This is a modern-English version of Mutual Aid: A Factor of Evolution, originally written by Kropotkin, Petr Alekseevich, kniaz. It has been thoroughly updated, including changes to sentence structure, words, spelling, and grammar—to ensure clarity for contemporary readers, while preserving the original spirit and nuance. If you click on a paragraph, you will see the original text that we modified, and you can toggle between the two versions.

Scroll to the bottom of this page and you will find a free ePUB download link for this book.

MUTUAL AID

A FACTOR OF EVOLUTION
BY P. KROPOTKIN

1902

1902

INTRODUCTION

Two aspects of animal life impressed me most during the journeys which I made in my youth in Eastern Siberia and Northern Manchuria. One of them was the extreme severity of the struggle for existence which most species of animals have to carry on against an inclement Nature; the enormous destruction of life which periodically results from natural agencies; and the consequent paucity of life over the vast territory which fell under my observation. And the other was, that even in those few spots where animal life teemed in abundance, I failed to find—although I was eagerly looking for it—that bitter struggle for the means of existence, among animals belonging to the same species, which was considered by most Darwinists (though not always by Darwin himself) as the dominant characteristic of struggle for life, and the main factor of evolution.

Two aspects of animal life struck me the most during my travels in Eastern Siberia and Northern Manchuria when I was young. One was the harsh reality of the struggle for survival that most animal species face against a harsh environment; the massive loss of life that occurs periodically due to natural causes; and the resulting scarcity of life across the vast areas I observed. The other was that, even in the few places where animal life was abundant, I couldn’t find—no matter how hard I looked—that intense competition for survival among animals of the same species, which many Darwinists (though not always Darwin himself) believed to be the main characteristic of the struggle for life and a key factor in evolution.

The terrible snow-storms which sweep over the northern portion of Eurasia in the later part of the winter, and the glazed frost that often follows them; the frosts and the snow-storms which return every year in the second half of May, when the trees are already in full blossom and insect life swarms everywhere; the early frosts and, occasionally, the heavy snowfalls in July and August, which suddenly destroy myriads of insects, as well as the second broods of the birds in the prairies; the torrential rains, due to the monsoons, which fall in more temperate regions in August and September—resulting in inundations on a scale which is only known in America and in Eastern Asia, and swamping, on the plateaus, areas as wide as European States; and finally, the heavy snowfalls, early in October, which eventually render a territory as large as France and Germany, absolutely impracticable for ruminants, and destroy them by the thousand—these were the conditions under which I saw animal life struggling in Northern Asia. They made me realize at an early date the overwhelming importance in Nature of what Darwin described as "the natural checks to over-multiplication," in comparison to the struggle between individuals of the same species for the means of subsistence, which may go on here and there, to some limited extent, but never attains the importance of the former. Paucity of life, under-population—not over-population—being the distinctive feature of that immense part of the globe which we name Northern Asia, I conceived since then serious doubts—which subsequent study has only confirmed—as to the reality of that fearful competition for food and life within each species, which was an article of faith with most Darwinists, and, consequently, as to the dominant part which this sort of competition was supposed to play in the evolution of new species.

The harsh snowstorms that hit the northern part of Eurasia in late winter, and the freezing frost that often follows; the frosts and snowstorms that return every year in the second half of May when the trees are already blooming and insects are everywhere; the early frosts and, occasionally, heavy snowfall in July and August that suddenly wipe out countless insects, as well as the second broods of birds in the prairies; the torrential rains from the monsoons that fall in more temperate regions in August and September—causing floods on a scale only seen in America and Eastern Asia, and inundating areas as large as European countries on the plateaus; and finally, the heavy snowfall that comes early in October, making an area as large as France and Germany completely unlivable for herbivores, killing thousands of them—these were the conditions under which I observed animal life struggling in Northern Asia. They made me realize early on the crucial role of what Darwin described as "the natural checks to over-multiplication" in nature, compared to the competition among individuals of the same species for survival, which may happen to some extent but never reaches the significance of the former. The scarcity of life and under-population—not over-population—being the defining traits of that vast part of the world we call Northern Asia, I have since developed serious doubts—which further study has only confirmed—about the existence of that intense competition for food and survival within each species, which was a core belief for most Darwinists, and consequently, about the significant role that this type of competition was believed to play in the evolution of new species.

On the other hand, wherever I saw animal life in abundance, as, for instance, on the lakes where scores of species and millions of individuals came together to rear their progeny; in the colonies of rodents; in the migrations of birds which took place at that time on a truly American scale along the Usuri; and especially in a migration of fallow-deer which I witnessed on the Amur, and during which scores of thousands of these intelligent animals came together from an immense territory, flying before the coming deep snow, in order to cross the Amur where it is narrowest—in all these scenes of animal life which passed before my eyes, I saw Mutual Aid and Mutual Support carried on to an extent which made me suspect in it a feature of the greatest importance for the maintenance of life, the preservation of each species, and its further evolution.

On the other hand, wherever I saw a lot of animal life, like on the lakes where countless species and millions of individuals gathered to raise their young; in the colonies of rodents; in the migrations of birds that occurred on a truly American scale along the Usuri; and especially in a migration of fallow deer that I observed on the Amur, where tens of thousands of these smart animals came together from a vast area, moving ahead of the heavy snowfall to cross the Amur at its narrowest point—in all these scenes of animal life that unfolded before me, I noticed a level of Mutual Aid and Mutual Support that made me think it was a crucial factor for sustaining life, preserving each species, and its further evolution.

And finally, I saw among the semi-wild cattle and horses in Transbaikalia, among the wild ruminants everywhere, the squirrels, and so on, that when animals have to struggle against scarcity of food, in consequence of one of the above-mentioned causes, the whole of that portion of the species which is affected by the calamity, comes out of the ordeal so much impoverished in vigour and health, that no progressive evolution of the species can be based upon such periods of keen competition.

And finally, I saw among the semi-wild cattle and horses in Transbaikalia, and the wild ruminants everywhere, the squirrels, and so on, that when animals have to fight against food shortages due to one of the causes mentioned above, the entire part of the species affected by this hardship comes out of the experience weakened in strength and health, making it impossible for any positive evolution of the species to be based on such times of intense competition.

Consequently, when my attention was drawn, later on, to the relations between Darwinism and Sociology, I could agree with none of the works and pamphlets that had been written upon this important subject. They all endeavoured to prove that Man, owing to his higher intelligence and knowledge, may mitigate the harshness of the struggle for life between men; but they all recognized at the same time that the struggle for the means of existence, of every animal against all its congeners, and of every man against all other men, was "a law of Nature." This view, however, I could not accept, because I was persuaded that to admit a pitiless inner war for life within each species, and to see in that war a condition of progress, was to admit something which not only had not yet been proved, but also lacked confirmation from direct observation.

As a result, when I later focused on the connections between Darwinism and Sociology, I couldn’t agree with any of the writings and pamphlets that had been produced on this significant topic. They all tried to show that humans, due to their higher intelligence and knowledge, can ease the harsh realities of the struggle for survival among people; yet they all acknowledged at the same time that the competition for resources, from every animal against its peers, and from every person against all others, was "a law of Nature." I couldn’t accept this perspective, though, because I believed that acknowledging an unyielding internal battle for survival within each species, and viewing that battle as a basis for progress, was to accept something that not only hadn’t been proven yet but also lacked evidence from direct observation.

On the contrary, a lecture "On the Law of Mutual Aid," which was delivered at a Russian Congress of Naturalists, in January 1880, by the well-known zoologist, Professor Kessler, the then Dean of the St. Petersburg University, struck me as throwing a new light on the whole subject. Kessler's idea was, that besides the law of Mutual Struggle there is in Nature the law of Mutual Aid, which, for the success of the struggle for life, and especially for the progressive evolution of the species, is far more important than the law of mutual contest. This suggestion—which was, in reality, nothing but a further development of the ideas expressed by Darwin himself in The Descent of Man—seemed to me so correct and of so great an importance, that since I became acquainted with it (in 1883) I began to collect materials for further developing the idea, which Kessler had only cursorily sketched in his lecture, but had not lived to develop. He died in 1881.

On the contrary, a lecture "On the Law of Mutual Aid," given at a Russian Congress of Naturalists in January 1880 by the well-known zoologist, Professor Kessler, who was then the Dean of St. Petersburg University, really opened my eyes to the whole subject. Kessler proposed that in addition to the law of Mutual Struggle, there is also a law of Mutual Aid in Nature, which is far more important for the success of the struggle for life and especially for the progressive evolution of species than the law of mutual competition. This idea—which was essentially a further development of concepts expressed by Darwin himself in The Descent of Man—seemed so accurate and significant to me that after learning about it in 1883, I started gathering materials to further develop the idea that Kessler had only briefly outlined in his lecture but did not have the chance to elaborate on before he passed away in 1881.

In one point only I could not entirely endorse Kessler's views. Kessler alluded to "parental feeling" and care for progeny (see below, Chapter I) as to the source of mutual inclinations in animals. However, to determine how far these two feelings have really been at work in the evolution of sociable instincts, and how far other instincts have been at work in the same direction, seems to me a quite distinct and a very wide question, which we hardly can discuss yet. It will be only after we have well established the facts of mutual aid in different classes of animals, and their importance for evolution, that we shall be able to study what belongs in the evolution of sociable feelings, to parental feelings, and what to sociability proper—the latter having evidently its origin at the earliest stages of the evolution of the animal world, perhaps even at the "colony-stages." I consequently directed my chief attention to establishing first of all, the importance of the Mutual Aid factor of evolution, leaving to ulterior research the task of discovering the origin of the Mutual Aid instinct in Nature.

There’s only one point where I can’t fully agree with Kessler’s views. Kessler referred to "parental feeling" and care for offspring (see below, Chapter I) as the source of mutual tendencies in animals. However, figuring out how much these two feelings have actually influenced the development of social instincts, and how much other instincts have contributed to this as well, seems to me a completely different and much larger question that we can't really discuss just yet. Only after we’ve established the facts about mutual aid in different species and its significance for evolution will we be able to explore what aspects of the development of social feelings come from parental feelings and what comes from social behavior itself—the latter clearly having its roots in the earliest stages of animal evolution, possibly even during the "colony-stages." Therefore, I focused primarily on highlighting the importance of the Mutual Aid factor in evolution, leaving the task of uncovering the origin of the Mutual Aid instinct in nature for future research.

The importance of the Mutual Aid factor—"if its generality could only be demonstrated"—did not escape the naturalist's genius so manifest in Goethe. When Eckermann told once to Goethe—it was in 1827—that two little wren-fledglings, which had run away from him, were found by him next day in the nest of robin redbreasts (Rothkehlchen), which fed the little ones, together with their own youngsters, Goethe grew quite excited about this fact. He saw in it a confirmation of his pantheistic views, and said:—"If it be true that this feeding of a stranger goes through all Nature as something having the character of a general law—then many an enigma would be solved." He returned to this matter on the next day, and most earnestly entreated Eckermann (who was, as is known, a zoologist) to make a special study of the subject, adding that he would surely come "to quite invaluable treasuries of results" (Gespräche, edition of 1848, vol. iii. pp. 219, 221). Unfortunately, this study was never made, although it is very possible that Brehm, who has accumulated in his works such rich materials relative to mutual aid among animals, might have been inspired by Goethe's remark.

The significance of the Mutual Aid concept—"if its generality could only be shown"—wasn't lost on the naturalist's brilliance that was so evident in Goethe. When Eckermann mentioned to Goethe in 1827 that two little wren fledglings, which had escaped from him, were found the next day in a robins' nest (Rothkehlchen) being cared for alongside the robins' own chicks, Goethe became quite enthusiastic about this finding. He regarded it as a validation of his pantheistic beliefs, stating: "If it’s true that this kind of nurturing of outsiders is a general law in Nature—then many mysteries would be clarified." The following day, he passionately urged Eckermann (who, as we know, was a zoologist) to conduct a focused study on the topic, adding that he would surely uncover "invaluable treasures of insight" (Gespräche, edition of 1848, vol. iii. pp. 219, 221). Sadly, this research was never undertaken, although it’s entirely possible that Brehm, who compiled an extensive amount of material on mutual aid among animals, may have been inspired by Goethe's comment.

Several works of importance were published in the years 1872-1886, dealing with the intelligence and the mental life of animals (they are mentioned in a footnote in Chapter I of this book), and three of them dealt more especially with the subject under consideration; namely, Les Societes animales, by Espinas (Paris, 1877); La Lutte pour l'existence et l'association pout la lutte, a lecture by J.L. Lanessan (April 1881); and Louis Buchner's book, Liebe und Liebes-Leben in der Thierwelt, of which the first edition appeared in 1882 or 1883, and a second, much enlarged, in 1885. But excellent though each of these works is, they leave ample room for a work in which Mutual Aid would be considered, not only as an argument in favour of a pre-human origin of moral instincts, but also as a law of Nature and a factor of evolution. Espinas devoted his main attention to such animal societies (ants, bees) as are established upon a physiological division of labour, and though his work is full of admirable hints in all possible directions, it was written at a time when the evolution of human societies could not yet be treated with the knowledge we now possess. Lanessan's lecture has more the character of a brilliantly laid-out general plan of a work, in which mutual support would be dealt with, beginning with rocks in the sea, and then passing in review the world of plants, of animals and men. As to Buchner's work, suggestive though it is and rich in facts, I could not agree with its leading idea. The book begins with a hymn to Love, and nearly all its illustrations are intended to prove the existence of love and sympathy among animals. However, to reduce animal sociability to love and sympathy means to reduce its generality and its importance, just as human ethics based upon love and personal sympathy only have contributed to narrow the comprehension of the moral feeling as a whole. It is not love to my neighbour—whom I often do not know at all—which induces me to seize a pail of water and to rush towards his house when I see it on fire; it is a far wider, even though more vague feeling or instinct of human solidarity and sociability which moves me. So it is also with animals. It is not love, and not even sympathy (understood in its proper sense) which induces a herd of ruminants or of horses to form a ring in order to resist an attack of wolves; not love which induces wolves to form a pack for hunting; not love which induces kittens or lambs to play, or a dozen of species of young birds to spend their days together in the autumn; and it is neither love nor personal sympathy which induces many thousand fallow-deer scattered over a territory as large as France to form into a score of separate herds, all marching towards a given spot, in order to cross there a river. It is a feeling infinitely wider than love or personal sympathy—an instinct that has been slowly developed among animals and men in the course of an extremely long evolution, and which has taught animals and men alike the force they can borrow from the practice of mutual aid and support, and the joys they can find in social life.

Several important works were published between 1872 and 1886 that focused on the intelligence and mental life of animals (these are referenced in a footnote in Chapter I of this book), with three specifically addressing the topic at hand: Les Societes animales by Espinas (Paris, 1877); La Lutte pour l'existence et l'association pour la lutte, a lecture by J.L. Lanessan (April 1881); and Louis Buchner's book, Liebe und Liebes-Leben in der Thierwelt, which first appeared in 1882 or 1883, with a much-expanded second edition in 1885. Despite the excellence of each of these works, they leave ample opportunity for a study of Mutual Aid that considers it not just as evidence for a pre-human origin of moral instincts, but also as a natural law and an evolutionary factor. Espinas focused primarily on animal societies (like ants and bees) that are founded on a physiological division of labor. While his work offers many valuable insights, it was written at a time when the evolution of human societies couldn’t be explored with the understanding we have today. Lanessan's lecture presents a brilliantly organized outline for a work that would cover mutual support, starting from sea rocks and moving through the realms of plants, animals, and humans. Regarding Buchner's work, while it's thought-provoking and full of facts, I can't agree with its main premise. The book opens with a celebration of love, and most of its examples aim to demonstrate love and sympathy among animals. However, reducing animal sociability to love and sympathy diminishes its significance and universality, just as human ethics based on love and personal sympathy have limited our understanding of moral feelings overall. It’s not love for my neighbor—whom I might not even know—that compels me to grab a bucket of water and rush to their house when I see it on fire; it’s a broader, albeit more abstract, sense of human solidarity and sociability that drives me. The same goes for animals. It's not love, nor even true sympathy, that prompts a herd of grazing animals or horses to form a circle to fend off a wolf attack; nor is it love that brings wolves together into a hunting pack; it’s not love that encourages kittens or lambs to play, or groups of young birds to spend autumn days together; and neither love nor personal sympathy causes thousands of fallow deer spread over a territory as large as France to gather into separate herds, all heading to the same spot to cross a river. It's a feeling that’s far broader than love or personal sympathy—an instinct that has gradually evolved in animals and humans over a lengthy period, teaching both the strength found in mutual aid and support, as well as the joy derived from social life.

The importance of this distinction will be easily appreciated by the student of animal psychology, and the more so by the student of human ethics. Love, sympathy and self-sacrifice certainly play an immense part in the progressive development of our moral feelings. But it is not love and not even sympathy upon which Society is based in mankind. It is the conscience—be it only at the stage of an instinct—of human solidarity. It is the unconscious recognition of the force that is borrowed by each man from the practice of mutual aid; of the close dependency of every one's happiness upon the happiness of all; and of the sense of justice, or equity, which brings the individual to consider the rights of every other individual as equal to his own. Upon this broad and necessary foundation the still higher moral feelings are developed. But this subject lies outside the scope of the present work, and I shall only indicate here a lecture, "Justice and Morality" which I delivered in reply to Huxley's Ethics, and in which the subject has been treated at some length.

The importance of this distinction will be easily understood by anyone studying animal psychology, and even more so by those looking into human ethics. Love, sympathy, and self-sacrifice definitely play a huge role in the ongoing development of our moral emotions. However, it’s not love, and not even sympathy, that society is built upon in humanity. It's the conscience—whether it's just an instinct—of human solidarity. It's the unintentional acknowledgment of the strength that each person gains from practicing mutual aid; the close link between everyone’s happiness and the happiness of others; and the sense of justice or fairness, which leads individuals to see the rights of every other person as equal to their own. On this solid and necessary foundation, even higher moral feelings are developed. However, this topic goes beyond the focus of this work, and I will only mention a lecture, "Justice and Morality," that I gave in response to Huxley’s Ethics, where I explored this subject in more detail.

Consequently I thought that a book, written on Mutual Aid as a Law of Nature and a factor of evolution, might fill an important gap. When Huxley issued, in 1888, his "Struggle-for-life" manifesto (Struggle for Existence and its Bearing upon Man), which to my appreciation was a very incorrect representation of the facts of Nature, as one sees them in the bush and in the forest, I communicated with the editor of the Nineteenth Century, asking him whether he would give the hospitality of his review to an elaborate reply to the views of one of the most prominent Darwinists; and Mr. James Knowles received the proposal with fullest sympathy. I also spoke of it to W. Bates. "Yes, certainly; that is true Darwinism," was his reply. "It is horrible what 'they' have made of Darwin. Write these articles, and when they are printed, I will write to you a letter which you may publish." Unfortunately, it took me nearly seven years to write these articles, and when the last was published, Bates was no longer living.

Consequently, I thought that a book about Mutual Aid as a Law of Nature and a factor of evolution could fill an important gap. When Huxley released his "Struggle-for-life" manifesto (Struggle for Existence and its Bearing upon Man) in 1888, I felt it was a very misleading portrayal of the facts of Nature, as observed in the bush and the forest. I reached out to the editor of the Nineteenth Century, asking if he would be open to publishing a detailed response to the views of one of the leading Darwinists, and Mr. James Knowles responded positively to my proposal. I also discussed it with W. Bates. "Yes, definitely; that is true Darwinism," he replied. "It's terrible what 'they' have made of Darwin. Write these articles, and once they’re published, I’ll send you a letter that you can publish." Unfortunately, it took me nearly seven years to write these articles, and by the time the last one was published, Bates had already passed away.

After having discussed the importance of mutual aid in various classes of animals, I was evidently bound to discuss the importance of the same factor in the evolution of Man. This was the more necessary as there are a number of evolutionists who may not refuse to admit the importance of mutual aid among animals, but who, like Herbert Spencer, will refuse to admit it for Man. For primitive Man—they maintain—war of each against all was the law of life. In how far this assertion, which has been too willingly repeated, without sufficient criticism, since the times of Hobbes, is supported by what we know about the early phases of human development, is discussed in the chapters given to the Savages and the Barbarians.

After discussing the importance of mutual aid in different animal species, I clearly needed to talk about the significance of this same factor in the evolution of humans. This was especially important since there are several evolutionists who may acknowledge the role of mutual aid among animals but, like Herbert Spencer, refuse to accept it for humans. They argue that for primitive humans, the rule was a struggle of all against each other. The extent to which this claim, which has been too readily repeated without enough scrutiny since Hobbes's time, is supported by what we know about the early stages of human development is explored in the chapters dedicated to Savages and Barbarians.

The number and importance of mutual-aid institutions which were developed by the creative genius of the savage and half-savage masses, during the earliest clan-period of mankind and still more during the next village-community period, and the immense influence which these early institutions have exercised upon the subsequent development of mankind, down to the present times, induced me to extend my researches to the later, historical periods as well; especially, to study that most interesting period—the free medieval city republics, of which the universality and influence upon our modern civilization have not yet been duly appreciated. And finally, I have tried to indicate in brief the immense importance which the mutual-support instincts, inherited by mankind from its extremely long evolution, play even now in our modern society, which is supposed to rest upon the principle: "every one for himself, and the State for all," but which it never has succeeded, nor will succeed in realizing.

The number and significance of mutual-aid organizations created by the innovative spirit of primitive and semi-primitive people during humanity's earliest clan period, and even more during the following village-community period, as well as the huge impact these early institutions have had on the further development of humanity up to the present day, led me to expand my research into later historical periods too. In particular, I was interested in studying that fascinating time—the free medieval city republics—whose widespread influence on our modern civilization has yet to be fully recognized. Finally, I have attempted to briefly highlight the immense importance of the mutual-support instincts that humanity has inherited from its lengthy evolution, which still play a significant role in our current society, which is thought to be based on the idea: "every man for himself, and the State for all," yet has never successfully achieved, nor will it ever achieve, that ideal.

It may be objected to this book that both animals and men are represented in it under too favourable an aspect; that their sociable qualities are insisted upon, while their anti-social and self-asserting instincts are hardly touched upon. This was, however, unavoidable. We have heard so much lately of the "harsh, pitiless struggle for life," which was said to be carried on by every animal against all other animals, every "savage" against all other "savages," and every civilized man against all his co-citizens—and these assertions have so much become an article of faith—that it was necessary, first of all, to oppose to them a wide series of facts showing animal and human life under a quite different aspect. It was necessary to indicate the overwhelming importance which sociable habits play in Nature and in the progressive evolution of both the animal species and human beings: to prove that they secure to animals a better protection from their enemies, very often facilities for getting food and (winter provisions, migrations, etc.), longevity, therefore a greater facility for the development of intellectual faculties; and that they have given to men, in addition to the same advantages, the possibility of working out those institutions which have enabled mankind to survive in its hard struggle against Nature, and to progress, notwithstanding all the vicissitudes of its history. It is a book on the law of Mutual Aid, viewed at as one of the chief factors of evolution—not on all factors of evolution and their respective values; and this first book had to be written, before the latter could become possible.

It might be argued that this book portrays both animals and humans in too positive a light, focusing on their social qualities while barely touching on their anti-social and self-serving instincts. However, this was unavoidable. We've heard so much recently about the "harsh, relentless struggle for survival," which supposedly happens between every animal and all other animals, every "savage" against other "savages," and every civilized person against their fellow citizens—and these claims have become widely accepted—that it was necessary to present a wide range of facts showing animal and human life from a different perspective. It was essential to highlight the significant role that social behavior plays in nature and in the evolution of both animal species and humans: to show that social behaviors provide animals with better protection from their enemies, often help them find food and prepare for winter, promote longevity, and thus support the development of intellectual abilities; and that for humans, in addition to those benefits, social behaviors have enabled the creation of institutions that help mankind survive the challenges of nature and make progress despite the ups and downs of history. This book discusses the law of Mutual Aid, viewed as one of the key factors of evolution—not all factors of evolution and their respective importance; and this foundational book had to be written before the latter could be explored.

I should certainly be the last to underrate the part which the self-assertion of the individual has played in the evolution of mankind. However, this subject requires, I believe, a much deeper treatment than the one it has hitherto received. In the history of mankind, individual self-assertion has often been, and continually is, something quite different from, and far larger and deeper than, the petty, unintelligent narrow-mindedness, which, with a large class of writers, goes for "individualism" and "self-assertion." Nor have history-making individuals been limited to those whom historians have represented as heroes. My intention, consequently, is, if circumstances permit it, to discuss separately the part taken by the self-assertion of the individual in the progressive evolution of mankind. I can only make in this place the following general remark:—When the Mutual Aid institutions—the tribe, the village community, the guilds, the medieval city—began, in the course of history, to lose their primitive character, to be invaded by parasitic growths, and thus to become hindrances to progress, the revolt of individuals against these institutions took always two different aspects. Part of those who rose up strove to purify the old institutions, or to work out a higher form of commonwealth, based upon the same Mutual Aid principles; they tried, for instance, to introduce the principle of "compensation," instead of the lex talionis, and later on, the pardon of offences, or a still higher ideal of equality before the human conscience, in lieu of "compensation," according to class-value. But at the very same time, another portion of the same individual rebels endeavoured to break down the protective institutions of mutual support, with no other intention but to increase their own wealth and their own powers. In this three-cornered contest, between the two classes of revolted individuals and the supporters of what existed, lies the real tragedy of history. But to delineate that contest, and honestly to study the part played in the evolution of mankind by each one of these three forces, would require at least as many years as it took me to write this book.

I definitely won't downplay the role that individual self-assertion has played in the evolution of humanity. However, I think this topic needs a much deeper exploration than it has received so far. Throughout history, individual self-assertion has often been, and still is, something quite different from, as well as far broader and deeper than, the petty, narrow-mindedness that many writers mistakenly equate with "individualism" and "self-assertion." Moreover, the individuals who have made a mark in history were not only those whom historians have portrayed as heroes. Therefore, if circumstances allow, I plan to discuss separately the role of individual self-assertion in the progressive evolution of humanity. For now, I can only make this general observation: when the Mutual Aid institutions—the tribe, the village community, the guilds, the medieval city—started to lose their original character over time, becoming plagued by parasitic growths that hindered progress, the rebellion of individuals against these institutions took on two different forms. Some who rose up aimed to reform the old institutions or to develop a better form of community based on the same Mutual Aid principles; for instance, they sought to introduce the principle of "compensation" instead of retribution, and later on, the forgiveness of offenses, or even a higher ideal of equality before human conscience, as opposed to compensation based on class-value. At the same time, another group of individual rebels sought to dismantle the protective institutions of mutual support solely to enhance their own wealth and power. This three-way struggle between the two groups of rebellious individuals and the supporters of the existing order encapsulates the true tragedy of history. However, to outline that struggle and to honestly examine the contributions of each of these three forces to human evolution would take me at least as many years as it took to write this book.

Of works dealing with nearly the same subject, which have been published since the publication of my articles on Mutual Aid among Animals, I must mention The Lowell Lectures on the Ascent of Man, by Henry Drummond (London, 1894), and The Origin and Growth of the Moral Instinct, by A. Sutherland (London, 1898). Both are constructed chiefly on the lines taken in Buchner's Love, and in the second work the parental and familial feeling as the sole influence at work in the development of the moral feelings has been dealt with at some length. A third work dealing with man and written on similar lines is The Principles of Sociology, by Prof. F.A. Giddings, the first edition of which was published in 1896 at New York and London, and the leading ideas of which were sketched by the author in a pamphlet in 1894. I must leave, however, to literary critics the task of discussing the points of contact, resemblance, or divergence between these works and mine.

Of works addressing similar topics that have been published since my articles on Mutual Aid among Animals, I should mention The Lowell Lectures on the Ascent of Man, by Henry Drummond (London, 1894), and The Origin and Growth of the Moral Instinct, by A. Sutherland (London, 1898). Both are mainly based on the ideas presented in Buchner's Love, and the second work discusses the role of parental and familial feelings as the primary influences in the development of moral emotions in detail. A third work that examines humanity and follows similar themes is The Principles of Sociology, by Prof. F.A. Giddings, with its first edition published in 1896 in New York and London, after the author outlined the main concepts in a pamphlet in 1894. However, I'll leave it to literary critics to analyze the connections, similarities, or differences between these works and mine.

The different chapters of this book were published first in the Nineteenth Century ("Mutual Aid among Animals," in September and November 1890; "Mutual Aid among Savages," in April 1891; "Mutual Aid among the Barbarians," in January 1892; "Mutual Aid in the Medieval City," in August and September 1894; and "Mutual Aid amongst Modern Men," in January and June 1896). In bringing them out in a book form my first intention was to embody in an Appendix the mass of materials, as well as the discussion of several secondary points, which had to be omitted in the review articles. It appeared, however, that the Appendix would double the size of the book, and I was compelled to abandon, or, at least, to postpone its publication. The present Appendix includes the discussion of only a few points which have been the matter of scientific controversy during the last few years; and into the text I have introduced only such matter as could be introduced without altering the structure of the work.

The different chapters of this book were first published in the Nineteenth Century ("Mutual Aid among Animals," in September and November 1890; "Mutual Aid among Savages," in April 1891; "Mutual Aid among the Barbarians," in January 1892; "Mutual Aid in the Medieval City," in August and September 1894; and "Mutual Aid amongst Modern Men," in January and June 1896). My original plan for releasing them in book form was to include in an Appendix a lot of materials, along with discussions on several secondary topics, that had to be left out of the articles. However, it turned out that the Appendix would double the size of the book, so I had to drop, or at least postpone, its publication. The current Appendix only covers a few points that have been debated in scientific circles over the past few years, and I have incorporated into the text only what could fit without changing the overall structure of the work.

I am glad of this opportunity for expressing to the editor of the Nineteenth Century, Mr. James Knowles, my very best thanks, both for the kind hospitality which he offered to these papers in his review, as soon as he knew their general idea, and the permission he kindly gave me to reprint them.

I am grateful for this opportunity to express my sincere thanks to the editor of the Nineteenth Century, Mr. James Knowles, for both the warm hospitality he extended to these papers in his review once he understood their overall idea, and for the permission he generously granted me to reprint them.

Bromley, Kent, 1902.

Bromley, Kent, 1902.

CHAPTER I

MUTUAL AID AMONG ANIMALS

Struggle for existence. Mutual Aid a law of Nature and chief factor of progressive evolution. Invertebrates. Ants and Bees. Birds, hunting and fishing associations. Sociability. Mutual protection among small birds. Cranes, parrots.

Struggle for existence. Mutual Aid is a law of Nature and a key factor in progressive evolution. Invertebrates. Ants and Bees. Birds, hunting and fishing groups. Sociability. Mutual protection among small birds. Cranes, parrots.

The conception of struggle for existence as a factor of evolution, introduced into science by Darwin and Wallace, has permitted us to embrace an immensely wide range of phenomena in one single generalization, which soon became the very basis of our philosophical, biological, and sociological speculations. An immense variety of facts:—adaptations of function and structure of organic beings to their surroundings; physiological and anatomical evolution; intellectual progress, and moral development itself, which we formerly used to explain by so many different causes, were embodied by Darwin in one general conception. We understood them as continued endeavours—as a struggle against adverse circumstances—for such a development of individuals, races, species and societies, as would result in the greatest possible fulness, variety, and intensity of life. It may be that at the outset Darwin himself was not fully aware of the generality of the factor which he first invoked for explaining one series only of facts relative to the accumulation of individual variations in incipient species. But he foresaw that the term which he was introducing into science would lose its philosophical and its only true meaning if it were to be used in its narrow sense only—that of a struggle between separate individuals for the sheer means of existence. And at the very beginning of his memorable work he insisted upon the term being taken in its "large and metaphorical sense including dependence of one being on another, and including (which is more important) not only the life of the individual, but success in leaving progeny."(1)

The idea of the struggle for existence as a factor in evolution, introduced by Darwin and Wallace, has allowed us to understand an incredibly broad range of phenomena under one overarching concept, which quickly became the foundation of our philosophical, biological, and sociological theories. A vast array of facts—such as how the functions and structures of living beings adapt to their environments, physiological and anatomical evolution, intellectual development, and even moral growth, which we once explained with many different causes—was unified by Darwin under one general idea. We viewed these as ongoing efforts—a struggle against difficult circumstances—aimed at fostering the greatest possible richness, diversity, and intensity of life in individuals, races, species, and societies. It's possible that at first, Darwin himself wasn't completely aware of the broad applicability of the concept he initially used to explain only one set of facts related to the accumulation of individual variations in emerging species. However, he anticipated that the term he was introducing into science would lose its philosophical and true meaning if it was only interpreted in a narrow way—as just a struggle between individual beings for mere survival. Right at the start of his groundbreaking work, he emphasized that the term should be understood in its "large and metaphorical sense, including the dependence of one being on another, and also (which is more significant) not just the survival of the individual, but the success in producing offspring."(1)

While he himself was chiefly using the term in its narrow sense for his own special purpose, he warned his followers against committing the error (which he seems once to have committed himself) of overrating its narrow meaning. In The Descent of Man he gave some powerful pages to illustrate its proper, wide sense. He pointed out how, in numberless animal societies, the struggle between separate individuals for the means of existence disappears, how struggle is replaced by co-operation, and how that substitution results in the development of intellectual and moral faculties which secure to the species the best conditions for survival. He intimated that in such cases the fittest are not the physically strongest, nor the cunningest, but those who learn to combine so as mutually to support each other, strong and weak alike, for the welfare of the community. "Those communities," he wrote, "which included the greatest number of the most sympathetic members would flourish best, and rear the greatest number of offspring" (2nd edit., p. 163). The term, which originated from the narrow Malthusian conception of competition between each and all, thus lost its narrowness in the mind of one who knew Nature.

While he primarily used the term in its limited sense for his own specific purpose, he cautioned his followers against making the mistake (which he seems to have made himself at one point) of overestimating its narrow meaning. In The Descent of Man, he devoted several powerful pages to illustrate its proper, broader sense. He pointed out how, in countless animal societies, the competition among individual members for resources lessens, how competition is replaced by cooperation, and how this shift leads to the development of intellectual and moral abilities that provide the species with the best chances for survival. He suggested that in these cases, the fittest are not necessarily the physically strongest or the most cunning, but those who learn to work together to support one another, both strong and weak, for the benefit of the community. "Those communities," he wrote, "which included the greatest number of the most sympathetic members would flourish best, and rear the greatest number of offspring" (2nd edit., p. 163). The term, which originated from the narrow Malthusian concept of competition among all individuals, thus lost its limitation in the mind of someone who understood Nature.

Unhappily, these remarks, which might have become the basis of most fruitful researches, were overshadowed by the masses of facts gathered for the purpose of illustrating the consequences of a real competition for life. Besides, Darwin never attempted to submit to a closer investigation the relative importance of the two aspects under which the struggle for existence appears in the animal world, and he never wrote the work he proposed to write upon the natural checks to over-multiplication, although that work would have been the crucial test for appreciating the real purport of individual struggle. Nay, on the very pages just mentioned, amidst data disproving the narrow Malthusian conception of struggle, the old Malthusian leaven reappeared—namely, in Darwin's remarks as to the alleged inconveniences of maintaining the "weak in mind and body" in our civilized societies (ch. v). As if thousands of weak-bodied and infirm poets, scientists, inventors, and reformers, together with other thousands of so-called "fools" and "weak-minded enthusiasts," were not the most precious weapons used by humanity in its struggle for existence by intellectual and moral arms, which Darwin himself emphasized in those same chapters of Descent of Man.

Unfortunately, these comments, which could have formed the basis for some of the most impactful research, were overshadowed by the vast amounts of data collected to demonstrate the effects of real competition for survival. Moreover, Darwin never tried to take a closer look at the relative importance of the two aspects of the struggle for existence that appear in the animal kingdom, and he never wrote the work he intended to address the natural limits to overpopulation, even though that work would have been essential for understanding the true meaning of individual struggle. Indeed, on the very pages previously mentioned, amidst evidence disproving the limited Malthusian view of struggle, the old Malthusian idea re-emerged—specifically, in Darwin's comments about the supposed problems with keeping the "weak in mind and body" in our civilized societies (ch. v). As if thousands of weak-bodied and ailing poets, scientists, inventors, and reformers, along with countless so-called "fools" and "weak-minded enthusiasts," were not the most valuable assets humanity possesses in its struggle for existence through intellectual and moral means, which Darwin himself highlighted in those same chapters of Descent of Man.

