money, and creates a central market for borrowing and lending credit. While it doesn’t directly create more physical wealth, it boosts the efficiency of existing wealth; it greases the wheels of the industrial machine. Getting rid of banks would mean losing valuable labor-saving tools. Banks also provide an additional service by promoting better business practices within the community. By offering credit to active businesses, banks are always evaluating the collateral security presented to them and the stability of the enterprises seeking their support. They promote promptness and precision in business transactions.

Because in their public nature banks are very analogous to money, they have always been looked upon as properly subject to more supervision than most private business, and government has always exercised a considerable measure of control over them, sometimes for good, sometimes for evil.

Because banks are public entities and are very similar to money, they have always been regarded as needing more oversight than most private businesses, and the government has always maintained a significant level of control over them, sometimes beneficially, sometimes harmfully.

§ II. TYPICAL BANK MONEY

Nature of typical bank money

1. Typical bank money consists of notes issued by banks on the credit of their general assets, without special regulation by law. As no two leading countries have quite the same system of bank-notes, the subject is a difficult one. It is well to begin, therefore, with a clear conception of typical bank money, unregulated by government. Such a form of note is one with which few now living in the United States have had any experience, as the present national bank-notes differ in essential ways from the typical form. Typical bank-notes are notes issued by banks as a means of loaning their credit. The borrower, instead of receiving a credit balance at the bank subject to check, gets notes which he hands on to other men. These notes are returned for redemption to the issuing bank as soon as any one wishes specie in their stead. The limit of the issue of such notes[Pg 466] is the need of the community for that form of money, and if they are promptly redeemed in gold on demand, they never can exceed that amount. A holder of a note (in the absence of special regulations) has the same claim on the bank that a depositor has. As it is to the interest of the bank to keep in circulation as many notes as possible, there is a temptation to abuse the power of note-issue, to which many banks yielded in the period of so-called "wild-cat banking" before the Civil War.

1. Typical bank money consists of notes issued by banks based on the value of their overall assets, without specific regulations set by law. Since no two major countries have exactly the same banknote system, this topic is quite complex. It's useful to start with a clear understanding of typical bank money that isn't government-regulated. Few people living in the United States today have experienced this type of note, as the current national bank notes are fundamentally different from the typical form. Typical banknotes are issued by banks as a way to lend out their credit. Instead of receiving a credit balance at the bank that can be accessed through checks, the borrower receives notes to use with others. These notes can be exchanged for redemption at the issuing bank whenever someone prefers cash in return. The total amount of these notes[Pg 466] is based on the community's need for that type of money, and if they are quickly redeemed for gold upon request, they can never exceed that amount. A person holding a note (without any specific regulations) has the same claim on the bank as a depositor. Since it benefits the bank to keep as many notes in circulation as possible, there’s a risk of misusing the note-issuing power, which many banks did during the so-called "wild-cat banking" era before the Civil War.

Bank-notes viewed as commercial paper

2. Bank-notes are viewed by some as a form of commercial credit. Typical bank-notes are not legal tender, and every one has the legal right to take or refuse them as he pleases. It is therefore said by some that bank-note issue is of no special concern to the state, that it can safely be left to individual self-interest. It is said that if one has little faith in a note, he may refuse to accept it. But in reality every one is compelled to take the money that is current. The average citizen cannot know the credit of distant banks, and thus has not the same power of judging wisely in taking bank-notes that he has in making deposits in the bank of his own neighborhood. Between bank-notes and ordinary promissory notes, there are other differences of a nature pretty generally recognized. Bank-notes pass without endorsement and thus depend on the credit of the bank alone, not like checks, on the credit of the person from whom received. They yield no interest to the holder. They are intended to be used as money and are so used. Thus they come near to paper money in their nature, and the banks are near to exercising the right of coinage.

2. Some people see bank notes as a type of commercial credit. Typical bank notes aren't legal tender, and everyone has the legal right to accept or reject them as they choose. Because of this, some argue that the issuance of bank notes isn't a significant concern for the government and can be safely managed by individual self-interest. They say that if someone has little trust in a note, they can refuse to take it. But in reality, everyone has to accept the money that is in circulation. The average person can't judge the creditworthiness of distant banks, so they don't have the same ability to make informed decisions about accepting bank notes as they do for deposits in their local bank. There are also other recognized differences between bank notes and regular promissory notes. Bank notes can be transferred without endorsement and rely solely on the bank's credit, unlike checks, which depend on the credit of the person who issued them. They don't earn any interest for the holder. They are meant to be used as money, and that's exactly how they're used. Thus, they are very similar to paper money, and the banks are close to having the right to issue currency.

Bank-notes viewed as a form of political money

3. By others, bank-notes are considered to be almost identical with government paper money. Some opponents of bank-note issue declare that it is a usurpation of the prerogatives of government, and that no power but the sovereign state should issue money. While many in America to-day hold this view, the comparison probably is false and strained. Typical bank-notes, unlike inconvertible paper money, depend[Pg 467] for their value on the credit of the bank, not on their legal-tender quality and on political power. They must be redeemed on penalty of insolvency; government notes need not be, and yet will circulate at par if properly limited.

3. Some people believe that banknotes are nearly the same as government paper money. Some critics of banknote issuance argue that it undermines the authority of the government, asserting that only the sovereign state should produce money. While many people in America today share this belief, the comparison is likely inaccurate and exaggerated. Unlike non-convertible paper money, typical banknotes derive[Pg 467] their value from the credibility of the bank rather than their legal tender status and government power. They must be redeemed to avoid insolvency; government notes do not have this requirement, yet they can still circulate at face value if properly regulated.

While these differences mark off government paper money pretty sharply from typical bank-notes, it must be noted that in many cases actual bank-note issues have been far from this typical form. In the days of "wild-cat" banking, bank-notes were issued in excess and fell below par, yet the man in a Western community who dared to ask the bank to redeem the notes in specie was not only frowned on by the bank, but condemned by the public, which felt that business was endangered by such a demand. Redemption on demand would have required a reduction of the amount of money in circulation and would have caused a fall in prices. Inflation of the bank currency went on with results almost identical with those following an excessive issue of government paper money. Not formal law but public opinion made such bank-notes essentially political money.

While these differences clearly distinguish government paper money from regular banknotes, it's important to note that in many cases, actual banknote issues have strayed far from this typical form. During the "wild-cat" banking days, banknotes were issued excessively and often fell below their value, yet in a Western community, a person who dared to ask the bank to exchange the notes for coin was not only frowned upon by the bank but also condemned by the public, who believed that such a demand threatened business. Redeeming on demand would have required reducing the money available in circulation, leading to a drop in prices. The inflation of bank currency continued, resulting in outcomes very similar to those that followed an excessive issue of government paper money. It was not formal law but rather public opinion that made these banknotes effectively political money.

Policy of public regulation of bank-notes

4. The public nature of bank money has led to many forms of public regulation of their issues. Bank-notes thus stand midway in their economic nature between political money and private notes, sharing something of the character of each. An extreme analogy in either direction is misleading. It is of great social importance that the circulating medium should be reliable. The least possible amount of the citizen's energy and thought should be required to decide whether the money is good or bad. Nevertheless, those opposed to state interference in industry declare that if the citizen is not left to look out for himself, the growth of stupidity will be encouraged; and they say that it is no more essential for the state to guarantee the quality of bank-notes than the quality of woolen cloth or of sugar. Few, however, take so extreme a view, and it is generally held that it is a function of the state to insure in a greater or less degree the quality of the money in circulation. The[Pg 468] actual bank-notes of the leading countries are thus of many varieties. The Canadian notes are the most nearly typical bank-notes issued to-day; those of Germany come next, while those of the United States have little of the typical character.

4. The public nature of bank money has led to various forms of public regulation regarding their issuance. Bank notes are positioned between political money and private notes in their economic nature, sharing characteristics of both. An extreme comparison in either direction can be misleading. It is vital for social stability that the medium of exchange be dependable. Citizens should expend the least amount of energy and thought possible to determine whether their money is valid or not. However, those against government intervention in industry argue that if individuals aren't allowed to take care of themselves, it will promote ignorance; they claim it's not necessary for the state to assure the quality of bank notes any more than it is for it to guarantee the quality of wool or sugar. Nevertheless, few share such a radical view, and it's generally accepted that it's the government's role to ensure, to some extent, the quality of the money in circulation. The[Pg 468] actual bank notes from the leading countries come in many varieties. Canadian notes are currently the most typical bank notes issued today; those from Germany follow closely, while the United States notes lack much of the typical quality.

§ III. BANKS OF THE UNITED STATES TO-DAY

Forms of banks in the United States

1. The three forms of banks in the United States are private, state, and national. Any one with a little capital may become a private banker. There are "curbstone brokers" in almost every town, and some of the great financial houses are private banks. But the law will not allow this to go very far. Some states will not allow a man to put up a sign announcing himself as a banker unless he complies with certain banking laws. In some states even private banks are subjected to the same inspection as the state banks and are required to make the same reports to the state officials. State banks are those organized under special state banking laws. They are usually subject to inspection by state-bank commissioners, must make regular reports, and are required to comply with certain rules as to their reserves, rates, and investments. In any case they do not issue bank-notes, because the national laws now tax the notes of state banks so heavily that they are unprofitable. National banks, the largest and most important portion of our banking system, were authorized by law in 1863, during the Civil War. They are subject to stricter regulation and inspection than are other banks, and that regulation is perhaps an advantage to them, as it strengthens public confidence in their stability. Yet this regulation does not insure the depositors against loss, as some national banks fail every year. They may be organized with twenty-five thousand dollars capital in towns of less than three thousand population, with fifty thousand dollars in towns of less than six thousand, with one hundred thousand dollars in cities of less than fifty thousand, and with two hundred thousand dollars in larger cities.

1. The three types of banks in the United States are private, state, and national. Anyone with a bit of capital can become a private banker. There are "curbstone brokers" in almost every town, and some of the major financial firms are private banks. However, the law doesn't allow this to go too far. Some states prohibit individuals from putting up a sign identifying themselves as a banker unless they follow certain banking regulations. In some states, even private banks must go through the same inspections as state banks and are required to submit the same reports to state officials. State banks are those established under specific state banking laws. They typically undergo inspections by state banking commissioners, must provide regular reports, and must adhere to specific rules regarding their reserves, rates, and investments. In any case, they do not issue banknotes because national laws have imposed such heavy taxes on the notes of state banks that they are not profitable. National banks, the largest and most significant part of our banking system, were authorized by law in 1863 during the Civil War. They are subject to stricter regulations and inspections than other banks, which may actually benefit them by increasing public confidence in their stability. However, this regulation does not guarantee depositors against loss, as some national banks fail every year. They can be established with a capital of twenty-five thousand dollars in towns with less than three thousand population, fifty thousand dollars in towns with less than six thousand, one hundred thousand dollars in cities with less than fifty thousand, and two hundred thousand dollars in larger cities.

Nature of our national bank-notes

2. Our national bank-notes have no essential mark of typical bank money. The one marked peculiarity of the national banks of the United States as compared with those of other countries, is their mode of note-issue. They perform all the other functions of banks, essential and unessential, and perform them well, but the issue of bank-notes is optional with them, and some of them do not issue any bank-notes. The legal condition to their issue is that bonds of the United States shall be purchased in the open market and deposited with the treasurer of the United States. Until 1900, notes might be issued only to ninety per cent. of the value of the bonds deposited; but now they may be issued up to the par value of the bonds. The notes, being secured by the value of the bonds, rest on the credit of the government, not on the credit of the bank. These notes are not promptly sent back for redemption to the banks issuing them, as is done with typical bank-notes. They may circulate thousands of miles away from the bank that issued them, and for years after that bank has gone out of business. They are not an "elastic currency" increasing or diminishing with the needs of business. The changes in their amount depend upon the chance of the banks to make more or less in this way than by any other use of their capital, and this in turn depends largely on the price of bonds and on the rate of interest they bear. From 1864 to 1870, fortunes were made from this source, but in recent years there has been little opportunity of gain from note-issues. Our present bank-note issues are not on a logical basis, and satisfy no one entirely. They are of importance neither to the bank, to which they afford little or no profit, nor to the public, for which they do a service equally well done by silver certificates, greenbacks, or coins.

2. Our national banknotes don't have any distinct features of typical bank money. The one unique aspect of the national banks in the United States, compared to those in other countries, is how they issue notes. They conduct all other essential and non-essential banking functions well, but issuing banknotes is optional for them, and some do not issue any at all. The legal requirement for issuing these notes is that they must purchase U.S. bonds in the open market and deposit them with the U.S. Treasurer. Until 1900, they could only issue notes up to ninety percent of the bonds' value; now, they can issue notes up to the full par value of the bonds. Since these notes are backed by the value of the bonds, their credibility relies on the government, not on the bank itself. These notes are not quickly returned for redemption to the banks that issued them, as is done with typical banknotes. They can circulate thousands of miles from the issuing bank and for years after that bank has closed. They are not an "elastic currency" that adjusts according to business needs. The amount of these notes depends on how banks can profit from them compared to other uses of their capital, which largely depends on bond prices and their interest rates. From 1864 to 1870, people made fortunes from this, but in recent years, there have been few opportunities for profit from note issues. Our current banknote system is not based on a logical framework and doesn't fully satisfy anyone. They hold little value for the banks, as they provide minimal profit, and for the public, they serve a function just as well performed by silver certificates, greenbacks, or coins.

Suggested reforms of the bank-note system

Along with the discussion of the currency has gone, since 1896, a vigorous discussion of the banking system. The two problems are so closely related that a change in the one suggests readjustment of the other. One extreme plan is to[Pg 470] abolish bank-notes entirely and to replace them with additional issues of greenbacks; the other extreme plan is to authorize the issue of almost typical bank-notes. A modification of the Canadian banking system, which has great merits, is held up for imitation. Bills have been repeatedly before Congress authorizing the maintenance of a general guarantee fund with which the notes of failed banks could be redeemed, and at the same time authorizing branch banks such as those in Canada. Public sentiment has never strongly favored this plan, however, and there is more likelihood of the passage of a bill providing for emergency notes in time of financial stress, after the plan followed in Germany.

Since 1896, there has been an active discussion about the banking system alongside the debate about currency. The two issues are so intertwined that a change in one typically requires adjustments in the other. One radical idea is to[Pg 470] eliminate banknotes entirely and substitute them with more greenbacks; the opposite extreme is to permit the issuance of almost standard banknotes. A modified version of the Canadian banking system, which has significant advantages, is being considered for adoption. Bills have frequently been presented in Congress to establish a general guarantee fund to redeem the notes of failed banks, and to allow for branch banks like those in Canada. However, public support for this plan has never been strong, and it's more likely that a bill will pass allowing for emergency notes during financial crises, similar to the one used in Germany.

Bank regulation a protective measure

That the control of banking is an important duty of government is the conclusion of the practical world. The various banking systems of the leading countries embody different plans for the one purpose of the adequate control of banking in the public interest. Government control of bank-notes is felt to be of the same nature as factory inspection, that is, to be a protective measure. When public interests are at stake and private interests conflict with them, government acts to forbid one citizen from doing harm, and to protect other citizens from injury.

That managing banking is an important responsibility of the government is the view of the practical world. The different banking systems in leading countries represent various approaches aimed at adequately controlling banking for the public good. Government oversight of banknotes is regarded as similar to factory inspections, serving as a protective measure. When public interests are at risk and private interests clash with them, the government steps in to prevent one person from causing harm and to safeguard other citizens from injury.


CHAPTER 49

TAXATION IN ITS RELATION TO VALUE

§ I. PURPOSES OF TAXATION

Taxation defined

1. Provision for the expense of organized government is the fundamental purpose of taxation. Taxation may be defined as the taking by the government of private property for public uses. This implies a certain degree of compulsion. When the national government accepts ten million dollars in trust for the Carnegie Institution, it is not taxation, though wealth is given for public uses. The effects of taxation pervade all industrial affairs, but they will be discussed here only in relation to the value of goods and to the distribution of incomes. By taxation the government interferes with the individual's free choice and with the impersonal economic forces. It expends income in different ways from those which would be chosen by the individual.

1. The main goal of taxation is to cover the costs of a structured government. Taxation can be defined as the government's taking of private property for public use. This involves a certain level of compulsion. When the national government accepts ten million dollars in trust for the Carnegie Institution, it isn't considered taxation, even though the wealth is intended for public use. The impacts of taxation affect all aspects of business, but we will only cover them here in relation to the value of goods and the distribution of income. Through taxation, the government interferes with individual choice and with impersonal economic forces. It spends income in ways that individuals might not choose themselves.

Taxation for public defense

The primary purpose of taxation is public defense. War often has driven men into closer social relations. Public defense requires sacrifice on the part of the family and of the individual. In family or patriarchal communities all share a common income and combine in the common defense, but self-preservation compels such small communities to form a larger, stronger state for the common defense. Personal service in the field gives place to money taxes permitting a more regular, continuing, and perfect organization of military forces.

The main goal of taxation is public defense. War often brings people into closer social connections. Public defense requires sacrifices from both families and individuals. In family or patriarchal communities, everyone shares a common income and comes together for mutual defense, but self-preservation pushes these small communities to unite into a larger, stronger state for collective protection. Personal service in the military is replaced by cash taxes, allowing for a more structured, ongoing, and efficient organization of armed forces.

To preserve domestic order

Next comes the need of civil government to insure domestic tranquillity. As political unity grows, the citizens need less[Pg 472] often protection against foreign foes, and they need more often, relatively, defense against the aggressions of some of their own countrymen. The preservation of domestic order requires police, courts of justice, and other agencies. The ideal of the anarchist to do without government is nowhere realized. Everywhere there must be government to preserve peace and to protect property. Unfortunately, this need grows with the growing density of population. Crime increases when men swarm in great cities. To maintain and operate the social machinery requires ever-increasing resources. The courts which settle disputes between men, and which interpret their contracts, are agencies of peace, displacing physical contests. Many other public expenses tend to enlarge, as those for legislative bodies, public buildings, statistical inquiries, the printing of public documents. Government on these accounts has become in modern times an increasingly costly institution.

Next comes the need for civil government to ensure domestic peace. As political unity increases, citizens need less[Pg 472] often protection from foreign enemies, and they need relatively more defense against the aggressions of some of their fellow countrymen. Keeping domestic order requires police, courts, and other agencies. The ideal of the anarchist to live without government is never fully realized. There must be government everywhere to maintain peace and protect property. Unfortunately, this need increases as the population grows denser. Crime rises when people crowd into large cities. Maintaining and operating the social system requires ever-increasing resources. The courts that resolve disputes between individuals and interpret their contracts serve as peacekeeping agencies, replacing physical confrontations. Many other public expenses tend to grow as well, such as those for legislative bodies, public buildings, statistical studies, and printing public documents. Government, for these reasons, has become an increasingly expensive institution in modern times.

Developing public wants; social and industrial welfare

2. The promotion of the social and industrial welfare of society has come to be an important purpose of taxation. Some functions of government, less essential than the primary ones just mentioned, seem naturally to grow out of them. In a democratic society, popular education is one of the necessary conditions of good government, as it appears that domestic order is not possible in a democratic state without intelligent citizens. Step by step the functions of government are widened. Some industrial functions are performed by the government in connection with the primary needs. Lighthouses are necessary to guide the navy, but they also serve to guide the merchant marine and to aid industry. The post was established as an agent of political and military government to connect the ruler with the outposts (a fact the name post indicates), but the postal service has grown in every country to be a great industrial and social agency. The consular service, beginning in the political need of keeping official representatives in foreign lands, has grown to be a great economic agency. Consuls are[Pg 473] commercial travelers, advancing the trade-interests of their countries in all quarters of the globe. These social and industrial functions have been increasing of late. As the national and local governments engage more in industry, they usually make larger demands in the shape of taxation.

2. Promoting the social and industrial welfare of society has become an important goal of taxation. Some government functions, while not as crucial as the primary ones mentioned, naturally develop from them. In a democratic society, public education is essential for good governance since domestic order is unlikely without informed citizens. The functions of government expand gradually. Some industrial roles are taken on by the government alongside primary needs. Lighthouses are essential for guiding the navy, but they also help the merchant marine and support industry. The postal service was created to connect political and military leaders with distant areas (as indicated by the name "post"), but it has grown in every country into a significant industrial and social entity. The consular service, which started from the political need to have official representatives abroad, has evolved into an important economic service. Consuls are[Pg 473] commercial ambassadors, promoting their countries' trade interests around the world. These social and industrial roles have been increasing recently. As national and local governments become more involved in industry, they typically impose greater taxation demands.

The sphere of the state expands

It is along the border-line between the primary and the secondary purposes of taxation that the contest goes on regarding the proper functions of government. If they are to stop short of the extreme of socialism, where shall the line be drawn? The movement has been of late toward greater government activity; more of the wants of men are thus supplied through the agency of the state. That year by year a greater sum is taken by taxation and spent for the citizen is a fact that may be recognized without debate here. The toll-road becomes a public road, the toll-bridge becomes free, more is supplied by taxation for schools, for advanced research, and for technical training. In our country great wealth was given by the Morrill Act to scientific and technical schools. The state universities, against much opposition, have become in many states of the Union the dominant educational force. Moreover, taxation often is used as a means not merely of raising revenue, but of discouraging one kind of industry and encouraging another. One industry wanes or dies under increasing burdens, another waxes strong by fostering exemptions and bounties. A large share of this "protective legislation" is done under the guise of taxation.

It’s at the intersection of the main and secondary purposes of taxation that the debate rages on about the proper roles of government. If we want to avoid going too far into socialism, where do we draw the line? Recently, there has been a trend towards more government involvement; more of what people need is being provided by the state. It's undeniable that each year, a larger amount is collected through taxes and spent on citizens. Toll roads are becoming public roads, toll bridges are now free, and tax funds are increasing for schools, advanced research, and technical training. In our country, significant wealth was allocated to scientific and technical schools through the Morrill Act. State universities have, despite considerable opposition, become the leading educational institutions in many states. Additionally, taxation is often used not just to generate revenue, but also to discourage certain industries while promoting others. As one industry struggles or disappears under heavier taxes, another thrives due to exemptions and incentives. Much of this "protective legislation" is disguised as taxation.

Government as a consumption good and as a means of production

3. Shifting of the limits of state action and corresponding changes in the weight of taxation are constantly affecting value and incomes. Society as a whole is made up of many groups of industry. Government is the largest of these, collecting and expending more than any individual or corporation. Government is in one aspect a consumption good. In return for its collective cost men collectively get the enjoyment of social organization, markedly in contrast with the uncertain ties and hazards of primitive communities. But[Pg 474] government becomes also a mode of social investment, an indirect agent, a productive enterprise. Wealth applied through it secures a greater product than is possible by individual action. Government can maintain lighthouses more economically than individuals could otherwise secure them.

3. The shifting boundaries of government action and the resulting changes in tax burdens continuously influence value and income. Society is made up of various industry groups, with the government being the largest, collecting and spending more than any individual or corporation. In some ways, the government functions as a consumption good. In exchange for its collective cost, people gain the benefits of social organization, which stands in stark contrast to the unpredictable bonds and risks of early communities. But[Pg 474] the government also serves as a form of social investment, acting as an indirect agent and a productive enterprise. Wealth utilized through government can generate a greater return than what individual efforts could achieve. The government can operate lighthouses more cost-effectively than individuals could manage on their own.

Apportioning of the cost

But when the government undertakes these various tasks, the expense falls unequally on individuals and affects differently their incomes. When free schools take the place of private schools, the law compels every one to contribute to education. To many individuals it is a matter of indifference whether they pay tuition or taxes, but the wealthy bachelor sometimes grumbles when forced to help in educating the day-laborer's family of twelve. The average result may be right, but individuals diverge from the average and thus have constantly a motive to attempt to change the limits of governmental action. Happily the subject is not always viewed with selfish eyes. The ethical and patriotic thought is not, "How will this affect my interests?" but, "How will it affect the general interests?" But as the question of value is always involved, men are usually found favoring or opposing a measure of taxation according as it affects their own income. Thus taxation is inevitably an economic question.

But when the government takes on these various tasks, the costs don’t fall evenly on everyone and impact incomes differently. When public schools replace private ones, the law requires everyone to contribute to education. For many people, it doesn’t matter whether they pay tuition or taxes, but a wealthy bachelor might complain when he has to help fund the education of a day laborer’s family of twelve. The average outcome might be fair, but individuals differ from that average and therefore constantly have a reason to try to change the extent of government activity. Luckily, the topic isn’t always viewed through a selfish lens. The ethical and patriotic perspective isn’t, “How will this affect my interests?” but instead, “How will it affect everyone’s interests?” However, because the question of value is always in play, people tend to support or oppose a tax measure based on how it impacts their own income. So, taxation inevitably becomes an economic issue.

§ II. FORMS OF TAXATION

The various forms of taxes
On incomes
On property
On expenditure
On business

1. Taxes usually are a portion taken from the income arising from labor or from wealth. In rare cases more than the net income of wealth may be taken, but the aim of taxation in general is to take only a portion of the income for public uses. As economic income has many sources, it may be intercepted at many different points, and taxation may take various forms. First, private income may be appropriated by a tax on income. This is the simplest in thought, but the administrative difficulties of the income-tax[Pg 475] are great in practice. It is not easy to determine the money value of the various sources of enjoyment that come into a man's possession in the course of a year, including, as the ideal requires, the immaterial gratifications along with the material. A second form is a tax on property in proportion to value. Since the value of material wealth is the capitalization of the rentals at the prevailing rate of interest, the property tax, so far as it applies to material wealth, should take an approximately equal proportion of incomes. If it were accurately assessed, it would be in some respects better than a tax on actual rents, for it reaches the prospective, or speculative, rental. A third form of tax is one on consumption, or expenditure. This is but another mode of attacking income, for in the long run income is spent, not always by the individual who earned it, but by some one, and thus it is reached by a tax on expenditure. The principal consumption taxes in the United States are the tariff duties and the internal revenues of the national government. In time of war, internal revenues are extended in the United States to a multitude of articles, but usually they are limited (with minor exceptions) to liquor and tobacco. A fourth form of tax is one on selected agencies of industry; such are business taxes, licenses, taxes on investment in business, corporation taxes, etc. These burdens are diffused and rest eventually on some income, not always exactly ascertainable. Actual tax systems combine these forms in great variety, subtracting many minute fractions from each citizen's income in ways unsuspected by him.

1. Taxes are usually a portion taken from the income earned from work or from wealth. In rare cases, more than the net income from wealth can be taken, but generally, the goal of taxation is to take only a portion of income for public purposes. Since economic income comes from many sources, it can be intercepted at various points, and taxation can take numerous forms. First, private income can be taxed as an income tax. This is the simplest conceptually, but the administrative challenges of the income tax[Pg 475] are significant in practice. It’s not easy to determine the money value of the different sources of enjoyment that a person gains over the course of a year, including, as the ideal states, the intangible benefits along with the tangible ones. The second form is a tax on property based on its value. Since the value of material wealth is calculated by the expected rent at the current interest rate, a property tax, as it pertains to material wealth, should take an approximately equal portion of incomes. If it were assessed accurately, it might be better than a tax on actual rents since it accounts for potential or speculative rent. A third form of tax is a consumption tax, or expenditure tax. This is just another way to tax income because, ultimately, income is spent, not always by the individual who earned it but by someone, and this is why it can be taxed on expenditure. The main consumption taxes in the United States are tariffs and internal revenues collected by the national government. During wartime, internal revenues are extended to a wide variety of items, but typically they are limited (with minor exceptions) to alcohol and tobacco. A fourth form of tax targets specific industries; these include business taxes, licenses, taxes on business investments, corporation taxes, etc. These burdens are distributed and ultimately fall on some income, which is not always easy to pinpoint. Actual tax systems mix these forms in various ways, deducting many small fractions from each person's income in ways they may not even realize.

Changes of taxation and in capitalization

2. The immediate effect of a change in the form of taxation is a change in the market value of goods. If the new tax reduces the net rent of any productive agent, it reduces likewise its value, which is but the capitalization of its net rental. If taxes are taken off of factories and put upon farm rents, factories rise and farm-land falls in value. The immediate change in value is much greater than the annual[Pg 476] tax, for if five dollars is to be taken permanently from the annual rental of the farm, nearly one hundred dollars is taken at once from its selling value.

2. The immediate result of changing the tax system is a change in the market value of goods. If the new tax lowers the net income of any productive asset, it also reduces its value, which is essentially the total of its net income. If taxes on factories are removed and placed on farm rents, the value of factories increases while farm land decreases. The immediate change in value is much larger than the annual[Pg 476] tax, because if five dollars is permanently deducted from the annual rental of the farm, nearly one hundred dollars is taken off its selling price at once.

Taxes are reckoned by enterprisers as a part of the cost of production whenever the conditions of competition and of substitution make it possible to do so. In such a case the products rise in price and most of the tax falls upon the consumers. In the Civil War an increase in the tax on whisky increased its selling price, and distillers who owned stocks on which a smaller tax had already been paid reaped profits of millions of dollars. When recently the tax on tea was increased in England, all dealers who had accumulated a stock before the law went into effect were gainers. Every change in taxation inevitably affects, either favorably or unfavorably, many interests. The chance to anticipate a change in tax laws or to get, from those in power, information of a proposed change, makes speculation possible and political corruption profitable.

Taxes are considered by business owners as part of the production cost whenever competition and substitution make it feasible. In such situations, product prices go up, and most of the tax burden falls on consumers. During the Civil War, an increase in the tax on whiskey raised its selling price, allowing distillers who had existing stocks with a lower tax to make millions in profits. Similarly, when the tea tax was raised in England, all dealers who had stockpiled tea before the law took effect benefited. Any change in taxation inevitably impacts many interests, whether positively or negatively. The opportunity to foresee a change in tax laws or to get information about potential changes from those in power makes speculation possible and can lead to political corruption being profitable.

Shifting and incidence of taxation

3. After every change in taxation, competition among bargainers goes on and a new equilibrium of prices results. The citizen who pays a tax into the public treasury is not always the one whose income is reduced in the long run. In most cases the final and regular burden of the tax is distributed over a number of incomes. The passing on of the burden is called the shifting of the tax; the location of the final burden is called the incidence of the tax. The lawmaker cannot tell exactly where the weight will fall. The principles of value give some guidance in the inquiry, but the workings of the principle are difficult to follow. Certain it is that the new tax, both in its collection and in its expenditure, becomes a new influence in industry. Some occupations are made more attractive, others less so. Some places are made more, others less, desirable to live in. As property thus fluctuates in value, as investments become more or less remunerative, the market price of corporation stocks rises and falls. The rate of adjustment varies greatly[Pg 477] under different conditions. The inflow and the outflow of labor and capital are more or less rapid in the various industries.

3. After every change in taxes, competition among negotiators continues, resulting in a new price equilibrium. The person who pays a tax into the public treasury isn’t always the one who ultimately sees a reduction in their income. In most situations, the final and ongoing burden of the tax is spread out across multiple incomes. The transfer of this burden is known as the shifting of the tax; the final placement of the burden is called the incidence of the tax. The lawmaker can't predict exactly where the impact will land. The principles of value provide some direction in this analysis, but the details can be hard to follow. What's certain is that the new tax, both in how it’s collected and spent, becomes a new factor in the economy. Some jobs become more appealing, while others become less so. Some areas become more, and others less, desirable places to live. As property values fluctuate and investments vary in profitability, the market price of corporate stocks rises and falls. The rate of adjustment varies significantly[Pg 477] under different circumstances. The movement of labor and capital is generally more or less swift across the various industries.

Many personal incomes affected

The fact that a change in taxation is a disturbing element in price is not to be thought insignificant merely because "all comes out right in the end." Every change in taxation is an element of uncertainty in business and increases the fortunes of some men at the expense of others. Hence no considerable change should be made without good reasons in its favor. The older taxes have the virtue of stability, but in many cases they have grown out of harmony with the industrial conditions. While, therefore, from time to time there is a real need of a reform in the tax system, it should not be undertaken without recognizing the many and complex interests involved.

The idea that a change in taxation disrupts prices shouldn't be seen as unimportant just because it "all works out in the end." Every tax change introduces uncertainty for businesses and benefits some people at the cost of others. So, no major change should happen without solid reasons to support it. Older taxes have the advantage of being stable, but in many instances, they no longer align with current industrial conditions. While there's often a genuine need for reform in the tax system, it shouldn't be approached without acknowledging the many complicated interests involved.

§ III. PRINCIPLES AND PRACTICE

Various standards of justice suggested

1. Taxation should be adjusted with reference to the general social interest. Many standards have been suggested to measure the distribution of the burden of taxation, such as benefit, equality, and ability. Each of these terms is capable of various interpretations which have changed from time to time. The benefit derived by any citizen from most of the public services evidently cannot be measured with exactness. The standard of equality cannot be applied in any literal sense to strong and weak, to rich and poor. It is possible, however, to interpret equality with reference not to objective goods, but to the psychic sacrifice occasioned by taxation. Ability thus is of many kinds and may be differently understood. Some think ability to bear taxation is "in exact proportion to the money income"; others believe that it increases at a greater rate than money income, and favor, therefore, progressive taxation, that is, higher rates on the larger incomes.

1. Taxation should be adjusted to reflect the general social interest. Many criteria have been proposed to evaluate how the tax burden is distributed, including benefit, equality, and ability. Each of these concepts can be interpreted in various ways that have evolved over time. The benefits that any citizen receives from most public services clearly can't be measured with precision. The standard of equality can't be applied literally to the strong and weak, or the rich and poor. However, it is possible to interpret equality not in terms of tangible goods, but regarding the emotional sacrifice caused by taxation. Ability comes in many forms and can be understood differently. Some people think the ability to handle taxation is "directly proportional to money income"; others believe it grows at a faster pace than money income, and therefore support progressive taxation, meaning higher rates on larger incomes.

Social welfare as the aim

The conflicting interests of the classes in each period are to some degree softened by the social conscience, and taxes are adjusted according to a vaguely held ideal of the social welfare. Social expediency, more or less broadly interpreted, determines who shall be taxed and what will give the best social results. The exemptions from taxation in feudal times were great, and viewed from our standpoint were inequitable, for it was the upper classes who escaped while the peasants bore all the burdens. The landlords and nobility who were assumed to be performing important social functions, often had outgrown their usefulness. Exemptions are granted liberally in most states to-day for some purposes and to some classes of citizens; to educational, religious, and charitable institutions; to the homes of priests and ministers; to homesteads purchased with pension money, etc. California alone of all the states in the Union continued until 1903 to tax churches and private schools. The social interest requires that taxes be both elastic and productive, so that the needs of the government shall be amply provided for. The harmonizing of these needs in the laws of taxation requires a high degree of wisdom, of foresight, and of integrity, in the legislator and in the citizen. No hard-and-fast rule for the apportioning of taxes can be laid down. The decision must be made in each generation by social opinion, guided by the social conscience.

The conflicting interests of different social classes in each period are somewhat eased by a sense of social responsibility, and taxes are adjusted based on a loosely held ideal of social welfare. The interpretation of social necessity, more or less broadly defined, dictates who gets taxed and what will yield the best social outcomes. Back in feudal times, tax exemptions were significant and, from our perspective, unfair, as it was the upper classes who avoided taxes while the peasants shouldered all the burdens. The landlords and nobility, who were thought to have important social roles, often no longer served a useful purpose. Nowadays, many states offer generous tax exemptions for various reasons and specific groups; these include educational, religious, and charitable organizations; the homes of clergy; and homesteads bought with pension funds, among others. California was the only state in the Union that continued to tax churches and private schools until 1903. The social interest demands that taxes be both flexible and effective, ensuring that government needs are fully met. Balancing these needs in tax laws requires a high level of wisdom, foresight, and integrity from both lawmakers and citizens. There can't be a fixed rule for how taxes should be allocated; the decisions must be made each generation by societal opinion, guided by social conscience.

Principles of administration

2. The administration of taxation should be economical, certain, and uniform. Whatever taxes are adopted, whether on property or income, whether at a proportional or a progressive rate, their justice and expediency depend largely on their administration. Principle and practice in this as in most affairs may go far apart. Some laws are more easily and economically executed than others. The time of collection should be as convenient as possible for the citizen, and the mode of payment should be the most simple. As to the time, method of payment, and amount, the utmost certainty is desirable. Taxation that is variable, shifting, dependent on personal whim and favoritism, is despotism. Above all,[Pg 479] the administration of the law should be uniform and impartial,—yet this is a principle most frequently departed from in practice. The assessment of taxes has to be intrusted to men with fallible judgment, imperfect knowledge, and selfish interests. The assessor is as near a despot as any agent of popular government to-day. Not infrequently it is to men incapable of earning two dollars a day in any private business that the power is given of passing judgment on the value of millions of dollars' worth of property. Under the circumstances, evils are to be expected and they occur. The small property-owner often is crushed under the unequal assessment while the large owner comes lightly off. Political friends are favored, political foes are made to suffer. Woman nearly everywhere pays more than her fair share of taxes, a fact that the advocates of woman suffrage do not fail to urge as an argument for their cause, although women's disadvantage in this matter is little greater than that of any man without special political influence.

2. The administration of taxes should be efficient, clear, and consistent. Regardless of the types of taxes implemented, whether on property or income, whether at a flat or graduated rate, their fairness and practicality depend a lot on how they are administered. Theory and practice in this area, like in many others, can be quite different. Some laws are easier and cheaper to enforce than others. Tax collection should happen at the most convenient time for citizens, and payment methods should be as straightforward as possible. The timing, payment method, and amounts should be as certain as possible. Taxation that is unpredictable, arbitrary, or influenced by personal bias is a form of tyranny. Above all, [Pg 479] the administration of the law should be consistent and fair—yet this principle is often neglected in reality. The task of assessing taxes falls to people who have flawed judgment, limited knowledge, and personal agendas. The assessor is as close to a tyrant as any representative of a democratic government today. Frequently, the authority to judge the value of millions of dollars in property is given to individuals who couldn't earn two dollars a day in a private job. Given this situation, problems are to be expected, and they do arise. Small property owners often get burdened by unfair assessments while larger owners get off easy. Political allies get preferential treatment, while political adversaries face penalties. Women almost everywhere end up paying more than their fair share of taxes, a fact that advocates for women's voting rights highlight as an argument for their cause, even though the disadvantage women face in this regard is not much greater than that of any man without special political clout.

Importance of taxation as a public question

3. The relation of taxation to private incomes makes it one of the largest public questions of the day. The discussion of taxation has accompanied the growth of free government in England and America from the time of Magna Charta. The control of the public purse frequently was the occasion of conflict between the monarch and the people. Taxation was a leading issue in the American Revolution. While, therefore, it cannot be said that the subject has been of no great importance in the past, it is true that in our own national history since the adoption of the Constitution, taxation has not been much discussed, except in the one aspect of the tariff. Constitutional and political questions, states rights, and the question of slavery, long absorbed the interest of citizens and legislators. But with the aroused interest of the public in economic problems, taxation is attracting, and is certain to attract in the next few years, increasing attention in local, commonwealth, and national politics.

3. The relationship between taxation and private incomes makes it one of the biggest public issues today. The conversation around taxation has been part of the growth of free government in England and America since the time of the Magna Carta. Control over public funds often led to conflicts between the monarch and the people. Taxation was a major issue during the American Revolution. While it can't be claimed that this topic has never been important in the past, it's true that in our national history since the Constitution was adopted, taxation hasn’t been widely discussed, except for the tariff. Constitutional and political questions, states' rights, and the issue of slavery occupied the interests of citizens and lawmakers for a long time. However, with the rising public interest in economic issues, taxation is gaining attention and is likely to become even more significant in local, state, and national politics in the coming years.


CHAPTER 50

THE GENERAL THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE

§ I. INTERNATIONAL TRADE AS A CASE OF EXCHANGE

The motive of individual gain in foreign trade

1. International trade is exchange between individual men, and has the same object as other exchange of goods. The term international trade should not be misunderstood as meaning that nations rather than individuals engage in it. International trade differs from domestic trade only in the fact that the parties are citizens of different sovereign states. Exchanges between men in the same village, between those in neighboring villages, and between those in different countries, are prompted by essentially the same economic motive—the wish to increase the want-gratifying power of goods. In every such case both parties gain or think they are gaining. In international trade there is the same chance for mistake as in domestic trade, but no more. In a single transaction in either domestic or foreign trade one party may be cheated, but the continuance of trade relations is dependent on continued benefits. The once generally accepted maxim that the gain of one in trade is the loss of another, is rarely applied now except to international trade. The starting point for the consideration of this subject is in this proposition: Foreign trade is carried on by individuals, for individual gain, with the same motives and for the same benefits as are found in other trade.

1. International trade is the exchange between individual people and serves the same purpose as other trade in goods. The term international trade shouldn't be confused to mean that countries, instead of individuals, participate in it. International trade only differs from domestic trade in that the people involved are citizens of different sovereign states. Exchanges between people in the same village, those in neighboring villages, and those in different countries are driven by essentially the same economic motivation—the desire to enhance the ability of goods to satisfy wants. In each case, both parties benefit or believe they benefit. In international trade, there’s the same potential for mistakes as in domestic trade, but not more. In a single transaction in either domestic or foreign trade, one party may be deceived, but ongoing trade relationships rely on ongoing advantages. The once widely accepted idea that one party's gain in trade is another's loss is now rarely applied outside of international trade. The starting point for discussing this topic is this idea: Foreign trade is conducted by individuals, for their own benefit, with the same motivations and for the same rewards that exist in other types of trade.

Natural differences affecting foreign trade
Political boundaries and trade

2. As commerce has grown, the territorial division of labor has correspondingly increased. Although economic[Pg 481] motives have had influence in political affairs and have helped to determine political groupings and the limits of modern nations, there is to-day no very close correspondence between political and economic boundary lines. Both industrial and political conditions have changed so rapidly that the lines often have tended to diverge rather than to agree. It is common for two portions of a nation to exchange far less than do two portions of entirely different nations. The great territorial divisions of industry are determined first and mainly by differences of climate, soil, and natural resources. Thus trade arises easily between north and south, between warm and frigid climes, between new countries and old, between regions sparsely and regions densely populated. Foreign trade with distant lands is as old as history. In medieval times the luxuries of the temperate zone were mostly articles produced in the tropics. Political divisions usually have not been large enough to embrace widely varied soils and climates, the Roman Empire being an exception in marked contrast with the comparatively small political units of the Middle Ages. Before modern methods of transportation, a large free federal state like our republic was impossible. As in recent centuries the large political units have been formed, the question has arisen, Shall the political boundary be likewise the economic boundary marking the limits of trade? The firm constitutional Union of the American states arose out of difficulties with regard to trade. The German Zollverein, the forerunner of the modern German Empire, had a similar origin. The Australian Federation consummated within the last few years has grown out of the need of adjusting tariffs and tariff boundaries. These larger political units containing such varied resources can in larger measure, but never completely, become independent of the rest of the world if they will.

2. As trade has expanded, the division of labor by region has also increased. Although economic[Pg 481] factors have influenced political matters and have shaped political groups and the borders of modern nations, today there’s not a close match between political and economic boundaries. Both industrial and political circumstances have changed so quickly that the boundaries often drift apart instead of aligning. It’s common for two parts of a country to trade far less with each other than with two regions from completely different countries. The significant divisions of industry are primarily influenced by variations in climate, soil, and natural resources. Therefore, trade flows easily between northern and southern areas, between warm and cold climates, between new nations and old ones, and between densely and sparsely populated regions. Foreign trade with far-off countries is as old as time. In medieval times, the luxuries of the temperate zone were mostly produced in tropical regions. Political divisions typically haven’t been extensive enough to cover widely varying soils and climates, with the Roman Empire being a notable exception compared to the smaller political units of the Middle Ages. Before modern transportation methods, a large, free federal state like our republic wasn’t feasible. As larger political entities have formed in recent centuries, the question has emerged: Should political borders also serve as economic borders defining trade limits? The strong constitutional Union of the American states developed from trade-related conflicts. The German Customs Union, which led to the modern German Empire, originated similarly. The Australian Federation, established in the last few years, arose from the need to reconcile tariffs and tariff boundaries. These bigger political units, with their diverse resources, can mostly, but never entirely, become independent of the rest of the world if they choose to do so.

Differences in culture and industry

Territorial division of trade is determined secondly by differences in the accumulation of wealth, in the development[Pg 482] of capital, of invention, and of organization, in the degree of intelligence of the workers, and in the grade of civilization. It is mainly trade due to this second group of causes, and carried on between old and new countries of about the same latitude, that is the subject of discussion in economic treatises on international trade.

Territorial division of trade is influenced secondly by differences in wealth accumulation, the development of capital, invention, and organization, as well as the intelligence of workers and the level of civilization. This type of trade, driven mainly by this second group of factors and occurring between old and new countries at similar latitudes, is the focus of discussions in economic studies on international trade.

Comparative costs as between individual workers

3. The doctrine of comparative costs is that relative, not absolute, advantages of production determine for a country the benefits of international trade. The free-trade question in any country is whether it is for its interests as a whole to permit trade between its citizens and the citizens of other countries. The question appears especially difficult where both countries have natural resources of about the same character (as iron and coal in the case of England and America), and where, therefore, both can produce the things that are exchanged. If American labor can produce as much iron in a day as English labor,—or more,—is it not foolish and wasteful, it is asked, not to produce that wealth? Now, exactly the same case is presented in simple neighborhood exchanges. The merchant may be able to keep his books better than does the bookkeeper whom he employs. The proprietor may be able to sweep out the store better than the cheap boy does it. The carpenter may be able to raise better vegetables than can the gardener from whom he purchases, and yet the merchant and the carpenter do not quit their better-paying work and turn to clerking or to raising vegetables.

3. The principle of comparative costs means that it's the relative, not absolute, advantages of production that decide the benefits of international trade for a country. The debate over free trade in any country is whether it's in the best interest of the country as a whole to allow trade between its citizens and those from other countries. This question becomes especially complicated when both countries have similar natural resources (like iron and coal in the case of England and America), making it possible for both to produce the items being traded. If American workers can produce as much iron in a day as English workers—or even more—people question whether it's wasteful not to generate that wealth. The same scenario can be seen in simple neighborhood exchanges. A merchant might be better at keeping books than the bookkeeper he employs. The store owner might be able to clean the store more effectively than the low-paid worker doing it. The carpenter might be able to grow better vegetables than the gardener he buys from, yet neither the merchant nor the carpenter abandons their higher-paying jobs to take up bookkeeping or vegetable gardening.

As between communities differing in advantages

It often happens that both countries can technically produce both the articles that are internationally exchanged. It may frequently happen that one of the two countries has an advantage in amount of sacrifice and effort, as to both articles; but if the advantage is greater in one article than in the other, the foreigners, like the low-paid clerk, will be willing to exchange at a ratio that will make it profitable to specialize in the product wherein the greater superiority lies. Therefore not the advantage as to a single product, enjoyed by one country over the other is most important[Pg 483] in determining whether to produce at home or to exchange, but the comparative advantages enjoyed in the production of the two articles in question.

It often happens that both countries can technically produce the goods that are exchanged internationally. It may frequently occur that one of the countries has an edge in terms of sacrifice and effort for both goods; however, if this advantage is more significant in one product than in the other, the foreigners, like the low-paid clerk, will be willing to trade at a ratio that makes it beneficial to focus on the product where that greater advantage exists. Therefore, the key factor in deciding whether to produce domestically or to trade is not just the advantage one country has over the other in a single product[Pg 483], but the comparative advantages in producing both goods being discussed.

Examples of comparative costs

It must be remembered that comparative cost as here used refers to cost in effort, not to money cost,—a point on which there is often confusion. The money cost of a certain product is often greater in a new country because wages are high, and wages are high just because psychic cost is low, that is, because labor can produce so much. At the time of the great gold discoveries in 1849-50, the price of goods in California was much higher than in the East, and much higher in Australia than in Europe. A day's labor doubtless would produce as much food in Australia and in California as in New England and in Norway, but it produced far more gold. Hence butter and cheese were shipped by long routes from Norway to Australia and from New England around Cape Horn to California, to be exchanged for gold. One of the standing arguments against foreign trade is based on the idea that a country cannot profitably import goods unless it is at an absolute disadvantage in their production. It is declared that as our country can produce these goods "as well" as foreign countries (meaning with as few days' labor), there is a loss on every unit imported.

It should be noted that comparative cost, as used here, refers to effort, not monetary cost—a point that often causes confusion. The monetary cost of a certain product can be higher in a new country because wages are elevated, and wages are high because the psychic cost is low, meaning labor can produce so much. During the major gold discoveries in 1849-50, the prices of goods in California were much higher than in the East, and significantly higher in Australia than in Europe. A day's work would likely yield as much food in Australia and California as in New England and Norway, but it produced far more gold. This is why butter and cheese were transported long distances from Norway to Australia and from New England around Cape Horn to California in exchange for gold. One common argument against foreign trade is based on the idea that a country cannot profitably import goods unless it has an absolute disadvantage in producing them. It is claimed that since our country can produce these goods "just as well" as foreign countries (meaning with as few days' labor), there is a loss on every unit imported.

Selection of the most paying industries

4. The equation of international exchange is that adjustment of prices which results in the equalizing of the imports and exports of the country. The superiority of a new country over an old one is not equally great in every line of industry. It is almost certainly most marked in those enterprises where natural resources are employed. To compete with the older country in less favored industries, capital and labor in the new are forced to take a lower rate than they can earn in the more favored. Without any government supervision, therefore, but simply through the choice of enterprisers seeking the best investment of capital, industries are developed in which the country is either most markedly superior or least inferior to its neighbors.

4. The equation of international trade is the adjustment of prices that balances a country's imports and exports. The advantages of a new country compared to an old one aren't equally strong across all industries. They're usually most significant in sectors that utilize natural resources. To compete with the older country in less advantageous industries, capital and labor in the new country have to accept lower wages than they would earn in more advantageous sectors. So, without any government oversight, but simply through the choices of entrepreneurs looking for the best ways to invest their capital, industries develop where the country has a clear advantage or is at least less behind its neighbors.

If the productive energies of men interchanged between industries and between countries with perfect readiness, a perfect equilibrium of advantage would everywhere result. In every country, in every occupation, labor and capital of given quality and amount would receive the same reward. But the interchange of labor and capital between countries is never without friction. Adam Smith said that "a man is of all sorts of luggage the most difficult to be transported." The higher wages in a new country are sufficient to attract constantly from the older lands a portion of their labor supply; the higher rate of interest in the new countries attracts constant additions of capital; yet, despite these forces working toward equalization, the inequality may remain and through the working of other influences even increase in the course of years.

If people's productive energies easily shifted between industries and countries, there would be a perfect balance of benefits everywhere. In every country and every job, labor and capital of the same quality and quantity would receive equal rewards. However, the movement of labor and capital between countries is never frictionless. Adam Smith noted that "a man is of all sorts of luggage the most difficult to be transported." The higher wages in a new country are enough to consistently draw some of the workforce away from older countries; similarly, the higher interest rates in new countries attract ongoing investments of capital. Yet, despite these forces pushing for balance, disparities can persist and even grow over time due to other influences.