It happened with Darwin's theory as it always happens with theories having any bearing upon human relations. Instead of widening it according to his own hints, his followers narrowed it still more. And while Herbert Spencer, starting on independent but closely allied lines, attempted to widen the inquiry into that great question, "Who are the fittest?" especially in the appendix to the third edition of the Data of Ethics, the numberless followers of Darwin reduced the notion of struggle for existence to its narrowest limits. They came to conceive the animal world as a world of perpetual struggle among half-starved individuals, thirsting for one another's blood. They made modern literature resound with the war-cry of woe to the vanquished, as if it were the last word of modern biology. They raised the "pitiless" struggle for personal advantages to the height of a biological principle which man must submit to as well, under the menace of otherwise succumbing in a world based upon mutual extermination. Leaving aside the economists who know of natural science but a few words borrowed from second-hand vulgarizers, we must recognize that even the most authorized exponents of Darwin's views did their best to maintain those false ideas. In fact, if we take Huxley, who certainly is considered as one of the ablest exponents of the theory of evolution, were we not taught by him, in a paper on the 'Struggle for Existence and its Bearing upon Man,' that,

It happened with Darwin's theory just like it does with any theory that touches on human relationships. Instead of expanding it based on his own suggestions, his followers narrowed it even further. While Herbert Spencer, working from a similar but independent perspective, tried to broaden the discussion around the important question, "Who are the fittest?" especially in the appendix to the third edition of the Data of Ethics, countless followers of Darwin restricted the idea of the struggle for existence to its tightest definition. They came to see the animal kingdom as a relentless battleground among underfed individuals, driven to harm one another. Modern literature echoed with the lament for the defeated, as if that was the final word in today's biology. They elevated the "merciless" struggle for personal gain to a fundamental biological principle that humanity must also accept, or risk being overwhelmed in a world built on mutual destruction. Setting aside the economists who only know a few terms from natural science gleaned from secondary sources, we must acknowledge that even the most respected advocates of Darwin's theories contributed to maintaining those misconceptions. In fact, if we look at Huxley, who is undoubtedly regarded as one of the most competent interpreters of the theory of evolution, weren't we taught by him, in a paper on the 'Struggle for Existence and its Bearing upon Man,' that,

"from the point of view of the moralist, the animal world is on about the same level as a gladiators' show. The creatures are fairly well treated, and set to, fight hereby the strongest, the swiftest, and the cunningest live to fight another day. The spectator has no need to turn his thumb down, as no quarter is given."

"From a moral perspective, the animal world is pretty much like a gladiator show. The animals are relatively well cared for, and those that are the strongest, fastest, and most clever get to survive and fight another day. The audience doesn’t need to signal for mercy since no one is spared."

Or, further down in the same article, did he not tell us that, as among animals, so among primitive men,

Or, further down in the same article, didn't he tell us that, just like with animals, among primitive humans,

"the weakest and stupidest went to the wall, while the toughest and shrewdest, those who were best fitted to cope with their circumstances, but not the best in another way, survived. Life was a continuous free fight, and beyond the limited and temporary relations of the family, the Hobbesian war of each against all was the normal state of existence."(2)

"the weakest and dumbest ended up on the losing side, while the strongest and smartest, those best equipped to handle their situations, but not necessarily the best in other ways, survived. Life was a constant battle, and beyond the narrow and temporary bonds of family, the Hobbesian struggle of each person against everyone else was the usual way of life."(2)

In how far this view of nature is supported by fact, will be seen from the evidence which will be here submitted to the reader as regards the animal world, and as regards primitive man. But it may be remarked at once that Huxley's view of nature had as little claim to be taken as a scientific deduction as the opposite view of Rousseau, who saw in nature but love, peace, and harmony destroyed by the accession of man. In fact, the first walk in the forest, the first observation upon any animal society, or even the perusal of any serious work dealing with animal life (D'Orbigny's, Audubon's, Le Vaillant's, no matter which), cannot but set the naturalist thinking about the part taken by social life in the life of animals, and prevent him from seeing in Nature nothing but a field of slaughter, just as this would prevent him from seeing in Nature nothing but harmony and peace. Rousseau had committed the error of excluding the beak-and-claw fight from his thoughts; and Huxley committed the opposite error; but neither Rousseau's optimism nor Huxley's pessimism can be accepted as an impartial interpretation of nature.

In what way this view of nature is backed by facts will be shown through the evidence presented here regarding the animal kingdom and early humans. However, it should be noted right away that Huxley's perspective on nature holds just as little validity as a scientific conclusion as Rousseau's opposing view, which portrayed nature as filled with love, peace, and harmony disrupted by humanity's presence. In reality, taking a stroll in the forest, observing any animal community, or even reading any serious work about animal life (whether it's D'Orbigny's, Audubon's, or Le Vaillant's—whatever it may be) inevitably leads a naturalist to contemplate the role that social life plays in the lives of animals. This exploration prevents them from seeing nature solely as a battleground, just as it stops them from viewing it as nothing but harmony and peace. Rousseau made the mistake of ignoring the brutal realities of nature, while Huxley fell into the trap of the opposite error; yet neither Rousseau's optimism nor Huxley's pessimism can be regarded as an unbiased understanding of nature.

As soon as we study animals—not in laboratories and museums only, but in the forest and the prairie, in the steppe and the mountains—we at once perceive that though there is an immense amount of warfare and extermination going on amidst various species, and especially amidst various classes of animals, there is, at the same time, as much, or perhaps even more, of mutual support, mutual aid, and mutual defence amidst animals belonging to the same species or, at least, to the same society. Sociability is as much a law of nature as mutual struggle. Of course it would be extremely difficult to estimate, however roughly, the relative numerical importance of both these series of facts. But if we resort to an indirect test, and ask Nature: "Who are the fittest: those who are continually at war with each other, or those who support one another?" we at once see that those animals which acquire habits of mutual aid are undoubtedly the fittest. They have more chances to survive, and they attain, in their respective classes, the highest development of intelligence and bodily organization. If the numberless facts which can be brought forward to support this view are taken into account, we may safely say that mutual aid is as much a law of animal life as mutual struggle, but that, as a factor of evolution, it most probably has a far greater importance, inasmuch as it favours the development of such habits and characters as insure the maintenance and further development of the species, together with the greatest amount of welfare and enjoyment of life for the individual, with the least waste of energy.

As soon as we study animals—not just in labs and museums, but also in the forest and the prairie, the steppe and the mountains—we quickly notice that while there's a lot of fighting and extermination happening among different species, and especially among various classes of animals, there's just as much, if not more, mutual support, cooperation, and defense among animals of the same species or at least the same community. Sociability is just as much a natural law as mutual competition. Of course, it's very difficult to roughly estimate the relative significance of these two sets of facts. But if we pose an indirect question to Nature: "Who are the fittest: those who are constantly at war with one another, or those who help each other out?" it becomes clear that animals that develop habits of mutual aid are undoubtedly the fittest. They have better chances of survival, and they reach the highest levels of intelligence and physical organization within their respective groups. When considering the countless examples that support this perspective, we can confidently assert that mutual aid is as essential to animal life as mutual struggle, but in terms of evolution, it likely plays a far more significant role because it promotes the development of traits and behaviors that ensure the survival and continued growth of the species, while also maximizing welfare and enjoyment of life for the individual, with minimal energy waste.

Of the scientific followers of Darwin, the first, as far as I know, who understood the full purport of Mutual Aid as a law of Nature and the chief factor of evolution, was a well-known Russian zoologist, the late Dean of the St. Petersburg University, Professor Kessler. He developed his ideas in an address which he delivered in January 1880, a few months before his death, at a Congress of Russian naturalists; but, like so many good things published in the Russian tongue only, that remarkable address remains almost entirely unknown.(3)

Of Darwin's scientific followers, the first one I know of who fully understood the significance of Mutual Aid as a natural law and a key factor in evolution was a prominent Russian zoologist, the late Dean of St. Petersburg University, Professor Kessler. He elaborated on his ideas in a speech he gave in January 1880, just a few months before his death, at a Congress of Russian naturalists; however, like many valuable works published only in Russian, that remarkable speech has remained mostly unknown.

"As a zoologist of old standing," he felt bound to protest against the abuse of a term—the struggle for existence—borrowed from zoology, or, at least, against overrating its importance. Zoology, he said, and those sciences which deal with man, continually insist upon what they call the pitiless law of struggle for existence. But they forget the existence of another law which may be described as the law of mutual aid, which law, at least for the animals, is far more essential than the former. He pointed out how the need of leaving progeny necessarily brings animals together, and, "the more the individuals keep together, the more they mutually support each other, and the more are the chances of the species for surviving, as well as for making further progress in its intellectual development." "All classes of animals," he continued, "and especially the higher ones, practise mutual aid," and he illustrated his idea by examples borrowed from the life of the burying beetles and the social life of birds and some mammalia. The examples were few, as might have been expected in a short opening address, but the chief points were clearly stated; and, after mentioning that in the evolution of mankind mutual aid played a still more prominent part, Professor Kessler concluded as follows:—

"As a long-time zoologist," he felt he had to speak out against the misuse of the term—the struggle for existence—taken from zoology, or at least against overstating its significance. Zoology, he pointed out, along with fields that study humans, constantly emphasizes what they call the harsh law of struggle for existence. But they overlook another principle that could be called the law of mutual aid, which is far more vital for animals than the former. He noted how the necessity to reproduce brings animals together, and, "the more individuals stick together, the more they support each other, and the better the chances for the species to survive, as well as to advance in its intellectual development." "All types of animals," he continued, "especially the more advanced ones, engage in mutual aid," and he illustrated his point with examples from the behavior of burying beetles and the social lives of birds and some mammals. The examples were limited, as expected in a brief opening address, but the main points were clearly articulated; and after mentioning that mutual aid played an even more significant role in human evolution, Professor Kessler concluded as follows:—

"I obviously do not deny the struggle for existence, but I maintain that the progressive development of the animal kingdom, and especially of mankind, is favoured much more by mutual support than by mutual struggle…. All organic beings have two essential needs: that of nutrition, and that of propagating the species. The former brings them to a struggle and to mutual extermination, while the needs of maintaining the species bring them to approach one another and to support one another. But I am inclined to think that in the evolution of the organic world—in the progressive modification of organic beings—mutual support among individuals plays a much more important part than their mutual struggle."(4)

"I definitely acknowledge the struggle for survival, but I believe that the progress of the animal kingdom, especially humans, is supported much more by cooperation than by competition. All living beings have two basic needs: nutrition and reproduction. The first leads to competition and even destruction, while the need to sustain the species encourages them to come together and help each other. However, I tend to think that in the development of the living world—in the gradual change of living beings—cooperation among individuals is much more significant than their competition."(4)

The correctness of the above views struck most of the Russian zoologists present, and Syevertsoff, whose work is well known to ornithologists and geographers, supported them and illustrated them by a few more examples. He mentioned sone of the species of falcons which have "an almost ideal organization for robbery," and nevertheless are in decay, while other species of falcons, which practise mutual help, do thrive. "Take, on the other side, a sociable bird, the duck," he said; "it is poorly organized on the whole, but it practises mutual support, and it almost invades the earth, as may be judged from its numberless varieties and species."

The correctness of these views resonated with most of the Russian zoologists present, and Syevertsoff, whose work is well known among ornithologists and geographers, supported them and added a few more examples. He mentioned some species of falcons that have "an almost perfect setup for theft," yet are in decline, while other species of falcons that cooperate do thrive. "On the flip side, consider a social bird, the duck," he said; "it's generally not well organized, but it practices mutual support, and it almost dominates the land, as seen in its countless varieties and species."

The readiness of the Russian zoologists to accept Kessler's views seems quite natural, because nearly all of them have had opportunities of studying the animal world in the wide uninhabited regions of Northern Asia and East Russia; and it is impossible to study like regions without being brought to the same ideas. I recollect myself the impression produced upon me by the animal world of Siberia when I explored the Vitim regions in the company of so accomplished a zoologist as my friend Polyakoff was. We both were under the fresh impression of the Origin of Species, but we vainly looked for the keen competition between animals of the same species which the reading of Darwin's work had prepared us to expect, even after taking into account the remarks of the third chapter (p. 54). We saw plenty of adaptations for struggling, very often in common, against the adverse circumstances of climate, or against various enemies, and Polyakoff wrote many a good page upon the mutual dependency of carnivores, ruminants, and rodents in their geographical distribution; we witnessed numbers of facts of mutual support, especially during the migrations of birds and ruminants; but even in the Amur and Usuri regions, where animal life swarms in abundance, facts of real competition and struggle between higher animals of the same species came very seldom under my notice, though I eagerly searched for them. The same impression appears in the works of most Russian zoologists, and it probably explains why Kessler's ideas were so welcomed by the Russian Darwinists, whilst like ideas are not in vogue amidst the followers of Darwin in Western Europe.

The willingness of Russian zoologists to embrace Kessler's views seems completely natural, as most of them have had the chance to study the animal world in the vast, uninhabited areas of Northern Asia and Eastern Russia; it's impossible to explore such regions without arriving at similar conclusions. I remember the impression the animal world of Siberia made on me when I explored the Vitim region alongside my talented zoologist friend, Polyakoff. We were both freshly influenced by the "Origin of Species," yet we found ourselves searching in vain for the intense competition between animals of the same species that Darwin's work had led us to expect, even after considering the comments from the third chapter (p. 54). We observed many adaptations for mutual struggle against harsh climate conditions or various predators, and Polyakoff wrote several insightful pages about the interdependence of carnivores, ruminants, and rodents in their geographic distribution; we witnessed many instances of mutual support, especially during the migrations of birds and ruminants. However, even in the Amur and Usuri regions, teeming with animal life, I rarely noticed instances of real competition and struggle between similar higher animals, despite my eager searches. This same impression appears in the works of most Russian zoologists, likely explaining why Kessler's ideas were so well-received among Russian Darwinists, while similar ideas aren't popular among Darwin's followers in Western Europe.

The first thing which strikes us as soon as we begin studying the struggle for existence under both its aspects—direct and metaphorical—is the abundance of facts of mutual aid, not only for rearing progeny, as recognized by most evolutionists, but also for the safety of the individual, and for providing it with the necessary food. With many large divisions of the animal kingdom mutual aid is the rule. Mutual aid is met with even amidst the lowest animals, and we must be prepared to learn some day, from the students of microscopical pond-life, facts of unconscious mutual support, even from the life of micro-organisms. Of course, our knowledge of the life of the invertebrates, save the termites, the ants, and the bees, is extremely limited; and yet, even as regards the lower animals, we may glean a few facts of well-ascertained cooperation. The numberless associations of locusts, vanessae, cicindelae, cicadae, and so on, are practically quite unexplored; but the very fact of their existence indicates that they must be composed on about the same principles as the temporary associations of ants or bees for purposes of migration. As to the beetles, we have quite well-observed facts of mutual help amidst the burying beetles (Necrophorus). They must have some decaying organic matter to lay their eggs in, and thus to provide their larvae with food; but that matter must not decay very rapidly. So they are wont to bury in the ground the corpses of all kinds of small animals which they occasionally find in their rambles. As a rule, they live an isolated life, but when one of them has discovered the corpse of a mouse or of a bird, which it hardly could manage to bury itself, it calls four, six, or ten other beetles to perform the operation with united efforts; if necessary, they transport the corpse to a suitable soft ground; and they bury it in a very considerate way, without quarrelling as to which of them will enjoy the privilege of laying its eggs in the buried corpse. And when Gleditsch attached a dead bird to a cross made out of two sticks, or suspended a toad to a stick planted in the soil, the little beetles would in the same friendly way combine their intelligences to overcome the artifice of Man. The same combination of efforts has been noticed among the dung-beetles.

The first thing that stands out as we start examining the struggle for existence in both its direct and metaphorical forms is the wealth of examples of mutual aid, not just for raising offspring, as most evolutionists acknowledge, but also for individual safety and securing necessary food. In many major branches of the animal kingdom, mutual aid is the norm. We even find mutual aid among the lowest animals, and we should be ready to discover someday, through studies of microscopic pond life, examples of unconscious mutual support from microorganisms. Of course, our understanding of invertebrate life, aside from termites, ants, and bees, is extremely limited; yet, even concerning lower animals, we can gather some well-documented instances of cooperation. The countless swarms of locusts, vanessa butterflies, tiger beetles, cicadas, and others are largely unexplored, but their existence suggests they are formed on similar principles to the temporary gatherings of ants or bees for migration. Regarding beetles, there are well-documented examples of mutual aid among burying beetles (Necrophorus). They need decaying organic matter to lay their eggs in, providing food for their larvae, but that matter shouldn’t decompose too quickly. So, they tend to bury the remains of various small animals they find on their travels. Generally, they live solitary lives, but when one discovers a dead mouse or bird that it can’t bury alone, it calls four, six, or ten other beetles for help; if needed, they carry the corpse to suitable soft ground and bury it carefully, without fighting over who gets to lay eggs in the buried body. When Gleditsch attached a dead bird to a cross made of two sticks or suspended a toad on a stick placed in the ground, these little beetles would similarly work together to outsmart human tricks. The same collaborative efforts have been observed among dung beetles.

Even among animals standing at a somewhat lower stage of organization we may find like examples. Some land-crabs of the West Indies and North America combine in large swarms in order to travel to the sea and to deposit therein their spawn; and each such migration implies concert, co-operation, and mutual support. As to the big Molucca crab (Limulus), I was struck (in 1882, at the Brighton Aquarium) with the extent of mutual assistance which these clumsy animals are capable of bestowing upon a comrade in case of need. One of them had fallen upon its back in a corner of the tank, and its heavy saucepan-like carapace prevented it from returning to its natural position, the more so as there was in the corner an iron bar which rendered the task still more difficult. Its comrades came to the rescue, and for one hour's time I watched how they endeavoured to help their fellow-prisoner. They came two at once, pushed their friend from beneath, and after strenuous efforts succeeded in lifting it upright; but then the iron bar would prevent them from achieving the work of rescue, and the crab would again heavily fall upon its back. After many attempts, one of the helpers would go in the depth of the tank and bring two other crabs, which would begin with fresh forces the same pushing and lifting of their helpless comrade. We stayed in the Aquarium for more than two hours, and, when leaving, we again came to cast a glance upon the tank: the work of rescue still continued! Since I saw that, I cannot refuse credit to the observation quoted by Dr. Erasmus Darwin—namely, that "the common crab during the moulting season stations as sentinel an unmoulted or hard-shelled individual to prevent marine enemies from injuring moulted individuals in their unprotected state."(5)

Even among animals that are a bit simpler in structure, we can find similar examples. Some land crabs from the West Indies and North America gather in large groups to travel to the sea and lay their eggs, and each migration shows teamwork, cooperation, and mutual support. Regarding the big Molucca crab (Limulus), I was impressed (in 1882, at the Brighton Aquarium) by how much these awkward creatures could help a fellow crab in need. One of them had flipped onto its back in a corner of the tank, and its heavy, pot-like shell made it hard to get back on its feet, especially since there was an iron bar in the corner making things even trickier. Its companions came to help, and for an hour, I watched them trying to assist their stranded friend. Two crabs worked together, pushing from underneath, and after a lot of effort, they managed to lift it upright; however, the iron bar then stopped them from completing the rescue, causing the crab to tumble back onto its back. After several tries, one of the helpers went to the bottom of the tank and brought two more crabs, who started pushing and lifting their helpless friend with renewed strength. We stayed in the Aquarium for over two hours, and when we left, we looked back at the tank: the rescue efforts were still underway! After witnessing that, I can't ignore the observation made by Dr. Erasmus Darwin—that "the common crab during the molting season sends an unmolthed or hard-shelled individual to stand guard and protect molted individuals in their vulnerable state."(5)

Facts illustrating mutual aid amidst the termites, the ants, and the bees are so well known to the general reader, especially through the works of Romanes, L. Buchner, and Sir John Lubbock, that I may limit my remarks to a very few hints.(6) If we take an ants' nest, we not only see that every description of work-rearing of progeny, foraging, building, rearing of aphides, and so on—is performed according to the principles of voluntary mutual aid; we must also recognize, with Forel, that the chief, the fundamental feature of the life of many species of ants is the fact and the obligation for every ant of sharing its food, already swallowed and partly digested, with every member of the community which may apply for it. Two ants belonging to two different species or to two hostile nests, when they occasionally meet together, will avoid each other. But two ants belonging to the same nest or to the same colony of nests will approach each other, exchange a few movements with the antennae, and "if one of them is hungry or thirsty, and especially if the other has its crop full … it immediately asks for food." The individual thus requested never refuses; it sets apart its mandibles, takes a proper position, and regurgitates a drop of transparent fluid which is licked up by the hungry ant. Regurgitating food for other ants is so prominent a feature in the life of ants (at liberty), and it so constantly recurs both for feeding hungry comrades and for feeding larvae, that Forel considers the digestive tube of the ants as consisting of two different parts, one of which, the posterior, is for the special use of the individual, and the other, the anterior part, is chiefly for the use of the community. If an ant which has its crop full has been selfish enough to refuse feeding a comrade, it will be treated as an enemy, or even worse. If the refusal has been made while its kinsfolk were fighting with some other species, they will fall back upon the greedy individual with greater vehemence than even upon the enemies themselves. And if an ant has not refused to feed another ant belonging to an enemy species, it will be treated by the kinsfolk of the latter as a friend. All this is confirmed by most accurate observation and decisive experiments.(7)

Facts showing how mutual aid works among termites, ants, and bees are widely recognized by readers, especially through the studies of Romanes, L. Buchner, and Sir John Lubbock, so I’ll keep my comments brief.(6) When we look at an ant nest, we see that all kinds of tasks—raising young, foraging, building, tending to aphids, and so on—are done based on the principles of voluntary mutual aid. We also need to acknowledge, as Forel points out, that a key aspect of the lives of many ant species is that every ant is expected to share its food, which has already been consumed and partially digested, with any other member of the community that asks for it. When two ants from different species or rival nests encounter each other, they tend to avoid one another. However, ants from the same nest or colony will approach each other, perform some antenna movements, and "if one of them is hungry or thirsty, especially if the other has a full crop … it will ask for food." The ant that is asked for food never declines; it opens its mandibles, positions itself properly, and regurgitates a drop of clear fluid that the hungry ant licks up. Sharing food with other ants is such a significant behavior in the lives of free ants that it consistently occurs both for feeding hungry companions and for nurturing larvae. As a result, Forel views the digestive system of ants as having two parts: one at the back for the individual’s use, and the front part primarily for the community's benefit. If an ant with a full crop has been greedy enough to refuse to feed a fellow ant, it will be treated as an enemy, or even worse. If this refusal happens while its relatives are battling another species, they will retaliate against the selfish individual more fiercely than against the enemies themselves. Conversely, if an ant feeds another from a rival species, it will be regarded by the latter's relatives as a friend. All of this has been confirmed by precise observations and clear experiments.(7)

In that immense division of the animal kingdom which embodies more than one thousand species, and is so numerous that the Brazilians pretend that Brazil belongs to the ants, not to men, competition amidst the members of the same nest, or the colony of nests, does not exist. However terrible the wars between different species, and whatever the atrocities committed at war-time, mutual aid within the community, self-devotion grown into a habit, and very often self-sacrifice for the common welfare, are the rule. The ants and termites have renounced the "Hobbesian war," and they are the better for it. Their wonderful nests, their buildings, superior in relative size to those of man; their paved roads and overground vaulted galleries; their spacious halls and granaries; their corn-fields, harvesting and "malting" of grain;(8) their, rational methods of nursing their eggs and larvae, and of building special nests for rearing the aphides whom Linnaeus so picturesquely described as "the cows of the ants"; and, finally, their courage, pluck, and, superior intelligence—all these are the natural outcome of the mutual aid which they practise at every stage of their busy and laborious lives. That mode of life also necessarily resulted in the development of another essential feature of the life of ants: the immense development of individual initiative which, in its turn, evidently led to the development of that high and varied intelligence which cannot but strike the human observer.(9)

In that vast part of the animal kingdom that includes over a thousand species—so many that Brazilians say Brazil belongs to the ants, not to humans—there's no competition within the same nest or the collection of nests. No matter how fierce the battles between different species or the terrible things done in war, mutual support within the community, devotion that becomes a habit, and often self-sacrifice for the greater good are the norm. Ants and termites have moved past the "Hobbesian war," and it's served them well. Their incredible nests, their structures, which are relatively larger than those built by humans; their paved pathways and above-ground vaulted tunnels; their spacious chambers and storage spaces; their gardens, the harvesting and "malting" of grain; their organized ways of caring for their eggs and larvae, and building special nests to raise the aphids that Linnaeus famously referred to as "the cows of the ants"; and finally, their courage, determination, and advanced intelligence—all of this is a direct result of the mutual aid they provide at every stage of their industrious lives. This way of living also naturally led to the growth of another crucial aspect of ant life: the significant development of individual initiative, which in turn clearly contributed to the development of that high and diverse intelligence that inevitably catches the attention of human observers.

If we knew no other facts from animal life than what we know about the ants and the termites, we already might safely conclude that mutual aid (which leads to mutual confidence, the first condition for courage) and individual initiative (the first condition for intellectual progress) are two factors infinitely more important than mutual struggle in the evolution of the animal kingdom. In fact, the ant thrives without having any of the "protective" features which cannot be dispensed with by animals living an isolated life. Its colour renders it conspicuous to its enemies, and the lofty nests of many species are conspicuous in the meadows and forests. It is not protected by a hard carapace, and its stinging apparatus, however dangerous when hundreds of stings are plunged into the flesh of an animal, is not of a great value for individual defence; while the eggs and larvae of the ants are a dainty for a great number of the inhabitants of the forests. And yet the ants, in their thousands, are not much destroyed by the birds, not even by the ant-eaters, and they are dreaded by most stronger insects. When Forel emptied a bagful of ants in a meadow, he saw that "the crickets ran away, abandoning their holes to be sacked by the ants; the grasshoppers and the crickets fled in all directions; the spiders and the beetles abandoned their prey in order not to become prey themselves;" even the nests of the wasps were taken by the ants, after a battle during which many ants perished for the safety of the commonwealth. Even the swiftest insects cannot escape, and Forel often saw butterflies, gnats, flies, and so on, surprised and killed by the ants. Their force is in mutual support and mutual confidence. And if the ant—apart from the still higher developed termites—stands at the very top of the whole class of insects for its intellectual capacities; if its courage is only equalled by the most courageous vertebrates; and if its brain—to use Darwin's words—"is one of the most marvellous atoms of matter in the world, perhaps more so than the brain of man," is it not due to the fact that mutual aid has entirely taken the place of mutual struggle in the communities of ants?

If we only knew about animal life what we know about ants and termites, we could confidently say that mutual aid (which leads to mutual trust, the first step towards courage) and individual initiative (the first step towards intellectual progress) are way more important than competition in the evolution of the animal kingdom. In fact, ants thrive without any of the "protective" traits that animals living alone need. Their color makes them easy targets for predators, and the large nests of many species stand out in meadows and forests. They lack a hard shell, and while their stinging ability can be dangerous when many stings are unleashed on another animal, it's not very useful for individual defense; plus, the eggs and larvae of ants are a tasty treat for many forest dwellers. Yet, even in large numbers, ants aren't often taken down by birds, not even by anteaters, and they're feared by most larger insects. When Forel released a bag of ants in a meadow, he noted that "the crickets ran away, abandoning their burrows to be raided by the ants; grasshoppers and crickets scattered in all directions; spiders and beetles left their prey to avoid becoming prey themselves;" even wasp nests were overtaken by ants after battles where many ants sacrificed themselves for the safety of their colony. Even the fastest insects can't escape, and Forel frequently observed butterflies, gnats, flies, and others caught off guard and killed by ants. Their strength lies in mutual support and mutual trust. And if the ant—besides the even more advanced termites—ranks at the top of the entire class of insects for its intellectual abilities; if its bravery is matched only by the most courageous vertebrates; and if its brain—to quote Darwin—"is one of the most marvelous pieces of matter in the world, possibly even more so than the human brain," isn't it because mutual aid has completely replaced competition in ant communities?

The same is true as regards the bees. These small insects, which so easily might become the prey of so many birds, and whose honey has so many admirers in all classes of animals from the beetle to the bear, also have none of the protective features derived from mimicry or otherwise, without which an isolatedly living insect hardly could escape wholesale destruction; and yet, owing to the mutual aid they practise, they obtain the wide extension which we know and the intelligence we admire, By working in common they multiply their individual forces; by resorting to a temporary division of labour combined with the capacity of each bee to perform every kind of work when required, they attain such a degree of well-being and safety as no isolated animal can ever expect to achieve however strong or well armed it may be. In their combinations they are often more successful than man, when he neglects to take advantage of a well-planned mutual assistance. Thus, when a new swarm of bees is going to leave the hive in search of a new abode, a number of bees will make a preliminary exploration of the neighbourhood, and if they discover a convenient dwelling-place—say, an old basket, or anything of the kind—they will take possession of it, clean it, and guard it, sometimes for a whole week, till the swarm comes to settle therein. But how many human settlers will perish in new countries simply for not having understood the necessity of combining their efforts! By combining their individual intelligences they succeed in coping with adverse circumstances, even quite unforeseen and unusual, like those bees of the Paris Exhibition which fastened with their resinous propolis the shutter to a glass-plate fitted in the wall of their hive. Besides, they display none of the sanguinary proclivities and love of useless fighting with which many writers so readily endow animals. The sentries which guard the entrance to the hive pitilessly put to death the robbing bees which attempt entering the hive; but those stranger bees which come to the hive by mistake are left unmolested, especially if they come laden with pollen, or are young individuals which can easily go astray. There is no more warfare than is strictly required.

The same goes for bees. These tiny insects, which could easily become prey for many birds and whose honey is loved by a wide range of animals from beetles to bears, don't have the protective features from mimicry or other means that would help a solitary insect avoid total destruction. Yet, because of the mutual support they practice, they achieve the extensive colonies we see and the intelligence we admire. By working together, they enhance their individual strengths; with a temporary division of labor and the ability of each bee to perform any task when needed, they reach a level of well-being and safety that no lone animal can expect, no matter how strong or well-armed it is. In their collaborations, they often achieve more than humans do when they fail to utilize effective teamwork. For instance, when a new swarm of bees is about to leave the hive to find a new home, several bees will scout the area, and if they find a suitable place—like an old basket—they will take over, clean it, and protect it, sometimes for an entire week until the swarm decides to settle in. But how many human settlers have perished in new lands simply because they didn't understand the importance of working together? By pooling their intelligence, bees can handle unexpected and challenging situations, like those bees at the Paris Exhibition that used their resinous propolis to secure a shutter to the glass plate in their hive wall. Furthermore, they show none of the violent tendencies and unnecessary aggression that many writers like to attribute to animals. The guards at the hive entrance ruthlessly eliminate robbing bees that try to enter, but they leave mistake visitors alone, especially if they're carrying pollen or are young bees that can easily get lost. There's no more fighting than absolutely necessary.

The sociability of the bees is the more instructive as predatory instincts and laziness continue to exist among the bees as well, and reappear each time that their growth is favoured by some circumstances. It is well known that there always are a number of bees which prefer a life of robbery to the laborious life of a worker; and that both periods of scarcity and periods of an unusually rich supply of food lead to an increase of the robbing class. When our crops are in and there remains but little to gather in our meadows and fields, robbing bees become of more frequent occurrence; while, on the other side, about the sugar plantations of the West Indies and the sugar refineries of Europe, robbery, laziness, and very often drunkenness become quite usual with the bees. We thus see that anti-social instincts continue to exist amidst the bees as well; but natural selection continually must eliminate them, because in the long run the practice of solidarity proves much more advantageous to the species than the development of individuals endowed with predatory inclinations. The cunningest and the shrewdest are eliminated in favour of those who understand the advantages of sociable life and mutual support.

The social behavior of bees is particularly enlightening because, despite their sociability, predatory instincts and laziness still exist among them and tend to resurface whenever their growth is supported by certain conditions. It’s well-known that there are always some bees that prefer a life of theft over the hard work of a laborer; both times of scarcity and times of plenty lead to an increase in the thieving bees. When our crops are harvested and there is little left to gather in our meadows and fields, the number of robbing bees goes up; conversely, around the sugar plantations in the West Indies and sugar refineries in Europe, stealing, laziness, and often even drunkenness become quite common among bees. This shows that anti-social behaviors persist among bees as well; however, natural selection must continuously weed them out because, over time, cooperation proves to be much more beneficial for the species than the survival of individuals with predatory tendencies. The most cunning and clever are eliminated in favor of those who recognize the benefits of a social life and mutual assistance.

Certainly, neither the ants, nor the bees, nor even the termites, have risen to the conception of a higher solidarity embodying the whole of the species. In that respect they evidently have not attained a degree of development which we do not find even among our political, scientific, and religious leaders. Their social instincts hardly extend beyond the limits of the hive or the nest. However, colonies of no less than two hundred nests, belonging to two different species (Formica exsecta and F. pressilabris) have been described by Forel on Mount Tendre and Mount Saleve; and Forel maintains that each member of these colonies recognizes every other member of the colony, and that they all take part in common defence; while in Pennsylvania Mr. MacCook saw a whole nation of from 1,600 to 1,700 nests of the mound-making ant, all living in perfect intelligence; and Mr. Bates has described the hillocks of the termites covering large surfaces in the "campos"—some of the nests being the refuge of two or three different species, and most of them being connected by vaulted galleries or arcades.(10) Some steps towards the amalgamation of larger divisions of the species for purposes of mutual protection are thus met with even among the invertebrate animals.

Certainly, neither the ants, the bees, nor even the termites have come up with the idea of a greater solidarity that includes the entire species. In that regard, they clearly haven't reached a level of development that we don't see even among our political, scientific, and religious leaders. Their social instincts barely go beyond the boundaries of the hive or the nest. However, colonies of no less than two hundred nests from two different species (Formica exsecta and F. pressilabris) have been described by Forel on Mount Tendre and Mount Saleve; and Forel claims that each member of these colonies recognizes every other member and that they all participate in common defense. Meanwhile, in Pennsylvania, Mr. MacCook observed a whole nation of about 1,600 to 1,700 nests of the mound-making ant, all living in perfect harmony; and Mr. Bates has documented the hillocks of termites covering large areas in the "campos," with some nests serving as homes for two or three different species, most connected by vaulted galleries or archways. Some steps toward bringing together larger groups of the species for mutual protection are therefore also seen among invertebrate animals.

Going now over to higher animals, we find far more instances of undoubtedly conscious mutual help for all possible purposes, though we must recognize at once that our knowledge even of the life of higher animals still remains very imperfect. A large number of facts have been accumulated by first-rate observers, but there are whole divisions of the animal kingdom of which we know almost nothing. Trustworthy information as regards fishes is extremely scarce, partly owing to the difficulties of observation, and partly because no proper attention has yet been paid to the subject. As to the mammalia, Kessler already remarked how little we know about their manners of life. Many of them are nocturnal in their habits; others conceal themselves underground; and those ruminants whose social life and migrations offer the greatest interest do not let man approach their herds. It is chiefly upon birds that we have the widest range of information, and yet the social life of very many species remains but imperfectly known. Still, we need not complain about the lack of well-ascertained facts, as will be seen from the following.

Moving on to higher animals, we find many more examples of clearly conscious mutual assistance for various purposes, although we must acknowledge that our understanding of the lives of higher animals is still quite limited. A significant amount of data has been gathered by top observers, but there are entire groups of the animal kingdom about which we know almost nothing. Reliable information regarding fish is extremely rare, partly due to the challenges of observation and partly because the subject hasn't received adequate attention. Regarding mammals, Kessler already pointed out how little we understand about their lifestyles. Many of them are nocturnal; others hide underground; and those ruminants whose social lives and migrations are most fascinating do not allow humans to get close to their herds. Our knowledge of birds is the most extensive, but even so, the social lives of many species are still poorly understood. However, we shouldn't complain about the shortage of well-established facts, as the following will demonstrate.

I need not dwell upon the associations of male and female for rearing their offspring, for providing it with food during their first steps in life, or for hunting in common; though it may be mentioned by the way that such associations are the rule even with the least sociable carnivores and rapacious birds; and that they derive a special interest from being the field upon which tenderer feelings develop even amidst otherwise most cruel animals. It may also be added that the rarity of associations larger than that of the family among the carnivores and the birds of prey, though mostly being the result of their very modes of feeding, can also be explained to some extent as a consequence of the change produced in the animal world by the rapid increase of mankind. At any rate it is worthy of note that there are species living a quite isolated life in densely-inhabited regions, while the same species, or their nearest congeners, are gregarious in uninhabited countries. Wolves, foxes, and several birds of prey may be quoted as instances in point.

I don’t need to elaborate on how males and females come together to raise their young, provide food during the early stages of life, or hunt together; it’s worth noting that these partnerships are the norm even among the least social carnivores and predatory birds. These associations are particularly interesting because they allow for more tender emotions to develop even among animals that are otherwise quite ruthless. Additionally, the fact that larger social groups are uncommon among carnivores and birds of prey can mostly be attributed to their feeding habits, but it can also be partly explained by the changes brought about by the rapid growth of the human population. It’s interesting to observe that some species lead isolated lives in heavily populated areas, while the same species or their closest relatives are social in less populated regions. Wolves, foxes, and various birds of prey serve as examples of this phenomenon.

However, associations which do not extend beyond the family bonds are of relatively small importance in our case, the more so as we know numbers of associations for more general purposes, such as hunting, mutual protection, and even simple enjoyment of life. Audubon already mentioned that eagles occasionally associate for hunting, and his description of the two bald eagles, male and female, hunting on the Mississippi, is well known for its graphic powers. But one of the most conclusive observations of the kind belongs to Syevertsoff. Whilst studying the fauna of the Russian Steppes, he once saw an eagle belonging to an altogether gregarious species (the white-tailed eagle, Haliactos albicilla) rising high in the air for half an hour it was describing its wide circles in silence when at once its piercing voice was heard. Its cry was soon answered by another eagle which approached it, and was followed by a third, a fourth, and so on, till nine or ten eagles came together and soon disappeared. In the afternoon, Syevertsoff went to the place whereto he saw the eagles flying; concealed by one of the undulations of the Steppe, he approached them, and discovered that they had gathered around the corpse of a horse. The old ones, which, as a rule, begin the meal first—such are their rules of propriety-already were sitting upon the haystacks of the neighbourhood and kept watch, while the younger ones were continuing the meal, surrounded by bands of crows. From this and like observations, Syevertsoff concluded that the white-tailed eagles combine for hunting; when they all have risen to a great height they are enabled, if they are ten, to survey an area of at least twenty-five miles square; and as soon as any one has discovered something, he warns the others.(11) Of course, it might be argued that a simple instinctive cry of the first eagle, or even its movements, would have had the same effect of bringing several eagles to the prey. But in this case there is strong evidence in favour of mutual warning, because the ten eagles came together before descending towards the prey, and Syevertsoff had later on several opportunities of ascertaining that the whitetailed eagles always assemble for devouring a corpse, and that some of them (the younger ones first) always keep watch while the others are eating. In fact, the white-tailed eagle—one of the bravest and best hunters—is a gregarious bird altogether, and Brehm says that when kept in captivity it very soon contracts an attachment to its keepers.

However, associations that don’t go beyond family ties are relatively unimportant in our case, especially since we know of many associations for broader purposes, such as hunting, mutual protection, and even just enjoying life. Audubon noted that eagles sometimes gather for hunting, and his description of the two bald eagles, a male and a female, hunting over the Mississippi is well known for its vivid detail. But one of the most convincing observations comes from Syevertsoff. While studying the wildlife of the Russian Steppes, he once saw an eagle from a truly social species (the white-tailed eagle, Haliaetus albicilla) soaring high in the air. It flew in wide circles in silence for about half an hour, and then suddenly its sharp call was heard. This cry was soon answered by another eagle that approached, followed by a third, a fourth, and so on, until nine or ten eagles gathered and quickly disappeared. In the afternoon, Syevertsoff went to the place where he had seen the eagles fly; hidden by the rolling terrain of the Steppe, he crept up on them and found that they had gathered around a dead horse. The older ones, who usually start eating first—such are their manners—were sitting on nearby haystacks keeping watch, while the younger ones continued to feast, surrounded by groups of crows. From this and similar observations, Syevertsoff concluded that white-tailed eagles team up for hunting; when they rise to a great height, if there are ten of them, they can survey an area of at least twenty-five square miles, and as soon as one eagle spots something, it alerts the others. Of course, it could be argued that a simple instinctual call from the first eagle, or even its movements, could have the same effect of attracting several other eagles to the prey. But in this instance, there is strong evidence supporting mutual signaling, since the ten eagles came together before heading down to the food, and Syevertsoff later had several chances to confirm that white-tailed eagles always gather to eat a carcass, with some of them (the younger ones first) always keeping watch while the others eat. In fact, the white-tailed eagle—one of the most courageous and skilled hunters—is a social bird overall, and Brehm states that when kept in captivity, it quickly forms a bond with its caretakers.

Sociability is a common feature with very many other birds of prey. The Brazilian kite, one of the most "impudent" robbers, is nevertheless a most sociable bird. Its hunting associations have been described by Darwin and other naturalists, and it is a fact that when it has seized upon a prey which is too big, it calls together five or six friends to carry it away. After a busy day, when these kites retire for their night-rest to a tree or to the bushes, they always gather in bands, sometimes coming together from distances of ten or more miles, and they often are joined by several other vultures, especially the percnopters, "their true friends," D'Orbigny says. In another continent, in the Transcaspian deserts, they have, according to Zarudnyi, the same habit of nesting together. The sociable vulture, one of the strongest vultures, has received its very name from its love of society. They live in numerous bands, and decidedly enjoy society; numbers of them join in their high flights for sport. "They live in very good friendship," Le Vaillant says, "and in the same cave I sometimes found as many as three nests close together."(12) The Urubu vultures of Brazil are as, or perhaps even more, sociable than rooks.(13) The little Egyptian vultures live in close friendship. They play in bands in the air, they come together to spend the night, and in the morning they all go together to search for their food, and never does the slightest quarrel arise among them; such is the testimony of Brehm, who had plenty of opportunities of observing their life. The red-throated falcon is also met with in numerous bands in the forests of Brazil, and the kestrel (Tinnunculus cenchris), when it has left Europe, and has reached in the winter the prairies and forests of Asia, gathers in numerous societies. In the Steppes of South Russia it is (or rather was) so sociable that Nordmann saw them in numerous bands, with other falcons (Falco tinnunculus, F. oesulon, and F. subbuteo), coming together every fine afternoon about four o'clock, and enjoying their sports till late in the night. They set off flying, all at once, in a quite straight line, towards some determined point, and, having reached it, immediately returned over the same line, to repeat the same flight.(14)

Sociability is a common trait among many birds of prey. The Brazilian kite, one of the boldest thieves, is also a very social bird. Darwin and other naturalists have documented its hunting groups, and it's true that when it catches prey that's too large, it calls five or six friends to help carry it away. After a busy day, when these kites settle down for the night in a tree or bush, they always gather in groups, sometimes coming from distances of ten miles or more, and they're often joined by other vultures, especially the percnopters, "their true friends," according to D'Orbigny. In another part of the world, in the Transcaspian deserts, they also have the same habit of nesting together, according to Zarudnyi. The sociable vulture, one of the strongest vultures, got its name from its love of company. They live in large groups and really enjoy being social; many of them join in high flights just for fun. "They live in very good friendship," Le Vaillant says, "and in the same cave I sometimes found as many as three nests close together." The Urubu vultures in Brazil are just as social, if not more so, than rooks. The small Egyptian vultures live in tight-knit communities. They play in groups in the air, gather to spend the night, and in the morning, they all go together to look for food, never having the slightest argument among them; this is the observation of Brehm, who had plenty of chances to watch their lives. The red-throated falcon is also frequently found in large groups in the forests of Brazil, and the kestrel (Tinnunculus cenchris), after leaving Europe, gathers in numerous flocks in the prairies and forests of Asia for the winter. In the Steppes of South Russia, it was so sociable that Nordmann observed them in large groups with other falcons (Falco tinnunculus, F. oesulon, and F. subbuteo) coming together every nice afternoon around four o'clock, enjoying their play until late at night. They would take off flying all at once in a straight line towards a specific point, and after reaching it, they would immediately return along the same path to repeat the flight.

To take flights in flocks for the mere pleasure of the flight, is quite common among all sorts of birds. "In the Humber district especially," Ch. Dixon writes, "vast flights of dunlins often appear upon the mud-flats towards the end of August, and remain for the winter…. The movements of these birds are most interesting, as a vast flock wheels and spreads out or closes up with as much precision as drilled troops. Scattered among them are many odd stints and sanderlings and ringed-plovers."(15)

To fly together just for the fun of it is pretty common among all types of birds. "In the Humber area in particular," Ch. Dixon writes, "huge flocks of dunlins often show up on the mud-flats towards the end of August and stay for the winter…. The way these birds move is really fascinating, as a large flock turns and spreads out or gathers tightly with the same precision as trained soldiers. Mixed in with them are many odd stints, sanderlings, and ringed plovers."(15)

It would be quite impossible to enumerate here the various hunting associations of birds; but the fishing associations of the pelicans are certainly worthy of notice for the remarkable order and intelligence displayed by these clumsy birds. They always go fishing in numerous bands, and after having chosen an appropriate bay, they form a wide half-circle in face of the shore, and narrow it by paddling towards the shore, catching all fish that happen to be enclosed in the circle. On narrow rivers and canals they even divide into two parties, each of which draws up on a half-circle, and both paddle to meet each other, just as if two parties of men dragging two long nets should advance to capture all fish taken between the nets when both parties come to meet. As the night comes they fly to their resting-places—always the same for each flock—and no one has ever seen them fighting for the possession of either the bay or the resting place. In South America they gather in flocks of from forty to fifty thousand individuals, part of which enjoy sleep while the others keep watch, and others again go fishing.(16) And finally, I should be doing an injustice to the much-calumniated house-sparrows if I did not mention how faithfully each of them shares any food it discovers with all members of the society to which it belongs. The fact was known to the Greeks, and it has been transmitted to posterity how a Greek orator once exclaimed (I quote from memory):—"While I am speaking to you a sparrow has come to tell to other sparrows that a slave has dropped on the floor a sack of corn, and they all go there to feed upon the grain." The more, one is pleased to find this observation of old confirmed in a recent little book by Mr. Gurney, who does not doubt that the house sparrows always inform each other as to where there is some food to steal; he says, "When a stack has been thrashed ever so far from the yard, the sparrows in the yard have always had their crops full of the grain."(17) True, the sparrows are extremely particular in keeping their domains free from the invasions of strangers; thus the sparrows of the Jardin du Luxembourg bitterly fight all other sparrows which may attempt to enjoy their turn of the garden and its visitors; but within their own communities they fully practise mutual support, though occasionally there will be of course some quarrelling even amongst the best friends.

It would be impossible to list all the different bird hunting groups here, but the fishing techniques of pelicans are definitely notable for their impressive order and intelligence, despite their awkwardness. They always fish in large groups, and after picking a suitable bay, they create a wide half-circle facing the shore, which they gradually narrow by paddling toward the shore, catching any fish that get trapped within the circle. In narrower rivers and canals, they even split into two groups, each forming a half-circle, and then paddle toward each other, much like two teams of people dragging long nets to capture all the fish between them as they meet. As night falls, they fly to their regular resting spots—each flock has its own preferred locations—and no one has ever seen them fight over either the bay or the resting place. In South America, they gather in flocks of forty to fifty thousand, where some sleep while others keep watch, and some go fishing. Finally, I must give credit to the often-maligned house sparrows for how reliably they share any discovered food with all members of their group. This fact was known to the Greeks, and it has been passed down through the ages how a Greek orator once declared (I quote from memory):—“While I speak to you, a sparrow has come to tell other sparrows that a slave has dropped a sack of corn on the floor, and they all go there to eat the grain.” It’s gratifying to see this old observation confirmed in a recent little book by Mr. Gurney, who believes that house sparrows always inform one another about where there’s food to scavenge. He notes, “When a stack has been threshed far away from the yard, the sparrows in the yard always have their crops full of grain.” It’s true that sparrows are very particular about keeping their territory free from outside intruders; for example, the sparrows in the Jardin du Luxembourg fiercely fight off any other sparrows that try to enjoy their garden and the visitors there. However, within their own communities, they fully practice supporting one another, though, as you’d expect, some squabbling can arise even among the closest friends.

Hunting and feeding in common is so much the habit in the feathered world that more quotations hardly would be needful: it must be considered as an established fact. As to the force derived from such associations, it is self-evident. The strongest birds of prey are powerless in face of the associations of our smallest bird pets. Even eagles—even the powerful and terrible booted eagle, and the martial eagle, which is strong enough to carry away a hare or a young antelope in its claws—are compelled to abandon their prey to bands of those beggars the kites, which give the eagle a regular chase as soon as they see it in possession of a good prey. The kites will also give chase to the swift fishing-hawk, and rob it of the fish it has captured; but no one ever saw the kites fighting together for the possession of the prey so stolen. On the Kerguelen Island, Dr. Coues saw the gulls to Buphogus—the sea-hen of the sealers—pursue make them disgorge their food, while, on the other side, the gulls and the terns combined to drive away the sea-hen as soon as it came near to their abodes, especially at nesting-time.(18) The little, but extremely swift lapwings (Vanellus cristatus) boldly attack the birds of prey. "To see them attacking a buzzard, a kite, a crow, or an eagle, is one of the most amusing spectacles. One feels that they are sure of victory, and one sees the anger of the bird of prey. In such circumstances they perfectly support one another, and their courage grows with their numbers."(19) The lapwing has well merited the name of a "good mother" which the Greeks gave to it, for it never fails to protect other aquatic birds from the attacks of their enemies. But even the little white wagtails (Motacilla alba), whom we well know in our gardens and whose whole length hardly attains eight inches, compel the sparrow-hawk to abandon its hunt. "I often admired their courage and agility," the old Brehm wrote, "and I am persuaded that the falcon alone is capable of capturing any of them…. When a band of wagtails has compelled a bird of prey to retreat, they make the air resound with their triumphant cries, and after that they separate." They thus come together for the special purpose of giving chase to their enemy, just as we see it when the whole bird-population of a forest has been raised by the news that a nocturnal bird has made its appearance during the day, and all together—birds of prey and small inoffensive singers—set to chase the stranger and make it return to its concealment.

Hunting and foraging together is such a common behavior in the bird world that hardly any more examples are needed; it’s an established fact. The strength derived from these associations is obvious. The strongest birds of prey can’t defend themselves against the groups of our smallest pet birds. Even eagles—even the powerful and fearsome booted eagle and the martial eagle, strong enough to carry away a hare or a young antelope in its claws—have to give up their catch to gangs of those scavenging kites, which chase the eagle as soon as they spot it with good prey. The kites will also chase the agile fishing-hawk and steal the fish it has caught, but no one has ever seen the kites fighting among themselves over the stolen prey. On Kerguelen Island, Dr. Coues observed gulls driving away Buphogus—the sea-hen of sealers—forcing them to spit out their food, while on the other side, the gulls and terns teamed up to chase away the sea-hen whenever it got close to their nests, especially during nesting season. The small but incredibly fast lapwings (Vanellus cristatus) bravely attack birds of prey. "Watching them take on a buzzard, kite, crow, or eagle is one of the most entertaining sights. You can tell they are confident of winning, and you can see the anger of the bird of prey. In such situations, they support each other perfectly, and their courage grows with their numbers." The lapwing truly deserves the title of "good mother" that the Greeks gave it, as it always protects other water birds from their enemies. Even the tiny white wagtails (Motacilla alba), familiar to us in our gardens and measuring barely eight inches, can force a sparrow-hawk to give up its hunt. "I have often admired their bravery and agility," wrote the old Brehm, "and I believe that only a falcon could capture any of them ... When a group of wagtails forces a bird of prey to retreat, they fill the air with their triumphant cries, and afterwards they disperse." They come together specifically to chase off their enemy, just like when the entire bird population of a forest gets stirred up by the news that a nocturnal bird has appeared during the day, and all—both birds of prey and small peaceful songbirds—join in to chase the intruder back to its hiding place.

What an immense difference between the force of a kite, a buzzard or a hawk, and such small birds as the meadow-wagtail; and yet these little birds, by their common action and courage, prove superior to the powerfully-winged and armed robbers! In Europe, the wagtails not only chase the birds of prey which might be dangerous to them, but they chase also the fishing-hawk "rather for fun than for doing it any harm;" while in India, according to Dr. Jerdon's testimony, the jackdaws chase the gowinda-kite "for simple matter of amusement." Prince Wied saw the Brazilian eagle urubitinga surrounded by numberless flocks of toucans and cassiques (a bird nearly akin to our rook), which mocked it. "The eagle," he adds, "usually supports these insults very quietly, but from time to time it will catch one of these mockers." In all such cases the little birds, though very much inferior in force to the bird of prey, prove superior to it by their common action.(20)

What a huge difference between the strength of a kite, a buzzard, or a hawk, and small birds like the meadow-wagtail; yet these little birds, through their teamwork and bravery, show that they are stronger than the powerful and armed predators! In Europe, wagtails not only chase away predatory birds that might threaten them, but they also pursue the fishing-hawk "more for fun than to actually harm it;" while in India, as Dr. Jerdon noted, jackdaws chase the gowinda-kite "just for the sake of amusement." Prince Wied observed the Brazilian eagle urubitinga being surrounded by countless flocks of toucans and cassiques (a bird similar to our rook), which taunted it. "The eagle," he adds, "usually tolerates these insults very calmly, but now and then it will catch one of these jesters." In all these situations, the little birds, despite being much weaker than the predatory bird, manage to come out on top through their collective action.

However, the most striking effects of common life for the security of the individual, for its enjoyment of life, and for the development of its intellectual capacities, are seen in two great families of birds, the cranes and the parrots. The cranes are extremely sociable and live in most excellent relations, not only with their congeners, but also with most aquatic birds. Their prudence is really astonishing, so also their intelligence; they grasp the new conditions in a moment, and act accordingly. Their sentries always keep watch around a flock which is feeding or resting, and the hunters know well how difficult it is to approach them. If man has succeeded in surprising them, they will never return to the same place without having sent out one single scout first, and a party of scouts afterwards; and when the reconnoitring party returns and reports that there is no danger, a second group of scouts is sent out to verify the first report, before the whole band moves. With kindred species the cranes contract real friendship; and in captivity there is no bird, save the also sociable and highly intelligent parrot, which enters into such real friendship with man. "It sees in man, not a master, but a friend, and endeavours to manifest it," Brehm concludes from a wide personal experience. The crane is in continual activity from early in the morning till late in the night; but it gives a few hours only in the morning to the task of searching its food, chiefly vegetable. All the remainder of the day is given to society life. "It picks up small pieces of wood or small stones, throws them in the air and tries to catch them; it bends its neck, opens its wings, dances, jumps, runs about, and tries to manifest by all means its good disposition of mind, and always it remains graceful and beautiful."(21) As it lives in society it has almost no enemies, and though Brehm occasionally saw one of them captured by a crocodile, he wrote that except the crocodile he knew no enemies of the crane. It eschews all of them by its proverbial prudence; and it attains, as a rule, a very old age. No wonder that for the maintenance of the species the crane need not rear a numerous offspring; it usually hatches but two eggs. As to its superior intelligence, it is sufficient to say that all observers are unanimous in recognizing that its intellectual capacities remind one very much of those of man.

However, the most noticeable effects of common life on the security of the individual, on enjoying life, and on developing intellectual abilities are seen in two major families of birds: the cranes and the parrots. Cranes are incredibly social and maintain excellent relationships not just with their own kind but also with many aquatic birds. Their caution is quite remarkable, as is their intelligence; they quickly adapt to new situations and respond accordingly. Their sentries always keep watch over a flock that is feeding or resting, and hunters understand just how hard it is to approach them. If humans manage to surprise them, they will never return to the same spot without first sending out a single scout, and then a group of scouts afterwards. When the scouting party returns and reports no danger, a second group of scouts is sent out to confirm the first report before the entire flock moves. Cranes form genuine friendships with similar species, and in captivity, no bird—except the equally social and highly intelligent parrot—develops such a true bond with humans. "It sees in man, not a master, but a friend, and tries to show it," Brehm concludes from his extensive personal experience. Cranes are active from early morning until late at night; however, they only spend a few hours in the morning looking for food, primarily plant-based. The rest of the day is dedicated to socializing. "It picks up small pieces of wood or stones, tosses them in the air, and tries to catch them; it bends its neck, spreads its wings, dances, jumps, runs around, and tries in every way to express its cheerful mood, always remaining graceful and beautiful." Because they live socially, cranes have very few enemies, and while Brehm occasionally saw one captured by a crocodile, he noted that apart from the crocodile, he knew of no foes to the crane. They avoid all threats due to their well-known caution and generally live to a very old age. It’s no wonder that cranes do not need to raise a large number of young to maintain their species; they typically hatch only two eggs. As for their superior intelligence, all observers agree that their intellectual abilities closely resemble those of humans.

The other extremely sociable bird, the parrot, stands, as known, at the very top of the whole feathered world for the development of its intelligence. Brehm has so admirably summed up the manners of life of the parrot, that I cannot do better than translate the following sentence:—

The other very sociable bird, the parrot, is widely regarded as the most intelligent of all birds. Brehm has wonderfully summarized the parrot's way of life, so I can't improve on translating the following sentence:—

"Except in the pairing season, they live in very numerous societies or bands. They choose a place in the forest to stay there, and thence they start every morning for their hunting expeditions. The members of each band remain faithfully attached to each other, and they share in common good or bad luck. All together they repair in the morning to a field, or to a garden, or to a tree, to feed upon fruits. They post sentries to keep watch over the safety of the whole band, and are attentive to their warnings. In case of danger, all take to flight, mutually supporting each other, and all simultaneously return to their resting-place. In a word, they always live closely united."

"Except during mating season, they live in large groups or bands. They pick a spot in the forest to settle down and head out every morning for their hunting trips. The members of each band stay closely connected, sharing both good and bad fortune. Together, they go to a field, a garden, or a tree in the morning to eat fruits. They assign sentries to watch over the safety of the entire group and pay attention to their alerts. If there is danger, they all flee together, helping each other out, and then return to their resting place at the same time. In short, they always stay tightly united."

They enjoy society of other birds as well. In India, the jays and crows come together from many miles round, to spend the night in company with the parrots in the bamboo thickets. When the parrots start hunting, they display the most wonderful intelligence, prudence, and capacity of coping with circumstances. Take, for instance, a band of white cacadoos in Australia. Before starting to plunder a corn-field, they first send out a reconnoitring party which occupies the highest trees in the vicinity of the field, while other scouts perch upon the intermediate trees between the field and the forest and transmit the signals. If the report runs "All right," a score of cacadoos will separate from the bulk of the band, take a flight in the air, and then fly towards the trees nearest to the field. They also will scrutinize the neighbourhood for a long while, and only then will they give the signal for general advance, after which the whole band starts at once and plunders the field in no time. The Australian settlers have the greatest difficulties in beguiling the prudence of the parrots; but if man, with all his art and weapons, has succeeded in killing some of them, the cacadoos become so prudent and watchful that they henceforward baffle all stratagems.(22)

They also enjoy the company of other birds. In India, jays and crows gather from many miles around to spend the night with the parrots in the bamboo thickets. When the parrots go foraging, they show amazing intelligence, caution, and ability to adapt to situations. For example, a group of white cockatoos in Australia. Before they raid a cornfield, they first send out a scouting party that takes positions in the tallest trees nearby, while other scouts settle in the trees between the field and the forest to relay signals. If the report comes back "All clear," a group of cockatoos will break off from the main flock, take to the air, and then fly toward the trees nearest to the field. They will carefully check out the area for a while, and only then will they give the signal to advance, at which point the entire flock launches an attack and ravages the field in no time. The Australian settlers find it extremely difficult to outsmart the cleverness of the parrots, but if humans, with all their tricks and weapons, manage to kill a few, the cockatoos become so cautious and alert that they effectively thwart all future plans.

There can be no doubt that it is the practice of life in society which enables the parrots to attain that very high level of almost human intelligence and almost human feelings which we know in them. Their high intelligence has induced the best naturalists to describe some species, namely the grey parrot, as the "birdman." As to their mutual attachment it is known that when a parrot has been killed by a hunter, the others fly over the corpse of their comrade with shrieks of complaints and "themselves fall the victims of their friendship," as Audubon said; and when two captive parrots, though belonging to two different species, have contracted mutual friendship, the accidental death of one of the two friends has sometimes been followed by the death from grief and sorrow of the other friend. It is no less evident that in their societies they find infinitely more protection than they possibly might find in any ideal development of beak and claw. Very few birds of prey or mammals dare attack any but the smaller species of parrots, and Brehm is absolutely right in saying of the parrots, as he also says of the cranes and the sociable monkeys, that they hardly have any enemies besides men; and he adds: "It is most probable that the larger parrots succumb chiefly to old age rather than die from the claws of any enemies." Only man, owing to his still more superior intelligence and weapons, also derived from association, succeeds in partially destroying them. Their very longevity would thus appear as a result of their social life. Could we not say the same as regards their wonderful memory, which also must be favoured in its development by society—life and by longevity accompanied by a full enjoyment of bodily and mental faculties till a very old age?

There’s no doubt that living in groups helps parrots develop a high level of near-human intelligence and feelings. Their exceptional intelligence has led top naturalists to refer to some species, especially the grey parrot, as the "birdman." It's well known that when a parrot is killed by a hunter, the others will fly over their fallen friend, screaming in distress, and as Audubon noted, “they themselves fall the victims of their friendship.” When two captive parrots from different species become friends, the accidental death of one can sometimes lead to the other dying from grief. It's also clear that in their communities, they find far more protection than they could ever achieve through physical traits like beaks and claws. Very few predators or mammals dare to attack anything but the smaller types of parrots. Brehm is absolutely correct in saying that parrots, like cranes and social monkeys, have few enemies besides humans; he adds, “It’s likely that larger parrots mostly die from old age rather than from being attacked by predators.” Only humans, with their superior intelligence and weapons—also a result of living in society—are able to significantly threaten them. Their long lifespans seem to be a benefit of their social nature. Could we not say the same about their amazing memory, which must also be enhanced by their social lives and the enjoyment of their physical and mental abilities well into old age?

As seen from the above, the war of each against all is not the law of nature. Mutual aid is as much a law of nature as mutual struggle, and that law will become still more apparent when we have analyzed some other associations of birds and those of the mammalia. A few hints as to the importance of the law of mutual aid for the evolution of the animal kingdom have already been given in the preceding pages; but their purport will still better appear when, after having given a few more illustrations, we shall be enabled presently to draw therefrom our conclusions.

As shown above, the idea that everyone is against everyone else isn't the law of nature. Helping each other is just as natural as competing, and this will become even clearer when we analyze other groups of birds and mammals. We've already touched on the significance of mutual aid for the evolution of animals in the previous pages, but its meaning will be clearer when we provide a few more examples, allowing us to draw our conclusions soon.

NOTES:

1. Origin of Species, chap. iii, p. 62 of first edition.

1. Origin of Species, chap. iii, p. 62 of the first edition.

2. Nineteenth Century, Feb. 1888, p. 165.

2. Nineteenth Century, Feb. 1888, p. 165.

3. Leaving aside the pre-Darwinian writers, like Toussenel, Fee, and many others, several works containing many striking instances of mutual aid—chiefly, however, illustrating animal intelligence were issued previously to that date. I may mention those of Houzeau, Les facultes etales des animaux, 2 vols., Brussels, 1872; L. Buchner's Aus dem Geistesleben der Thiere, 2nd ed. in 1877; and Maximilian Perty's Ueber das Seelenleben der Thiere, Leipzig, 1876. Espinas published his most remarkable work, Les Societes animales, in 1877, and in that work he pointed out the importance of animal societies, and their bearing upon the preservation of species, and entered upon a most valuable discussion of the origin of societies. In fact, Espinas's book contains all that has been written since upon mutual aid, and many good things besides. If I nevertheless make a special mention of Kessler's address, it is because he raised mutual aid to the height of a law much more important in evolution than the law of mutual struggle. The same ideas were developed next year (in April 1881) by J. Lanessan in a lecture published in 1882 under this title: La lutte pour l'existence et l'association pour la lutte. G. Romanes's capital work, Animal Intelligence, was issued in 1882, and followed next year by the Mental Evolution in Animals. About the same time (1883), Buchner published another work, Liebe und Liebes-Leben in der Thierwelt, a second edition of which was issued in 1885. The idea, as seen, was in the air.

3. Putting aside the writers before Darwin, like Toussenel, Fee, and many others, several works filled with impressive examples of mutual aid—mostly focusing on animal intelligence—were published before that time. I can mention Houzeau's *Les facultes etales des animaux*, 2 vols., Brussels, 1872; L. Buchner's *Aus dem Geistesleben der Thiere*, 2nd ed. in 1877; and Maximilian Perty's *Ueber das Seelenleben der Thiere*, Leipzig, 1876. Espinas released his most significant work, *Les Societes animales*, in 1877, where he emphasized the importance of animal societies and how they relate to species survival, providing a valuable discussion on the origin of societies. In fact, Espinas's book includes everything that has been written since about mutual aid, along with many other valuable insights. The reason I still highlight Kessler's address is that he elevated mutual aid to a law that is far more significant in evolution than the law of mutual struggle. Similar ideas were discussed the following year (in April 1881) by J. Lanessan in a lecture published in 1882 titled *La lutte pour l'existence et l'association pour la lutte*. G. Romanes's important work, *Animal Intelligence*, was published in 1882 and followed the next year by *Mental Evolution in Animals*. Around the same time (1883), Buchner released another work, *Liebe und Liebes-Leben in der Thierwelt*, with a second edition released in 1885. As you can see, the idea was in the air.

4. Memoirs (Trudy) of the St. Petersburg Society of Naturalists, vol. xi. 1880.

4. Memoirs (Trudy) of the St. Petersburg Society of Naturalists, vol. xi. 1880.

5. George J. Romanes's Animal Intelligence, 1st ed. p. 233.

5. George J. Romanes's Animal Intelligence, 1st ed. p. 233.

6. Pierre Huber's Les fourmis indigees, Geneve, 1861; Forel's Recherches sur les fourmis de la Suisse, Zurich, 1874, and J.T. Moggridge's Harvesting Ants and Trapdoor Spiders, London, 1873 and 1874, ought to be in the hands of every boy and girl. See also: Blanchard's Metamorphoses des Insectes, Paris, 1868; J.H. Fabre's Souvenirs entomologiques, Paris, 1886; Ebrard's Etudes des moeurs des fourmis, Geneve, 1864; Sir John Lubbock's Ants, Bees, and Wasps, and so on.

6. Pierre Huber's Indigenous Ants, Geneva, 1861; Forel's Research on Ants of Switzerland, Zurich, 1874, and J.T. Moggridge's Harvesting Ants and Trapdoor Spiders, London, 1873 and 1874, should be in the hands of every boy and girl. Also, check out Blanchard's Metamorphoses of Insects, Paris, 1868; J.H. Fabre's Entomological Memories, Paris, 1886; Ebrard's Studies on the Habits of Ants, Geneva, 1864; Sir John Lubbock's Ants, Bees, and Wasps, and more.

7. Forel's Recherches, pp. 244, 275, 278. Huber's description of the process is admirable. It also contains a hint as to the possible origin of the instinct (popular edition, pp. 158, 160). See Appendix II.

7. Forel's Research, pp. 244, 275, 278. Huber's description of the process is impressive. It also gives a clue about the possible origin of the instinct (popular edition, pp. 158, 160). See Appendix II.

8. The agriculture of the ants is so wonderful that for a long time it has been doubted. The fact is now so well proved by Mr. Moggridge, Dr. Lincecum, Mr. MacCook, Col. Sykes, and Dr. Jerdon, that no doubt is possible. See an excellent summary of evidence in Mr. Romanes's work. See also Die Pilzgaerten einiger Sud-Amerikanischen Ameisen, by Alf. Moeller, in Schimper's Botan. Mitth. aus den Tropen, vi. 1893.

8. The farming practices of ants are so remarkable that they’ve been questioned for a long time. However, this has now been clearly demonstrated by Mr. Moggridge, Dr. Lincecum, Mr. MacCook, Col. Sykes, and Dr. Jerdon, leaving no room for doubt. Check out an excellent summary of evidence in Mr. Romanes's work. Also, see Die Pilzgaerten einiger Sud-Amerikanischen Ameisen, by Alf. Moeller, in Schimper's Botan. Mitth. aus den Tropen, vi. 1893.

9. This second principle was not recognized at once. Former observers often spoke of kings, queens, managers, and so on; but since Huber and Forel have published their minute observations, no doubt is possible as to the free scope left for every individual's initiative in whatever the ants do, including their wars.

9. This second principle wasn’t recognized right away. Previous observers often referred to kings, queens, managers, and so on; however, since Huber and Forel published their detailed observations, there is no doubt about the freedom given to each individual’s initiative in everything the ants do, including their wars.

10. H.W. Bates, The Naturalist on the River Amazons, ii. 59 seq.

10. H.W. Bates, The Naturalist on the River Amazons, ii. 59 and following.

11. N. Syevertsoff, Periodical Phenomena in the Life of Mammalia, Birds, and Reptiles of Voroneje, Moscow, 1855 (in Russian).

11. N. Syevertsoff, Periodical Phenomena in the Life of Mammals, Birds, and Reptiles of Voroneje, Moscow, 1855 (in Russian).

12. A. Brehm, Life of Animals, iii. 477; all quotations after the French edition.

12. A. Brehm, Life of Animals, iii. 477; all quotes are from the French edition.

13. Bates, p. 151.

Bates, p. 151.

14. Catalogue raisonne des oiseaux de la faune pontique, in Demidoff's Voyage; abstracts in Brehm, iii. 360. During their migrations birds of prey often associate. One flock, which H. Seebohm saw crossing the Pyrenees, represented a curious assemblage of "eight kites, one crane, and a peregrine falcon" (The Birds of Siberia, 1901, p. 417).

14. Catalogue raisonné of the birds from the Pontic fauna, in Demidoff's Voyage; summaries in Brehm, iii. 360. During migration, birds of prey often group together. One flock, which H. Seebohm observed while crossing the Pyrenees, was an interesting mix of "eight kites, one crane, and a peregrine falcon" (The Birds of Siberia, 1901, p. 417).

15. Birds in the Northern Shires, p. 207.

15. Birds in the Northern Shires, p. 207.

16. Max. Perty, Ueber das Seelenleben der Thiere (Leipzig, 1876), pp. 87, 103.

16. Max. Perty, On the Mental Life of Animals (Leipzig, 1876), pp. 87, 103.

17. G. H. Gurney, The House-Sparrow (London, 1885), p. 5.

17. G. H. Gurney, The House-Sparrow (London, 1885), p. 5.

18. Dr. Elliot Coues, Birds of the Kerguelen Island, in Smithsonian Miscellaneous Collections, vol. xiii. No. 2, p. 11.

18. Dr. Elliot Coues, Birds of Kerguelen Island, in Smithsonian Miscellaneous Collections, vol. xiii. No. 2, p. 11.

19. Brehm, iv. 567.

19. Brehm, vol. 4, p. 567.

20. As to the house-sparrows, a New Zealand observer, Mr. T.W. Kirk, described as follows the attack of these "impudent" birds upon an "unfortunate" hawk.—"He heard one day a most unusual noise, as though all the small birds of the country had joined in one grand quarrel. Looking up, he saw a large hawk (C. gouldi—a carrion feeder) being buffeted by a flock of sparrows. They kept dashing at him in scores, and from all points at once. The unfortunate hawk was quite powerless. At last, approaching some scrub, the hawk dashed into it and remained there, while the sparrows congregated in groups round the bush, keeping up a constant chattering and noise" (Paper read before the New Zealand Institute; Nature, Oct. 10, 1891).

20. Regarding the house sparrows, a New Zealand observer, Mr. T.W. Kirk, described the attack of these "bold" birds on an "unlucky" hawk. "One day, he heard a really unusual noise, as if all the small birds in the area were engaged in one huge fight. When he looked up, he saw a large hawk (C. gouldi—a carrion eater) being bombarded by a group of sparrows. They kept swooping at him in large numbers from all directions at once. The poor hawk was totally helpless. Finally, as it neared some bushes, the hawk darted into them and stayed there, while the sparrows gathered in groups around the bush, maintaining a constant chatter and noise" (Paper read before the New Zealand Institute; Nature, Oct. 10, 1891).

21. Brehm, iv. 671 seq.

21. Brehm, iv. 671 and following.

22. R. Lendenfeld, in Der zoologische Garten, 1889.

22. R. Lendenfeld, in The Zoological Garden, 1889.

CHAPTER II

MUTUAL AID AMONG ANIMALS (continued)

MUTUAL AID AMONG ANIMALS (continued)

Migrations of birds. Breeding associations. Autumn societies. Mammals: small number of unsociable species. Hunting associations of wolves, lions, etc. Societies of rodents; of ruminants; of monkeys. Mutual Aid in the struggle for life. Darwin's arguments to prove the struggle for life within the species. Natural checks to over-multiplication. Supposed extermination of intermediate links. Elimination of competition in Nature.

Migrations of birds. Breeding groups. Autumn communities. Mammals: a small number of solitary species. Hunting packs of wolves, lions, etc. Societies of rodents, ruminants, and monkeys. Cooperation in the fight for survival. Darwin's arguments to show the struggle for survival within species. Natural checks on overpopulation. The assumed extinction of intermediate species. The removal of competition in nature.

As soon as spring comes back to the temperate zone, myriads and myriads of birds which are scattered over the warmer regions of the South come together in numberless bands, and, full of vigour and joy, hasten northwards to rear their offspring. Each of our hedges, each grove, each ocean cliff, and each of the lakes and ponds with which Northern America, Northern Europe, and Northern Asia are dotted tell us at that time of the year the tale of what mutual aid means for the birds; what force, energy, and protection it confers to every living being, however feeble and defenceless it otherwise might be. Take, for instance, one of the numberless lakes of the Russian and Siberian Steppes. Its shores are peopled with myriads of aquatic birds, belonging to at least a score of different species, all living in perfect peace—all protecting one another.

As soon as spring returns to the temperate zone, countless birds that are spread across the warmer regions of the South come together in numerous flocks and, filled with energy and joy, rush north to raise their young. Each of our hedges, groves, ocean cliffs, and the lakes and ponds scattered across Northern America, Northern Europe, and Northern Asia tells us at this time of year the story of what mutual aid means for the birds; the strength, energy, and protection it provides to every living creature, no matter how weak and defenseless it may be. For example, take one of the many lakes in the Russian and Siberian Steppes. Its shores are populated with countless aquatic birds from at least twenty different species, all living in perfect harmony—each one looking out for the others.

"For several hundred yards from the shore the air is filled with gulls and terns, as with snow-flakes on a winter day. Thousands of plovers and sand-coursers run over the beach, searching their food, whistling, and simply enjoying life. Further on, on almost each wave, a duck is rocking, while higher up you notice the flocks of the Casarki ducks. Exuberant life swarms everywhere."(1)

"For several hundred yards from the shore, the air is filled with seagulls and terns, like snowflakes on a winter day. Thousands of plovers and sandpipers run along the beach, foraging for food, whistling, and just enjoying life. Further along, on almost every wave, a duck is bobbing, while higher up you can see the flocks of Casarki ducks. Vibrant life is everywhere."(1)

And here are the robbers—the strongest, the most cunning ones, those "ideally organized for robbery." And you hear their hungry, angry, dismal cries as for hours in succession they watch the opportunity of snatching from this mass of living beings one single unprotected individual. But as soon as they approach, their presence is signalled by dozens of voluntary sentries, and hundreds of gulls and terns set to chase the robber. Maddened by hunger, the robber soon abandons his usual precautions: he suddenly dashes into the living mass; but, attacked from all sides, he again is compelled to retreat. From sheer despair he falls upon the wild ducks; but the intelligent, social birds rapidly gather in a flock and fly away if the robber is an erne; they plunge into the lake if it is a falcon; or they raise a cloud of water-dust and bewilder the assailant if it is a kite.(2) And while life continues to swarm on the lake, the robber flies away with cries of anger, and looks out for carrion, or for a young bird or a field-mouse not yet used to obey in time the warnings of its comrades. In the face of an exuberant life, the ideally-armed robber must be satisfied with the off-fall of that life.