Persistence of the differences

The laborers, enterprisers, and investors in the one country are thus in a position of more or less enduring advantage relative to those of the other countries. The advantage is sometimes said to be a "monopoly" which they, or the country as a whole, enjoy; but in the absence of any contractual limiting of competition, this is a misuse of the term monopoly. This variation in the degree of scarcity of agents in different territories is not peculiar to nations as a whole. Differences of the same nature exist between the Northern and the Southern states of the American Union, have continued for decades between Eastern and Western states, and are found even between neighboring counties. The differences between two countries, however, are likely to be more marked, the circulation of factors being so active within a country that it is allowable to speak broadly of prevailing national rates of wages and of interest.

The workers, entrepreneurs, and investors in one country have a relatively stable advantage over those in other countries. This advantage is sometimes referred to as a "monopoly" that they, or the country as a whole, possess; however, without any contractual limitations on competition, this use of the term monopoly is incorrect. The variation in the availability of resources across different regions isn't unique to nations as a whole. Similar differences exist between the Northern and Southern states of the United States, have persisted for decades between Eastern and Western states, and can even be found between neighboring counties. However, the differences between two countries are likely to be more pronounced since factors of production circulate so actively within a country that it's reasonable to generally discuss national rates of wages and interest.

The ratio of international demand defined

Every exchange of goods between the countries is made at a ratio that reflects, or expresses, this abiding difference in comparative costs. The imports into the favored country represent regularly the results of more units of labor of a given grade than do the corresponding exports. The ratio[Pg 485] which expresses the disparity of advantage of productive factors is called "the equation of international demand." This does not mean that the money value of the imports exceeds that of the exports, or vice versa. On the contrary, the equation itself embodies a maxim of international trade that "in the long run," or "on the average," imports and exports must be equal in value (i.e., equation of demand). This brings us to the theory of foreign exchanges, which is essential to an understanding of this feature of international trade.

Every exchange of goods between countries happens at a rate that reflects this ongoing difference in comparative costs. The imports into the favored country usually involve more units of labor of a certain quality compared to the corresponding exports. The ratio[Pg 485] that shows the disparity of advantage in productive factors is known as "the equation of international demand." This doesn't mean that the monetary value of imports is greater than that of exports, or the other way around. In fact, the equation itself illustrates a principle of international trade that "in the long run," or "on average," imports and exports must be equal in value (i.e., equation of demand). This leads us to the theory of foreign exchanges, which is crucial for understanding this aspect of international trade.

§ II. THEORY OF FOREIGN EXCHANGES OF MONEY

Purpose of foreign exchange
The rate of foreign exchange

1. Foreign exchange of money is the purchase and sale of the right to receive a given kind and weight of metal at a specified time and place. Par of exchange is the number of units of the standard coin of one country that contain the same amount of fine gold (or silver) as the standard coin of the other country. Usually the English pound is taken as the basis in the tables which express the ratio of the gold in the standard coins of different countries. The gold shipping point is par of exchange plus or minus the cost of moving the actual metal; it varies with means of transportation and communication. The par of exchange between England and America being $4.866 and the cost of expressing and insuring a gold pound between New York and London being approximately .03, the shipping point for the export of gold from New York is $4.896. At the upper and lower limits, there is a motive for shipping gold as a commodity. If each transaction were independent of all others, the cost of exchange would be the weight of metal called for, plus grains enough more to pay for loss of interest, cost of freight, risk, and trouble. In such a case it would cost $4.896 to remit one pound; while a debt of one pound payable in London would at the same time be worth $4.836 to the creditor in New York. When, in New York, a number of men having[Pg 486] bills to pay in London meet a number of owners of bills receivable in London, a market for London drafts is created and a rate of exchange results somewhere between the shipping points. In this is the explanation of the variation of the rate, and of the facts that the cost of outward exchange sometimes is less than the par of exchange and that the value of foreign drafts sometimes is above par.

1. Foreign exchange of money is the buying and selling of the right to receive a specific kind and weight of metal at a certain time and place. The par of exchange is the number of units of the standard currency of one country that hold the same amount of fine gold (or silver) as the standard currency of another country. Typically, the British pound serves as the basis in tables that show the gold ratio in the standard coins of different nations. The gold shipping point is the par of exchange plus or minus the cost of moving the actual metal; it varies based on transportation and communication methods. With the par of exchange between England and America at $4.866 and the cost of sending and insuring a gold pound from New York to London being about .03, the shipping point for exporting gold from New York is $4.896. At both upper and lower limits, there is an incentive to ship gold as a commodity. If each transaction were separate from others, the cost of exchange would be the weight of the metal required, plus extra grains to cover loss of interest, shipping costs, risks, and hassle. In that situation, it would cost $4.896 to send one pound; meanwhile, a one-pound debt due in London would be valued at $4.836 to the creditor in New York. When, in New York, a group of people with[Pg 486] bills to pay in London meets a group of people who have bills receivable in London, a market for London drafts is formed, creating an exchange rate that falls somewhere between the shipping points. This explains the fluctuations in the rate and why sometimes the cost of outward exchange is lower than the par of exchange and why the value of foreign drafts can sometimes exceed par.

Variation about par of exchange

The balancing of foreign exchanges is of essentially the same nature as the domestic cancelation of indebtedness. It is going on constantly between two merchants in the same town, between two banks in the same town who represent groups of merchants, between men in neighboring towns, between distant states like New York and California, and between the trading nations of the world. The price of exchange to the individual is reduced by the specializing of the business in the hands of a few dealers, permitting cancelation of indebtedness or offsetting of exchange, and greatly reducing the amount of bullion to be transported. Exchange varies above and below par as conditions change. When the movement of money is into the country, drafts on London are bought and sold for less than par, for every pound draft thus remitted to London reduces the need of shipping gold to this country, while every London draft collected in New York at such a time increases the need to ship gold.

The balancing of foreign exchanges is basically the same as settling debts domestically. It happens all the time between two merchants in the same city, between two banks in the same city that represent groups of merchants, between people in neighboring towns, between far-off states like New York and California, and between trading nations around the globe. The cost of exchange for individuals is lowered by specializing the business among a few dealers, allowing for the cancellation of debts or offsetting exchanges, which significantly decreases the amount of gold that needs to be transported. Exchange rates fluctuate above and below par as conditions change. When money flows into the country, drafts on London are bought and sold for less than par, because every pound draft sent to London reduces the need to ship gold to this country, while every London draft collected in New York at that time increases the need to ship gold.

The cash balance of international trade

2. International shipment of money is always just the amount needed to balance the accounts due. The proposition that in the long run the value of imports must equal the value of exports, while the fundamental truth in the theory of international trade, must be understood in a broad sense. Into the balance between the traders of two nations enter many items: the cash values of the imports and exports of each; freights, insurance premiums, and commissions; the expense of Americans traveling in foreign lands, and the cost of the foreign service of this government (such as the salaries of consuls and of diplomatic representatives)[Pg 487] which count as the importation to America of an equivalent amount of food, clothing, and sundry services; subsidies and war indemnities to foreign nations representing, as they do, an expenditure, which at the moment may be paid in coin, but which, as is to be more fully explained, must be offset ultimately in some way by exports.

2. International money transfers are usually just enough to settle the accounts owed. The idea that over time the value of imports must match the value of exports, while a key principle in international trade theory, needs to be understood in a broader context. The balance between traders from two countries includes many factors: the cash values of their imports and exports; shipping costs, insurance fees, and commissions; the expenses of Americans traveling abroad, and the costs related to the foreign services of our government (like the salaries of consuls and diplomatic representatives)[Pg 487] which count as imports to America equivalent to an amount of food, clothing, and various services; subsidies and war reparations to foreign countries representing, as they do, an expense that may currently be paid in cash, but which, as will be explained in more detail, must eventually be balanced out by exports.

Various credit items entering into the balance

Many credit transactions affect the balance one way or another until settled. The loans made by European capital to the American government or to individuals and corporations in America, as well as the European capital expended in purchasing American enterprises, require the remitting of gold to New York, and thus offset many imports of goods to New York otherwise calling for the remitting of gold to London. In the direction opposite to this, act the interest payments and the eventual repayment of the principal loan, for these require either money or goods to be exported from America to the value of the obligations. Loans that run for years thus offset annually (in their accruing interest) a portion of the exports of the debtor country. An excess of exports may therefore at any given moment indicate either that the country is in debt or that it is getting out of debt. An excess of exports is generally looked upon as an evidence of national prosperity; but it is absolutely inconclusive on the point. Finally, after all the items of imports and credit paper purchased abroad are set opposite the items of exports and promissory papers sold abroad, the balance is paid in gold bullion and is shipped one way or the other. Evidently the amount of gold shipped is but a small fraction of the total volume of transactions.

Many credit transactions impact the balance in various ways until they're settled. The loans made by European investors to the American government or to individuals and companies in the U.S., along with the European money spent on buying American businesses, require the transfer of gold to New York. This offsets many imports of goods to New York that would otherwise need gold sent to London. In the opposite direction, interest payments and the eventual repayment of the principal loan involve either money or goods being exported from America equal to the value of the obligations. Loans that last for years hence reduce (through their accruing interest) a portion of the debtor country's exports each year. An excess of exports at any given time might suggest that the country is in debt or that it's reducing its debt. Generally, a surplus of exports is seen as a sign of national prosperity, but it doesn't definitively prove it. Ultimately, after balancing all the items of imports and credit papers bought abroad against the items of exports and promissory papers sold abroad, the remaining balance is settled in gold bullion, which is shipped either way. Clearly, the gold shipped is just a small part of the total volume of transactions.

Industrial indebtedness is represented in various forms: bills of lading for goods shipped, drafts made by the creditor on his debtor for goods shipped or property sold, checks or letters of credit of travelers, bonds and notes public and private. These are the objects dealt in by the bankers who are the agents to carry on the work of exchange.

Industrial debt appears in different forms: shipping documents for goods delivered, drafts created by creditors on their debtors for goods sent or property sold, traveler’s checks or letters of credit, and both public and private bonds and notes. These are the items handled by bankers, who act as agents to facilitate the work of exchange.

Relations of the international flow of goods to the flow of money

3. The territorial distribution of money is both a determined[Pg 488] and a determining factor in international trade. It appears to be determined in that the balance of all accounts for or against the country must be settled eventually in money. After any such a settlement one country has less, the other more money than before. The change in the amount of money at once reacts on prices and becomes a determining factor in international trade. The flow of money out of a country causes money to tighten, interest rates on short loans in the large cities to stiffen, and prices slightly to fall. When prices fall, imports decline, as the country is not so good a place to sell in; when prices rise, imports increase, as it is a better place to sell in. As the opposite effect is produced on exports, there occurs immediately a change in the quantity of money which continues until the national credits and debits balance and for a brief time remain in equilibrium. If the trade of a country with its neighbors continued long to give a balance of imports of goods and of debit items (exclusive of money) it would ultimately be drained of all its coin, and would default payment or cease to import. If the trade constantly gave a balance of exports and credit items, money would continue to flow in, until prices rose to unexampled heights. In fact no such extreme is even remotely approached, for a slight movement of money in either direction at once influences prices and sets in motion counteracting forces. Decade after decade the circulating medium of leading countries changes only slightly in amount, and the fluctuations during periods of so-called "favorable balance of trade" and of "unfavorable balance of trade" represent only the smallest fraction of the value of goods passing through the ports of the country.

3. The geographical distribution of money is both a set[Pg 488] and a key factor in international trade. It seems to be set because the balance of all accounts for or against a country must eventually be settled in money. After any such settlement, one country ends up with less money, while the other has more than before. The change in the amount of money immediately affects prices and becomes a key influence in international trade. When money flows out of a country, it causes money to become scarce, interest rates on short loans in large cities to rise, and prices to slightly drop. When prices drop, imports decrease because the country is less favorable for selling; when prices rise, imports increase since it's a better place to sell. The opposite effect occurs with exports, leading to an immediate change in the money supply that continues until national credits and debits balance and briefly remain stable. If a country's trade with its neighbors consistently results in a surplus of imports and debit items (excluding money), it would ultimately run out of coin and stop making payments or cease imports altogether. If trade constantly results in a surplus of exports and credit items, money would keep flowing in until prices surged to unprecedented levels. In reality, such extremes are never reached, as even a slight movement of money in either direction quickly influences prices and triggers opposing forces. Year after year, the amount of circulating currency in leading countries changes only slightly, and the fluctuations during phases of so-called "favorable balance of trade" and "unfavorable balance of trade" account for just a tiny fraction of the value of goods moving through the ports of the country.

§ III. REAL BENEFITS OF FOREIGN TRADE

Fallacious explanations of the gains from foreign trade

1. The direct advantages of foreign trade consist in the increased efficiency it imparts to productive forces. In explanation of the advantages of foreign trade it is said to be[Pg 489] a vent for surplus production and to give a wider market to what would otherwise go to waste. This involves the same fallacy as the "lump of labor," the destruction of machinery, and the praise of luxury. If backward nations now give a vent for products which would otherwise rot in the warehouses, at length a time will come when the world will have an enormous surplus unless neighboring planets can be successively annexed. Again it is said that the great purpose of foreign trade is to keep exports in excess of imports so that money may constantly increase in amount. The ideal of such theorists is an impossible condition where the country would constantly sell and never buy. In the commercial view the sole object of foreign trade is to afford a profit to the merchants, regardless of the welfare of the mass of the citizens.

1. The main benefits of foreign trade come from the increased efficiency it brings to production. It is often explained that foreign trade acts as[Pg 489]

The real advantages of foreign trade

The main advantage of foreign trade is the same as that of any other exchange. It is hardly necessary to review the explanation here: the increased efficiency of labor when it is applied in the way for which each country is best fitted; the liberation of productive forces for the best uses; the development of special branches of industry with increasing returns; the larger scale production with resulting greater use of machinery and with increased chance of invention; the destruction of local monopolies.

The primary benefit of foreign trade is similar to that of any other exchange. It’s not really necessary to delve into the explanation here: labor becomes more efficient when it's applied in the way that each country is most suited for; productive forces are freed up for their most effective uses; specific industries develop with increasing returns; production scales up, resulting in greater machinery usage and more opportunities for innovation; and local monopolies are broken down.

The moral and intellectual gains of foreign commerce were formerly much emphasized. Commerce is an agent of progress; it stimulates the arts and sciences; it creates bonds of common interest; it gives an understanding of foreign peoples and an appreciation of their merits; it raises a commercial and moral barrier to war; and it furthers the ideal of a world federation, the brotherhood of man.

The moral and intellectual benefits of international trade were once heavily highlighted. Trade is a driver of progress; it encourages the arts and sciences; it creates connections of shared interests; it fosters an understanding of other cultures and an appreciation of their strengths; it builds a commercial and ethical barrier against war; and it promotes the vision of a global federation, the unity of humanity.

Conflict between general and special interests
Prevalence of protective tariffs

2. Free foreign trade thus has in its favor the presumption of advantage to the citizens; but various interests may be adversely affected. The general attitude of economic students for a century and a half has been favorable to a large measure of freedom in foreign trade. But the actual[Pg 490] practice of nations is opposed to the principles laid down by the philosophers and accepted by nearly all serious students of the question. Germany adopted very restrictive measures under Bismarck in 1879 and by a recent law has discouraged trade still further. France, Italy, and other smaller nations of Europe have strong protective tariffs. The United States has followed a restrictive policy for the last century almost unvaryingly. The explanation of this contradiction is not entirely simple. Free trade is not the most desirable thing for every one. Great interests are affected by foreign trade and certain of these interests are able to dominate legislation. The general proposition of free trade between nations, as advocated by most economists since Adam Smith, is rejected by a majority of the people, by the politicians, and by the legislators.

2. Free foreign trade generally seems beneficial to citizens; however, various interests may be negatively impacted. For the past century and a half, the general perspective among economics students has been supportive of significant freedom in foreign trade. Yet, the actual[Pg 490] actions of countries contradict the principles established by philosophers and accepted by nearly all serious scholars on the topic. Germany implemented highly restrictive measures under Bismarck in 1879 and has recently introduced laws that further discourage trade. France, Italy, and several smaller nations in Europe maintain strong protective tariffs. The United States has consistently upheld a restrictive policy for almost the entire last century. The reason for this contradiction isn't entirely straightforward. Free trade isn't ideal for everyone. Major interests are influenced by foreign trade, and some of these interests can dominate legislation. The general idea of free trade between nations, supported by most economists since Adam Smith, is opposed by a majority of the population, politicians, and lawmakers.


CHAPTER 51

THE PROTECTIVE TARIFF

§ I. THE NATURE AND CLAIMS OF PROTECTION

Nature of a tariff for revenue

1. A protective tariff is a schedule of import duties so arranged as to give appreciably more favorable conditions to some domestic industries than they would enjoy with free trade. Tariff duties were first laid to get revenues for the government. The first effect of the tariff is the same as that of any tax that enters as a new factor into enterpriser's cost—the domestic price of the taxed article tends to rise. Other results then follow. If the article cannot be produced within the country (as oranges, spices, and coffee, in England, Norway, and Sweden), its consumption is reduced. The lessening of demand may affect somewhat the price in the producing country and may compel the foreign producers to sell each unit for less than before. As such a tariff does not increase home production, it is for revenue, not for protection.

1. A protective tariff is a set of import duties designed to provide significantly better conditions for certain domestic industries than they would have under free trade. Tariff duties were initially implemented to generate revenue for the government. The immediate effect of the tariff is similar to any tax that adds a new expense to the costs for businesses—the domestic price of the taxed item tends to increase. Other effects then follow. If the item cannot be produced within the country (like oranges, spices, and coffee in England, Norway, and Sweden), its consumption decreases. The drop in demand may slightly impact the price in the producing country and might force foreign producers to sell each unit for less than before. Since such a tariff does not boost local production, it exists for revenue, not for protection.

Effects upon home industry

But if the article can be produced in the importing country at the new price, "home industries" will start. If the whole demand at home is thus supplied, imports stop and therewith stop all revenues to the government from that source. This is a prohibitive or completely protective tariff. Most tariffs combine the characters both of revenue and protective measures. Where the freight charges are low along the coast and on the main lines of transportation, some imports take place; while farther inland, where freight charges are high, some home production of the same goods takes place.[Pg 492] A tariff that reduces imports but does not cut them off entirely is either a revenue tariff with incidental protection or a protective tariff with incidental revenue. The difference is partly one of legislative intention, partly one of degree only.

But if the product can be made in the importing country at the new price, "home industries" will begin. If all the demand at home is met this way, imports will stop, which will also stop all government revenue from that source. This is a prohibitive or completely protective tariff. Most tariffs serve both revenue-generating and protective purposes. When freight charges are low along the coast and on major transportation routes, some imports occur; while further inland, where freight charges are higher, some domestic production of the same goods takes place.[Pg 492] A tariff that reduces imports but doesn’t eliminate them completely is either a revenue tariff with some protection or a protective tariff with some revenue. The difference is partly based on legislative intent and partly a matter of degree.

The beginning of the tariff under the Constitution

2. The tariff question has been the most discussed of economic questions in American politics. The tariff bill passed by the first session of Congress in 1789 was primarily a revenue measure with rates averaging only about five per cent.; but incidentally it was protective (as most tariffs are), being laid on imports of iron and cloth, the production of which had been undertaken to some extent before, but which thus were further encouraged. Between 1808 and 1812, the United States and England were in constant disagreement, and our government repeatedly laid an embargo on British commerce, closing our ports to British ships, and British ports to our ships. The war from 1812 to 1815 almost annihilated American trade on the ocean. Added to this discouragement of foreign trade was the high tariff imposed, in the vain effort to get revenue from greatly decreased imports. Altogether these causes almost completely stopped importation and forced the American people to rely on their own efforts for such goods. Some industries having been "stimulated" in a high degree, their destruction was threatened by the repeal of the high war tariffs. Many investments and interests were at stake, and the tariff became a most important question.

2. The tariff issue has been the most talked-about economic question in American politics. The tariff bill that passed in the first session of Congress in 1789 was mainly a revenue measure, with rates averaging only about five percent; but it was also protective (as most tariffs are), applying to imports of iron and cloth, industries that had been developing to some extent before but were further encouraged by this. Between 1808 and 1812, the United States and England were in constant conflict, and our government repeatedly imposed an embargo on British trade, closing our ports to British ships and British ports to ours. The war from 1812 to 1815 nearly obliterated American trade on the ocean. On top of this discouragement of foreign trade was the high tariff imposed in a futile attempt to generate revenue from drastically reduced imports. Together, these factors almost completely halted imports and forced the American people to depend on their own resources for goods. Some industries that had been "stimulated" significantly faced destruction with the repeal of the high war tariffs. Many investments and interests were at risk, making the tariff a crucial issue.

The tariff controversy before 1865

The first period of real discussion of the protective policy was between 1816 and 1846. The result of the first twelve years was an increase of the tariff rates which, in 1828, reached a high point. By the compromise of 1832, the rates were reduced by steps till 1841. Again from 1842 to 1846 was a brief period of higher duties, followed by a policy which, relatively speaking, was one for revenue, from 1846 to 1860. Again in the Civil War, 1861-65, the rates were steadily increased without much discussion, the tariff not[Pg 493] being the leading question at a time when the prosecution of the war was absorbing nearly all attention.

The first real discussions about the protective policy happened between 1816 and 1846. In the first twelve years, tariff rates increased, peaking in 1828. Following the compromise of 1832, the rates were gradually reduced until 1841. Then, from 1842 to 1846, there was a short period of higher duties, after which a policy focused more on revenue was adopted from 1846 to 1860. During the Civil War, from 1861 to 1865, rates were steadily raised without much debate, as the tariff wasn’t the main issue at a time when the war was taking up almost all of the attention.

Recent discussion of the tariff

The latest period of discussion was from 1874 to 1892. In the Tilden and Hayes campaign of 1876 the tariff was made the leading issue and the advocates of a lower tariff were very nearly successful. In 1880, protection again triumphed in the election of Garfield. In the election of Cleveland in 1884, the issue of tariff reform had some part, but no effective legislation on the subject was enacted in the next four years. In 1888, Cleveland was defeated in a campaign fought mainly on the tariff issue, and Harrison was elected as a pronounced protectionist. In 1892, Cleveland was reëlected on the issue of tariff reform. From that time, however, there has been a lull in the discussion of the tariff question. The campaign of 1892 was the last presidential election in which the tariff was the dominant issue. Since 1896, the money question and imperialism have quite crowded the tariff issue off the stage.

The most recent period of discussion was from 1874 to 1892. During the Tilden and Hayes campaign of 1876, the tariff became the main issue, and supporters of a lower tariff came very close to winning. In 1880, protection once again won out with Garfield's election. In the 1884 election, Cleveland’s campaign included tariff reform, but no significant legislation was passed on the issue during the following four years. In 1888, Cleveland lost in a campaign primarily focused on the tariff, and Harrison, a strong protectionist, was elected. In 1892, Cleveland was re-elected based on the promise of tariff reform. However, since then, discussions about the tariff have slowed down. The 1892 campaign was the last presidential election where the tariff was the central issue. Since 1896, topics like the money question and imperialism have largely overshadowed the tariff debate.

The "balance of trade" argument

3. A leading argument in favor of a protective tariff is that by encouraging an excess of exports it maintains a favorable balance of trade. This notion of the favorable balance of trade appears in several forms. One of these, already discussed in connection with foreign exchanges, is that the exports of a country in the form of merchandise must exceed the imports if the country is to prosper. The ideal cherished is to keep more merchandise constantly flowing out of the country than comes in. An interesting commentary on this delusion is the fact that this is the usual situation in poor debtor countries having constant interest payments to meet; while the opposite of the ideal is the situation in rich creditor countries. England for many years in the period of her greatest prosperity has had a constant excess of imports, these being goods to the value of the interest payments due to Englishmen from investments abroad.

3. One main argument for a protective tariff is that by promoting an increase in exports, it helps maintain a favorable balance of trade. This idea of a favorable balance of trade appears in various ways. One, which we've already talked about in relation to foreign exchanges, is that a country's exports in the form of goods must be greater than its imports for that country to thrive. The goal is to have more goods consistently leaving the country than coming in. An interesting observation about this misconception is that it's typically the case in poor debtor countries that have ongoing interest payments to make; whereas the opposite scenario tends to be true in wealthy creditor countries. For many years during its peak prosperity, England had a consistent surplus of imports, which were goods equivalent to the interest payments owed to English investors from overseas investments.

"To keep money at home"

4. Another argument is that the protective tariff keeps money at home which, if trade is free, will be sent abroad to[Pg 494] buy foreign goods, thus impoverishing the country. This is the "favorable balance of trade" argument, with the emphasis on money rather than on goods. A superficial glance at the trade relations of an old and rich country with a new province seems to give evidence for such a belief. The older country is lending capital (which it sends to the debtor country in the form of goods) and it has at the same time a larger supply of money. These two facts—the lack of money and the poverty of the newer country—are looked upon by the protectionist as due to the importation of goods. The real cause of the imports to the newer country and of its scanty money-supply, it need hardly be said, is its comparative poverty. Europe and the United States, in their trade with China and South America, do not get gold in exchange, but merchandise of various sorts. It is true that in the trade of England and New York with great gold-producing districts, such as California, South Africa, and Alaska, gold is received in return for merchandise, for to these districts gold is merchandise and its export does not drain them of their supply. The richer states in the Union do not drain the poorer states of money. A few years ago the states of Kansas, Nebraska, Iowa, and their neighbors were filled with resentment against the money-lenders of the Eastern states. There was a widespread belief that hard times were due to an insufficient currency. Attempted action took the form of the greenback and free-silver movements, which were defeated by the opposition of the East, but there can be little doubt that if the Federal Constitution had not forbidden it, the discontented states would have established a protective tariff "to keep their money at home." Few advocates of protective tariffs are ready to admit that the money-supply of the country is dependent on the general wealth of the country, and on the methods of doing business, rather than on a protective tariff.

4. Another argument is that the protective tariff keeps money at home which, if trade is free, will be sent abroad to[Pg 494] buy foreign goods, thus impoverishing the country. This is the "favorable balance of trade" argument, focusing on money rather than goods. A quick look at the trade relations between an old, wealthy country and a new province seems to support this belief. The older country lends capital (which it sends to the debtor country as goods) and simultaneously has a larger amount of money available. These two facts—the lack of money and the poverty of the newer country—are viewed by protectionists as being caused by the importation of goods. The real reason for the imports to the newer country and its limited money supply is clearly its relative poverty. When Europe and the United States trade with China and South America, they don't receive gold in exchange but various types of merchandise. It's true that in the trade between England and New York with major gold-producing areas like California, South Africa, and Alaska, they do receive gold in return for merchandise, since to these regions, gold is considered merchandise and exporting it doesn’t deplete their supply. The wealthier states in the Union don’t drain the poorer states of money. A few years ago, the states of Kansas, Nebraska, Iowa, and their neighbors were very upset with the money-lenders from the Eastern states. There was a widespread belief that hard times were due to a lack of currency. Efforts to address this took the form of the greenback and free-silver movements, which were blocked by the opposition from the East, but it’s clear that if the Federal Constitution hadn’t prohibited it, the unhappy states would have set up a protective tariff "to keep their money at home." Few supporters of protective tariffs are willing to admit that the country’s money supply depends more on the overall wealth of the nation and the business methods in use, rather than on a protective tariff.

The "two profits" argument

5. It is said that the tariff keeps "two profits" at home, foreign trade gives but one. The word "profits" is here[Pg 495] used in the popular sense of gain from a single transaction. This argument becomes somewhat confused, for certainly in the admission that there are "two profits" in a trade, the notion that "one man's gain is another's loss" is rejected. Both parties are said to profit and both profits are thought to be secured at home when two citizens are forced to trade with each other. There is an error in elementary arithmetic here, both as to the number and as to the aggregate amount of profits. The purpose of a protective tariff is to compel two of the citizens of a country to trade with each other instead of trading with two citizens of a foreign state; the number of profits is therefore not increased by substituting domestic for foreign trade. What, then, as to the size and aggregate amount of the profits? The margin of advantage is not the same on all exchanges; the exchange is made if there is a margin to both parties, no matter how small it is; but the generous "profit" on one transaction where the conditions of the two parties are very different may be greater than the total of petty margins on a dozen exchanges between two traders of evenly matched powers. Can it safely be assumed that every trade with a foreigner is less advantageous than one with a fellow-citizen? Diamond cuts diamond, but two shrewd Yankees left to themselves surely should not be worsted in bargains with the universe. If they could exchange to better advantage with each other they probably would discover it as soon as the interested manufacturers and political orators who can prove so eloquently that they know the other man's business better than he knows it himself. Forcing the home trade is doubtless to the advantage of one citizen, but it is not likely to be to the advantage of both citizens.

5. It's said that the tariff keeps "two profits" at home, while foreign trade offers just one. The term "profits" here[Pg 495] is used in the common sense of gain from a single transaction. This argument gets a bit confusing because acknowledging that there are "two profits" in a trade implies that the idea of "one person's gain is another's loss" doesn't hold. Both parties are said to profit, and both of those profits are thought to be secured at home when two citizens are required to trade with each other. There's a mistake in basic math here, both in terms of quantity and the total amount of profits. The goal of a protective tariff is to force two citizens of a country to trade with each other instead of trading with two citizens from a foreign country; therefore, the total number of profits doesn't increase by replacing foreign trade with domestic trade. So, what about the size and total amount of the profits? The margin of profit isn't the same across all trades; a trade occurs if there's a benefit for both sides, no matter how small; however, the significant "profit" from one transaction where the conditions of the two parties differ greatly might exceed the sum of small margins from a dozen transactions between two equally matched traders. Can we safely assume that every trade with a foreigner is less beneficial than one with a fellow citizen? A smart deal can happen, but two clever Americans, left to their own devices, should not end up with worse bargains against the world. If they could find a better deal with each other, they would likely realize that sooner than the interested manufacturers and political speakers who can convincingly argue that they know the other person's business better than they know it themselves. Forcing domestic trade may benefit one citizen, but it probably won’t benefit both.

The claim that protection raises wages

6. The most effective popular argument for protection is that it raises, or maintains, the general scale of wages in the country. This argument is two-fold: first, when wages are low in a country it is claimed that a tariff is needed to raise them; and, secondly, when wages are high it is argued[Pg 496] that a tariff alone can preserve them. In Germany the fear is of the higher paid and more efficient labor of England. In America, where wages at all times have been higher than in England, it was first argued that because of the greater cost of production, due to high wages, the tariff was needed to start certain industries; but after the tariff had long been established and the old argument had been forgotten, it was said that the tariff was the cause of the high wages and must be maintained to protect against the (so-called) "pauper" labor of the older countries. That wages generally are higher in new countries and where a tariff prevails is always claimed to be one of the chief fruits of a protective policy. The cause of the high wages in America appears to be the productive efficiency of industry under existing conditions. Labor is surrounded here with advantages in the forms of rich natural resources and of mechanical appliances such as never before were combined. Because of the scarcity of workers in particular protected industries, wages may be higher in them than in some other industries; but such workers form a small fraction of the population. The claim that the general scale of wages in all occupations is raised by the tariff protecting this fraction, is no less invalid than the sweeping claims in favor of trade-unions.

6. The most convincing argument for protection is that it increases or maintains the overall level of wages in the country. This argument has two parts: first, when wages are low in a country, it's said that a tariff is necessary to raise them; and second, when wages are high, it's argued[Pg 496] that a tariff is essential to keep them that way. In Germany, there’s concern about the higher paid and more efficient labor in England. In America, where wages have always been higher than in England, the initial argument was that because of higher production costs due to these wages, a tariff was needed to kickstart certain industries. However, after the tariff was long in place and the original argument faded, it became claimed that the tariff was responsible for the high wages and needed to be maintained to protect against the (so-called) "pauper" labor from older countries. It's always claimed that wages are generally higher in new countries and where a tariff exists, which is considered one of the main benefits of a protective policy. The reason for the high wages in America seems to be the productive efficiency of industry under current conditions. Workers here enjoy benefits from abundant natural resources and machinery that have never been combined like this before. Due to a shortage of workers in certain protected industries, wages may be higher in those sectors than in others; however, those workers represent a small portion of the overall population. The assertion that the general level of wages across all jobs is raised by the tariff protecting this small group is just as unfounded as the sweeping claims made in favor of trade-unions.

§ II. THE REASONABLE MEASURE OF JUSTIFICATION OF PROTECTION

Political arguments for protection

1. For military and political reasons an otherwise uneconomic tariff may be justified. It usually is admitted by the believers in free trade that in the interest of diplomacy, to secure proper concessions, tariffs may sometimes be levied. Even in England, where protective arguments long have had little acceptance, Mr. Chamberlain, with his eye on a tariff union and imperial federation of England and her colonies, has been advocating this policy. In such a case there is no pretense that the justification of the tariff is[Pg 497] its immediate economic advantages; it is an expenditure for ultimate gain. By the same argument a protective tariff is upheld as a means of defense—to encourage the building of ships, arsenals, and factories for munitions. It is always questionable whether an outright expenditure would not be better, whether the government cannot build its own arsenals, ship-yards, etc., more cheaply than it can foster private enterprise by means of a tariff.

1. For military and political reasons, an otherwise unprofitable tariff may be justified. Supporters of free trade generally agree that, in the interest of diplomacy and to secure essential concessions, tariffs may sometimes be imposed. Even in England, where protective arguments have long been unpopular, Mr. Chamberlain, looking toward a tariff union and an imperial federation with England and her colonies, has been promoting this policy. In this case, there is no pretense that the tariff's justification is[Pg 497] its immediate economic benefits; it's seen as an investment for future gain. Similarly, a protective tariff is defended as a means of protection—to encourage the development of ships, arsenals, and munitions factories. It's always debatable whether direct spending would be more effective, or whether the government could build its own arsenals, shipyards, etc., more cost-effectively than it can support private businesses through a tariff.

The infant-industry argument
Applied to America

2. Protection may be defended as encouraging infant industries and thus diversifying the industries of the country. Most free-trade writers concede a limited validity to this argument. If the natural resources of a land are adapted to an industry, it may be called into being early by a fostering protective tariff. This is merely anticipating and hastening the natural order of progress. In the American colonies the manufactures of iron, cloth, hats, ships, and furniture sprang up not only without "protection," but despite numerous harassing trade restrictions made in the interest of the English merchants; and they continued in some cases despite their absolute prohibition by Parliament. Can it be doubted that many of these industries would have developed and flourished in America under no other fostering influences than those of rich resources and of economy in freights? The growth of industries in the Middle West in the last twenty-five years has been phenomenal. The discovery of natural gas and the presence of abundant coal, ore, and timber have enabled them to develop without protection against the Eastern states. Industries capable of eventual self-support must in most cases naturally appear in due time. Economic forces will bring them out. It is a trite but valid remark that protective tariffs are often like hothouse culture, anticipating the season by a few weeks and at great cost. The question is whether the mere possession of the hothouse is a luxury worth the price, if meantime the products can be gotten more cheaply by exchange. English manufactures flourished because they were well established,[Pg 498] had excellent coal supplies, great stores of iron ore, and low-paid labor which did not have the opportunity of better alternatives, as did the American workman. If America had imported more (it would not have been all) of her iron and coal, the English mines would have been exhausted earlier, and America's advantage surely would have asserted itself in time. Her iron manufactures undoubtedly were hastened—they cannot truly be said to have been created—by the protective tariff.

2. Protection can be justified as a way to support new industries and therefore diversify a country's economy. Most free-trade writers acknowledge that there's some truth to this argument. If a country's natural resources are suited for a particular industry, that industry can emerge earlier with the help of a protective tariff. This is simply speeding up the natural process of development. In the American colonies, industries like iron, textiles, hats, ships, and furniture arose not only without "protection," but in spite of various restrictive trade measures imposed to benefit English merchants; in some instances, they even thrived despite being outright banned by Parliament. Can we really doubt that many of these industries would have grown and thrived in America with nothing but rich resources and lower shipping costs? The industrial growth in the Midwest over the past twenty-five years has been impressive. The discovery of natural gas and the availability of coal, ore, and timber allowed these industries to develop without protection from the Eastern states. Industries that can eventually support themselves will generally surface in due time. Economic forces will drive their emergence. It's a clichéd but accurate statement that protective tariffs are often like hothouse farming, bringing about growth a few weeks early at a high cost. The real question is whether owning the hothouse is worth the expense if the products can be obtained more cheaply through trade. English industries thrived because they were well-established,[Pg 498] had ample coal, plenty of iron ore, and low-wage labor, which lacked better options, unlike American workers. If America had imported more (but not all) of her iron and coal, the English mines would have been depleted sooner, and America's advantages would definitely have emerged over time. Her iron industries were certainly accelerated by the protective tariff, but they can't be said to have been created by it.

Social effects of the tariff

Industries are forced into an earlier diversification by tariffs. The peculiar advantages of a new country attract labor and enterprise into a few lines. Is it an evil? Contrast Iowa, Dakota, and Minnesota, or Kansas, if you please, with New York and Pennsylvania. Is it so certain that a dense population congested in cities and crowded in factories and mines is a more ideal social aggregation than is a community of prosperous farmers? The smoky industrialism fostered by protection often puts a premium on a low grade of immigrant and keeps him an alien to the American spirit. It would be surprising if Americanism on the Western plains were not as good as in the Eastern cities. But the infant-industry argument appeals strongly to the enterprise and the speculative spirit of Americans, who like to do all things rapidly and on a large scale. Every village aspires to be a great industrial center. Americans are impatient of the suggestion that things "will come in time"; they like things to come at once.

Industries are pushed into diversifying earlier due to tariffs. The unique advantages of a new country draw in labor and entrepreneurship in specific areas. Is this a bad thing? Compare Iowa, Dakota, and Minnesota, or Kansas, if you prefer, with New York and Pennsylvania. Is it really true that a dense population packed into cities and working in factories and mines is a better social setup than a community of thriving farmers? The smoky industrial environment encouraged by protectionism often rewards a lower quality of immigrant and keeps them disconnected from the American spirit. It would be surprising if American culture on the Western plains wasn't just as good as in the Eastern cities. However, the argument for supporting new

The "home-market" argument as to freights

3. The tariff develops a home market for the products of agriculture. It has been especially hard to reconcile the farmers in America to the tariff. While in England the protection that existed before 1846 was almost entirely for the benefit of the landholding interests, the tariff in America has been peculiarly favorable to manufactures. The "home-market" argument is the protectionist appeal that has proved most effective with the American farmers. This argument, which takes on several aspects, is akin to the[Pg 499] "two-profits" argument when it declares that the shipping of food to Europe and the importing of manufactures involve a great cost for freight which could be saved by manufacturing "at home." Of course the farmer is supposed to pay this cost, although there is nothing in the argument to show that it is not all paid by the European, either the manufacturer or the food consumer. Home trade "saves the freights" for the farmer only in case he can buy goods under a tariff with less of his own labor and products than under free trade. The payment of freight charges is true economy when the goods can be bought at a distance on more favorable terms than near home. The freight-argument proves too much, for it condemns every exchange, within the country, of goods produced a stone's throw away from the consumer.

3. The tariff creates a domestic market for agricultural products. It has been particularly challenging to get American farmers on board with the tariff. While in England, the protection that existed before 1846 primarily benefited landowners, the tariff in America has been especially advantageous for manufacturers. The "home-market" argument is the protectionist appeal that has resonated most with American farmers. This argument, which has several facets, resembles the[Pg 499] "two-profits" argument when it claims that shipping food to Europe and importing manufactured goods involves significant freight costs that could be avoided by producing "at home." Naturally, the farmer is expected to bear this cost, although there's nothing in the argument to suggest that it isn't entirely covered by the European, either the manufacturer or the food consumer. Domestic trade "saves freight costs" for the farmer only if he can purchase goods under a tariff using less of his own labor and products compared to free trade. Paying freight charges can be economical when goods can be bought from afar on better terms than locally. The freight argument is overly broad, as it criticizes any exchange within the country of goods produced just a short distance from the consumer.

As to security of trade

Again, the home-market argument dwells on the greater steadiness of domestic trade. War or political changes, it is said, may change the demand for products. This is true, but no other changes have affected American agriculture so radically as the peaceful development of domestic transportation and the opening of the West.

Again, the home-market argument focuses on the greater stability of domestic trade. It's said that war or political changes can shift the demand for products. This is true, but no other developments have impacted American agriculture as dramatically as the peaceful growth of domestic transportation and the expansion into the West.

As to the value of farm-lands

The home-market argument is strongest when addressed, not to all farmers, but to one class of farmers, those whose lands are situated nearer the manufacturing cities. The higher value taken on by land as it is converted from the extensive cultivation of corn and wheat to dairying, fruit, and market-gardening, is pointed to as a benefit of protection. The decaying agriculture and deserted farms throughout the great industrial states during the past twenty-five years are pathetic evidence that this benefit has failed to come to the average farmer just where it should be most expected. There is, however, a partial validity in the argument as applied to a comparatively small number of farmers, who gain as landholders, not as tillers of the soil.

The home-market argument is strongest when directed not at all farmers, but specifically at those whose land is closer to manufacturing cities. The increased value of land as it shifts from growing corn and wheat to dairying, fruit, and market gardening is cited as a benefit of protection. The decline of agriculture and abandoned farms across the major industrial states over the past twenty-five years serves as sad evidence that this benefit hasn't reached the average farmer where it was most anticipated. However, there is some truth in the argument when it comes to a relatively small group of farmers, who benefit as landowners rather than as cultivators.

Exports and exhaustion of the soil

4. The tariff may keep some of the natural resources of a new country from becoming quickly exhausted. The export[Pg 500] of food takes out of the soil and out of the country fertile qualities never to be returned. The shipment of several hundred million dollars of food products year after year represents a tremendous drain from the soil of the United States. The assumption, however, that the use of the food in this country would preserve the fertility of our own fields has been in the main mistaken. The fertile material in the food shipped for human consumption five miles away from the field is almost absolutely lost. Engineering skill has as yet succeeded in saving hardly a fraction of the fertile organic matter that flows into the sewers, that is dumped into river and ocean, and that is buried in heaps at the borders of our cities. On the other hand, the increased use of iron, coal, and timber, as a result of encouraging manufactures, has very effectually aided in exhausting the natural resources of the country.

4. The tariff may help prevent some of a new country's natural resources from being used up too quickly. The export[Pg 500] of food removes fertile qualities from the soil and the country that will never be returned. The annual shipment of several hundred million dollars' worth of food products represents a massive drain on the soil of the United States. However, the belief that using the food locally would maintain the fertility of our own fields has mostly been incorrect. The fertile material in food sent for human consumption, just five miles away from the field, is almost completely lost. Engineering has yet to save more than a tiny fraction of the fertile organic matter that goes into sewers, gets dumped into rivers and oceans, and is piled in heaps at the edges of our cities. On the other hand, the increased use of iron, coal, and timber, driven by the growth of manufacturing, has significantly contributed to the depletion of the country's natural resources.

Protection as a monopoly measure

5. A new country has a limited potential monopoly in certain kinds of products; a tariff may make it effective. The opening up of a new country with rich natural resources may be a great gain to the average consumer in the older countries, although it causes a loss to a special class of landowners. Whether the citizens of the older or of the newer country shall reap the greater benefit in the trade depends on the reciprocal demand for the two classes of goods, as was seen in discussing the equation of international demand. A wide margin of advantage may go to one party and a narrow margin to the citizen of the more favored land. To put it concretely: if America, having great natural resources for agriculture, continues to exchange food for manufactures up to the narrowest margin of advantage, England reaps most of the benefits of the trade. An American tariff on manufactures from England will, under such conditions, check the demand for English products and compel some Americans to leave farming. This reduction of the American supply of wheat or corn and of the American demand for English manufactures compels a new ratio of exchange. It is conceivable[Pg 501] that exchanging fewer goods at a larger margin of advantage, will give a larger total of gain to the favored nation. Thus, by the shifting of the ratio of exchange, foreigners may be compelled to pay a part of the tariff to enjoy the favored market. This is but a special case of the monopoly principle; the government by law artificially limits the supply of goods offered by its citizens.

5. A new country can have a limited potential monopoly on certain types of products; a tariff can make this effective. Opening up a new country with abundant natural resources can greatly benefit the average consumer in older countries, even though it may harm a specific group of landowners. Whether people in the older or newer country gain more from this trade depends on the mutual demand for both types of goods, as discussed in the international demand equation. One side may gain significantly while the other may gain only slightly. To put it simply: if America, with its rich agricultural resources, continues to trade food for manufactured goods up to the minimum threshold of advantage, England receives most of the trade benefits. An American tariff on English manufactured goods will, in this scenario, reduce demand for those products and force some Americans to stop farming. This decrease in American wheat or corn supply and the reduced demand for English goods will create a new exchange ratio. It’s possible[Pg 501] that trading fewer goods at a greater margin of advantage will provide a larger overall benefit to the favored nation. Therefore, as the exchange ratio shifts, foreigners could end up paying part of the tariff to access the advantageous market. This is just a specific example of the monopoly principle; the government uses laws to artificially limit the supply of goods offered by its citizens.

Limited monopoly advantages of America

This argument is somewhat subtle, but probably is the soundest one in the theory of protection. The supposed conditions seldom occur, but they may exist, and probably have existed in America. When the great system of internal transportation was developed in the United States before that of the other new countries, this country had such peculiar advantages for the production of food that the quantity was enormously increased and the prices fell. At such a time the tariff may work toward retarding the unfavorable turn in the ratio of exchange and toward reëstablishing early a more favorable ratio. But the limited application of the principle must be recognized. The potential competition of undeveloped countries on all sides, seeking to develop their resources, to raise their own food, and to profit by the higher prices in the world-market caused by the tariff, threaten the peculiar advantages of the favored land. A great nation with its manifold interests is not eminently fitted to practice the gentle art of monopoly.

This argument is a bit subtle, but it's likely the strongest one in the theory of protection. The supposed conditions rarely happen, but they can exist and probably have in America. When the major system of internal transportation was developed in the United States before similar systems in other new countries, this country had such unique advantages for food production that the quantity increased dramatically and prices dropped. During such a time, the tariff might help slow down a negative shift in the exchange ratio and work towards reestablishing a more favorable ratio sooner. However, the limited application of this principle needs to be acknowledged. The potential competition from developing countries all around, trying to tap into their resources, grow their own food, and benefit from the higher prices in the global market created by the tariff, poses a threat to the unique advantages of the favored land. A large nation with its many interests isn’t well-suited to effectively manage the soft skills of monopoly.

§ III. VALUES AS AFFECTED BY PROTECTION

Influence on the value of capital

1. An increase of the tariff is favorable to many capitalists and to many owners of natural resources. A denial of large general advantages in protection is not the denial of all its influence on value. On the contrary, it cannot be too strongly emphasized that manifold interests are affected by the tariff. Owners of natural mineral resources are among the first to benefit. When the price of iron is low, many iron- and coal-mines may yield no rent and have small prospective[Pg 502] values. A tariff forcing home production opens the marginal resources and gives them a large capital value. Factory sites and surrounding lands leap from the level of rural prices to that of city real estate. The owners of farms situated near the new industries have a home market and get scarcity prices, as they alone can supply the needed fresh vegetables and dairy products. Wealth less favorably situated, however, is in many cases depressed in value because its products exchange for smaller amounts of other products.

1. An increase in tariffs benefits many capitalists and owners of natural resources. Just because we deny large overall benefits of protection doesn’t mean we ignore its impact on value. In fact, it's important to highlight that various interests are influenced by tariffs. Owners of natural mineral resources are among the first to gain. When iron prices are low, many iron and coal mines may not generate any profits and have low future values. A tariff that promotes domestic production opens up marginal resources and significantly increases their capital value. Factory locations and nearby land surge from rural price levels to that of urban real estate. Farmers located near new industries gain a local market and command higher prices, as they are the only ones able to provide fresh vegetables and dairy products. However, wealth in less advantageous locations often sees a drop in value because its products trade for smaller amounts compared to others.

The special gains and the general burden

2. A tariff is immediately favorable to some enterprises and to special classes of workmen. Enterprisers already acquainted with and engaged in a business always may hope to gain by the higher prices immediately following a rise in the tariff rates on their particular products. Though they are granted no enduring monopoly by the protection, they for the time enjoy the advantage of being on the ground and reap the first fruits of the favoring conditions. The enterpriser usually profits when the price of his product suddenly rises. Usually skilled workmen are affected slowly by competition when there is any considerable increase of their special industry. The burden of higher prices is very soon distributed to a number of less favored citizens. A part of it may be borne by the retail merchant, a part by his customers. The weight falling on each is usually small, often unsuspected, always hard to measure. The increased benefit is concentrated in a few industries and accrues to a comparatively few producers. Here is a recipe for riches: get everybody to give you a penny; they'll not miss it, and it will mean a great deal to you. Something like this happens in the case of many protected industries; every consumer of the article pays a penny more, a few wage-earners gain, and a few enterprisers wax wealthy.

2. A tariff is beneficial right away for some businesses and specific groups of workers. Business owners who are already familiar with and involved in a certain industry can expect to profit from the higher prices that come just after a rise in tariff rates on their products. Even though they don't get a permanent monopoly through this protection, they enjoy the temporary advantage of being ahead and benefit first from the favorable conditions. Usually, business owners profit when the price of their goods rises suddenly. Skilled workers typically feel the impact of competition slowly, especially when there's a significant increase in their specific field. The burden of higher prices quickly spreads out among less fortunate citizens. Part of it might be absorbed by the retail merchant, and part by their customers. The impact on each individual is usually small, often unnoticed, and always difficult to quantify. The increased benefits are concentrated in a few industries, benefiting a relatively small number of producers. Here’s a way to get rich: have everyone give you a penny; they won’t notice, and it will mean a lot to you. This scenario is similar in many protected industries; every consumer pays a penny more, a few wage-earners benefit, and a few entrepreneurs become wealthy.

Sudden tariff reduction injurious

3. A sudden reduction of the tariff causes local crises and may bring on a general crisis. The repeal of the tariff works in a direction the reverse of its enactment. The benefits[Pg 503] of the lower prices are diffused; the immediate injury is concentrated and acute. Factories are closed, capital is depreciated, labor is thrown out of employment. The organic nature of local industry causes the evil to be felt by many classes. Merchants, professional men, servants, and skilled laborers that are tributary to the depressed industry, suffer. The effects are transmitted to commercial and financial centers and credit is shaken. The readjustment of industry is slow and much capital is lost in the process.

3. A sudden cut in tariffs can lead to local crises and may trigger a widespread crisis. Removing the tariff has the opposite effect of putting it in place. The advantages[Pg 503] of lower prices are spread out, while the immediate damage is focused and severe. Factories shut down, investments lose value, and workers lose their jobs. The interconnected nature of local industries means that many different groups are affected. Merchants, professionals, service workers, and skilled laborers who rely on the struggling industry all face hardship. The repercussions reach commercial and financial hubs, shaking confidence. Adjusting the industry takes time, and a significant amount of capital is lost along the way.

The two policies in political discussion

It is rarely appreciated how great is the tactical advantage enjoyed in political contests by the advocates of a high tariff. They can so easily impress the popular judgment with the evident fruits of their own policy, and with the immediate dangers of the policy of their opponents. The low-tariff advocates in America undoubtedly have made the mistake of underestimating or of quite overlooking these immediate effects. They have been too abstractly doctrinaire, and have argued too absolutely for the merits of free trade. They have opposed one extreme system by another, with no thought of the inexpediency and injustice of sweeping changes. There is a strong feeling among business men that any tariff, be it high or low, is better than a shifting policy. Despite the great preponderance of domestic production over foreign trade, it is perhaps too much to say that the tariff is unimportant in our present conditions. It can, however, be said that the tariff agitation has taught that radical changes, especially sudden and large reductions, are fraught with evils, and that business can adjust itself in large measure to any settled conditions. The future of the tariff discussion in America is hard to prophesy. The infant-industry argument now is of little force. With the widening of our international relations are growing interests favorable to reciprocity or to other freer trade relations.