And here are the robbers—the strongest, the most cunning ones, those "perfectly organized for theft." You hear their hungry, angry, dismal cries as they spend hours waiting for a chance to snatch one unprotected individual from this mass of living beings. But as soon as they get close, their presence is signaled by dozens of voluntary sentries, and hundreds of gulls and terns set off to chase the robber away. Driven by hunger, the robber soon drops his usual precautions: he suddenly rushes into the living mass; but, attacked from all sides, he has to retreat again. In sheer desperation, he targets the wild ducks; but the clever, social birds quickly form a flock and fly away if the robber is an erne; they dive into the lake if it’s a falcon; or they create a cloud of water-spray to confuse the attacker if it’s a kite. While life continues to thrive on the lake, the robber flies off, crying out in anger, looking for carrion or a young bird or a field mouse that hasn’t yet learned to heed the warnings of its friends. In the midst of such vibrant life, the perfectly equipped robber must settle for the leftovers of that life.

Further north, in the Arctic archipelagoes,

Further north, in the Arctic islands,

"you may sail along the coast for many miles and see all the ledges, all the cliffs and corners of the mountain-sides, up to a height of from two to five hundred feet, literally covered with sea-birds, whose white breasts show against the dark rocks as if the rocks were closely sprinkled with chalk specks. The air, near and far, is, so to say, full with fowls."(3)

"you can cruise along the coast for many miles and see all the ledges, cliffs, and corners of the mountains rising around two to five hundred feet high, literally covered with seabirds, whose white breasts stand out against the dark rocks as if the rocks were sprinkled with chalk spots. The air, both near and far, is, so to speak, full of birds."(3)

Each of such "bird-mountains" is a living illustration of mutual aid, as well as of the infinite variety of characters, individual and specific, resulting from social life. The oyster-catcher is renowned for its readiness to attack the birds of prey. The barge is known for its watchfulness, and it easily becomes the leader of more placid birds. The turnstone, when surrounded by comrades belonging to more energetic species, is a rather timorous bird; but it undertakes to keep watch for the security of the commonwealth when surrounded by smaller birds. Here you have the dominative swans; there, the extremely sociable kittiwake-gulls, among whom quarrels are rare and short; the prepossessing polar guillemots, which continually caress each other; the egoist she-goose, who has repudiated the orphans of a killed comrade; and, by her side, another female who adopts any one's orphans, and now paddles surrounded by fifty or sixty youngsters, whom she conducts and cares for as if they all were her own breed. Side by side with the penguins, which steal one another's eggs, you have the dotterels, whose family relations are so "charming and touching" that even passionate hunters recoil from shooting a female surrounded by her young ones; or the eider-ducks, among which (like the velvet-ducks, or the coroyas of the Savannahs) several females hatch together in the same nest, or the lums, which sit in turn upon a common covey. Nature is variety itself, offering all possible varieties of characters, from the basest to the highest: and that is why she cannot be depicted by any sweeping assertion. Still less can she be judged from the moralist's point of view, because the views of the moralist are themselves a result—mostly unconscious—of the observation of Nature.

Each of these "bird-mountains" is a living example of mutual aid, as well as the endless variety of individual characters shaped by social life. The oyster-catcher is famous for its willingness to confront birds of prey. The barge is known for its vigilance and often takes the lead among more docile birds. The turnstone, when with more active companions, is a rather timid bird; however, it steps up to guard the community when with smaller species. Here you have the dominant swans; there, the very friendly kittiwake-gulls, which rarely have long or serious disputes; the charming polar guillemots, who are always showing affection to each other; the selfish female goose, who has abandoned the orphans of a deceased comrade; and beside her, another female who takes in any orphaned chicks, now swimming with fifty or sixty young ones, caring for them as if they were all her own. Next to the penguins, who steal each other's eggs, are the dotterels, whose family ties are so "lovely and touching" that even dedicated hunters hesitate to shoot a female with her chicks; or the eider-ducks, among which, like the velvet-ducks or the coroyas of the savannahs, several females will collectively hatch eggs in the same nest, or the lums, which take turns sitting on a communal brood. Nature is pure variety, showcasing every kind of character, from the lowest to the highest: that's why she can't be captured by any broad generalization. Even more so, she can't be evaluated from a moral standpoint, since moral perspectives are largely an unconscious product of observing Nature.

Coming together at nesting-time is so common with most birds that more examples are scarcely needed. Our trees are crowned with groups of crows' nests; our hedges are full of nests of smaller birds; our farmhouses give shelter to colonies of swallows; our old towers are the refuge of hundreds of nocturnal birds; and pages might be filled with the most charming descriptions of the peace and harmony which prevail in almost all these nesting associations. As to the protection derived by the weakest birds from their unions, it is evident. That excellent observer, Dr. Coues, saw, for instance, the little cliff-swallows nesting in the immediate neighbourhood of the prairie falcon (Falco polyargus). The falcon had its nest on the top of one of the minarets of clay which are so common in the canons of Colorado, while a colony of swallows nested just beneath. The little peaceful birds had no fear of their rapacious neighbour; they never let it approach to their colony. They immediately surrounded it and chased it, so that it had to make off at once.(4)

Coming together during nesting season is so common for most birds that we hardly need more examples. Our trees are filled with groups of crows' nests; our hedges are packed with nests of smaller birds; our farmhouses provide shelter for colonies of swallows; our old towers are home to hundreds of nocturnal birds; and we could fill pages with the beautiful descriptions of the peace and harmony present in almost all these nesting communities. As for the protection that weaker birds gain from these unions, it’s clear. That keen observer, Dr. Coues, noted, for example, the little cliff swallows nesting right next to the prairie falcon (Falco polyargus). The falcon had its nest on top of one of the clay minarets that are common in the canyons of Colorado, while a colony of swallows nested just below. The little peaceful birds had no fear of their predatory neighbor; they never allowed it near their colony. They quickly surrounded it and chased it off, forcing it to leave immediately.

Life in societies does not cease when the nesting period is over; it begins then in a new form. The young broods gather in societies of youngsters, generally including several species. Social life is practised at that time chiefly for its own sake—partly for security, but chiefly for the pleasures derived from it. So we see in our forests the societies formed by the young nuthatchers (Sitta caesia), together with tit-mouses, chaffinches, wrens, tree-creepers, or some wood-peckers.(5) In Spain the swallow is met with in company with kestrels, fly-catchers, and even pigeons. In the Far West of America the young horned larks live in large societies, together with another lark (Sprague's), the skylark, the Savannah sparrow, and several species of buntings and longspurs.(6) In fact, it would be much easier to describe the species which live isolated than to simply name those species which join the autumnal societies of young birds—not for hunting or nesting purposes, but simply to enjoy life in society and to spend their time in plays and sports, after having given a few hours every day to find their daily food.

Life in communities doesn’t stop when nesting season ends; it starts anew in a different way. The young birds come together in groups, usually made up of several species. They socialize mainly for its own sake—partly for safety, but mostly for the enjoyment it brings. In our forests, we see young nuthatches hanging out with titmice, chaffinches, wrens, treecreepers, and even some woodpeckers. In Spain, you’ll find swallows mingling with kestrels, flycatchers, and even pigeons. In the western United States, young horned larks form large groups alongside another lark (Sprague's), skylarks, Savannah sparrows, and various types of buntings and longspurs. In fact, it’s much simpler to list the species that live alone than to name all the species that join the autumn groups of young birds—not for hunting or nesting, but just to enjoy company and have fun after spending a few hours each day looking for food.

And, finally, we have that immense display of mutual aid among birds-their migrations—which I dare not even enter upon in this place. Sufficient to say that birds which have lived for months in small bands scattered over a wide territory gather in thousands; they come together at a given place, for several days in succession, before they start, and they evidently discuss the particulars of the journey. Some species will indulge every afternoon in flights preparatory to the long passage. All wait for their tardy congeners, and finally they start in a certain well chosen direction—a fruit of accumulated collective experience—the strongest flying at the head of the band, and relieving one another in that difficult task. They cross the seas in large bands consisting of both big and small birds, and when they return next spring they repair to the same spot, and, in most cases, each of them takes possession of the very same nest which it had built or repaired the previous year.(7)

And finally, we see an incredible display of teamwork among birds—their migrations—which I won’t delve into here. It's enough to say that birds that have spent months in small groups spread across a wide area come together in the thousands. They gather at a specific spot for several days before they set off, clearly discussing the details of their journey. Some species practice flying every afternoon to get ready for the long trip. They all wait for their slower companions, and then they take off in a carefully chosen direction—based on their shared experiences—with the strongest birds leading the way and taking turns in that challenging role. They cross the oceans in large flocks that include both big and small birds, and when they return the following spring, they go back to the same location, and in most cases, each one occupies the exact nest they built or fixed up the year before.

This subject is so vast, and yet so imperfectly studied; it offers so many striking illustrations of mutual-aid habits, subsidiary to the main fact of migration—each of which would, however, require a special study—that I must refrain from entering here into more details. I can only cursorily refer to the numerous and animated gatherings of birds which take place, always on the same spot, before they begin their long journeys north or south, as also those which one sees in the north, after the birds have arrived at their breeding-places on the Yenisei or in the northern counties of England. For many days in succession—sometimes one month—they will come together every morning for one hour, before flying in search of food—perhaps discussing the spot where they are going to build their nests.(8) And if, during the migration, their columns are overtaken by a storm, birds of the most different species will be brought together by common misfortune. The birds which are not exactly migratory, but slowly move northwards and southwards with the seasons, also perform these peregrinations in flocks. So far from migrating isolately, in order to secure for each separate individual the advantages of better food or shelter which are to be found in another district—they always wait for each other, and gather in flocks, before they move north or south, in accordance with the season.(9)

This topic is really broad and yet still not fully explored; it shows many fascinating examples of mutual aid that support the main concept of migration—each one of these examples would require its own detailed study—so I won’t go into more specifics here. I can only briefly mention the numerous lively gatherings of birds that happen, always at the same location, before they start their long trips north or south, as well as those that occur in the north after the birds arrive at their breeding sites along the Yenisei or in the northern regions of England. For several days in a row—sometimes up to a month—they will meet every morning for about an hour before flying off in search of food—possibly discussing where they plan to build their nests.(8) And if a storm catches their flocks during migration, birds of very different species will come together because of shared misfortune. The birds that aren’t strictly migratory but move slowly north and south with the seasons also travel in groups. Instead of migrating alone to secure better food or shelter that might be available in other areas, they always wait for one another and gather in flocks before heading north or south, depending on the season.(9)

Going now over to mammals, the first thing which strikes us is the overwhelming numerical predominance of social species over those few carnivores which do not associate. The plateaus, the Alpine tracts, and the Steppes of the Old and New World are stocked with herds of deer, antelopes, gazelles, fallow deer, buffaloes, wild goats and sheep, all of which are sociable animals. When the Europeans came to settle in America, they found it so densely peopled with buffaloes, that pioneers had to stop their advance when a column of migrating buffaloes came to cross the route they followed; the march past of the dense column lasting sometimes for two and three days. And when the Russians took possession of Siberia they found it so densely peopled with deer, antelopes, squirrels, and other sociable animals, that the very conquest of Siberia was nothing but a hunting expedition which lasted for two hundred years; while the grass plains of Eastern Africa are still covered with herds composed of zebra, the hartebeest, and other antelopes.

Shifting our focus to mammals, the first thing that stands out is the striking numerical dominance of social species over the few carnivores that are solitary. The plateaus, Alpine regions, and Steppes of both the Old and New Worlds are filled with herds of deer, antelopes, gazelles, fallow deer, buffalo, wild goats, and sheep— all of which are social animals. When Europeans settled in America, they encountered such vast numbers of buffalo that pioneers had to halt their progress whenever a herd of migrating buffalo crossed their path, with the migration sometimes taking two to three days. When the Russians took control of Siberia, they found it teeming with deer, antelopes, squirrels, and other social animals, making the conquest of Siberia essentially a hunting expedition that lasted for two hundred years; meanwhile, the grasslands of Eastern Africa are still populated with herds of zebras, hartebeests, and other antelopes.

Not long ago the small streams of Northern America and Northern Siberia were peopled with colonies of beavers, and up to the seventeenth century like colonies swarmed in Northern Russia. The flat lands of the four great continents are still covered with countless colonies of mice, ground-squirrels, marmots, and other rodents. In the lower latitudes of Asia and Africa the forests are still the abode of numerous families of elephants, rhinoceroses, and numberless societies of monkeys. In the far north the reindeer aggregate in numberless herds; while still further north we find the herds of the musk-oxen and numberless bands of polar foxes. The coasts of the ocean are enlivened by flocks of seals and morses; its waters, by shoals of sociable cetaceans; and even in the depths of the great plateau of Central Asia we find herds of wild horses, wild donkeys, wild camels, and wild sheep. All these mammals live in societies and nations sometimes numbering hundreds of thousands of individuals, although now, after three centuries of gunpowder civilization, we find but the debris of the immense aggregations of old. How trifling, in comparison with them, are the numbers of the carnivores! And how false, therefore, is the view of those who speak of the animal world as if nothing were to be seen in it but lions and hyenas plunging their bleeding teeth into the flesh of their victims! One might as well imagine that the whole of human life is nothing but a succession of war massacres.

Not too long ago, the small streams of North America and Northern Siberia were home to colonies of beavers, and up until the seventeenth century, similar colonies thrived in Northern Russia. The flat lands of the four major continents are still filled with countless colonies of mice, ground squirrels, marmots, and other rodents. In the lower latitudes of Asia and Africa, the forests continue to be home to numerous families of elephants, rhinoceroses, and countless groups of monkeys. In the far north, reindeer gather in endless herds; even further north, there are herds of musk oxen and numerous bands of polar foxes. The ocean coasts are alive with groups of seals and walruses; its waters are filled with social cetaceans; and even in the depths of the Central Asia plateau, there are herds of wild horses, wild donkeys, wild camels, and wild sheep. All these mammals live in societies and groups that sometimes number in the hundreds of thousands, although now, after three centuries of gunpowder civilization, we only find remnants of the vast populations that once existed. How small, in comparison, are the numbers of carnivores! And how misguided are those who describe the animal kingdom as if it were solely filled with lions and hyenas sinking their bloody teeth into the flesh of their victims! One might as well think that all of human life is just a series of war massacres.

Association and mutual aid are the rule with mammals. We find social habits even among the carnivores, and we can only name the cat tribe (lions, tigers, leopards, etc.) as a division the members of which decidedly prefer isolation to society, and are but seldom met with even in small groups. And yet, even among lions "this is a very common practice to hunt in company."(10) The two tribes of the civets (Viverridae) and the weasels (Mustelidae) might also be characterized by their isolated life, but it is a fact that during the last century the common weasel was more sociable than it is now; it was seen then in larger groups in Scotland and in the Unterwalden canton of Switzerland. As to the great tribe of the dogs, it is eminently sociable, and association for hunting purposes may be considered as eminently characteristic of its numerous species. It is well known, in fact, that wolves gather in packs for hunting, and Tschudi left an excellent description of how they draw up in a half-circle, surround a cow which is grazing on a mountain slope, and then, suddenly appearing with a loud barking, make it roll in the abyss.(11) Audubon, in the thirties, also saw the Labrador wolves hunting in packs, and one pack following a man to his cabin, and killing the dogs. During severe winters the packs of wolves grow so numerous as to become a danger for human settlements, as was the case in France some five-and-forty years ago. In the Russian Steppes they never attack the horses otherwise than in packs; and yet they have to sustain bitter fights, during which the horses (according to Kohl's testimony) sometimes assume offensive warfare, and in such cases, if the wolves do not retreat promptly, they run the risk of being surrounded by the horses and killed by their hoofs. The prairie-wolves (Canis latrans) are known to associate in bands of from twenty to thirty individuals when they chase a buffalo occasionally separated from its herd.(12) Jackals, which are most courageous and may be considered as one of the most intelligent representatives of the dog tribe, always hunt in packs; thus united, they have no fear of the bigger carnivores.(13) As to the wild dogs of Asia (the Kholzuns, or Dholes), Williamson saw their large packs attacking all larger animals save elephants and rhinoceroses, and overpowering bears and tigers. Hyenas always live in societies and hunt in packs, and the hunting organizations of the painted lycaons are highly praised by Cumming. Nay, even foxes, which, as a rule, live isolated in our civilized countries, have been seen combining for hunting purposes.(14) As to the polar fox, it is—or rather was in Steller's time—one of the most sociable animals; and when one reads Steller's description of the war that was waged by Behring's unfortunate crew against these intelligent small animals, one does not know what to wonder at most: the extraordinary intelligence of the foxes and the mutual aid they displayed in digging out food concealed under cairns, or stored upon a pillar (one fox would climb on its top and throw the food to its comrades beneath), or the cruelty of man, driven to despair by the numerous packs of foxes. Even some bears live in societies where they are not disturbed by man. Thus Steller saw the black bear of Kamtchatka in numerous packs, and the polar bears are occasionally found in small groups. Even the unintelligent insectivores do not always disdain association.

Association and mutual aid are common among mammals. We see social behavior even among carnivores, and the cat family (lions, tigers, leopards, etc.) is the only group that clearly prefers solitude over social interaction, often found alone or in very small groups. Yet, even lions often hunt in groups. The two families of civets and weasels can also be seen as solitary, but interestingly, the common weasel was more social in the last century, often spotted in larger groups in Scotland and Switzerland’s Unterwalden region. The dog family is particularly social, and hunting in groups is a key trait among its many species. Wolves are known to hunt in packs; Tschudi described how they form a half-circle to surround a grazing cow on a mountain and then appear suddenly with loud barking to make it tumble into the abyss. In the 1830s, Audubon observed Labrador wolves hunting in packs and even attacking a man’s dogs outside his cabin. During harsh winters, wolf packs can become so numerous that they pose a threat to human settlements, as was the case in France about 45 years ago. In the Russian Steppes, wolves only attack horses in packs, yet they face fierce battles, where horses, according to Kohl's report, sometimes engage offensively, risking the wolves being surrounded and trampled. Prairie wolves (Canis latrans) are known to band together into groups of twenty to thirty when chasing a buffalo that strays from its herd. Jackals, which are quite brave and considered intelligent members of the dog family, always hunt in packs, and together, they aren’t afraid of larger predators. The wild dogs of Asia (Kholzuns or Dholes) have been seen in large packs attacking all animals except elephants and rhinoceroses, even overpowering bears and tigers. Hyenas always live and hunt in groups, and Cumming praised the hunting strategies of the painted lycaons. Even foxes, typically solitary in civilized areas, have been observed hunting together. The polar fox was—or at least was during Steller's time—one of the most social animals; reading Steller's account of how Behring's crew fought against these clever little creatures makes one wonder more about the extraordinary intelligence of the foxes and their teamwork in digging out hidden food, or about the cruelty of humans driven to desperation by large numbers of foxes. Some bears also live in groups where undisturbed by humans. Steller noted that black bears in Kamtchatka often gathered in large packs, and polar bears are sometimes found in small groups. Even unintelligent insectivores occasionally join together.

However, it is especially with the rodents, the ungulata, and the ruminants that we find a highly developed practice of mutual aid. The squirrels are individualist to a great extent. Each of them builds its own comfortable nest, and accumulates its own provision. Their inclinations are towards family life, and Brehm found that a family of squirrels is never so happy as when the two broods of the same year can join together with their parents in a remote corner of a forest. And yet they maintain social relations. The inhabitants of the separate nests remain in a close intercourse, and when the pine-cones become rare in the forest they inhabit, they emigrate in bands. As to the black squirrels of the Far West, they are eminently sociable. Apart from the few hours given every day to foraging, they spend their lives in playing in numerous parties. And when they multiply too rapidly in a region, they assemble in bands, almost as numerous as those of locusts, and move southwards, devastating the forests, the fields, and the gardens; while foxes, polecats, falcons, and nocturnal birds of prey follow their thick columns and live upon the individuals remaining behind. The ground-squirrel—a closely-akin genus—is still more sociable. It is given to hoarding, and stores up in its subterranean halls large amounts of edible roots and nuts, usually plundered by man in the autumn. According to some observers, it must know something of the joys of a miser. And yet it remains sociable. It always lives in large villages, and Audubon, who opened some dwellings of the hackee in the winter, found several individuals in the same apartment; they must have stored it with common efforts.

However, it's especially with rodents, ungulates, and ruminants that we see a highly developed practice of mutual aid. Squirrels tend to be quite individualistic. Each one builds its own comfortable nest and gathers its own food supplies. They lean towards family life, and Brehm found that a family of squirrels is happiest when the two litters from the same year can come together with their parents in a secluded area of the forest. Still, they maintain social relationships. The residents of separate nests stay in close contact, and when pine cones become scarce in their forest, they move in groups. As for the black squirrels of the Far West, they are very sociable. Aside from the few hours they spend each day searching for food, they enjoy playing together in large groups. When they reproduce too quickly in an area, they gather in swarms, almost as numerous as locusts, and migrate south, devastating the forests, fields, and gardens in their path while foxes, weasels, falcons, and nocturnal birds of prey trail behind, feeding on the stragglers. The ground squirrel—a closely related species—is even more sociable. It likes to stockpile food, storing large quantities of edible roots and nuts in its underground burrows, which are often raided by humans in the fall. Some observers suggest it must know some of the pleasures of being a miser. Yet, it remains social. It always lives in large colonies, and Audubon, who opened some burrows during the winter, found several individuals in the same den; they must have worked together to store food.

The large tribe, of the marmots, which includes the three large genuses of Arctomys, Cynomys, and Spermophilus, is still more sociable and still more intelligent. They also prefer having each one its own dwelling; but they live in big villages. That terrible enemy of the crops of South Russia—the souslik—of which some ten millions are exterminated every year by man alone, lives in numberless colonies; and while the Russian provincial assemblies gravely discuss the means of getting rid of this enemy of society, it enjoys life in its thousands in the most joyful way. Their play is so charming that no observer could refrain from paying them a tribute of praise, and from mentioning the melodious concerts arising from the sharp whistlings of the males and the melancholic whistlings of the females, before—suddenly returning to his citizen's duties—he begins inventing the most diabolic means for the extermination of the little robbers. All kinds of rapacious birds and beasts of prey having proved powerless, the last word of science in this warfare is the inoculation of cholera! The villages of the prairie-dogs in America are one of the loveliest sights. As far as the eye can embrace the prairie, it sees heaps of earth, and on each of them a prairie-dog stands, engaged in a lively conversation with its neighbours by means of short barkings. As soon as the approach of man is signalled, all plunge in a moment into their dwellings; all have disappeared as by enchantment. But if the danger is over, the little creatures soon reappear. Whole families come out of their galleries and indulge in play. The young ones scratch one another, they worry one another, and display their gracefulness while standing upright, and in the meantime the old ones keep watch. They go visiting one another, and the beaten footpaths which connect all their heaps testify to the frequency of the visitations. In short, the best naturalists have written some of their best pages in describing the associations of the prairie-dogs of America, the marmots of the Old World, and the polar marmots of the Alpine regions. And yet, I must make, as regards the marmots, the same remark as I have made when speaking of the bees. They have maintained their fighting instincts, and these instincts reappear in captivity. But in their big associations, in the face of free Nature, the unsociable instincts have no opportunity to develop, and the general result is peace and harmony.

The large tribe of marmots, which includes the three big genera of Arctomys, Cynomys, and Spermophilus, is even more social and intelligent. They prefer having their own homes but live in large colonies. That dreaded enemy of South Russia's crops—the souslik—of which around ten million are killed each year by humans, lives in countless colonies; meanwhile, while Russian provincial assemblies seriously debate how to deal with this societal threat, the souslik enjoys life in its thousands, carefree. Their playful antics are so delightful that no observer can help but admire them, and they often mention the pleasant concerts of sharp whistling from the males and the melancholic whistling from the females, right before—quickly shifting back to their civic responsibilities—they start devising the most nefarious ways to wipe out the little thieves. After numerous predatory birds and beasts have failed, the latest advancement in this fight is the inoculation of cholera! The prairie-dog villages in America are one of the most beautiful sights. As far as the eye can see across the prairie, there are mounds of dirt, and on each one stands a prairie dog, having lively conversations with its neighbors through short barks. As soon as danger approaches, they all vanish into their burrows in an instant; they've disappeared as if by magic. But once the threat passes, the little creatures quickly come back out. Whole families emerge from their tunnels and start playing. The young ones scratch and tease each other, showcasing their agility while standing on their hind legs, while the adults keep a lookout. They visit one another frequently, and the well-worn paths connecting the mounds show just how often they socialize. In short, the best naturalists have written some of their finest observations about the social lives of America's prairie dogs, the marmots of the Old World, and the polar marmots of the Alpine regions. Yet, I must point out about the marmots what I observed when discussing the bees: they have maintained their fighting instincts, which can resurface in captivity. However, in their large groups, facing the freedom of nature, their antisocial instincts don't have a chance to develop, leading to an overall atmosphere of peace and harmony.

Even such harsh animals as the rats, which continually fight in our cellars, are sufficiently intelligent not to quarrel when they plunder our larders, but to aid one another in their plundering expeditions and migrations, and even to feed their invalids. As to the beaver-rats or musk-rats of Canada, they are extremely sociable. Audubon could not but admire "their peaceful communities, which require only being left in peace to enjoy happiness." Like all sociable animals, they are lively and playful, they easily combine with other species, and they have attained a very high degree of intellectual development. In their villages, always disposed on the shores of lakes and rivers, they take into account the changing level of water; their domeshaped houses, which are built of beaten clay interwoven with reeds, have separate corners for organic refuse, and their halls are well carpeted at winter time; they are warm, and, nevertheless, well ventilated. As to the beavers, which are endowed, as known, with a most sympathetic character, their astounding dams and villages, in which generations live and die without knowing of any enemies but the otter and man, so wonderfully illustrate what mutual aid can achieve for the security of the species, the development of social habits, and the evolution of intelligence, that they are familiar to all interested in animal life. Let me only remark that with the beavers, the muskrats, and some other rodents, we already find the feature which will also be distinctive of human communities—that is, work in common.

Even the tough animals like rats, which constantly fight in our cellars, are smart enough not to squabble when they raid our food supplies. Instead, they help each other during their stealing missions and migrations, and even care for their sick. As for the beaver-rats or musk-rats of Canada, they are very social. Audubon couldn’t help but admire "their peaceful communities, which require only being left in peace to enjoy happiness." Like all social animals, they are energetic and playful, easily mingling with other species, and they have achieved a high level of intelligence. In their villages, always located by lakes and rivers, they consider the changing water levels; their dome-shaped homes, built from compacted clay and reeds, have separate areas for waste, and their interiors are well carpeted in winter; they are warm yet well-ventilated. As for the beavers, known for their friendly nature, their incredible dams and villages, where generations live and die without knowing any enemies except for otters and humans, perfectly illustrate what mutual aid can do for the safety of the species, the development of social habits, and the evolution of intelligence, making them well-known to anyone interested in animal life. Let me just mention that with beavers, muskrats, and some other rodents, we already see a characteristic that will also be found in human communities—that is, working together.

I pass in silence the two large families which include the jerboa, the chinchilla, the biscacha, and the tushkan, or underground hare of South Russia, though all these small rodents might be taken as excellent illustrations of the pleasures derived by animals from social life.(15) Precisely, the pleasures; because it is extremely difficult to say what brings animals together—the needs of mutual protection, or simply the pleasure of feeling surrounded by their congeners. At any rate, our common hares, which do not gather in societies for life in common, and which are not even endowed with intense parental feelings, cannot live without coming together for play. Dietrich de Winckell, who is considered to be among the best acquainted with the habits of hares, describes them as passionate players, becoming so intoxicated by their play that a hare has been known to take an approaching fox for a playmate.(16) As to the rabbit, it lives in societies, and its family life is entirely built upon the image of the old patriarchal family; the young ones being kept in absolute obedience to the father and even the grandfather.(17) And here we have the example of two very closely-allied species which cannot bear each other—not because they live upon nearly the same food, as like cases are too often explained, but most probably because the passionate, eminently-individualist hare cannot make friends with that placid, quiet, and submissive creature, the rabbit. Their tempers are too widely different not to be an obstacle to friendship.

I quietly pass by the two large families that include the jerboa, chinchilla, biscacha, and the tushkan, or underground hare of South Russia, even though all these small rodents are great examples of the joys animals get from social life. It really is about the joys; it's tough to figure out what brings animals together—whether it's the need for protection or just the enjoyment of being around others like them. Anyway, our common hares, which don’t form groups for shared living and lack strong parental instincts, still need to come together to play. Dietrich de Winckell, who is considered one of the best experts on hare habits, describes them as enthusiastic players, so caught up in their fun that a hare has been known to mistake an approaching fox for a playmate. On the other hand, rabbits live in groups, and their family life resembles the traditional patriarchal structure, with the young ones completely obedient to their father and even their grandfather. Here we see two closely related species that can't stand each other—not because they eat nearly the same food, as is often suggested, but likely because the passionate, highly individual hare struggles to connect with the calm, quiet, and submissive rabbit. Their very different natures make it hard for them to be friends.

Life in societies is again the rule with the large family of horses, which includes the wild horses and donkeys of Asia, the zebras, the mustangs, the cimarrones of the Pampas, and the half-wild horses of Mongolia and Siberia. They all live in numerous associations made up of many studs, each of which consists of a number of mares under the leadership of a male. These numberless inhabitants of the Old and the New World, badly organized on the whole for resisting both their numerous enemies and the adverse conditions of climate, would soon have disappeared from the surface of the earth were it not for their sociable spirit. When a beast of prey approaches them, several studs unite at once; they repulse the beast and sometimes chase it: and neither the wolf nor the bear, not even the lion, can capture a horse or even a zebra as long as they are not detached from the herd. When a drought is burning the grass in the prairies, they gather in herds of sometimes 10,000 individuals strong, and migrate. And when a snow-storm rages in the Steppes, each stud keeps close together, and repairs to a protected ravine. But if confidence disappears, or the group has been seized by panic, and disperses, the horses perish and the survivors are found after the storm half dying from fatigue. Union is their chief arm in the struggle for life, and man is their chief enemy. Before his increasing numbers the ancestors of our domestic horse (the Equus Przewalskii, so named by Polyakoff) have preferred to retire to the wildest and least accessible plateaus on the outskirts of Thibet, where they continue to live, surrounded by carnivores, under a climate as bad as that of the Arctic regions, but in a region inaccessible to man.(18)

Life in society is once again the norm for the large family of horses, which includes the wild horses and donkeys of Asia, zebras, mustangs, the cimarrones of the Pampas, and the semi-wild horses of Mongolia and Siberia. They all form multiple groups made up of several herds, each led by a dominant male with several mares. These countless inhabitants of both the Old and New Worlds are generally poorly organized for defending against their many predators and harsh climate conditions. They would have quickly disappeared from the earth if it weren't for their social nature. When a predator approaches, multiple herds come together; they fend off the predator and sometimes even chase it away. Not even wolves, bears, or lions can catch a horse or zebra as long as they stay within the herd. During droughts that scorch the grass in the prairies, they gather in herds of up to 10,000 individuals and migrate. When blizzards hit the Steppes, each herd stays close together and heads to a protected ravine. But if they lose trust, or if panic takes over and they scatter, the horses die, and the survivors are often found after the storm barely hanging on from exhaustion. Unity is their main strength in the fight for survival, while humans are their greatest threat. In the face of increasing human populations, the ancestors of our domestic horse (Equus Przewalskii, named by Polyakoff) have chosen to retreat to the wildest and most inaccessible plateaus on the edges of Tibet, where they continue to live surrounded by predators in a climate as harsh as that of the Arctic, but in an area that is inaccessible to humans.

Many striking illustrations of social life could be taken from the life of the reindeer, and especially of that large division of ruminants which might include the roebucks, the fallow deer, the antelopes, the gazelles, the ibex, and, in fact, the whole of the three numerous families of the Antelopides, the Caprides, and the Ovides. Their watchfulness over the safety of their herds against attacks of carnivores; the anxiety displayed by all individuals in a herd of chamois as long as all of them have not cleared a difficult passage over rocky cliffs, the adoption of orphans; the despair of the gazelle whose mate, or even comrade of the same sex, has been killed; the plays of the youngsters, and many other features, could be mentioned. But perhaps the most striking illustration of mutual support is given by the occasional migrations of fallow deer, such as I saw once on the Amur. When I crossed the high plateau and its border ridge, the Great Khingan, on my way from Transbaikalia to Merghen, and further travelled over the high prairies on my way to the Amur, I could ascertain how thinly-peopled with fallow deer these mostly uninhabited regions are.(19) Two years later I was travelling up the Amur, and by the end of October reached the lower end of that picturesque gorge which the Amur pierces in the Dousse-alin (Little Khingan) before it enters the lowlands where it joins the Sungari. I found the Cossacks in the villages of that gorge in the greatest excitement, because thousands and thousands of fallow deer were crossing the Amur where it is narrowest, in order to reach the lowlands. For several days in succession, upon a length of some forty miles up the river, the Cossacks were butchering the deer as they crossed the Amur, in which already floated a good deal of ice. Thousands were killed every day, and the exodus nevertheless continued. Like migrations were never seen either before or since, and this one must have been called for by an early and heavy snow-fall in the Great Khingan, which compelled the deer to make a desperate attempt at reaching the lowlands in the east of the Dousse mountains. Indeed, a few days later the Dousse-alin was also buried under snow two or three feet deep. Now, when one imagines the immense territory (almost as big as Great Britain) from which the scattered groups of deer must have gathered for a migration which was undertaken under the pressure of exceptional circumstances, and realizes the difficulties which had to be overcome before all the deer came to the common idea of crossing the Amur further south, where it is narrowest, one cannot but deeply admire the amount of sociability displayed by these intelligent animals. The fact is not the less striking if we remember that the buffaloes of North America displayed the same powers of combination. One saw them grazing in great numbers in the plains, but these numbers were made up by an infinity of small groups which never mixed together. And yet, when necessity arose, all groups, however scattered over an immense territory, came together and made up those immense columns, numbering hundreds of thousands of individuals, which I mentioned on a preceding page.

Many vivid examples of social life can be found in the lives of reindeer, particularly among the larger group of herbivores that includes roebucks, fallow deer, antelopes, gazelles, and ibex, as well as the numerous families of Antelopides, Caprides, and Ovides. Their vigilance in protecting their herds from predators, the anxiety shown by chamois when not all members have crossed a challenging path over rocky cliffs, their care for orphans, the despair of a gazelle mourning the loss of a mate or even a same-sex companion, the playful behavior of the young, and many other traits could be highlighted. However, the most remarkable example of mutual support comes from the occasional migrations of fallow deer, which I observed once along the Amur River. When I crossed the high plateau and its bordering ridge, the Great Khingan, on my journey from Transbaikalia to Merghen, and continued over the high prairies to the Amur, I noted how few fallow deer inhabited these largely uninhabited areas. Two years later, while traveling up the Amur, I reached the picturesque gorge the river carves through the Dousse-alin (Little Khingan) by the end of October, just before it enters the lowlands where it meets the Sungari. I found the Cossacks in the villages of that gorge in great excitement because thousands of fallow deer were crossing the Amur at its narrowest point to reach the lowlands. For several consecutive days, spanning about forty miles of the river, the Cossacks were hunting the deer as they crossed the Amur, which already had a considerable amount of ice. Thousands were killed each day, yet the migration continued. Such migrations had never been seen before or since, likely triggered by an early and heavy snowfall in the Great Khingan, forcing the deer to make a desperate attempt to reach the lowlands east of the Dousse mountains. Just a few days later, the Dousse-alin itself was also covered in two or three feet of snow. When one considers the vast territory (almost as large as Great Britain) from which these scattered deer must have gathered for a migration prompted by extraordinary circumstances, and realizes the challenges they overcame before all the deer arrived at the shared decision to cross the Amur further south where it was narrowest, it’s impossible not to admire the social behavior displayed by these intelligent animals. This fact remains striking when we remember that buffaloes in North America exhibited the same abilities to congregate. They grazed in large numbers across the plains, but these numbers were composed of countless small groups that never mixed. Yet, when necessary, all these groups, no matter how spread out over a vast space, came together and formed those colossal herds, sometimes numbering in the hundreds of thousands, which I mentioned earlier.

I also ought to say a few words at least about the "compound families" of the elephants, their mutual attachment, their deliberate ways in posting sentries, and the feelings of sympathy developed by such a life of close mutual support.(20) I might mention the sociable feelings of those disreputable creatures the wild boars, and find a word of praise for their powers of association in the case of an attack by a beast of prey.(21) The hippopotamus and the rhinoceros, too, would occupy a place in a work devoted to animal sociability. Several striking pages might be given to the sociability and mutual attachment of the seals and the walruses; and finally, one might mention the most excellent feelings existing among the sociable cetaceans. But I have to say yet a few words about the societies of monkeys, which acquire an additional interest from their being the link which will bring us to the societies of primitive men.

I should also mention a few things about the "compound families" of elephants, their strong bonds, their thoughtful ways of posting sentries, and the sense of sympathy that comes from living in such close-knit communities. I could talk about the social nature of those less reputable creatures, wild boars, and commend their ability to band together when faced with a predator. The hippopotamus and rhinoceros also deserve a spot in a discussion about animal social behavior. Several interesting pages could be dedicated to the social interactions and strong connections among seals and walruses; and lastly, one should note the great camaraderie found among social cetaceans. But I need to add a few words about monkey societies, which gain additional significance because they link us to the communities of early humans.

It is hardly needful to say that those mammals, which stand at the very top of the animal world and most approach man by their structure and intelligence, are eminently sociable. Evidently we must be prepared to meet with all varieties of character and habits in so great a division of the animal kingdom which includes hundreds of species. But, all things considered, it must be said that sociability, action in common, mutual protection, and a high development of those feelings which are the necessary outcome of social life, are characteristic of most monkeys and apes. From the smallest species to the biggest ones, sociability is a rule to which we know but a few exceptions. The nocturnal apes prefer isolated life; the capuchins (Cebus capucinus), the monos, and the howling monkeys live but in small families; and the orang-outans have never been seen by A.R. Wallace otherwise than either solitary or in very small groups of three or four individuals, while the gorillas seem never to join in bands. But all the remainder of the monkey tribe—the chimpanzees, the sajous, the sakis, the mandrills, the baboons, and so on—are sociable in the highest degree. They live in great bands, and even join with other species than their own. Most of them become quite unhappy when solitary. The cries of distress of each one of the band immediately bring together the whole of the band, and they boldly repulse the attacks of most carnivores and birds of prey. Even eagles do not dare attack them. They plunder our fields always in bands—the old ones taking care for the safety of the commonwealth. The little tee-tees, whose childish sweet faces so much struck Humboldt, embrace and protect one another when it rains, rolling their tails over the necks of their shivering comrades. Several species display the greatest solicitude for their wounded, and do not abandon a wounded comrade during a retreat till they have ascertained that it is dead and that they are helpless to restore it to life. Thus James Forbes narrated in his Oriental Memoirs a fact of such resistance in reclaiming from his hunting party the dead body of a female monkey that one fully understands why "the witnesses of this extraordinary scene resolved never again to fire at one of the monkey race."(22) In some species several individuals will combine to overturn a stone in order to search for ants' eggs under it. The hamadryas not only post sentries, but have been seen making a chain for the transmission of the spoil to a safe place; and their courage is well known. Brehm's description of the regular fight which his caravan had to sustain before the hamadryas would let it resume its journey in the valley of the Mensa, in Abyssinia, has become classical.(23) The playfulness of the tailed apes and the mutual attachment which reigns in the families of chimpanzees also are familiar to the general reader. And if we find among the highest apes two species, the orang-outan and the gorilla, which are not sociable, we must remember that both—limited as they are to very small areas, the one in the heart of Africa, and the other in the two islands of Borneo and Sumatra have all the appearance of being the last remnants of formerly much more numerous species. The gorilla at least seems to have been sociable in olden times, if the apes mentioned in the Periplus really were gorillas.

It’s hardly necessary to say that the mammals at the top of the animal kingdom, which are closest to humans in terms of their structure and intelligence, are highly social. We clearly should expect to encounter all kinds of personalities and behaviors across such a vast part of the animal kingdom that includes hundreds of species. However, it must be noted that sociability, cooperative action, mutual protection, and a strong development of the emotions required for social living are traits typical of most monkeys and apes. From the smallest to the largest species, sociability is a norm, with only a few exceptions. Nocturnal apes prefer to live alone; capuchins (Cebus capucinus), monos, and howler monkeys usually live in small family groups; and orangutans have only been observed by A.R. Wallace living either solitarily or in very small groups of three or four. Gorillas also seem to avoid forming large groups. In contrast, the rest of the monkey species—chimpanzees, sajous, sakis, mandrills, baboons, and others—are extremely social. They live in large groups and even interact with other species. Most of them become quite unhappy when alone. The cries of distress from any member of the group quickly bring the entire group together, and they bravely fend off attacks from most carnivores and birds of prey, with even eagles avoiding them. They often raid our fields in groups, with older ones looking out for the safety of the group. The little tee-tees, with their sweet, youthful faces that so impressed Humboldt, hug and protect each other when it rains, wrapping their tails around their shivering friends. Several species show great care for their injured, refusing to abandon a wounded companion during a retreat until they confirm it’s dead and that they can't help it. James Forbes recounted in his Oriental Memoirs a story of such determination in retrieving the body of a female monkey from his hunting party that it’s clear why "the witnesses of this extraordinary scene resolved never again to fire at one of the monkey race." In some species, multiple individuals will work together to flip over a stone to look for ant eggs underneath. Hamadryas not only have sentinels but have also been seen forming a chain to pass food to a safe location; their bravery is well-documented. Brehm famously described the battle his caravan had to fight in order for them to continue their journey in the Mensa Valley, in Abyssinia. The playful nature of tailed apes and the strong bonds within chimpanzee families are also well-known. And while we find that two of the most advanced apes, the orangutan and the gorilla, are not social creatures, we must remember that both are confined to very small regions—one in central Africa and the other in the two islands of Borneo and Sumatra—suggesting they may be the last remnants of once more numerous species. The gorilla at least seems to have been social in the past, assuming that the apes mentioned in the Periplus were indeed gorillas.

We thus see, even from the above brief review, that life in societies is no exception in the animal world; it is the rule, the law of Nature, and it reaches its fullest development with the higher vertebrates. Those species which live solitary, or in small families only, are relatively few, and their numbers are limited. Nay, it appears very probable that, apart from a few exceptions, those birds and mammals which are not gregarious now, were living in societies before man multiplied on the earth and waged a permanent war against them, or destroyed the sources from which they formerly derived food. "On ne s'associe pas pour mourir," was the sound remark of Espinas; and Houzeau, who knew the animal world of some parts of America when it was not yet affected by man, wrote to the same effect.

We can see, even from this brief review, that life in societies is common in the animal world; it's the norm, the law of Nature, and it reaches its fullest expression in higher vertebrates. There are only a few species that live alone or in small family groups, and their numbers are limited. In fact, it's very likely that, except for a few exceptions, the birds and mammals that are not social now once lived in groups before humans increased in number and waged a continuous battle against them or destroyed their food sources. "We don't associate to die," was the wise observation of Espinas; and Houzeau, who observed the animal life in certain parts of America before human influence took hold, echoed this sentiment.

Association is found in the animal world at all degrees of evolution; and, according to the grand idea of Herbert Spencer, so brilliantly developed in Perrier's Colonies Animales, colonies are at the very origin of evolution in the animal kingdom. But, in proportion as we ascend the scale of evolution, we see association growing more and more conscious. It loses its purely physical character, it ceases to be simply instinctive, it becomes reasoned. With the higher vertebrates it is periodical, or is resorted to for the satisfaction of a given want—propagation of the species, migration, hunting, or mutual defence. It even becomes occasional, when birds associate against a robber, or mammals combine, under the pressure of exceptional circumstances, to emigrate. In this last case, it becomes a voluntary deviation from habitual moods of life. The combination sometimes appears in two or more degrees—the family first, then the group, and finally the association of groups, habitually scattered, but uniting in case of need, as we saw it with the bisons and other ruminants. It also takes higher forms, guaranteeing more independence to the individual without depriving it of the benefits of social life. With most rodents the individual has its own dwelling, which it can retire to when it prefers being left alone; but the dwellings are laid out in villages and cities, so as to guarantee to all inhabitants the benefits and joys of social life. And finally, in several species, such as rats, marmots, hares, etc., sociable life is maintained notwithstanding the quarrelsome or otherwise egotistic inclinations of the isolated individual. Thus it is not imposed, as is the case with ants and bees, by the very physiological structure of the individuals; it is cultivated for the benefits of mutual aid, or for the sake of its pleasures. And this, of course, appears with all possible gradations and with the greatest variety of individual and specific characters—the very variety of aspects taken by social life being a consequence, and for us a further proof, of its generality.(24)

Association occurs in the animal world at all stages of evolution; according to Herbert Spencer's grand idea, which is brilliantly explained in Perrier's Colonies Animales, colonies are at the very beginning of evolution in the animal kingdom. However, as we move up the evolutionary scale, we notice that association becomes more and more conscious. It loses its purely physical nature, it stops being just instinctive, and it becomes reasoned. With higher vertebrates, it is periodic or is used to meet specific needs—like reproduction, migration, hunting, or mutual defense. It can even be occasional, such as when birds come together to fend off a thief, or mammals unite under exceptional circumstances to migrate. In this latter case, it represents a voluntary change from typical behavior. The association can often be seen in different levels—the family first, then groups, and finally the association of groups that are usually scattered but come together when necessary, as we observed with bison and other ruminants. It can also take on more advanced forms, allowing individuals greater independence without sacrificing the benefits of social life. Most rodents have their own homes where they can retreat when they want to be alone; however, these homes are arranged in villages and cities, ensuring that all inhabitants enjoy the benefits and joys of social life. Finally, in several species like rats, prairie dogs, hares, etc., social life continues despite the quarrelsome or self-centered tendencies of individual members. Thus, it is not enforced, as it is with ants and bees, by the physiological structure of the individuals; instead, it is nurtured for the advantages of mutual support or simply for enjoyment. This manifests in all possible variations and with great diversity in individual and species characteristics—the very variety of social life is a reflection of its widespread nature and further confirms its generality.

Sociability—that is, the need of the animal of associating with its like—the love of society for society's sake, combined with the "joy of life," only now begins to receive due attention from the zoologists.(25) We know at the present time that all animals, beginning with the ants, going on to the birds, and ending with the highest mammals, are fond of plays, wrestling, running after each other, trying to capture each other, teasing each other, and so on. And while many plays are, so to speak, a school for the proper behaviour of the young in mature life, there are others, which, apart from their utilitarian purposes, are, together with dancing and singing, mere manifestations of an excess of forces—"the joy of life," and a desire to communicate in some way or another with other individuals of the same or of other species—in short, a manifestation of sociability proper, which is a distinctive feature of all the animal world.(26) Whether the feeling be fear, experienced at the appearance of a bird of prey, or "a fit of gladness" which bursts out when the animals are in good health and especially when young, or merely the desire of giving play to an excess of impressions and of vital power—the necessity of communicating impressions, of playing, of chattering, or of simply feeling the proximity of other kindred living beings pervades Nature, and is, as much as any other physiological function, a distinctive feature of life and impressionability. This need takes a higher development and attains a more beautiful expression in mammals, especially amidst their young, and still more among the birds; but it pervades all Nature, and has been fully observed by the best naturalists, including Pierre Huber, even amongst the ants, and it is evidently the same instinct which brings together the big columns of butterflies which have been referred to already.

Sociability—that is, the need for animals to associate with their kind—the love of being in society for its own sake, combined with the "joy of life," is just now starting to get the attention it deserves from zoologists. We know today that all animals, starting with ants, moving on to birds, and ending with the highest mammals, enjoy playing, wrestling, chasing one another, trying to catch each other, teasing each other, and so on. Many of these games serve as a way for young animals to learn appropriate behavior for adult life, while others, aside from their practical purposes, are, along with dancing and singing, simply expressions of excess energy—"the joy of life"—and a need to connect with others, whether they are the same species or different ones. In short, this is a clear display of sociability, which is a defining characteristic of the entire animal kingdom. Whether the feeling is fear, triggered by a predator's arrival, or a moment of happiness that erupts when animals are healthy and especially when they are young, or just a need to express an overflow of sensations and energy—the urge to share feelings, play, chatter, or simply be close to other like-minded living beings is present throughout Nature. This, like any other physiological function, is a fundamental aspect of life and the ability to feel. This need evolves further and takes on a more beautiful expression in mammals, particularly among their young, and even more so in birds; yet it is found across all of Nature and has been thoroughly observed by leading naturalists, including Pierre Huber, even among ants, and it’s clearly the same instinct that draws together large groups of butterflies we've mentioned earlier.

The habit of coming together for dancing and of decorating the places where the birds habitually perform their dances is, of course, well known from the pages that Darwin gave to this subject in The Descent of Man (ch. xiii). Visitors of the London Zoological Gardens also know the bower of the satin bower-bird. But this habit of dancing seems to be much more widely spread than was formerly believed, and Mr. W. Hudson gives in his master-work on La Plata the most interesting description, which must be read in the original, of complicated dances, performed by quite a number of birds: rails, jacanas, lapwings, and so on.

The practice of gathering to dance and decorating the spots where birds typically perform their dances is, of course, well documented in Darwin's discussion on this topic in The Descent of Man (ch. xiii). Visitors to the London Zoo are also familiar with the bower of the satin bower-bird. However, this dance habit appears to be much more widespread than previously thought, and Mr. W. Hudson offers in his key work on La Plata a fascinating description—best read in the original—of the intricate dances carried out by various birds, including rails, jacanas, lapwings, and others.

The habit of singing in concert, which exists in several species of birds, belongs to the same category of social instincts. It is most strikingly developed with the chakar (Chauna chavarris), to which the English have given the most unimaginative misnomer of "crested screamer." These birds sometimes assemble in immense flocks, and in such cases they frequently sing all in concert. W.H. Hudson found them once in countless numbers, ranged all round a pampas lake in well-defined flocks, of about 500 birds in each flock.

The habit of singing together, which is found in several bird species, falls under the same category of social instincts. It is especially prominent in the chakar (Chauna chavarris), which the English have unimaginatively labeled as the "crested screamer." These birds often gather in large flocks, and when they do, they frequently sing in unison. W.H. Hudson once observed them in vast numbers, lined up around a pampas lake in clearly defined groups of about 500 birds each.

"Presently," he writes, "one flock near me began singing, and continued their powerful chant for three or four minutes; when they ceased the next flock took up the strains, and after it the next, and so on, until once more the notes of the flocks on the opposite shore came floating strong and clear across the water—then passed away, growing fainter and fainter, until once more the sound approached me travelling round to my side again."

"Right now," he writes, "one group nearby started singing, and kept up their powerful song for three or four minutes; when they stopped, the next group took over, then the next one after that, and so on, until the sounds from the flocks on the other shore came drifting strong and clear across the water—then faded away, becoming softer and softer, until the sound came back to me, circling around to my side again."

On another occasion the same writer saw a whole plain covered with an endless flock of chakars, not in close order, but scattered in pairs and small groups. About nine o'clock in the evening, "suddenly the entire multitude of birds covering the marsh for miles around burst forth in a tremendous evening song…. It was a concert well worth riding a hundred miles to hear."(27) It may be added that like all sociable animals, the chakar easily becomes tame and grows very attached to man. "They are mild-tempered birds, and very rarely quarrel"—we are told—although they are well provided with formidable weapons. Life in societies renders these weapons useless.

On another occasion, the same writer saw a vast plain filled with countless chakars, not gathered closely but scattered in pairs and small groups. Around nine o'clock in the evening, "suddenly the entire multitude of birds covering the marsh for miles around burst forth in a tremendous evening song…. It was a concert well worth riding a hundred miles to hear."(27) It’s worth noting that, like all social animals, the chakar easily becomes tame and forms strong bonds with humans. "They are gentle birds and very rarely fight," we are told, even though they have formidable weapons. Living in groups makes these weapons ineffective.

That life in societies is the most powerful weapon in the struggle for life, taken in its widest sense, has been illustrated by several examples on the foregoing pages, and could be illustrated by any amount of evidence, if further evidence were required. Life in societies enables the feeblest insects, the feeblest birds, and the feeblest mammals to resist, or to protect themselves from, the most terrible birds and beasts of prey; it permits longevity; it enables the species to rear its progeny with the least waste of energy and to maintain its numbers albeit a very slow birth-rate; it enables the gregarious animals to migrate in search of new abodes. Therefore, while fully admitting that force, swiftness, protective colours, cunningness, and endurance to hunger and cold, which are mentioned by Darwin and Wallace, are so many qualities making the individual, or the species, the fittest under certain circumstances, we maintain that under any circumstances sociability is the greatest advantage in the struggle for life. Those species which willingly or unwillingly abandon it are doomed to decay; while those animals which know best how to combine, have the greatest chances of survival and of further evolution, although they may be inferior to others in each of the faculties enumerated by Darwin and Wallace, save the intellectual faculty. The highest vertebrates, and especially mankind, are the best proof of this assertion. As to the intellectual faculty, while every Darwinist will agree with Darwin that it is the most powerful arm in the struggle for life, and the most powerful factor of further evolution, he also will admit that intelligence is an eminently social faculty. Language, imitation, and accumulated experience are so many elements of growing intelligence of which the unsociable animal is deprived. Therefore we find, at the top of each class of animals, the ants, the parrots, and the monkeys, all combining the greatest sociability with the highest development of intelligence. The fittest are thus the most sociable animals, and sociability appears as the chief factor of evolution, both directly, by securing the well-being of the species while diminishing the waste of energy, and indirectly, by favouring the growth of intelligence.

Life in societies is the strongest tool in the fight for survival, in every sense, as shown by numerous examples in the previous pages, and it could be backed up by even more evidence if needed. Living in groups helps the weakest insects, birds, and mammals defend themselves against the fiercest predators; it allows for longer lifespans; it helps species raise their young with minimal energy loss and maintain their populations, even with a very slow birth rate; and it enables social animals to move in search of new homes. So, while we fully recognize that traits like strength, speed, protective colors, cleverness, and resilience to hunger and cold—pointed out by Darwin and Wallace—are important attributes that make individuals or species well-suited in specific situations, we argue that sociability is the greatest advantage for survival in all circumstances. Species that abandon social living, whether willingly or not, are destined to decline; meanwhile, animals that excel at teamwork have the best chances of surviving and evolving further, even if they are inferior to others in each of the traits listed by Darwin and Wallace, except for intellect. The most advanced vertebrates, particularly humans, are the best proof of this claim. Regarding intellect, while every supporter of Darwin will agree that it's the most powerful weapon in the struggle for survival and a key factor for further evolution, they'll also acknowledge that intelligence is a fundamentally social trait. Communication, imitation, and accumulated experience are all elements of increasing intelligence that unsocial animals lack. For this reason, at the top of each animal class, we find ants, parrots, and monkeys, all exhibiting high sociability along with advanced intelligence. Therefore, the fittest are the most social animals, and sociability stands out as a primary driver of evolution, both directly by ensuring the well-being of the species while minimizing energy waste, and indirectly by promoting intelligence development.

Moreover, it is evident that life in societies would be utterly impossible without a corresponding development of social feelings, and, especially, of a certain collective sense of justice growing to become a habit. If every individual were constantly abusing its personal advantages without the others interfering in favour of the wronged, no society—life would be possible. And feelings of justice develop, more or less, with all gregarious animals. Whatever the distance from which the swallows or the cranes come, each one returns to the nest it has built or repaired last year. If a lazy sparrow intends appropriating the nest which a comrade is building, or even steals from it a few sprays of straw, the group interferes against the lazy comrade; and it is evident that without such interference being the rule, no nesting associations of birds could exist. Separate groups of penguins have separate resting-places and separate fishing abodes, and do not fight for them. The droves of cattle in Australia have particular spots to which each group repairs to rest, and from which it never deviates; and so on.(28) We have any numbers of direct observations of the peace that prevails in the nesting associations of birds, the villages of the rodents, and the herds of grass-eaters; while, on the other side, we know of few sociable animals which so continually quarrel as the rats in our cellars do, or as the morses, which fight for the possession of a sunny place on the shore. Sociability thus puts a limit to physical struggle, and leaves room for the development of better moral feelings. The high development of parental love in all classes of animals, even with lions and tigers, is generally known. As to the young birds and mammals whom we continually see associating, sympathy—not love—attains a further development in their associations. Leaving aside the really touching facts of mutual attachment and compassion which have been recorded as regards domesticated animals and with animals kept in captivity, we have a number of well certified facts of compassion between wild animals at liberty. Max Perty and L. Buchner have given a number of such facts.(29) J.C. Wood's narrative of a weasel which came to pick up and to carry away an injured comrade enjoys a well-merited popularity.(30) So also the observation of Captain Stansbury on his journey to Utah which is quoted by Darwin; he saw a blind pelican which was fed, and well fed, by other pelicans upon fishes which had to be brought from a distance of thirty miles.(31) And when a herd of vicunas was hotly pursued by hunters, H.A. Weddell saw more than once during his journey to Bolivia and Peru, the strong males covering the retreat of the herd and lagging behind in order to protect the retreat. As to facts of compassion with wounded comrades, they are continually mentioned by all field zoologists. Such facts are quite natural. Compassion is a necessary outcome of social life. But compassion also means a considerable advance in general intelligence and sensibility. It is the first step towards the development of higher moral sentiments. It is, in its turn, a powerful factor of further evolution.

Moreover, it's clear that life in societies would be completely impossible without the development of social feelings and, especially, a collective sense of justice that becomes a habit. If every individual continually exploited their advantages without others stepping in to help those wronged, no society would exist. Feelings of justice develop, to some degree, in all social animals. No matter where the swallows or cranes come from, each one returns to the nest it built or repaired last year. If a lazy sparrow tries to take over the nest a friend is building, or even steals some twigs from it, the group intervenes against the lazy sparrow. Clearly, without such interventions being the norm, no nesting groups of birds could survive. Separate groups of penguins have their own resting spots and fishing areas, and they don’t fight over them. In Australia, cattle have specific places where each group goes to rest, and they never stray from them; and so on. We have plenty of direct observations of the peaceful coexistence in bird nesting groups, rodent villages, and herbivore herds. However, on the flip side, we know few sociable animals that quarrel as frequently as rats in our cellars or walruses, who fight over sunny spots on the shore. Sociability thus sets limits on physical conflict and allows for the growth of better moral feelings. The strong development of parental love in all animal classes, even lions and tigers, is well known. As for young birds and mammals that we often see socializing, their bonds develop into sympathy—not love—during their interactions. Aside from the touching stories of mutual affection and compassion recorded among domesticated and captive animals, there are numerous verified accounts of compassion among wild animals in the wild. Max Perty and L. Buchner have provided many such accounts. J.C. Wood's story of a weasel that picked up and carried away an injured friend is quite popular. Similarly, Captain Stansbury, during his trip to Utah, observed a blind pelican being fed, quite well, by other pelicans that brought fish from thirty miles away. When a herd of vicuñas was being chased by hunters, H.A. Weddell saw, more than once on his journey to Bolivia and Peru, strong males lagging behind to protect the herd’s retreat. Instances of compassion for wounded comrades are frequently noted by all field zoologists. Such facts are entirely natural. Compassion is a necessary result of social life. But compassion also signifies a significant advancement in general intelligence and sensitivity. It is the first step toward developing higher moral sentiments and, in turn, a powerful factor for further evolution.

If the views developed on the preceding pages are correct, the question necessarily arises, in how far are they consistent with the theory of struggle for life as it has been developed by Darwin, Wallace, and their followers? and I will now briefly answer this important question. First of all, no naturalist will doubt that the idea of a struggle for life carried on through organic nature is the greatest generalization of our century. Life is struggle; and in that struggle the fittest survive. But the answers to the questions, "By which arms is this struggle chiefly carried on?" and "Who are the fittest in the struggle?" will widely differ according to the importance given to the two different aspects of the struggle: the direct one, for food and safety among separate individuals, and the struggle which Darwin described as "metaphorical"—the struggle, very often collective, against adverse circumstances. No one will deny that there is, within each species, a certain amount of real competition for food—at least, at certain periods. But the question is, whether competition is carried on to the extent admitted by Darwin, or even by Wallace; and whether this competition has played, in the evolution of the animal kingdom, the part assigned to it.

If the views presented in the previous pages are correct, we must ask how they align with the theory of the struggle for life developed by Darwin, Wallace, and their followers. I will now briefly address this important question. First of all, no naturalist would dispute that the concept of a struggle for life throughout the natural world is the biggest idea of our century. Life is a struggle, and in that struggle, the fittest survive. However, the answers to the questions, "What tools are mainly used in this struggle?" and "Who are the fittest in this struggle?" can vary widely depending on how much importance is placed on the two different aspects of the struggle: the direct one for food and safety among individuals, and the struggle that Darwin referred to as "metaphorical"—the often collective struggle against unfavorable circumstances. No one will deny that there is some real competition for food within each species—at least during certain times. But the real question is whether that competition occurs to the extent that Darwin, or even Wallace, suggested, and if this competition has played the role in the evolution of the animal kingdom that has been assigned to it.

The idea which permeates Darwin's work is certainly one of real competition going on within each animal group for food, safety, and possibility of leaving an offspring. He often speaks of regions being stocked with animal life to their full capacity, and from that overstocking he infers the necessity of competition. But when we look in his work for real proofs of that competition, we must confess that we do not find them sufficiently convincing. If we refer to the paragraph entitled "Struggle for Life most severe between Individuals and Varieties of the same Species," we find in it none of that wealth of proofs and illustrations which we are accustomed to find in whatever Darwin wrote. The struggle between individuals of the same species is not illustrated under that heading by even one single instance: it is taken as granted; and the competition between closely-allied animal species is illustrated by but five examples, out of which one, at least (relating to the two species of thrushes), now proves to be doubtful.(32) But when we look for more details in order to ascertain how far the decrease of one species was really occasioned by the increase of the other species, Darwin, with his usual fairness, tells us:

The main idea in Darwin's work is definitely about real competition happening within each animal group for food, safety, and the chance to reproduce. He often mentions areas being populated with animals up to their limits, and from that overcrowding, he concludes there has to be competition. However, when we search his work for solid evidence of that competition, we must admit that we don't find it convincing enough. If we look at the section titled "Struggle for Life most severe between Individuals and Varieties of the same Species," we see that it lacks the abundance of evidence and examples that we usually find in Darwin's writings. The struggle between individuals of the same species isn't illustrated in that section with even one example; it's simply assumed. The competition between closely related animal species is supported by just five examples, and at least one of those, regarding two species of thrushes, is now questionable. But when we seek more details to understand how much the decline of one species was really caused by the rise of another, Darwin, as always, fairly tells us:

"We can dimly see why the competition should be most severe between allied forms which fill nearly the same place in nature; but probably in no case could we precisely say why one species has been victorious over another in the great battle of life."

"We can vaguely understand why competition is most intense among related forms that occupy similar roles in nature; however, it’s likely that we can never quite pinpoint why one species has triumphed over another in the overall struggle for survival."

As to Wallace, who quotes the same facts under a slightly-modified heading ("Struggle for Life between closely-allied Animals and Plants often most severe"), he makes the following remark (italics are mine), which gives quite another aspect to the facts above quoted. He says:

As for Wallace, who mentions the same facts under a slightly changed title ("Struggle for Life between closely-allied Animals and Plants often most severe"), he makes the following remark (italics are mine), which provides a different perspective on the facts mentioned above. He says:

"In some cases, no doubt, there is actual war between the two, the stronger killing the weaker. But this is by no means necessary, and there may be cases in which the weaker species, physically, may prevail by its power of more rapid multiplication, its better withstanding vicissitudes of climate, or its greater cunning in escaping the attacks of common enemies."

"In some cases, it's true that there is actual conflict between the two, with the stronger one killing the weaker. But this is definitely not always the case, and there might be situations where the physically weaker species can succeed because it reproduces faster, adapts better to changes in climate, or is smarter at avoiding attacks from shared enemies."

In such cases what is described as competition may be no competition at all. One species succumbs, not because it is exterminated or starved out by the other species, but because it does not well accommodate itself to new conditions, which the other does. The term "struggle for life" is again used in its metaphorical sense, and may have no other. As to the real competition between individuals of the same species, which is illustrated in another place by the cattle of South America during a period of drought, its value is impaired by its being taken from among domesticated animals. Bisons emigrate in like circumstances in order to avoid competition. However severe the struggle between plants—and this is amply proved—we cannot but repeat Wallace's remark to the effect that "plants live where they can," while animals have, to a great extent, the power of choice of their abode. So that we again are asking ourselves, To what extent does competition really exist within each animal species? Upon what is the assumption based? The same remark must be made concerning the indirect argument in favour of a severe competition and struggle for life within each species, which may be derived from the "extermination of transitional varieties," so often mentioned by Darwin. It is known that for a long time Darwin was worried by the difficulty which he saw in the absence of a long chain of intermediate forms between closely-allied species, and that he found the solution of this difficulty in the supposed extermination of the intermediate forms.(33) However, an attentive reading of the different chapters in which Darwin and Wallace speak of this subject soon brings one to the conclusion that the word "extermination" does not mean real extermination; the same remark which Darwin made concerning his expression: "struggle for existence," evidently applies to the word "extermination" as well. It can by no means be understood in its direct sense, but must be taken "in its metaphoric sense." If we start from the supposition that a given area is stocked with animals to its fullest capacity, and that a keen competition for the sheer means of existence is consequently going on between all the inhabitants—each animal being compelled to fight against all its congeners in order to get its daily food—then the appearance of a new and successful variety would certainly mean in many cases (though not always) the appearance of individuals which are enabled to seize more than their fair share of the means of existence; and the result would be that those individuals would starve both the parental form which does not possess the new variation and the intermediate forms which do not possess it in the same degree. It may be that at the outset, Darwin understood the appearance of new varieties under this aspect; at least, the frequent use of the word "extermination" conveys such an impression. But both he and Wallace knew Nature too well not to perceive that this is by no means the only possible and necessary course of affairs.

In such cases, what’s called competition might not be competition at all. One species fails, not because it’s wiped out or starved by the other species, but because it doesn’t adapt well to new conditions that the other does. The term "struggle for life" is again used metaphorically and may have no other meaning. Regarding real competition among individuals of the same species, which is illustrated elsewhere by the cattle of South America during a drought, its significance is lessened because it comes from domesticated animals. Bisons migrate in similar situations to escape competition. No matter how intense the struggle between plants—and this is well-documented—we can’t help but repeat Wallace’s observation that "plants live where they can," while animals largely have the freedom to choose their habitats. So again, we ask ourselves, how much does competition really exist within each animal species? What is this assumption based on? The same point applies to the indirect argument supporting intense competition and struggle for life within each species, which may come from the "extermination of transitional varieties," often noted by Darwin. It’s known that Darwin was troubled for a long time by the missing long chain of intermediate forms between closely related species, and he resolved this difficulty with the idea of supposed extermination of those intermediate forms. However, a careful reading of the chapters where Darwin and Wallace discuss this topic leads to the conclusion that the word "extermination" doesn’t mean actual extermination; the same point Darwin made about his term "struggle for existence" clearly applies to "extermination" too. It can’t be understood in its literal sense but must be taken "in its metaphorical sense." If we assume that a certain area is fully stocked with animals, and there’s intense competition for basic survival among all the inhabitants—where each animal has to compete against all its peers to get daily food—then the emergence of a new and successful variety would often mean (though not always) that individuals can claim more than their fair share of resources; the outcome would be that those individuals cause both the parental form lacking the new variation and the intermediate forms with it to starve. At first, Darwin might have viewed the rise of new varieties this way; at least, his frequent use of "extermination" gives that impression. But both he and Wallace understood nature well enough to realize that this isn’t the only possible scenario.

If the physical and the biological conditions of a given area, the extension of the area occupied by a given species, and the habits of all the members of the latter remained unchanged—then the sudden appearance of a new variety might mean the starving out and the extermination of all the individuals which were not endowed in a sufficient degree with the new feature by which the new variety is characterized. But such a combination of conditions is precisely what we do not see in Nature. Each species is continually tending to enlarge its abode; migration to new abodes is the rule with the slow snail, as with the swift bird; physical changes are continually going on in every given area; and new varieties among animals consist in an immense number of cases-perhaps in the majority—not in the growth of new weapons for snatching the food from the mouth of its congeners—food is only one out of a hundred of various conditions of existence—but, as Wallace himself shows in a charming paragraph on the "divergence of characters" (Darwinism, p. 107), in forming new habits, moving to new abodes, and taking to new sorts of food. In all such cases there will be no extermination, even no competition—the new adaptation being a relief from competition, if it ever existed; and yet there will be, after a time, an absence of intermediate links, in consequence of a mere survival of those which are best fitted for the new conditions—as surely as under the hypothesis of extermination of the parental form. It hardly need be added that if we admit, with Spencer, all the Lamarckians, and Darwin himself, the modifying influence of the surroundings upon the species, there remains still less necessity for the extermination of the intermediate forms.

If the physical and biological conditions of a specific area, the range of a species, and the behaviors of all its members stayed the same, then the sudden emergence of a new variety could lead to the extinction of individuals that lack the new characteristic that defines this variety. However, this scenario is not what we observe in nature. Each species is constantly aiming to expand its habitat; migration to new areas happens for both slow snails and fast birds. Physical changes are always occurring in any given area, and new varieties in animals often arise not from developing new tools to compete for food, which is just one of many survival factors, but as Wallace illustrates in a captivating passage on the "divergence of characters" (Darwinism, p. 107), through the development of new habits, relocation to new environments, and the adoption of different food sources. In all these situations, extermination—and even competition—will typically not occur, as the new adaptation helps avoid competition if it existed at all. Still, over time, there will be gaps in the intermediate forms due to the survival of those best suited for the new conditions, just as if we had assumed the parental form was exterminated. It hardly needs to be said that if we accept the modifying influence of the environment on species, as Spencer, all Lamarckians, and Darwin himself do, there is even less need for the extinction of intermediate forms.

The importance of migration and of the consequent isolation of groups of animals, for the origin of new varieties and ultimately of new species, which was indicated by Moritz Wagner, was fully recognized by Darwin himself. Consequent researches have only accentuated the importance of this factor, and they have shown how the largeness of the area occupied by a given species—which Darwin considered with full reason so important for the appearance of new varieties—can be combined with the isolation of parts of the species, in consequence of local geological changes, or of local barriers. It would be impossible to enter here into the discussion of this wide question, but a few remarks will do to illustrate the combined action of these agencies. It is known that portions of a given species will often take to a new sort of food. The squirrels, for instance, when there is a scarcity of cones in the larch forests, remove to the fir-tree forests, and this change of food has certain well-known physiological effects on the squirrels. If this change of habits does not last—if next year the cones are again plentiful in the dark larch woods—no new variety of squirrels will evidently arise from this cause. But if part of the wide area occupied by the squirrels begins to have its physical characters altered—in consequence of, let us say, a milder climate or desiccation, which both bring about an increase of the pine forests in proportion to the larch woods—and if some other conditions concur to induce the squirrels to dwell on the outskirts of the desiccating region—we shall have then a new variety, i.e. an incipient new species of squirrels, without there having been anything that would deserve the name of extermination among the squirrels. A larger proportion of squirrels of the new, better adapted variety would survive every year, and the intermediate links would die in the course of time, without having been starved out by Malthusian competitors. This is exactly what we see going on during the great physical changes which are accomplished over large areas in Central Asia, owing to the desiccation which is going on there since the glacial period.

The significance of migration and the resulting isolation of animal groups for the development of new varieties and, ultimately, new species was highlighted by Moritz Wagner and fully acknowledged by Darwin himself. Subsequent research has further emphasized the importance of this factor, demonstrating how the size of the area inhabited by a species—which Darwin rightly deemed crucial for the emergence of new varieties—can interact with the isolation of parts of that species due to local geological changes or barriers. It's impossible to delve into this broad topic here, but a few observations can illustrate how these forces work together. It's known that specific portions of a species will often adapt to a new type of food. For example, squirrels will move to fir-tree forests when there’s a shortage of cones in the larch forests, and this dietary change has notable physiological effects on them. If this shift in habits is temporary—if, the following year, cones are plentiful again in the larch woods—no new variety of squirrels will emerge from this. However, if part of the large area occupied by the squirrels begins to change physically—due to, for instance, a milder climate or drying conditions, which both increase the proportion of pine forests relative to larch—and if other conditions encourage squirrels to live on the edges of the drying area, then we will see a new variety, essentially a nascent new species of squirrels, without any process of extermination among the squirrels. A larger number of squirrels in the newly adapted variety would survive each year, while the intermediate forms would gradually die off, not due to competition but simply by natural attrition. This phenomenon is precisely what we observe during the significant physical changes occurring across extensive regions of Central Asia due to the ongoing desiccation since the glacial period.

To take another example, it has been proved by geologists that the present wild horse (Equus Przewalski) has slowly been evolved during the later parts of the Tertiary and the Quaternary period, but that during this succession of ages its ancestors were not confined to some given, limited area of the globe. They wandered over both the Old and New World, returning, in all probability, after a time to the pastures which they had, in the course of their migrations, formerly left.(34) Consequently, if we do not find now, in Asia, all the intermediate links between the present wild horse and its Asiatic Post-Tertiary ancestors, this does not mean at all that the intermediate links have been exterminated. No such extermination has ever taken place. No exceptional mortality may even have occurred among the ancestral species: the individuals which belonged to intermediate varieties and species have died in the usual course of events—often amidst plentiful food, and their remains were buried all over the globe.

To provide another example, geologists have shown that the current wild horse (Equus Przewalski) has gradually evolved during the later parts of the Tertiary and Quaternary periods. However, throughout this timeline, its ancestors weren't restricted to a specific, limited area of the planet. They roamed across both the Old World and the New World, likely returning after a while to the pastures they had previously left during their migrations. Consequently, if we don't find all the intermediate links between the present wild horse and its Asiatic Post-Tertiary ancestors in Asia now, it doesn't mean that these intermediate links have been wiped out. Such extermination has never occurred. It's possible that no unusual mortality took place among the ancestral species: individuals belonging to intermediate varieties and species have died as part of the normal course of events—often with plenty of food around, and their remains have been buried all over the world.