It’s not often acknowledged how significant the tactical edge is for high-tariff supporters in political battles. They can easily sway public opinion with the clear benefits of their policy and the immediate threats posed by their opponents’ policies. Low-tariff advocates in America have certainly erred by underestimating or ignoring these immediate impacts. They’ve been too idealistic and have made overly absolute arguments for free trade. They’ve countered one extreme with another, without considering the impracticality and unfairness of sweeping changes. Many businesspeople feel that any tariff, whether high or low, is preferable to an inconsistent policy. Even with domestic production greatly outpacing foreign trade, it might be too strong to claim that the tariff is insignificant under current conditions. However, it can be said that the tariff debate has shown that drastic changes, especially sudden and drastic cuts, bring many problems, and that business can largely adapt to stable conditions. The future of tariff discussions in America is difficult to predict. The argument for protecting young industries is becoming less persuasive. As our international relations expand, there are growing interests that favor reciprocity or other forms of freer trade.


CHAPTER 52

OTHER PROTECTIVE SOCIAL AND LABOR LEGISLATION

§ I. SOCIAL LEGISLATION

City growth and new social problems

1. Under modern conditions many laws restricting free competition are required to secure the health and convenience of the citizens. The rapid growth of city populations has brought new social and economic problems. The friction in social relations is greater when men are crowded together. In 1790, three per cent. only of our population lived in cities of over eight thousand; to-day the percentage is thirty-three. Then the city dwellers numbered one hundred and thirty-one thousand; now they number twenty-five millions. Then there were but six cities of eight thousand or over; now there are five hundred and forty-five. Then the largest city (Philadelphia) numbered fifty thousand persons; to-day the largest city (New York) numbers three millions. Many laws are survivals suited only to the older rural conditions. In London, these problems were first forced into prominence, and a law passed after the great fire of 1665 to regulate the rebuilding of houses, streets, sidewalks, and sewers, foreshadowed alike the American law of special assessments and the modern tenement-house legislation. A mass of laws wise and foolish has resulted from the attempt to meet the new conditions. The laws of nuisance and of sanitation have been rapidly changing.

1. In today's world, many laws that limit free competition are necessary to ensure the health and well-being of citizens. The rapid increase in city populations has created new social and economic challenges. There's more friction in social interactions when people are crammed together. In 1790, only three percent of our population lived in cities with over eight thousand people; today, that percentage is thirty-three. Back then, there were one hundred thirty-one thousand city dwellers; now there are twenty-five million. Then, there were only six cities with eight thousand or more residents; now there are five hundred forty-five. At that time, the largest city (Philadelphia) had fifty thousand residents; today, the largest city (New York) has three million. Many laws still reflect older rural conditions. In London, these issues first gained attention, leading to a law passed after the great fire of 1665 that regulated the rebuilding of houses, streets, sidewalks, and sewers, which anticipated both the American law on special assessments and modern tenement regulations. A mix of wise and foolish laws has emerged from the effort to adapt to these new conditions. The laws regarding nuisances and sanitation have been changing rapidly.

Need of social regulation

Why not leave such subjects to individuals? It is for the interest of every one that his back yard should not be a[Pg 505] place of noisome smells and disagreeable sights. But men are at times strangely obstinate, selfish, and neglectful, and through one man's fault a whole community may suffer. The refusal of one man to put a sewer in front of his house would block the improvement of a whole street. The obstinacy of one may bring an epidemic upon an entire city. There must be a plan, and by law the will of the majority must be imposed upon the unsocial few. Where voluntary coöperation fails, compulsory coöperation often is necessary. Thus health laws, tax laws, and improvement laws regulate many of the acts of citizens, limit the use of property, and compel men to a course against their own wishes and judgments. The justification for these limitations on the right of private property, on free choice of the individual, on "free competition," must be found in the social result secured.

Why not leave these matters to individuals? It benefits everyone if their backyard isn't a place filled with bad smells and unpleasant sights. But sometimes, people can be surprisingly stubborn, selfish, and neglectful, and because of one person's failure, an entire community can suffer. If one person refuses to install a sewer in front of their house, it could hinder the improvement of an entire street. The stubbornness

Tenement-house laws in cities
Interests affected

2. Tenement-house legislation is an important recent expression of this social protective policy. As city population grows denser, land increases in value, and the evils of bad housing threaten the welfare of the great majority of city dwellers. Light, sun, air are shut out, and cleanliness, decency, and home life are made impossible. Two policies are open to the public. It may be left to private enterprise to solve the problem. If the tenant agrees to rent a disease-breeding house, he is the first to suffer. The interests of investors, it is said, will supply as good a house as each tenant can pay for. The other policy now adopted is to set a minimum standard of sanitation and comfort, to which all builders and owners must attain. Property owners are no longer left free to determine plans, height of building, proportion of lot built on, lighting, materials, and workmanship. Complying with the legal requirements, they are left quite free to collect whatever rent they can get. Such legislation is partly in the interest of the body of landowners as against the selfish desires of some individuals. One bad building may bring down the rent of all on the street. Partly, however,[Pg 506] the regulation is in the interest of the tenants and of society as a whole, and against that of the landlord. The rents from slum property are threatened; hence the strong opposition always manifested against tenement-house legislation by some landlords, architects, and contractors, who fight it bitterly as an interference with their interests and as a confiscation of their property. It is not quite certain how marked will be the effect of this policy in making the rents too high for the poorer tenants and driving them into the country. But this result, predicted by the enemies of the policy, is not so undesirable, and the enlightened sentiment of the public to-day favors all efforts to destroy the breeding-places of disease, misery, and crime.

2. Tenement-house laws are a significant recent sign of this social safety net policy. As city populations become more crowded, land values rise, and the problems of poor housing threaten the well-being of most city residents. Access to light, sunlight, and fresh air is blocked, making cleanliness, decency, and a home life nearly impossible. There are two approaches available to the public. One option is to let private businesses tackle the problem. If a tenant chooses to rent a place that breeds diseases, they are the first to suffer. It’s believed that the investors will provide a suitable house for whatever price the tenant can afford. The other approach currently adopted is to establish a minimum standard of hygiene and comfort that all builders and property owners must meet. Property owners no longer have the freedom to decide on plans, building height, lot coverage, lighting, materials, and construction quality on their own. While they must comply with legal requirements, they remain free to charge whatever rent they can get. This legislation serves partly to protect landowners' interests against some individuals' selfish desires. One poor building can lower the rent for everyone on that street. However, it also serves the tenants' and society's interests as a whole, opposing the landlords' interests. Rents from rundown properties are at risk; hence, some landlords, architects, and contractors fiercely resist tenement-house legislation, seeing it as an infringement on their interests and a confiscation of their property. It's uncertain how significantly this policy will raise rents for low-income tenants and push them into rural areas. Yet, the outcome predicted by opponents of the policy isn't necessarily a bad thing, and today’s progressive public sentiment supports all efforts to eliminate the sources of disease, suffering, and crime.

Public inspection of goods used in the homes

3. Laws forbid adulteration of products for domestic use and provide for public inspection. English laws of the Middle Ages forbade false measures and the sale of defective goods, and provided for the inspection of markets in the cities. Recent legislation in many lands has developed much further the policy of insuring the purity or the safety of articles consumed in the home. The oleomargarin law passed by Congress was, however, designed as protective legislation in the interest of the farmer. Usually, the self-interest of the purchaser is the best safeguard for the quality of goods; but personal inspection by each buyer frequently is difficult and time-consuming, requiring special and unusual knowledge of the products, and special costly testing apparatus. The state undertakes, therefore, to set a minimum standard of quality, and to apply it by the economical method of social coöperation. This policy extends only to staple products and to a comparatively few articles. It would be impossible as well as unwise to apply it to art products, except to protect the morality of the community. This inspection sometimes raises the price, but the evils are small compared with the convenience and the benefits resulting to the citizen. He is assured that the article he buys is of standard quality, and if he wishes a cheaper[Pg 507] quality there is no law to prevent his adulterating it for his own use.

3. Laws prohibit tampering with products meant for home use and allow for public inspections. English laws from the Middle Ages banned false measurements and the sale of defective goods, and required market inspections in cities. Recent laws in many countries have taken this a step further to ensure the purity and safety of items consumed at home. The oleomargarine law passed by Congress was actually aimed at protecting farmers' interests. Generally, the buyer's self-interest serves as the best protection for product quality; however, it can be tough and time-consuming for each buyer to inspect items personally, as it requires specialized knowledge and expensive testing equipment. Therefore, the government steps in to establish a minimum quality standard, applying it through cost-effective social cooperation. This policy only covers basic products and a limited number of items. It wouldn't be practical or wise to extend this to art products, except when it comes to protecting community morality. While this inspection can sometimes raise prices, the drawbacks are minor compared to the convenience and benefits it brings to consumers. Buyers can be confident that the products they purchase are of standard quality, and if they want a cheaper[Pg 507] option, there's no law stopping them from altering it for personal use.

State support of education

4. Other kinds of social amelioration undertaken by the state, through free, compulsory education, charity, and temperance legislation, are likewise interferences with competition and freedom of contract. Many of these are so customary that they are not thought of in this light. Schools are productive enterprises, education is industry, and the supply of this service is always in large measure undertaken by private enterprise and could be left entirely to it. But free elementary education is the established policy, and is no longer debatable in America and France. In England the policy is still debated, much as is that of public ownership of trolley lines in America. One by one the states are passing compulsory education laws, and thus interfering still further with the freedom of the individual. The affection of parents can in most cases be trusted to provide for the education of children, but when family affection fails, the child and the state are the victims of the resulting ignorance, crime, and pauperism. State support of higher education is more in dispute. It is a universally accepted view that social welfare requires a more generous support for higher education than could be secured if it were sold at a competitive price; but while in eastern America its provision is left mainly to private gifts, in the West and South it is undertaken largely by the state. The justification of this policy must be found, not in the benefit to the particular students, but in the benefit diffused throughout the commonwealth by the encouragement of science, arts, and letters.

4. Other forms of social improvement initiated by the government, like free, mandatory education, charity, and laws promoting temperance, also interfere with competition and the freedom to make contracts. Many of these practices are so routine that they aren’t viewed in this way. Schools are productive enterprises; education is an industry, and much of this service is typically provided by private organizations, which could take over completely. However, free elementary education is now the established norm and is no longer up for debate in America and France. In England, this issue is still contested, similar to the debate over public ownership of trolley lines in America. One by one, states are enacting compulsory education laws, which further restrict individual freedom. In most cases, parents’ love can be relied upon to ensure their children receive an education, but when that familial support fails, both the child and the state suffer from the resulting ignorance, crime, and poverty. State funding for higher education is more contentious. There's a widely held belief that social welfare necessitates more funding for higher education than what could be achieved through competitive pricing; yet while in Eastern America, it mainly relies on private donations, in the West and South, it is largely managed by the state. The rationale for this approach should be sought not in the direct benefits to the individual students, but in the broader advantages for society that result from advancing science, the arts, and literature.

Public charity
Temperance legislation

The system of public relief for the defective classes of blind, deaf, insane, feeble-minded, and paupers, are examples of the social protective policy. The public interest undoubtedly is served by having these suffering classes systematically relieved, but the extent and nature of the provision are questions ever in debate. Still more debated is temperance legislation, both as to licensing and as to prohibiting the[Pg 508] liquor traffic. Nowhere is the manufacture and sale of intoxicating liquor treated quite like the traffic in most other goods, because it is recognized that the public interest is affected in a different way. While it is beyond question that society should protect itself against the drunkard, it is more doubtful whether it owes to the man, for his sake, protection against his own blunders. Not even the gods can save the stupid. Temperance legislation is strongest in its social aspect. The opponent of it usually champions the individualist view; its partisans uphold, in varying degrees, the social view.

The public assistance system for those who are blind, deaf, mentally ill, mentally challenged, and those living in poverty is an example of a social protection policy. It’s clear that helping these vulnerable groups benefits society, but there’s ongoing debate about how much support is needed and what form it should take. Even more contentious is temperance legislation, concerning both the licensing and prohibition of the[Pg 508] liquor trade. The production and sale of alcoholic beverages aren't treated the same way as most other goods because it’s understood that the public interest is impacted differently. While it's unquestionable that society must protect itself from the effects of alcoholism, it's less clear whether it has a responsibility to shield individuals from their own mistakes. Not even deities can save the foolish. Temperance laws focus mainly on social issues. Those against such laws typically advocate for individual rights, while their supporters emphasize social responsibility, albeit to varying degrees.

Other laws to protect public morals

Similar questions arise regarding lotteries, gambling, betting, horse-racing, etc. When a man backs a worthless horse against the field, money probably is transferred from the stupider to the shrewder party. The philosopher may say that the sooner a fool and his money are parted the better; but the broken gambler remains a burden and a threat to honest society. Gambling, lotteries, and speculation cause embezzlement, crime, unhappy homes, and wrecked lives. Here are to be found with difficulty the true boundaries between ethics and expediency. A busybody despotism may protect the fool, but it thereby helps to perpetuate and multiply his folly; yet if the fool is left alone, he too often is a plague to the wise and the virtuous.

Similar questions come up about lotteries, gambling, betting, horse racing, and so on. When someone bets on a worthless horse against the rest of the field, money likely moves from the less savvy to the more clever player. The philosopher might argue that it's better for a fool to lose his money sooner rather than later, but the broken gambler still becomes a burden and a threat to honest society. Gambling, lotteries, and speculation lead to embezzlement, crime, unhappy homes, and ruined lives. It's hard to define the true limits between ethics and practicality. A meddling authority might try to protect the fool, but in doing so, it only encourages and increases his foolishness; yet if the fool is left to his own devices, he often becomes a nuisance to the wise and virtuous.

Usury laws as social legislation

5. Usury laws are found almost universally in civilized lands. By usury was formerly meant any payment for the loan of goods or money; now it means only excessive payments. In former times moralists and lawmakers were opposed to all usury or interest. Most loans were made in times of distress. The sources of loanable capital and the chances of profitable investment were fewer in the past than to-day. For the last four centuries there has been on the question of usury a gradual change of opinion, beginning in the commercial centers and most rapid in the countries with more developed industry. A moderate rate of interest is now everywhere permitted; but in all but a few communities[Pg 509] the rate that can be collected is limited by law, and penalties more or less severe are imposed on the usurious lender. It has been noted in another connection that usury laws are practically evaded in a number of ways within the letter of the law. Many writers maintain that usury laws do more harm than good even to the borrower, whom they are designed to protect. In a developed credit economy, where a regular money-market exists, they are superfluous, to say the least, as most loans are made below the legal rate. Such laws, however, have a partial justification. In a small money-market they to some extent protect the weak borrower at the moment of distress from the rapacity of the would-be usurer. Their utility is disappearing, but in simpler industrial conditions usury laws are fruits of the social conscience, a recognition of the duty to protect the weaker citizen in the period of his direst need.

5. Usury laws are nearly universal in civilized countries. In the past, usury referred to any payment for borrowing goods or money; now it only refers to excessive charges. Historically, moralists and lawmakers opposed all usury or interest. Most loans were made during difficult times. There were fewer sources of loanable capital and opportunities for profitable investments in the past than there are today. Over the last four centuries, perspectives on usury have gradually shifted, starting in commercial hubs and changing most rapidly in countries with more developed industries. A moderate interest rate is now allowed almost everywhere; however, in nearly all communities[Pg 509], the rate that can be charged is capped by law, and varying degrees of penalties are imposed on usurious lenders. It has been noted in other contexts that usury laws are often circumvented in various ways that comply with the letter of the law. Many writers argue that usury laws do more harm than good, even for the borrowers they aim to protect. In a developed credit economy with a functioning money market, these laws are largely unnecessary since most loans are given below the legal rate. Nonetheless, such laws hold some justification. In a small money market, they somewhat protect vulnerable borrowers in times of crisis from predatory lenders. Their usefulness is diminishing, but in simpler industrial settings, usury laws reflect a societal duty to safeguard weaker citizens during their most desperate times.

§ II. LABOR LEGISLATION

Growth of child-labor legislation

1. Factory laws now limit in many ways the employment of women and children, and the hours of work. Factory legislation began in England, early in the nineteenth century, to check some of the worst evils then showing themselves in the factories. It has since increased in England and has been copied rapidly by other countries. Some of the agricultural states of the Union have as yet no factory laws, but the states industrially more advanced have many. They are made, first, to apply to children. The evil of forcing children into factories is easily recognized. The child, subject to the commands of his parents or guardians, is not a free agent. At times a lazy father is tempted to support himself in idleness on the wages of his young children. Often poverty leads the parents to rob their children of health, of schooling, and of the joys of childhood. Child-labor depresses the wages of adults and the evil grows. Children laboring long hours in close and grimy factories,[Pg 510] and growing into blighted and ignorant manhood, are a threat to society. In agricultural conditions, such as have prevailed generally in America, there is far less need of limiting the hours of work and the age at which children may begin to work. The barefoot boy trudging over clover-fields to carry water to the harvesters may be the happier, healthier, and better for his work.

1. Factory laws now restrict in many ways the employment of women and children and set limits on working hours. Factory legislation started in England in the early nineteenth century to address some of the worst problems that were becoming apparent in factories. Since then, it has expanded in England and has been quickly adopted by other countries. Some agricultural states in the Union still lack factory laws, but states that are more industrially developed have many. These laws are primarily aimed at protecting children. The issue of forcing children into factories is easily recognized. A child, under the authority of their parents or guardians, is not truly independent. Sometimes a lazy father is tempted to rely on his children's wages to support himself. Often, poverty drives parents to deprive their children of health, education, and the joys of childhood. Child labor drives down the wages of adults, and the problem just gets worse. Children working long hours in cramped, dirty factories, [Pg 510] and growing up into damaged and uneducated adults, pose a risk to society. In agricultural settings, which have generally been the norm in America, there is significantly less need to restrict work hours and the minimum age for children to start working. The barefoot boy walking through clover fields to bring water to the harvesters might be happier, healthier, and better off because of his work.

Women's work and shorter hours

The work of women in factories tends to depress the wages of men, is inevitably harmful to family life, and, when the work is arduous and continuous, the evils are visited upon succeeding generations. In the early days of the factory system in England, the hours of work were lengthened in order to make the machinery earn as much as possible. The first laws regulating hours applied especially to women and children, limiting their work to ten or twelve hours daily. Later, this regulation was made to apply to men, and now is found in most civilized lands. In recent years the agitation has been for an eight-hour day, and doubtless it will some day be adopted in the majority of trades.

The work of women in factories tends to lower men's wages, negatively impacts family life, and when the work is tough and non-stop, the consequences affect future generations. In the early days of the factory system in England, work hours were extended to maximize machine output. The first laws that regulated working hours targeted women and children, limiting their work to ten or twelve hours a day. Later, these regulations were extended to men and are now found in most developed countries. In recent years, the push has been for an eight-hour workday, which will likely be adopted widely in various industries someday.

The workmen's remedies for injuries

2. Many laws provide for the health and safety of workers in factories and mines. Both workman and employer are in many ways interested in providing against danger from fire, bad ventilation and lighting, bad sanitation, unprotected and dangerous machinery, and bad moral conditions in the factories and other places of work. What can the workman do to protect himself? (1) He may refuse to work whenever the conditions are bad. But this requires that he inspect the factory and judge of the sanitary conditions in each case, and that he then resist the temptation to accept employment of which he may be sorely in need. (2) He may ask higher wages to compensate for the added risk. But this is not practically possible with his insufficient knowledge of conditions, and it supposes an equal caution in many other workers. It is well that individual men are not excessively cautious, or the state would lack brave citizens and defenders. It is better that the forethought[Pg 511] be in part exercised by the community collectively. (3) The person injured in health or limb may sue for damages. But this, with his means and knowledge, is often impossible, and is a costly process, yielding a pitiful recompense for a blighted life.

2. Many laws protect the health and safety of workers in factories and mines. Both workers and employers are interested in preventing dangers like fire hazards, poor ventilation and lighting, unsanitary conditions, unguarded and hazardous machinery, and negative moral environments in factories and other workplaces. What can a worker do to protect himself? (1) He can refuse to work when conditions are unsafe. However, this means he has to check the factory and assess the sanitary conditions each time, and then resist the urge to take a job he might desperately need. (2) He can ask for higher wages to make up for the extra risk. But this isn’t really feasible due to his limited understanding of the conditions, and it assumes that other workers are just as cautious. It’s a good thing individual workers aren’t overly cautious; otherwise, the state would miss out on brave citizens and defenders. It’s better for the community as a whole to shoulder some of that responsibility. (3) A person injured physically or mentally can sue for damages. But with their limited resources and knowledge, this is often impossible and can be an expensive process, resulting in only a small payout for a ruined life.

Factory laws to reduce accidents

The employer is interested in attracting better workmen at lower wages, and in avoiding damages by making the conditions of work favorable. The law seeks the same end by more economical ways when it sets a minimum standard. Experience shows that certain safety appliances should always be present to prevent the evils; for a state to leave their provision to self-interest, is to trifle with the welfare of its citizens. Factory legislation usually is opposed by employers because of the expense it causes; but if the regulations apply to all factories, the expense becomes a part of the cost of production and is shifted, like the other expenses of production, to the general body of consumers, of which the employers form only a small part.

The employer wants to attract better workers while paying lower wages and to prevent damage by making working conditions better. The law aims for the same goal through more cost-effective methods by establishing a minimum standard. Experience shows that certain safety devices should always be available to prevent issues; relying on self-interest for their provision risks the well-being of citizens. Factory laws are usually opposed by employers due to the costs involved; however, if these regulations apply to all factories, the expenses become part of the production costs and are passed on to consumers, of whom employers make up just a small portion.

Legal regulation of wage-payment

3. Laws regulate the form, time, and methods of payment in manufactures and mining. Companies sometimes keep stores and pay the workers in mines and factories in goods, instead of money. Such a store in the hands of a philanthropic employer might easily be made, without expense to himself, a great boon to his workmen, giving them more than the benefits of consumers' coöperation. But the usual result is told by the fact that such stores are known as "truck stores," "pluck-me stores." They are most often found where some one large corporation dominates in the community, as in mines, where the workers are in a very dependent condition. If the higher prices demanded practically lower real wages, it would seem that the worker had an immediate remedy in his power to demand higher money-wages. Recognizing that this is for the most part an illusion—for it is just in such places that the conditions for free competition are least present—the law in many states prohibits these stores. It regulates also the measuring of work, fixing the[Pg 512] size of screens and of cars used in coal-mining. The law is especially favorable to the hand-laborer in regard to the collection of his wages, requiring regular monthly or fortnightly or sometimes weekly payments. Mechanics' liens give to workmen in the building trades the first claim on the products of their labor.

3. Laws control how and when payments are made in manufacturing and mining. Companies sometimes run stores and pay their workers in mines and factories with goods instead of cash. A store in the hands of a generous employer could easily become a significant benefit for his workers, offering them more than what they would get from consumer cooperatives, without costing him anything. However, the reality is that these stores are often referred to as "truck stores" or "pluck-me stores." They usually appear in places where a single large corporation has a stronghold in the community, such as in mining, where workers are heavily dependent. If the higher prices charged effectively reduce real wages, it might seem that workers could simply demand higher cash wages as a solution. But this is mostly an illusion—these are the places where conditions for free competition are the least present. Therefore, many states have laws that prohibit these stores. The laws also regulate how work is measured, including setting standards for the[Pg 512] size of screens and cars used in coal mining. The law is particularly supportive of manual laborers regarding wage collection, requiring payments to be made regularly, either monthly, bi-weekly, or sometimes weekly. Mechanics' liens ensure that workers in the building trades have the first claim on the results of their work.

Limitation of freedom of contract

4. In some cases the law forbids "contracting out," and the courts fix the terms of the contract. In general, the law does not interfere with the right of the citizen to make any formal contract he chooses. It confines itself to providing rules and agencies for interpreting and enforcing the contracts when made. Employers often compel workmen to sign a release from damages in case of accident. This practice was forbidden even by common law, and many recent statutes have specifically provided that employers cannot "contract out" of the right to claim damages. The courts are particularly watchful of the interests of children, who are usually deemed incapable of entering into contracts binding them to their injury. Sailors, likewise, have long been protected and guarded by the law, because, journeying far from home, they are peculiarly in the power of their employers. The English courts may even change the contract if the sailors have been coerced by their masters. The rights of married women to mortgage their property is limited in some states in recognition of the undue influence that may be exercised by their husbands. The attempts in the last twenty years to settle the Irish land-question have resulted in a steady increase of the interference of law and courts with the freedom of contract between tenant and landlord. Though in many ways freedom of contract is thus limited, competition is not entirely destroyed; it is turned in other and usually better directions.

4. In some situations, the law prevents "contracting out," and the courts set the terms of the contract. Generally, the law does not interfere with a citizen's right to enter into any formal contract they choose. It focuses on providing rules and agencies for interpreting and enforcing those contracts once they're made. Employers often force workers to sign waivers that release them from liability in case of an accident. This practice was even prohibited by common law, and many recent laws specifically state that employers cannot "contract out" of the right to claim damages. The courts pay particular attention to the interests of children, who are typically considered unable to enter into contracts that could harm them. Similarly, sailors have been protected by law for a long time, as they are often far from home and vulnerable to their employers' control. English courts may even alter contracts if sailors were coerced by their superiors. In some states, the rights of married women to mortgage their property are limited to acknowledge the undue influence their husbands could exert. Over the past twenty years, efforts to resolve the Irish land issue have led to increasing interference from laws and courts in the contracts between tenants and landlords. While freedom of contract is limited in many ways, competition is not completely eliminated; instead, it is directed toward other, typically better, outcomes.

General nature of this social legislation
Economic or moral objects primary

5. This group of social laws resembles protective tariffs in preventing free competition, but differs from them in varying ways and degrees. Writers class all such laws as protective legislation, in that they depart from the rule of free[Pg 513] trade taken in its broadest sense. It does not follow, however, that all these laws stand or fall together,—that if the protective tariff is wrong, all are wrong. The justification of every such measure is limited and relative, and therefore of varying strength. All protective measures are alike in that the free choice of the citizen is forbidden by law. The argument for the tariff is economic and political. The tariff does not seek to prevent a moral evil; foreign trade is morally as good as other trade. In a large majority of social laws the moral purpose is fundamental. It is the demand of humanity that competition be placed on a higher plane. Tariff legislation is primarily in the interest of a special well-to-do class, with which other citizens are compelled unwillingly to trade. Most social legislation is to protect the weak from being forced into contracts injurious to their welfare and happiness. In any case, social legislation is not to be justified by any but the most general abstract principle,—the attainment of the best social result. The best test of social protective laws is their contribution to a higher independence and to a freer competition on a higher, more worthy, and more humane plane.

5. This group of social laws is similar to protective tariffs in restricting free competition, but differs in various ways and degrees. Writers classify all such laws as protective legislation because they move away from the principle of free[Pg 513] trade when viewed broadly. However, it doesn’t mean that all these laws rise or fall together—just because the protective tariff is flawed doesn’t mean all are flawed. The justification for each of these measures is limited and relative, and thus varies in strength. All protective measures share the fact that citizens’ free choice is restricted by law. The argument for the tariff is both economic and political. The tariff doesn’t aim to eliminate a moral wrong; foreign trade is as morally acceptable as any other trade. In most social laws, the moral aim is fundamental. Humanity demands that competition be elevated to a higher standard. Tariff legislation primarily serves a specific affluent class, with which other citizens must reluctantly engage in trade. Most social legislation exists to protect the vulnerable from being coerced into contracts that harm their welfare and happiness. In any case, social legislation should only be justified by the most general abstract principle—the pursuit of the best social outcome. The best way to evaluate social protective laws is by their contribution to greater independence and more meaningful competition on a higher, more worthy, and more humane level.


CHAPTER 53

PUBLIC OWNERSHIP OF INDUSTRY

§ I. EXAMPLES OF PUBLIC OWNERSHIP

The kinds of political units

1. Local political units generally acquire only industries whose products must be used in the place where produced. The word industry is used here in a broad sense, including agents of psychic income not usually so classed, such as public parks. The grouping of publicly owned industries according to the size and importance of the political units cannot be exact, because some classes of industries are owned by several kinds of political units. Yet, especially with application to American conditions, an approximate classification may be made on this principle. Federal states consist of three main groups of political units: national, provincial, and local. Provincial units are the largest subdivisions, as the American "states," or commonwealths, the German states, and the provinces in other countries. The term local political unit is more complex and may mean county, township, village, city, and school or sanitary district; but most of what is to be said of local ownership refers to cities or to incorporated villages.

1. Local political units usually only take on industries whose products need to be used where they are made. The term industry is used here in a broader sense, including sources of non-tangible benefits not typically categorized that way, like public parks. The classification of publicly owned industries based on the size and significance of the political units can’t be precise, since some types of industries are owned by various kinds of political units. Still, particularly in the context of American conditions, a rough classification can be established based on this principle. Federal states are made up of three main groups of political units: national, provincial, and local. Provincial units are the largest subdivisions, like American "states," or commonwealths, the German states, and the provinces in other countries. The term local political unit is more complicated and can refer to county, township, village, city, and school or sanitary district; however, most of what will be discussed about local ownership relates to cities or incorporated villages.

Municipal ownership of parks, libraries, &c.
Of bridges, markets, waterworks, &c.

Nearly all public parks and recreation grounds are owned by cities. As population has become more dense, private yards of any extent become impossible, in cities, for all but the wealthy. Public ownership of parks insures recreation grounds to the common man in the most economical way. Of late the movement for large and small public parks and playgrounds has gone on rapidly in American cities. Related[Pg 515] to parks are public baths, public libraries, art collections, museums, zoölogical gardens, etc. Some have declared that such a policy stops little short of a paralyzing socialism for the masses. Reason and experience fail to reveal any such danger so long as the things supplied gratify the higher tastes—as art, music, literature, innocent social recreation. Not until the necessities of life, as bread, clothing, and houses, are supplied, is encouragement given to the increase of improvident families and to the breaking down of independent character. The means of local communication—streets, roads, bridges—were once owned largely by private citizens. Here and there still are found toll roads and toll bridges built under charters granted a century ago, but tolls on public thoroughfares are for the most part abolished. A public market, where the producer from the farm and the city consumer can meet, is an old institution that is now being established anew in many cities. The providing of apparatus for extinguishing fires is always a public duty; the conveyance of waste water is increasingly a public function; and the supply of pure water, while often a private enterprise in villages, and sometimes in large cities, is increasingly undertaken by public agencies. Public ownership of gas and electric lighting is less common, as the utility supplied is not so essential and the industry is somewhat less subject to monopoly; but the difference is one of degree only. Street-railroads are often under public ownership in Europe; but there has thus far been no case of the kind in the United States, and only one in Canada.

Almost all public parks and recreation areas are owned by cities. As populations have become denser, having private yards of any size in cities has become impossible for everyone except the wealthy. Public ownership of parks ensures that everyone has access to recreational spaces in the most affordable way. Recently, the movement for both large and small public parks and playgrounds has rapidly progressed in American cities. Alongside parks, there are public baths, libraries, art collections, museums, zoos, and more. Some argue that this approach is dangerously close to a form of paralyzing socialism for the masses. However, reason and experience show no such threat as long as the provided amenities cater to higher tastes—like art, music, literature, and innocent social activities. It's only when basic needs, like food, clothing, and shelter, are met that there's a risk of promoting careless family growth and undermining independent character. Local infrastructure—streets, roads, and bridges—was once mostly owned by private individuals. There are still some toll roads and bridges built under charters from a century ago, but most tolls on public routes have been eliminated. Public markets, where farmers and city consumers can connect, are an old tradition that's being revived in many cities. Providing firefighting equipment is always a public responsibility; managing wastewater is increasingly a public task; and while supplying clean water is often a private initiative in villages and sometimes in larger cities, it's more frequently handled by public agencies now. Public ownership of gas and electric services is less common since these utilities aren't as essential and the industry is somewhat less prone to monopolies; but it’s still a matter of degree. Street railways are often publicly owned in Europe; however, there hasn't been a similar case in the United States yet, with only one instance in Canada.

American failures in state industry

2. The American state owns and conducts industries mainly whose products have a wider territorial use. The American commonwealth has retired from some fields where once it was engaged in industry. Students of American history know that between the years 1830 and 1840 some states engaged largely, even wildly, in the building of canals and undertook to construct railroads, to start banks, and to engage in other enterprises. The undertaking of these industries[Pg 516] was determined often by political and by selfish local interests, and their operation often was wasteful. A few enterprises succeeded, the most notable of these being the Erie Canal in New York. The unsuccessful ones remained worthless property in the hands of the state or were sold to private companies, as in the case of the Pennsylvania railroad. This reckless state enterprise was a bitter lesson in public ownership, and even after seventy-five years is not without effect on public opinion. For a long time no proposal for public ownership could have a fair hearing in America. But railroads and canals are publicly owned, and more or less successfully operated, in many foreign countries, as in Prussia and other German states, in Switzerland, and in the new states of Australia.

2. The American government owns and operates industries primarily whose products have a wider regional use. The American commonwealth has stepped back from some areas where it was once involved in industry. Those who study American history know that between 1830 and 1840, some states were heavily, even recklessly, invested in building canals and attempted to construct railroads, start banks, and engage in other ventures. The pursuit of these industries[Pg 516] was often driven by political motives and self-serving local interests, and their management frequently resulted in waste. A few projects succeeded, the most famous being the Erie Canal in New York. The unsuccessful ones remained as useless property owned by the state or were sold to private companies, like the Pennsylvania railroad. This reckless state involvement was a harsh lesson in public ownership, and even after seventy-five years, it still impacts public opinion. For a long time, no proposal for public ownership could be taken seriously in America. However, railroads and canals are publicly owned and managed with varying degrees of success in many foreign countries, such as Prussia and other German states, Switzerland, and the new states of Australia.

State ownership of various kinds

There has been recently a rise of interest in forestry in America. This is especially likely to be a state enterprise wherever the forest tracts are entirely within the limits of the state, as is the case of the Adirondacks in New York. Most of the forests in Germany are either communal or state-owned. The schools, a great industry for turning out a product of public utility, are largely conducted by the American state and by local units rather than by the nation or by private enterprise. The state encourages researches in the arts and sciences, and gives technical training. A variety of minor enterprises have been undertaken by states to supply salt, phosphate, banking facilities, even some manufactures. In the prisons and public institutions, states, such as New York, that have adopted the system of labor on public account engage in agriculture and manufacturing on a large scale, the products, amounting to millions of dollars annually, being used almost entirely by public agencies.

There has recently been a surge of interest in forestry in America. This is especially likely to be a state initiative wherever the forest areas are entirely within the state's borders, as is the case with the Adirondacks in New York. Most of the forests in Germany are either owned by the community or the state. The schools, which play a significant role in producing valuable public goods, are largely run by state and local governments rather than by the federal government or private companies. The state promotes research in the arts and sciences and provides technical training. Various smaller projects have been started by states to supply salt, phosphate, banking services, and even some manufacturing. In prisons and public institutions, states like New York that have adopted a system of state-run labor engage in large-scale agriculture and manufacturing, with the products—worth millions of dollars annually—being used almost entirely by public agencies.

National ownership of various kinds

3. The nation owns and controls many industries of the widest use and most general interest. Some industries grow out of the political needs of government. Established as a means of communication with military outposts, the post became a convenient means of communication for merchants[Pg 517] and other citizens and grew into a great economic institution. In most countries the telegraph is publicly owned and has been annexed to the post, to which it is very closely related in purpose. The national improvements connected with rivers and harbors were first political—that is, they were for the use of the governmental navy; they became, secondly, commercial—for the free use of all citizens engaged in trade; and they continue to unite these two characters. Forestry is most largely undertaken in this country by the national government, doubtless because the large forest areas in the West extend over state boundaries, and because large tracts of public lands were still unsold at the time public attention was attracted to the subject. Since 1890, the policy of reserving great areas for forests, and picturesque districts for national parks, has developed greatly. In some countries mines are thought to be peculiarly fitted for national ownership and control. In Germany, the state owns some coal, salt, and other mines. Coinage and banking are everywhere looked upon as a function of sovereignty, and yet it is no more necessary for a nation to own its own mint in order to control the monetary system than for it to print the bank-notes in order to regulate their issue. The American government has its own printing office and therewith its share of troubles with organized labor. The fish commission, and the various branches of the department, coöperate with private industry in many ways. In Germany, compulsory insurance is provided for the workingman. This hasty survey suggests that the industries undertaken by government are both varied in nature and large in extent, although small in proportion to the mass of private industry.

3. The nation owns and controls many industries that are widely used and of general interest. Some industries arise from the political needs of the government. Established as a way to communicate with military outposts, the postal system became a convenient means of communication for merchants[Pg 517] and other citizens, evolving into a significant economic institution. In most countries, the telegraph is publicly owned and closely linked to the postal service, serving similar purposes. National improvements related to rivers and harbors were initially political—that is, they served the government’s navy; they later became commercial—to benefit all citizens engaged in trade; and they still combine these two roles. Forestry is primarily managed in this country by the federal government, likely because the large forest areas in the West cross state lines and because substantial tracts of public land remained unsold when the public started paying attention to the issue. Since 1890, the policy of reserving large areas for forests and scenic regions for national parks has greatly expanded. In some countries, mines are viewed as particularly suitable for national ownership and control. In Germany, the state owns certain coal, salt, and other mines. Coinage and banking are generally considered a function of sovereignty, yet it is not necessary for a nation to own its mint to control the monetary system, just as it does not need to print banknotes to regulate their issuance. The American government has its own printing office, which brings its own challenges with organized labor. The fish commission and various branches of the department collaborate with private industries in many ways. In Germany, mandatory insurance is provided for workers. This quick overview indicates that the industries managed by the government are diverse and extensive, although they are small compared to the overall private industry.

§ II. ECONOMIC ASPECTS OF PUBLIC OWNERSHIP

The primary need of public ownership

1. Public ownership is primarily to control the essential agencies of government. A large part of public ownership and activity in industry develops from political functions.[Pg 518] As society evolves, what was unessential to political life becomes essential. Civilized government requires the use of a number of material agents. Buildings for legislative and executive officers, custom-houses, post-offices, lighthouses, can be rented of private citizens, as post-offices usually are in small places; but it is obviously economical and convenient in large cities for the government to own the public buildings. Government can reduce to a minimum its employment of labor by "farming out" the taxes, as all countries once did to some extent, and as France continued to do up to the French Revolution. It is now the settled policy for government to own or control its essential agencies, but this does not involve in every case the employment of day-labor direct to clean the streets, to collect garbage, etc. The more simple political functions shade off into the economic. To coinage usually are added the issue of legal-tender notes and certain banking functions; the post carries packages, transmits money, and in some cases performs the function of a savings-bank for small amounts. The only open question is as to the proper limit to this development.

1. Public ownership is mainly about controlling the essential agencies of government. Much of public ownership and activity in industry arises from political functions.[Pg 518] As society changes, things that were once unimportant to political life become necessary. A functioning government requires various physical resources. Buildings for legislative and executive officers, customs houses, post offices, and lighthouses can be rented from private citizens, just like post offices often are in small towns; however, in large cities, it's clearly more economical and convenient for the government to own public buildings. The government can minimize its labor costs by outsourcing taxes, as all countries once did to some extent and as France continued to do until the French Revolution. It’s now a common practice for the government to own or control its essential agencies, but this doesn’t necessarily mean hiring day laborers directly to clean the streets, collect garbage, etc. The simpler political functions blend into economic ones. Coinage is typically accompanied by the issuance of legal-tender notes and some banking functions; the post is responsible for delivering packages, transferring money, and in some cases acting as a savings bank for small amounts. The only remaining question is where to draw the line on this development.

Conflict of public and private interests

2. Public industry expands to supply as free goods many essentials of good citizenship, and to insure cheaper and more bountiful supplies of others. It is the ideal of Herbert Spencer and of a small surviving group of laissez faire philosophers that government should confine itself exclusively to the most essential political functions, leaving the economic functions absolutely alone. It should keep the peace, prevent men from beating and robbing each other, and preserve the personal liberty of the citizen. They assume that all of the economic needs will be provided by competition, in the best way humanly possible, in quantities and at the rate needed. In many cases, however, the general interest fails to harmonize with that of the individual. The forest has an immediate utility to the consumers of lumber, and it has also a diffused utility in its influence on industry, on climate, and on torrents and floods. Yet, as the private owner cannot[Pg 519] control enough of the forest to affect the climate, and could not sell climate even if he could affect it, he will cut down the tree whenever he can gain by doing so. In this situation either government control or government ownership of forests is essential.

2. Public industry grows to provide many essentials of good citizenship as free goods, ensuring cheaper and more abundant supplies of others. The ideal of Herbert Spencer and a small group of surviving laissez faire philosophers is that the government should focus solely on the most essential political functions, leaving economic functions completely untouched. It should maintain peace, stop people from harming and stealing from each other, and protect the personal freedom of citizens. They believe that all economic needs will be met by competition in the best way possible, in the right amounts and at the needed pace. However, in many situations, the general interest doesn't align with that of the individual. A forest is immediately useful to lumber consumers, but it also provides broader benefits through its effects on industry, climate, and flood control. Yet, since a private owner can't control enough of the forest to impact the climate and couldn't sell climate even if they could affect it, they will chop down trees whenever it profits them. In this scenario, either government regulation or government ownership of forests is crucial.

Social economy of some public industry

In some cases the difficulty of private ownership is in the excessive cost of collecting for the service. The cost of maintaining tollhouses at short intervals on a turnpike sometimes exceeds the amount collected. Collection in other cases, as for the service of lighthouses to passing ships, is impossible. Public industry secures, through the economy of large production, a cheaper and more efficient service, the benefits and costs being diffused throughout the community. The benefits of the work of experiment-stations for agriculture are felt immediately by the farmers, but are diffused to all citizens. A manufacturer able to keep his methods secret, or to retain his advantages for a time, can afford to undertake experiments in his factory, but the farmer seldom can. The public ownership of parks for the use of all gives a maximum of economy in the production of the most essential utilities—fresh air, sunshine, natural beauty, and playgrounds in the midst of crowded populations. Municipal ownership of waterworks is an extension of the same idea. Not only because large amounts of water are used by the public, but because cheap, pure, abundant water is an essential condition to good citizenship, speculation should in every possible way be eliminated from this industry.

In some cases, the challenge of private ownership comes from the high cost of collecting for the service. The expense of maintaining toll booths at short distances on a turnpike can sometimes be greater than the amount collected. In other situations, like the service of lighthouses for passing ships, collection is impossible. Public industry benefits from the efficiency of large-scale production, providing a cheaper and more effective service, with the benefits and costs spread across the community. The advantages of the work done by agricultural experiment stations are directly felt by farmers but also benefit all citizens. A manufacturer who can keep their methods secret or maintain their advantages for a while might afford to experiment in their factory, but farmers rarely can. Public ownership of parks for everyone ensures maximum efficiency in providing vital resources—fresh air, sunlight, natural beauty, and recreational spaces within crowded areas. Municipal ownership of waterworks follows the same principle. Since large amounts of water are consumed by the public, and because affordable, clean, and abundant water is essential for good citizenship, any speculative practices in this industry should be minimized.

Monopolistic nature of localized industries

3. Public ownership tends constantly to include the industries of a monopolistic nature, locally supplying general necessities. This is no abstract principle; it is merely a statement of what is seen to be happening. Some industries are of such a nature that they drift inevitably into monopolistic control. Waterworks, gas, electric lighting, street-railways, telephone systems, are among these. However fierce may be the competition for a time, sooner or later either one company drives out the other or buys it up, or both come[Pg 520] to an agreement by which the public is made to pay higher prices.

3. Public ownership tends to consistently involve industries that are monopolistic in nature and provide essential services locally. This isn't just a theoretical idea; it’s simply a reflection of what we observe happening. Some industries naturally end up being monopolized. Waterworks, gas, electric lighting, street railways, and telephone systems are examples of this. No matter how intense the competition may be for a time, eventually, either one company forces out the other, buys it out, or they both reach[Pg 520] an agreement that results in the public paying higher prices.

Localized production favors monopoly

A feature favoring the growth of monopoly when such industries are left to private enterprise, is the need to produce and supply the utility at a given locality. While two street-railways can compete on neighboring streets, it is physically impossible for two or more to compete on the same street. Two systems of water-mains or gas-mains can be put down, as sometimes is done, but this is not only a great economic waste, but the tearing up of the streets is an intolerable public nuisance. This difficulty is less marked in the case of telephones and electric lighting, and some persons still cling to faith in competition to regulate the rates in those industries; but faith in competition between water-companies and between gas-companies has been given up by nearly all students of the subject.

A key factor that supports the growth of monopoly when these industries are left to private companies is the necessity to produce and supply the utility in a specific location. While two streetcar lines can compete on adjacent streets, it’s impossible for two or more to compete on the same street. Two sets of water or gas mains can be installed, as is sometimes done, but this creates significant economic waste, and tearing up the streets is an unbearable public nuisance. This issue is less pronounced with telephones and electric lighting, and some people still believe in competition to keep rates in check in those fields; however, most experts have abandoned faith in competition among water and gas companies.

Gains from large production favor monopoly

4. A second feature favoring monopoly in such industries is the marked advantage of large production in them. These industries are usually spoken of as "industries of increasing returns." This advantage is enjoyed in some degree by every enterprise, but it is gradually neutralized and limited (as has been noted elsewhere). The need to extend an expensive physical plant to every point where customers are to be served, and the very much smaller cost per unit of delivering large amounts of water, gas, electricity, transportation, etc., on the same street, offered a greater inducement for one competitor to crowd out or buy out the other at a more than liberal price. Even then, larger net dividends and correspondingly larger capitalization are secured than were before possible to both companies combined.

4. A second feature that favors monopoly in these industries is the clear benefit of large-scale production. These industries are often referred to as "industries of increasing returns." Every business experiences this advantage to some extent, but it gradually diminishes and gets limited (as noted elsewhere). The necessity to expand an expensive physical infrastructure to every location where customers need service, combined with the significantly lower cost per unit for delivering large volumes of water, gas, electricity, transportation, etc., on the same street, provides a stronger incentive for one competitor to push out or acquire the other at a generous price. Even so, larger net profits and correspondingly larger capitalization are achieved than what was previously possible for both companies together.

Uniformity of products favors monopoly

5. A third feature favoring monopoly is uniformity in the quality of the product furnished. It is a general truth that competition is most persistent where there is the greatest range of choice open to the customer, and consequently the most individual treatment required in the enterpriser. An artist, even a storekeeper, attracts about him a body of patrons[Pg 521] who like his product (for the merchant's manner and method of dealing are a part of the quality of his goods), and who cannot be tempted away by slight differences in price. Rival companies in the stage of competition are seen to claim superiority for their particular goods and to improve their service in every way possible. A new telephone company, entering where a monopoly has held the field, works at once a wonderful betterment in rates, courtesy, and service. But as the product of all competitors attains the highest technical standard possible at the time, the rivalry is reduced to one of price, and it is usually a "fight to the finish."

5. One reason that supports monopolies is the consistency in product quality. It's generally true that competition is strongest when customers have the most choices available, leading to the need for more personalized treatment from business owners. An artist or even a shopkeeper attracts a group of loyal customers[Pg 521] who appreciate their product (because the merchant's style and how they interact are part of the quality of their goods), and these customers are not easily swayed by minor price differences. Competing companies often claim their goods are superior and strive to enhance their services in all possible ways. When a new telephone company enters a market previously dominated by a monopoly, it can immediately improve rates, customer service, and overall service quality. However, as the products from all competitors reach the highest technical standards available, the competition often boils down to price, which typically becomes a "fight to the finish."

Franchises favor monopoly

6. A fourth feature favoring monopoly in these enterprises is the necessity of making permanent and exceptional use of the public streets and alleys. If this right were granted by a general law to every citizen, this feature would be sufficiently implied in the foregoing discussion. As it would be intolerable to allow private interests to use public property in whatever way they wished, the legislative body makes special grants in such cases in view of the circumstances. Not only is the legislature (or council, or county board of commissioners, etc.) induced by the economic difficulties to withhold a charter to a second company, but it is exposed to the greatest corrupting influences by the one already established. The knowledge of the opposition to be encountered in getting a franchise must keep competitors out, even though monopoly prices are maintained.

6. A fourth factor that supports monopoly in these businesses is the need to make ongoing and exceptional use of public streets and alleys. If this right were granted by a general law to every citizen, this aspect would be clearly implied in the previous discussion. Since it would be unacceptable to let private interests use public property however they wanted, the legislative body makes special grants in these cases based on the circumstances. Not only is the legislature (or council, or county board of commissioners, etc.) compelled by economic challenges to deny a charter to a second company, but it also becomes vulnerable to significant corrupting influences from the existing one. The awareness of the obstacles involved in obtaining a franchise must deter competitors, even if monopoly prices remain high.

In view of these several features, which are so closely related that they form a common character, more or less fully shared by various industries, and especially in view of the necessity for the formal granting to them of peculiar privileges in the form of a public franchise, the public, in order to protect the general interest, is forced to undertake an exceptional control of these industries.

Considering these various features, which are closely interconnected to create a shared character among different industries, and especially because there is a need to formally grant them specific privileges through a public franchise, the public must take on an exceptional level of control over these industries to protect the general interest.

Modes of controlling public utilities

7. Several courses are open to the public, acting in its political capacity, to retain these monopoly advantages for the general welfare. First, it may do nothing, trusting[Pg 522] vainly to competition to regulate the rate, or consciously leaving the result to be worked out by the monopoly principle; this is what in most cases has been done in the past in America. Second, in granting the franchise it may attempt to fix near cost the charge for the service or product, so that the franchise will be worth little or nothing. Third, it may leave the rate to be fixed by the monopoly principle, but charge for the franchise so much that the value of the monopoly is appropriated into the public treasury. Fourth, it may have public officials carry on the business, either selling the product at cost or making monopoly profits that go into the public treasury. Various combinations of these plans are followed in practice, the most common plan being the fixing of maximum rates which, with improved methods, generally become ineffective. It is difficult to fix a uniform rate that is equitable, because conditions change, and, further, because a uniform rate must be applied to all parts of the town, although the cost of service varies greatly. It is difficult to sell the franchise for near what it is worth, because of the uncertainty, of the political blackmail, and of the limited number of competent bidders. There remains only the policy of public ownership to secure the profits of monopoly to the public, either directly or in a diffused manner.

7. Several options are available to the public, acting in its political role, to maintain these monopoly advantages for the overall benefit. First, it may choose to do nothing, naively trusting[Pg 522] competition to set the rate, or deliberately leaving the outcome to the monopoly principle; this is what has often been done in the past in America. Second, when granting the franchise, it may try to set the price for the service or product close to cost, making the franchise nearly worthless. Third, it might allow the monopoly principle to set the rate but charge so much for the franchise that the value of the monopoly gets funneled into the public treasury. Fourth, it could have public officials run the business, either selling the product at cost or making monopoly profits that go into the public treasury. Various combinations of these strategies are used in practice, with the most common being the establishment of maximum rates that, with improved methods, usually become ineffective. Fixing a uniform rate that is fair is challenging because conditions change, and additionally, a uniform rate must apply to all parts of the town, even though the cost of service varies widely. Selling the franchise for its actual value is difficult due to uncertainty, political pressure, and the limited number of qualified bidders. The only remaining option is public ownership to ensure that the profits of monopoly benefit the public, either directly or indirectly.

Economic basis of public ownership
Cost under public or private ownership

8. Public ownership is economically justified when it secures a utility of widespread consumption, otherwise impossible, or insures the public a better quality or a lower price. The question of public ownership is not exclusively an economic question. There are incidental problems, such as its effects on enterprise and on political integrity, with which it is not possible here to deal. In the main, however, public ownership is simply a business proposition which must be justified by its economic results. In the case of a general social benefit not to be secured without public ownership, as popular education or the climatic effect of forests, the only question to answer is whether the utility is worth the cost. In[Pg 523] the case of industries already in private hands, as waterworks, gas and electric lighting, there is needed, to make a wise decision possible, a knowledge of the effect a change to public ownership will have on value. If public officials can furnish some goods cheaper than they are furnished by private enterprise, it is because of the wide margin of monopoly profit, not because there is any magic in public ownership. The same general items of cost must be met. The first cost of the plant and the annual interest payments are much the same. Experience shows that, because of political influence, wages are likely to be higher under public ownership, but salaries of officials are higher under private ownership. On the whole, public industry in these respects probably has no advantage. Some items of cost may be less under public management. Public collection of dues along with taxes is an advantage not enjoyed by private companies. Several public officials sometimes share the same office and thus reduce expenses. In small towns the public electric lighting and waterworks have been operated more economically under one roof. Public industry does not have to meet the cost of lobbying and blackmail which are often forced upon private companies. But the greatest source of saving in public ownership is the value of monopoly privileges that, under private management, go into private pockets.

8. Public ownership makes sense economically when it provides a widely used service that couldn’t be achieved otherwise, or when it guarantees the public better quality or lower prices. The question of public ownership isn't just about economics. There are related concerns, like its impact on businesses and political integrity, that we can’t explore here. However, the core of public ownership is simply a business case that needs to be validated by its economic outcomes. When it comes to a general social benefit that can only be achieved through public ownership, such as public education or the environmental benefits of forests, the question is whether the utility justifies the cost. In[Pg 523] situations where industries are already privately owned, like waterworks, gas, and electric lighting, it's crucial to understand how a shift to public ownership will affect value for a wise decision. If public officials can provide certain services cheaper than private companies, it's due to the significant profits that come from monopolies, not because public ownership has any special advantages. The same general costs need to be met. The initial investment for the facilities and the annual interest payments are largely similar. Experience shows that, due to political influences, wages tend to be higher under public ownership, while salaries for officials can be higher in private settings. Overall, there may not be a clear advantage to public industry in these areas. Some costs might be lower under public management. Public entities can collect dues alongside taxes, which private companies can’t do. In smaller towns, public electric and water services have been more cost-effective when managed together. Public industries don’t have to bear the costs of lobbying and corruption that often pressure private companies. However, the biggest savings in public ownership come from the value of monopoly privileges that, under private management, benefit only a few individuals.

Character of public officials
Limits and effects of public ownership

The temptation to political corruption may be more insistent when a large force of men is constantly employed, and when large supplies are constantly purchased, by public officials, but the temptation is not so strong or so centralized as it is in the granting of franchises to wealthy corporations. Public industry is weakened by the absence of certain motives to excellence that are present in private business. The income of public officials not being dependent on the economy of management, the spur and motives of competitive industry are lacking. No social discovery has made individual honesty and civic virtue useless to good government.

The pressure for political corruption might be stronger when a large group of people is always employed and when public officials are frequently buying large supplies. However, this temptation isn't as intense or focused as when wealthy corporations are granted franchises. Public industries suffer because they lack the strong incentives for excellence that exist in private business. Since public officials’ income doesn’t depend on effective management, they miss out on the drive and motivations that come from competition. No social advancement has rendered personal integrity and civic responsibility irrelevant to effective governance.

The decision in any specific case is one dependent on local[Pg 524] conditions, and the exact limits of public ownership are not fixed. Industry is changing so rapidly that new experience is needed each year. The main outlines of public ownership, however, are now in large part determined. Some industries do well, others ill, under public management, and between these lie many debatable cases. Waterworks and probably electric lighting, because of the comparative simplicity of their operation, are more suitable for public ownership than are gas-works. No absolute line divides the one group from the other. But whatever the changes, the student of the theory of value must never overlook the fact that the increase of public ownership is altering in manifold ways the prices of goods, and is reacting also on the production, distribution, and consumption of incomes.

The decision in any specific case depends on local[Pg 524] conditions, and the exact boundaries of public ownership aren't set in stone. Industries are changing so quickly that new experiences are needed each year. However, the main frameworks of public ownership are largely established now. Some industries perform well under public management, while others do poorly, and there are many gray areas in between. Water systems and probably electric lighting are more suited for public ownership due to the relative simplicity of their operations compared to gas works. There’s no clear-cut line separating the two groups. But no matter the changes, anyone studying the theory of value must remember that the rise in public ownership is affecting prices of goods in various ways and is also influencing the production, distribution, and consumption of incomes.


CHAPTER 54

RAILROADS AND INDUSTRY

§ I. TRANSPORTATION AS A FORM OF PRODUCTION

Productivity of transportation

1. Transportation of goods and men is one of the most important modes of production. When utility was thought of as inherent in things rather than as resulting from a relation between things and wants, it was usual to consider only those industries as truly productive that brought something physical into existence, as do agriculture and the extractive industries. Even after it was recognized that a change of form also imparted value, it was still denied that a changing of place could be truly productive industry. But when production is seen to be the bringing of things into right relations with wants, transportation may be deemed to be the primary and typical mode of increasing income. Movement is necessary to the existence of animals. The animal, in the order of evolution a higher form of life than the more fixed plants, goes to seek food, and has open to it a wider range of possibilities in life. With slight exceptions, it is true that the only way in which animals can bring about better place-relations between their wants and goods is by moving themselves. To this power man has added that of moving goods and thus adds enormously to income. Agents being valued in accordance with their net productiveness, the nearness to market and the ease of transporting the product are large factors in price. The location of a field enters into its value as truly as do the chemical qualities of the soil. A rocky field near a market may be richer, in an industrial[Pg 526] sense, than the richest soil far remote, which can be used by men only at the cost of their alienation from society. Means of transportation set a limit to social and political groupings, to the size of the market, and to the possibility of exchange. Indeed, all exchange value is conditioned upon the possibility of transportation.

1. Transporting goods and people is one of the most important ways to produce. When people thought of utility as something inherent in items rather than as a result of the relationship between items and needs, only industries that physically created something, like agriculture and extraction, were seen as truly productive. Even after it was acknowledged that changing the form of goods added value, many still denied that changing their location could be a productive industry. However, when we understand production as the act of aligning things with our needs, transportation can be viewed as the main way to increase income. Movement is essential for the survival of animals. Animals, being a more advanced form of life in evolution compared to stationary plants, seek out food and have a broader range of life possibilities. With few exceptions, animals can only improve the relationship between their needs and goods by moving. Humans have enhanced this ability by being able to move goods, greatly increasing income. Agents are valued based on their net productivity, so proximity to the market and the ease of transporting products are significant factors in pricing. The location of a field contributes to its value just as much as the chemical properties of the soil do. A rocky field near a market can be more valuable from an industrial[Pg 526] perspective than the richest soil far away, which can only be utilized by people at the cost of separating them from society. Transportation methods limit social and political structures, the size of the market, and the potential for exchange. In fact, all exchange value relies on the ability to transport items.

Original local advantages

2. Natural differences in the grades of fertility and of accessibility determine first the most valued locations. Primitive man, dependent on the bounties of nature, had to take things as he found them. Few places unite the best grades of the essential things: water, food, fertile soil, a favorable climate, protection against enemies. Between tribe and tribe went on ceaseless war for the few favored spots of the earth. Where transportation is possible, trade can supply one or more of the missing elements. International trade began early, wherever it could, to strengthen economically the weak localities. Advantages in transportation are sometimes better than fertile soil and rich resources. The early centers of civilization were on the banks of rivers and the shores of seas. Around the Mediterranean were the ancient empires. Trading-towns grew up at ports and at the favored points of trade: Tyre, Sidon, Carthage, Florence, Genoa, Venice, Antwerp, London, New York. The early settlements in America were grouped along the coast. Without the cheap communication afforded by water, the colonies would have been cut off from the benefits of continuing contact with the older civilization. It would have been a great price to pay, even for a rich continent.

2. The natural variations in fertility and accessibility define the most desirable locations. Early humans, relying on nature's resources, had to accept whatever conditions they encountered. Very few places offered the best combination of essential resources: water, food, fertile land, a suitable climate, and protection from threats. Constant conflicts arose between tribes for control of these limited, prime locations. When transportation was feasible, trade could provide some of the missing resources. International trade started early, wherever it was possible, to economically support weaker regions. Sometimes, advantages in transportation outweighed fertile land and abundant resources. The first centers of civilization developed along rivers and coastlines. The ancient empires surrounded the Mediterranean. Trading cities emerged at ports and key trading points: Tyre, Sidon, Carthage, Florence, Genoa, Venice, Antwerp, London, New York. Early American settlements were clustered along the coast. Without the inexpensive transportation offered by waterways, the colonies would have been isolated from the ongoing interaction with older civilizations. This would have been a steep cost, even for a resource-rich continent.

Influence of waterways on local advantages

3. The opening up of new water-routes of travel has profoundly altered the prosperity of nations. Sometimes the relation of cause and effect is the reverse of that just noted. The conquest of Asia Minor by the Turks closed the lines of travel with the East, destroyed the trade of the Italian cities, and stimulated exploration for new routes. The War of 1812 in America stopped the coast trade and forced on the wagon-roads between the New England and the Southern states a[Pg 527] great traffic, which declined quickly at the close of the war. Again, the growth of population and industry shifts the center of trade, as it did from the south to the north of Europe, and as it is doing from England to America. The discovery of new routes, however, has wrought the most rapid and sweeping changes. These three causes united, about the time of the discovery of America, to overthrow the prosperity of the older cities of Europe, while the opening of the resources in America, the abundance of silver and gold, trade with the colonists and the Indians, showered wealth and trade into the lap of Spain, Holland, Belgium, England, and the northern cities of Germany. Such changes continue under our eyes. The Erie Canal has an influence on values in every township from New York to Buffalo, and along the lake shores to the head of Lake Superior. The Suez Canal marked an epoch in ocean travel. The American Isthmian Canal will affect the value of many investments, from the Gulf of Mexico to the Pacific Coast. A marked change in transportation thus shifts the level of values in a locality. Fortunes are made and lost. One community rises and another sinks. Increments and decrements of value on a great scale are unearned, and all classes of goods are affected, though in varying degrees.

3. The opening of new water routes for travel has significantly changed the wealth of nations. Sometimes the relationship between cause and effect is the opposite of what was just mentioned. The Turks' conquest of Asia Minor shut down the travel routes to the East, harmed the trade of Italian cities, and sparked exploration for new paths. The War of 1812 in America halted coastal trade and forced heavy traffic onto wagon roads between the New England and Southern states, which quickly decreased after the war ended. Additionally, population growth and industrialization shift trade centers, as seen with the movement from southern to northern Europe, and now from England to America. However, the discovery of new routes has led to the fastest and most extensive changes. These three factors combined around the time of America's discovery to undermine the prosperity of older European cities, while the opening of resources in America, along with the wealth of silver and gold and trade with colonists and Native Americans, poured wealth and commerce into Spain, Holland, Belgium, England, and the northern German cities. Such changes are still happening today. The Erie Canal impacts property values in every township from New York to Buffalo and along the lake shores up to the head of Lake Superior. The Suez Canal marked a significant turning point in ocean travel. The American Isthmian Canal will influence the value of many investments, from the Gulf of Mexico to the Pacific Coast. A significant change in transportation therefore alters property values in a region. Fortunes can be made or lost. One community thrives while another declines. Changes in value on a large scale occur without effort, affecting all categories of goods, though to different extents.

§ II. THE RAILROAD AS A CARRIER

Technical vs. economic efficiency of transportation

1. Different modes of transport are more or less economical relatively to the other industrial conditions. Not only new routes but new agents of travel change the scale of values. In early societies, undeveloped industrially, first men, then domestic animals, were used as beasts of burden. The first vehicles are technically simple in design and construction; on land are used drags, sleds, carts; on waterways are used rafts, canoes, barges, and boats. Primitive means of transportation had to be inexpensive, for poverty and the uncertainty of early society forbade the tying up of large resources[Pg 528] in them. Technical efficiency of means of transportation may be contrasted with economic efficiency. Technical goodness is absolute, and is measured in speed and weight of cargo; economic efficiency is relative, and varies with the money cost and money value of the services. A turnpike is more efficient than a mud road, yet in some districts it is bad economy to build it. A railroad is more efficient than a cart, yet in some places even pack-horses are more economical. To be economical, the expenditure needed to supply the efficient agent must be warranted by the volume and value of traffic.

1. Different modes of transport are more or less economical compared to other industrial conditions. New routes and new forms of travel change the scale of values. In early societies, which were not industrialized, humans and then domesticated animals served as beasts of burden. The first vehicles were technically simple in design and construction; on land, there were drags, sleds, and carts; on waterways, there were rafts, canoes, barges, and boats. Primitive transportation methods had to be inexpensive because the poverty and uncertainty of early society prevented the allocation of large resources[Pg 528] to them. The technical efficiency of transportation methods can be contrasted with their economic efficiency. Technical quality is absolute, measured in speed and cargo weight; economic efficiency is relative and varies with the monetary cost and value of services. A turnpike is more efficient than a muddy road, yet in some areas, it may not be economically viable to build one. A railroad is more efficient than a cart, yet in some locations, even pack-horses can be more economical. To be cost-effective, the investment needed to support an efficient means of transport must be justified by the volume and value of traffic.

Economic advantages of natural waterways

2. The most economical means of transportation before the railroad were the waterways, natural and artificial. Some natural waterways still afford the most economical means of transportation between favorably situated ports. Coal is shipped most cheaply in sailing vessels from Wales around Cape Horn to ports along the western coasts of America. A part of California's regular fuel-supply is obtained in this way. Coal has been shipped from Pennsylvania to Europe, and in the anthracite coal-strike in 1902, some was shipped from England to America. Invention has reduced the cost of construction and operation of vessels and has increased their safety and speed, thus multiplying the efficiency of the natural waterways. The large cities in America are situated on waterways, usually where there is a break in transportation requiring reshipment, as, for example, at New York, San Francisco, Buffalo, New Orleans, Cincinnati, Chicago, Minneapolis, and St. Paul. Likewise many of the small cities and villages, serving as local trading centers, owe their existence to similar though less powerful influences.

2. The most cost-effective way of getting around before the railroad was through waterways, both natural and man-made. Some natural waterways still provide the most affordable transportation between well-placed ports. Coal is shipped most cheaply in sailing ships from Wales, around Cape Horn, to ports along the western coasts of America. This method supplies a part of California's regular fuel needs. Coal has also been shipped from Pennsylvania to Europe, and during the anthracite coal strike in 1902, some was brought from England to America. Innovations have lowered the costs to build and operate vessels while enhancing their safety and speed, greatly improving the efficiency of natural waterways. Major cities in America are located near waterways, usually where a change in transportation is necessary, such as in New York, San Francisco, Buffalo, New Orleans, Cincinnati, Chicago, Minneapolis, and St. Paul. Similarly, many small towns and villages that act as local trading hubs owe their existence to comparable, albeit less significant, factors.

Merits and defects of canals

Canals are begun as connecting links in a system of natural waterways to extend the advantages of cheap transportation. The Erie Canal not only serves the three hundred miles of territory along its banks, but it opened to commerce all the lands tributary to the Great Lakes. The great advantage of canals is cheapness of operation due to the simplicity of the machinery needed and to the great loads that can be moved[Pg 529] with small power. A cent a ton-mile is a paying rate on a canal. For heavy, slow-moving freight, the railroads can hardly rival the canals at their best. As canals, however, can be built only along a level country and where the water supply is at a high level, their construction is limited to a small portion of the country. The law of extensive diminishing returns applies strongly to the construction of canals. The first canals are easily constructed and economically operated, but it is only with greater cost and difficulty that the system can be successively extended. In temperate climates their use is limited by ice to a part of the year, and the summer's drought sometimes limits it still further. At its best, therefore, the small land-locked canal is fitted only to be a supplementary agent in the system of transportation wherever industry demands high speed and great regularity. Far different is the case of the oceanic canal in a tropical climate.

Canals are created as connections in a system of natural waterways to enhance the benefits of low-cost transportation. The Erie Canal not only serves the three hundred miles of land along its banks but also opened up all the lands connected to the Great Lakes for trade. The major advantage of canals is their low operating costs, thanks to the simplicity of the machinery required and the ability to transport heavy loads with minimal power. A cent per ton-mile is a profitable rate on a canal. For heavy, slow-moving freight, railroads can hardly compete with canals at their best. However, canals can only be built in flat areas and where the water supply is high, so their construction is limited to a small part of the country. The principle of diminishing returns applies strongly to canal construction. The initial canals are easily built and economically operated, but extending the system comes with increased costs and difficulties. In temperate regions, their use is limited by ice for part of the year, and summer droughts can further restrict usage. Thus, at best, a small land-locked canal is only suitable as a supplementary part of the transportation system where industries need high speed and consistent service. In contrast, the situation is very different for oceanic canals in tropical climates.

Superior advantages of railroads

3. The railroad is rapidly surpassing in importance every other agency of transportation. Even in respect to cheapness, the unique virtue of waterways in favored localities, the railroad has been making rapid gains. Improvements in roadbed, rails, cars, engines, and other equipment are reducing greatly the cost of conducting traffic on the main lines of roads. The adaptability of the railroad excels that of any other agent of transportation; it can go over mountains or tunnel through them. In certainty its superiority is marked; floods and snows may delay it for a day, but there is no seasonal stoppage of traffic. In speed, the railroad so far excels that the canal can survive only by dividing the traffic, taking the lower grades of freight, and leaving to the railroad the passenger traffic and fast freight.

3. The railroad is quickly becoming more important than any other means of transportation. Even when it comes to cost, the special advantage of waterways in certain areas, the railroad is making significant progress. Upgrades to the tracks, trains, cars, engines, and other equipment are greatly lowering the cost of moving goods on the main routes. The flexibility of the railroad surpasses that of any other transportation option; it can travel over mountains or tunnel through them. Its superiority is clear; floods and snow might delay it for a day, but traffic doesn't stop seasonally. In terms of speed, the railroad is so much faster that the canal can only stay relevant by taking on the slower freight and leaving the passenger and fast freight traffic to the railroad.

Results of the rapid growth of railroads

Because of these qualities, the extension of the railroads in the last fifty years has been so rapid that it has not given time for a gradual adaptation of industry. It has worked in many places revolutionary changes. The building of railroads in the Mississippi valley in the seventies lowered the[Pg 530] value of Eastern farms, ruined many English farmers, and depressed the peasantry in all western Europe. With the prices that resulted when the fertile lands of the Western prairies were opened to the world's markets, the stony and worked-out lands of the older districts could not compete. Great regions are still to be opened in this manner in Russia, Siberia, Africa, and South America. While one can only speculate upon the effects this development will have, the changes promise to be less sudden and tremendous than those of the last twenty years. Many minor changes, of no less moment in limited districts, result from the building of railroads. Local trading-centers decrease in importance. Villages and towns, hoping to be enriched by the railroads, see trade going to the cities. Commerce becomes centralized. Enormous increase of value at a few points is offset by losses in other localities.

Because of these qualities, the expansion of the railroads in the last fifty years has been so fast that it hasn’t allowed for a gradual adjustment of industry. It has caused revolutionary changes in many areas. The construction of railroads in the Mississippi Valley in the seventies drove down the value of Eastern farms, devastated many English farmers, and harmed the peasantry across Western Europe. With the prices that resulted when the fertile lands of the Western prairies were opened to the global market, the rocky and exhausted lands of the older regions couldn’t compete. Vast areas are still to be developed in a similar way in Russia, Siberia, Africa, and South America. While we can only guess the effects this development will have, the changes are likely to be less sudden and extreme than those of the last twenty years. Many smaller changes, which are just as significant in specific areas, result from the construction of railroads. Local trading centers lose importance. Villages and towns, hoping to benefit from the railroads, find trade shifting to the cities. Commerce becomes centralized. The huge increase in value at a few locations is balanced by losses in other areas.

§ III. DISCRIMINATION IN RATES ON RAILROADS

Monopoly power of railroads

1. The railroad has more monopoly power in fixing rates at points along its lines than is the case with other agents of transportation. The ownership of the wagons, ships, and canal-boats of a country is usually divided. Every point along the line of the turnpike or the canal and at ocean ports enjoys competition between carriers, the great shipping combinations not having been successfully formed as yet. In the early days of the railroads it was believed that a company or the government would own the rails and charge toll to the different carriers, who would own cars and conduct the traffic as was done on the canals. Experience soon showed the utter impracticability of this scheme and the need of unified management. The railroad, therefore, has a monopoly at all points on its line not touched by other carriers. This, like all other monopoly, is limited by the need to secure some business and to meet competition at terminal points. The railroads in private hands early began to "charge what the traffic would[Pg 531] bear" at every station, thus practising various forms of discrimination disastrous in their effects on the citizens.

1. The railroad has more control over setting rates at points along its routes than other transportation options do. In a country, ownership of wagons, ships, and canal boats is typically spread out. Every location along the turnpike or canal, as well as at ocean ports, benefits from competition between carriers since major shipping alliances haven’t been effectively established yet. In the early days of railroads, people thought that a company or the government would own the tracks and charge different carriers tolls, who would own the cars and manage the traffic like it was done on the canals. However, experiences quickly revealed the impracticality of this approach and highlighted the need for centralized management. Consequently, the railroad holds a monopoly at all points along its line where no other carriers are present. This, like any other monopoly, is constrained by the necessity to attract some business and to compete at terminal locations. Private railroads soon started to “charge what the traffic would[Pg 531] bear” at every station, leading to various forms of discrimination that had disastrous effects on citizens.

Discrimination as to goods

2. Discrimination as to goods is charging more for transporting one kind of goods than for another without a corresponding difference in the cost. When reasonably understood, this proposition does not apply to a higher charge for goods of greater bulk, as more per pound for feathers than for iron, the "dead weight" of car being much greater in one case than in the other. It does not apply where there is a difference in risk, as in carrying bricks and powder, or coal and crockery; nor where there is a difference in trouble, as in shipping live stock and wheat. Any difference that can reasonably be explained as due to a difference in cost is not discrimination; on the other hand a difference in cost without a difference in rate is discrimination. Discrimination as to goods may be by value, as low rates for heavy, cheap goods and high rates for lighter, valuable ones. Coal always goes at a low rate as compared with dry goods, and sometimes more is charged for coal to be used for gas than for coal to be used for heating purposes. Discrimination as to goods is the most usual and, if reasonably employed, one of the most justifiable of the various kinds of rate discriminations.

2. Discrimination regarding goods means charging more to transport one type of goods than another without a valid difference in cost. When understood correctly, this idea doesn’t apply to higher charges for bulkier goods, like paying more per pound for feathers than for iron, since the "dead weight" of the car is much greater in one case than in the other. It also doesn’t apply when there’s a difference in risk, such as transporting bricks versus powder, or coal versus crockery; nor does it apply when there’s a difference in labor, like shipping live animals versus wheat. Any difference that can be reasonably explained as a difference in cost isn’t discrimination; however, a difference in cost without a difference in rate is discrimination. Discrimination regarding goods can be based on value, such as lower rates for heavy, inexpensive goods and higher rates for lighter, valuable ones. Coal usually has a lower rate compared to dry goods, and sometimes the rate for coal used for gas is higher than for coal used for heating. Discrimination in goods is the most common and, if used reasonably, one of the most justifiable types of rate discrimination.

Local discrimination

3. Discrimination between places (local discrimination) is charging different rates to two localities for substantially the same service. This occurs when local rates are high and through rates are low; when rates at local points are high and at competing points are low; when less is charged for shipments consigned to foreign ports than for domestic shipments; when more is charged for goods going east than for goods going west. The causes of local discrimination are: first, water-competition, found at great trade centers such as New York and San Francisco; second, differences in terminal facilities, making some places better shipping-points than others; third, competition by other railroads, which is concentrated at certain points, only four thousand (one tenth) of the stations of the United States being junctions; fourth,[Pg 532] the influence of powerful individuals or large corporations and the personal favoritism shown by railroad officials.

3. Local discrimination is charging different rates to two areas for essentially the same service. This happens when local rates are high while through rates are low; when rates at local locations are high and rates at competing locations are low; when less is charged for shipments going to foreign ports compared to domestic shipments; when more is charged for goods traveling east than for those heading west. The reasons for local discrimination include: first, water competition, seen in major trade centers like New York and San Francisco; second, differences in terminal facilities that make some locations better shipping points than others; third, competition from other railroads that is focused in specific areas, with only four thousand (one tenth) of the stations in the United States being junctions; fourth, [Pg 532] the influence of powerful individuals or large corporations and the personal favoritism shown by railroad officials.

Its effects

The effect of discrimination is to develop some districts and depress others; to stimulate cities and blight villages; to destroy established industries; to foster monopolies at favored points; and to sacrifice the future revenues of the road by forcing industry to move to the competing points to get the low rates. The power of railroad officials arbitrarily to cause rates to rise or fall is happily limited in practice by the need of earning as large and as regular an income as possible, but even as exercised it has been at times as great as that possessed by many political rulers.

The impact of discrimination is to uplift some areas while holding others back; to boost cities and ruin towns; to dismantle existing industries; to encourage monopolies in certain places; and to compromise future income for the railroads by pushing businesses to relocate to competing areas for better rates. Thankfully, the ability of railroad officials to raise or lower rates is mostly restricted by the necessity to earn a steady and substantial income, but even so, their control has at times been as significant as that of various political leaders.

Personal discrimination

4. Discrimination between shippers (personal discrimination) is charging one person more than another for substantially the same service. This most odious of railroad vices, rarely practised openly, is done by false billing of weight, by wrong descriptions or false classification to reduce the charge below published rate-sheets, by carrying some goods free, by issuing passes to one and not to all patrons under the same conditions, or by donations or rebates after the regular rate has been paid. In some cases a subordinate agent shares his commission with the shipper, and the transaction does not appear on the books of the company. In other cases favored shippers are given secret information that the rate is to be changed, so that they are enabled to regulate their shipments to secure the lower rate.

4. Discrimination between shippers (personal discrimination) is charging one person more than another for essentially the same service. This most despicable of railroad practices, rarely done openly, occurs through false weight billing, incorrect descriptions, or misleading classifications to lower the charge below the published rate sheets, by transporting some goods for free, by issuing passes to some patrons but not others under the same conditions, or by offering kickbacks or discounts after the regular rate has been paid. In some situations, a lower-level agent shares their commission with the shipper, and the transaction doesn't get recorded in the company's books. In other cases, favored shippers receive insider information that a rate change is coming, allowing them to adjust their shipments to take advantage of the lower rate.

Causes of personal discrimination

One group of reasons for personal discrimination is connected with the interests of the road. It is to build up new business; it is to make competition with rival roads more effective by favoring certain agents, as is very commonly done in the Western grain business; it is to exclude competition, as by refusing to make a rate from a connecting line or to receive materials for a new railroad which is to be a competitor; and it is to satisfy large shippers whose power, skill, and persistence make the concession necessary. Another group of reasons has to do with the interests of company officials.[Pg 533] It is to enable them to grant special favors to friends; or it is to build up a business in which they are interested; or it is to earn a bribe that has been given them.

One reason for personal discrimination is related to the interests of the railroad. It’s about developing new business; it’s about making competition with rival railroads more effective by favoring certain agents, which is very common in the Western grain trade; it’s about excluding competition, like refusing to set a rate from a connecting line or to accept materials for a new railroad that will be a competitor; and it’s about satisfying large shippers whose power, skill, and persistence make this concession necessary. Another set of reasons involves the interests of company officials.[Pg 533] It’s about enabling them to grant special favors to friends; or it’s about building a business in which they have a personal interest; or it’s about receiving a bribe that has been offered to them.

Evils of personal discrimination

That the evils of personal discrimination are great, need hardly be said. It introduces uncertainty, fear, and danger into all business; it causes business men to waste, socially viewed, an enormous fund of energy to get good rates and to guard against surprises; it grants unearned fortunes and destroys those honestly made; it gives enormous power and presents strong temptations to railroad officials to injure the interests of the stockholders on the one hand and of the public on the other.

The problems caused by personal discrimination are significant, and there's little need to point that out. It brings uncertainty, fear, and risk into every business. It leads businesspeople to waste a massive amount of energy, socially speaking, just to secure fair rates and protect themselves from unexpected issues. It awards unearned wealth and undermines those who earn their fortunes honestly. It gives substantial power and creates powerful temptations for railroad executives to harm the interests of shareholders on one hand and the public on the other.

Apart from government, the railroad represents the greatest single economic factor in personal distribution. It has introduced a new form of problem into economic society. It has created a monopoly comparable to the prerogatives of feudal lords. No other industrial agency in private hands so affects all the producing forces of society and exercises such a potent influence on values.

Apart from the government, the railroad is the biggest single economic factor in personal distribution. It has brought a new type of problem into the economy. It has created a monopoly similar to the privileges of feudal lords. No other private industry impacts all the productive forces of society or has such a strong influence on values.


CHAPTER 55

THE PUBLIC NATURE OF RAILROADS

§ I. PUBLIC PRIVILEGES OF RAILROAD CORPORATIONS

Public nature of railroad franchises

1. Railroads enjoy peculiar public privileges through their charters, franchises, and the right of eminent domain. Railroads in our country are owned by private corporations and are managed by private citizens, not, as in some countries, by public officials. They have been built under the motive of private enterprise, in the interest of the investor, not as a charity or as a public benefaction. Railroad-building appears thus at first glance to be a case of free competition where public interests are served in the following of private interests. But, looked at more closely, it may be seen to be in many ways different from the ordinary competitive business. Competition would make the building of railroads a matter of bargain with proprietors along the line, and an obdurate farmer could compel a long detour or could block the whole undertaking. But the public says: a public enterprise is of more importance than the interests of a single farmer. By charter or by franchise the railroad is granted the power of eminent domain, whereby the property of private citizens may be taken from them at an appraised valuation. The manufacturer, enjoying no such privilege, can only by ordinary purchase obtain a site urgently needed for his business. Why may the railway exercise the sovereign power of government and invade other private property rights? Because the railway is peculiarly "affected with a public interest." The primary object is not to favor the railroads, but to benefit[Pg 535] the community. These charters and franchises are granted sparingly in most European countries. In this country they have been granted recklessly, often in general laws, by states keen in their rivalry for railroad extension. When thus great public privileges had been granted without reserve to private corporations, it was realized, too late in many cases, that a mistake had been made and that an impossible situation had been created.

1. Railroads have unique public privileges through their charters, franchises, and the right of eminent domain. In our country, railroads are owned by private companies and run by private citizens, unlike in some countries where they are managed by public officials. They have been developed with the goal of private enterprise, focusing on the interests of investors, not as a charitable act or public service. At first glance, railroad construction seems like free competition benefiting public interests while pursuing private interests. However, upon closer inspection, it differs significantly from typical competitive businesses. Competition would mean negotiating with property owners along the route, and a stubborn farmer could force a lengthy detour or completely halt the project. But the public asserts that a public enterprise is more important than one farmer's interests. By charter or franchise, railroads are given the power of eminent domain, allowing them to take private citizens' property at a determined value. Manufacturers, lacking such privileges, can only acquire necessary land through regular purchase. Why can railroads use the government's sovereign power to encroach on private property rights? Because railroads are uniquely "affected with a public interest." The main aim isn’t to support railroads but to benefit[Pg 535] the community. These charters and franchises are typically granted sparingly in many European countries. In this country, however, they have been granted indiscriminately, often through broad legislation, by states eager to boost railroad expansion. When such significant public privileges were recklessly given to private companies, many realized too late that a mistake had been made, leading to an untenable situation.

State and National aid to American railroads

2. In America and in many other countries, large grants of lands and money have been made to railroads on the ground of their peculiar public nature. Railroads were granted not only peculiar powers and privileges, but also material aid. The railroad enterprise was uncertain, the possibilities of its growth could not be foreseen, and private capital would not invest without great inducements. In European countries where capitalists were less enterprising or venturesome than in America, railroad extension was very slow except where the state in some manner extended its aid to the enterprise. The American states abandoned the principle of non-interference most recklessly, and vied with each other in giving lands, money, and privileges, in loaning bonds, in subscribing for stock, and in releasing from taxation. These protective measures fostering a special enterprise were expected by increasing wealth to diffuse a greater welfare throughout the community. Many of the states were forced to the point of bankruptcy by their reckless generosity, and some of them repudiated the debts thus incurred. The national government then took up the same policy and granted lands to the states to be used for this purpose. The first example of this was the grant to the Illinois Central road, in 1850, of a great strip of land through the state from north to south. Grants were made in fourteen states, covering tens of millions of acres of land. Then the national government, between 1863 and 1869, aided the building of the Pacific railroads by granting outright twenty square miles of land for every mile of track and by loaning the credit of the government[Pg 536] to the extent of fifty million dollars—a debt settled by compromise only after thirty years.

2. In the U.S. and many other countries, large land and money grants were given to railroads due to their unique public role. Railroads received not just special powers and privileges, but also significant financial support. The railroad business was unpredictable, its growth potential was hard to predict, and private investors were hesitant to put money in without strong incentives. In European countries where investors were less daring than in the U.S., railroad expansion was slow unless the government provided some form of support. American states recklessly abandoned the principle of non-interference and competed with one another to offer lands, money, and privileges, to loan bonds, to buy stock, and to exempt from taxes. These supportive measures aimed at promoting a specific business were expected to create increased wealth and greater well-being for the community. Many states found themselves nearly bankrupt due to their excessive generosity, and some even refused to pay back the debts they had accrued. Then the national government adopted the same strategy and gave lands to the states for this purpose. The first instance of this was in 1850 when a significant strip of land was granted to the Illinois Central railroad to run through the state from north to south. Grants were made in fourteen states, totaling tens of millions of acres. Between 1863 and 1869, the national government further supported the construction of the Pacific railroads by granting twenty square miles of land for every mile of track and by lending the government's credit[Pg 536] for up to fifty million dollars—a debt that was only resolved through compromise after thirty years.

Railroad grants by localities

Counties, townships, cities, and villages along the line of projected roads then entered into keen competition to secure them. Bonds, bonuses, tax-exemptions, and many special privileges were granted. To obtain this new Aladdin's lamp, this great wealth-bringer, localities mortgaged their prosperity for years to come. The promoters bargained skilfully for these grants, playing off town against town, cultivating the speculative spirit, punishing the obdurate. Not the civil engineer, but the financial engineer platted the devious lines of many a railroad on the level prairies of America. The effects of these grants were in many cases disastrous, and since 1870 they have been forbidden in a number of states by legislation and by state constitutions. But before this era of generosity ended, probably the railroads had received more public aid than has ever been given to any other form of industry in private hands.

Counties, townships, cities, and villages along the proposed roads then started competing vigorously to secure them. They offered bonds, bonuses, tax exemptions, and many special privileges. To get this new Aladdin's lamp, this source of great wealth, local areas mortgaged their prosperity for years to come. The promoters skillfully negotiated these grants, pitting towns against each other, encouraging speculative behavior, and penalizing those who resisted. It wasn't the civil engineer, but the financial engineer who mapped out the complex routes of many railroads across the flat prairies of America. The consequences of these grants were often disastrous, and since 1870, they have been banned in several states through legislation and state constitutions. However, before this era of generosity came to an end, railroads likely received more public support than any other private industry ever has.

Investors' view of railroads' obligations

3. The railroads are now generally held to have peculiar public duties corresponding to their privileges. Do all these grants in the past make the railroads other than mere private enterprises? One answer, that of those financially interested in the railroads, is No. They say that the bargain was a fair one, and is now closed. The public gave because it expected benefit; the corporation fulfilled its agreement by building the road. The terms of the charter, as granted, determine the rights of the public; but no new terms can now be read into it, even though the public now sees the question in a new light. Similar grants, though not so large, have been made to other industries. Bounties have been given to sugar-factories; tariffs have favored iron-forges and woolen-mills; factories have been given, by competing cities, land and exemption from taxation; yet no attempt is made on that account to control these businesses in a peculiar way and to treat them as public enterprises. So, it is said, the railroad is still merely a private business.

3. Railroads are generally recognized as having specific public responsibilities that correspond to their privileges. Do all these past grants make railroads anything more than just private businesses? One perspective, that of those financially involved in the railroads, is No. They argue that the agreement was fair and is now settled. The public contributed because it anticipated benefits; the company met its obligations by constructing the railway. The charter's terms, as granted, define the public's rights, but no new conditions can be added now, even if the public views the issue differently today. Other industries have received similar, albeit smaller, grants. Subsidies have been awarded to sugar factories; tariffs have benefited iron foundries and woolen mills; cities competing for factories have offered land and tax exemptions; yet, there has been no effort to oversee these businesses in a special manner or treat them as public enterprises. Thus, it is said, the railroad remains just a private business.

Social view of railroads' obligations

But the social answer is stronger than this. As to the precedent of tariff- and bounty-favored enterprises, most careful students would admit a close analogy in the two cases, but would maintain that the tariff policy also has been carried to an unjustifiable extreme, and that it could not be used to vindicate a still greater assault on public rights. But, further, privileges of railroads are greater in amount and more important in character than those granted to any ordinary private enterprise. The legislatures recognize constantly the peculiar public functions of the railroads. In other private enterprises, investors take all the risk; legislatures and courts recognize the duty of guarding, where possible, the investment of capital in railroads. Laws have been passed in several states to protect the railroads against ticket-scalping. Whenever the question comes before them, the courts maintain the right of the railroads to earn a fair dividend. Private enterprise has been invited to undertake a public work, yet public interests are paramount.

But the social response is stronger than this. When it comes to the examples of businesses that benefit from tariffs and subsidies, most careful observers would agree there's a strong similarity between the two situations, but they would argue that the tariff policy has been taken to an unreasonable extreme and can't justify an even greater violation of public rights. Additionally, the privileges given to railroads are larger in scale and more significant in nature than those given to any typical private business. Legislation consistently acknowledges the unique public roles of railroads. In other private enterprises, investors bear all the risks; however, lawmakers and courts recognize the need to protect capital investments in railroads where they can. Laws have been enacted in several states to shield railroads from ticket scalping. Whenever the issue arises, the courts uphold the right of railroads to earn a fair profit. Private businesses have been encouraged to take on public projects, but the interests of the public take precedence.

Need of harmonizing public and private interests

If an extremely abstract view is taken there is danger of losing sight of the real problem, which is that of harmonizing these two interests in thought and in public policy. Yet the extreme advocates of the private control of railroads have resented indignantly any public interference with railroad rates and with railroad management as an infringement of individual liberty. At the time of the passage of the Interstate Commerce Act this position was inconsistently taken by those in whose interests free competition had been violently set aside at the very outset of railroad construction, and for whom government interference had made possible great fortunes. The railroads cannot change from a public to a private character just as it suits their convenience. They cannot be allowed to play Dr. Jekyll and Mr. Hyde; smooth and affable in the character of public agents when public advantages are to be gained, and then as private enterprises ugly and scowling, flouting the public interests, charging all the traffic will bear, and resisting all reasonable regulation and[Pg 538] conditions. Though railroads are private enterprises as regards the character of the investment, they are public enterprises as to their privileges, functions, and obligations.

If you take an extremely abstract view, there's a risk of losing sight of the real issue, which is balancing these two interests in thought and public policy. However, the strong supporters of private control over railroads have fiercely resisted any public interference with railroad rates and management, claiming it infringes on individual freedom. At the time the Interstate Commerce Act was passed, this stance was inconsistently held by those who benefited from free competition being forcefully eliminated right at the start of railroad construction and who had reaped huge fortunes thanks to government intervention. The railroads can't just switch from being public to private whenever it's convenient for them. They can't act like Dr. Jekyll and Mr. Hyde; being friendly and accommodating as public agents when they stand to gain from public advantages, and then turning into private enterprises, nasty and dismissive, ignoring public interests, charging whatever they can, and resisting all reasonable regulations and[Pg 538] conditions. While railroads may be considered private enterprises in terms of investment, they are public enterprises in terms of their privileges, functions, and responsibilities.

§ II. POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC POWER OF RAILROAD MANAGERS

Railroad rates like taxes

1. In various ways railroad managers exercise great political influence and power. Some writers maintain that the power to make rates on railroads is a power of taxation. They point out that if rates are not subject to fixed rules imposed by the state, the private managers of railroads wield the power of the lawmaker. By changing the rates on foreign exports or imports, the railroads frequently have made or nullified a protective tariff and have defeated the intention of the legislature. High rates on state-owned roads have openly been used in lieu of protective duties. These facts go to show that a change of railroad rates between two places within the country is similar in effect to the imposing or repeal of tariff duties between them.

1. In many ways, railroad managers hold significant political influence and power. Some writers argue that the ability to set rates for railroads amounts to a form of taxation. They point out that if rates aren't governed by strict rules from the state, private railroad managers have the power similar to lawmakers. By adjusting rates on exports or imports, railroads have often created or overturned protective tariffs and undermined the intentions of the legislature. High rates on state-owned railroads have openly replaced protective duties. These facts indicate that changing railroad rates between two locations within the country is akin to imposing or repealing tariff duties between them.

Political influence of railroads

The wealth and industrial importance of the railroads give them widespread political power in other ways. It is commonly charged in some states that the legislature and the courts are "owned" by the railroads. The railroads, in part because they are the victims at times of attempts at blackmail by dishonest public officials, are compelled in self-defense to maintain a lobby. The railroad lobby, defensive and offensive, is in many states the all-powerful "third house." Railroads even have their agents in the primaries, they enter political conventions, they dictate nominations from the lowest office up to that of governor, and they elect judges and legislators. The extent to which this is done differs according as the railroads have large or small interests within the state. How is this great political problem to be met except by an appreciation of its importance and by a growth of public integrity?

The wealth and importance of the railroads give them significant political power in various ways. In some states, people often claim that the legislature and the courts are "controlled" by the railroads. The railroads, partly because they sometimes fall victim to blackmail attempts by corrupt public officials, feel the need to maintain a lobby for their protection. The railroad lobby, both defensive and aggressive, acts as a powerful "third house" in many states. Railroads even have their people involved in the primaries, participate in political conventions, influence nominations for positions from the lowest office to governor, and help elect judges and legislators. The degree to which this occurs varies depending on whether the railroads have large or small stakes in the state. How can we address this significant political issue other than by recognizing its importance and fostering greater public integrity?

The complex obligations of railroad directors

2. The economic power of the higher railroad officials enables[Pg 539] them to exercise certain functions of an important public nature. When the railroad was a young industry, its essentially public nature was not recognized. It was at first thought to be simply an iron-track turnpike to which the old English law of common carriers would apply. As this and similar notions proved illusory, the railroad manager became invested with complex and often conflicting duties to the stockholders and to the public. He wore his conscience-burden lightly, and frequently made little attempt to meet the one and no attempt whatever to meet the other obligation. The new field offered for speculation gave opportunities for great private fortunes. There were no precedents, no ripened public opinion, no established code of ethics, to govern. It was a betrayal of the interests of the stockholders when directors formed "construction companies" and granted contracts to themselves at outrageously high prices. It was an injury not only to shippers, but also to the stockholders, when special rates were granted to friends and to industries in which the directors were interested.

2. The economic power of higher railroad officials allows[Pg 539] them to perform certain important public functions. When the railroad industry was young, its fundamentally public nature wasn't recognized. Initially, it was considered just an iron-track toll road that the old English law of common carriers would apply to. As these and similar ideas turned out to be false, the railroad manager was given complex and often conflicting responsibilities to both the stockholders and the public. He carried the weight of his conscience lightly, often making little effort to fulfill one obligation and completely ignoring the other. The new opportunities for speculation allowed for the creation of large private fortunes. There were no precedents, no well-formed public opinion, and no established ethics to guide actions. It was a betrayal of stockholder interests when directors formed "construction companies" and awarded contracts to themselves at ridiculously high prices. It not only harmed shippers but also hurt the stockholders when special rates were given to friends and businesses in which the directors had a stake.

Unclear convictions as to the railroads' public nature

It is believed that a better code of business morality has developed, and that the officers' relation of trusteeship toward the shareholders is now more often recognized. But practical ethics need to be developed much farther than this. A railroad manager is engaged by the stockholders, is responsible to them, and looks to them for his promotion. Hence their interests are uppermost whenever the welfare of the public is not in harmony with the earning of liberal dividends. The manager feels bound to defend the principle of "charging what the traffic will bear" in the case of each individual, locality, and kind of goods. If this ruins some men and enriches others, if it destroys the prosperity of cities to increase the earnings of the road, at all events he feels he has done his full duty. Railroad directors do not yet recognize, and possibly never will, that their office is more than a private trusteeship, that it is a public trust.

It’s thought that a stronger standard of business ethics has emerged, and that the officers’ role as trustees for the shareholders is more frequently acknowledged. However, practical ethics still need significant development. A railroad manager is hired by the stockholders, is accountable to them, and looks to them for advancement. Therefore, their interests take priority whenever the public’s welfare isn’t aligned with the goal of providing generous dividends. The manager feels obligated to uphold the principle of “charging what the traffic will bear” for each individual, location, and type of goods. If this ruins some people and benefits others, if it harms the prosperity of cities to boost the railroad’s profits, he still believes he has fulfilled his obligations. Railroad directors still don’t recognize, and likely never will, that their role is more than just a private trusteeship; it is a public trust.

Progress of railroad consolidation

3. The progress of consolidation among railroads is putting[Pg 540] into fewer hands greater financial and economic power. The early railroads, many of which were built in sections of a few miles in length, have been slowly welded into continuous trunk lines with many branches. The New York Central between Albany and Buffalo was a consolidation, by Commodore Vanderbilt, of sixteen short lines. The Pennsylvania system was formed link by link from scores of small roads. The growth of consolidation recently has been more rapid than ever before. Sixty per cent. of the mileage of the United States is under the control of five interests; seventy-five per cent. is controlled by a group of men that can sit about one table. The country is being divided territorially into great railroad domains, within each of which one financial interest is dominant. Great financial alliances and "community of interests" still further unify the policy of the leading roads.

3. The ongoing consolidation among railroads is putting[Pg 540] more power into fewer hands, both financially and economically. The early railroads, many of which were built in short segments of just a few miles, have gradually merged into continuous trunk lines with numerous branches. The New York Central, connecting Albany and Buffalo, was a consolidation of sixteen short lines by Commodore Vanderbilt. The Pennsylvania system was developed link by link from many small railroads. The pace of consolidation has picked up recently, faster than ever before. Sixty percent of the railway mileage in the United States is controlled by five interests; seventy-five percent is managed by a small group of men who could all sit around one table. The country is being divided into large railroad territories, each dominated by a specific financial interest. Significant financial alliances and shared interests further unify the strategies of the leading railroads.

Economic results of consolidation

Toward this result strong economic forces are working. Consolidation has many technical advantages: it saves time, reduces the unit cost of administration and of handling goods, gives better use of the rolling stock and of the terminal facilities of the railroads, and insures continuous train service. It has the advantages of other large production and the possible economies of the trusts. Most important, however, from the point of view of the railroads, is the prevention of competition and the making possible of higher rates and larger dividends. The statement that competition is not an effective regulator of railroads often is misunderstood to mean that it in no way acts on rates. It is true that competition between roads does not prevent discrimination and excessive charges between stations on one line only; but competition usually has acted powerfully at well-recognized "competing points." The larger the area controlled by one management, the fewer are the competing points; the larger, therefore, is the power over the rate and the more completely the monopoly principle applies. It is a grim jest to say that consolidation does not change the railroad situation as regards the question of rates.

Toward this result, strong economic forces are at play. Consolidation has many technical benefits: it saves time, lowers the administration and handling costs of goods, optimizes the use of rail vehicles and terminal facilities, and ensures consistent train service. It carries the advantages of large-scale production and the potential cost savings seen in trusts. Most importantly, from the railway companies' perspective, it prevents competition, allowing for higher rates and increased dividends. The idea that competition is not an effective regulator of railroads is often misunderstood to mean that it has no impact on rates. While it's true that competition between railroads doesn’t stop discrimination and high charges between stations on a single line, competition generally exerts significant influence at recognized "competing points." The larger the area controlled by a single management, the fewer the competing points; hence, the greater the power over rates, and the more the monopoly principle is entrenched. It's a grim joke to claim that consolidation doesn’t alter the railroad situation regarding rates.

§ III. COMMISSIONS TO CONTROL RAILROADS

Railroad evils and the old legal remedies

1. Most of the states have undertaken, through commissions, to regulate the railroads in the public interest. When it became evident that public and private interests in the railroads were so divergent, it still was not easy to determine how the public was to be safeguarded. At first, some general conditions such as maximum rates were inserted in the laws and charters; but these were not adaptable to changing conditions and, for lack of administrative agents, could not be enforced. The early efforts at state ownership were, as was noted above, futile and disastrous, the remedy of state ownership, as then applied, being worse than the disease. The old law of common carriers gave to individual shippers an uncertain redress in the courts for unreasonable rates; but the remedy was costly because the aggrieved shipper had to employ counsel, to gather evidence, and to risk the penalty of failure; it was slow, for while delay was death to the shipper's business, cases hung for months or years in the courts; it was ineffectual, for even when the case was won, the shipper was not repaid for all his losses, and the same discrimination could be immediately repeated against him and other shippers.

1. Most states have established commissions to regulate railroads in the public interest. When it became clear that public and private interests in railroads were so different, it was still challenging to figure out how to protect the public. Initially, some general rules like maximum rates were added to laws and charters; however, these rules weren't flexible enough for changing situations and couldn't be enforced due to a lack of administrative agents. The early attempts at state ownership, as mentioned earlier, were ineffective and detrimental, with the approach to state ownership, as it was applied then, being worse than the problem itself. The old law regarding common carriers provided individual shippers with uncertain legal relief against unreasonable rates; however, pursuing this remedy was costly because the affected shipper had to hire a lawyer, gather evidence, and risk failure; it was slow, as delays were detrimental to the shipper's business, with cases lingering in courts for months or even years; and it was ineffective since even if the shipper won, they weren't compensated for all their losses, and the same discrimination could easily happen again to them and other shippers.