In short, if we carefully consider this matter, and, carefully re-read what Darwin himself wrote upon this subject, we see that if the word "extermination" be used at all in connection with transitional varieties, it must be used in its metaphoric sense. As to "competition," this expression, too, is continually used by Darwin (see, for instance, the paragraph "On Extinction") as an image, or as a way-of-speaking, rather than with the intention of conveying the idea of a real competition between two portions of the same species for the means of existence. At any rate, the absence of intermediate forms is no argument in favour of it.

In short, if we think this through carefully and re-read what Darwin wrote on this topic, we can see that if the term "extermination" is used at all in relation to transitional varieties, it must be understood in a metaphorical way. As for "competition," Darwin uses this term frequently (for example, in the section "On Extinction") more as a figure of speech rather than to suggest a real competition between two parts of the same species for survival. In any case, the lack of intermediate forms doesn't support this idea.

In reality, the chief argument in favour of a keen competition for the means of existence continually going on within every animal species is—to use Professor Geddes' expression—the "arithmetical argument" borrowed from Malthus.

In reality, the main argument for the ongoing intense competition for resources among every animal species is, to quote Professor Geddes, the "arithmetical argument" taken from Malthus.

But this argument does not prove it at all. We might as well take a number of villages in South-East Russia, the inhabitants of which enjoy plenty of food, but have no sanitary accommodation of any kind; and seeing that for the last eighty years the birth-rate was sixty in the thousand, while the population is now what it was eighty years ago, we might conclude that there has been a terrible competition between the inhabitants. But the truth is that from year to year the population remained stationary, for the simple reason that one-third of the new-born died before reaching their sixth month of life; one-half died within the next four years, and out of each hundred born, only seventeen or so reached the age of twenty. The new-comers went away before having grown to be competitors. It is evident that if such is the case with men, it is still more the case with animals. In the feathered world the destruction of the eggs goes on on such a tremendous scale that eggs are the chief food of several species in the early summer; not to, say a word of the storms, the inundations which destroy nests by the million in America, and the sudden changes of weather which are fatal to the young mammals. Each storm, each inundation, each visit of a rat to a bird's nest, each sudden change of temperature, take away those competitors which appear so terrible in theory.

But this argument doesn't prove anything at all. We could look at a number of villages in South-East Russia, where the people have plenty of food but no sanitation facilities. Over the last eighty years, the birth rate was sixty per thousand, and the population is still what it was eighty years ago, so we might think there’s been fierce competition among the inhabitants. But the reality is that the population stayed the same year after year because one-third of newborns died before their sixth month, half died within the next four years, and out of every hundred born, only about seventeen made it to twenty. The newcomers left before they had a chance to become competitors. It's clear that if this happens with humans, it's even more so with animals. In the world of birds, the loss of eggs is so massive that eggs are the main food for several species in early summer; not to mention the storms and floods that destroy nests by the millions in America, along with the sudden weather shifts that can be deadly for young mammals. Every storm, every flood, every rat visiting a bird’s nest, and every sudden temperature change takes away those competitors that seem so intimidating in theory.

As to the facts of an extremely rapid increase of horses and cattle in America, of pigs and rabbits in New Zealand, and even of wild animals imported from Europe (where their numbers are kept down by man, not by competition), they rather seem opposed to the theory of over-population. If horses and cattle could so rapidly multiply in America, it simply proved that, however numberless the buffaloes and other ruminants were at that time in the New World, its grass-eating population was far below what the prairies could maintain. If millions of intruders have found plenty of food without starving out the former population of the prairies, we must rather conclude that the Europeans found a want of grass-eaters in America, not an excess. And we have good reasons to believe that want of animal population is the natural state of things all over the world, with but a few temporary exceptions to the rule. The actual numbers of animals in a given region are determined, not by the highest feeding capacity of the region, but by what it is every year under the most unfavourable conditions. So that, for that reason alone, competition hardly can be a normal condition. But other causes intervene as well to cut, down the animal population below even that low standard. If we take the horses and cattle which are grazing all the winter through in the Steppes of Transbaikalia, we find them very lean and exhausted at the end of the winter. But they grow exhausted not because there is not enough food for all of them—the grass buried under a thin sheet of snow is everywhere in abundance—but because of the difficulty of getting it from beneath the snow, and this difficulty is the same for all horses alike. Besides, days of glazed frost are common in early spring, and if several such days come in succession the horses grow still more exhausted. But then comes a snow-storm, which compels the already weakened animals to remain without any food for several days, and very great numbers of them die. The losses during the spring are so severe that if the season has been more inclement than usual they are even not repaired by the new breeds—the more so as all horses are exhausted, and the young foals are born in a weaker condition. The numbers of horses and cattle thus always remain beneath what they otherwise might be; all the year round there is food for five or ten times as many animals, and yet their population increases extremely slowly. But as soon as the Buriate owner makes ever so small a provision of hay in the steppe, and throws it open during days of glazed frost, or heavier snow-fall, he immediately sees the increase of his herd. Almost all free grass-eating animals and many rodents in Asia and America being in very much the same conditions, we can safely say that their numbers are not kept down by competition; that at no time of the year they can struggle for food, and that if they never reach anything approaching to over-population, the cause is in the climate, not in competition.

As for the facts about the incredibly rapid growth of horses and cattle in America, pigs and rabbits in New Zealand, and even wild animals brought in from Europe (where their numbers are controlled by humans, not by competition), they seem to contradict the idea of overpopulation. If horses and cattle could multiply so quickly in America, it simply proves that, despite the countless buffaloes and other herbivores that existed in the New World at that time, the grass-eating population was far lower than what the prairies could support. If millions of newcomers have found plenty of food without starving the original prairie population, we should conclude that Europeans discovered a lack of grass-eaters in America, not an excess. We have good reasons to believe that a lack of animal population is the natural state of things worldwide, with just a few temporary exceptions. The actual number of animals in a given area is determined not by the region's highest feeding capacity, but by what it can sustain each year under the worst conditions. Therefore, competition can hardly be considered a normal situation. Additionally, other factors come into play that reduce animal populations even below that low standard. If we look at the horses and cattle grazing all winter in the Steppes of Transbaikalia, we find them very thin and worn out by the end of winter. However, they don’t grow weak because there isn’t enough food for all of them—the grass buried under a thin layer of snow is plentiful—but because it’s difficult to access it beneath the snow, and this difficulty applies to all horses equally. Also, days of icy frost are common in early spring, and if several of these days happen in a row, the horses become even more exhausted. Then a snowstorm can force the already weakened animals to go several days without food, leading to a significant number of deaths. The losses in spring are so severe that if the weather has been harsher than usual, they aren’t even compensated by new births—the situation is worsened by the fact that all horses are depleted, and the young foals are born in a weaker state. Consequently, the numbers of horses and cattle always remain lower than they could be; there’s enough food year-round for five or ten times as many animals, yet their population increases very slowly. However, as soon as the Buriate owner makes even a slight provision of hay in the steppe and opens it up during icy frost or heavier snowfall, he immediately sees the growth of his herd. Since almost all free-grazing animals and many rodents in Asia and America are in very similar conditions, we can confidently say that their numbers are not kept down by competition; at no time of the year do they struggle for food, and if they never approach overpopulation, the reason lies in the climate, not competition.

The importance of natural checks to over-multiplication, and especially their bearing upon the competition hypothesis, seems never to have been taken into due account. The checks, or rather some of them, are mentioned, but their action is seldom studied in detail. However, if we compare the action of the natural checks with that of competition, we must recognize at once that the latter sustains no comparison whatever with the other checks. Thus, Mr. Bates mentions the really astounding numbers of winged ants which are destroyed during their exodus. The dead or half-dead bodies of the formica de fuego (Myrmica saevissima) which had been blown into the river during a gale "were heaped in a line an inch or two in height and breadth, the line continuing without interruption for miles at the edge of the water."(35) Myriads of ants are thus destroyed amidst a nature which might support a hundred times as many ants as are actually living. Dr. Altum, a German forester, who wrote a very interesting book about animals injurious to our forests, also gives many facts showing the immense importance of natural checks. He says, that a succession of gales or cold and damp weather during the exodus of the pine-moth (Bombyx pini) destroy it to incredible amounts, and during the spring of 1871 all these moths disappeared at once, probably killed by a succession of cold nights.(36) Many like examples relative to various insects could be quoted from various parts of Europe. Dr. Altum also mentions the bird-enemies of the pine-moth, and the immense amount of its eggs destroyed by foxes; but he adds that the parasitic fungi which periodically infest it are a far more terrible enemy than any bird, because they destroy the moth over very large areas at once. As to various species of mice (Mus sylvaticus, Arvicola arvalis, and A. agrestis), the same author gives a long list of their enemies, but he remarks: "However, the most terrible enemies of mice are not other animals, but such sudden changes of weather as occur almost every year." Alternations of frost and warm weather destroy them in numberless quantities; "one single sudden change can reduce thousands of mice to the number of a few individuals." On the other side, a warm winter, or a winter which gradually steps in, make them multiply in menacing proportions, notwithstanding every enemy; such was the case in 1876 and 1877.(37) Competition, in the case of mice, thus appears a quite trifling factor when compared with weather. Other facts to the same effect are also given as regards squirrels.

The significance of natural limits on overpopulation, especially regarding the competition hypothesis, seems to have been largely overlooked. Some of these limits are mentioned, but their effects are rarely examined in detail. If we compare the impact of natural limits to that of competition, it's clear that the latter pales in comparison. For example, Mr. Bates points out the astonishing number of winged ants that are killed during their migration. The dead or dying bodies of the fire ants (Myrmica saevissima) that were swept into the river during a storm "were piled in a line an inch or two high and wide, and this line continued uninterrupted for miles along the water's edge."(35) Countless ants are wiped out in a nature that could support a hundred times as many as are currently alive. Dr. Altum, a German forester who wrote a fascinating book about animals harmful to our forests, also provides numerous examples that illustrate the immense role of natural limits. He notes that a series of storms or cold and damp weather during the migration of the pine moth (Bombyx pini) can devastate its population, and in the spring of 1871, all of these moths vanished unexpectedly, likely killed by a series of cold nights.(36) Many similar examples regarding various insects could be cited from different parts of Europe. Dr. Altum also discusses the bird predators of the pine moth and the vast number of its eggs destroyed by foxes; however, he emphasizes that the parasitic fungi that periodically plague it are a much greater threat than any bird, as they can wipe out the moth across large areas simultaneously. Regarding different species of mice (Mus sylvaticus, Arvicola arvalis, and A. agrestis), the same author lists many of their predators but notes: "However, the most severe enemies of mice are not other animals, but sudden weather changes that occur almost every year." Fluctuations between frost and warm weather kill them in massive numbers; "one single sudden change can reduce thousands of mice to just a few." Conversely, a mild winter or a gradually approaching winter can lead to alarming population growth, regardless of their predators; this happened in 1876 and 1877.(37) Thus, in the case of mice, competition seems a trivial factor compared to weather. Similar facts can also be found regarding squirrels.

As to birds, it is well known how they suffer from sudden changes of weather. Late snow-storms are as destructive of bird-life on the English moors, as they are in Siberia; and Ch. Dixon saw the red grouse so pressed during some exceptionally severe winters, that they quitted the moors in numbers, "and we have then known them actually to be taken in the streets of Sheffield. Persistent wet," he adds, "is almost as fatal to them."

As for birds, it's well known how they struggle with sudden weather changes. Late snowstorms are just as harmful to bird life on the English moors as they are in Siberia; Ch. Dixon observed the red grouse affected so much during some particularly harsh winters that they left the moors in large numbers, "and we even saw them captured in the streets of Sheffield." He adds, "Continuous wet weather is almost as lethal to them."

On the other side, the contagious diseases which continually visit most animal species destroy them in such numbers that the losses often cannot be repaired for many years, even with the most rapidly-multiplying animals. Thus, some sixty years ago, the sousliks suddenly disappeared in the neighbourhood of Sarepta, in South-Eastern Russia, in consequence of some epidemics; and for years no sousliks were seen in that neighbourhood. It took many years before they became as numerous as they formerly were.(38)

On the other hand, the contagious diseases that constantly affect most animal species kill so many that the losses often can't be recovered for many years, even with the fastest-reproducing animals. For example, around sixty years ago, the sousliks suddenly vanished near Sarepta in South-Eastern Russia due to some epidemics, and for years, no sousliks were spotted in that area. It took a long time before they became as numerous as they used to be. (38)

Like facts, all tending to reduce the importance given to competition, could be produced in numbers. Of course, it might be replied, in Darwin's words, that nevertheless each organic being "at some period of its life, during some season of the year, during each generation or at intervals, has to struggle for life and to suffer great destruction," and that the fittest survive during such periods of hard struggle for life. But if the evolution of the animal world were based exclusively, or even chiefly, upon the survival of the fittest during periods of calamities; if natural selection were limited in its action to periods of exceptional drought, or sudden changes of temperature, or inundations, retrogression would be the rule in the animal world. Those who survive a famine, or a severe epidemic of cholera, or small-pox, or diphtheria, such as we see them in uncivilized countries, are neither the strongest, nor the healthiest, nor the most intelligent. No progress could be based on those survivals—the less so as all survivors usually come out of the ordeal with an impaired health, like the Transbaikalian horses just mentioned, or the Arctic crews, or the garrison of a fortress which has been compelled to live for a few months on half rations, and comes out of its experience with a broken health, and subsequently shows a quite abnormal mortality. All that natural selection can do in times of calamities is to spare the individuals endowed with the greatest endurance for privations of all kinds. So it does among the Siberian horses and cattle. They are enduring; they can feed upon the Polar birch in case of need; they resist cold and hunger. But no Siberian horse is capable of carrying half the weight which a European horse carries with ease; no Siberian cow gives half the amount of milk given by a Jersey cow, and no natives of uncivilized countries can bear a comparison with Europeans. They may better endure hunger and cold, but their physical force is very far below that of a well-fed European, and their intellectual progress is despairingly slow. "Evil cannot be productive of good," as Tchernyshevsky wrote in a remarkable essay upon Darwinism.(39)

Like facts, there could be plenty of evidence showing that competition isn't as important as it's often seen. Of course, one could respond with Darwin’s observation that at some point in their lives, during certain seasons, each species has to fight for survival and endure significant destruction, and that the ones best suited for survival get through these tough times. However, if the evolution of the animal kingdom were solely, or mostly, about the survival of the fittest during crises, and if natural selection only acted during extreme droughts, sudden temperature shifts, or floods, then regression would be the norm in the animal kingdom. The survivors of a famine or a severe outbreak of diseases like cholera or smallpox in less developed regions are not necessarily the strongest, healthiest, or smartest. Progress can't be founded on those survivors, especially since most who make it through such hardships come out with weakened health, like the mentioned Transbaikalian horses, or crews in the Arctic, or a fortress garrison forced to live on half rations for months, who emerge with lasting health issues and a significantly higher mortality rate. During calamities, natural selection can only favor individuals with the greatest endurance for various hardships. This is evident among Siberian horses and cattle that have the stamina to survive by feeding on Polar birch when needed and endure cold and hunger. However, no Siberian horse can carry as much weight as a European horse can easily manage; no Siberian cow produces half the milk a Jersey cow does, and no individuals from less developed regions can compare to Europeans. They may have better endurance against hunger and cold, but their physical strength is significantly lower than that of a well-fed European, and their intellectual development is discouragingly slow. "Evil cannot be productive of good," as Tchernyshevsky wrote in an insightful essay on Darwinism.

Happily enough, competition is not the rule either in the animal world or in mankind. It is limited among animals to exceptional periods, and natural selection finds better fields for its activity. Better conditions are created by the elimination of competition by means of mutual aid and mutual Support.(40) In the great struggle for life—for the greatest possible fulness and intensity of life with the least waste of energy—natural selection continually seeks out the ways precisely for avoiding competition as much as possible. The ants combine in nests and nations; they pile up their stores, they rear their cattle—and thus avoid competition; and natural selection picks out of the ants' family the species which know best how to avoid competition, with its unavoidably deleterious consequences. Most of our birds slowly move southwards as the winter comes, or gather in numberless societies and undertake long journeys—and thus avoid competition. Many rodents fall asleep when the time comes that competition should set in; while other rodents store food for the winter, and gather in large villages for obtaining the necessary protection when at work. The reindeer, when the lichens are dry in the interior of the continent, migrate towards the sea. Buffaloes cross an immense continent in order to find plenty of food. And the beavers, when they grow numerous on a river, divide into two parties, and go, the old ones down the river, and the young ones up the river and avoid competition. And when animals can neither fall asleep, nor migrate, nor lay in stores, nor themselves grow their food like the ants, they do what the titmouse does, and what Wallace (Darwinism, ch. v) has so charmingly described: they resort to new kinds of food—and thus, again, avoid competition.

Fortunately, competition isn't the dominant factor in the animal kingdom or among humans. It only occurs during specific times among animals, while natural selection finds better opportunities elsewhere. Better conditions emerge when competition is reduced through mutual support and cooperation. In the ongoing fight for survival—aiming for a full and vibrant life while wasting the least energy—natural selection continuously looks for ways to minimize competition. Ants form colonies and communities; they gather resources and farm other species, thereby avoiding competition. Natural selection favors ant species that excel at this. Many birds migrate south as winter approaches or join together in large flocks to undertake long journeys, thus sidestepping competition. Various rodents hibernate when competition arises, while others store food for winter and form large communities for protection. Reindeer move toward the coast when the interior lichen dries up, and buffaloes traverse vast landscapes searching for abundant food. Beavers, when populations grow in a river, split into two groups, with the older ones heading downstream and the younger ones going upstream to avoid competition. When animals cannot hibernate, migrate, or gather food like ants, they adapt like the titmouse, as Wallace (Darwinism, ch. v) beautifully described, by seeking out new food sources—once again avoiding competition.

"Don't compete!—competition is always injurious to the species, and you have plenty of resources to avoid it!" That is the tendency of nature, not always realized in full, but always present. That is the watchword which comes to us from the bush, the forest, the river, the ocean. "Therefore combine—practise mutual aid! That is the surest means for giving to each and to all the greatest safety, the best guarantee of existence and progress, bodily, intellectual, and moral." That is what Nature teaches us; and that is what all those animals which have attained the highest position in their respective classes have done. That is also what man—the most primitive man—has been doing; and that is why man has reached the position upon which we stand now, as we shall see in the subsequent chapters devoted to mutual aid in human societies.

"Don’t compete!—competition always harms the species, and you have plenty of resources to avoid it!" That’s the way nature tends to work, not always fully recognized, but always there. That’s the message we get from the bush, the forest, the river, and the ocean. "So, work together—practice mutual aid! That’s the best way to ensure maximum safety and the best chance for survival and progress, physically, mentally, and morally." That’s what Nature teaches us; and that’s what all those animals that have reached the highest positions in their groups have done. That’s also what humans—the most primitive humans—have been doing; and that’s why humans have achieved their current status, as we’ll explore in the following chapters about mutual aid in human societies.

NOTES:

1. Syevettsoff's Periodical Phenomena, p. 251.

1. Syevettsoff's Periodical Phenomena, p. 251.

2. Seyfferlitz, quoted by Brehm, iv. 760.

2. Seyfferlitz, quoted by Brehm, iv. 760.

3. The Arctic Voyages of A.E. Nordenskjold, London, 1879, p. 135. See also the powerful description of the St. Kilda islands by Mr. Dixon (quoted by Seebohm), and nearly all books of Arctic travel.

3. The Arctic Voyages of A.E. Nordenskjold, London, 1879, p. 135. See also the vivid description of the St. Kilda islands by Mr. Dixon (quoted by Seebohm), along with almost all books on Arctic travel.

4. Elliot Coues, in Bulletin U.S. Geol. Survey of Territories, iv. No. 7, pp. 556, 579, etc. Among the gulls (Larus argentatus), Polyakoff saw on a marsh in Northern Russia, that the nesting grounds of a very great number of these birds were always patrolled by one male, which warned the colony of the approach of danger. All birds rose in such case and attacked the enemy with great vigour. The females, which had five or six nests together on each knoll of the marsh, kept a certain order in leaving their nests in search of food. The fledglings, which otherwise are extremely unprotected and easily become the prey of the rapacious birds, were never left alone ("Family Habits among the Aquatic Birds," in Proceedings of the Zool. Section of St. Petersburg Soc. of Nat., Dec. 17, 1874).

4. Elliot Coues, in Bulletin U.S. Geol. Survey of Territories, iv. No. 7, pp. 556, 579, etc. Among the gulls (Larus argentatus), Polyakoff observed on a marsh in Northern Russia that the nesting areas of a large number of these birds were always monitored by one male, which alerted the colony to approaching danger. In such cases, all the birds would take flight and vigorously defend against the threat. The females, which had five or six nests grouped on each hillock of the marsh, left their nests in an orderly fashion to find food. The fledglings, which are otherwise very vulnerable and easily become targets for predatory birds, were never left unattended ("Family Habits among the Aquatic Birds," in Proceedings of the Zool. Section of St. Petersburg Soc. of Nat., Dec. 17, 1874).

5. Brehm Father, quoted by A. Brehm, iv. 34 seq. See also White's Natural History of Selborne, Letter XI.

5. Brehm Father, cited by A. Brehm, iv. 34 and following. Also see White's Natural History of Selborne, Letter XI.

6. Dr. Coues, Birds of Dakota and Montana, in Bulletin U.S. Survey of Territories, iv. No. 7.

6. Dr. Coues, Birds of Dakota and Montana, in Bulletin U.S. Survey of Territories, iv. No. 7.

7. It has often been intimated that larger birds may occasionally transport some of the smaller birds when they cross together the Mediterranean, but the fact still remains doubtful. On the other side, it is certain that some smaller birds join the bigger ones for migration. The fact has been noticed several times, and it was recently confirmed by L. Buxbaum at Raunheim. He saw several parties of cranes which had larks flying in the midst and on both sides of their migratory columns (Der zoologische Garten, 1886, p. 133).

7. It has often been suggested that larger birds might sometimes carry some smaller birds when they cross the Mediterranean together, but this remains uncertain. On the other hand, it is clear that some smaller birds join the larger ones during migration. This has been observed several times, and it was recently confirmed by L. Buxbaum in Raunheim. He saw several groups of cranes with larks flying among them and on both sides of their migration paths (Der zoologische Garten, 1886, p. 133).

8. H. Seebohm and Ch. Dixon both mention this habit.

8. H. Seebohm and Ch. Dixon both note this behavior.

9. The fact is well known to every field-naturalist, and with reference to England several examples may be found in Charles Dixon's Among the Birds in Northern Shires. The chaffinches arrive during winter in vast flocks; and about the same time, i.e. in November, come flocks of bramblings; redwings also frequent the same places "in similar large companies," and so on (pp. 165, 166).

9. Every field naturalist knows this well, and in relation to England, several examples can be found in Charles Dixon's Among the Birds in Northern Shires. Chaffinches arrive in huge flocks during winter, and around the same time, in November, flocks of bramblings show up as well; redwings also visit the same areas "in similarly large groups," and so on (pp. 165, 166).

10. S.W. Baker, Wild Beasts, etc., vol. i. p. 316.

10. S.W. Baker, Wild Beasts, etc., vol. i. p. 316.

11. Tschudi, Thierleben der Alpenwelt, p. 404.

11. Tschudi, Animal Life in the Alpine World, p. 404.

12. Houzeau's Etudes, ii. 463.

12. Houzeau's Studies, ii. 463.

13. For their hunting associations see Sir E. Tennant's Natural History of Ceylon, quoted in Romanes's Animal Intelligence, p. 432.

13. For their hunting groups, see Sir E. Tennant's Natural History of Ceylon, referenced in Romanes's Animal Intelligence, p. 432.

14. See Emil Huter's letter in L. Buchner's Liebe.

14. Check out Emil Huter's letter in L. Buchner's Liebe.

15. With regard to the viscacha it is very interesting to note that these highly-sociable little animals not only live peaceably together in each village, but that whole villages visit each other at nights. Sociability is thus extended to the whole species—not only to a given society, or to a nation, as we saw it with the ants. When the farmer destroys a viscacha-burrow, and buries the inhabitants under a heap of earth, other viscachas—we are told by Hudson—"come from a distance to dig out those that are buried alive" (l.c., p. 311). This is a widely-known fact in La Plata, verified by the author.

15. Regarding the viscacha, it's fascinating to note that these very social little creatures not only live harmoniously together in each village but also that entire villages visit each other at night. Their sociability extends to the entire species—not just to one community, or to a nation, as we observed with the ants. When a farmer destroys a viscacha burrow and buries the residents under a pile of dirt, other viscachas—according to Hudson—“come from a distance to dig out those that are buried alive” (l.c., p. 311). This is a well-known fact in La Plata, confirmed by the author.

16. Handbuch für Jäger und Jagdberechtigte, quoted by Brehm, ii. 223.

16. Handbook for Hunters and Hunting Rights Holders, quoted by Brehm, ii. 223.

17. Buffon's Histoire Naturelle.

Buffon's Natural History.

18. In connection with the horses it is worthy of notice that the quagga zebra, which never comes together with the dauw zebra, nevertheless lives on excellent terms, not only with ostriches, which are very good sentries, but also with gazelles, several species of antelopes, and gnus. We thus have a case of mutual dislike between the quagga and the dauw which cannot be explained by competition for food. The fact that the quagga lives together with ruminants feeding on the same grass as itself excludes that hypothesis, and we must look for some incompatibility of character, as in the case of the hare and the rabbit. Cf., among others, Clive Phillips-Wolley's Big Game Shooting (Badminton Library), which contains excellent illustrations of various species living together in East Africa.

18. Regarding the horses, it's interesting to note that the quagga zebra, which never mixes with the dauw zebra, still gets along well not only with ostriches, which are great at keeping watch, but also with gazelles, various types of antelopes, and gnus. This shows there's a mutual dislike between the quagga and the dauw that can't be explained by competition for food. Since the quagga shares habitat with ruminants that eat the same grass, that theory doesn't hold up, so we need to consider some kind of character incompatibility, similar to the relationship between hares and rabbits. Cf., among others, Clive Phillips-Wolley's Big Game Shooting (Badminton Library), which has fantastic illustrations of different species coexisting in East Africa.

19. Our Tungus hunter, who was going to marry, and therefore was prompted by the desire of getting as many furs as he possibly could, was beating the hill-sides all day long on horseback in search of deer. His efforts were not rewarded by even so much as one fallow deer killed every day; and he was an excellent hunter.

19. Our Tungus hunter, who was about to get married and thus motivated to collect as many furs as he could, spent all day riding on horseback, searching the hills for deer. Despite his efforts, he didn’t manage to catch a single fallow deer each day; and he was a skilled hunter.

20. According to Samuel W. Baker, elephants combine in larger groups than the "compound family." "I have frequently observed," he wrote, "in the portion of Ceylon known as the Park Country, the tracks of elephants in great numbers which have evidently been considerable herds that have joined together in a general retreat from a ground which they considered insecure" (Wild Beasts and their Ways, vol. i. p. 102).

20. According to Samuel W. Baker, elephants gather in larger groups than just the "compound family." "I've seen," he wrote, "in the area of Ceylon known as the Park Country, plenty of tracks from elephants that clearly indicate large herds coming together in a general retreat from a place they felt was unsafe" (Wild Beasts and their Ways, vol. i. p. 102).

21. Pigs, attacked by wolves, do the same (Hudson, l.c.).

21. Pigs attacked by wolves react similarly (Hudson, l.c.).

22. Romanes's Animal Intelligence, p. 472.

22. Romanes's Animal Intelligence, p. 472.

23. Brehm, i. 82; Darwin's Descent of Man, ch. iii. The Kozloff expedition of 1899-1901 have also had to sustain in Northern Thibet a similar fight.

23. Brehm, i. 82; Darwin's Descent of Man, ch. iii. The Kozloff expedition from 1899-1901 also had to endure a similar struggle in Northern Tibet.

24. The more strange was it to read in the previously-mentioned article by Huxley the following paraphrase of a well-known sentence of Rousseau: "The first men who substituted mutual peace for that of mutual war—whatever the motive which impelled them to take that step—created society" (Nineteenth Century, Feb. 1888, p. 165). Society has not been created by man; it is anterior to man.

24. It was even more surprising to read in the previously-mentioned article by Huxley the following rephrasing of a famous sentence by Rousseau: "The first people who chose mutual peace over mutual war—regardless of their reasons for doing so—created society" (Nineteenth Century, Feb. 1888, p. 165). Society was not created by humans; it existed before humans.

25. Such monographs as the chapter on "Music and Dancing in Nature" which we have in Hudson's Naturalist on the La Plata, and Carl Gross' Play of Animals, have already thrown a considerable light upon an instinct which is absolutely universal in Nature.

25. Monographs like the chapter on "Music and Dancing in Nature" found in Hudson's Naturalist on the La Plata and Carl Gross' Play of Animals have already shed significant light on an instinct that is completely universal in Nature.

26. Not only numerous species of birds possess the habit of assembling together—in many cases always at the same spot—to indulge in antics and dancing performances, but W.H. Hudson's experience is that nearly all mammals and birds ("probably there are really no exceptions") indulge frequently in more or less regular or set performances with or without sound, or composed of sound exclusively (p. 264).

26. Many bird species have a habit of gathering together—often at the same place—to engage in playful antics and dance routines. According to W.H. Hudson, almost all mammals and birds ("there are probably really no exceptions") frequently partake in regular or organized performances, whether they include sound, consist solely of sound, or are silent (p. 264).

27. For the choruses of monkeys, see Brehm.

27. For the groups of monkeys, see Brehm.

28. Haygarth, Bush Life in Australia, p. 58.

28. Haygarth, Bush Life in Australia, p. 58.

29. To quote but a few instances, a wounded badger was carried away by another badger suddenly appearing on the scene; rats have been seen feeding a blind couple (Seelenleben der Thiere, p. 64 seq.). Brehm himself saw two crows feeding in a hollow tree a third crow which was wounded; its wound was several weeks old (Hausfreund, 1874, 715; Buchner's Liebe, 203). Mr. Blyth saw Indian crows feeding two or three blind comrades; and so on.

29. Just to mention a few examples, a wounded badger was taken away by another badger that suddenly showed up; rats have been observed feeding a blind couple (Seelenleben der Thiere, p. 64 seq.). Brehm himself witnessed two crows feeding a third crow that was injured; its injury had been there for several weeks (Hausfreund, 1874, 715; Buchner's Liebe, 203). Mr. Blyth saw Indian crows feeding two or three blind companions; and so on.

30. Man and Beast, p. 344.

30. Man and Beast, p. 344.

31. L.H. Morgan, The American Beaver, 1868, p. 272; Descent of Man, ch. iv.

31. L.H. Morgan, The American Beaver, 1868, p. 272; Descent of Man, ch. iv.

32. One species of swallow is said to have caused the decrease of another swallow species in North America; the recent increase of the missel-thrush in Scotland has caused the decrease of the song-thrush; the brown rat has taken the place of the black rat in Europe; in Russia the small cockroach has everywhere driven before it its greater congener; and in Australia the imported hive-bee is rapidly exterminating the small stingless bee. Two other cases, but relative to domesticated animals, are mentioned in the preceding paragraph. While recalling these same facts, A.R. Wallace remarks in a footnote relative to the Scottish thrushes: "Prof. A. Newton, however, informs me that these species do not interfere in the way here stated" (Darwinism, p. 34). As to the brown rat, it is known that, owing to its amphibian habits, it usually stays in the lower parts of human dwellings (low cellars, sewers, etc.), as also on the banks of canals and rivers; it also undertakes distant migrations in numberless bands. The black rat, on the contrary, prefers staying in our dwellings themselves, under the floor, as well as in our stables and barns. It thus is much more exposed to be exterminated by man; and we cannot maintain, with any approach to certainty, that the black rat is being either exterminated or starved out by the brown rat and not by man.

32. One type of swallow is thought to have caused a decline in another swallow species in North America; the recent rise of the missel-thrush in Scotland has led to a decrease in the song-thrush; the brown rat has replaced the black rat in Europe; in Russia, the small cockroach has pushed out its larger relatives everywhere; and in Australia, the imported hive bee is quickly wiping out the small stingless bee. Two other examples related to domesticated animals are mentioned in the previous paragraph. While recalling these same facts, A.R. Wallace notes in a footnote regarding the Scottish thrushes: "Prof. A. Newton, however, informs me that these species do not interfere in the way here stated" (Darwinism, p. 34). Regarding the brown rat, it's known that, due to its amphibious behavior, it typically stays in the lower parts of human homes (like basements, sewers, etc.), as well as along the banks of canals and rivers; it also migrates in large groups. The black rat, on the other hand, tends to remain inside our homes, under the floor, and in our stables and barns. This makes it much more vulnerable to extermination by humans, and we cannot say with any certainty that the black rat is being eliminated or starved out by the brown rat rather than by people.

33. "But it may be urged that when several closely-allied species inhabit the same territory, we surely ought to find at the present time many transitional forms…. By my theory these allied species are descended from a common parent; and during the process of modification, each has become adapted to the conditions of life of its own region, and has supplanted and exterminated its original parent-form and all the transitional varieties between its past and present states" (Origin of Species, 6th ed. p. 134); also p. 137, 296 (all paragraph "On Extinction").

33. "However, some might argue that when several closely related species live in the same area, we should currently find many transitional forms…. According to my theory, these related species come from a common ancestor; and through the process of change, each has adapted to the living conditions of its own environment, pushing out and eliminating its original parent form and all the transitional varieties between its earlier and current states" (Origin of Species, 6th ed. p. 134); also p. 137, 296 (all paragraph "On Extinction").

34. According to Madame Marie Pavloff, who has made a special study of this subject, they migrated from Asia to Africa, stayed there some time, and returned next to Asia. Whether this double migration be confirmed or not, the fact of a former extension of the ancestor of our horse over Asia, Africa, and America is settled beyond doubt.

34. According to Madame Marie Pavloff, who has studied this subject extensively, they migrated from Asia to Africa, stayed there for a while, and then returned to Asia. Whether this two-way migration is confirmed or not, it's clear that the ancestor of our horse once extended its range across Asia, Africa, and America.

35. The Naturalist on the River Amazons, ii. 85, 95.

35. The Naturalist on the River Amazons, ii. 85, 95.

36. Dr. B. Altum, Waldbeschadigungen durch Thiere und Gegenmittel (Berlin, 1889), pp. 207 seq.

36. Dr. B. Altum, Damage to Forests by Animals and Remedies (Berlin, 1889), pp. 207 et seq.

37. Dr. B. Altum, ut supra, pp. 13 and 187.

37. Dr. B. Altum, as mentioned above, pp. 13 and 187.

38. A. Becker in the Bulletin de la Societe des Naturalistes de Moscou, 1889, p. 625.

38. A. Becker in the Bulletin of the Society of Naturalists of Moscow, 1889, p. 625.

39. Russkaya Mysl, Sept. 1888: "The Theory of Beneficency of Struggle for Life, being a Preface to various Treatises on Botanics, Zoology, and Human Life," by an Old Transformist.

39. Russkaya Mysl, Sept. 1888: "The Theory of the Benefits of the Struggle for Survival, serving as a Preface to various Essays on Botany, Zoology, and Human Life," by an Old Transformist.

40. "One of the most frequent modes in which Natural Selection acts is, by adapting some individuals of a species to a somewhat different mode of life, whereby they are able to seize unappropriated places in Nature" (Origin of Species, p. 145)—in other words, to avoid competition.

40. "One of the most common ways Natural Selection works is by adapting some individuals in a species to a slightly different way of life, allowing them to take advantage of unclaimed opportunities in Nature" (Origin of Species, p. 145)—in other words, to avoid competition.

CHAPTER III

MUTUAL AID AMONG SAVAGES

Supposed war of each against all. Tribal origin of human society. Late appearance of the separate family. Bushmen and Hottentots. Australians, Papuas. Eskimos, Aleoutes. Features of savage life difficult to understand for the European. The Dayak's conception of justice. Common law.

Supposed conflict of everyone against everyone. The tribal roots of human society. The late emergence of the nuclear family. Bushmen and Hottentots. Australians, Papuans. Eskimos, Aleuts. Aspects of primitive life that are challenging for Europeans to comprehend. The Dayak's idea of justice. Common law.

The immense part played by mutual aid and mutual support in the evolution of the animal world has been briefly analyzed in the preceding chapters. We have now to cast a glance upon the part played by the same agencies in the evolution of mankind. We saw how few are the animal species which live an isolated life, and how numberless are those which live in societies, either for mutual defence, or for hunting and storing up food, or for rearing their offspring, or simply for enjoying life in common. We also saw that, though a good deal of warfare goes on between different classes of animals, or different species, or even different tribes of the same species, peace and mutual support are the rule within the tribe or the species; and that those species which best know how to combine, and to avoid competition, have the best chances of survival and of a further progressive development. They prosper, while the unsociable species decay.

The significant role of mutual aid and support in the evolution of the animal world has been briefly discussed in the previous chapters. Now, we need to look at the role of these same factors in the evolution of humanity. We noticed how few animal species live solitary lives and how countless ones live in groups, whether for mutual defense, hunting and storing food, raising their young, or simply enjoying life together. We also observed that while there is quite a bit of conflict among different groups of animals, species, or even different tribes of the same species, peace and support are the norms within a tribe or species. Those species that excel at cooperation and avoiding competition have the best chances of survival and further development. They thrive, while those that are antisocial decline.