Object and working of the state commissions

Attempting to remedy these evils, thirty-one of the states have appointed commissions and, as the most important states are included, this mode of regulation applies probably to four fifths of all traffic beginning and ending in a single state. These commissions differ in power, but in general they attempt to prevent excessive discrimination in rates and to check all railroad practices injurious to the public welfare. The commission principle, strongly opposed at first by the railroads, has been upheld by the courts and is now an established public policy. The state commissions, however, have fallen far short of a solution of the problem. Though they have done much to make the accounts of the railroads intelligible, something to make the rates reasonable and subject[Pg 542] to rule, and much to educate public sentiment, on the whole their results have been disappointing. It has been difficult to get commissioners at once strong, able, and honest; the public does not yet know its own mind well enough to support the commissions properly; and—more fatal weakness still—the courts early decided that state commissions could regulate only the traffic originating and ending within the state, and this left untouched the much greater volume and more important class of interstate traffic.

In an effort to address these issues, thirty-one states have set up commissions, and since the most significant states are included, this method of regulation likely covers about four-fifths of all traffic starting and ending within a single state. These commissions vary in their authority, but generally, they aim to prevent unfair discrimination in rates and to curb railroad practices that harm the public good. The commission principle, which the railroads initially strongly opposed, has been supported by the courts and is now a recognized public policy. However, state commissions have not effectively solved the problem. While they have done a lot to make railroad accounting clearer, made rates more reasonable and regulated, and helped educate public opinion, their overall results have been disappointing. It has been challenging to find commissioners who are strong, competent, and honest; the public isn't fully informed enough to adequately support the commissions; and—an even greater drawback—courts determined early on that state commissions could only regulate traffic that originated and ended within the state, leaving the much larger and more significant interstate traffic unregulated.

Passage of the Interstate Commerce Act

2. The Interstate Commerce Commission is an agency by which it was hoped to secure a uniform national public control of railroads. Public hostility to private railroad management was greatest in the regions where the most rapid building of roads occurred from 1866 to 1873. One center of grievances was in "the granger states" of Illinois, Wisconsin, Kansas, Nebraska, Iowa, and Minnesota; another center was in the oil regions of Ohio and Pennsylvania. The Eastern states were not without their troubles, for the report of the Hepburn Committee of the New York legislature in 1879 shows that discrimination between shippers prevailed to an almost incredible degree in every portion of New York state. When the courts, in 1886, decided that the greater portion of the railroad rates could not be treated by state commissions, national control was loudly demanded. Scores of bills were presented to Congress between 1870 and 1886, and, despite the bitter opposition of the railroads, the Interstate Commerce Act was passed in 1887.

2. The Interstate Commerce Commission is an agency created to ensure a consistent national public oversight of railroads. Public anger toward private railroad management was highest in the areas where the fastest construction of railroads took place from 1866 to 1873. One major source of complaints was in the "Granger states" of Illinois, Wisconsin, Kansas, Nebraska, Iowa, and Minnesota; another was in the oil regions of Ohio and Pennsylvania. The Eastern states also faced their issues, as shown by the Hepburn Committee report from the New York legislature in 1879, which revealed that discrimination among shippers was alarmingly widespread across New York state. When the courts ruled in 1886 that most railroad rates could not be regulated by state commissions, there was a loud call for national oversight. Numerous bills were introduced in Congress between 1870 and 1886, and despite strong opposition from the railroads, the Interstate Commerce Act was enacted in 1887.

Its provisions

The act laid down some general rules: that rates should be just and reasonable; that railroads should not pool, or agree to divide, their earnings to avoid competition; that they should, unless expressly excused, fix rates in accordance with the long- and short-haul principle (to charge no more for a shorter distance than for a longer one on the same line and in the same direction, the shorter being included within the longer). The act provided for a commission of five men, to be appointed by the President, which might require uniform[Pg 543] accounts from the railroads, and which should enforce the provisions of the act.

The law established some basic guidelines: that rates should be fair and reasonable; that railroads shouldn't collude or agree to share profits to dodge competition; that they should set rates in line with the long- and short-haul principle, meaning they can't charge more for a shorter distance than for a longer one on the same route in the same direction, with the shorter route included in the longer one unless specifically exempted. The law also created a commission of five members, appointed by the President, which could require standardized[Pg 543] accounting from the railroads and would enforce the law's stipulations.

Results of the act

3. The object of the Interstate Commerce Act has been but imperfectly attained. This brief proposition sums up the story of years of efforts and defeated hopes. The powers of the commission have proved inadequate to attain the main purposes of the act—the prevention of discrimination and the securing of steady and equitable rates to all shippers. By the decisions of the federal courts, the commission's power has been reduced far below the intentions of the Congress that passed the law. The railroads have in many cases refused to obey the orders of the commission and have succeeded in maintaining their refusal. Admirable results have been secured in the way of uniform accounting, uniformity of rates has been somewhat furthered at times, and the public has been in many cases enlightened. But the greatest evils remain. Railroads still give secret rates in great numbers; many competent witnesses before the Industrial Commission in 1900 and 1901 testified that discrimination had never been worse. From time to time the recognition of the injury to dividends wrought by discriminating rates prompts some railroad to offer its coöperation to the commission, and this inspires new hopes of an effective administration of the act. The pressure of competition, however, soon forces the penitent road back into its old ways. On one thing the railroads and the commission are agreed: that pooling should be permitted, though the commission wishes to have this under strict supervision. To this point the public has not yet advanced.

3. The goal of the Interstate Commerce Act has only been partially achieved. This simple statement summarizes years of effort and unfulfilled hopes. The commission’s authority has been insufficient to achieve the primary aims of the act—preventing discrimination and ensuring fair and stable rates for all shippers. Court decisions have considerably diminished the commission's power, falling far short of what Congress intended when they enacted the law. In many instances, railroads have ignored the commission’s orders and successfully maintained that defiance. While some progress has been made in uniform accounting practices and there has been occasional improvement in rate uniformity, the public has often been made more aware of these issues. However, significant problems persist. Railroads continue to offer secret rates in large quantities; many credible witnesses testified before the Industrial Commission in 1900 and 1901 that discrimination has never been worse. Periodically, the impact of discriminatory rates on dividends leads some railroads to offer their cooperation to the commission, sparking fresh hopes for effective enforcement of the act. Yet, the competitive market pressure often drives these repentant railroads back to their previous practices. The railroads and the commission agree on one point: pooling should be allowed, although the commission prefers it to be under strict oversight. However, the public has not yet progressed on this matter.

The railroad problem unsolved

Despite the general acceptance now of the principle that the railroads should be controlled in the public interest, despite the barren legal triumph of the commission principle, it is evident that the railroad is not yet under social control. The future must determine whether the solution is to be found in effective public regulation or in public ownership.

Despite the widespread agreement today that railroads should be regulated in the public's interest, and despite the empty legal victory of the commission principle, it’s clear that railroads are still not fully controlled by society. The future will reveal whether the answer lies in effective public regulation or in public ownership.


CHAPTER 56

PUBLIC POLICY AS TO CONTROL OF INDUSTRY

§ I. STATE REGULATION OF CORPORATE INDUSTRY

The social problems of corporations

1. The great increase of late in the number of industries under corporate control has brought new problems of social regulation. Inventions, machinery, better transportation, better communication, widening markets, have united to favor large-scale production, and this in turn to multiply corporations. Corporate organization makes possible greater massing of capital, greater stability of policy, and (because not dependent on a single life) greater permanence than does individual ownership. With these advantages the corporation brings also new social problems. The relations in corporate business are more complex than those in individual enterprise. The ordinary stockholder cannot have personal knowledge of the business or exercise personal supervision over his investment. The corporate official controls chiefly not his own wealth, but the wealth of others. When men deal personally with each other their sympathies are more appealed to. But, as noted in the case of the railroad, the corporate official at best seeks to satisfy his employers, often to the detriment both of the employes and of the public. Corporations are "soulless" because they permit less of the close personal relation that makes for morality. At various points in these later chapters on the relation of the state to industry, mention has been made of the measures society has taken to regulate corporate industry. The purpose now is to survey the field more systematically and to see the extent[Pg 545] of this regulation, the difficulties arising, and the principles involved.

1. The recent surge in the number of industries controlled by corporations has created new challenges for social regulation. Innovations, machinery, improved transportation, better communication, and expanding markets have combined to promote large-scale production, which in turn has increased the number of corporations. Corporate organization enables greater accumulation of capital, more stability in policy, and (since it’s not reliant on a single person’s lifespan) greater longevity than individual ownership. However, with these benefits come new social issues. The relationships in corporate business are more complex than those in sole proprietorships. Average stockholders cannot possess direct knowledge of the business or exercise personal oversight over their investments. Corporate officials primarily manage not their own wealth, but the wealth of others. When individuals interact directly with each other, their feelings are more engaged. But, as seen in the case of railroads, corporate officials often aim to please their employers, which can harm both employees and the public. Corporations are seen as "soulless" because they allow for less of the close personal connections that foster morality. Throughout these later chapters discussing the relationship between the state and industry, we've mentioned the steps society has taken to regulate corporate businesses. The current goal is to examine the landscape more thoroughly and to understand the scope[Pg 545] of this regulation, the challenges it creates, and the underlying principles involved.

Examples of public control of corporate industry

2. Numerous laws and commissions recently have been established to provide public regulation of industry. The Interstate Commerce Commission is the most prominent of the agencies for regulating corporate industry, as the railroad problem is the most prominent of the corporation questions. But before the advent of the railroad, banks had been recognized as having an exceptional public character. Not only stockholders, investors, depositors, and note-holders, but a large part of the public suffers losses by the failure of banks. As investigation by the various interested persons is quite impossible, the state through its agents inspects the books of the bank in a manner not thought of in the case of ordinary private business. The bank commission is the eye of the public, safeguarding the public welfare. State inspection of insurance companies, a later kind of corporate enterprise, grew out of a similar need. Insurance to provide for sickness, old age, or death is socially desirable and is possible in an equitable way only by the association of a large number of policy-holders. But inspection of the business by each policy-holder being impossible, regulation and control through some public agency is needed. The tax commissions now found in a majority of the states have been created principally to deal with corporations. In California, a debris commission regulates the relations between the farmers and the miners using hydraulic processes. A number of states have mining commissions, harbor commissions, labor commissions, boards of arbitration, and other similar bodies. The increase of these public agencies to regulate corporate industry has lately been condemned by some as a useless multiplication of state machinery. Doubtless some commissions have, through improper influences, been needlessly created; others having important duties have been intrusted to incompetent political appointees. But most of these commissions are needed, though at first their work may be ineffective.

2. Many laws and commissions have recently been created to regulate industry for the public good. The Interstate Commerce Commission is the most notable agency for overseeing corporate industry, as the railroad issue is the most significant corporate concern. However, before railroads emerged, banks were already recognized as having a unique public role. When banks fail, not just stockholders, investors, depositors, and note-holders, but a large portion of the public suffers losses. Since it’s impractical for various interested parties to investigate, the state, through its agents, inspects the bank's records in ways that wouldn’t apply to ordinary private businesses. The bank commission acts as the public's watchdog, protecting public welfare. State oversight of insurance companies, which emerged as a newer type of corporate enterprise, arose from a similar necessity. Insurance for sickness, old age, or death is socially beneficial and can be conducted fairly only by pooling a large number of policyholders. However, individual policyholders can’t monitor the business, so it requires regulation and control by a public agency. The tax commissions now found in most states have been primarily established to address corporations. In California, a debris commission oversees the relationships between farmers and miners using hydraulic methods. Several states have mining commissions, harbor commissions, labor commissions, boards of arbitration, and other similar organizations. The rise of these public agencies to regulate corporate industry has recently been criticized by some as an unnecessary increase in state bureaucracy. Certainly, some commissions have been created unnecessarily due to improper influences, and others with important responsibilities have been assigned to unqualified political appointees. However, most of these commissions are necessary, even if their effectiveness may take time to develop.

Helplessness of the small investor

3. There is a strong and increasing demand for publicity in the business of the ordinary corporation, as a protection to investors. The law has looked upon corporations, with few exceptions, as private businesses, having the right to keep every detail of their management secret from their rivals. The inner management, therefore, has been closely hidden from most of the stockholders, who, in the economic analysis, are in the main the enterprisers. More and more the business and capital of the country has thus come into the control of the few. The ordinary investor in corporate stock "buys a pig in a poke" and trusts to the integrity of officers working behind closed doors, responsible to no one, too often speculating in the stock of their own companies. The unearned gains thus secured have tainted with dishonesty many a large fortune. No small part of the evil is the closing of the avenues of safe investment to the small capitalists, giving to a favored few a measure of monopoly in investments yielding large returns. Only recently has it been recognized that no large corporation can now be a private business in the old sense. The evolution of industry has left investors and shareholders without protection in advance of a wrong, and usually without legal redress when a wrong has been committed.

3. There is a strong and growing demand for transparency in the business of regular corporations to protect investors. The law has generally viewed corporations, with few exceptions, as private businesses that can keep every detail of their management secret from competitors. As a result, the inner workings have been kept hidden from most shareholders, who are primarily the investors. Increasingly, the business and capital of the country have come under the control of a small number of people. The typical investor in corporate stock risks “buying a pig in a poke” and relies on the integrity of executives who operate behind closed doors, answerable to no one, too often speculating in their own company’s stock. The unearned profits gained this way have stained many large fortunes with dishonesty. A significant part of the problem is that small investors are being shut out of safe investment opportunities, giving a privileged few a monopoly on high-return investments. It has only recently been acknowledged that no large corporation can be a private business in the traditional sense. The evolution of industry has left investors and shareholders without protection before harm occurs and usually without any legal recourse after a wrong has taken place.

Steps toward publicity to protect investors

The demand for some remedy for a condition whose seriousness has been steadily increasing has not come so much from radical quarters as from business and financial circles. In England, some of the worst abuses have been corrected by legislation. In 1900, a bill was drafted at the suggestion of Theodore Roosevelt, then Governor of New York, which aimed eventually to make the corporation a quasi-public institution, open to inspection. The organizers of a company voluntarily accepting the act were to be personally responsible for the statements in its prospectus; its issue of stock was to be limited to actual investment and to be publicly made; its office and records were to be open to inspection. Though public opinion was not ready for this bill, and it failed of passage, the bureau of corporations of the new department[Pg 547] of commerce of the federal government, established in 1903 under President Roosevelt, may be looked upon as a fruit of this initial attempt.

The demand for some solution to a problem that has been getting more serious has not come mainly from radical groups but from the business and financial sectors. In England, some of the worst abuses have been addressed through legislation. In 1900, a bill was proposed at the suggestion of Theodore Roosevelt, who was then the Governor of New York, aiming to make corporations quasi-public institutions that would be open to scrutiny. Organizers of a company that chose to comply with the act would be held personally accountable for the claims in its prospectus; their stock issuance would be limited to actual investments and would need to be made public; their offices and records would have to be accessible for inspection. Although public opinion wasn't ready for this bill, and it did not pass, the Bureau of Corporations created in 1903 within the new Department[Pg 547] of Commerce under President Roosevelt can be seen as a result of this early effort.

Broad social grounds for publicity

4. Greater publicity of corporation business is essential in the interest of the public. With the interests of the investor are usually united more general public interests; but in many cases the two groups of interests conflict. Some persons favor control of corporations only to the degree needed to protect investors, but others place the policy on broader social grounds. The ability of a manufacturing corporation, at times, by threats of removal, to coerce unfair terms from the community, from its employees, and from those who supply it with materials, has led to the proposal that factories shall be forbidden to change their location without the consent of the state.

4. It's important to make corporate business more transparent for the public good. The interests of investors often align with wider public interests, but sometimes these two groups have conflicting goals. Some people support regulating corporations just enough to protect investors, while others argue for a broader social responsibility. At times, manufacturing companies use the threat of moving to force unfair terms from the community, their employees, and their suppliers, which has led to proposals that companies should not be allowed to relocate without state approval.

Publicity to insure just prices

Especially does it seem desirable, if it is possible, to preserve the benefits of competition, by forbidding rates and agreements in restraint of trade. The old English idea, inherited in our law, is that the highest price that can be got in an open market, under ordinary conditions, is in general a just price. The control of any line of industry by a few corporations makes secret agreement much more easy, and thus replaces a general market-price by a discriminating rate, the highest that each individual will bear. A trust's price might still be a reasonable one if the seller met competition in every market; but it is not reasonable when opposition is crushed by local and by individual discriminations. The methods by which this result is obtained shrink from the public gaze. They include secret agreements with railroad agents, a system of espionage on the business of competitors, secret special rates to the competitor's customers, to say nothing more of corrupt political influence. Publicity in corporation accounts is the first condition to a public and uniform price. The need thus to develop potential competition is especially strong where a monopoly in a natural product exists. A more general recognition of the public nature of corporations[Pg 548] will lead to further legislation and to the appointment of corporation commissions, as has been done already in some states.

It seems especially important, if possible, to maintain the benefits of competition by banning pricing and agreements that restrict trade. The traditional English concept, carried over into our laws, is that the highest price achievable in an open market, under normal conditions, is usually a fair price. When a few companies control a particular industry, it makes secret agreements easier and replaces a general market price with a discriminatory rate, the highest that each individual will accept. A trust's pricing might still be reasonable if the seller faces competition in every market; however, it becomes unreasonable when opposition is eliminated through local and individual discrimination. The ways this happens are hidden from public view. They involve secret agreements with railroad agents, spying on competitors' businesses, secret special rates for a competitor's customers, not to mention corrupt political influence. Transparency in corporate finances is essential for achieving a public and consistent price. The need to foster potential competition is especially urgent where a monopoly over a natural product exists. A broader acknowledgment of the public nature of corporations[Pg 548] will lead to more legislation and the establishment of corporate commissions, as has already occurred in some states.

§ II. DIFFICULTIES OF PUBLIC CONTROL OF INDUSTRY

Growing need of social coöperation

1. The progress of industry is compelling greater social contact and more use of the agencies of government. The numerous exemplifications of this general statement that have been met in the course of this study have a common cause. In simple conditions of industry, where most of the productive energies were given to securing the necessities of life, the struggle of men was with nature. Social relations then were simple and crude, such as those of chattel slavery. Now, most men get their livelihood from their bargains with other men. The relations of men with nature now are fewer, and less close; the relations of men with men are more numerous and complex. Efficient coöperation is a factor in production. Right social relations are more essential to industry than a fertile soil.

1. The growth of industry is driving more social interaction and increasing the use of government resources. The various examples of this general statement encountered throughout this study share a common cause. In simpler industrial conditions, where most productive efforts were focused on securing life's essentials, the struggle was primarily against nature. Social relationships were then straightforward and basic, resembling those of chattel slavery. Today, most people earn their living through agreements with others. The interactions between people and nature are now fewer and less direct; however, the relationships between people are more numerous and complex. Effective cooperation is crucial for production. Proper social relationships are more vital for industry than fertile land.

The practical limits of legislative reform

The social institutions of any community are its answer, expressed in human consciousness and in formal laws, to this difficult problem of living together. Laws and ways for regulating industry may be good or bad. The good laws are those in harmony with human nature, giving the best motives for work and the greatest happiness both in the effort and in its reward. The merit of laws, therefore, is relative to human nature; those good for one kind of citizens may be bad for another. Men cannot be legislated into honesty without limit. The best that is possible is to enact laws that encourage the best in men as they are. A dishonest community neither has, nor is capable of choosing, men honest enough to supervise the others. Society cannot, by any amount of tugging and pulling on legislative boot-straps, lift itself above its own moral plane. But though the change in formal law cannot far precede, it may lag behind and retard,[Pg 549] social progress. Law tardily adjusted to social needs tempts and corrupts men. A time has never been when a higher wisdom could not have corrected some ancient grievance, have leveled some unmerited inequality, and, by making laws as good as men were capable of administering at the moment, have freed their energies for further advances. It is only a spirit of moderate expectation that will not be cast down by the results of legal "reforms." Hence it cannot be hoped that abuses will not appear in the attempts to regulate private industry. Fallible men make mistakes and commit injustice, sometimes greater than that which they are seeking to prevent.

The social institutions of any community are its response, expressed in human awareness and formal laws, to the challenging issue of living together. Laws and regulations for managing industry can be good or bad. Good laws align with human nature, providing the best motivations for work and the greatest happiness both in the effort and in its rewards. The value of laws, therefore, depends on human nature; what works for one group of citizens may not work for another. People can't be forced into honesty without limits. The best we can do is create laws that encourage the best in people as they are. A dishonest community neither has nor can choose individuals honest enough to oversee others. Society cannot elevate itself above its own moral standard, no matter how much it tries to enforce laws. However, while changes in formal law can't significantly lead social progress, they can lag behind and slow it down, [Pg 549]. Laws that are slow to adapt to social needs tempt and corrupt people. There has never been a time when a greater wisdom couldn’t have resolved some old grievance, leveled out some unfair inequality, and created laws that matched what people were actually capable of handling at the time, freeing their energy for further progress. It is only with a spirit of moderate expectation that one won’t be discouraged by the outcomes of legal "reforms." Therefore, it’s unrealistic to expect that problems won’t arise in the attempts to regulate private industry. Fallible individuals make mistakes and commit injustices, sometimes greater than those they aim to prevent.

Local selfishness in industrial legislation

2. Legislative interference with industry presents temptations to community selfishness to misuse social legislation. Community greed is not more lovely than individual greed. Many a citizen holds up a high standard for the public official and bewails the corruptions of politics when the legislator votes for his own interest instead of for his constituents' interests. Such a citizen rarely reflects that the responsibility for many legislative abuses comes back to the community and to the individual voter. Can the water rise higher than its source? Is it a high conception of a representative's duty that he should out-talk, outwit, and out-vote his fellow-representatives, to get "a graft" for the men who elect him? In many communities, the one public question of importance is tariff legislation in favor of the local industries. This selfish issue bribes the electorate, and blinds it and its legislator to every question of the general welfare. A great industrial commonwealth steeps its public life in corruption when its voters sell their political birthright for a duty on iron. Many congressmen are so burdened with the task of securing some public expenditure in their district to help their constituents that they have little thought and less interest to give to larger public questions. If a local improvement will furnish labor and increase the value of surrounding property, though it is most uneconomic for the general community,[Pg 550] the representative is expected to labor hard to secure it. Many citizens see little harm in "log-rolling" by the legislator,—that is, in his voting for a law without merit in order to get another law that his constituents want. The guilt of this worst form of bribery comes back to the community that forces its representatives to such a course, sinking public morality to a lower level.

2. Government interference with business often tempts communities to exploit social laws for selfish reasons. Community greed isn't any better than individual greed. Many citizens demand high standards from public officials and lament political corruption when lawmakers prioritize their own interests over those of their constituents. Yet, such citizens rarely consider that the blame for many legislative abuses falls back on the community and individual voters. Can the water rise higher than its source? Is it a noble idea of a representative’s duty for them to outtalk, outsmart, and outvote their fellow representatives just to get a "kickback" for the people who elected them? In many areas, the only significant public issue is tariff laws that favor local businesses. This self-serving concern bribes voters, blinding them and their lawmakers to broader issues affecting the general welfare. A large industrial state drowns its public life in corruption when its voters trade their political rights for a tax break on iron. Many congress members are so focused on securing public funds for their districts to help their constituents that they hardly think about, let alone care for, larger public issues. If a local project will create jobs and raise property values, even if it's not the best option for the community as a whole,[Pg 550] the representative is expected to work hard to make it happen. Many citizens see no problem with "log-rolling" by lawmakers—that is, supporting a law with no merit in exchange for passing another law that benefits their constituents. The blame for this serious form of bribery ultimately falls back on the community that pushes its representatives toward such actions, dragging public morality down to a lower level.

Political corruption in industrial legislation

3. The power of the legislature to affect private fortunes presents strong temptations to public representatives. That the legislator is so often true to a high standard of public duty, goes to illustrate the familiar truth that the individual moral code is better than that of communities. That some individuals betray their trust is less surprising. The Credit-Mobilier scandal, in connection with legislation in aid of the Union Pacific Railroad, implicated many congressmen. A few years ago, in one of the greatest states, it was discovered that an innocent-looking bill, relating to the rights of property-owners on streams, practically involved the gift, to a ring of men, of a quarter of a billion dollars' worth of coal-lands, lying under the navigable streams, and belonging to the state. Such temptations for wealth-getting are too great for men selected solely for their ability to obtain offices and pensions for political supporters, and to secure class-legislation for reputable citizens. The power of the legislative bodies to grant franchises and to permit the use of public property to corporations, constantly gives opportunity for dishonesty and occasion for scandal in the larger cities. The histories of the granting of franchises in New York, Philadelphia, Pittsburg, St. Louis, and many other municipalities, are full of black pages. Public duties are too heavy for the public integrity. Industrial power has grown faster than the civic conscience, and somehow the balance must be made even.

3. The ability of the legislature to impact private wealth creates strong temptations for public representatives. The fact that lawmakers often uphold a high standard of public duty highlights the familiar truth that an individual’s moral code tends to be better than that of communities. It's less surprising that some individuals betray their trust. The Credit-Mobilier scandal, related to legislation supporting the Union Pacific Railroad, involved many congress members. A few years ago, in one of the largest states, an innocuous-looking bill concerning property rights on streams was found to effectively gift a quarter of a billion dollars' worth of coal lands—lying beneath navigable streams and owned by the state—to a group of men. Such temptations for wealth are too strong for those chosen solely for their ability to secure jobs and pensions for political supporters, and to obtain special legislation for well-connected citizens. The power of legislative bodies to grant franchises and allow the use of public property by corporations continuously creates opportunities for dishonesty and occasions for scandal in larger cities. The histories of franchise grants in New York, Philadelphia, Pittsburgh, St. Louis, and many other municipalities are filled with dark episodes. Public responsibilities are too burdensome for public integrity. Industrial power has outpaced civic ethics, and there must be some way to restore balance.

Heavy duties of the courts

4. The power of the courts and of executive officers in the interpreting and executing of laws governing business has become greater. With closer contact of men there is greater friction in social relations, and litigation increases.[Pg 551] Fortunes turn on the result of a civil suit. While juries often are corrupt, yet it is remarkable how well the courts have kept their integrity in the midst of great temptations. Professional pride and the noble traditions of the English judiciary strengthen the individual's character on the bench, not infrequently transforming a dishonest lawyer into a just judge; but popular elections, selfish interests, and the social forces of wealth and ambition make the task at times too heavy.

4. The power of the courts and executive officers in interpreting and enforcing laws related to business has increased. With closer connections between people, there's more friction in social relationships, and litigation is on the rise.[Pg 551] Fortunes can hinge on the outcome of a civil lawsuit. While juries can sometimes be corrupt, it's impressive how well the courts have maintained their integrity amidst significant temptations. Professional pride and the noble traditions of the English judiciary enhance the character of individuals on the bench, often transforming a dishonest lawyer into a fair judge; however, popular elections, selfish interests, and the social forces of wealth and ambition sometimes make the challenge too great.

Integrity needed in public officials

The executive branch of government is necessarily intrusted with great power, increasing with the extent of social regulation. The Secretary of the Treasury has discretion as to the sale and purchase of bonds, and thus can affect the rate of discount and the selling price of securities. One man's decision, if known in advance, makes possible fortunes for private pockets. A recognition of the importance of these facts, which are typical of a great class of facts, must help to develop a higher sense of public duty. Patriotism has been thought of too narrowly. The enemies of early society were outside its borders, and the citizen who traitorously gave them aid was held in abhorrence. Now, independently, in many quarters is voiced the conviction that the greatest enemies of society are within its borders, and that political corruption is the modern form of treason. A higher conception of civic virtue is required to meet the added tasks of society. Public official control must be united with private industrial control in a way to present the fewest temptations to the betrayal of public trust. Now, as never before, must be felt the wisdom of Emerson's words: "The best political economy is the care and culture of men."

The executive branch of government is entrusted with significant power, which grows as social regulations expand. The Secretary of the Treasury has the authority to buy and sell bonds, which can influence discount rates and the market prices of securities. One person's decision, if anticipated, can lead to substantial profits for individuals. Acknowledging these important facts, which represent a larger group of similar facts, should foster a stronger sense of public responsibility. Patriotism has often been viewed too narrowly. In the past, the enemies of society were seen as those outside its borders, and citizens who aided them were despised. Now, many believe that the biggest threats to society come from within, and that political corruption represents a modern form of treason. We need a higher understanding of civic virtue to tackle the new challenges facing society. Public oversight must be integrated with private industry management to minimize temptations that lead to violations of public trust. Now, more than ever, we should recognize the wisdom in Emerson's words: "The best political economy is the care and culture of men."

§ III. TREND OF POLICY AS TO PUBLIC INDUSTRIAL ACTIVITY

Recent growth of state socialism

1. There has been a large increase of state socialism in recent years. The term state socialism, broadly understood, includes all the forms of public participation in industry[Pg 552] that have been passed in review: ownership by towns, cities, state, or nation; laws regulating the freedom of contract; agencies to inspect conditions and to enforce the laws; commissions to supervise and control corporate industry. From every direction comes evidence of the increase of state socialism within the past twenty-five years. To those accustomed to think of the spirit of the Germanic races as that of individual liberty and enterprise, it seems remarkable that this increase has been greater among people of Teutonic origin (Germany, England, America, Australia) than among those of Latin race. The change seems to be a part of the movement of democracy, even the measures of Bismarck in Germany having been taken to ward off the demands of the radical party. The mere name of socialism no longer frightens the citizens of a free state, and when men of strong individualistic spirit even claim with pride that they are socialists, the meaning of that term is becoming very vague indeed.

1. There has been a significant rise in state socialism in recent years. The term state socialism, broadly understood, includes all the ways the public is involved in industry[Pg 552] that have been considered: ownership by towns, cities, the state, or the nation; laws governing contract freedom; agencies to inspect conditions and enforce the laws; commissions to oversee and control corporate industry. Evidence of the growth of state socialism has emerged from all directions over the past twenty-five years. For those used to thinking of the spirit of Germanic people as one of individual liberty and entrepreneurship, it's striking that this increase has been more pronounced among people of Teutonic backgrounds (Germany, England, America, Australia) than among those of Latin heritage. This shift appears to be part of the democratic movement, with even Bismarck's actions in Germany taken to fend off demands from radical groups. The mere mention of socialism no longer intimidates citizens of a free state, and when individuals with strong individualistic beliefs pridefully identify as socialists, the meaning of that term is becoming increasingly unclear.

Varieties of socialism

2. State socialism must not be confused with collectivism, or radical socialism. The word socialism is so variously defined that the earnest student sometimes despairs of getting a clear understanding of it. The thought of socialism ranges from the simplest form of state interference, such as the support of public schools and public fire-departments, up to complete public ownership of all industry. It is well to describe as radical socialists those who would abolish private property, and would strike at the very root of the existing order of society. The modern form of radical socialism originated among German thinkers of the school of Karl Marx, but it has many supporters in other lands. The typical radical socialist claims to possess the only pure brand of social reform, disdains any interest in state socialism, and scoffs at state control as mere temporizing, as not even a single step toward radical socialism.

2. State socialism should not be mistaken for collectivism or radical socialism. The term socialism is defined in so many different ways that serious students often get frustrated trying to understand it clearly. The idea of socialism ranges from basic government involvement, like funding public schools and fire departments, to complete government ownership of all industries. It’s useful to refer to those who want to eliminate private property and challenge the foundations of our current society as radical socialists. The modern version of radical socialism started with German thinkers from Karl Marx's school but has many backers in other countries as well. The typical radical socialist believes they have the only true form of social reform, shows no interest in state socialism, and mocks state control as mere compromise, arguing it isn’t even a real step toward radical socialism.

Aim of state socialism

The typical state socialist agrees that these measures do not logically force him toward the extremer view. He is at[Pg 553] heart an individualist, believing that the motive forces of society are in human character, not in governmental machinery; but he seeks to prevent some kinds of competition, to put other kinds on a better basis; "to make the rules of the game fairer," but not to suppress it. According to this difference in ultimate plan, men and present measures can in general be classified. Yet one view sometimes shades into the other in the life-history of a single individual. Believers in moderate interference sometimes move toward the extreme, and the most radical thinkers, sometimes with no less honesty, become, with broadening experience, more and more moderate. It would be surprising if any one who is thinking and growing in social philosophy should succeed in so exactly adjusting to each other all his opinions, as to be absolutely consistent at a particular moment in his views on social policy.

The average state socialist believes that these measures don't necessarily push him toward a more extreme viewpoint. He is, at[Pg 553] heart, an individualist, thinking that the driving forces of society come from human nature, not from government systems; however, he wants to prevent certain types of competition and improve the conditions of others. His goal is "to make the rules of the game fairer," without eliminating competition entirely. This difference in overall perspective allows us to generally categorize people and current measures. Yet, one viewpoint can often blend into another within the life of a single person. Supporters of moderate intervention sometimes lean toward more extreme ideas, while even the most radical thinkers can, with broader experience, become more moderate. It would be surprising if anyone thinking deeply about social philosophy could perfectly reconcile all their views to be completely consistent at any one moment regarding social policy.

Unripe social philosophy

3. It is not safe to predict from present evidence a continued trend toward extreme social control. Social prophecy is fascinating. Men like to answer out of their ignorance the question, Whither are we tending? A deeper study of social law should give this power, but it is not won by hasty generalization. Unripe social philosophers assume that because the theory of biological evolution is correct, the particular theory of social evolution which they choose to invent or accept is unimpeachable. Radical socialism is the exaggerated statement of a present social need. It is a bridging with hope, not with experience, of the chasm between reality and the dreams of the unsuccessful.

3. It's not safe to assume from current evidence that there's a trend toward extreme social control. Social predictions are intriguing. People often want to answer the question, Where are we headed? based on their lack of knowledge. A deeper understanding of social principles should provide this insight, but it cannot be achieved through quick assumptions. Inexperienced social theorists think that just because the theory of biological evolution is right, the specific theory of social evolution they choose to create or agree with is beyond question. Radical socialism is an overstated response to a current social need. It's a hopeful connection, not an experienced one, bridging the gap between reality and the aspirations of those who have failed.

Progress of social control
True Aim of social control

It is true that many evidences point to an increase in social control for some time to come. The laws, the institutions, the prevailing morality of society, have not kept pace with industrial growth in this period of sweeping change. What is seen, however, is a small arc of the curve of progress. Much of the social regulation in the Middle Ages was similar to that which is now increasing. Legislation by gilds and privileges of private corporations hedged industry about.[Pg 554] A reaction against this in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries brought on national and state control, and state interference of another kind rapidly increased until the time of Adam Smith. Then a strong reaction came, and the next period of fifty years saw far less of interference. The years from 1825 to 1840 were those of the greatest state socialism ever seen in America, but the results were so unfortunate that a violent reaction followed. The recent great increase of state activity is not likely to be continued indefinitely. The path of progress is a spiral. There are forces already at work creating a resistance to any great extension of this movement. Competition of the healthier sort cannot be suppressed without paralyzing results. Inequality and the opportunity for ability to realize itself cannot be destroyed. The social regulations must be of a sort to liberate the best energies of men, not to enchain them. If the evils of state regulation increasingly appear to outweigh the benefits, a limit must be put to the movement. While social control may aid in lifting production and competition to a higher and more moral plane, the ability of society will refuse to be ruled by the standards of the weak and inefficient.

It’s true that there are many signs pointing to an increase in social control for the foreseeable future. The laws, institutions, and general morals of society have not kept up with industrial growth during this time of significant change. What we see is just a small part of the larger curve of progress. Much of the social regulation in the Middle Ages was similar to what is currently on the rise. Rules set by guilds and privileges given to private corporations surrounded the industry.[Pg 554] A backlash against this in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries led to national and state control, and state interference of a different kind grew rapidly until the time of Adam Smith. Then a strong pushback occurred, and the next fifty years saw much less interference. The years from 1825 to 1840 represented the highest level of state socialism ever encountered in America, but the outcomes were so negative that a strong reaction followed. The recent significant increase in state activity is unlikely to continue indefinitely. Progress moves in a spiral. There are already forces at work resisting any major expansion of this movement. Healthy competition cannot be suppressed without harmful consequences. Inequality and the chance for individuals to achieve success cannot be eliminated. Social regulations need to be designed to unleash people’s best energies, not restrict them. If the drawbacks of state regulation begin to overshadow the benefits, there must be limits to this movement. While social control may help elevate production and competition to a higher, more ethical level, society will resist being governed by the standards of the weak and ineffective.


CHAPTER 57

FUTURE TREND OF VALUES

§ I. PAST AND PRESENT OF ECONOMIC SOCIETY

Definition of economics recalled

1. The meaning and scope of economics can be better seen at the end than at the beginning of its study. The proposition with which this inquiry opened may well be recalled in the closing chapter. The words of the formal definition of economics should at this point convey a fuller meaning. In the wide range of subjects passed in review has been sought the answer to one question: What determines and affects the values of good?

1. The meaning and scope of economics can be better understood at the end than at the beginning of its study. The idea we started with might be useful to reflect on in the final chapter. The formal definition of economics should now convey a deeper understanding. Throughout the various topics we've covered, we aimed to answer one question: What influences and determines the value of goods?

Influence of economics on practical life

Perhaps now also can be better appreciated what the influence of such a study might and should be on practical action. At times economic students have gained the ear of statesmen and rulers, and have exercised much influence upon practical politics. It is sometimes bemoaned that economists have to-day so small a direct part in the government of our republic. They certainly have a greater part to-day than they had twenty years ago, but if they had not, there would be small occasion for regret. The immediate influence of the specialist on those in authority is at most times less in a republic than it is in a monarchy, at those rare times when a ruler shows the students his favor. That influence in America is mostly indirect, but it is no less sure and lasting. The results of the earnest pursuit of economic inquiry in the universities and outside of them are already appearing, not in dramatic ways, but in the more subtle, surer form of an intelligent public opinion.

Maybe it's easier to see now what impact a study like this could and should have on real-world actions. Sometimes, economics students have been listened to by politicians and leaders, influencing practical politics a lot. People often lament that economists play such a small direct role in the governance of our republic today. They definitely have a bigger role now than they did twenty years ago, but even if they didn't, there wouldn't be much reason to regret it. The direct influence of specialists on those in power is usually smaller in a republic than in a monarchy, except for those rare moments when a ruler takes a liking to the scholars. That influence in America is mostly indirect, but it's no less certain and lasting. The results of serious economic research conducted in universities and elsewhere are already becoming visible, not in dramatic ways, but in the more subtle and reliable form of informed public opinion.

Examples of mistaken social prophecy

2. Economic science has not reached a stage that permits of much prophecy. Prediction is sometimes given as the test of science. This test, however, is one that only astronomy can meet in any remarkable degree. Chemistry can tell much of what will happen in the laboratory, but nothing of the date of future powder-mill explosions. Geology answers the question "What?" with surmises, and "When?" with an estimate of a few million years more or less. Is it surprising that in human affairs still less prediction is possible? There are countless unmeasured factors in human action. Such generalizations as are possible must be based on actions that appear and reappear with practical constancy. Though a number of facts unite to suggest some conclusions as to the immediate future, the experience of the last century bids one beware of sweeping predictions. The close of the French Revolution was a period marked by much speculation regarding the future of society. The optimists, with faith in the perfectability of human nature and of society, believed that all social ills were due to bad government; if despotism were but overthrown, man's nature would develop, untrammeled, to perfection. The economists of that day were sceptical, because, looking deeper, they saw sources of misery in the scantiness of man's environment, and in the sloth, ignorance, and incapacity of human nature. The pessimists—the communists, and socialists of that day—seeing the same evils, had other explanations to offer. While the economists of that day believed the conditions of poverty and misery to be inevitable, the pessimists pronounced them unendurable, and advocated a radical social change as the only hope of saving the masses from starvation. In such a variety of mutually contradictory views there must have been much error, but likewise much truth if it could be disentangled.

2. Economic science hasn't progressed to a point that allows for much prediction. Prediction is sometimes considered a benchmark for science. However, this is a standard that only astronomy can meet to any significant extent. Chemistry can forecast many outcomes in the lab, but it can't predict when future powder-mill explosions will occur. Geology can provide insights on "What?" through guesses, and "When?" with an estimate of several million years, give or take. Is it any wonder that even less prediction is possible in human affairs? There are countless unmeasured factors in human behavior. The generalizations that can be made must rely on actions that happen repeatedly with practical consistency. Although several facts converge to suggest conclusions about the near future, last century's experiences caution against broad predictions. The end of the French Revolution was a time filled with speculation about society's future. Optimists, believing in the perfectibility of human nature and society, thought that all social problems were due to poor governance; they assumed that if despotism were overthrown, human nature would blossom into perfection. Economists of that time were skeptical because, digging deeper, they recognized that the roots of suffering lay in the scarcity of resources and in human nature's apathy, ignorance, and limitations. The pessimists—communists and socialists of that era—identified the same issues but had different explanations. While economists believed poverty and misery were unavoidable, the pessimists deemed them intolerable and pushed for radical social change as the only way to save the masses from starvation. Amid such a range of conflicting viewpoints, there was likely considerable error, but also significant truth to be uncovered.

Economic prophecies of the nineteenth century

3. The unexpected changes in transportation and in industry altered the course of economic development in the last century. Much of the economic theory of that day appears absurd in the light of history. The inventions of the period,[Pg 557] from Adam Smith's writings to Ricardo's (1776 to 1820), were mostly for use in manufacturing. This suggested to the minds of that time the progressive cheapening of cloth, iron, pottery, and of all other products of machinery, but not the cheapening of food. Indeed, the situation in western Europe then suggested strongly the opinion that the products of the soil would steadily become more difficult to get. The railroad was not of practical importance until after 1830; the steamboat was not applied to ocean travel until 1837. The opening of a rich continent and its annexation, by these new agencies, to the available resources of the older countries were not dreamed of. It was not fully appreciated that a great change in social standards, controlling the growth of population, was in progress. This was the panorama of the progress of society as seen by both the conservative economists and the socialists of less than a century ago: continued invention, an increasing population, low wages, scanty food, growing wealth for the few, and growing poverty and misery for the masses.

3. The unexpected changes in transportation and industry changed the direction of economic development in the last century. Much of the economic theory from that time seems ridiculous in light of history. The inventions of the period,[Pg 557] from Adam Smith's writings to Ricardo's (1776 to 1820), were mostly aimed at manufacturing. This led people of that time to believe that items like cloth, iron, pottery, and other manufactured goods would continually get cheaper, but they didn't think the same would happen to food. In fact, the situation in western Europe suggested that agricultural products would become harder to obtain. The railroad didn't become practically important until after 1830, and the steamboat wasn't used for ocean travel until 1837. The idea of opening up a rich continent and connecting its resources to those of older countries through these new methods was not even a consideration. People didn't fully realize there was a significant change in social standards affecting population growth happening. This was the landscape of societal progress as viewed by both conservative economists and socialists less than a century ago: ongoing invention, a growing population, low wages, insufficient food, increasing wealth for the few, and rising poverty and misery for the many.

Unexpected course of development in the nineteenth century

4. The actual course of economic development in the nineteenth century falsified the predictions alike of optimists, economists, and pessimists. Not foreseeing the great supplies of natural resources soon to be made available for the older countries, the men of that day naturally thought of the supply of land as limited and fixed. Supply in the economic sense means the amount available at the given time in the market; but despite the great areas since brought into the world-markets, the false idea of a century ago still persists in the text-books, and shapes economic reasoning. It is vain to say that the circumstances have been unique and that the general principle is still valid. Much of the so-called orthodox economic analysis was essentially erroneous as applied to the conditions of the past century; it is erroneous to-day and will be so for years to come, if it ever fits the facts. New continents are about to be opened. The building of railroads the length of South America and to the center of Africa will[Pg 558] make available new mineral wealth, rare woods, enormous forests, and some of the greatest food-producing areas on the globe. Population in Christendom has increased more rapidly than ever before in the history of the world, but it has not overtaken the progress in resources. The rate of increase of population is slackening. The result of this combination of events has been a general rise of the conditions making for popular welfare. Despite the problems and the abuses that every new change brings, the civilized world undoubtedly is more prosperous to-day than ever before. The greatest misery and discontent is in the more backward communities. This is past and present; what of the economic future? Is the present condition a normal one—is this prosperity likely to grow or to decline? Thus far, surely, the economic student may question the oracles; for though the distant future is veiled from man's view, the role of economic theory is to show causal relations, to convert mystery into reason, and thus to give a lamp to the feet of the present.

4. The actual course of economic development in the nineteenth century contradicted the predictions of optimists, economists, and pessimists alike. Not anticipating the vast supplies of natural resources that were soon to be available to older countries, people at that time naturally viewed the supply of land as limited and fixed. In economic terms, supply means the amount available at any given time in the market; but despite the large areas that have since been integrated into global markets, the mistaken belief from a century ago still persists in textbooks and influences economic reasoning. It’s pointless to argue that the circumstances have been unique and that the general principle still holds true. Much of what is considered orthodox economic analysis was fundamentally incorrect when applied to the conditions of the past century; it’s still incorrect today and will remain so for years to come, if it ever accurately reflects reality. New continents are about to be explored. The construction of railroads stretching across South America and into the center of Africa will[Pg 558] open up access to new mineral wealth, rare woods, vast forests, and some of the most productive agricultural areas on the planet. Population in Christian countries has grown more rapidly than ever before in history, but it hasn’t caught up with the progress in resources. The growth rate of the population is slowing down. The result of this combination of events has been a general improvement in conditions that contribute to public welfare. Despite the challenges and abuses that every new change brings, the civilized world is undoubtedly more prosperous today than ever before. The greatest misery and discontent are found in the more underdeveloped communities. This describes the past and present; what about the economic future? Is the current situation a normal one—will this prosperity continue to grow or decline? So far, surely, the economic student may question the predictions; for though the distant future is hidden from view, the role of economic theory is to clarify causal relationships, to turn mystery into reason, and thus to provide guidance for the present.

§ II. THE ECONOMIC FUTURE OF SOCIETY

Exhaustion of certain natural resources

1. Present industrial progress is largely due to material conditions, temporarily favorable. Many of the materials now being destroyed in immense quantities have been slowly stored up through the ages and are not renewable.[4] Till modern times man knew little of the world beneath its crust. Living, he scratched the earth's surface, and dying, left his bones to fertilize the soil. But to-day, man exhausts the stores in the interior of the earth, burns the treasures of the carboniferous age, casts the fertilizing elements into the ocean, and leaves the world an empty shell. Forests are being so rapidly cut off that the price of fuel-wood and lumber in many parts of the United States has, within twenty years, been multiplied[Pg 559] by three. The world's store of iron ore is not yet fully known, but much of it has been measured, and of the deposits known to be within the United States over one half are said to be owned by one corporation, and they are enough to continue its present output no more than sixty years. Many other natural products are in like manner gathered by civilized man from a stock created long ago. While the supply of vegetable food promises to be ample, the supply of meat will be maintained with difficulty as population becomes denser.

1. The current industrial progress is mostly due to temporarily favorable material conditions. Many of the materials we're using up in huge amounts have been slowly accumulated over time and are not renewable.[4] Until recently, people knew very little about what lies beneath the Earth's surface. In life, they scratched the ground, and in death, their bones enriched the soil. But today, we deplete the resources inside the Earth, burn the remnants from the carbon age, dump essential nutrients into the ocean, and leave our planet an empty shell. Forests are being cut down so quickly that the price of firewood and lumber in many parts of the United States has tripled[Pg 559] in just twenty years. We don't yet fully understand the world's supply of iron ore, but we know a lot about it, and more than half of the known deposits in the United States are owned by a single corporation, which will only be able to sustain its current output for about sixty more years. Many other natural resources are similarly harvested by modern society from reserves established long ago. While the supply of plant-based foods seems sufficient, maintaining the meat supply will be challenging as the population increases.

Possibilities of other resources

2. Many other inexhaustible sources of essential materials have not yet been developed. What has just been said is the darker side. The coal-mines can be emptied, but so long as the sun shines and the rains fall, Niagara will remain as a source of light, heat, and power. The tides flow on forever. In every thunder-storm enough force is dissipated to run thousands of factories. The heat in the center of the globe, though not inexhaustible, would suffice for man's needs for many centuries. The force in Mount Pelée, if chained and utilized, would run a million factories a million years. It is not too much to hope that engineering skill will some day reach and utilize these sources. Such a cheapening and diffusion of power would put a new face on many of the problems of industry. New sources of materials undoubtedly will be developed. It is reasonable to hope that before iron ore has become extremely scarce, a cheap and practicable method of extracting aluminium from clay will have been perfected. Secure of these permanent sources, civilization will stand on a firmer foundation.

2. Many other endless sources of essential materials have yet to be developed. What I've just mentioned is the negative side. Coal mines can be depleted, but as long as the sun shines and the rain falls, Niagara will continue to be a source of light, heat, and power. The tides will keep flowing forever. During every thunderstorm, enough energy is released to power thousands of factories. The heat at the center of the Earth, although not infinite, would be enough to meet humanity's needs for many centuries. The energy from Mount Pelée, if harnessed and used, could power a million factories for a million years. It’s not too much to hope that engineering expertise will one day tap into these sources. Such an affordable and widespread supply of energy would transform many of the challenges in industry. New sources of materials are sure to be found. It’s reasonable to expect that before iron ore becomes extremely rare, a cost-effective and practical method for extracting aluminum from clay will be developed. With these reliable sources secured, civilization will be on a stronger foundation.

Effect on values of shifting centers of power and materials

A great displacement of local values must accompany this shifting of the centers of power and materials. When the coal districts are heaps of slag and cinders, industry will be found near the water-power. Because of distance from raw materials, New England even now finds herself hard pushed in her rivalry with the Southern states in the manufacture of textiles. The industrial map of our country will be greatly altered a hundred years hence. The possession of rich natural[Pg 560] resources to-day does not insure a community enduring prosperity.

A significant change in local values must go hand in hand with the shifting of power and resources. When the coal mining areas are just piles of waste and ashes, industry will move closer to water power sources. Because of the distance from raw materials, New England is currently struggling to compete with the Southern states in textile manufacturing. The industrial landscape of our country will be dramatically different a hundred years from now. Having abundant natural[Pg 560] resources today does not guarantee long-term prosperity for a community.

Effect of accumulating wealth

3. The mass and quality of wealth will increase rapidly if social and political conditions remain stable. The main method of increasing wealth must be the putting of energies and resources into more abiding forms. In order that a motive for saving may be present, there must be stable conditions. Increasing subordination of present to future will be accompanied by a fall in the rate of interest. The growth of wealth means a higher quality of all artificial productive agents. A larger part of the energies of men will then be directed merely to supervising the developed machinery. Man will live in a better environment, in a better and richer world. Wages must rise as the quality of tools and machinery improves. Population most probably will not increase proportionately and the relation of the labor-supply to the resources with which it works should be more and more in favor of the laboring classes. The difficult problems of the concentrated control of industry and of the control of wealth must be solved in the interests of all.

3. The amount and quality of wealth will grow quickly if social and political conditions stay stable. The main way to increase wealth should be by investing energy and resources into more sustainable forms. For there to be a reason to save, there must be stable conditions. A greater focus on the future over the present will lead to lower interest rates. The growth of wealth means a higher quality of all artificial productive tools. More of people's energy will then be spent just on overseeing the developed machinery. People will live in a better environment, in a richer world. Wages should go up as the quality of tools and machinery improves. The population probably won’t increase proportionately, and the ratio of labor supply to the resources they work with should increasingly benefit the working class. The challenging issues of concentrated industry control and wealth management must be addressed for the benefit of everyone.

Social progress vs. race progress

4. Improvement of the race biologically, through selection of the ablest individuals, has been a great factor in human progress. Social progress is not necessarily the steady biological betterment of the native ability of men. The education of the average member of society is becoming yearly better; it is doubtful whether the innate capacity of a new-born babe in Europe and America to-day is greater than it was among our Germanic ancestors in Roman times. Indeed, the progress of the past two thousand years has been in social organization, in the enlargement and simplifying of the mass of knowledge which has to be reappropriated by each new individual, rather than in race-breeding and in quality.

4. Improving the human race biologically by selecting the most capable individuals has been a significant factor in human progress. Social progress doesn't necessarily mean a consistent biological improvement in innate human abilities. The average person’s education is getting better each year; it's questionable whether the potential of a newborn baby in Europe and America today is any greater than that of our Germanic ancestors during Roman times. In fact, the progress made over the past two thousand years has been more about social organization and expanding and simplifying the body of knowledge that each new individual needs to learn, rather than about breeding for racial quality.

Nature vs. culture

Few thoughtful persons now hold the view that the race can be rapidly improved biologically by the process of educating the individual. Education is cumulative in so far as it builds up a better environment into which other children[Pg 561] will be born, but the betterment is not due to the inheritance by the child of the acquired knowledge and skill of the parent. If this question is open to dispute among biologists, it is only as regards a minute increment of improvement. Practically, selection is the only means of improving the innate capacity of any species in any large measure. Many forces were at work in the past to lift man above the brute, and especially to increase the average brain-power of the human race. The weak, the ignorant, the incapable in primitive societies were ruthlessly killed off. The strong, the sagacious, and the enterprising left the largest numbers of descendants.

Few thoughtful people today believe that we can quickly improve the race biologically just by educating individuals. Education builds a better environment for future generations to be born into, but the improvement doesn't come from children inheriting the knowledge and skills their parents gained. While there might be some debate among biologists about a slight improvement, it’s clear that selection is the primary way to enhance the innate abilities of any species on a larger scale. Various forces throughout history helped elevate humanity above lesser beings and boosted the average intelligence of our species. The weak, the uneducated, and the incapable in early societies were often eliminated, while the strong, wise, and resourceful tended to have the most descendants.

Decrease of the successful elements

5. Progress will be checked if the native quality of the race declines. Under modern conditions, especially within the last quarter of a century, the successful elements of society are becoming less fertile. Large families were the rule among the capable pioneers of America; now they are rare except in the lower industrial ranks. Democracy and opportunity are favoring this process of increasing the mediocre and reducing the excellent strains of stock. Caste and status kept successful generations of capable men in humble social ranks from which only by chance some remarkable individual could rise. In a democracy, those of marked ability can more easily move into the better-paid callings and professions. This individual good fortune, however, reduces the probability of offspring. In the higher social ranks are more bachelors and old maids than in the lower ranks, and fewer children are born to each marriage. The president of our oldest university has shown that one fourth of the graduates of the last generation have remained single, and that the average number of children of the married graduate is two. That group of men, therefore, has left only three fourths enough descendants to maintain its numbers, and as the population has doubled within the same generation, that class represents only three eighths as large a proportion of the American stock as formerly.

5. Progress will be monitored if the inherent quality of the race declines. In today's world, especially over the last 25 years, the successful segments of society are becoming less fertile. Large families were common among the capable pioneers of America; now they are rare except in the lower industrial levels. Democracy and opportunity are encouraging this trend of increasing mediocrity while diminishing the superior strains of people. Social class and status kept generations of capable individuals in lower social positions, from which only by chance could some exceptional person rise. In a democracy, those with notable abilities can more easily advance into better-paying jobs and professions. However, this individual success reduces the likelihood of having children. There are more single people and unmarried individuals in higher social classes than in lower ones, and each marriage in those classes results in fewer children. The president of our oldest university has indicated that one-fourth of the graduates from the last generation have remained single, and the average number of children per married graduate is two. Thus, that group of men has produced only three-fourths enough descendants to maintain its numbers, and since the population has doubled within the same generation, that class now makes up only three-eighths of the American population compared to before.

The menace to progress

This sterilization of ability has cumulative results. If society[Pg 562] were composed in equal parts of two distinct strains of stock, not intermarrying; if the total population kept intact from one generation to another (say each period of thirty years), but the superior strain contributed only three fourths of its own number, at the end of five generations it would have sunk from one half to a little more than one eighth of the population. A period brief in the life of nations would serve to leave it an almost negligible factor in social life. There can hardly be a doubt that at present our society is on the average increasing far more from the less provident, less enterprising, less intelligent classes. There has not yet been time for many of the cumulative effects of this process to appear. Progress is threatened unless social institutions can be so adjusted as to reverse the present process of multiplying the poorest, and of extinguishing the most capable families.

This reduction in ability has long-term effects. If society[Pg 562] were made up of two distinct groups that did not intermarry, and if the population remained the same over generations (let's say every thirty years), but the more capable group contributed only three-quarters of its number, after five generations, it would drop from half to just over one-eighth of the population. A relatively short time in the life of nations could make it an almost insignificant part of social life. It's clear that right now, our society is largely growing from the less resourceful, less ambitious, and less intelligent groups. There hasn't been enough time for many of the long-term impacts of this trend to show. Progress is at risk unless social institutions can be adjusted to reverse the current trend of increasing the number of the poorest while diminishing the most capable families.

Sympathy and selfishness in relation to progress

6. If progress is to continue, there must be left a wide field for the ambitions and for the competition of individuals. The results of any given ability are dependent upon the energy with which it is used. The social machinery finds its motive force in the nature of men. In taking economic wants as the starting point of our study, it was not implied that men were entirely selfish. Sympathy widens; economic wants include family, friends, and, in a growing measure, humanity. The happiness of a truly socialized man consists in part in the happiness of his fellows. As social sympathy broadens, the sense of duty becomes a stronger economic force. Men change, but not rapidly, and not always for the better. It is unsafe to overestimate the generosity of men. Individual wants and interests must, so far as can now be seen, continue to be among the stronger forces that move society. Progress is made because to exceptional ability in general is now presented the hope of large rewards.

6. If we want to keep moving forward, we need to leave plenty of room for individual ambitions and competition. The outcome of any given skill depends on the effort put into it. The social system gets its driving force from human nature. When we use economic needs as the basis for our study, we’re not suggesting that people are completely selfish. Compassion expands; economic needs include family, friends, and increasingly, all of humanity. The happiness of a truly social person partly comes from the happiness of others. As social compassion grows, the sense of duty becomes a stronger economic force. People do change, but not quickly, and not always for the better. It’s risky to overestimate people’s generosity. Individual needs and interests will likely remain some of the strongest forces that drive society. Progress happens because exceptional talent is now seen as having the potential for significant rewards.

Status endangering progress
Envy endangering progress

These dynamic forces making for progress are at present, however, threatened from two sides. Enterprise is threatened from the side of privilege or status. The avoidance of[Pg 563] certain kinds of work which, by social convention, come to be regarded as degrading, takes much ability out of business. The freedom of America to so great a degree from this disdain of honest labor has been a large factor in her progress, but it is endangered when men become timidly conservative of social position. Progress is threatened, secondly, by democracy, with its tendency to carry the notion of literal equality over into industry. When democracy becomes envious, it denies to exceptional ability an exceptional reward. The line of growth must be the resultant of the positive forces in these two principles. The energy of the social reformer must be directed along rational lines. If this can be done, the economic outlook is for a great development of wealth and popular welfare. Economics must be looked upon as the study of the forces in human nature as much as of the material resources of the world.

These dynamic forces driving progress are currently under threat from two directions. Enterprise is at risk from privilege or status. The rejection of[Pg 563] certain types of work, which society often views as degrading, removes a lot of talent from the business world. America's relative freedom from this disdain for honest labor has significantly contributed to its progress, but this is jeopardized when people become overly cautious about their social standing. Progress is also endangered by democracy, which tends to push the idea of absolute equality into industries. When democracy becomes envious, it denies exceptional talent the rewards they deserve. The path to growth needs to result from the positive forces of these two principles. The efforts of social reformers must be channeled in rational ways. If this can happen, the economic future holds the promise of great wealth and public well-being. Economics should be viewed as a study of the forces within human nature as well as the material resources of the world.


QUESTIONS AND CRITICAL NOTES

The Questions.—These questions are not intended to be used merely as[Pg 567] tests of knowledge of the text. They leave untouched many of the most important questions in the reading, and they raise other inquiries hardly hinted at in it. The list began ten years ago with one or two questions on each topic, assigned in advance of lectures and recitations, with the object of arousing the student's thought, quickening his observation, and stimulating his interest in the subjects. The possibilities of helpful questions of this kind are hardly more than suggested by the examples given, and every teacher will find peculiar opportunities in his own neighborhood for other similar inquiries.

The Questions.—These questions aren't just meant to test how well you know the text. They overlook many of the key issues in the reading and introduce other questions that aren't really touched upon. This list started ten years ago with a couple of questions on each topic, assigned ahead of the lectures and discussions, to get students thinking, enhance their observation skills, and spark their interest in the subjects. The potential for useful questions like these is barely hinted at in the examples provided, and every teacher will discover unique opportunities in their own area for additional similar questions.

Other questions are more of the nature of those in Problems in Political Economy, by W. G. Sumner (published by Holt & Co., New York, 1884), which are intended to be reasoned out in the light of principles given in the class-room. Many teachers and students have found much help in that little book, which in turn acknowledges large obligations to earlier lists of questions. The changed point of view in economic theory has, however, made most of the older problems of this nature unusable except after reformulation. Fertile in suggestions of both of the kinds of questions mentioned are two books by H. J. Davenport, Outlines of Economic Theory and Outlines of Elementary Economics (The Macmillan Co., New York, 1896 and 1897), though some of the questions imply theoretical views differing from those of this book. Excellent lists of questions with references to reading have been prepared by W. G. L. Taylor, in his Exercises in Economics (The University Publishing Co., Lincoln, Neb., 1900). The list of problems of this kind can easily be extended to meet the special conditions of each community.

Other questions are more like those in Problems in Political Economy, by W. G. Sumner (published by Holt & Co., New York, 1884), which are meant to be analyzed using the principles discussed in class. Many teachers and students have found that little book quite helpful, which also acknowledges its heavy reliance on earlier question lists. However, the shift in perspective in economic theory has rendered most of the older problems of this kind unusable without reformulation. Two books by H. J. Davenport, Outlines of Economic Theory and Outlines of Elementary Economics (The Macmillan Co., New York, 1896 and 1897), are rich in suggestions for both types of questions mentioned, although some queries reflect theoretical viewpoints that differ from those in this book. Excellent lists of questions with reading references have been created by W. G. L. Taylor in his Exercises in Economics (The University Publishing Co., Lincoln, Neb., 1900). The list of problems of this kind can easily be expanded to address the specific needs of each community.

THE BIBLIOGRAPHICAL NOTES.--The few references and critical notes given are intended as a help to teachers and advanced students desirous of following some of the more recent contributions to controverted points in economic theory. No attempt has been made to furnish a list of books for the beginner or the regular reader. Among accessible books containing helpful lists of that kind may be mentioned:

THE BIBLIOGRAPHICAL NOTES.--The few references and critical notes provided are meant to assist teachers and advanced students who want to explore some of the more recent contributions to debated issues in economic theory. There’s no effort to create a list of books for beginners or casual readers. Some available books that include useful lists of that kind are:

[Pg 568]The Reader's Guide in Economic, Social, and Political Science, by Bowker and Iles.

[Pg 568]The Reader's Guide in Economic, Social, and Political Science, by Bowker and Iles.

Outlines of Economics, by R. T. Ely (published by Macmillan, New York, 2d ed., 1900). Contains both questions and bibliographies.

Outlines of Economics, by R. T. Ely (published by Macmillan, New York, 2nd ed., 1900). Includes questions and bibliographies.

Introduction to the Study of Economics, by C. J. Bullock (published by Silver, Burdett & Co., 2d ed., 1900). The references to the literature are given by pages or sections at the end of each chapter, and at the back is a list (about twenty pages) of the most useful texts, documents, and materials.

Introduction to the Study of Economics, by C. J. Bullock (published by Silver, Burdett & Co., 2nd ed., 1900). The references to the literature are provided by pages or sections at the end of each chapter, and there is a list (about twenty pages) of the most useful texts, documents, and materials at the back.

Financial History of the United States, by D. R. Dewey (published by Longmans, Green & Co., 1903). Contains excellent references on public finances, tariff, banking, and taxation of the United States.

Financial History of the United States, by D. R. Dewey (published by Longmans, Green & Co., 1903). Contains great references on public finances, tariffs, banking, and taxation in the United States.

Introduction to Economics, by H. R. Seager (published by Holt & Co., New York, 1903). Each of the first twenty-six chapters is followed by fresh and well-selected references varying from one line to nearly a page in length. A good general bibliographical note is given on pp. 61-2.

Introduction to Economics, by H. R. Seager (published by Holt & Co., New York, 1903). Each of the first twenty-six chapters includes new and carefully chosen references, ranging from a single line to almost a page long. A solid general bibliographical note can be found on pages 61-62.

Chapter 1. The Nature and Purpose of Political Economy

1. Has political economy anything to do with woman suffrage, the liquor problem, a republican vs. a monarchical form of government, the silver question?

1. Does political economy have anything to do with women's suffrage, the alcohol issue, a republican vs. a monarchical system of government, the silver debate?

2. Is political economy a study of things or of men?

2. Is political economy about studying things or people?

3. Shall a piece of coal be studied in geology, botany, physics, chemistry, or economics?

3. Should a piece of coal be examined in geology, botany, physics, chemistry, or economics?

4. Do you expect to acquire wealth more easily as a result of the study of political economy?

4. Do you think you'll be able to gain wealth more easily by studying political economy?

5. Of what practical use do you think political economy is?

5. How useful do you think political economy is in real life?

6. Is political economy necessary to the understanding of the business world, or vice versa?

6. Is understanding political economy essential for grasping the business world, or is it the other way around?

7. How wide a knowledge would a complete understanding of industrial society require?

7. How extensive would a complete understanding of industrial society need to be?

8. Did the discovery of America make the study of political economy more important?

8. Did the discovery of America make the study of political economy more important?

Chapter 2. The Economic Reasons

1. If you found $10 to-day on the street, what would you do with it?

1. If you found $10 today on the street, what would you do with it?

2. What would be the chief differences between your use of it now and at the age of five or the age of twelve?

2. What would be the main differences between how you use it now and how you used it at age five or twelve?

3. Name Crusoe's wants in the order of their importance.

3. List Crusoe's wants in order of how important they are.

4. Is it well to be contented with your lot? Is it well to be discontented?

4. Is it good to be satisfied with what you have? Is it good to be unsatisfied?

5. Why does a horse like hay and a man prefer meat?

5. Why does a horse enjoy hay while a man prefers meat?

6. Are the wants of a savage more easily satisfied than those of civilized men? Why?

6. Are a savage's wants easier to satisfy than those of civilized people? Why?

7. How many motives led you to come to college?

7. How many reasons brought you to college?

8. If you ever worked for wages, or a salary, was that the only motive? What else?

8. If you ever worked for pay or a salary, was that your only motivation? What else?

9. James Bryce says that the incomes of American university professors are much less than those of men of corresponding ability in law and medicine. If true, why?

9. James Bryce says that the salaries of American university professors are much lower than those of professionals with similar skills in law and medicine. If that's the case, why?

10. If you could, would you do nothing always? Why?

10. If you could, would you always choose to do nothing? Why?

11. Which would you prefer, to clerk in a store at $1.50 a day, or to lay masonry at $2? Why?

11. Which would you rather do, work as a clerk in a store for $1.50 a day, or do masonry for $2? Why?

12. Do men work better under threat or when their pride is appealed to?

12. Do men perform better when they feel threatened or when their pride is appealed to?

13. Is pride as powerful a motive as greed, in economic action?

13. Is pride as strong a motivating factor as greed in economic actions?

14. Do you know any persons that work from a sense of duty alone?

14. Do you know anyone who works solely out of a sense of duty?

15. Are charity workers usually well paid? Why?

15. Are charity workers typically paid well? Why?

Chapter 3. Wealth and Wellbeing

1. What is it to be economical of money?

1. What does it mean to be careful with money?

2. Why did Crusoe work at all?

2. Why did Crusoe even bother to work?

3. When he began to work at one thing, why did he ever stop to work at another?

3. When he started working on one thing, why did he ever stop to work on something else?

4. What is the difference in utility between the water in a solid mountain reservoir and the same water when it is flooding the valley?

4. What’s the difference in usefulness between the water in a solid mountain reservoir and the same water when it’s flooding the valley?

5. Does it change the utility of a load of powder to touch a match to it?

5. Does lighting a match change the usefulness of a load of powder?

6. Is water useful? Is dynamite?

6. Is water useful? What about dynamite?

7. Is the last bait worth more when the fish are biting well?

7. Is the last bait more valuable when the fish are biting well?

8. Are the following wealth: food, tobacco, medicine, whisky, good looks, good health, a wooden leg?

8. Are the following considered wealth: food, tobacco, medicine, whiskey, attractiveness, good health, a prosthetic leg?

9. Is a book full of useful information, wealth? Is a head full of useful knowledge, wealth?

9. Is a book packed with useful information considered wealth? Is a mind filled with useful knowledge considered wealth?

10. Is a ship at the bottom of the ocean, or gold in the mine, wealth?

10. Is a ship at the bottom of the ocean, or gold in the mine, considered wealth?

11. Is well-being in proportion to wealth? Why?

11. Is well-being connected to wealth? Why?

12. Are services, music, a theatrical performance, a gambler's pack of cards, wealth?

12. Are services, music, a stage show, a deck of cards for gambling, wealth?

Note.—The theory of marginal utility broadly outlined in chapters 3-5 has been worked out in detail by the group of writers called[Pg 570] the Austrian economists. The mechanism, or the technique, of marginal utility and exchange as they conceive of it, is essentially what this text seeks to explain. Our application and development of the conception of marginal utility differs from theirs, however, in ways that will appear as the text advances.

Note.—The theory of marginal utility discussed in chapters 3-5 has been further developed by a group of writers known as [Pg 570] the Austrian economists. Their understanding of the mechanisms and techniques of marginal utility and exchange is essentially what this text aims to explain. However, our approach and development of the concept of marginal utility will differ from theirs in ways that will become clear as the text continues.

For more detailed discussion of many points in chapter 3, see Smart, Introduction to the Theory of Value, pp. 9-17; Wieser, Natural Value, pp. 3-16; Böhm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital, pp. 129-153.

For a more detailed discussion of several topics in chapter 3, refer to Smart, Introduction to the Theory of Value, pp. 9-17; Wieser, Natural Value, pp. 3-16; Böhm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital, pp. 129-153.

Chapter 4. The Nature of Demand

1. Give illustrations of the difference between desire and demand.

1. Provide examples of the difference between desire and demand.

2. Do people actually expend their incomes so as to get the maximum utility judged by a standard they would admit to be morally sound?

2. Do people really spend their money in a way that maximizes satisfaction based on a standard they believe is morally right?

3. What causes a demand for an additional supply of food? Of books?

3. What triggers the need for more food? More books?

4. If you never eat corn-bread, will the failure of the corn-crop affect your grocery bill?

4. If you never eat cornbread, will the failure of the corn crop affect your grocery bill?

5. Give examples you have seen of a higher price of one thing causing an increasing use of another.

5. Provide examples you've noticed where a rise in the price of one item leads to a greater use of another.

6. Do you buy what you most desire?

6. Do you purchase what you really want?

7. Give examples of cases where supply is fixed, and demand varies.

7. Provide examples of situations where the supply is fixed, and the demand changes.

8. Give examples of demand shifting from one product to another.

8. Provide examples of demand changing from one product to another.

Note.—For a more detailed discussion see works cited: Smart, 18-33; Böhm-Bawerk, 159-169; Wieser, 16-36.

Note.—For a more in-depth discussion, refer to the works mentioned: Smart, 18-33; Böhm-Bawerk, 159-169; Wieser, 16-36.

Chapter 5. Trading in a Market

1. Are merchants producers of wealth, or are their profits merely subtracted from the wealth already produced?

1. Do merchants create wealth, or do their profits just take away from the wealth that's already been produced?

2. Is the railroad productive? Why?

2. Is the railroad effective? Why?

3. Give examples within your observation of improved productive processes increasing exchange; of the reverse.

3. Provide examples from your observation of improved productive processes that enhance exchange, and examples of the opposite.

4. Why is exchange profitable if it is fair?

4. Why is trade beneficial if it's fair?

5. Would doubling all commodities affect their exchange value?

5. Would doubling the amount of all goods change their exchange value?

6. Is part of a stock of goods ever worth more than the whole? Examples.

6. Is a part of a stock of goods ever worth more than the entire stock? Examples.

7. Do you ever take account of a difference of five cents in deciding whether to purchase?

7. Do you ever consider a five-cent difference when deciding whether to buy something?

8. Is barter more or less frequent now in America than formerly? In the world?

8. Is barter more or less common now in America than it used to be? What about in the world?

9. Is there any causal relationship between commerce and manufactures? If so, in what way?

9. Is there a causal relationship between commerce and manufacturing? If yes, how does it work?

10. In a time of high excitement gold was sold for more at one side of the room than at the other side; how account for this?

10. In a time of high excitement, gold was sold for more on one side of the room than on the other; how can we explain this?

11. Give examples of, and reasons for, two prices in the same market.

11. Provide examples of two prices in the same market and explain the reasons behind them.

12. What effect on prices should be expected from an invention that makes possible the carrying of fresh meat from South America to England?

12. What impact on prices can we expect from an invention that allows fresh meat to be transported from South America to England?

13. Describe the method of selling any product you know about. What is the market in which it is sold?

13. Describe the method of selling any product you know about. What is the market where it's sold?

Note.—See works cited: Smart, pp. 40-63; Böhm-Bawerk, 193-222; Wieser, 39-53.

Note.—Refer to the cited works: Smart, pp. 40-63; Böhm-Bawerk, pp. 193-222; Wieser, pp. 39-53.

Chapter 6. Emotional Rewards

1. Is it possible to compare the value of the portrait-painter's service with that of the gardener?

1. Can you compare the value of a portrait painter's work with that of a gardener?

2. To call the teacher's work unproductive, and the ditch-digger's work productive was once usual, but is so no longer; give reasons for either view.

2. It was once common to say that the teacher's work is unproductive and the ditch-digger's work is productive, but that’s not the case anymore; provide reasons for either perspective.

3. It is usual to call the use of a house for business purposes a productive use, but its use as a residence an unproductive one. What reasons are there for and against this?

3. It’s common to refer to using a house for business as a productive use, while using it as a residence is seen as unproductive. What are the arguments for and against this?

4. Give a list of material agents that are yielding non-material uses.

4. Provide a list of material agents that are producing non-material uses.

5. Give examples of personal services that are most immediately expressed as gratifications.

5. Provide examples of personal services that are most directly expressed as forms of satisfaction.

Note.—The phrase "psychic income," used here for the first time, expresses a conception long neglected, but essential to the advancement of psychological economics. The idea has been recognized in the writings of Edwin Cannan, Irving Fisher, W. M. Daniels, and perhaps of late by others. It was discussed by the author in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, pp. 19-30, especially pp. 25-26, in an article called "Recent Discussion of the Capital Concept" (November, 1900).

Note.—The term "psychic income," introduced here for the first time, refers to a concept that has been ignored for too long but is essential for the advancement of psychological economics. This idea has been recognized in the works of Edwin Cannan, Irving Fisher, W. M. Daniels, and possibly others more recently. The author discussed it in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, pp. 19-30, particularly pp. 25-26, in an article called "Recent Discussion of the Capital Concept" (November, 1900).

Chapter 7. Wealth and Its Indirect Uses

1. Give reasons for attributing exchange value to the waves of the ocean; to a waterfall, a water-wheel, a loom, a piece of cloth, a dress made of the cloth.

1. Provide reasons for assigning exchange value to the ocean waves; to a waterfall, a water wheel, a loom, a piece of fabric, a dress made from that fabric.

2. Show the connection between these things.

2. Show how these things are connected.

3. How can the use of a flock of sheep be of value to one who must return them all to the owner?

3. How can using a flock of sheep benefit someone who needs to return them all to the owner?

4. Why should the use of a machine that never can be a direct cause of gratification, have a value that men will pay for?

4. Why should using a machine that can never directly provide satisfaction have a value that people will pay for?

5. Give examples of wealth never becoming a direct cause of gratification, yet whose possession is greatly valued.

5. Give examples of wealth that doesn't directly lead to happiness, yet is highly valued.

Note.—The conception in this chapter was ably presented by Böhm-Bawerk in Capital and Interest, Bk. III, ch. v, pp. 219-227. He does not, however, make use of it in a theory of rent.

Note.—The concept in this chapter was thoroughly explored by Böhm-Bawerk in Capital and Interest, Book III, chapter v, pages 219-227. However, he does not apply it in a theory of rent.

Chapter 8. The Lease Agreement

1. What things beside land are rented?

1. What else can be rented besides land?

2. What is the form of contract used in the renting of farms, business buildings, and residences, in the community where you live?

2. What type of contract is used for renting farms, commercial buildings, and homes in your community?

3. Does the rent of pianos, type-writers, or masquerade-suits depend on the value of the thing rented? Is the rental a moderate return on the investment?

3. Does the rental cost of pianos, typewriters, or costume outfits depend on the value of the rented item? Is the rent a reasonable return on the investment?

4. What are the difficulties in determining tenants' improvements?

4. What challenges come up when figuring out tenants' improvements?

Note.—Various writers have recognized that social, class distinctions had an influence on the conceptions of rent and capital in England in the eighteenth century; see Fetter, article on "The Next Decade of Economic Theory," in American Economic Association, 3d ser., Vol. III, pp. 236-246, especially 243-4; also A. S. Johnson, Rent in Modern Economic Theory, p. 19, and references there given. Heretofore, however, there has not been assigned to the form of the contract the significance here given it. A discussion of the points at issue will be found in The Relations between Rent and Interest, by F. A. Fetter and others (published by Macmillan, New York, 1904), pp. 8-10, on the renting contract.

Note.—Different authors have noted that social and class distinctions affected the concepts of rent and capital in England during the eighteenth century; see Fetter, article on "The Next Decade of Economic Theory," in American Economic Association, 3rd ser., Vol. III, pp. 236-246, especially 243-4; also A. S. Johnson, Rent in Modern Economic Theory, p. 19, and the references provided there. However, until now, the form of the contract hasn’t been given the importance it deserves. A discussion of the relevant points can be found in The Relations between Rent and Interest, by F. A. Fetter and others (published by Macmillan, New York, 1904), pp. 8-10, regarding the renting contract.

Chapter 9. The Law of Diminishing Returns

1. Is it possible to do twice the amount of business in any store-room by doubling the stock and the force of clerks?

1. Can any store-room really double its business just by doubling the inventory and the number of clerks?

2. Is it possible to expand a university indefinitely by increasing the force of teachers and the equipment, without enlarging the buildings?

2. Can a university keep growing indefinitely by adding more teachers and equipment, without expanding the buildings?

3. Why do men cultivate two acres instead of one? Where land is plentiful, why do not men cultivate two acres instead of one?

3. Why do men farm two acres instead of one? When land is abundant, why don’t people farm two acres instead of one?

4. Are there any things, not free goods, that could be indefinitely increased without increasing difficulty?

4. Are there any things, other than free goods, that could be increased infinitely without making it harder?

5. English farmers raise thirty-five bushels of wheat per acre, Americans perhaps fifteen; why this difference?

5. English farmers produce thirty-five bushels of wheat per acre, while American farmers produce about fifteen. What accounts for this difference?

6. Why did people go to Dakota and Iowa when there was still room in New England?

6. Why did people move to Dakota and Iowa when there was still space in New England?

7. Why put up a twenty-story building? Why not build a fifty-story one?

7. Why build a twenty-story building? Why not go for a fifty-story one?

Note.—The broad reading here given to the law of diminishing returns is so recent that even the latest texts have recognized it only in a partial manner, defining "the law" in the old terms confined to land. For the old statement see J. S. Mill, Principles of Political Economy (1846), Bk. I, ch. XII. Writers even so advanced as[Pg 573] Alfred Marshall follow Mill with no essential modification. For a good historical account of the doctrine see Edwin Cannan, History of the Theories of Production and Distribution, pp. 147-182 (1893; 2d ed., with additions, 1903), which advances no positive theory, but makes evident many inconsistencies in the older view. A keen analysis and important contribution to economic thought was made by J. R. Commons, Distribution of Wealth, pp. 116-159 (1895). John B. Clark, in various earlier articles, and in his Distribution of Wealth (1900), has done more than any one else to develop the conception of "a universal law of economic variation." In magazine articles by various writers, the same idea has been developed, but no thorough-going application of it has been made in the available text-books.

Note.—The broad interpretation of the law of diminishing returns presented here is so new that even the most recent texts have only partially acknowledged it, defining "the law" using outdated terms that relate only to land. For the older explanation, see J. S. Mill, Principles of Political Economy (1846), Bk. I, ch. XII. Even progressive authors like[Pg 573] Alfred Marshall still follow Mill without making significant changes. For an insightful historical overview of the doctrine, refer to Edwin Cannan, History of the Theories of Production and Distribution, pp. 147-182 (1893; 2d ed., with additions, 1903), which does not propose a new theory but points out many inconsistencies in older views. A sharp analysis and crucial contribution to economic thought came from J. R. Commons, Distribution of Wealth, pp. 116-159 (1895). John B. Clark, through several earlier articles and his Distribution of Wealth (1900), has contributed more than anyone else to the idea of "a universal law of economic variation." This concept has also been explored in magazine articles by various authors, but a comprehensive application of it has not yet been made in the available textbooks.

Chapter 10. The Theory of Rent

1. Is competition severe in the renting of land in your community?

1. Is there a lot of competition for renting land in your community?

2. Give examples you have seen of a rise of rent; the cause. Of a fall of rent; the cause.

2. Provide examples you've observed of rent increasing; what caused it. Also, provide examples of rent decreasing; what caused that.

3. Does the existence of the land of California have any effect on rents in New York city? On agricultural rents in New York state?

3. Does the existence of California have any impact on rents in New York City? On agricultural rents in New York State?

4. If all the land on an island were equally fertile and equally convenient of access, would any of it pay a rent?

4. If all the land on an island were equally fertile and easy to access, would any of it generate rent?

5. If you owned the Golden Gate, or the harbor of New York, could you rent it?

5. If you owned the Golden Gate or New York Harbor, could you rent it out?

6. How does the hire of a team of horses resemble the rent of land?

6. How is hiring a team of horses similar to renting land?

7. How do livery charges in a college town in commencement week illustrate the subject of rent?

7. How do delivery fees in a college town during graduation week illustrate the topic of rent?

8. Show how a change of circumstances may raise the rent of machinery.

8. Demonstrate how changes in circumstances can increase the cost of machine rental.

Note.—Although most texts still present the older, narrow conception of land rent, its defects have been revealed by many critics. J. B. Clark has been the chief champion of the broader conception; American Economic Association, 1st ser., Vol. III, No. 2, Capital and Its Earnings (1888); and Distribution of Wealth, ch. IX and ch. XIII. See our summary of the present situation, American Economic Association, 3d ser., Vol. II, p. 241 (1900). Alfred Marshall's effort to save the older conception by compromise on a "quasi-rent" doctrine has many supporters, but this doctrine is examined in detail and criticized adversely by the writer in an article entitled "The Passing of the Old Rent Concept," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, pp. 416-455 (1901). For both negative and positive reasons for a change in the concept, see The Relations between Rent and Interest, before cited (in note to ch. 8).

Note.—While many texts still adhere to the older, limited view of land rent, numerous critics have highlighted its shortcomings. J. B. Clark has been the primary advocate for a broader perspective; American Economic Association, 1st ser., Vol. III, No. 2, Capital and Its Earnings (1888); and Distribution of Wealth, ch. IX and ch. XIII. For an overview of the current situation, see American Economic Association, 3d ser., Vol. II, p. 241 (1900). Alfred Marshall's attempt to maintain the older view through a compromise on a "quasi-rent" theory has garnered many supporters, but this theory is thoroughly examined and critiqued in the author's article titled "The Passing of the Old Rent Concept," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, pp. 416-455 (1901). For both the supportive and opposing reasons for changing the concept, refer to The Relations between Rent and Interest, mentioned earlier (in the note to ch. 8).

Chapter 11. Repair, Depreciation, and Destruction of Wealth

1. What is the difficulty in the definition: Rent is the payment for the original and indestructible powers of the soil?

1. What makes it difficult to define: Rent is the payment for the original and everlasting resources of the land?

2. If the value of improvements on land is all counted, is there anything over? Examples.

2. If we take into account the total value of improvements on the land, is there anything left over? Examples.

3. What is stumpage? Does it differ from rent?

3. What is stumpage? Is it different from rent?

4. What do you know about the methods of renting mines?

4. What do you know about how to rent mines?

5. What methods are adopted to keep up the efficiency of factories?

5. What methods are used to maintain the efficiency of factories?

Note.—Compare and note the inconsistent use of the term "rent" by Ricardo, pp. 34-5 and 45-6, McCulloch's edition. See also article, "Depreciation," in Palgrave's Dictionary.

Note.—Look for and note the inconsistent use of the term "rent" by Ricardo, pages 34-5 and 45-6, in McCulloch's edition. Also, refer to the article "Depreciation" in Palgrave's Dictionary.

Chapter 12. Rise in Renters and Rental Prices

1. What are the most obvious ways of increasing the productiveness of land?

1. What are the most obvious ways to make land more productive?

2. How does a new railroad affect the value of the land it passes through?

2. How does a new railroad impact the value of the land it crosses?

3. How would the rent of a rocky island be affected if it became a summer resort?

3. How would the rent of a rocky island change if it turned into a summer resort?

4. Mention any cases you may have seen where a greater value was imparted to land by a newly discovered use.

4. Share any examples you might have seen where land gained more value because of a newly discovered use.

5. A tunnel was made to drain a mine; the stock doubled in price. Was it really the stock, the old mine, or the new hole in the mountain-side that had increased in value?

5. A tunnel was dug to drain a mine; the stock price doubled. Was it really the stock, the old mine, or the new hole in the mountainside that had gained in value?

6. Criticize the statement that, in an economic sense, land is a "fixed stock for all time."

6. Critique the idea that, economically speaking, land is a "fixed stock for all time."

Note.—The changes which the rent concept is undergoing can be traced in the work of Alfred Marshall. See Principles of Economics, Bk. V, ch. IX on "Quasi-rent," and ch. X on "Situation Rent," and Bk. VI, ch. IX, Secs. 6-7, in which Marshall modifies the older conception of rent. This is discussed in "The Passing of the Old Rent Concept," cited above (in note to ch. 10).

Note.—The shifts in the understanding of rent can be observed in Alfred Marshall's work. Look at Principles of Economics, Book V, chapter IX on "Quasi-rent," and chapter X on "Situation Rent," as well as Book VI, chapter IX, Sections 6-7, where Marshall revises the traditional view of rent. This is discussed in "The Passing of the Old Rent Concept," mentioned earlier (in the note to chapter 10).

Chapter 13. Money as a Tool for Exchange

1. Why do you value money? Do you value it more than the things it buys?

1. Why do you value money? Do you value it more than the things it purchases?

2. What functions does money perform in society?

2. What roles does money play in society?

3. Could a country better do without money, horses, or roads?

3. Could a country manage better without money, horses, or roads?

4. If money is a tool, what does it make?

4. If money is a tool, what does it create?

5. What is the difficulty in deciding whether to call the following money: gold ingots, gold coin, silver dollars, copper cents, greenbacks, bank-checks, chalk-marks to keep account?

5. What makes it challenging to determine whether to classify the following as money: gold ingots, gold coins, silver dollars, copper cents, greenbacks, bank checks, or chalk marks for keeping track?

6. Are men wealthy in proportion to the money they have? Are countries?

6. Are men wealthy based on how much money they have? Are countries?

7. Would a nation be poorer if, like Sparta, it prohibited all money?

7. Would a nation be worse off if, like Sparta, it banned all money?

Chapter 14. The Money Economy and the Idea of Capital

1. Are national bonds or promissory notes, wealth?

1. Are national bonds or promissory notes considered wealth?

2. Is it money or things that the borrower wants?

2. Is it money or stuff that the borrower wants?

3. If you were starting a factory on credit, would you rent the machines or buy them with borrowed money? Why?

3. If you were starting a factory with borrowed money, would you rent the machines or buy them with that loan? Why?

4. When a man says he has a certain capital invested in his business, does he mean to include the value of the land and buildings?

4. When a man says he has a certain amount of capital invested in his business, does he mean to include the value of the land and buildings?

5. What is the meaning of the phrase, "a capitalistic age"?

5. What does the phrase "a capitalistic age" mean?

Note.—We are indebted to the economic historians for a better understanding of the important influence money has had on economic organization. See Hildebrand's notable article in the first number of the Jahrbücher, and Ashley, English Economic History. J. B. Clark was the first among contemporary economists to emphasize the value concept of capital. The scholarly and judicial article by Irving Fisher on "Precedents for Defining Capital" in Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 1904, makes possible better understanding and agreement on the subject. I am pleased to say that in this article, and in personal correspondence, Professor Fisher disavows the interpretation I had thought (see "Recent Discussion," etc.) that his words required. His conception of capital is thus, in essentials, the one here employed, differing from it not in thought, but merely in terminology. Professor Fisher's original studies of the capital concept, in the Economic Journal in 1896-7, are indispensable to an understanding of the development of this important phase of the new economic theory. The connection between the conclusions of economic history and the value concept of capital in economic theory has been made by the author in essays before cited under chapters 6 and 8: "Recent Discussion of the Capital Concept"; "The Next Decade of Economic Theory," and "The Relations between Rent and Interest."

Note.—We owe a lot to economic historians for helping us understand the significant impact money has on economic organization. Check out Hildebrand's remarkable article in the first issue of the Jahrbücher, as well as Ashley's English Economic History. J. B. Clark was the first modern economist to emphasize the concept of capital as a value. Irving Fisher's detailed and analytical article on "Precedents for Defining Capital" in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1904, provides clarity and a better consensus on the subject. I’m pleased to mention that in this article, along with our personal correspondence, Professor Fisher clarifies that my earlier interpretation (see "Recent Discussion," etc.) of his views was incorrect. His understanding of capital is closely aligned with the one used here, differing only in terms of terminology, not in substance. Professor Fisher’s early work on the capital concept in the Economic Journal from 1896-7 is crucial for understanding the development of this important aspect of modern economic theory. The connection between findings in economic history and the value concept of capital in economic theory has been explored by the author in the previously mentioned essays in chapters 6 and 8: "Recent Discussion of the Capital Concept"; "The Next Decade of Economic Theory," and "The Relations between Rent and Interest."

Chapter 15. The Capitalization of All Types of Rent

1. What relation is there between the rate of interest and the price of land bearing a given rental?

1. What is the relationship between the interest rate and the price of land that has a specific rental value?

2. If a $100 share of railroad stock sells at par when interest on loans is at 5%, what will be its price when interest rises to 6%? When interest falls to 4%?

2. If a $100 share of railroad stock sells at the original price when interest on loans is at 5%, what will its price be when interest rises to 6%? What about when interest falls to 4%?

3. If a business is very successful and its dividends double, what will be the effect on the selling price of its stock?

3. If a business is really successful and its dividends double, what will be the impact on the selling price of its stock?

Note.—The subject is almost foreign to the standard works on economics, which have continued to look upon capital as primary, and its income as derived. Numerous recent articles will be found, however, dealing with concrete problems where the logical and the practical views are seen to be the same; e.g., W. Z. Ripley, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, p. 106 (1900), article on "The Capitalization of Public Service Corporations"; also article in Engineering News, Vol. XXVIII, p. 492 (November, 1892).

Note.—This topic is mostly missing from standard economics textbooks, which usually focus on capital and treat its income as an afterthought. However, many recent articles tackle specific issues where logical and practical views match; for example, W. Z. Ripley, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, p. 106 (1900), article on "The Capitalization of Public Service Corporations"; also an article in Engineering News, Vol. XXVIII, p. 492 (November, 1892).

Chapter 16. Interest on Money Loans

1. Some money-lenders in cities get 10% a day from fruit-vendors for the advance of small sums of money, and the losses are very slight. Pawnbroking pays frequently 25 to 100% per year. In these cases what affects the rate of interest?

1. Some moneylenders in cities charge 10% a day to fruit vendors for lending small amounts of money, and the losses are very minimal. Pawnbroking often yields returns of 25 to 100% per year. In these situations, what influences the interest rate?

2. Through what agency does the Western farmer borrow Eastern capital?

2. How does the Western farmer borrow money from the East?

3. How do Englishmen invest in American railroads?

3. How do British people invest in American railroads?

4. In what ways can a lender collect a high rate of interest without appearing to do so?

4. How can a lender charge a high-interest rate without making it obvious?

5. What would be the effect upon the rate of interest in a new state if it passed a law preventing the collection of loans by outside lenders?

5. What would happen to the interest rate in a new state if it passed a law that stopped outside lenders from collecting loans?

6. Why has interest been about 10% in the West, 7% in the Central States, 5% in New York, 4% in Germany?

6. Why has the interest been about 10% in the West, 7% in the Central States, 5% in New York, and 4% in Germany?

7. What is the money market? Who are the buyers and sellers, and what do they buy and sell?

7. What is the money market? Who are the buyers and sellers, and what do they trade?

8. In a panic, interest rises on short loans and prices fall, while it is almost impossible to borrow money; does this show that the amount of money determines the interest rate?

8. In a panic, interest rates increase on short loans and prices drop, while it's nearly impossible to borrow money; does this indicate that the amount of money determines the interest rate?

9. When gold is leaving England, the bank raises the rate of discount (interest); does this show that the quantity of money determines the rate of interest?

9. When gold is leaving England, the bank increases the discount rate (interest); does this indicate that the amount of money determines the interest rate?

Chapter 17. The Time-value Theory

1. Give examples of a high cost for the use of wealth without the borrowing of money.

1. Provide examples of a high price for using wealth without borrowing money.

2. Give some examples of the neglect of repairs through lack of resources, and show how it involved time-value.

2. Provide some examples of neglecting repairs due to a lack of resources, and explain how it affected the value of time.

3. What would be some of the first effects on production if interest on money loans fell to one half its present rate?

3. What would be some of the initial impacts on production if the interest on money loans dropped to half its current rate?

4. Which is the more important for the rate of interest, the amount of money in the banks or the amount of goods in the country?

4. Which is more important for the interest rate, the amount of money in the banks or the amount of goods in the country?

5. How would the rate of interest be affected if the amount of money were doubled at once?

5. How would the interest rate change if the amount of money was suddenly doubled?

Note.—In an interesting article on "Prestige Value," by L. M. Keasbey, in Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 1903, has been developed one phase of the thought in Sec. II, proposition 2.

Note.—In an interesting article titled "Prestige Value" by L. M. Keasbey, published in the Quarterly Journal of Economics in May 1903, one aspect of the idea presented in Section II, proposition 2 has been examined.

The very active recent discussion of "the interest problem" has done much to clarify economic theory; but almost the entire recent literature of the subject (as seen from our point of view) is based on a defective concept of capital. See in Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XVII, pp. 163-180 (November, 1902), article entitled "The 'Roundabout Process' in the Interest Theory," the author's criticism[Pg 577] of Böhm-Bawerk's Positive Theory. All the recent "marginal productivity" interest theories are at fault, we venture to say, in trying to derive income from capital instead of deriving the amount of capital from rent.

The recent heated discussion about "the interest problem" has significantly clarified economic theory; however, nearly all the recent literature on the subject (from our perspective) is based on a flawed understanding of capital. See the article "The 'Roundabout Process' in the Interest Theory" in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XVII, pp. 163-180 (November 1902), where the author critiques[Pg 577] Böhm-Bawerk's Positive Theory. All the recent "marginal productivity" interest theories seem to share the same error, as we would suggest, by attempting to derive income from capital instead of defining the amount of capital based on rent.

Chapter 18. Relatively Fixed and Relatively Increasing Forms of Capital

1. Why not raise seals in California and fruit in Alaska?

1. Why not farm seals in California and grow fruit in Alaska?

2. Has the rainfall any relation to the density of population?

2. Is there a connection between rainfall and population density?

3. Has the isothermal line any relation to the number of millionaires?

3. Is there any connection between the isothermal line and the number of millionaires?

4. What physical reasons account for the greatness of ancient Egypt, of Venice, of Holland, of England, of the United States?

4. What physical factors explain the greatness of ancient Egypt, Venice, Holland, England, and the United States?

5. Is all land useful? Is all land wealth?

5. Is all land valuable? Is all land rich in resources?

6 Is there a different term for land that is wealth and land that is not?

6 Is there a different term for valuable land and land that isn't?

7. Are there different economic terms for hewn and unhewn blocks of stone? What makes the difference?

7. Are there different economic terms for carved and uncarved stone blocks? What creates the distinction?

Note.—A meritorious though fragmentary essay to rethink the old conception of natural resources and to express them in new terms, is Natural Economy, by A. H. Gibson, 1901, reviewed by the writer in Journal of Political Economy, March, 1902.

Note.—A valuable yet unfinished essay that looks to redefine the conventional perspective on natural resources and offer a fresh viewpoint is Natural Economy by A. H. Gibson, published in 1901, and reviewed by the author in the Journal of Political Economy, March 1902.

Chapter 19. How Saving and Production Are Impacted by the Interest Rate

1. The savings of the people of the United States are nearly a billion dollars a year. What and where are they?

1. Americans save nearly a billion dollars a year. What are they saving for and where do these savings go?

2. What are the main social conditions necessary to saving?

2. What are the key social conditions needed for saving?

3. What influence has commercial morality on saving?

3. How does commercial ethics affect saving?

4. Do savings-banks and insurance companies stimulate saving, or do they exist because of a disposition to save?

4. Do savings banks and insurance companies encourage saving, or do they exist because people tend to save?

5. What influence has the formation of joint-stock companies on saving?

5. How has the creation of joint-stock companies affected saving?

6. Will you save more or less if the rate of interest falls?

6. Will you save more or less if the interest rate drops?

7. Distinguish between hoarding and saving.

7. Differentiate between hoarding and saving.

8. A woman cut the wool from a sheep's back, spun and wove it by old hand-methods, and within twenty-four hours wore the dress made of it. Is more or less time needed in production with the best machinery and processes?

8. A woman sheared the wool from a sheep's back, spun it, and wove it using traditional methods, and within twenty-four hours, she wore the dress made from it. Does it take more or less time to produce this with the best machines and processes?

9. Ricardo said that on account of the cheapness of food in America there was less temptation to employ machines than in England, where food was high. What is the fact about this temptation in America?

9. Ricardo said that because food is cheaper in America, there is less temptation to use machines than in England, where food is expensive. What is the reality of this temptation in America?

Note.—The older abstinence theory of interest is given by F. A. Walker, Political Economy, Secs. 87-93. A noteworthy advance was the able article, by T. N. Carver, in Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. VIII, p. 40 (1893), "The Place of Abstinence in the Theory of Interest." A number of writers have written (fallaciously, in our judgment) on the "fallacy of saving," arguing that the capital-market easily becomes glutted; the contrary view is well presented by Cassel, The Nature and Necessity of Interest (1903), pp. 96-157, in chapters on what he calls "The Demand for Waiting," and "The Supply of Waiting."

Note.—The older theory of abstinence regarding interest is explained by F. A. Walker in Political Economy, Sections 87-93. A notable improvement came from T. N. Carver's insightful article in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. VIII, p. 40 (1893), titled "The Place of Abstinence in the Theory of Interest." Some authors have incorrectly discussed what they call the "fallacy of saving," suggesting that the capital market can easily become oversaturated; the opposing viewpoint is thoroughly articulated by Cassel in The Nature and Necessity of Interest (1903), pp. 96-157, in chapters he refers to as "The Demand for Waiting" and "The Supply of Waiting."

Chapter 20. Work and Types of Workers

1. Is dancing labor? Is the dancing of a dancing-master labor? If he would rather dance than eat, is it labor?

1. Is dancing work? Is the dancing of a dance instructor work? If he prefers dancing over eating, is it still work?

2. Enumerate some kinds of labor necessary to produce bread.

2. List some types of work needed to make bread.

3. "Washing of clothes is unproductive labor; therefore as little of it should be done as possible." Criticize the argument.

3. "Washing clothes is a waste of time; therefore, we should do as little of it as possible." Criticize the argument.

4. Would you say that differences in ability at manual trades are due to practice or to native talent? If to both, in what proportion?

4. Do you think the differences in skill at manual trades come from practice or natural talent? If it's a mix of both, what ratio would you suggest?

5. Do sons usually follow the father's trade? Is it more or less common than formerly for them to do so?

5. Do sons typically take up their father's profession? Is it more or less common for them to do this now than it was in the past?

6. Do you know from personal observation whether a Mexican, a German, or an American, is the best workman?

6. Do you know from personal experience whether a Mexican, a German, or an American is the best worker?

7. What important personal traits are needed to make a man an efficient market-gardener?

7. What important personal traits are needed to make a man an effective market gardener?

8. Which would be of the greatest economic advantage, to increase by 50% the intelligence, the physical strength, or the integrity of the workers of this country?

8. Which would provide the greatest economic benefit: increasing the intelligence, physical strength, or integrity of the workers in this country by 50%?

Chapter 21. The Supply of Labor

1. Has the principle of the survival of the fittest any influence on the population of America?

1. Does the principle of survival of the fittest have any impact on the population of America?

2. What limits the number of wild rabbits? Of tame pigeons? Do the same influences act in the case of men?

2. What limits the population of wild rabbits? Of domesticated pigeons? Do the same factors apply to humans?

3. What other influences affect population?

3. What other factors impact population?

4. What relation is there between population and mountains, temperature and water-supply?

4. What is the relationship between population and mountains, temperature, and water supply?

5. It has been said that the supply of labor is fixed by biologic laws. Is it therefore not subject to economic influences?

5. It has been said that the supply of labor is determined by biological laws. Is it not influenced by economic factors?

6. What application do you think the principle of diminishing returns has to the question of population?

6. How do you think the principle of diminishing returns applies to the issue of population?

7. What is meant by the standard of life?

7. What does the standard of living mean?

Note.—The subject of population generally is discussed under the name of "The Malthusian Doctrine" and much space is given to it[Pg 579] in the texts. So much useless controversy has been occasioned by the ambiguities of Malthus's argument that it seemed best not to introduce this difficulty into the text. The subject is discussed with broadest view by A. T. Hadley, Economics, Secs. 47-60. The writer attempted to make a judicial study of Malthus and his work in Versuch einer Bevölkerungslehre, Jena, 1894, and sought to put the discussion on higher ground in an article in the Yale Review, August, 1898, "The Essay of Malthus, a Centennial Review."

Note.—The subject of population is commonly known as "The Malthusian Doctrine," and it gets a lot of focus[Pg 579] in the literature. There's been a lot of unnecessary debate because of the ambiguities in Malthus's argument, so it was decided not to include this topic in the text. A. T. Hadley explores this subject in depth in Economics, Sections 47-60. The author aimed to provide a balanced examination of Malthus and his work in Versuch einer Bevölkerungslehre, Jena, 1894, and sought to enhance the discourse in an article in the Yale Review, August 1898, titled "The Essay of Malthus, a Centennial Review."