It is evident that it would be quite contrary to all that we know of nature if men were an exception to so general a rule: if a creature so defenceless as man was at his beginnings should have found his protection and his way to progress, not in mutual support, like other animals, but in a reckless competition for personal advantages, with no regard to the interests of the species. To a mind accustomed to the idea of unity in nature, such a proposition appears utterly indefensible. And yet, improbable and unphilosophical as it is, it has never found a lack of supporters. There always were writers who took a pessimistic view of mankind. They knew it, more or less superficially, through their own limited experience; they knew of history what the annalists, always watchful of wars, cruelty, and oppression, told of it, and little more besides; and they concluded that mankind is nothing but a loose aggregation of beings, always ready to fight with each other, and only prevented from so doing by the intervention of some authority.

It’s clear that it would be completely against everything we understand about nature if humans were an exception to such a widespread rule. If a creature as defenseless as humans, in their early days, found their protection and ability to progress not through mutual support like other animals, but in a reckless competition for personal gain, disregarding the interests of the species, it would be difficult to accept. For someone who is used to the idea of unity in nature, this idea seems completely unjustifiable. Yet, despite being unlikely and unscientific, it has always had its supporters. There have always been writers who viewed humanity pessimistically. They understood it, at least superficially, through their limited experiences; they knew about history mainly what the chroniclers, focused on wars, cruelty, and oppression, reported, and not much else. They concluded that humanity is just a loose collection of beings, always ready to fight with one another, only held back by the intervention of some authority.

Hobbes took that position; and while some of his eighteenth-century followers endeavoured to prove that at no epoch of its existence—not even in its most primitive condition—mankind lived in a state of perpetual warfare; that men have been sociable even in "the state of nature," and that want of knowledge, rather than the natural bad inclinations of man, brought humanity to all the horrors of its early historical life,—his idea was, on the contrary, that the so-called "state of nature" was nothing but a permanent fight between individuals, accidentally huddled together by the mere caprice of their bestial existence. True, that science has made some progress since Hobbes's time, and that we have safer ground to stand upon than the speculations of Hobbes or Rousseau. But the Hobbesian philosophy has plenty of admirers still; and we have had of late quite a school of writers who, taking possession of Darwin's terminology rather than of his leading ideas, made of it an argument in favour of Hobbes's views upon primitive man, and even succeeded in giving them a scientific appearance. Huxley, as is known, took the lead of that school, and in a paper written in 1888 he represented primitive men as a sort of tigers or lions, deprived of all ethical conceptions, fighting out the struggle for existence to its bitter end, and living a life of "continual free fight"; to quote his own words—"beyond the limited and, temporary relations of the family, the Hobbesian war of each against all was the normal state of existence."(1)

Hobbes held that view, and while some of his followers in the eighteenth century tried to argue that at no point in history— not even in its most basic state—did humanity exist in a constant state of conflict; that people have been social even in "the state of nature," and that lack of knowledge, rather than humanity's inherent bad nature, led to the horrors of early human history—he believed that the so-called "state of nature" was essentially just a continuous battle between individuals, randomly thrown together by the whims of their basic existence. It's true that science has advanced since Hobbes's time, and we have more reliable foundations than Hobbes's or Rousseau's theories. However, the Hobbesian philosophy still has many supporters; recently, there has been a group of writers who, rather than engaging with Darwin's main concepts, have used his terminology to argue in favor of Hobbes's beliefs about primitive humans, even managing to make them seem scientific. Huxley, as is well-known, led this group, and in a paper written in 1888, he depicted primitive humans as akin to tigers or lions, lacking any ethical understanding, fighting for survival until the end, and living a life of "constant free conflict"; to quote his exact words—"beyond the limited and, temporary relations of the family, the Hobbesian war of each against all was the normal state of existence."(1)

It has been remarked more than once that the chief error of Hobbes, and the eighteenth-century philosophers as well, was to imagine that mankind began its life in the shape of small straggling families, something like the "limited and temporary" families of the bigger carnivores, while in reality it is now positively known that such was not the case. Of course, we have no direct evidence as to the modes of life of the first man-like beings. We are not yet settled even as to the time of their first appearance, geologists being inclined at present to see their traces in the pliocene, or even the miocene, deposits of the Tertiary period. But we have the indirect method which permits us to throw some light even upon that remote antiquity. A most careful investigation into the social institutions of the lowest races has been carried on during the last forty years, and it has revealed among the present institutions of primitive folk some traces of still older institutions which have long disappeared, but nevertheless left unmistakable traces of their previous existence. A whole science devoted to the embryology of human institutions has thus developed in the hands of Bachofen, MacLennan, Morgan, Edwin Tylor, Maine, Post, Kovalevsky, Lubbock, and many others. And that science has established beyond any doubt that mankind did not begin its life in the shape of small isolated families.

It has been pointed out multiple times that the main mistake of Hobbes and the philosophers of the eighteenth century was believing that humanity started out as small, wandering families, similar to the "limited and temporary" groups of larger carnivores. However, we now know this isn’t true. We don’t have direct evidence about how the first human-like beings lived. We’re still not even certain about when they first appeared, with geologists currently suggesting that their traces can be found in the pliocene or even miocene layers of the Tertiary period. But we do have an indirect method that allows us to shed some light on that distant past. Over the last forty years, thorough research into the social structures of the most primitive races has uncovered signs of even older institutions that have long since vanished but left clear evidence of their previous existence. A whole field of study focused on the development of human institutions has emerged through the work of Bachofen, MacLennan, Morgan, Edwin Tylor, Maine, Post, Kovalevsky, Lubbock, and many others. This field has established, without a doubt, that humanity did not start as isolated small families.

Far from being a primitive form of organization, the family is a very late product of human evolution. As far as we can go back in the palaeo-ethnology of mankind, we find men living in societies—in tribes similar to those of the highest mammals; and an extremely slow and long evolution was required to bring these societies to the gentile, or clan organization, which, in its turn, had to undergo another, also very long evolution, before the first germs of family, polygamous or monogamous, could appear. Societies, bands, or tribes—not families—were thus the primitive form of organization of mankind and its earliest ancestors. That is what ethnology has come to after its painstaking researches. And in so doing it simply came to what might have been foreseen by the zoologist. None of the higher mammals, save a few carnivores and a few undoubtedly-decaying species of apes (orang-outans and gorillas), live in small families, isolatedly straggling in the woods. All others live in societies. And Darwin so well understood that isolately-living apes never could have developed into man-like beings, that he was inclined to consider man as descended from some comparatively weak but social species, like the chimpanzee, rather than from some stronger but unsociable species, like the gorilla.(2) Zoology and palaeo-ethnology are thus agreed in considering that the band, not the family, was the earliest form of social life. The first human societies simply were a further development of those societies which constitute the very essence of life of the higher animals.(3)

Far from being a basic form of organization, the family is actually a late development in human evolution. Looking back into the early anthropology of humanity, we find people living in societies—in tribes similar to those of advanced mammals; a very slow and lengthy evolution was necessary to transform these societies into the gentile or clan structure, which in turn had to go through another long evolution before the first signs of family, whether polygamous or monogamous, could emerge. Societies, groups, or tribes—not families—were the original form of organization for humanity and its earliest ancestors. This is what ethnology has concluded after its careful research. In doing so, it arrived at what could have been anticipated by zoologists. None of the higher mammals, except for a few carnivores and some clearly declining ape species (like orangutans and gorillas), live in small families, scattered alone in the woods. All the others live in societies. Darwin understood so well that solitary-living apes could never have evolved into human-like beings that he suggested humans likely descended from a relatively weak but social species, such as the chimpanzee, rather than from a stronger but unsocial species like the gorilla. Zoology and early anthropology thus agree that the band, not the family, was the earliest form of social life. The first human societies were simply an extension of the kinds of societies that are essential to the lives of higher animals.

If we now go over to positive evidence, we see that the earliest traces of man, dating from the glacial or the early post-glacial period, afford unmistakable proofs of man having lived even then in societies. Isolated finds of stone implements, even from the old stone age, are very rare; on the contrary, wherever one flint implement is discovered others are sure to be found, in most cases in very large quantities. At a time when men were dwelling in caves, or under occasionally protruding rocks, in company with mammals now extinct, and hardly succeeded in making the roughest sorts of flint hatchets, they already knew the advantages of life in societies. In the valleys of the tributaries of the Dordogne, the surface of the rocks is in some places entirely covered with caves which were inhabited by palaeolithic men.(4) Sometimes the cave-dwellings are superposed in storeys, and they certainly recall much more the nesting colonies of swallows than the dens of carnivores. As to the flint implements discovered in those caves, to use Lubbock's words, "one may say without exaggeration that they are numberless." The same is true of other palaeolithic stations. It also appears from Lartet's investigations that the inhabitants of the Aurignac region in the south of France partook of tribal meals at the burial of their dead. So that men lived in societies, and had germs of a tribal worship, even at that extremely remote epoch.

If we shift our focus to positive evidence, we can see that the earliest signs of humans, dating back to the glacial or early post-glacial period, provide clear proof that people were living in societies even then. Isolated finds of stone tools from the old stone age are quite rare; however, wherever one flint tool is discovered, others are usually found, often in large numbers. During the time when people were living in caves or under large overhanging rocks, alongside mammals that are now extinct, and were just starting to make basic flint hatchets, they already understood the benefits of communal living. In the valleys of the Dordogne's tributaries, the surfaces of some rocks are completely covered with caves that were inhabited by palaeolithic humans.(4) Sometimes, these cave dwellings are stacked in layers, resembling more of a nesting colony of swallows than the dens of predators. Regarding the flint tools found in those caves, to use Lubbock's phrase, "one could say without exaggeration that they are countless." The same goes for other palaeolithic sites. Lartet's research also indicates that the people from the Aurignac region in the south of France shared communal meals during the burial of their dead. This demonstrates that humans lived in societies and had the beginnings of tribal worship, even in that extremely distant time.

The same is still better proved as regards the later part of the stone age. Traces of neolithic man have been found in numberless quantities, so that we can reconstitute his manner of life to a great extent. When the ice-cap (which must have spread from the Polar regions as far south as middle France, middle Germany, and middle Russia, and covered Canada as well as a good deal of what is now the United States) began to melt away, the surfaces freed from ice were covered, first, with swamps and marshes, and later on with numberless lakes.(5) Lakes filled all depressions of the valleys before their waters dug out those permanent channels which, during a subsequent epoch, became our rivers. And wherever we explore, in Europe, Asia, or America, the shores of the literally numberless lakes of that period, whose proper name would be the Lacustrine period, we find traces of neolithic man. They are so numerous that we can only wonder at the relative density of population at that time. The "stations" of neolithic man closely follow each other on the terraces which now mark the shores of the old lakes. And at each of those stations stone implements appear in such numbers, that no doubt is possible as to the length of time during which they were inhabited by rather numerous tribes. Whole workshops of flint implements, testifying of the numbers of workers who used to come together, have been discovered by the archaeologists.

The same is still better demonstrated when it comes to the later part of the Stone Age. Countless traces of Neolithic man have been found, allowing us to reconstruct his way of life to a significant extent. When the ice cap (which must have extended from the Polar regions as far south as central France, central Germany, and central Russia, covering Canada as well as much of what is now the United States) began to melt, the areas freed from ice were initially covered with swamps and marshes, and later with countless lakes.(5) Lakes filled every depression in the valleys before their waters carved out the lasting channels that, in a later period, became our rivers. And wherever we explore, in Europe, Asia, or America, we find evidence of Neolithic man along the shores of the literally countless lakes from that time, which we could call the Lacustrine period. The traces are so numerous that we can only marvel at the relative density of the population during that time. The "stations" of Neolithic man are closely spaced on the terraces that now outline the shores of the former lakes. At each of these stations, stone tools appear in such abundance that there is no doubt about the length of time they were inhabited by fairly large tribes. Entire workshops of flint tools, revealing the number of workers who used to gather there, have been uncovered by archaeologists.

Traces of a more advanced period, already characterized by the use of some pottery, are found in the shell-heaps of Denmark. They appear, as is well known, in the shape of heaps from five to ten feet thick, from 100 to 200 feet wide, and 1,000 feet or more in length, and they are so common along some parts of the sea-coast that for a long time they were considered as natural growths. And yet they "contain nothing but what has been in some way or other subservient to the use of man," and they are so densely stuffed with products of human industry that, during a two days' stay at Milgaard, Lubbock dug out no less than 191 pieces of stone-implements and four fragments of pottery.(6) The very size and extension of the shell heaps prove that for generations and generations the coasts of Denmark were inhabited by hundreds of small tribes which certainly lived as peacefully together as the Fuegian tribes, which also accumulate like shellheaps, are living in our own times.

Traces of a more advanced time, already marked by the use of pottery, can be found in the shell mounds of Denmark. These mounds are typically five to ten feet thick, 100 to 200 feet wide, and over 1,000 feet long, and they are so prevalent along certain parts of the coastline that for a long time they were thought to be natural formations. However, they "contain nothing but what has been in some way or other subservient to the use of man," and they are packed with products of human activity so densely that during a two-day stay at Milgaard, Lubbock unearthed 191 pieces of stone tools and four pottery fragments.(6) The sheer size and extent of the shell mounds indicate that for generations, the coasts of Denmark were inhabited by hundreds of small tribes that likely coexisted peacefully, much like the Fuegian tribes, which also accumulate like shell heaps, do in our own times.

As to the lake-dwellings of Switzerland, which represent a still further advance in civilization, they yield still better evidence of life and work in societies. It is known that even during the stone age the shores of the Swiss lakes were dotted with a succession of villages, each of which consisted of several huts, and was built upon a platform supported by numberless pillars in the lake. No less than twenty-four, mostly stone age villages, were discovered along the shores of Lake Leman, thirty-two in the Lake of Constance, forty-six in the Lake of Neuchatel, and so on; and each of them testifies to the immense amount of labour which was spent in common by the tribe, not by the family. It has even been asserted that the life of the lake-dwellers must have been remarkably free of warfare. And so it probably was, especially if we refer to the life of those primitive folk who live until the present time in similar villages built upon pillars on the sea coasts.

As for the lake dwellings of Switzerland, which represent an even greater advancement in civilization, they provide even better evidence of life and work in communities. It’s known that even during the Stone Age, the shores of the Swiss lakes were dotted with a series of villages, each made up of several huts and built on platforms supported by numerous stilts in the water. At least twenty-four mostly Stone Age villages have been found along the shores of Lake Geneva, thirty-two in Lake Constance, forty-six in Lake Neuchâtel, and so forth; each one reflects the immense amount of labor that was invested collectively by the community, not just by individual families. It has even been suggested that the life of the lake dwellers must have been remarkably peaceful, devoid of warfare. And it likely was, especially when we consider the lives of those primitive people who still live today in similar villages built on stilts along coastal areas.

It is thus seen, even from the above rapid hints, that our knowledge of primitive man is not so scanty after all, and that, so far as it goes, it is rather opposed than favourable to the Hobbesian speculations. Moreover, it may be supplemented, to a great extent, by the direct observation of such primitive tribes as now stand on the same level of civilization as the inhabitants of Europe stood in prehistoric times.

It’s clear from the quick points above that our understanding of primitive humans isn’t as limited as it might seem, and, to the extent that we do have knowledge, it often contradicts rather than supports Hobbes' theories. Additionally, we can greatly enhance this understanding by directly observing primitive tribes that are currently at the same level of civilization as Europeans were in prehistoric times.

That these primitive tribes which we find now are not degenerated specimens of mankind who formerly knew a higher civilization, as it has occasionally been maintained, has sufficiently been proved by Edwin Tylor and Lubbock. However, to the arguments already opposed to the degeneration theory, the following may be added. Save a few tribes clustering in the less-accessible highlands, the "savages" represent a girdle which encircles the more or less civilized nations, and they occupy the extremities of our continents, most of which have retained still, or recently were bearing, an early post-glacial character. Such are the Eskimos and their congeners in Greenland, Arctic America, and Northern Siberia; and, in the Southern hemisphere, the Australians, the Papuas, the Fuegians, and, partly, the Bushmen; while within the civilized area, like primitive folk are only found in the Himalayas, the highlands of Australasia, and the plateaus of Brazil. Now it must be borne in mind that the glacial age did not come to an end at once over the whole surface of the earth. It still continues in Greenland. Therefore, at a time when the littoral regions of the Indian Ocean, the Mediterranean, or the Gulf of Mexico already enjoyed a warmer climate, and became the seats of higher civilizations, immense territories in middle Europe, Siberia, and Northern America, as well as in Patagonia, Southern Africa, and Southern Australasia, remained in early postglacial conditions which rendered them inaccessible to the civilized nations of the torrid and sub-torrid zones. They were at that time what the terrible urmans of North-West Siberia are now, and their population, inaccessible to and untouched by civilization, retained the characters of early post-glacial man. Later on, when desiccation rendered these territories more suitable for agriculture, they were peopled with more civilized immigrants; and while part of their previous inhabitants were assimilated by the new settlers, another part migrated further, and settled where we find them. The territories they inhabit now are still, or recently were, sub-glacial, as to their physical features; their arts and implements are those of the neolithic age; and, notwithstanding their racial differences, and the distances which separate them, their modes of life and social institutions bear a striking likeness. So we cannot but consider them as fragments of the early post-glacial population of the now civilized area.

That the primitive tribes we see today are not degenerated versions of humans who once experienced a higher civilization, as has sometimes been suggested, has been clearly demonstrated by Edwin Tylor and Lubbock. To the arguments against the degeneration theory, the following can be added. Aside from a few tribes located in remote highlands, these "savages" form a belt around the more or less civilized nations and inhabit the edges of our continents, many of which still retain, or recently had, an early post-glacial character. Examples include the Eskimos and their relatives in Greenland, Arctic America, and Northern Siberia; and in the Southern Hemisphere, the Australians, Papuans, Fuegians, and partly, the Bushmen. Within the civilized areas, similar primitive groups are found only in the Himalayas, the highlands of Australasia, and the plateaus of Brazil. It should be noted that the glacial age did not end uniformly across the entire planet. It continues to persist in Greenland. Therefore, at a time when the coastal regions of the Indian Ocean, the Mediterranean, or the Gulf of Mexico were already experiencing a warmer climate and fostering higher civilizations, vast areas in central Europe, Siberia, and Northern America, as well as in Patagonia, Southern Africa, and Southern Australasia, remained in early post-glacial conditions that made them inaccessible to the civilized nations of the tropical and subtropical regions. They were at that time what the formidable urmans of North-West Siberia are now, and their population, cut off from and untouched by civilization, retained the traits of early post-glacial humans. Later, as drying out made these territories more suitable for agriculture, they were settled by more civilized immigrants; while some of the original inhabitants were assimilated by the newcomers, others migrated further and settled where they are now found. The areas they inhabit still have, or recently had, sub-glacial physical features; their arts and tools resemble those of the Neolithic period; and despite their racial differences and the distances between them, their ways of life and social structures share remarkable similarities. Thus, we cannot help but view them as remnants of the early post-glacial population of the now civilized regions.

The first thing which strikes us as soon as we begin studying primitive folk is the complexity of the organization of marriage relations under which they are living. With most of them the family, in the sense we attribute to it, is hardly found in its germs. But they are by no means loose aggregations of men and women coming in a disorderly manner together in conformity with their momentary caprices. All of them are under a certain organization, which has been described by Morgan in its general aspects as the "gentile," or clan organization.(7)

The first thing that stands out as we start studying primitive communities is the complexity of their marriage systems. For most of them, the concept of family, as we understand it, barely exists in its early forms. However, they aren’t just random groups of men and women coming together based on fleeting desires. They all function under a specific organization, which Morgan has described in general terms as the "gentile," or clan organization.

To tell the matter as briefly as possible, there is little doubt that mankind has passed at its beginnings through a stage which may be described as that of "communal marriage"; that is, the whole tribe had husbands and wives in common with but little regard to consanguinity. But it is also certain that some restrictions to that free intercourse were imposed at a very early period. Inter-marriage was soon prohibited between the sons of one mother and her sisters, granddaughters, and aunts. Later on it was prohibited between the sons and daughters of the same mother, and further limitations did not fail to follow. The idea of a gens, or clan, which embodied all presumed descendants from one stock (or rather all those who gathered in one group) was evolved, and marriage within the clan was entirely prohibited. It still remained "communal," but the wife or the husband had to be taken from another clan. And when a gens became too numerous, and subdivided into several gentes, each of them was divided into classes (usually four), and marriage was permitted only between certain well-defined classes. That is the stage which we find now among the Kamilaroi-speaking Australians. As to the family, its first germs appeared amidst the clan organization. A woman who was captured in war from some other clan, and who formerly would have belonged to the whole gens, could be kept at a later period by the capturer, under certain obligations towards the tribe. She may be taken by him to a separate hut, after she had paid a certain tribute to the clan, and thus constitute within the gens a separate family, the appearance of which evidently was opening a quite new phase of civilization.

To put it simply, there's no doubt that early humans went through a stage known as "communal marriage," where everyone in a tribe shared partners with little consideration for family ties. However, some limits on this free exchange were established pretty early on. Inter-marriage was soon banned among the sons of one mother with her sisters, granddaughters, and aunts. Later, it was also forbidden between the sons and daughters of the same mother, with even more restrictions emerging over time. The concept of a gens, or clan, which included all assumed descendants from a single lineage (or those who came together as a group), developed, and marriage within the clan was completely banned. It stayed "communal," but partners had to be chosen from outside their clan. As a gens grew too large, it split into several smaller gentes, each further divided into classes (usually four), with marriage allowed only between specific, defined classes. This is the situation we see today among the Kamilaroi-speaking Australians. Regarding the family, its earliest forms emerged within the clan structure. A woman captured in war from another clan, who would have once belonged to the entire gens, could later be kept by her captor, with certain responsibilities to the tribe. She could be taken to a separate hut after paying a tribute to the clan, thereby forming a distinct family within the gens, marking the beginning of a completely new phase of civilization.

Now, if we take into consideration that this complicated organization developed among men who stood at the lowest known degree of development, and that it maintained itself in societies knowing no kind of authority besides the authority of public opinion, we at once see how deeply inrooted social instincts must have been in human nature, even at its lowest stages. A savage who is capable of living under such an organization, and of freely submitting to rules which continually clash with his personal desires, certainly is not a beast devoid of ethical principles and knowing no rein to its passions. But the fact becomes still more striking if we consider the immense antiquity of the clan organization. It is now known that the primitive Semites, the Greeks of Homer, the prehistoric Romans, the Germans of Tacitus, the early Celts and the early Slavonians, all have had their own period of clan organization, closely analogous to that of the Australians, the Red Indians, the Eskimos, and other inhabitants of the "savage girdle."(9) So we must admit that either the evolution of marriage laws went on on the same lines among all human races, or the rudiments of the clan rules were developed among some common ancestors of the Semites, the Aryans, the Polynesians, etc., before their differentiation into separate races took place, and that these rules were maintained, until now, among races long ago separated from the common stock. Both alternatives imply, however, an equally striking tenacity of the institution—such a tenacity that no assaults of the individual could break it down through the scores of thousands of years that it was in existence. The very persistence of the clan organization shows how utterly false it is to represent primitive mankind as a disorderly agglomeration of individuals, who only obey their individual passions, and take advantage of their personal force and cunningness against all other representatives of the species. Unbridled individualism is a modern growth, but it is not characteristic of primitive mankind.(10)

Now, if we consider that this complex organization developed among people at the lowest level of advancement, and that it was sustained in societies that recognized no authority other than the authority of public opinion, it becomes evident how deeply social instincts must have been rooted in human nature, even at its most basic stages. A person who can live under such an organization and willingly follow rules that often conflict with their personal desires is certainly not someone devoid of ethical principles or regulation of their passions. The point becomes even more significant when we think about the ancient origins of the clan organization. It is now known that the primitive Semites, the Greeks of Homer, the prehistoric Romans, the Germans described by Tacitus, the early Celts, and the early Slavs all had their own periods of clan organization, closely resembling those of the Australians, Native Americans, Eskimos, and other inhabitants of the "savage belt." So, we must accept that either the evolution of marriage laws followed the same path among all human races, or the foundations of clan rules developed among some common ancestors of the Semites, Aryans, Polynesians, etc., before their separation into distinct races, and that these rules have persisted, even now, among groups long separated from that common ancestry. Both possibilities suggest a remarkable resilience of the institution—so strong that no individual attacks could dismantle it over the many thousands of years it existed. The very persistence of clan organization shows how completely misguided it is to depict primitive humans as a chaotic mix of individuals, who only follow their personal passions and leverage their individual strength and cunning against others of their kind. Unrestrained individualism is a modern development, but it is not typical of primitive humanity.

Going now over to the existing savages, we may begin with the Bushmen, who stand at a very low level of development—so low indeed that they have no dwellings and sleep in holes dug in the soil, occasionally protected by some screens. It is known that when Europeans settled in their territory and destroyed deer, the Bushmen began stealing the settlers' cattle, whereupon a war of extermination, too horrible to be related here, was waged against them. Five hundred Bushmen were slaughtered in 1774, three thousand in 1808 and 1809 by the Farmers' Alliance, and so on. They were poisoned like rats, killed by hunters lying in ambush before the carcass of some animal, killed wherever met with.(11) So that our knowledge of the Bushmen, being chiefly borrowed from those same people who exterminated them, is necessarily limited. But still we know that when the Europeans came, the Bushmen lived in small tribes (or clans), sometimes federated together; that they used to hunt in common, and divided the spoil without quarrelling; that they never abandoned their wounded, and displayed strong affection to their comrades. Lichtenstein has a most touching story about a Bushman, nearly drowned in a river, who was rescued by his companions. They took off their furs to cover him, and shivered themselves; they dried him, rubbed him before the fire, and smeared his body with warm grease till they brought him back to life. And when the Bushmen found, in Johan van der Walt, a man who treated them well, they expressed their thankfulness by a most touching attachment to that man.(12) Burchell and Moffat both represent them as goodhearted, disinterested, true to their promises, and grateful,(13) all qualities which could develop only by being practised within the tribe. As to their love to children, it is sufficient to say that when a European wished to secure a Bushman woman as a slave, he stole her child: the mother was sure to come into slavery to share the fate of her child.(14)

Now let's talk about the Bushmen, who are at a very basic level of development—so basic that they have no homes and sleep in holes they dig in the ground, sometimes covered by makeshift screens. When Europeans settled in their land and wiped out deer, the Bushmen began stealing the settlers' cattle, which led to a horrendous war against them. Five hundred Bushmen were killed in 1774, followed by three thousand in 1808 and 1809 at the hands of the Farmers' Alliance, and this continued. They were poisoned like vermin, hunted down by ambush near animal carcasses, and killed wherever they were found. Our understanding of the Bushmen is largely shaped by the very people who exterminated them, which limits our knowledge. However, we do know that when Europeans arrived, the Bushmen lived in small tribes (or clans), sometimes working together; they hunted cooperatively and shared their catch without fighting; they never left their wounded behind and showed deep affection for their comrades. Lichtenstein tells a touching story about a Bushman who nearly drowned in a river and was saved by his companions. They removed their furs to cover him, shivered in the cold, dried him off, rubbed him near the fire, and smeared warm grease on his body until he was revived. When the Bushmen encountered Johan van der Walt, a man who treated them kindly, they responded with heartfelt gratitude and loyalty to him. Both Burchell and Moffat describe them as kind-hearted, selfless, trustworthy, and grateful—all traits that could only develop through practice within their community. Regarding their love for children, it's enough to say that when a European wanted to capture a Bushman woman as a slave, he would steal her child; the mother was sure to follow her child into slavery.

The same social manners characterize the Hottentots, who are but a little more developed than the Bushmen. Lubbock describes them as "the filthiest animals," and filthy they really are. A fur suspended to the neck and worn till it falls to pieces is all their dress; their huts are a few sticks assembled together and covered with mats, with no kind of furniture within. And though they kept oxen and sheep, and seem to have known the use of iron before they made acquaintance with the Europeans, they still occupy one of the lowest degrees of the human scale. And yet those who knew them highly praised their sociability and readiness to aid each other. If anything is given to a Hottentot, he at once divides it among all present—a habit which, as is known, so much struck Darwin among the Fuegians. He cannot eat alone, and, however hungry, he calls those who pass by to share his food. And when Kolben expressed his astonishment thereat, he received the answer. "That is Hottentot manner." But this is not Hottentot manner only: it is an all but universal habit among the "savages." Kolben, who knew the Hottentots well and did not pass by their defects in silence, could not praise their tribal morality highly enough.

The same social behaviors define the Hottentots, who are only slightly more advanced than the Bushmen. Lubbock calls them "the dirtiest animals," and they truly are. Their only clothing is a fur draped around their necks until it falls apart; their huts consist of a few sticks put together and covered with mats, lacking any furniture inside. Although they raise oxen and sheep and seem to have known iron before meeting Europeans, they still rank among the lowest on the human scale. Yet, those who have interacted with them praise their friendliness and willingness to help one another. If a Hottentot receives something, he immediately shares it with everyone around—similar to what struck Darwin about the Fuegians. He can't eat alone and, no matter how hungry he is, he invites those passing by to join him in his meal. When Kolben expressed his surprise at this, he was told, "That is Hottentot manner." However, this isn't just specific to Hottentots; it's nearly a universal trait among "savages." Kolben, who was familiar with the Hottentots and didn't shy away from pointing out their flaws, could not praise their communal morality enough.

"Their word is sacred," he wrote. They know "nothing of the corruptness and faithless arts of Europe." "They live in great tranquillity and are seldom at war with their neighbours." They are "all kindness and goodwill to one another.. One of the greatest pleasures of the Hottentots certainly lies in their gifts and good offices to one another." "The integrity of the Hottentots, their strictness and celerity in the exercise of justice, and their chastity, are things in which they excel all or most nations in the world."(15)

"Their word is sacred," he wrote. They know "nothing of the corruption and deceitful practices of Europe." "They live in great peace and are rarely at war with their neighbors." They are "all kindness and goodwill toward one another. One of the greatest pleasures of the Hottentots is certainly in their generosity and support for each other." "The integrity of the Hottentots, their seriousness and quickness in delivering justice, and their purity are qualities in which they surpass all or most nations in the world."(15)

Tachart, Barrow, and Moodie(16) fully confirm Kolben's testimony. Let me only remark that when Kolben wrote that "they are certainly the most friendly, the most liberal and the most benevolent people to one another that ever appeared on the earth" (i. 332), he wrote a sentence which has continually appeared since in the description of savages. When first meeting with primitive races, the Europeans usually make a caricature of their life; but when an intelligent man has stayed among them for a longer time, he generally describes them as the "kindest" or "the gentlest" race on the earth. These very same words have been applied to the Ostyaks, the Samoyedes, the Eskimos, the Dayaks, the Aleoutes, the Papuas, and so on, by the highest authorities. I also remember having read them applied to the Tunguses, the Tchuktchis, the Sioux, and several others. The very frequency of that high commendation already speaks volumes in itself.

Tachart, Barrow, and Moodie(16) fully support Kolben's account. I just want to point out that when Kolben said, "they are certainly the most friendly, the most liberal, and the most benevolent people to one another that ever appeared on the earth" (i. 332), he wrote a line that has repeatedly shown up in descriptions of so-called savages. When Europeans first encounter primitive cultures, they usually create a caricature of their lives; however, after spending more time with them, an insightful observer typically describes them as the "kindest" or "gentlest" people on Earth. These very terms have been used to describe the Ostyaks, the Samoyedes, the Eskimos, the Dayaks, the Aleoutes, the Papuas, and others by respected authorities. I also recall seeing these words used for the Tunguses, the Tchuktchis, the Sioux, and several others. The sheer frequency of this high praise speaks volumes.

The natives of Australia do not stand on a higher level of development than their South African brothers. Their huts are of the same character: very often simple screens are the only protection against cold winds. In their food they are most indifferent: they devour horribly putrefied corpses, and cannibalism is resorted to in times of scarcity. When first discovered by Europeans, they had no implements but in stone or bone, and these were of the roughest description. Some tribes had even no canoes, and did not know barter-trade. And yet, when their manners and customs were carefully studied, they proved to be living under that elaborate clan organization which I have mentioned on a preceding page.(17)

The Aboriginal people of Australia are not at a more advanced level of development than their South African counterparts. Their shelters are similar in nature; often, simple screens are the only defense against cold winds. When it comes to food, they are quite indifferent: they consume badly decayed corpses, and cannibalism is practiced during times of scarcity. When Europeans first encountered them, they only had tools made from stone or bone, and these were very crude. Some tribes even lacked canoes and were unaware of trading. However, when their customs and traditions were examined closely, it became clear that they were part of a complex clan organization, which I mentioned on a previous page.(17)

The territory they inhabit is usually allotted between the different gentes or clans; but the hunting and fishing territories of each clan are kept in common, and the produce of fishing and hunting belongs to the whole clan; so also the fishing and hunting implements.(18) The meals are taken in common. Like many other savages, they respect certain regulations as to the seasons when certain gums and grasses may be collected.(19) As to their morality altogether, we cannot do better than transcribe the following answers given to the questions of the Paris Anthropological Society by Lumholtz, a missionary who sojourned in North Queensland:(20)—

The land they live on is typically divided among the different clans; however, the hunting and fishing areas for each clan are shared, and the catch from these activities belongs to the entire clan, along with the tools used for hunting and fishing. Meals are also shared. Like many other indigenous groups, they follow certain rules about the seasons for collecting specific gums and grasses. Regarding their overall morality, we can best present the following responses provided to the questions from the Paris Anthropological Society by Lumholtz, a missionary who spent time in North Queensland:

"The feeling of friendship is known among them; it is strong. Weak people are usually supported; sick people are very well attended to; they never are abandoned or killed. These tribes are cannibals, but they very seldom eat members of their own tribe (when immolated on religious principles, I suppose); they eat strangers only. The parents love their children, play with them, and pet them. Infanticide meets with common approval. Old people are very well treated, never put to death. No religion, no idols, only a fear of death. Polygamous marriage, quarrels arising within the tribe are settled by means of duels fought with wooden swords and shields. No slaves; no culture of any kind; no pottery; no dress, save an apron sometimes worn by women. The clan consists of two hundred individuals, divided into four classes of men and four of women; marriage being only permitted within the usual classes, and never within the gens."

"The feeling of friendship is known among them; it's strong. Weak people usually receive support; sick people are very well taken care of; they are never abandoned or killed. These tribes are cannibals, but they rarely eat their own tribe members (except when sacrificed for religious reasons, I guess); they only eat strangers. Parents love their children, play with them, and care for them. Infanticide is generally accepted. Old people are treated very well and are never killed. There is no religion, no idols, just a fear of death. Polygamous marriage exists, and disputes within the tribe are resolved through duels fought with wooden swords and shields. There are no slaves; no culture of any kind; no pottery; no clothing except for an apron sometimes worn by women. The clan consists of two hundred individuals, divided into four classes of men and four of women; marriage is only permitted within the usual classes, and never within the gens."

For the Papuas, closely akin to the above, we have the testimony of G.L. Bink, who stayed in New Guinea, chiefly in Geelwink Bay, from 1871 to 1883. Here is the essence of his answers to the same questioner:(21)—

For the Papuas, similar to the above, we have the account of G.L. Bink, who lived in New Guinea, mainly in Geelwink Bay, from 1871 to 1883. Here’s the main point of his responses to the same questioner:(21)—

"They are sociable and cheerful; they laugh very much. Rather timid than courageous. Friendship is relatively strong among persons belonging to different tribes, and still stronger within the tribe. A friend will often pay the debt of his friend, the stipulation being that the latter will repay it without interest to the children of the lender. They take care of the ill and the old; old people are never abandoned, and in no case are they killed—unless it be a slave who was ill for a long time. War prisoners are sometimes eaten. The children are very much petted and loved. Old and feeble war prisoners are killed, the others are sold as slaves. They have no religion, no gods, no idols, no authority of any description; the oldest man in the family is the judge. In cases of adultery a fine is paid, and part of it goes to the negoria (the community). The soil is kept in common, but the crop belongs to those who have grown it. They have pottery, and know barter-trade—the custom being that the merchant gives them the goods, whereupon they return to their houses and bring the native goods required by the merchant; if the latter cannot be obtained, the European goods are returned.(22) They are head-hunters, and in so doing they prosecute blood revenge. 'Sometimes,' Finsch says, 'the affair is referred to the Rajah of Namototte, who terminates it by imposing a fine.'"

"They're social and cheerful; they laugh a lot. They're more timid than brave. Friendship is pretty strong among people from different tribes, and even stronger within the tribe. A friend will often pay off a debt for their friend, with the understanding that the friend will repay it without interest to the lender’s children. They take care of the sick and the elderly; old people are never abandoned, and they’re never killed—unless they’re a long-term sick slave. Sometimes, war prisoners are eaten. Children are spoiled and loved. Old and weak war prisoners are killed, while the others are sold into slavery. They have no religion, gods, idols, or any authority; the oldest man in the family acts as the judge. If someone commits adultery, a fine is paid, and part of it goes to the community. The land is held in common, but the crops belong to those who grow them. They make pottery and know how to trade—typically, the merchant gives them goods, and then they go back home to bring the native goods the merchant needs; if they can’t find those, they return the European goods. They practice head-hunting and seek revenge for bloodshed. 'Sometimes,' Finsch says, 'the issue is taken to the Rajah of Namototte, who resolves it by imposing a fine.'"

When well treated, the Papuas are very kind. Miklukho-Maclay landed on the eastern coast of New Guinea, followed by one single man, stayed for two years among tribes reported to be cannibals, and left them with regret; he returned again to stay one year more among them, and never had he any conflict to complain of. True that his rule was never—under no pretext whatever—to say anything which was not truth, nor make any promise which he could not keep. These poor creatures, who even do not know how to obtain fire, and carefully maintain it in their huts, live under their primitive communism, without any chiefs; and within their villages they have no quarrels worth speaking of. They work in common, just enough to get the food of the day; they rear their children in common; and in the evenings they dress themselves as coquettishly as they can, and dance. Like all savages, they are fond of dancing. Each village has its barla, or balai—the "long house," "longue maison," or "grande maison"—for the unmarried men, for social gatherings, and for the discussion of common affairs—again a trait which is common to most inhabitants of the Pacific Islands, the Eskimos, the Red Indians, and so on. Whole groups of villages are on friendly terms, and visit each other en bloc.