Chapter 22. Conditions for Productive Work

1. Is hunger the cause of food?

1. Is hunger what drives us to seek food?

2. Is there any relation between a republican form of government and the growth of manufactures.

2. Is there a connection between a republican form of government and the growth of manufacturing?

3. What are the necessary conditions to the building of a house: (a) natural forces; (b) changes in material things; (c) human activities; (d) social conditions?

3. What are the essential conditions for constructing a house: (a) natural forces; (b) changes in material objects; (c) human activities; (d) social conditions?

4. Is the public school system an economic factor? Where among the four preceding heads would you classify it?

4. Is the public school system an economic factor? Where would you place it among the four categories mentioned earlier?

5. From an economic standpoint, can we say that robbery really reduces the wealth in existence?

5. From an economic perspective, can we say that robbery actually decreases the available wealth?

6. When does an industrious man stop working on his own farm, and why?

6. When does a hard-working person stop working on their own farm, and why?

7. With a given number of workers, what may be causes of differences in the labor-supply?

7. With a certain number of workers, what could be the reasons for differences in the labor supply?

8. Would men work better if they ate more?

8. Would people do better work if they ate more?

9. What moral agencies increase the efficiency of labor?

9. What moral factors boost the productivity of work?

10. Is there a strong selfish motive for men to increase their efficiency in most industries? How effective is it?

10. Is there a strong self-serving reason for men to boost their efficiency in most industries? How effective is it?

11. What effect has republican government on the efficiency of labor?

11. How does a republican government impact the efficiency of labor?

12. Why is the variety of occupations greater or less than formerly? What is influencing the change?

12. Why are there more or fewer job options now compared to the past? What factors are driving this change?

13. What cases have you seen where great skill came from practice?

13. What situations have you encountered where incredible skill was developed through practice?

14. What gain is it for men to work together instead of singly?

14. What benefit do men get from working together instead of alone?

15. With increasing division of labor is there greater or less opportunity for the payment of laborers according to the piece-wage plan?

15. With the growing division of labor, is there more or less chance for workers to be paid based on piece wages?

16. Discuss the following statement: Under the piece-work system the foreman looks out for the quality and the operative for the quantity of the work; under the time-wage system the foreman looks out for the quantity and the laborer for the quality of the work.

16. Discuss the following statement: In the piece-work system, the foreman supervises the quality while the worker focuses on the quantity of the work; in the time-wage system, the foreman monitors the quantity, and the laborer checks the quality of the work.

17. What remedy has the foreman for an inefficient laborer working under the time-wage system?

17. What solution does the foreman have for a slow worker under the hourly wage system?

18. Is time- or piece-work best adapted to the following kinds of[Pg 580] laborers: coal-miners, coopers, farm-hands, printers, engravers, shoe-factory hands, railroad brakemen, telegraph operators?

18. Is time or piecework better suited for the following types of[Pg 580] workers: coal miners, barrel makers, farm workers, printers, engravers, shoe factory workers, railroad brakemen, telegraph operators?

Chapter 23. The Law of Wages

1. What is the effect of free common schools on the comparative wages of skilled and of unskilled laborers?

1. What impact do free public schools have on the wage differences between skilled and unskilled workers?

2. What would be the effect of technical and industrial schools on the wages of artisans?

2. What would be the impact of technical and industrial schools on the wages of skilled workers?

3. If a man is not content with $2 a day, why does he not do work that is paid $5 a day?

3. If a man isn't satisfied with $2 a day, why doesn't he take a job that pays $5 a day?

4. What is the effect on wages of differences in the danger, pleasurableness, social distinction, expense of preparation, of occupation?

4. What is the impact on wages from variations in the level of danger, enjoyment, social status, cost of training, and type of work?

5. If women are paid less than men for the same work, why are men employed at all?

5. If women earn less than men for doing the same job, then why are men even hired?

6. What is the difference between these definitions: wages is the share of labor; wages is the payment by one man to another for his services?

6. What’s the difference between these definitions: wages as the share of labor; wages as the payment from one person to another for their services?

7. If the supply of labor of any class were to be decreased 10% would wages rise in like proportion?

7. If the supply of labor in any category were to decrease by 10%, would wages increase proportionately?

8. Since under the piece-work system a man is paid only for what he does, is there any reason for discharging a workman employed under this plan whose efficiency falls below the average?

8. Since in the piece-work system a person is paid only for what they produce, is there any reason to let go of a worker on this plan if their performance drops below average?

Chapter 24. The Connection Between Labor and Value

1. May a singer of songs or a mixer of drinks be called a productive laborer?

1. Can a singer or a bartender be considered a productive worker?

2. Are fine products high in price because wages are high, or vice versa?

2. Are high-quality products expensive because wages are high, or is it the other way around?

3. Is common, unskilled labor "scarce" (in any reasonable sense of the word) in China? in the United States?

3. Is common, unskilled labor "scarce" (in any reasonable sense of the word) in China? in the United States?

4. Can a manufacturer pay the same to laborers if the product will be marketed next year, as he can if it is to be marketed to-morrow? If so, how is the value of the labor adjusted to its product?

4. Can a manufacturer pay laborers the same amount if the product will be sold next year as they can if it will be sold tomorrow? If so, how is the value of the labor adjusted to its product?

Note.—An able discussion of the effect of discounting in the sale of labor in the market is given by Böhm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital, pp. 313-318 et seq.; see also Wieser, Natural Value, numerous passages. The changes in industrial organization are treated with historic insight by Hadley, Economics, Secs. 341-354. F. W. Taussig's Wages and Capital (1896) gives a sympathetic interpretation of the wage-fund doctrine; the work is especially valuable for its excellent review of the history of the subject and for the chapters analyzing the modern industrial process.

Note.—Böhm-Bawerk provides a thorough discussion of how discounting impacts the job market in his book, Positive Theory of Capital, pages 313-318 et seq.; also look at Wieser's Natural Value for several pertinent sections. Hadley gives a historical perspective on changes in industrial organization in Economics, Sections 341-354. F. W. Taussig's Wages and Capital (1896) offers a sympathetic view on the wage-fund doctrine; this work is especially valuable for its comprehensive review of the topic's history and its chapters that analyze the modern industrial process.

[Pg 581]

Chapter 25. The Wage System and Its Effects

1. Why has machinery changed the relations of workman to master?

1. Why have machines changed the relationship between workers and bosses?

2. In what ways does labor get paid for its share, and who pays it?

2. How is labor compensated for its contribution, and who is responsible for that payment?

3. Will a day's work of a common laborer buy more to-day than it would a half century ago? Why?

3. Can a day’s wages for a regular worker buy more today than it could fifty years ago? Why?

4. Are the opportunities for workmen to rise to the rank of masters as great as formerly?

4. Are the chances for workers to advance to the level of masters as good as they used to be?

5. Are wages independent of the other kinds of income?

5. Are wages separate from other types of income?

Chapter 26. Machines and Work

1. Do you think that the amount of work is reduced by new machinery? Point out ambiguities in the question.

1. Do you think that new machines reduce the amount of work? Point out any unclear parts in the question.

2. What is the difference to the workman whether he becomes more efficient or works with a better machine?

2. What difference does it make to the worker whether he becomes more efficient or uses a better machine?

3. Is the work of any kind fixed in quantity? What would cause it to change?

3. Is the amount of work in any way set? What could make it change?

4. What kinds of laborers were thrown out of employment by the invention of the type-writer? What kinds of labor found employment as a result of its invention? Was the net result a gain or a loss of employment?

4. What types of workers lost their jobs because of the invention of the typewriter? What types of jobs became available because of its invention? Was the overall impact a gain or a loss of employment?

5. Answer the same questions with regard to the invention of railroads, mowing-, binding-, and threshing-machines; or the new roller-process of flour milling.

5. Answer the same questions about the invention of railroads, mowing machines, binding machines, and threshing machines; or the new roller process of flour milling.

6. Can you describe from your own experience any example of readjustment of labor due to introduction of new machinery?

6. Can you share from your own experience an example of how labor was adjusted because of the introduction of new machinery?

Chapter 27. Unions

1. Does it make any difference in the permanence of an increase of wages brought about by a strike, whether the employer is one of the more successful or one of the less successful in that business?

1. Does it matter for the long-term stability of a wage increase resulting from a strike if the employer is one of the more successful or one of the less successful in that industry?

2. Is there any similarity between the methods of trade-unions and the etiquette of the medical and the legal professions?

2. Are there any similarities between the ways trade unions operate and the standards of conduct in the medical and legal professions?

3. If you were an officer of a trade-union, would you begin a strike when trade was good or when it was poor?

3. If you were a trade union officer, would you start a strike when business was booming or when it was struggling?

4. If you can do more work in two hours than in one, can you do more continuously in sixteen consecutive hours than in eight?

4. If you can accomplish more work in two hours than in one, can you get more done continuously in sixteen straight hours than in eight?

5. What determines the maximum study-time for the earnest student?

5. What decides the maximum study time for the dedicated student?

6. If as much is produced in a general eight-hour day, who benefits?

6. If the same amount is produced in an eight-hour workday, who gains?

7. If production is reduced one fourth by shorter hours, is "work made" to that degree for the unemployed?

7. If production is reduced by a quarter due to shorter hours, does that create "work" for the unemployed to that extent?

8. If all day-laborers should agree to work with one hand tied behind them, would their wages go up or down? Would it be good or bad for the whole class of laborers?

8. If all manual workers agreed to work with one hand tied behind their backs, would their pay increase or decrease? Would that be beneficial or detrimental for the entire group of workers?

Chapter 28. Production and the Combination of the Factors

1. What is production? Does the economic idea of production conflict with the physical principle that matter cannot be created?

1. What is production? Does the economic concept of production clash with the physical principle that matter cannot be created?

2. Is it production to buy fifty cents' worth of yarn and knit a pair of socks worth twenty-five cents if you enjoy doing it? If you do not enjoy it?

2. Is it worth it to buy fifty cents' worth of yarn and knit a pair of socks that are worth twenty-five cents if you enjoy it? What if you don’t enjoy it?

3. Give examples of factors of production.

3. Give examples of production factors.

4. What factors of production must be combined by a savage to produce a canoe?

4. What production factors does a person in a primitive society need to combine to make a canoe?

5. Outline the combination of factors that has produced New York bread made from Minnesota wheat.

5. Describe the combination of factors that has led to New York bread being made from Minnesota wheat.

6. What is the largest manufacturing establishment in your home town? Would a number of smaller establishments of the same sort and with the same aggregate capacity succeed as well? Why?

6. What is the biggest manufacturing facility in your hometown? Would several smaller facilities of the same type and with the same overall capacity be just as successful? Why?

7. Have you observed the growth of any local industry from a small beginning to large proportions? If so, how do you account for it?

7. Have you seen any local businesses grow from small beginnings to significant sizes? If so, what do you think caused that growth?

8. Would you prefer to begin your business career with a large company or with a small merchant? Why?

8. Would you rather start your business career with a big company or a small business? Why?

9. Through what historic stages has production passed?

9. What historical stages has production gone through?

10. Give examples of the industrial advantages of America as compared with Europe.

10. Provide examples of the industrial advantages that America has over Europe.

Chapter 29. Business Organization and the Entrepreneur's Role

1. What is the relative importance of organization in sawing wood, building houses, running a small store, or a large factory?

1. How important is organization when it comes to sawing wood, building houses, running a small store, or managing a large factory?

2. Which wins the battle: the general, the soldiers, or the armament?

2. Who wins the battle: the general, the soldiers, or the weapons?

3. What determines whether a crop is poor or good: the ground, the weather, or the farmer?

3. What decides if a crop is bad or good: the soil, the weather, or the farmer?

4. Why do some businesses give increasing returns as they grow?

4. Why do some businesses see greater profits as they expand?

5. One has said: "The natural differences in powers and aptitudes are certainly not greater than are natural differences in stature." Is this sound in an economic sense?

5. It has been said: "The natural differences in abilities and talents are definitely not greater than the natural differences in height." Is this valid from an economic perspective?

6. Who runs the business in a large store owned by a large family? Who has the risk?

6. Who manages the business in a big store owned by a large family? Who bears the risk?

7. Who is the enterpriser in a stock company where there is a[Pg 583] superintendent elected by a board of directors, themselves elected by shareholders with one vote per share?

7. Who is the entrepreneur in a stock company where there is a[Pg 583] superintendent elected by a board of directors, which is elected by shareholders with one vote for each share?

8. Who is the employer in a coöperative cooper-shop whose superintendent is elected by the workmen?

8. Who is the employer in a cooperative workshop where the workers elect the superintendent?

9. Has "a good chance in life" much to do with success?

9. Does having "a good chance in life" really relate to success?

10. What are the chief elements of business success?

10. What are the main elements of business success?

11. Is modern business competition a competition of men only?

11. Is modern business competition just a competition among people?

Chapter 30. Production Costs

1. What is the cost of a good you have made entirely with your own labor?

1. What is the value of something you’ve created entirely through your own work?

2. What is the difference to the employer between rent, interest, and wages as items of cost?

2. What’s the difference for the employer between rent, interest, and wages as costs?

3. Is there anything in common between "cost, the onerous exertion necessary to get goods," and cost as the money expenses of production?

3. Is there anything in common between "cost, the heavy effort needed to acquire goods," and cost as the monetary expenses of production?

4. Why does a merchant engage in one business rather than in another?

4. Why does a merchant choose one business over another?

5. When prices fall, what determines which factories shall close, and which workmen shall be discharged?

5. When prices drop, what decides which factories will shut down and which workers will be let go?

6. Does the value of a product conform to the capital that has been put into it.

6. Does the value of a product match the capital that has been invested in it?

Note.—For a fuller treatment of the more recent view of the subject, see Smart, pp. 64-83; Wieser, Natural Value, pp. 171-214; Böhm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital, pp. 179-189, 223-234. The defects of such revisions as that attempted by Alfred Marshall are pointed out in Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, pp. 432-452, article "The Passing of the Old Rent Concept."

Note.—For a more detailed view on the latest perspectives on the topic, check out Smart, pp. 64-83; Wieser, Natural Value, pp. 171-214; and Böhm-Bawerk, Positive Theory of Capital, pp. 179-189, 223-234. The limitations of revisions like the one attempted by Alfred Marshall are discussed in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. XV, pp. 432-452, in the article "The Passing of the Old Rent Concept."

Chapter 31. The Law of Profits

1. Business being poor, one employer is making good profits; how different will be the wages he pays from those paid by the unsuccessful employer?

1. With business being slow, one employer is making good profits; how different will the wages he pays be from those paid by the unsuccessful employer?

2. How many of the men you know at the head of large businesses started life poor?

2. How many of the men you know who lead big companies started out poor?

3. Was the rise in fortune due most often to chance, inheritance of wealth, or exceptional ability and power of work?

3. Was the increase in fortune mostly due to luck, inherited wealth, or exceptional talent and hard work?

4. How should the income of an inventor be classified, as wages or profits?

4. How should an inventor's income be categorized, as wages or profits?

5. Are the profits of the employer deducted from wages? Are the high wages of skilled labor deducted from the wages of unskilled?

5. Are the employer's profits taken out of wages? Are the high wages of skilled workers deducted from the wages of unskilled workers?

Chapter 32. Profit Sharing, Producers' and Consumers' Cooperation

1. Describe any case of profit-sharing you may have seen in operation.

1. Describe any example of profit-sharing you've seen in action.

2. Is advertising of any social service or is its sole purpose to divert trade from one merchant to another?

2. Is advertising for any social service, or is it just meant to direct business from one seller to another?

3. In what ways are retail stores wasteful in their expenditures? Can this be avoided?

3. How are retail stores wasteful with their spending? Can this be prevented?

4. If you have seen a coöperative store in operation tell what was its success.

4. If you've seen a cooperative store in operation, describe its success.

5. Are you willing to pay more for goods in order to have a choice of stores?

5. Are you willing to pay extra for products to have a variety of stores to choose from?

Chapter 33. Monopoly Earnings

1. How is the blacksmith free to compete with the physician and how not? In what sense have we assumed that competition exists?

1. How is the blacksmith able to compete with the doctor and in what ways is he not? In what sense are we assuming that competition exists?

2. Is there competition between the owner of good land and the owner of poor land?

2. Is there competition between the owner of good land and the owner of bad land?

3. Has the owner of a poor gold-mine a monopoly? Has the owner of a rich mine a monopoly?

3. Does the owner of a low-value gold mine have a monopoly? Does the owner of a high-value mine have a monopoly?

4. Does the ownership of land give a monopoly? The ownership of a horse?

4. Does owning land create a monopoly? What about owning a horse?

5. In what sense is a street-railway a monopoly? What is the value of its franchise?

5. In what way does a street railway operate as a monopoly? What is the worth of its franchise?

6. Why does the public consent to grant patents or public franchises?

6. Why does the public agree to grant patents or public franchises?

7. If one company controlled all the petroleum in the world, what would it consider in fixing the selling price?

7. If one company had control over all the oil in the world, what factors would it take into account when setting the selling price?

8. Why will railroads issue commutation tickets?

8. Why will railroads issue monthly commuter tickets?

Note.—Of the very large recent literature bearing on monopoly and trusts may be mentioned as especially useful: J. B. Clark, Control of Trusts; R. T. Ely, Monopolies and Trusts; J. W. Jenks, The Trust Problem (a summary by the expert for the Industrial Commission); J. E. le Rossignol, Monopolies, Past and Present; Report of the Chicago Conference on Trusts, 1899; Report of the United States Industrial Commission, 19 vols., 1900-2 (a mine of information).

Note.—Among the many recent works on monopolies and trusts, the following are especially useful: J. B. Clark, Control of Trusts; R. T. Ely, Monopolies and Trusts; J. W. Jenks, The Trust Problem (a summary by the expert for the Industrial Commission); J. E. le Rossignol, Monopolies, Past and Present; Report of the Chicago Conference on Trusts, 1899; Report of the United States Industrial Commission, 19 vols., 1900-2 (a wealth of information).

Chapter 34. Rise of Trusts and Combinations

1. What advantages are there to manufacturers in combination? What to the public?

1. What benefits do manufacturers gain from coming together? What about the public?

2. What relation has improved transportation and other means of communication to trusts?

2. How have improved transportation and other means of communication impacted trusts?

3. Name as many economic monopolies as you can.

3. List as many economic monopolies as you can.

4. What large trusts have recently been formed?

4. What major trusts have been created recently?

5. Does the public consider the growth of trusts to be good or bad? What do students of the question think of it?

5. Does the public view the rise of trusts as positive or negative? What do experts on the topic think about it?

Chapter 35. Impact of Trusts on Prices

1. Can the large factory always outsell the small one? Why?

1. Can the big factory always sell more than the small one? Why?

2. Why are trusts or selling agreements formed?

2. Why are trusts or sales agreements created?

3. Describe any agreement of which you know, made between merchants or manufacturers for the purpose of regulating prices. Did prices go up or down as a result?

3. Describe any agreements you know of that were made between merchants or manufacturers to control prices. Did prices increase or decrease as a result?

4. Would it be a good thing for society if a trust made great economies in production, crowded out its smaller competitors, and maintained prices just where they were before, dividing among its shareholders the amounts saved?

4. Would it benefit society if a trust significantly cut production costs, pushed out its smaller competitors, and kept prices the same as before, sharing the savings among its shareholders?

5. How would the effects on society be different if prices were reduced by better organization and the prevention of waste?

5. How would the impact on society change if prices were lowered through better organization and reducing waste?

6. Is it good public policy to allow a trust to undersell its smaller competitor in one district while it keeps up its prices elsewhere?

6. Is it good public policy to let a trust sell at a lower price than its smaller competitor in one area while maintaining higher prices in other places?

Chapter 36. Gambling, Speculation, and Profits for Promoters

1. Do you think that store-keepers fix the price of the produce they buy of the farmers? If so, to what extent?

1. Do you think that shop owners set the prices for the products they buy from farmers? If yes, how much do they control them?

2. Can brokers fix the price of grain on the market? How, and to what extent?

2. Can brokers set the price of grain in the market? How do they do this, and to what extent?

3. What is speculation? Give examples you have seen.

3. What is speculation? Provide examples you have encountered.

4. Were they, on the whole, good for the community?

4. Were they, overall, beneficial for the community?

5. Give other examples showing the difference between a gambling-house and an insurance company?

5. Provide more examples that highlight the difference between a casino and an insurance company.

6. Is the immorality of betting based on economic grounds?

6. Is the immorality of gambling rooted in economic reasons?

7. Ought lotteries to be permitted by law?

7. Should lotteries be allowed by law?

8. Ought speculation in mines to be permitted by law?

8. Should speculation in mines be allowed by law?

9. Ought the profits of the farmer from a sudden rise in the value of wheat be confiscated to the public?

9. Should the profits of the farmer from a sudden increase in the value of wheat be taken for the public good?

Note.—The ablest study of the subject is by H. C. Emery, Speculation on the Stock and Produce Exchanges of the United States, in Columbia University Studies in History, Economics, and Public Law, Vol. VII, No. 2, 1896.

Note.—The most useful research on this topic comes from H. C. Emery's book, Speculation on the Stock and Produce Exchanges of the United States, published in Columbia University Studies in History, Economics, and Public Law, Vol. VII, No. 2, 1896.

Chapter 37. Crises and Economic Recessions

1. What is a financial crisis? An industrial depression?

1. What is a financial crisis? An economic downturn?

2. Define the expressions "over-production" and "under-consumption."

2. Define the terms "over-production" and "under-consumption."

3. In a period of depression is there less money than usual in the country? In the banks?

3. During a period of economic downturn, is there less money than usual in the country? In the banks?

4. If there were twice as much money in the world, would panics take place?

4. If there were twice as much money in the world, would there still be panics?

5. Before a financial crisis how are prices, high or low? After a panic?

5. Before a financial crisis, are prices high or low? After a panic?

6. What economic changes occurred in your own community in the panic of 1893-4, or in the years 1903-4?

6. What economic changes happened in your own community during the panic of 1893-94, or in the years 1903-04?

7. Do people save more in good times or hard times?

7. Do people save more during good times or tough times?

Chapter 38. Personal Property and Inheritance

1. If the law permits certain classes to be fleeced without redress, is wealth thereby reduced?

1. If the law allows certain groups to be taken advantage of without any recourse, does that actually decrease wealth?

2. What are vested rights? Do they ever stand in the way of progress? Examples.

2. What are vested rights? Do they ever hinder progress? Examples.

3. Is it right that the lucky inventor of a popular toy should make $100 a day from it?

3. Is it fair for the lucky inventor of a popular toy to earn $100 a day from it?

4. Is it right that an inventor should by patent laws be able to keep the profits of his business high?

4. Is it fair for an inventor to use patent laws to keep their business profits high?

5. Do you know of any father who created more wealth because he could bequeath it to his son?

5. Do you know any dad who made more money just because he could pass it on to his son?

6. Does the son work as hard when he inherits his father's wealth?

6. Does the son put in the same effort after inheriting his father's wealth?

7. What is the effect of private property on saving?

7. How does private property affect saving?

8. If capital is needed in production why is the question of justice raised when its use is paid for?

8. If capital is necessary for production, why is the issue of justice brought up when its use is compensated?

Chapter 39. Income and Social Services

1. What is it to earn a living? How many people do it?

1. What does it mean to earn a living? How many people are doing it?

2. When is a man poor?

2. When is a man poor?

3. Would it be a good thing if the boot-black got a dollar a shine?

3. Would it be a good idea if the shoe shiner got a dollar for each shine?

4. Does luck have greater influence on business success in an old country or a new one?

4. Does luck have a bigger impact on business success in an established country or a developing one?

5. Ditto in agriculture, mining, commerce, or manufactures?

5. The same goes for agriculture, mining, commerce, or manufacturing?

6. A rare coin and a piece of land sold for the same price one year, and the next year both sold for double the amount. Was there an unearned increment in both cases, and of the same kind?

6. A rare coin and a piece of land sold for the same price one year, and the next year both sold for double the amount. Was there an unearned increase in both cases, and of the same kind?

7. If rewards were equal, what would determine the choice of work?

7. If the rewards were the same, what would influence the decision on which job to choose?

Note.—The most important contributions to the theory of consumption have been made by S. N. Patten in his numerous writings, among them: The Consumption of Wealth (1889); Theory of Dynamic Economics (1892); The Theory of Prosperity (1902). A[Pg 587] number of the ideas are well restated in more simple terms by E. T. Devine in Economics, especially pp. 375-396, and 73-111 (applies to chapter 41).

Note.—The most important contributions to the theory of consumption have been made by S. N. Patten in his numerous writings, including: The Consumption of Wealth (1889); Theory of Dynamic Economics (1892); The Theory of Prosperity (1902). Some of these ideas are clearly restated in simpler terms by E. T. Devine in Economics, especially on pages 375-396 and 73-111 (related to chapter 41).

Chapter 40. Waste and Luxury

1. Can we determine what luxury is, or give the notion definiteness?

1. Can we figure out what luxury really is, or define the concept clearly?

2. Do you feel a sense of injustice when you read of a millionaire's ball if you are not a millionaire?

2. Do you feel a sense of injustice when you read about a millionaire's party if you're not a millionaire?

3. Can you excuse the sense of injustice felt by the hungry man when he sees you wear patent-leather shoes and kid gloves?

3. Can you understand the sense of injustice felt by the hungry man when he sees you wearing shiny leather shoes and fancy gloves?

4. Under private property, can men complain of the use made by others of their wealth on the ground merely that it was unwise?

4. Under private property, can people complain about how others use their wealth just because it's considered unwise?

5. Is luxury necessary to give employment to labor?

5. Is luxury essential for creating jobs for workers?

6. Is the spendthrift the best friend of labor?

6. Is the wasteful spender the best friend of hard work?

7. Ought legislation attempt to prevent luxury, or can public opinion affect it?

7. Should legislation try to prevent luxury, or can public opinion influence it?

8. Is smoking high-priced cigars economically justifiable, assuming that the smoker is wealthy and does not injure his health thereby?

8. Is smoking expensive cigars financially justified, assuming that the smoker is wealthy and doesn't harm his health as a result?

9. Wines, balls, pensions are said to be good because they put money into circulation. Criticize.

9. People say that wines, parties, and pensions are good because they get money moving around. Critique this idea.

10. What is the difference between the consumption of wealth and its destruction?

10. What’s the difference between spending wealth and wasting it?

11. In what ways can a piece of iron be consumed, economically speaking?

11. In what ways can a piece of iron be used up, economically speaking?

12. Was the great Chicago fire, which led to the rebuilding of the city, a good thing economically?

12. Was the great Chicago fire, which resulted in the city's rebuilding, a positive thing economically?

Chapter 41. How Consumption Affects Production

1. What are complementary goods? Give some illustrations.

1. What are complementary goods? Provide some examples.

2. Can people live on the future, consuming in advance of production? How is it with the nation in time of war?

2. Can people rely on the future, consuming before production happens? What happens to a nation during wartime?

3. Does economic theory throw any light on the ethics of miserliness?

3. Does economic theory provide any insight into the ethics of being stingy?

4. It is said that the demand of the day-laborer for cheap white shirts has reduced the wages of the women who make them. Criticize.

4. It's said that the demand from day laborers for inexpensive white shirts has driven down the wages of the women who make them. Critique.

5. What effect on wealth would a change of climate have, whereby the consumption of coal would be decreased?

5. How would a change in climate that reduces coal consumption affect wealth?

6. If manna fell from heaven daily in a climate where clothing and shelter were unnecessary, what effect on wealth would result?

6. If manna fell from heaven every day in a place where clothing and shelter weren’t needed, how would that affect wealth?

Chapter 42. Distribution of Social Income

1. What different ideas does the expression "distribution of wealth" suggest to you?

1. What different ideas does the phrase "distribution of wealth" bring to mind for you?

2. What different methods of obtaining an income have you noted among the men you know?

2. What different ways of making money have you observed among the guys you know?

3. How can a yard of cloth be said to be distributed to the labor and capital producing it?

3. How can we say that a yard of fabric is shared among the labor and capital that produced it?

4. If two men of equal skill go fishing together, how would they find a rule for dividing the catch?

4. If two guys with the same skill level go fishing together, how would they figure out a way to split the catch?

5. If one is more skilful or stronger, or owns the boat and the tackle, how would it affect the division? Would any rule be attainable?

5. If someone is more skilled or stronger, or owns the boat and the gear, how would that impact the division? Would any rule be possible?

6. If socialism reduced the total product, would it still be desirable because of the better distribution?

6. If socialism decreased the overall output, would it still be worth it due to the improved distribution?

7. What classes of thinkers are most inclined to take up socialism? (Classes considered socially, industrially, as to race, as to economic and historical training.)

7. What groups of thinkers are most likely to adopt socialism? (Groups considered in terms of social class, industry, race, as well as their economic and historical background.)

Chapter 43. Overview of the Theory of Value

1. Mention any cases you can think of where merely changing the place of things added to their value; or changing their form; or where the mere lapse of time added to the value of the thing.

1. Think of any examples where just moving things around increased their value; or changing their appearance; or where just the passage of time increased the value of the item.

2. What effect on wages and interest does the bringing in of foreign capital have?

2. What impact does bringing in foreign capital have on wages and interest?

3. If, through greater efficiency of labor, wealth increases, which share benefits?

3. If increased efficiency in work leads to more wealth, who gets to benefit from it?

4. What would be the effect on wages, interest, and land rent of a sudden addition of rich land to the country?

4. What would happen to wages, interest, and land rent if a large amount of wealthy land was suddenly added to the country?

5. What would be the effect on interest, land rent, and wages of a great increase of national saving?

5. What would be the impact on interest rates, land rent, and wages from a significant increase in national savings?

6. What concern have the poor in the abundance of capital? The rich in the abundance of labor?

6. What worry do the poor have in a world full of capital? What do the rich worry about in a world full of labor?

7. Walker says that the laborer gets what is left after the other shares are deducted according to their law; wages are the residual claimant. Are the other shares independent of wages?

7. Walker states that the worker receives what remains after the other shares are taken out based on their rules; wages are the leftover claim. Are the other shares separate from wages?

8. Can wage-earners be shut out from all advantages in the land of the country?

8. Can workers be excluded from all benefits in their country's land?

9. Are high wages and high interest seen to go together? Give such examples as you think of.

9. Are high wages and high interest rates viewed as linked? Provide any examples you can think of.

10. Do improvements in agriculture increase or decrease the rent of land?

10. Do advancements in agriculture raise or lower land rent?

Chapter 44. Free Competition and Government Action

1. What is economic freedom? How different from political freedom?

1. What is economic freedom? How is it different from political freedom?

2. Does the presence of a policeman increase or diminish competition among men?

2. Does having a cop around increase or decrease competition among guys?

3. Are most positive laws intended to hinder competition or make it freer?

3. Are most laws meant to limit competition or make it more open?

4. In what ways does competition reduce the total product?

4. How does competition decrease the overall product?

5. Is custom a better regulator of economic action than competition?

5. Is custom a better guide for economic behavior than competition?

6. Criticize the doctrine of economic harmony, giving examples.

6. Critique the idea of economic harmony, providing examples.

Chapter 45. Use, Currency, and Worth of Money

1. If gold were to become as plentiful as iron, would it be worth more or less than iron?

1. If gold became as abundant as iron, would it be worth more or less than iron?

2. Some say Providence has indicated gold and silver as the materials for money. How has this been done?

2. Some people say that fate has pointed to gold and silver as the materials for money. How has this happened?

3. Why does nearly all the gold produced in California leave the state? What keeps any of it there?

3. Why does almost all the gold produced in California leave the state? What makes any of it stay?

4. Who makes coins? Would jewelers make better ones?

4. Who makes coins? Would jewelers create better ones?

5. When gold comes out of the mine is the gain to the community greater or less than when the same value of grain is harvested?

5. Is the benefit to the community greater or less when gold is extracted from the mine compared to when the same amount of grain is harvested?

6. Does gold cost the day-laborer as much in California as in New York?

6. Does gold cost the day laborer as much in California as it does in New York?

7. What are the principal things besides money uses that cause a demand for gold and silver?

7. What are the main things, aside from their monetary uses, that create a demand for gold and silver?

8. The mint price of an ounce of gold, .900 fine, is alike at San Francisco and Philadelphia, $18.604. Why is gold ever shipped from California to New York?

8. The market price of an ounce of gold, .900 fine, is the same in San Francisco and Philadelphia, $18.604. Why is gold ever shipped from California to New York?

9. Give examples of things that increase the demand for money.

9. Give examples of things that boost the demand for money.

10. Note any habits of friends that result in their carrying more or less money than others of the same income.

10. Take note of any habits of your friends that lead them to have more or less money compared to others with the same income.

11. What determines the amount of money needed by different persons, towns, states, and nations?

11. What factors determine how much money different people, towns, states, and nations need?

12. When goods are exchanged for money or money for goods, what is the gain?

12. When products are traded for cash or cash for products, what’s the benefit?

13. On an isolated island would it make any difference as to the value of money if there were but one gold-mine or several competing ones, supposing that the output were the same?

13. On an isolated island, would it matter to the value of money if there was just one gold mine or multiple competing ones, assuming that the output was the same?

Chapter 46. Token Currency and Government Paper Money

1. Define legal-tender as applied to money. What is meant by fiat money?

1. Define legal tender when it comes to money. What does fiat money mean?

2. Show the difference between convertible and inconvertible money.

2. Explain the difference between convertible and inconvertible money.

3. The government of the island of Guernsey having no money, issued paper-notes to pay for the building of a market. They circulated and were gradually taken up as the market earned its cost, during ten years. When they were all redeemed and burned, the[Pg 590] island had the market free of cost. Explain how this could be done. (This is from Sumner's Problems in Political Economy.)

3. The government of the island of Guernsey, lacking funds, issued paper notes to finance the construction of a market. These notes circulated and were gradually redeemed as the market generated revenue over ten years. Once all the notes were redeemed and destroyed, the[Pg 590] island had the market at no cost. Explain how this was possible. (This is from Sumner's Problems in Political Economy.)

Chapter 47. The Standard of Deferred Payments

1. If every piece of money should miraculously be doubled in a night, whose interests would be affected?

1. If every dollar suddenly doubled overnight, who would be impacted?

2. Is the fact of one man's gain and another man's loss by chance of any economic or political importance?

2. Does one person's gain and another person's loss by chance have any significance in economics or politics?

3. What gives rise to the belief sometimes held that money is an invariable standard of value?

3. What leads to the belief that money is a constant standard of value?

4. Is there anything in the nature of mining that keeps the ratio of the supply of gold and silver nearly uniform?

4. Is there something about mining that ensures the supply ratio of gold and silver stays fairly consistent?

5. Is the value of gold and silver due to the action of government?

5. Is the value of gold and silver determined by government actions?

6. Does the principle of the substitution of goods have any bearing on the value of metals under bimetallism?

6. Does the principle of substituting goods affect the value of metals in bimetallism?

7. Note carefully, and indicate the different meanings of bimetallism; of demonetization.

7. Pay close attention and point out the different meanings of bimetallism and demonetization.

8. What is the extent of the influence one nation can have on the ratio of the two precious metals?

8. How much influence can one country have on the ratio of the two precious metals?

9. If money wages are higher and general prices are lower, how is the laborer affected? Is this due to the appreciation of money?

9. If wages are higher and general prices are lower, how does this impact the worker? Is this because of the increase in the value of money?

10. Can you get a kind of money that will make the things that are sold, dearer, and the things that are bought, cheaper?

10. Is there a way to get money that makes things for sale more expensive and things being bought cheaper?

11. What are the main reasons given for the ratio of 16 to 1?

11. What are the main reasons provided for the 16 to 1 ratio?

Chapter 48. Banking and Credit

1. What does a bank do for a community?

1. What does a bank do for a community?

2. What are the sources of income to a bank?

2. What are the sources of income for a bank?

3. Can a bank that issues its own notes afford to lend cheaper than the ordinary capitalist?

3. Can a bank that issues its own notes afford to lend at a lower rate than regular investors?

4. What is discount and deposit?

4. What are discount and deposit?

5. Do all banks issue notes? Why?

5. Do all banks issue banknotes? Why?

6. What is the function of a clearing-house?

6. What does a clearinghouse do?

7. If there are twenty banks in a town and no clearing-house, how many collections would have to be made by all the banks daily assuming that each day depositors of each bank receive checks on the other nineteen banks?

7. If there are twenty banks in a town and no clearing-house, how many collections would all the banks have to make daily, assuming that each day depositors of each bank receive checks from the other nineteen banks?

8. Does a clearing-house enable the banks that belong to it to get along with a smaller cash reserve?

8. Does a clearinghouse allow the banks that are part of it to maintain a smaller cash reserve?

9. What element of security is furnished by clearing-houses during panics?

9. What aspect of security do clearinghouses provide during times of panic?

Chapter 49. Taxation and Its Relation to Value

1. Does taxation ever infringe on the right of private property?

1. Does taxation ever violate the right to private property?

2. What is it a citizen gets in return for his taxes?

2. What does a citizen get in return for their taxes?

3. Is there any relation between the taxes paid and the benefits secured from government?

3. Is there any connection between the taxes paid and the benefits received from the government?

4. A recent newspaper item says: "This is the year real estate is assessed. Turn the cow loose in the front yard, tear down the fence, make things look generally dilapidated, for it will be money in your pocket." What does this indicate regarding taxation?

4. A recent newspaper article says: "This is the year real estate is assessed. Let the cow roam free in the front yard, take down the fence, and let everything look run-down because it will save you money." What does this suggest about taxation?

5. The parts of an estate divided into fifteen equal shares by expert real estate agents were soon after assessed variously from $900 to $2850 for purposes of taxation. What does this indicate? (From Sumner's Problems.)

5. The sections of an estate divided into fifteen equal parts by expert real estate agents were soon assessed at various values from $900 to $2,850 for tax purposes. What does this indicate? (From Sumner's Problems.)

6. In what ways may we understand the proposition that taxation should be proportioned to ability?

6. How can we understand the idea that taxes should be based on someone's ability to pay?

7. Can taxation be used to secure some of the profits of large corporations?

7. Can taxes be used to capture some of the profits of big corporations?

Chapter 50. The General Theory of International Trade

1. Is it bad policy to let the people of Palo Alto spend money in San Francisco for things that could be produced at home?

1. Is it poor policy to allow the people of Palo Alto to spend money in San Francisco on things that could be made locally?

2. Pensions are defended as putting money in circulation. Is this like any tariff arguments you have heard?

2. Pensions are justified as a way to keep money flowing in the economy. Is this similar to any tariff arguments you’ve come across?

3. Is it bad policy for California to buy New England manufactures?

3. Is it a bad idea for California to buy products from New England?

4. If there were no legal bar to a tariff between the states, would a tariff probably be imposed? If so, would it be a wise measure?

4. If there weren't any legal restrictions on a tariff between the states, would a tariff likely be put in place? If it were, would it be a smart move?

5. A nation with n dollars in circulation has to pay a war indemnity of n dollars to another country having the same circulation, how much money will each then have, and what will be the effect on prices, foreign trade, rate of exchange? (From Davenport.)

5. A country with n dollars in circulation has to pay a war indemnity of n dollars to another country that has the same amount in circulation. How much money will each country have afterward, and what will be the impact on prices, foreign trade, and exchange rates? (From Davenport.)

6. If large shipments of wheat are made to England, will bills of exchange on London be higher or lower in New York?

6. If big shipments of wheat are sent to England, will the exchange rates for bills on London be higher or lower in New York?

7. What effect on exchange has the holding of American bonds abroad?

7. How does holding American bonds abroad affect exchange rates?

Chapter 51. The Protectionist Tariff

1. If all trade is exchange do not the members of a trust reduce their income when they raise the price of their products by artificial agreement?

1. If all trade is about exchange, don’t the members of a trust lower their income when they artificially agree to raise the prices of their products?

2. Is there any likeness between trade-unions and tariffs? Between tariffs and factory legislation?

2. Is there any similarity between labor unions and tariffs? Between tariffs and factory laws?

3. Can it be of advantage to trade freely with one nation if general free trade is bad?

3. Can it be beneficial to trade freely with one country if overall free trade is harmful?

4. Who gained when Hawaiian sugar (before annexation) was admitted free of duty, while other sugar was taxed?

4. Who benefited when Hawaiian sugar (before annexation) was allowed in without a duty, while other sugar was taxed?

5. If it would pay us to admit goods free, may we be justified in taxing them to force concessions from the other country?

5. If it would benefit us to allow goods in without charge, can we justify taxing them to gain concessions from the other country?

6. What have you read this year about reciprocity?

6. What have you read this year about reciprocity?

Chapter 52. Additional Social and Labor Protection Laws

1. Is granting patents an interference with trade similar to tariffs?

1. Is giving out patents an interference with trade like tariffs?

2. What reasons are given in justification of laws closing barbershops on Sundays?

2. What reasons are provided to justify the laws that close barbershops on Sundays?

3. Can a person owning a lot on a residence street of a city erect a glue-factory on it?

3. Can someone who owns a lot on a residential street in a city build a glue factory on it?

4. What have you noted as to the benefits or hardships of restricting child labor in factories?

4. What have you observed about the advantages or challenges of limiting child labor in factories?

5. Are men less able to bargain for the loan of money than for other things?

5. Are men less capable of negotiating for a loan of money than for other things?

6. Can law fix the rate of interest at any point desired? If so, then why not at zero; if not, then why fix any maximum rate of interest?

6. Can the law set the interest rate at any desired level? If it can, then why not set it to zero? If it can’t, then why set any maximum interest rate?

7. Are interest rates changing in America?

7. Are interest rates changing in the U.S.?

8. In what ways is the rate of interest affected by the rise or fall of the value of money?

8. How does the increase or decrease in the value of money impact interest rates?

Chapter 53. Public Ownership of Industry

1. What are municipal franchises? Where are they?

1. What are municipal franchises? Where can they be found?

2. What kinds of municipal industries have you seen in operation? How successful were they?

2. What types of local government industries have you observed in action? How successful were they?

3. What are the main arguments for and against the city ownership and control of gas and waterworks?

3. What are the main arguments for and against city ownership and control of gas and water services?

4. What troubles arise from city politics?

4. What issues come up because of city politics?

5. Name the industries that are owned and controlled by towns and cities of which you have a personal knowledge.

5. List the industries that are owned and managed by towns and cities that you know about personally.

6. Which of them are most satisfactory in your judgment? Which the least so?

6. Which ones do you think are the most satisfactory? Which ones are the least?

7. What is the public sentiment in your home community as to the ownership of industries by the town or city?

7. What’s the general feeling in your local community about the town or city owning industries?

8. What forms of state activity favor survival of unfit men and bad traits of character? What forms help the fittest to survive?

8. What types of government actions support the survival of unfit individuals and negative character traits? What types promote the survival of the strongest?

Note.—For exhaustive and well-arranged references on all aspects of municipal control and municipal ownership see R. C. Brooks,[Pg 593] Bibliography of Municipal Problems, pp. 157-169, in Municipal Affairs, Vol. V, No. 1 (March, 1901).

Note.—For thorough and organized references on every aspect of city management and ownership, check out R. C. Brooks, Bibliography of Municipal Problems, pp. 157-169, in Municipal Affairs, Vol. V, No. 1 (March, 1901).

Chapter 54. Railroads and Industry

1. Why is transportation a greater problem in the United States than in Europe?

1. Why is transportation a bigger issue in the United States than in Europe?

2. Show in what way natural waterways have determined the location of leading cities in America.

2. Describe how natural waterways have influenced the locations of major cities in America.

3. Give examples of cities whose growth has been caused by railroads.

3. Provide examples of cities that have grown because of railroads.

4. What interests favor and what oppose the building of an isthmian canal?

4. What interests support and what oppose the construction of an isthmian canal?

5. Mention in order of economic importance four things that would happen if all American railroads were suddenly to be destroyed.

5. List in order of economic importance four things that would happen if all American railroads were suddenly destroyed.

6. What cases have you seen where the railways impose unjustly on the public?

6. What instances have you encountered where the railways unfairly burden the public?

7. Give instances you have seen or heard of where two shippers paid different rates for the same service.

7. Provide examples you’ve seen or heard of where two shippers were charged different rates for the same service.

8. Why should preachers get half-fare rates?

8. Why should preachers receive half-price fares?

9. If your neighbor rides on a pass and you pay your fare, are you helping to pay for his ride?

9. If your neighbor uses a pass and you pay your fare, are you helping to cover the cost of their ride?

10. Do you know any large cities that are more favorable shipping-points than neighboring towns? Give reasons.

10. Are there any big cities that are better shipping hubs than the nearby towns? Explain why.

Chapter 55. The Public Nature of Railroads

1. What legal rights do the builders of a railroad have that are not enjoyed by all citizens?

1. What legal rights do railroad builders have that other citizens don’t have?

2. Can you see any clear distinction between the public nature of a railroad and of a horse and carriage?

2. Can you see any clear difference between the public aspect of a railroad and a horse and carriage?

3. What harm can there be in the acceptance of passes by judges, legislators, and other public officials?

3. What harm is there in judges, legislators, and other public officials accepting passes?

4. Ought the law prohibit the sale of tickets by "scalpers"?

4. Should the law ban the sale of tickets by "scalpers"?

5. Who has the greater political power, the president of the Pennsylvania Railroad, or the governor of that state?

5. Who has more political power, the president of the Pennsylvania Railroad or the governor of that state?

Chapter 56. Public Policy on Industry Control

1. What effect would it have if the state should make laborers work for unsuccessful employers at lower wages than for successful ones?

1. What impact would it have if the government made workers labor for failing companies at lower pay than for profitable ones?

2. Or should reduce rents for the less capable merchants and manufacturers?

2. Or should we lower rents for less capable merchants and manufacturers?

3. Is there any rule for determining the limits of state interference?

3. Is there any guideline for figuring out how far a state can interfere?

4. Why does the question of the control of the railways in the interest of the public present especial difficulties in America?

4. Why does the issue of controlling the railways for the public's benefit create particular challenges in America?

Chapter 57. Future Trends in Values

1. Make a list of the things discussed in this course that tend toward improving the average condition of men.

1. Create a list of the topics covered in this course that aim to enhance the overall well-being of people.

2. Make a list of those that tend toward worse conditions for the mass of men.

2. Create a list of those that lead to worse situations for the majority of people.

3. State what kinds of material agents will probably increase in value relative to other kinds, giving reasons.

3. Describe which types of materials are likely to increase in value compared to others, and explain why.

4. State what to your mind are three important economic problems whose answer is most uncertain, giving reasons.

4. Identify what you think are three important economic issues that have the most uncertain answers, and explain why.

5. If you had the power, what single public measure that you believe would be practicable and effective would you put on the statute books, in order to make a juster division of the social income? Give reasons.

5. If you had the power, what one public policy that you think would be feasible and effective would you implement to create a fairer distribution of social income? Explain your reasoning.

Note.—On the subject of this chapter, see Devine, Economics, ch. XVII (disposition of the social surplus); Jenks, The Trust Problem, pp. 190-211; Marshall, Bk. VI, chs. XI and XII.

Note.—For more information on this chapter, see Devine, Economics, ch. XVII (distribution of the social surplus); Jenks, The Trust Problem, pp. 190-211; Marshall, Bk. VI, chs. XI and XII.


INDEX

[Pg 597] Ability, variety, 177-83;
physical differences, 178;
intelligence, 179;
training, 180;
moral qualities, 180;
inequality, 181;
scarcity, 182;
and occupation, 203;
grades, 212;
types, 264;
selection, 270-2;
sterilization, 561-2

Abstinence, definition, kinds, 163;
see Saving

Acquisition vs. social production, 259

Affection in personal distribution, 402

Agricultural classes, opposition to commercial, 113

Agricultural stage, 261

Agriculture, machinery in, 238

Alternative uses, relation to costs, 277

America, farms let on shares, 59;
land changes hands, 60;
exhaustion of the lands, 82;
use of interchangeable parts, 85;
destruction of forests, 87;
coal deposits, 88-9;
improvement of horses, 91;
watch-factory, 92;
price of horses in Boer War, 95;
discovery of mines, 102;
varied industrial conditions, 108;
use of money, 109;
expression of wealth, 114;
land became part of world's supply, 155;
standard of living, 192;
size of families, 193;
food supply, 194;
increase of population, 194;
army rations, 196;
standard of food, 196;
caste, 199;
democracy and efficiency, 200;
wage system dominant, 227;
wages, 232;
changing occupations, 234;
favorable effect of machinery, 242;
difference of race among workers, 247;
industrial superiority, 262;
Oriental competition, 263;
fortunes, 271;
profit-sharing, 283;
producers' coöperation, 296;
consumers' coöperation, 300;
industrial stage, 313;
crises, 352;
gifts by wealthy men, 368;
law of inheritance, 373;
fortunes, 375;
dress of workers, 397;
colonial policy toward, 425, 426;
custom, 426;
gold standard, 432;
silver supplies from, 441;
gold supplies, 442;
paper money, 448-9;
effect of silver supplies from, 454, 457;
effect of gold output, 457;
banks, 468-70;
discussion of taxation, 479;
prices in California, 483;
in different sections, 484;
protective tariff, 491-503;
growth of manufactures, 497;
factory laws, 509-12;
state enterprise, 514-17;
early settlement on the coast, 526;
trade in War of 1812, 526;
canals, 528;
railroad building, 529;
aid to railroads, 535

American Federation of Labor, 245;
claims of, 254

American Revolution, economic issues in, 8

Animal economy, provision for wants, 40

Animals, problem of numbers, 185-6

Antisocial profits, 289;
of monopoly, 311;
from speculation, 377;
antisocial use of ability, 378

Appropriation stage, 261

Ashley, W. J., 575

Assignats, 448

Attribution of product, 176

Austrian economists, 570

Authoritative distribution, 406-8;
[Pg 598]use of, 410-11


Balance of trade, international, 486-7;
so-called favorable, 493

Bank-notes, and paper money compared, 447;
typical, 465-8;
in United States, 469

Banks, and credit, 462-70;
functions, 462-5;
in United States, 468-70

Barter, definition, 31;
under simple conditions, 32-5;
difficulty of, 99;
decline, 108-14;
economy in Middle Ages, 110

Bequest, limitation of right, 368

Bets, see Gambling

Bimetallism, international, 457-9;
national, 459-61

Biologic doctrine of population, 186, 187

Biology, shows inequality of talents, 181

Birth-rate, of animals, 187;
decreasing American, 193, 561

Böhm-Bawerk, E. von, 570, 571, 572, 577, 580, 583

Boycott, 251

Brooks, R. C., 593

Building laws, 505

Bullock, C. J., 568

Buyers, bidding, 34;
margin of advantage, 35


Canadian bank-notes, 468, 470

Canals, as carriers, 528-9

Cannan, Edwin, 571, 573

Capital, origin of term, 112;
concept in modern business, 114-7;
definition, 115;
not identical with money, 115;
purpose of borrowing, 116;
sum, expressed in years' purchase, 121;
sum of expected rents, 122;
value not primary, 123;
stock, 127;
value of stocks fluctuate, 134;
time-value and, 142;
fixed and increasable forms, 152-3;
use by enterprisers, 285;
insured by enterprisers, 286;
in coöperation, 295;
large, 312;
amount in factories, 315;
value affected by protection, 501

Capitalistic, age, 114, 117;
monopoly, 306

Capitalization, of all forms of rent, 118-30;
rent-charges as an example of, 118;
of land rents, 124;
of uniform or varying series of rents, 125-6;
increasing role, 127;
of any continuing income, 128;
of franchises, 129;
of corporate incomes, 130;
rate, 147;
and interest, 168;
influenced by taxation, 475

Capitalization, theory of crises, 353-4

Carlyle, T., on wage, 229

Carnegie, Andrew, 268, 270, 372, 377;
economies of gifts to libraries, 387, 390

Carver, T. N., 578

Cassel, 578

Caste, and efficiency, 199

Chance, unavoidable, 333;
average in industry, 334;
artificial, 334;
legitimate and illegitimate, 335

Character, affected by expenditure, 398;
highest point of production, 400;
unity of choice determining, 401

Charitable distribution, 405-6

Charity, public, 507

Cheating and gambling, 335

Child-labor legislation, 509

Choice, of goods, harmony in, 400

Cities, wealth of, contrasted with feudal estates, 111, 113;
growth, 504;
large, on waterways, 528

City ownership, 514-5;
see Public ownership

Clark, J. B., 398;
theory of profits and wages, 418, 573, 575, 584

Clews, Henry, on Wall Street finance, 378

Climate, and income, 48

Closed shop, 249-50

Clothing and efficiency, 196;
effect of choice of, 396

Coal, use and exhaustion, 88, 558;
strike of 1902, 251, 252

Coinage, 433-6;
definition, 433;
free or gratuitous, 434-6;
token, 443-7;
free and gratuitous, 443

Coins, light-weight, 443-7

Collective bargaining, 248

Collective enjoyment, as a mode of distribution, 408

[Pg 599]Collectivism, 552

Combination and wages, 253-6;
of the factors, 260;
opposes competition, 429;
of capital, see Trusts

Comforts, relative meaning, 11;
and luxury, 388

Commercial monopoly, 306

Commercial paper, discounting of, 132

Commissions, to control railroads; 541-3;
to control corporations, 545

Commodity-money theory, 450

Common denominator of values, see Money

Commons, J. R., 573

Communism, among Germanic tribes, questioned, 365

Comparative costs, doctrine of, 482-3

Competition, definition, 33;
one-sided, 33;
present limitations on, 228;
the worker in, 229;
reduced by trade-unions, 248-50;
costly in mercantile business, 298;
free, not equality of efficiency, 303;
alleged cause of trusts, 322;
persistence of, 331;
and state action, 422-30;
and custom, 422-5;
economic harmony through, 425-8;
social limiting of, 428-30;
modern restrictions, 504

Competitive distribution, 409-10

Competitive price, forces governing, 308

Complementary agents, and value, 78;
intensive use of, 78;
labor and wealth, 175

Compulsory distribution, 404

Conquest theory of property, 363

Consolidation of railroads, 539-40

Consumers, determining costs, 280;
gain from trusts, 325

Consumers', choice influences value, 392;
choice influences wages, 394;
coöperation, 298-301;
League, 394

Consumption, reaction upon production, 392-401;
definition of economic, 392;
reaction upon material agents, 392-5;
reaction upon efficiency of workers, 395-410;
effects on consumer, 398;
as a conventional division of political economy, 419

Consumption, tax on, 475

Consumption goods, definition, 20;
immediately enjoyable, 21;
a part of income, 41;
differential advantages, 73-5;
diagram, grades by quality, 75;
proposed uses, 161;
saved, 166;
see Goods

Continental notes, 448

Contracting out, forbidden, 512

Contract interest, see Interest

Contract rent, see Rent

Contract wages, see Wages

Coöperation, producers', 295-7;
consumers', 298-301

Corporation, securities, 127-8;
public-service, 129;
increase of, 133

Cost, involved in improvements, 90;
of operation, 168;
in larger production, 319;
of government, 474;
see Comparative costs

Cost of production, 273-81;
from the enterpriser's point of view, 273-6;
psychic, 273;
alternative, 274;
money, 274;
and price 276;
from the economist's standpoint, 276-81, 422

Courts and industrial legislation, 543, 550-1

Credit, sales involve interest, 134;
and banking, 462-70

Crises and industrial depressions, 345-55;
caused by sudden tariff changes, 502-3

Crusoe economy, subjective valuations, 30;
time-value, 131, 140;
saving, 166;
economic wages, 208;
present and future goods, 219-20;
need of judgment, 265

Cultivation, margin of, 64;
see Utilization

Custom, and rents, 56;
and efficiency, 199, 200;
affecting distribution, 409;
and competition, 422-5, 429


Daniels, Winthrop M., 571

[Pg 600]Davenport, Herbert J., 567

Death-rate, decreasing, 192

Debts, public, as investments, 133

Deferred payments, standard of, 453-61;
definition, 453;
ideals for a standard, 455-7

Demand, definition, 27;
social aspect of choice, 28;
law of, 28;
curve, 29;
elasticity, 29;
reciprocal, becomes exchange, 30;
curve, diagram, 35

Democracy, and efficiency, 199;
effect on race progress, 561, 563

Deposit and discount, 462

Depreciation and rent, 85-7

Desire, see Wants

Destruction, and rent, of wealth, 87-9;
accidental, of wealth, 381-2;
intentional, 382-3

Devine, Edward T., 587, 594

Dewey, Davis R., 568

Differential advantages, in consumption goods, 73-5;
in indirect goods, 75-80

Diminishing returns, law, 61-72;
definition, 61;
of all agents, 62;
technical, 62;
economic, 63;
other meanings of term, 66-9;
general application to space relations, 67-8;
confused with large production, 68;
technical, 68;
historical, 68;
development of the concept, 69-72;
applies to all wealth, 70;
and population, 184;
and productivity of labor, 215;
the broadest principle of value, 420

Diminishing utility, law, 22;
diagram, 24;
relation to diminishing returns, 71

Directors, of railroads, obligations of, 539

Discount, commercial, 132, 135

Discovery enlarges natural resources, 156

Discrimination in rates, by monopoly, 310;
in railroad rates, 530-3

Distribution, personal and functional, 359;
impersonal, 360;
personal, nature of, 402-3;
definition, 402;
of the social income, 402-11;
methods of, 404-11;
as a conventional division of political economy, 419

Dividends, manipulation of, 130

Division of labor, 201-4;
definition, 201;
kinds, 201;
advantages, 202;
calls for directive ability, 264;
growth of territorial, 480-2

Dollar, meaning of, 435

Drink, effect of, 396

Durable agents, see Goods

Durableness of rented agents, 55


Economic goods, definition of, 19;
see Goods

Economic harmony, through competition, 425-8;
definition, 427

Economic law, nature of, 206

Economic monopoly, 306

Economic motives, see Wants

Economic production, 258;
see Production

Economic rent, see Rent

Economic wages, see Wages

Economics, nature and purpose 3-8;
definition, 3, 4;
subject matter, 4;
place among social sciences, 5, 6;
as a science, 7;
synonym for political economy, 7;
democratic in aim, 8;
importance, 8;
aim of study, 412;
a part only of social science, 413;
central point of, 413;
redefined, 555;
relation to practical life, 555

Economy, involves choice, 27;
the barter, 108;
the money, 108-14

Education, free public, 507

Efficiency, talent, and training as factors in, 180;
resultant of many qualities, 181;
of labor, 195-204;
equality of, not essential to competition, 423;
see Ability

Ely, Richard T., 568, 584

Emery, Henry C., 585

Employer, adjusts labor to interest rate, 220;
see Enterpriser

Employment, no lack of, 183

Energy, sources of, and income, 50

Engels, Frederick, 416

England, idea of rent in, 59;
long leases, 59;
food supply during Napoleonic wars, 69;
coal deposits, 89;
wages, 232;
[Pg 601]changes in 18th century, 237;
loans, 240;
abnormal effect of machinery, 241;
coöperation, 296, 299;
use of term monopoly, 304;
cotton crisis, 345;
crises, 348;
endowments limited, 368;
grants to royal families, 373;
gold standard, 432;
prices in Napoleonic wars, 442;
bank restriction act, 448-9;
balance of imports, 493;
discussion of protection, 496

Enjoyable goods, see Consumption goods

Enterprise, income, and social service, 376-7

Enterpriser, function of, 265-72;
qualities of, 267-70;
selection of, 270-2;
his task, 273-5;
his costs, 275;
medium for consumers' estimates, 280;
profits of, 283;
origin of term, 284;
his services reviewed, 285-8;
his risk, 287;
intermediary in industry, 287;
lacking in coöperation, 297;
relation to profit-sharing and coöperation, 300;
as risk-taker, 338

Environment, betterment, 92, 162

Ethics, definition, 6;
and economics of time-value, 144;
of consumption, 395, 398, 401;
of railroad problem, 532, 539;
see Morality

Europe, industrial methods of, 262

Exchange, in a market, 30-8;
and demand, 30, 31;
advantage, 31;
isolated, 32;
of present and future goods, 145-9;
as a conventional division of political economy, 419;
foreign and domestic, of money, 463;
international, see International trade

Extensive margin of indirect goods, 78-9;
see Utilization

Extravagance to give employment, 386


Factors, definition, 260;
combination of, 260-4;
cost of, 274;
proportioning of, 275;
mutual employment of, 420

Factory, system, growth and effect, 243-4;
change in number, 314;
limits to growth, 319;
legislation, 509-13

Farmers and the tariff, 498-9

Fauna and income, 49

Feeling and utility, 26

Fiat-money theory, 450-1

Fisher, Irving, 571, 575

Fixed charges, 168

Flora and income, 49

Food, and income, 50;
and efficiency, 196;
effect of, 396;
laws and inspection of goods, 506

Foreign exchanges, theory of, 485-8

Forestry, need of, 88

Forests, destruction of, 87-8

Franchises, for public utilities, 96;
capitalizing of, 129;
granting monopolies, 522

Free competition, see Competition

Free coinage, money value, 435

Freedom, economic, 422-30;
definition, 422

Free goods, definition, 19;
on the margin of utilization, 75

Free-silver movement in America, 459-61

Free trade, see International trade

Future rents capitalized, 125


Gambling vs. insurance, 333-8;
definition of typical, 334;
economic theory of 336

George, Henry, his theory of value, 417

Gibson, A. H., 577

Gilman, N. P., on profit-sharing, 293

Glut theory of crises, 351-2

Gold, fitness as money, 102;
as money, 432-3;
supply of, 435;
discoveries, 442;
as a standard, 455, 457;
increased output, 461;
shipping point, 485

Goods, definition, 19;
adjustment to wants, 21;
shifting series, 27;
substitution, 27;
series of, 39;
relation of indirect to gratification, 46;
enjoyable, 47;
durable, 47;
unripened, 47;
[Pg 602]degrees of durableness, 48;
limited number, 52;
free and unlimited, 152

Government, a condition of efficient labor, 198;
as consumptive good and productive agent, 473;
paper money, see Paper money

Granger stores, 300

Gratification, defined, 16;
and marginal utility, 22;
temporary, 39;
at different times, 45;
time-value of, 141, 143

Greenbacks, 448, 451

Gresham's law, 446-7


Hadley, A. T., 579, 580

Happiness, and wealth, 18;
and ostentation, 388;
and character, 401

Hildebrand, 575

Historical diminishing returns, 68;
confused with technical, 70;
see Diminishing returns

Home-market argument for protection, 498-9

Honesty, a condition of efficiency, 198;
of public officials, 551

Household industry in America, 313


Immigration and protection, 498

Improvements to increase products, 90

Incidence of taxation, 476

Income, as a flow of goods, 39-42;
national, social, individual, private, objective, money, 40;
gross, net, 41;
of consumption goods, 41;
present, future, 41;
funded, unfunded, 42;
as a series of gratifications, 43;
psychic, 43-5;
all sources of, are productive, 43;
affected by objective conditions, 48-52;
affected by increasing capital, 152;
and social service, 370-80;
from property, 370-6;
from personal services, 376-80;
justice of large, 389-91;
distribution of the social, 402-11;
and taxation, 474-7;
affected by crises, 354-5;
personal and impersonal shares, 359-62;
personal, 361;
complex sources of psychic, 403

Increasable agents, 153-5;
scale of increasableness, 158

Increase, of product, 90;
of agents, 92, 95;
of rent-bearer affects others, 93

Indestructibility imputed to rented agents, 55

Indirect goods, see Goods

Individualism, extreme, its ideal of competition, 410

Industrial depressions, definition, 346

Industrial revolution caused by machinery, 237

Industrial stage, 261

Industry, changes in, affecting money, 101;
money reacts upon, 102;
diversity of condition in America, 108;
changes in Europe, 109;
growing complexity as interest falls, 168

Infant-industry argument for protection, 497

Inheritance, effect on industry, 12;
social effects, 369-73

Insurance, origin, 337;
economic theory of, 338;
sound conditions in, 338

Integration of industry, 321

Intensive margin, see Utilization

Interest, opposition to, in Middle Ages, 112;
the modern contract forms for borrowing wealth, 114;
contract and rent contract, 116;
on loans contrasted with rent-charges, 120;
increased use of, 121;
permitted by Rome, 122;
two modes of approach, 123;
"the prevailing rate" and capitalization, 124;
on money loans, 131-7;
gross and net, 132;
in credit sales, 134;
concealed, 135;
evasion of legal rate, 135;
adjustment of business to the rate, 140;
rate of contract, 147-8;
in sacrifice sale, 149;
and time-value, 150;
relation to rent, 150;
[Pg 603]first use of term, 151;
rate divides present and future uses, 159;
and future goods, diagram, 160;
equalizer of time-values, 162;
rate of, and saving, 165;
and capitalization, 168;
and improvements, 168;
rate relates present and future, 220;
contract, with enterpriser, 285;
conventional conception of, 413;
contract, and deferred payments, 454

Intermediate products and costs, 279

Internal revenue, 475

International demand, ratio of, 484-5

International trade, general theory of, 480-90;
as a case of exchange, 480-5;
definition, 480;
equation of international exchange, definition, 483;
cash balance of, 486;
real benefits of, 488-90

Interstate Commerce Act, discussion of, 537, 542;
workings of, 543;
importance of, 545

Inventions, affect rent, 85-6;
to increase rent-bearers, 91;
adds to supply, 156

Investment, and rate of interest, 148;
and saving, 165;
in stock of corporation, 342

Ireland, tenants' improvements in, 59

Iron law of wages, 216


Jenks, J. W., on trusts, 327, 584, 594

Jevons, W. S., on the coal-supply, 88

Johnson, A. S., 572

Justice in taxation, 477

Just price, 547


Keasbey, L. M., 576

Knights of Labor, 245


Labor, the old distinction between productive and unproductive, 43, 260;
and classes of laborers, 173-83;
definition, 173;
and play, 173;
pleasurable, 174;
and wealth, 175;
direct and indirect services, 176;
grades of, 177;
scarcity, 182;
supply of, 184-194;
employer's and social view, 184;
conditions for efficient, 195-204;
objective physical conditions, 195-8;
social conditions, 198-201;
division of, 201-4;
of different grades, 212;
relation to value, 215-25;
productivity of, 215;
distance from gratification, 219;
no unit of, 224;
value of product insured by enterpriser, 286;
economized in large production, 318;
legislation, 509-13

Labor theory of property, 364

Laissez faire, ideal of, 518

Land, rented in Middle Ages, 57, 110;
and diminishing returns, 69, 70;
and repairs, 81-2;
continues to be rented, 113;
products of increasing cost, 154;
relatively fixed in quantity, 154-5;
economic supply of, 155-6;
produced, 157;
not monopoly, 303

Land grants, to railroads, 535

Large industry, social effects of, 244;
in United States, 312-7;
advantages of, 318-20;
economics of combination, 321

Large production, confused with diminishing returns, 68;
sharing of the economics of, 325

Lasalle, Ferdinand, 416

Latin Union, 458

Law, definition, 6;
nature of economic, 206;
in relation to wealth, 361

Legislation and local interests, 549

Liberty of wage-worker, 231

Lloyd, Henry D., on coöperation, 296

Legal theory of property, 364

Legal-tender, quality of paper money, 447

Loans, short-time, 132, 137;
long-time, 133, 138

[Pg 604]Luck and profits, 289

Lump of labor, error of notion, 240

Luxury, relative meaning, 11; 385-91;
definition, 385;
fallacy of, 386-7


Machinery, need of repairs, 83-4;
and natural resources, 91;
definition, 236;
and labor, 236-44;
extent of use, 236-8;
age of, 237;
effect on wages, 239-44;
evils of sudden introduction, 239;
economy in large production, 318

Malthus, Robert, on fixity of land, 154;
on population, 579

Malthusian doctrine, 578

Manual workers, social service of, 379

Manufactures, fallacious contrast with agriculture, 67;
do not fix interest rate, 124-5;
machinery in, 283

Marx Karl, 416, 417

Marginal contribution of labor, 213

Marginal labor, 210

Marginal pair, 34;
diagram, 35

Marginal utility, definition, 23-7;
in barter, 32;
in use of goods, 64;
of consumption goods, 75;
of indirect goods, 78-9;
of wages, 211, 213;
fixes cost of factors, 277;
applied to gambling, 336-7;
in insurance, 338;
of income, 399;
extension of the principle, 420-1

Margin of advantage, 34;
diagram, 35

Markets, definition, 36;
exchange in, 36-8;
widening, 36-7;
growth, 263

Market value, built on subjective valuation, 35, 38;
of time, 145

Marriage, postponement, 190

Marshall, Alfred, 573, 574, 583, 594

Material resources, relation to efficiency, 195

Material wants as motives, 9

Medium of exchange, see Money

Merchants impart utility, 31

Middle Ages, markets, 36;
customary rents, 56;
renting contract, 57-9;
limited use of money, 109-13;
rent-charges, 118-22;
use of term interest, 151;
death-rate, 192;
caste, 199;
system of labor, 227;
industrial changes, 237;
marine insurance, 337;
no crises, 348;
favored classes, 373;
sumptuary laws, 390;
custom, 424;
competition, 425;
prices, 441;
depreciation of money, 444-5;
small political units in, 481;
control of industry in, 553

Mill, John Stuart, on fixity of land, 155;
on coöperation, 296, 361, 368, 398, 417, 572

Money, as a tool in exchange, 98-107;
origin, 98-103;
nature of use, 103-5;
value, 105-10;
as medium of exchange, 99;
qualities, 100;
materials, 101;
an indirect agent, 103;
as common denominator, 104;
as storehouse of saving, 105;
commodities with monetary use, 106;
general use of, 107;
defined, 107, 431-2;
and the concept of capital, 108-17;
use in various countries, 109;
increasing use in medieval cities, 111;
not identical with capital, 115;
time-value and, 142;
form taken by saving, 167;
movement of, before a crisis, 346;
use, coinage, and value, 431-42;
the precious metals as, 431-6;
quantity theory of, 436-42;
standard, or primary, 432;
fundamental use, 436;
average demand for, 437;
effect of changes in supply, 454, 457, 459;
territorial distribution, 487-8;
and foreign trade, 484

Money-changing, 463

Money market, for short-time loans, 137;
for productive loans, 139

Money theories of crises, 352-3

Monopoly, of labor, 253;
profits, 302-11;
nature of, 302-5;
definition, 304;
kinds of, 305-8;
test of, 308;
price fixed by, 308-11;
meaning, 312;
and supply, 324;
[Pg 605]profits, social burden, 326;
in protective tariff, 500-1;
in localized public utilities, 519-21;
public gain from, 522;
power of the railroad, 530, 533

Moral qualities in industry, 180

Morality, as motive, 13-14;
of luxury, 389;
opposes competition, 429

Mortgages, nature of security, 133

Motives, economic, 9-14;
see Wants


Nail trust, 329

Natural economy, 110

Natural law, philosophy of, 426

Natural resources, and income, 49;
exhaustion of, 89, 558;
adapted and improved, 90;
machinery an adaption of, 91;
development of, 560;
see Land

Natural-rights theory of property, 364

National ownership, 516-7;
see Public ownership

Necessities, relative meaning, 11

Negro, simple wants, 11;
caste sentiment regarding, 199;
working hours, 201

Normal price, 37


Occupation and talent, 203

Occupation theory of property, 363

Oil trust, 328

Open shop, 249-50

Organization, of workers, need of, 246;
required for efficiency, 262;
and the enterpriser's function, 265-72

Orthodox economists, 415, 416;
predictions of, 557

Over-production theory of crises, 351

Ownership, forms of, 363


Paper money, bank-notes as political, 466;
experiments, 447-9;
definition, 447;
theories of, 450-2

Par of exchange, definition, 485, 486

Pastoral stage, 261

Patten, S. N., 586

Permanent possession, 53;
see Capitalization, Property

Personal distribution, see Distribution

Physiocratic school, 415

Political corruption and industrial legislation, 550

Political economy, see Economics

Political money, see Paper money

Political monopoly, 305

Political security, and saving, 163;
a condition of efficiency, 198

Politics, definition, 6;
and the tariff, 503;
influence of railroads in, 538

Population, growth in Europe in 18th century, 69;
doctrine of, 184-7;
related to resources, 184;
animal stage of problem, 185;
human population, 186;
in human society, 187-90;
excess, 188;
control, 188;
current aspect of, 191-4;
resultant of many forces, 191;
growth not fatalistic, 191;
quality, 193, 561, 562;
increase in the 19th century, 194

Present and future, wants, 44;
rents, 125;
goods, 145;
competing for labor, 220-21

Price, definition, 36;
market and normal, 37;
under competition, 308;
under monopoly, 309-310;
of trusts affected by competition, 331;
a social fact, 360;
changes, see Money

Primitive society, war in, 188;
custom in, 424

Private property, and saving, 164;
and monopoly, 306;
and inheritance, 359-69;
origin, 362-6;
limitations, 367-9;
vs. socialism, 376

Producers injured by trusts, 330

Producers' coöperation, 295-7;
definition, 295

Production, and rate of interest, 166-9;
agents of, 175;
two sources of economic, 222;
and the combination of the factors, 257-64;
nature of, 257;
economic and personal, 258;
[Pg 606]social, 259;
vs. welfare, 398;
unity of process, 418;
as a conventional division of political economy, 419;
by transportation, 525

Productive goods, definition, 20;
affect output of labor, 195

Productive and unproductive industries, 260

Productive labor, see Labor

Profits, unearned, by some directors, 130;
on purchase of capital, 138;
margin of, 275;
loss of, 282-91;
definition, 282, 291;
meaning of terms, 282-5;
a species of economic wages, 284;
fluctuation of, 288;
statement of law, 289;
pseudo, 289;
chance, 289-90;
conditioned on skill, 290;
risk theory of, 291;
to promoters of trusts, 322;
of promoter, 342;
of trustee, 343;
before and after a crisis, 347;
relation to wages, 415;
Clark's theory, 418;
in foreign trade, 495

Profit-sharing, 292-5;
definition, 292

Progress, of the masses, 232;
cause of, 232-3;
must grow out of wage system, 234;
marked by control over nature, 261;
stimulated by luxury, 388;
and refinement of desire, 399;
by wise method of distribution, 411;
due to temporary conditions, 558;
social vs. racial, 560;
depends on race quality, 561;
depends on competition, 562;
endangered by status and envy, 563

Promoter, services of, 342;
profits, 342-3

Property, private, effect on industry, 12;
effect on population, 189, 190;
and wealth, 361-2;
definition, 362;
and social expediency, 370;
in land, 374;
defense of, 374-5;
see Private property

Property tax, 475

Protective social and labor legislation, 504-13

Protective tariff, claimed to be socially expedient, 374, 491-503;
definition, 491;
nature and claims of protection, 491-6;
measure of justification in, 496-501;
values as affected by, 501-3;
compared with other social legislation, 512

Psychic income, 39-45;
complex sources of, 403;
see Income

Psychology of crises, 354

Public control of industry, examples, 544-8;
difficulties, 548-51

Public interests, limiting private property, 367;
paramount in social legislation, 505-9

Public officers, interested in corporations, 343

Public ownership of industry, 514-24;
examples of, 514-7;
economic aspects of, 517-24

Public policy as to control of industry, see Public control

Public utilities, increase of rents from, 96

Public wants, development of, 472

Publicity of corporation management, 546-7


Quantity theory of money, 436-42;
definition, 438;
objections to, 439-41


Railroad, need of repairs, 83;
and industry, 525-33;
as a carrier, 527-30;
economic vs. technical efficiency, 527;
public nature of, 534-43;
privileges of, 534-8;
obligations of, 536-8;
political and economic power of, 538-40;
commissions to control, 541-3

Railroad rates, discrimination in, 530-3;
similarity to taxes, 538

Rank of goods, technical, 46

Rapp, George, 266

Real wages, definition, 207;
raised by machinery, 242

Recreation, influence on efficiency, 397

Religion, as economic motive, 13-14;
[Pg 607]opposes competition, 429

Remuneration, profit-sharing as a method, 295;
methods of, see Wages

Rent, the renting contract, 53-60;
origin of term, 53;
several meanings, 54;
essence, 55;
as usufruct, 55;
imputed durableness of rented agents, 55;
gross and net, 55;
economic and contract, 56-7;
history of contract, 56-60;
rent charge, 58;
economic rent wider than renting contract, 60;
connection with gratification, 73;
varies with quality, 75;
with quantity, diagram, 77;
limits of, 79;
economic and contract, 79-80;
of wealth, affected by repair, depreciation, and destruction, 81-9;
changes in, 90-7;
of money, 106;
basis of capitalization, 122-4;
discounted, 123;
relation to time-discount, 150-1;
and wages, mutually influence, 175;
"of ability," 178;
and wages, 205;
"of labor," 205;
relation to wages, 215-8, 221;
as personal or impersonal income, 359;
conventional conception of, 413;
as usufruct, 414;
in Middle Ages, 424

Rent-bearers and rents, 90-7

Rent-charges, 58;
sale and purchase, 118-22

Renting contract, 53-60;
definition, 57;
in the Middle Ages, 57;
narrow use, 58, 59, 60;
and economic rent, 60;
hindered improvements, 110;
contrasted with interest contract, 116

Repairs, and rent, 81-84;
do not prevent decay, 85;
and time-value, 143

Replenishing agents, 154

Rhodes, Cecil, 372

Ricardo, David, on fixity of land, 155;
labor theory of value, 224, 398, 417, 442, 574

Ripley, W. Z., 575

Risk by enterpriser, 287

Risk theory of profits, 291

Risk-taking, legitimate and illegitimate, 335

Roosevelt, Theodore, efforts to control corporations, 546

Rossignol, J. E. le, 584

Roundabout process, 46, 576


Sage, Russell, on great corporations, 377

Satisfaction, see Gratification

Saturation point for coinage, 443

Saving, and rate of interest, 159-63;
conditions favorable to, 163-6;
influence on methods of production, 166-9;
benefits, 169;
future effect of, 560

Scarcity, basis of economy, 19;
effect on utility, 73;
of various goods, 76;
of present goods, 146;
of common materials, 153;
of all economic goods, 153;
of human services, 182;
of labor, 207, 225;
not synonymous with monopoly, 302

Seager, H. R., 568

Seigniorage, definition, 434;
and value, 443-7

Self-interest, social effects of, 427

Sellers' margin of advantage, 35

Serfdom, conditions, 227;
see Middle Ages

Services, a condition of income, 207;
and wages, 210, 213;
social and individual estimates of, 379;
see Labor

Shifting of taxes, 476

Silver, fitness as money, 102;
as money, 432-3;
as a standard, 455

Single-tax, purpose, 374;
theory of value, 417

Skill, condition of continuing profits, 290;
of labor, see Ability

Slavery, as a system of labor, 227

Smart, 570, 571, 583

Smith, Adam, on money, 103, 181, 182;
his "Wealth of Nations," 425-6, 484, 557

Social amelioration, various kinds, 504-9

Social changes, and rents, 94;
temporary, 95

[Pg 608]Social classes, volitional control in, 190

Social control, progress of, 551-4;
see Public control

Social effects of a tariff, 498

Social-expediency theory of property, 365-6;
basis of private property, 370;
of inheritance, 370-3;
of class legislation, 373;
of protective tariffs, 374;
of rewarding talent, 378;
in taxation, 478

Social institutions and personal incomes, 360

Social legislation, growing need, 197, 504

Social sciences, nature, 5;
complexity, 5, 6

Socialism, extreme, its ideal of distribution, 410;
radical, vs. social reform, 552

Socialistic theory of value, 416

Socialists, predictions of, 553

Social prophecy, 553

Social regulation of bank-notes, 467, 470

Social service and income, 370-80

Specialization, and size of market, 263;
of risk-taking, 339-40

Speculation, in goods, 336;
as risk-taking, 338-42;
in all business, 339;
as insurance, 340;
by lambs, 341;
legitimate and illegitimate, 344;
income from, 376-7

Spencer, Herbert, 518

Spiritual needs as economic motives, 13-4

Stages of industry, 313

Standard of deferred payments, see Deferred payments

Standard of living, definition, 191;
Asiatic, 191;
American, 192;
theory of wages, 216;
result of sudden change in, 387-8;
change in 19th century, 557

State, function to direct competition, 429-30;
function of the, 471-3;
regulates railroads, 541-2;
regulates corporate industry, 544-8;
increasing functions, 548

State ownership, 515-6;
see Public ownership

State socialism, growth of, 551-2

Status, as method of distribution, 409

Storehouse of saving, see Money

Strength of men and women, 179

Strikes, 251;
violence, 252;
cost, 252

Subsidiary coinage, 445-6

Subsistence theory of wages, 217

Sugar trust, 328

Sumner, W. G., 567

Supply, relation to utility, 24-6;
curve, diagram, 35;
of land in economic sense, 155;
limitation of better qualities, 158;
of labor, 184;
and monopoly, 324;
and trust prices, 331

Sympathy, as an economic force, 13, 235


Talent and occupation, 203;
see Ability

Tariff for revenue, 491;
see Protective tariff

Taussig, F. W., 580

Taxation, in its relation to value, 471-9;
definition, 471;
purposes of, 471-4;
forms of, 474-7;
principles and practice, 477-9

Taxes, as a mode of distribution, 407

Technical diminishing returns, 68;
confused with historical, 70;
refers to limited time, 71

Technical rank of goods, 46

Temperance legislation, 507

Temporary use, 53;
see Rent

Tenement-house laws, 505

Time, in relation to wants, 44;
relation to gratification, 161

Time-discount, of future rents, 125-6;
rate fixed in practice, 126

Time relations of goods to wants, 46

Time-value, and interest, 131;
theory of, 141-51;
definition and scope, 141-5;
fixing of rate, 145-51;
and rate of interest, 159-50;
relation to wages, 219-22;
the highest problem of value, 414

[Pg 609]Tin-plate trust, 329

Token coins, 445-6

Trade-unions, 245-56;
objects, 245-8;
methods, 248-53;
claims of, 254;
effects, on wages, 253-6;
and profit-sharing, 294;
monopoly of labor, 308

Transportation, as a form of production, 525;
changes in 19th century, 529-30

Trant, book on trade-unions, 254-5

Trustee, speculating, 343

Trusts, in United States, growth of, 312-22;
recent organization of, 315-7;
economic possibilities of consolidation, 321;
causes of, 320-2;
in legal and popular sense, 320;
effect on prices, 323-32;
control of, 332


Under-consumption theory of crises, 351

Unearned increments, various kinds, 96

Unions, see Trade-unions

United States, see America

Unproductive labor, see Labor

Unripe goods, see Goods

Usufruct, see Rent

Usury, in Middle Ages, 113;
usury laws, 508

Utility, broad sense, 19;
see Marginal utility

Utilization, intensive margin, 64;
extensive, 65;
diagram, 65;
equilibrium of two margins, 66;
of indirect goods, 78-9


Value, definition, 20;
relation of labor to, 222-5;
characteristics of, 258;
cost of production explanation, 277;
genealogy of, (diagram) 278-80;
law of, and monopoly price, 311;
law of, and trusts, 323;
survey of the theory, 412;
the unit of, 413;
stages of value, 414;
various aspects, 419;
generality of the law, 420;
effect of taxation on, 475-7;
future trend of, 555-63

Value theories, relation to social reforms, 415-8

Volitional control, of population, 188, 189, 191, 193, 561


Wage contract, terms of, 229

Wage-fund theory of wages, 217

Wages, related to scarcity, 182;
and efficiency, 196;
law of, 205-14;
nature of, 205-8;
and rent, 205;
economic and contract, 206;
real and nominal, 207;
modes of earning, 208-11;
methods of remuneration, 211;
and the general law of value, 211-4;
term "general rate," 211;
differences in, 212;
statement of law, 213;
and rent, 215-8;
and time-value, 219-22;
law of wages, 215;
iron law, 216;
and ambition, 230;
rise of money form of, 232;
real, changes in, 232;
more better-paid callings, 233;
raised by machinery, 242;
in general industry determined by impersonal economic forces, 255;
and profits, 284;
and profit-sharing, 295;
as personal or impersonal income, 359;
influenced by consumers' choice, 394;
relation to profits, 415;
and protective tariff, 495;
laws regulating payment, 511

Wages system, and its result, 226-35;
defined, 226;
development, 227;
as it is, 229-31;
progress under, 232-5;
gloomy view of, 233

Walker, Francis A., theory of wages, 417, 578

Wants, material, 9-12;
non-material, 13-4;
of animals, 9;
primitive, 10;
civilized, 10;
and progress, 11;
growth, 12;
refinement, 12;
complex, 14;
dependence on things, 15;
relation to goods, 16;
kinds, 21;
changing, 26;
recurrence, 39;
in series, 39;
present and future, 44;
see Consumption

War, to remedy over-population, 188;
affects productive agents, 394

Waste, and luxury, 381-91;
of wealth, 381-5;
individual, 384;
in public outlay, 384-5;
fallacy of, 385

Water routes, influence on local advantages, 526-7;
[Pg 610]economy of, 528

Wealth, and welfare, 15-20;
definition, 17, 18;
and income, 41;
related to gratification, 44;
and its indirect uses, 46-52;
conditions of economic, 48-52;
in city and country, contrasted, 111;
loan of, in Middle Ages, 112;
concept, and capital concept, 116;
and property, 362;
inequality of, 375

Welfare, and wealth, 15-20;
and instinctive choice, 395;
vs. production, 398

Wieser, 570, 571, 580, 583

Wind and water as sources of power, 51

Woman's work, 510

Work, see Labor

Workers, effect of machinery on, 239-44;
need of organization, 246;
need of direction, 265-7;
and profit-sharing, 294;
gains from trusts, 325;
health in factories, 509-10


Years' purchase, 120

[Pg 597] Ability, variety, 177-83;
physical differences, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
intelligence, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
training, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
ethical traits, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
inequality, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
scarcity, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and job, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
grades, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
types, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
selection, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-2;
sterilization, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-2

Abstinence, definition, kinds, 163;
view Saving

Acquisition vs. social production, 259

Affection in personal distribution, 402

Agricultural classes, opposition to commercial, 113

Agricultural stage, 261

Agriculture, machinery in, 238

Alternative uses, relation to costs, 277

America, farms let on shares, 59;
land ownership changes, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
land exhaustion, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
use of interchangeable parts, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
deforestation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
coal deposits, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-9;
horse improvement, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
watch factory, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
price of horses during the Boer War, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
mines discovered, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
diverse industrial conditions, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
money usage, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
wealth display, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
land became part of the world's supply, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
quality of life, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
family size, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
food supply, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
population growth, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
military rations, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
food quality, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
caste, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
democracy and efficiency, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
dominant pay system, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
wages, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
switching jobs, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
positive impact of machinery, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
racial differences among workers, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
industrial dominance, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
Asian competition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
fortunes, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
profit-sharing, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
producers' cooperation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
consumer cooperation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
industrial stage, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
crises, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
gifts from rich men, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
inheritance law, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
fortunes, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
workers' attire, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
colonial policy toward __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
custom, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
gold standard, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
silver supplies from __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
gold supplies, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
cash, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-9;
effect of silver supplies from, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
effect of gold production, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
banks, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-70;
tax talk, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
California prices, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
in various sections, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
protective tariff, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-503;
manufacturing growth, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
factory laws, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-12;
state-owned enterprise, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-17;
coastal early settlement, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
trade during the War of 1812, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
canals, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
railroad construction, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
railroad assistance, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

American Federation of Labor, 245;
claims of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

American Revolution, economic issues in, 8

Animal economy, provision for wants, 40

Animals, problem of numbers, 185-6

Antisocial profits, 289;
of monopoly, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
from speculation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
antisocial use of skill, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Appropriation stage, 261

Ashley, W. J., 575

Assignats, 448

Attribution of product, 176

Austrian economists, 570

Authoritative distribution, 406-8;
[Pg 598]use of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-11


Balance of trade, international, 486-7;
so-called beneficial, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Bank-notes, and paper money compared, 447;
typical, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-8;
in the U.S., __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Banks, and credit, 462-70;
functions, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
in the U.S., __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-70

Barter, definition, 31;
under basic conditions, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
difficulty of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
decline, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-14;
economy in the Middle Ages, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Bequest, limitation of right, 368

Bets, see Gambling

Bimetallism, international, 457-9;
national, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-61

Biologic doctrine of population, 186, 187

Biology, shows inequality of talents, 181

Birth-rate, of animals, 187;
decreasing American, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__

Böhm-Bawerk, E. von, 570, 571, 572, 577, 580, 583

Boycott, 251

Brooks, R. C., 593

Building laws, 505

Bullock, C. J., 568

Buyers, bidding, 34;
edge, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__


Canadian bank-notes, 468, 470

Canals, as carriers, 528-9

Cannan, Edwin, 571, 573

Capital, origin of term, 112;
concept in modern business, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-7;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
not the same as money, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
purpose of borrowing, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
sum, expressed in years' purchase, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
sum of expected rents, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
value not primary, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
stock, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
stock values fluctuate, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
time value and, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
fixed and expandable forms, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-3;
used by entrepreneurs, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
insured by businesses, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
in cooperation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
large, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
amount in factories, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
value impacted by protection, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Capitalistic, age, 114, 117;
monopoly, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Capitalization, of all forms of rent, 118-30;
rent charges as an example of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of land rents, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of consistent or fluctuating rent amounts, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-6;
growing role, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of any ongoing income, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of franchises, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of corporate earnings, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
rate, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and interest, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
influenced by taxes, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Capitalization, theory of crises, 353-4

Carlyle, T., on wage, 229

Carnegie, Andrew, 268, 270, 372, 377;
gift economies for libraries, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__

Carver, T. N., 578

Cassel, 578

Caste, and efficiency, 199

Chance, unavoidable, 333;
average in the industry, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
artificial, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
legit and illegit, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Character, affected by expenditure, 398;
peak production, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
choice unity determining, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Charitable distribution, 405-6

Charity, public, 507

Cheating and gambling, 335

Child-labor legislation, 509

Choice, of goods, harmony in, 400

Cities, wealth of, contrasted with feudal estates, 111, 113;
growth, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
large, on waterways, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

City ownership, 514-5;
view Public ownership

Clark, J. B., 398;
theory of profits and wages, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_2__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_3__

Clews, Henry, on Wall Street finance, 378

Climate, and income, 48

Closed shop, 249-50

Clothing and efficiency, 196;
effect of choice of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Coal, use and exhaustion, 88, 558;
1902 strike, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__

Coinage, 433-6;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
free or complimentary, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-6;
token, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-7;
free and unnecessary, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Coins, light-weight, 443-7

Collective bargaining, 248

Collective enjoyment, as a mode of distribution, 408

[Pg 599]Collectivism, 552

Combination and wages, 253-6;
of the factors, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
opposes competition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of capital, see Trusts

Comforts, relative meaning, 11;
and luxury, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Commercial monopoly, 306

Commercial paper, discounting of, 132

Commissions, to control railroads; 541-3;
to regulate corporations, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Commodity-money theory, 450

Common denominator of values, see Money

Commons, J. R., 573

Communism, among Germanic tribes, questioned, 365

Comparative costs, doctrine of, 482-3

Competition, definition, 33;
one-sided, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
current limitations on, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
the worker in, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
reduced by unions, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-50;
expensive in retail, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
free, not equality of efficiency, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
alleged reason for trusts, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
persistence of __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and state action, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-30;
and custom, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
economic harmony through, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-8;
social restrictions of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-30;
current restrictions, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Competitive distribution, 409-10

Competitive price, forces governing, 308

Complementary agents, and value, 78;
heavy use of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
work and wealth, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Compulsory distribution, 404

Conquest theory of property, 363

Consolidation of railroads, 539-40

Consumers, determining costs, 280;
benefits from trusts, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Consumers', choice influences value, 392;
choice affects wages, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
cooperation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-301;
League, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Consumption, reaction upon production, 392-401;
definition of economic, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
reaction to material agents, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
reaction to worker efficiency, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-410;
effects on consumers, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
as a traditional branch of political economy, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Consumption, tax on, 475

Consumption goods, definition, 20;
instant gratification, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
a portion of income, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
competitive advantages, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
chart, grades by quality, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
proposed uses, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
saved, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
view products

Continental notes, 448

Contracting out, forbidden, 512

Contract interest, see Interest

Contract rent, see Rent

Contract wages, see Wages

Coöperation, producers', 295-7;
consumers', __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-301

Corporation, securities, 127-8;
public service, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
increase of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Cost, involved in improvements, 90;
of operation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
in larger production, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of government, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
check out Comparative costs

Cost of production, 273-81;
From the entrepreneur's perspective, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-6;
psychic, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
alternative, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
cash, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and price $276;
from the economist's perspective, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-81, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__

Courts and industrial legislation, 543, 550-1

Credit, sales involve interest, 134;
and banking, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-70

Crises and industrial depressions, 345-55;
caused by sudden tariff changes, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-3

Crusoe economy, subjective valuations, 30;
time value, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
saving, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
economic wages, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
present and future items, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-20;
need for judgment, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Cultivation, margin of, 64;
check Utilization

Custom, and rents, 56;
and efficiency, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
affecting distribution, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and competition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__


Daniels, Winthrop M., 571

[Pg 600]Davenport, Herbert J., 567

Death-rate, decreasing, 192

Debts, public, as investments, 133

Deferred payments, standard of, 453-61;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
ideals for a standard, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-7

Demand, definition, 27;
social factor of choice, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
law of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
curve, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
elasticity, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
exchange, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
curve, chart, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Democracy, and efficiency, 199;
impact on racial progress, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__

Deposit and discount, 462

Depreciation and rent, 85-7

Desire, see Wants

Destruction, and rent, of wealth, 87-9;
wealth by chance, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-2;
intentional, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-3

Devine, Edward T., 587, 594

Dewey, Davis R., 568

Differential advantages, in consumption goods, 73-5;
in indirect goods, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-80

Diminishing returns, law, 61-72;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of all agents, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
tech, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
economic, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
other meanings of term, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-9;
general application to space relations, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-8;
confused by large production, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
tech, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
historical, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
development of the concept, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-72;
applies to all wealth, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and population, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and labor productivity, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
the overall principle of value, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Diminishing utility, law, 22;
diagram, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
relation to diminishing returns, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Directors, of railroads, obligations of, 539

Discount, commercial, 132, 135

Discovery enlarges natural resources, 156

Discrimination in rates, by monopoly, 310;
in train fares, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-3

Distribution, personal and functional, 359;
impersonal, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
personal, nature of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-3;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of the social income, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-11;
methods of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-11;
as a traditional branch of political economy, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Dividends, manipulation of, 130

Division of labor, 201-4;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
kinds, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
pros, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
calls for leadership skills, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
growth of territorial, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-2

Dollar, meaning of, 435

Drink, effect of, 396

Durable agents, see Goods

Durableness of rented agents, 55


Economic goods, definition of, 19;
view products

Economic harmony, through competition, 425-8;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Economic law, nature of, 206

Economic monopoly, 306

Economic motives, see Wants

Economic production, 258;
view Production

Economic rent, see Rent

Economic wages, see Wages

Economics, nature and purpose 3-8;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
topic, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
place in social sciences, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
as a science, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
synonym for political economy, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
democratic in purpose, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
importance, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
study objective, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
a section of social science, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
central point of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
redefined, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
relation to real-life situations, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Economy, involves choice, 27;
the trade, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
the cash, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-14

Education, free public, 507

Efficiency, talent, and training as factors in, 180;
result of many qualities, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of work, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-204;
equality in, not necessary for competition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
view Capability

Ely, Richard T., 568, 584

Emery, Henry C., 585

Employer, adjusts labor to interest rate, 220;
check Enterpriser

Employment, no lack of, 183

Energy, sources of, and income, 50

Engels, Frederick, 416

England, idea of rent in, 59;
long leases, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
food supply in the Napoleonic Wars, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
coal deposits, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
wages, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
[Pg 601]18th-century changes, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
loans, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
unusual effect of machinery, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
cooperation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
use of term monopoly, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
cotton crisis, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
crises, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
endowments limited, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
grants to royal families, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
gold standard, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
prices during the Napoleonic Wars, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
bank restriction act, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-9;
balance of imports, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
discussion of protection, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Enjoyable goods, see Consumption goods

Enterprise, income, and social service, 376-7

Enterpriser, function of, 265-72;
qualities of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-70;
selection of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-2;
his task, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
his costs, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
medium for consumer estimates, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
profits of __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
origin of term, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
his services evaluated, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-8;
his risk, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
industry intermediary, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
lacking cooperation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
profit-sharing and cooperation, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
as a risk-taker, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Environment, betterment, 92, 162

Ethics, definition, 6;
and time-value economics, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of consumption, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_2__;
of railway issue, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
see Morality

Europe, industrial methods of, 262

Exchange, in a market, 30-8;
and demand, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
advantage, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
isolated, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of current and future goods, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-9;
as a standard branch of political economy, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
foreign and domestic money, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
international, see global trade

Extensive margin of indirect goods, 78-9;
view Utilization

Extravagance to give employment, 386


Factors, definition, 260;
combination of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-4;
cost of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
proportions of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
mutual employment of __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Factory, system, growth and effect, 243-4;
change in number, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
limits to growth, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
law, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-13

Farmers and the tariff, 498-9

Fauna and income, 49

Feeling and utility, 26

Fiat-money theory, 450-1

Fisher, Irving, 571, 575

Fixed charges, 168

Flora and income, 49

Food, and income, 50;
and efficiency, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
effect of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
regulations and product inspections, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Foreign exchanges, theory of, 485-8

Forestry, need of, 88

Forests, destruction of, 87-8

Franchises, for public utilities, 96;
capitalizing on, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
granting monopolies, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Free competition, see Competition

Free coinage, money value, 435

Freedom, economic, 422-30;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Free goods, definition, 19;
on the edge of use, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Free-silver movement in America, 459-61

Free trade, see International trade

Future rents capitalized, 125


Gambling vs. insurance, 333-8;
definition of typical, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
economic theory of __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

George, Henry, his theory of value, 417

Gibson, A. H., 577

Gilman, N. P., on profit-sharing, 293

Glut theory of crises, 351-2

Gold, fitness as money, 102;
as cash, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-3;
supply of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
discoveries, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
as a standard, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
increased productivity, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
shipping location, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Goods, definition, 19;
adjustment to desires, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
shifting series, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
substitution, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
series of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
relation of indirect to satisfaction, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
fun, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
durable, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
unripe, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
[Pg 602]levels of durability, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
limited number, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
free and unlimited, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Government, a condition of efficient labor, 198;
as a consumable product and a productive force, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
cash, see Paper money

Granger stores, 300

Gratification, defined, 16;
and marginal utility, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
temporary, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
at various times, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
time value of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__

Greenbacks, 448, 451

Gresham's law, 446-7


Hadley, A. T., 579, 580

Happiness, and wealth, 18;
and showiness, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and character, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Hildebrand, 575

Historical diminishing returns, 68;
confused with tech, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
see Diminishing returns

Home-market argument for protection, 498-9

Honesty, a condition of efficiency, 198;
of public officials, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Household industry in America, 313


Immigration and protection, 498

Improvements to increase products, 90

Incidence of taxation, 476

Income, as a flow of goods, 39-42;
national, social, individual, private, objective, money, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
gross, net, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
of consumer goods, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
present, future, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
funded, unfunded, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
as a series of rewards, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
psychic, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
all sources are productive, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
affected by objective conditions, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-52;
affected by rising capital, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and social service, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-80;
from property, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-6;
from personal services, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-80;
justice of large, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-91;
distribution of the social, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-11;
and taxes, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-7;
impacted by crises, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
personal and impersonal shares, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-62;
personal, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
complex sources of mental, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Increasable agents, 153-5;
scale of awesomeness, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Increase, of product, 90;
of agents, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_1__;
of rent-bearer impacts others, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Indestructibility imputed to rented agents, 55

Indirect goods, see Goods

Individualism, extreme, its ideal of competition, 410

Industrial depressions, definition, 346

Industrial revolution caused by machinery, 237

Industrial stage, 261

Industry, changes in, affecting money, 101;
money responds to, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
diversity of conditions in America, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
changes in Europe, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
increasing complexity as interest declines, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Infant-industry argument for protection, 497

Inheritance, effect on industry, 12;
social impact, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-73

Insurance, origin, 337;
economic theory of __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
good conditions in, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Integration of industry, 321

Intensive margin, see Utilization

Interest, opposition to, in Middle Ages, 112;
the current contract formats for loaning money, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
lease agreement, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
on loans vs. rent charges, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
increased use of __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
approved by Rome, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
two approaches, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
"the current rate" and capitalization, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
on money loans, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-7;
gross and net, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
in credit sales, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
hidden, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
avoidance of legal rate, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
adjustment of the business to the rate, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
contract rate, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-8;
in sacrifice sale, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and time value, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
relation to rent, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
[Pg 603]first use of term, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
rate separates current and future uses, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and future products, diagram, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
time-value equalizer, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
rate and savings, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and capitalization, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
and improvements, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
rate connects present and future, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
contract with entrepreneur, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
traditional idea of, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
contract and deferred payments, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__

Intermediate products and costs, 279

Internal revenue, 475

International demand, ratio of, 484-5

International trade, general theory of, 480-90;
as a case of exchange, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__-5;
definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
international exchange equation, definition, __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;
cash balance of __A_TAG_PLACEHOLDER_0__;

FOOTNOTES:

[1] Compiled from data given by "The Journal of Commerce and Commercial Bulletin," reprinted in "The Commercial Year Book," Vol. V, 1900, pp. 564-569.

[1] Compiled from data provided by "The Journal of Commerce and Commercial Bulletin," reprinted in "The Commercial Year Book," Vol. V, 1900, pp. 564-569.

[2] John Moody, "The Truth About the Trusts," 1904.

[2] John Moody, "The Truth About the Trusts," 1904.

[3] These statements are retained as they were made in March, 1903. In the following September occurred a very remarkable panic in stocks which had the minimum of effect on general business. While stock prices have somewhat recovered since that time, general business conditions, on the whole, tended for a while toward the worse until the spring of 1904.

[3] These statements are preserved as they were made in March 1903. The next September, there was a significant panic in the stock market that had little impact on overall business. While stock prices have somewhat bounced back since then, general business conditions, overall, worsened for a time until the spring of 1904.

[4] Though at first glance this may seem contradictory to the statement in the foregoing paragraph regarding the nature of supply, it will not be found so on closer examination.

[4] Although this might initially appear to contradict the earlier statement about the nature of supply, a closer look will reveal that it does not.


Download ePUB

If you like this ebook, consider a donation!