When treated well, the Papuas are very kind. Miklukho-Maclay landed on the eastern coast of New Guinea, accompanied by just one man, and spent two years among tribes known to be cannibals, leaving with a sense of regret. He returned for another year, and during that time, he never faced any conflicts. He made it a point never to say anything that wasn't true, nor to make promises he couldn't keep. These people, who don’t even know how to create fire but carefully maintain it in their huts, live under a primitive communal system without any chiefs, and within their villages, there are hardly any notable conflicts. They work together just enough to gather food for the day, raise their children collectively, and in the evenings, they dress up as best as they can and dance. Like all indigenous peoples, they love to dance. Each village has its barla, or balai—the "long house"—where unmarried men gather socially and discuss community matters, a feature that is common among many Pacific Islanders, Eskimos, and Native Americans. Whole groups of villages maintain friendly relationships and visit each other as a block.

Unhappily, feuds are not uncommon—not in consequence of "Overstocking of the area," or "keen competition," and like inventions of a mercantile century, but chiefly in consequence of superstition. As soon as any one falls ill, his friends and relatives come together, and deliberately discuss who might be the cause of the illness. All possible enemies are considered, every one confesses of his own petty quarrels, and finally the real cause is discovered. An enemy from the next village has called it down, and a raid upon that village is decided upon. Therefore, feuds are rather frequent, even between the coast villages, not to say a word of the cannibal mountaineers who are considered as real witches and enemies, though, on a closer acquaintance, they prove to be exactly the same sort of people as their neighbours on the seacoast.(23)

Unfortunately, feuds are quite common—not because of "overpopulation in the area," "intense competition," or other ideas from a business-minded era, but mainly due to superstition. Whenever someone falls ill, their friends and family gather together and intentionally discuss who might have caused the sickness. All potential enemies are taken into account, everyone shares their minor conflicts, and eventually, the true culprit is identified. An enemy from the neighboring village is deemed responsible, and a raid on that village is planned. As a result, feuds happen often, even between coastal villages, not to mention the cannibal mountain tribes who are seen as genuine witches and foes, though, upon closer inspection, they turn out to be just like their coastal neighbors. (23)

Many striking pages could be written about the harmony which prevails in the villages of the Polynesian inhabitants of the Pacific Islands. But they belong to a more advanced stage of civilization. So we shall now take our illustrations from the far north. I must mention, however, before leaving the Southern Hemisphere, that even the Fuegians, whose reputation has been so bad, appear under a much better light since they begin to be better known. A few French missionaries who stay among them "know of no act of malevolence to complain of." In their clans, consisting of from 120 to 150 souls, they practise the same primitive communism as the Papuas; they share everything in common, and treat their old people very well. Peace prevails among these tribes.(24) With the Eskimos and their nearest congeners, the Thlinkets, the Koloshes, and the Aleoutes, we find one of the nearest illustrations of what man may have been during the glacial age. Their implements hardly differ from those of palaeolithic man, and some of their tribes do not yet know fishing: they simply spear the fish with a kind of harpoon.(25) They know the use of iron, but they receive it from the Europeans, or find it on wrecked ships. Their social organization is of a very primitive kind, though they already have emerged from the stage of "communal marriage," even under the gentile restrictions. They live in families, but the family bonds are often broken; husbands and wives are often exchanged.(26) The families, however, remain united in clans, and how could it be otherwise? How could they sustain the hard struggle for life unless by closely combining their forces? So they do, and the tribal bonds are closest where the struggle for life is hardest, namely, in North-East Greenland. The "long house" is their usual dwelling, and several families lodge in it, separated from each other by small partitions of ragged furs, with a common passage in the front. Sometimes the house has the shape of a cross, and in such case a common fire is kept in the centre. The German Expedition which spent a winter close by one of those "long houses" could ascertain that "no quarrel disturbed the peace, no dispute arose about the use of this narrow space" throughout the long winter. "Scolding, or even unkind words, are considered as a misdemeanour, if not produced under the legal form of process, namely, the nith-song."(27) Close cohabitation and close interdependence are sufficient for maintaining century after century that deep respect for the interests of the community which is characteristic of Eskimo life. Even in the larger communities of Eskimos, "public opinion formed the real judgment-seat, the general punishment consisting in the offenders being shamed in the eyes of the people."(28)

Many vivid stories could be told about the harmony in the villages of the Polynesian people living on the Pacific Islands. However, they belong to a more developed stage of society. So, let’s shift our focus to the far north. Before we leave the Southern Hemisphere, I should mention that even the Fuegians, who have such a bad reputation, now appear in a much better light as they become better known. A few French missionaries living among them "know of no acts of malice to complain about." In their clans, which consist of 120 to 150 individuals, they practice the same basic communism as the Papuas; they share everything and treat their elders very well. There is peace among these tribes. With the Eskimos and their closest relatives—the Thlinkets, Koloshes, and Aleoutes—we find a good example of what humans may have been like during the Ice Age. Their tools are hardly different from those of prehistoric humans, and some of their tribes still don’t know how to fish; they only spear fish with a type of harpoon. They know how to use iron, but they get it from Europeans or find it on shipwrecks. Their social organization is quite primitive, though they have moved past "communal marriage," even with the social restrictions. They live in families, but family ties are often weak; husbands and wives frequently exchange partners. However, families remain united in clans, and how else could they survive harsh living conditions without closely joining forces? That’s exactly what they do, and the tribal ties are strongest where life is most challenging, particularly in North-East Greenland. Their typical home is a "long house," where several families live, divided by small partitions made of worn furs, with a shared entrance. Sometimes the house is shaped like a cross, in which case a communal fire is kept in the center. The German Expedition that spent a winter near one of these "long houses" found that "no quarrels disturbed the peace, no disputes arose about the use of this narrow space" during the long winter. "Scolding or even unkind words are considered a minor offense, unless presented in the proper legal form, namely, the nith-song." Close living and interdependence are enough to maintain, for centuries, the strong respect for community interests that defines Eskimo life. Even in larger Eskimo communities, "public opinion serves as the true court, with the general punishment being the offender being shamed in the eyes of the people."

Eskimo life is based upon communism. What is obtained by hunting and fishing belongs to the clan. But in several tribes, especially in the West, under the influence of the Danes, private property penetrates into their institutions. However, they have an original means for obviating the inconveniences arising from a personal accumulation of wealth which would soon destroy their tribal unity. When a man has grown rich, he convokes the folk of his clan to a great festival, and, after much eating, distributes among them all his fortune. On the Yukon river, Dall saw an Aleonte family distributing in this way ten guns, ten full fur dresses, 200 strings of beads, numerous blankets, ten wolf furs, 200 beavers, and 500 zibelines. After that they took off their festival dresses, gave them away, and, putting on old ragged furs, addressed a few words to their kinsfolk, saying that though they are now poorer than any one of them, they have won their friendship.(29) Like distributions of wealth appear to be a regular habit with the Eskimos, and to take place at a certain season, after an exhibition of all that has been obtained during the year.(30) In my opinion these distributions reveal a very old institution, contemporaneous with the first apparition of personal wealth; they must have been a means for re-establishing equality among the members of the clan, after it had been disturbed by the enrichment of the few. The periodical redistribution of land and the periodical abandonment of all debts which took place in historical times with so many different races (Semites, Aryans, etc.), must have been a survival of that old custom. And the habit of either burying with the dead, or destroying upon his grave, all that belonged to him personally—a habit which we find among all primitive races—must have had the same origin. In fact, while everything that belongs personally to the dead is burnt or broken upon his grave, nothing is destroyed of what belonged to him in common with the tribe, such as boats, or the communal implements of fishing. The destruction bears upon personal property alone. At a later epoch this habit becomes a religious ceremony. It receives a mystical interpretation, and is imposed by religion, when public opinion alone proves incapable of enforcing its general observance. And, finally, it is substituted by either burning simple models of the dead man's property (as in China), or by simply carrying his property to the grave and taking it back to his house after the burial ceremony is over—a habit which still prevails with the Europeans as regards swords, crosses, and other marks of public distinction.(31)

Eskimo life is based on communal living. What is gained through hunting and fishing belongs to the clan. However, in some tribes, especially in the West, influenced by the Danes, private property has started to take hold. To counteract the issues that come from individuals hoarding wealth, which could undermine their tribal unity, they have a unique tradition. When a man becomes wealthy, he invites his clan to a large feast and, after a lot of eating, shares his entire fortune with them. On the Yukon River, Dall observed an Aleonte family giving away ten guns, ten full fur outfits, 200 strings of beads, many blankets, ten wolf furs, 200 beavers, and 500 zibelines during such an event. Afterward, they changed out of their festive clothing, gave that away too, and donned ragged old furs, telling their relatives that though they are now poorer than anyone else, they have gained their friendship. Similar acts of wealth distribution seem to be a regular practice among the Eskimos, occurring in a specific season after showcasing all they’ve gathered throughout the year. I believe these distributions reflect a very old tradition, dating back to the early days of personal wealth; they must have served to restore equality among clan members after it had been disrupted by the wealth of a few. The periodic redistribution of land and the regular forgiving of debts seen historically in various cultures (Semites, Aryans, etc.) likely stemmed from this old custom. The practice of burying or destroying a person's belongings at their grave—common among primitive cultures—also probably originates from this tradition. While all personal items belonging to the deceased are burned or broken at their gravesite, nothing is destroyed that was shared with the tribe, such as boats or communal fishing gear. The destruction only pertains to personal property. Over time, this practice evolved into a religious ceremony, gaining a mystical interpretation and becoming mandated by religion when public opinion alone couldn’t ensure adherence. Eventually, it was replaced by either burning simple models of the deceased’s belongings (as seen in China) or taking the deceased's items to the grave and then bringing them back home after the burial— a habit that remains among Europeans regarding swords, crosses, and other symbols of public honor.

The high standard of the tribal morality of the Eskimos has often been mentioned in general literature. Nevertheless the following remarks upon the manners of the Aleoutes—nearly akin to the Eskimos—will better illustrate savage morality as a whole. They were written, after a ten years' stay among the Aleoutes, by a most remarkable man—the Russian missionary, Veniaminoff. I sum them up, mostly in his own words:—

The high standard of tribal morality among the Eskimos has often been highlighted in general literature. However, the following comments on the behaviors of the Aleoutes—who are quite similar to the Eskimos—will better illustrate the concept of savage morality as a whole. These observations were made after a ten-year stay with the Aleoutes by a truly remarkable individual—the Russian missionary, Veniaminoff. I’ll summarize them mostly in his own words:—

Endurability (he wrote) is their chief feature. It is simply colossal. Not only do they bathe every morning in the frozen sea, and stand naked on the beach, inhaling the icy wind, but their endurability, even when at hard work on insufficient food, surpasses all that can be imagined. During a protracted scarcity of food, the Aleoute cares first for his children; he gives them all he has, and himself fasts. They are not inclined to stealing; that was remarked even by the first Russian immigrants. Not that they never steal; every Aleoute would confess having sometime stolen something, but it is always a trifle; the whole is so childish. The attachment of the parents to their children is touching, though it is never expressed in words or pettings. The Aleoute is with difficulty moved to make a promise, but once he has made it he will keep it whatever may happen. (An Aleoute made Veniaminoff a gift of dried fish, but it was forgotten on the beach in the hurry of the departure. He took it home. The next occasion to send it to the missionary was in January; and in November and December there was a great scarcity of food in the Aleoute encampment. But the fish was never touched by the starving people, and in January it was sent to its destination.) Their code of morality is both varied and severe. It is considered shameful to be afraid of unavoidable death; to ask pardon from an enemy; to die without ever having killed an enemy; to be convicted of stealing; to capsize a boat in the harbour; to be afraid of going to sea in stormy weather; to be the first in a party on a long journey to become an invalid in case of scarcity of food; to show greediness when spoil is divided, in which case every one gives his own part to the greedy man to shame him; to divulge a public secret to his wife; being two persons on a hunting expedition, not to offer the best game to the partner; to boast of his own deeds, especially of invented ones; to scold any one in scorn. Also to beg; to pet his wife in other people's presence, and to dance with her to bargain personally: selling must always be made through a third person, who settles the price. For a woman it is a shame not to know sewing, dancing and all kinds of woman's work; to pet her husband and children, or even to speak to her husband in the presence of a stranger.(32)

Endurance (he wrote) is their main trait. It’s simply enormous. They not only take a morning dip in the frigid sea and stand bare on the beach absorbing the icy wind, but their endurance, even while working hard on limited food, exceeds all expectations. During times of food scarcity, the Aleout cares for his children first; he gives them everything he has and fasts himself. They're not prone to stealing; even the first Russian immigrants noticed this. It's not that they never steal; every Aleout would admit to having taken something at some point, but it’s always something small; the overall attitude is so innocent. The bond between parents and their children is moving, though it’s never shown in words or affectionate gestures. An Aleout finds it hard to make a promise, but once he does, he keeps it no matter what. (An Aleout gave Veniaminoff some dried fish, but it was forgotten on the beach hurriedly. He took it home. The next chance to send it to the missionary came in January; and in November and December, there was a severe food shortage in the Aleout camp. Yet, the fish was never touched by the starving people, and in January, it was sent on to its destination.) Their moral code is both complex and strict. It’s considered shameful to fear inevitable death; to ask forgiveness from an enemy; to die without ever having killed an enemy; to be caught stealing; to capsize a boat in the harbor; to be afraid of going to sea in rough weather; to be the first in a group on a long journey to falter if food runs low; to act greedily when spoils are divided, as everyone will give their share to the greedy person to shame him; to reveal a public secret to his wife; when two people are on a hunting trip, not to offer the best game to the partner; to boast about one’s own actions, especially if made up; to scold anyone in disdain. Also, to beg; to show affection to his wife in front of others, and to dance with her to negotiate personally: selling must always be done through a third person, who sets the price. For a woman, it’s shameful not to know how to sew, dance, and do all sorts of traditional women’s tasks; to show affection to her husband and children, or even to speak to her husband in front of a stranger.

Such is Aleoute morality, which might also be further illustrated by their tales and legends. Let me also add that when Veniaminoff wrote (in 1840) one murder only had been committed since the last century in a population of 60,000 people, and that among 1,800 Aleoutes not one single common law offence had been known for forty years. This will not seem strange if we remark that scolding, scorning, and the use of rough words are absolutely unknown in Aleoute life. Even their children never fight, and never abuse each other in words. All they may say is, "Your mother does not know sewing," or "Your father is blind of one eye."(33)

Such is Aleoute morality, which can also be further illustrated by their stories and legends. It’s worth noting that when Veniaminoff wrote (in 1840), only one murder had occurred in the past century among a population of 60,000 people, and that among 1,800 Aleoutes, there hadn’t been a single common law offense for forty years. This won't seem odd if we consider that scolding, mocking, and the use of harsh words are completely absent in Aleoute life. Even their children never fight or insult each other. All they might say is, "Your mom doesn’t know how to sew," or "Your dad is blind in one eye."(33)

Many features of savage life remain, however, a puzzle to Europeans. The high development of tribal solidarity and the good feelings with which primitive folk are animated towards each other, could be illustrated by any amount of reliable testimony. And yet it is not the less certain that those same savages practise infanticide; that in some cases they abandon their old people, and that they blindly obey the rules of blood-revenge. We must then explain the coexistence of facts which, to the European mind, seem so contradictory at the first sight. I have just mentioned how the Aleoute father starves for days and weeks, and gives everything eatable to his child; and how the Bushman mother becomes a slave to follow her child; and I might fill pages with illustrations of the really tender relations existing among the savages and their children. Travellers continually mention them incidentally. Here you read about the fond love of a mother; there you see a father wildly running through the forest and carrying upon his shoulders his child bitten by a snake; or a missionary tells you the despair of the parents at the loss of a child whom he had saved, a few years before, from being immolated at its birth, you learn that the "savage" mothers usually nurse their children till the age of four, and that, in the New Hebrides, on the loss of a specially beloved child, its mother, or aunt, will kill herself to take care of it in the other world.(34) And so on.

Many aspects of primitive life still confuse Europeans. The strong sense of community and the positive emotions that tribal people share with one another could be demonstrated with plenty of credible evidence. Yet, it remains true that these same individuals practice infanticide, sometimes abandon their elderly, and strictly follow the customs of blood revenge. We need to understand how these seemingly contradictory behaviors coexist. I’ve just pointed out how an Aleoute father will starve for days, giving all his food to his child; how a Bushman mother becomes devoted to the point of servitude for the sake of her child. I could fill pages with examples that highlight the genuinely loving relationships between these people and their children. Travelers often mention these bonds in passing. You’ll read about a mother’s deep love; see a father frantically running through the forest, carrying his snake-bitten child on his shoulders; or hear a missionary describe the despair of parents who lost a child he saved from being sacrificed at birth. You learn that "savage" mothers typically nurse their children until they’re four years old, and in the New Hebrides, when a mother or aunt loses a beloved child, she may take her own life to be with them in the afterlife. And so on.

Like facts are met with by the score; so that, when we see that these same loving parents practise infanticide, we are bound to recognize that the habit (whatever its ulterior transformations may be) took its origin under the sheer pressure of necessity, as an obligation towards the tribe, and a means for rearing the already growing children. The savages, as a rule, do not "multiply without stint," as some English writers put it. On the contrary, they take all kinds of measures for diminishing the birth-rate. A whole series of restrictions, which Europeans certainly would find extravagant, are imposed to that effect, and they are strictly obeyed. But notwithstanding that, primitive folk cannot rear all their children. However, it has been remarked that as soon as they succeed in increasing their regular means of subsistence, they at once begin to abandon the practice of infanticide. On the whole, the parents obey that obligation reluctantly, and as soon as they can afford it they resort to all kinds of compromises to save the lives of their new-born. As has been so well pointed out by my friend Elie Reclus,(35) they invent the lucky and unlucky days of births, and spare the children born on the lucky days; they try to postpone the sentence for a few hours, and then say that if the baby has lived one day it must live all its natural life.(36) They hear the cries of the little ones coming from the forest, and maintain that, if heard, they forbode a misfortune for the tribe; and as they have no baby-farming nor creches for getting rid of the children, every one of them recoils before the necessity of performing the cruel sentence; they prefer to expose the baby in the wood rather than to take its life by violence. Ignorance, not cruelty, maintains infanticide; and, instead of moralizing the savages with sermons, the missionaries would do better to follow the example of Veniaminoff, who, every year till his old age, crossed the sea of Okhotsk in a miserable boat, or travelled on dogs among his Tchuktchis, supplying them with bread and fishing implements. He thus had really stopped infanticide.

Like facts appear frequently; so when we see that these same loving parents commit infanticide, we have to acknowledge that the habit (whatever its eventual transformations may be) originated from sheer necessity, as an obligation to the community, and as a means to raise their already existing children. Generally, savages do not “multiply without limit,” as some English writers suggest. On the contrary, they take various measures to reduce the birth rate. A whole series of restrictions, which Europeans might find outrageous, are imposed for that purpose, and they are strictly followed. However, despite this, primitive people cannot raise all their children. It has been noted that as soon as they manage to improve their regular means of subsistence, they immediately start to abandon the practice of infanticide. Overall, parents follow that obligation reluctantly, and as soon as they can manage it, they look for all kinds of ways to save their newborns. As my friend Elie Reclus has pointed out so well, they come up with lucky and unlucky days for births, and they spare the children born on the lucky days; they try to delay the decision for a few hours and then say that if the baby survives the first day, it should live out its natural life. They hear the cries of little ones coming from the forest and believe that if heard, they predict misfortune for the tribe; and since they have no baby-farming or crèches to get rid of the children, everyone recoils from the necessity of carrying out the harsh decision; they prefer to leave the baby in the woods rather than take its life brutally. Ignorance, not cruelty, sustains infanticide; and instead of moralizing savages with sermons, missionaries would be better off following the example of Veniaminoff, who, every year until he was old, crossed the Sea of Okhotsk in a rickety boat or traveled on dog sleds among the Tchuktchis, providing them with bread and fishing gear. He truly made a difference in stopping infanticide.

The same is true as regards what superficial observers describe as parricide. We just now saw that the habit of abandoning old people is not so widely spread as some writers have maintained it to be. It has been extremely exaggerated, but it is occasionally met with among nearly all savages; and in such cases it has the same origin as the exposure of children. When a "savage" feels that he is a burden to his tribe; when every morning his share of food is taken from the mouths of the children—and the little ones are not so stoical as their fathers: they cry when they are hungry; when every day he has to be carried across the stony beach, or the virgin forest, on the shoulders of younger people there are no invalid carriages, nor destitutes to wheel them in savage lands—he begins to repeat what the old Russian peasants say until now-a-day. "Tchujoi vek zayedayu, Pora na pokoi!" ("I live other people's life: it is time to retire!") And he retires. He does what the soldier does in a similar case. When the salvation of his detachment depends upon its further advance, and he can move no more, and knows that he must die if left behind, the soldier implores his best friend to render him the last service before leaving the encampment. And the friend, with shivering hands, discharges his gun into the dying body. So the savages do. The old man asks himself to die; he himself insists upon this last duty towards the community, and obtains the consent of the tribe; he digs out his grave; he invites his kinsfolk to the last parting meal. His father has done so, it is now his turn; and he parts with his kinsfolk with marks of affection. The savage so much considers death as part of his duties towards his community, that he not only refuses to be rescued (as Moffat has told), but when a woman who had to be immolated on her husband's grave was rescued by missionaries, and was taken to an island, she escaped in the night, crossed a broad sea-arm, swimming and rejoined her tribe, to die on the grave.(37) It has become with them a matter of religion. But the savages, as a rule, are so reluctant to take any one's life otherwise than in fight, that none of them will take upon himself to shed human blood, and they resort to all kinds of stratagems, which have been so falsely interpreted. In most cases, they abandon the old man in the wood, after having given him more than his share of the common food. Arctic expeditions have done the same when they no more could carry their invalid comrades. "Live a few days more, maybe there will be some unexpected rescue!" West European men of science, when coming across these facts, are absolutely unable to stand them; they can not reconcile them with a high development of tribal morality, and they prefer to cast a doubt upon the exactitude of absolutely reliable observers, instead of trying to explain the parallel existence of the two sets of facts: a high tribal morality together with the abandonment of the parents and infanticide. But if these same Europeans were to tell a savage that people, extremely amiable, fond of their own children, and so impressionable that they cry when they see a misfortune simulated on the stage, are living in Europe within a stone's throw from dens in which children die from sheer want of food, the savage, too, would not understand them. I remember how vainly I tried to make some of my Tungus friends understand our civilization of individualism: they could not, and they resorted to the most fantastical suggestions. The fact is that a savage, brought up in ideas of a tribal solidarity in everything for bad and for good, is as incapable of understanding a "moral" European, who knows nothing of that solidarity, as the average European is incapable of understanding the savage. But if our scientist had lived amidst a half-starving tribe which does not possess among them all one man's food for so much as a few days to come, he probably might have understood their motives. So also the savage, if he had stayed among us, and received our education, may be, would understand our European indifference towards our neighbours, and our Royal Commissions for the prevention of "babyfarming." "Stone houses make stony hearts," the Russian peasants say. But he ought to live in a stone house first.

The same goes for what shallow observers call parricide. We just saw that the practice of abandoning old people isn't as common as some writers claim. It's been greatly exaggerated, but it does happen occasionally among nearly all primitive tribes; and in those cases, it comes from the same place as the abandonment of children. When a "primitive" person feels like a burden to his tribe, when every morning his share of food is taken from the mouths of the children—and the little ones aren’t as stoic as their fathers: they cry when they're hungry; when every day he has to be carried over the rocky beach or through the untouched forest by younger people—since there are no invalid carriages or people to push them in these wild places—he starts to echo what the old Russian peasants say even today. "Tchujoi vek zayedayu, Pora na pokoi!" ("I live other people's life: it is time to retire!") And he withdraws. He does what a soldier does in a similar situation. When the survival of his unit depends on moving forward and he can’t go any further, knowing he will die if left behind, the soldier asks his best friend to do him one last favor before the group leaves. The friend, with trembling hands, shoots him. The same goes for the "primitive" man. He tells himself it's time to die; he insists on doing this final duty to the community and gets the tribe's agreement; he digs his grave; he invites his family for one last meal together. His father did it, now it's his turn; and he says goodbye to his family with affection. The primitive person views death as part of his responsibilities to the community, so much so that he not only refuses to be saved (as Moffat reported), but when a woman was supposed to be sacrificed on her husband's grave and was rescued by missionaries, she escaped at night, swam across a large stretch of water, and rejoined her tribe to die at the grave. It has become a matter of deep significance for them. However, primitives generally are so hesitant to take a life outside of battle that no one will willingly shed human blood, resorting to various cunning methods, which have been misinterpreted. In most cases, they leave the old man in the woods after providing him with more than his share of food. Arctic expeditions have done the same when they could no longer carry their injured comrades. "Live a few more days; maybe there will be some unexpected rescue!" Western European scientists, confronted with these facts, simply can't accept them; they can't reconcile these actions with a high level of tribal morality, so they prefer to question the accuracy of reliable observers rather than trying to explain the coexistence of two contradictory facts: a strong tribal morality alongside the abandonment of parents and infanticide. But if those same Europeans told a primitive person that there are people, very kind, devoted to their own children, and so sensitive that they cry at staged misfortunes, living in Europe just around the corner from places where children die from sheer hunger, the primitive person wouldn't understand either. I remember how futilely I tried to help some of my Tungus friends grasp our individualistic civilization: they couldn’t, and they came up with the most bizarre suggestions. The truth is, a primitive, raised with an understanding of tribal solidarity in both good and bad times, can't comprehend a "moral" European who knows nothing of that solidarity, just as the average European can't grasp the primitive. But if our scientist had lived among a tribe that is barely surviving, without enough food for even a few days ahead, he might have understood their reasoning. Likewise, if the primitive had lived among us and received our education, he might understand our European disregard for our neighbors and our Royal Commissions to prevent "baby farming." "Stone houses make stony hearts," as Russian peasants say. But he'd have to live in a stone house first.

Similar remarks must be made as regards cannibalism. Taking into account all the facts which were brought to light during a recent controversy on this subject at the Paris Anthropological Society, and many incidental remarks scattered throughout the "savage" literature, we are bound to recognize that that practice was brought into existence by sheer necessity. But that it was further developed by superstition and religion into the proportions it attained in Fiji or in Mexico. It is a fact that until this day many savages are compelled to devour corpses in the most advanced state of putrefaction, and that in cases of absolute scarcity some of them have had to disinter and to feed upon human corpses, even during an epidemic. These are ascertained facts. But if we now transport ourselves to the conditions which man had to face during the glacial period, in a damp and cold climate, with but little vegetable food at his disposal; if we take into account the terrible ravages which scurvy still makes among underfed natives, and remember that meat and fresh blood are the only restoratives which they know, we must admit that man, who formerly was a granivorous animal, became a flesh-eater during the glacial period. He found plenty of deer at that time, but deer often migrate in the Arctic regions, and sometimes they entirely abandon a territory for a number of years. In such cases his last resources disappeared. During like hard trials, cannibalism has been resorted to even by Europeans, and it was resorted to by the savages. Until the present time, they occasionally devour the corpses of their own dead: they must have devoured then the corpses of those who had to die. Old people died, convinced that by their death they were rendering a last service to the tribe. This is why cannibalism is represented by some savages as of divine origin, as something that has been ordered by a messenger from the sky. But later on it lost its character of necessity, and survived as a superstition. Enemies had to be eaten in order to inherit their courage; and, at a still later epoch, the enemy's eye or heart was eaten for the same purpose; while among other tribes, already having a numerous priesthood and a developed mythology, evil gods, thirsty for human blood, were invented, and human sacrifices required by the priests to appease the gods. In this religious phase of its existence, cannibalism attained its most revolting characters. Mexico is a well-known example; and in Fiji, where the king could eat any one of his subjects, we also find a mighty cast of priests, a complicated theology,(38) and a full development of autocracy. Originated by necessity, cannibalism became, at a later period, a religious institution, and in this form it survived long after it had disappeared from among tribes which certainly practised it in former times, but did not attain the theocratical stage of evolution. The same remark must be made as regards infanticide and the abandonment of parents. In some cases they also have been maintained as a survival of olden times, as a religiously-kept tradition of the past.

Similar comments can be made about cannibalism. Considering all the facts revealed during a recent debate on this topic at the Paris Anthropological Society, along with various observations scattered throughout "savage" literature, we have to acknowledge that this practice arose out of sheer necessity. However, it was further evolved by superstition and religion into the forms it took in Fiji or Mexico. Even today, many indigenous people are forced to consume corpses in advanced stages of decay, and in times of extreme scarcity, some have had to dig up and eat human remains, even during an epidemic. These are verified facts. If we transport ourselves to the conditions humans faced during the Ice Age, in a damp and cold climate with limited plant food available, and consider the severe effects that scurvy still has on underfed people, remembering that meat and fresh blood are the only known remedies, we must recognize that humans, who were once grain-eating animals, became flesh-eaters during the Ice Age. There were plenty of deer at that time, but deer often migrate in Arctic regions and sometimes completely leave an area for years. In such cases, their last resources would vanish. During similar hardships, cannibalism was practiced even by Europeans, just as it was by indigenous people. To this day, they sometimes consume the bodies of their own deceased; they must have eaten the bodies of those who died. Elderly people passed away believing that their death was a final service to the tribe. This is why some indigenous groups view cannibalism as divinely ordained, as something mandated by a messenger from the heavens. But later, it lost its necessity and persisted as a superstition. Enemies had to be eaten to inherit their bravery; and, in a later time, parts like an enemy's eye or heart were consumed for the same reason; meanwhile, among other tribes with established priesthoods and developed mythologies, evil gods, thirsty for human blood, were invented, with priests requiring human sacrifices to appease these gods. In this religious phase, cannibalism reached its most grotesque forms. Mexico is a well-known example, and in Fiji, where the king could eat any of his subjects, there was also a powerful priesthood, a complex theology, and a full development of autocracy. Originating from necessity, cannibalism later became a religious institution, and in this form, it continued long after it faded from tribes that practiced it in the past but did not reach theocratic stages of development. The same can be said for infanticide and neglect of parents. In some cases, these have also persisted as remnants of ancient times, held as religious traditions from the past.

I will terminate my remarks by mentioning another custom which also is a source of most erroneous conclusions. I mean the practice of blood-revenge. All savages are under the impression that blood shed must be revenged by blood. If any one has been killed, the murderer must die; if any one has been wounded, the aggressor's blood must be shed. There is no exception to the rule, not even for animals; so the hunter's blood is shed on his return to the village when he has shed the blood of an animal. That is the savages' conception of justice—a conception which yet prevails in Western Europe as regards murder. Now, when both the offender and the offended belong to the same tribe, the tribe and the offended person settle the affair.(39) But when the offender belongs to another tribe, and that tribe, for one reason or another, refuses a compensation, then the offended tribe decides to take the revenge itself. Primitive folk so much consider every one's acts as a tribal affair, dependent upon tribal approval, that they easily think the clan responsible for every one's acts. Therefore, the due revenge may be taken upon any member of the offender's clan or relatives.(40) It may often happen, however, that the retaliation goes further than the offence. In trying to inflict a wound, they may kill the offender, or wound him more than they intended to do, and this becomes a cause for a new feud, so that the primitive legislators were careful in requiring the retaliation to be limited to an eye for an eye, a tooth for a tooth, and blood for blood.(41)

I will wrap up my comments by highlighting another practice that leads to many misunderstandings. I’m talking about the tradition of blood revenge. All primitive societies believe that any blood spilled must be avenged with blood. If someone is killed, the murderer has to die; if someone is injured, the aggressor must suffer the same fate. There are no exceptions to this rule, not even for animals; a hunter's blood is shed when he returns to the village after killing an animal. This is how savages view justice—a view that still exists in parts of Western Europe when it comes to murder. When both the offender and the victim are from the same tribe, the tribe and the victim work things out. However, when the offender belongs to another tribe, and that tribe refuses to offer compensation for some reason, the offended tribe decides to take matters into their own hands. Primitive people see everyone's actions as related to their tribe, so they easily believe that the entire clan is responsible for the actions of one member. As a result, retaliation can be directed at any member of the offender's clan or relatives. Often, though, the response goes beyond what was done. In trying to inflict injury, they might kill the offender or injure him more than they intended, leading to a new feud. Because of this, primitive lawmakers were careful to require that retaliation be limited to an eye for an eye, a tooth for a tooth, and blood for blood.

It is remarkable, however, that with most primitive folk like feuds are infinitely rarer than might be expected; though with some of them they may attain abnormal proportions, especially with mountaineers who have been driven to the highlands by foreign invaders, such as the mountaineers of Caucasia, and especially those of Borneo—the Dayaks. With the Dayaks—we were told lately—the feuds had gone so far that a young man could neither marry nor be proclaimed of age before he had secured the head of an enemy. This horrid practice was fully described in a modern English work.(42) It appears, however, that this affirmation was a gross exaggeration. Moreover, Dayak "head-hunting" takes quite another aspect when we learn that the supposed "headhunter" is not actuated at all by personal passion. He acts under what he considers as a moral obligation towards his tribe, just as the European judge who, in obedience to the same, evidently wrong, principle of "blood for blood," hands over the condemned murderer to the hangman. Both the Dayak and the judge would even feel remorse if sympathy moved them to spare the murderer. That is why the Dayaks, apart from the murders they commit when actuated by their conception of justice, are depicted, by all those who know them, as a most sympathetic people. Thus Carl Bock, the same author who has given such a terrible picture of head-hunting, writes:

It’s impressive, though, that among most primitive groups, feuds are actually a lot rarer than you might think; though in some cases, they can reach extreme levels, especially among mountain people pushed to the highlands by foreign invaders, like the mountain people of Caucasia and particularly those of Borneo—the Dayaks. Recently, we were told that among the Dayaks, feuds had escalated to the point that a young man couldn't marry or be recognized as an adult until he had taken the head of an enemy. This shocking practice was thoroughly described in a modern English book.(42) However, it seems that this claim was greatly exaggerated. Furthermore, Dayak "head-hunting" looks quite different when we realize that the so-called "headhunter" is not driven by personal feelings at all. He acts under what he believes is a moral duty to his tribe, much like a European judge who, following the same clearly wrong principle of "an eye for an eye," sends a convicted murderer to the gallows. Both the Dayak and the judge would even feel guilt if compassion led them to spare the murderer. This is why, aside from the killings they commit based on their view of justice, people familiar with the Dayaks describe them as a very compassionate group. Thus, Carl Bock, the same author who painted such a grim picture of head-hunting, writes:

"As regards morality, I am bound to assign to the Dayaks a high place in the scale of civilization…. Robberies and theft are entirely unknown among them. They also are very truthful…. If I did not always get the 'whole truth,' I always got, at least, nothing but the truth from them. I wish I could say the same of the Malays" (pp. 209 and 210).

"As for morality, I have to rate the Dayaks highly on the scale of civilization…. Robberies and theft are completely unknown to them. They are also very honest…. While I didn’t always get the 'whole truth,' I always received, at least, nothing but the truth from them. I wish I could say the same about the Malays" (pp. 209 and 210).

Bock's testimony is fully corroborated by that of Ida Pfeiffer. "I fully recognized," she wrote, "that I should be pleased longer to travel among them. I usually found them honest, good, and reserved … much more so than any other nation I know."(43) Stoltze used almost the same language when speaking of them. The Dayaks usually have but one wife, and treat her well. They are very sociable, and every morning the whole clan goes out for fishing, hunting, or gardening, in large parties. Their villages consist of big huts, each of which is inhabited by a dozen families, and sometimes by several hundred persons, peacefully living together. They show great respect for their wives, and are fond of their children; and when one of them falls ill, the women nurse him in turn. As a rule they are very moderate in eating and drinking. Such is the Dayak in his real daily life.

Bock's testimony is completely supported by that of Ida Pfeiffer. "I fully recognized," she wrote, "that I would enjoy traveling among them for longer. I usually found them honest, good, and reserved… much more so than any other nation I know."(43) Stoltze used almost the same words when discussing them. The Dayaks usually have just one wife and treat her well. They are very social, and every morning the entire clan goes out fishing, hunting, or gardening in large groups. Their villages are made up of large huts, each home to a dozen families, and sometimes several hundred people, living together peacefully. They show great respect for their wives and love their children; when one of them gets sick, the women take turns nursing him. Generally, they are very moderate in their eating and drinking. That’s the Dayak in his everyday life.

It would be a tedious repetition if more illustrations from savage life were given. Wherever we go we find the same sociable manners, the same spirit of solidarity. And when we endeavour to penetrate into the darkness of past ages, we find the same tribal life, the same associations of men, however primitive, for mutual support. Therefore, Darwin was quite right when he saw in man's social qualities the chief factor for his further evolution, and Darwin's vulgarizers are entirely wrong when they maintain the contrary.

It would be boring to repeat more examples from primitive life. No matter where we go, we see the same friendly behavior and sense of community. And when we try to understand the distant past, we find the same tribal way of living, the same groups of people, no matter how simple, coming together for mutual support. So, Darwin was completely correct when he identified social traits in humans as the main driver of their evolution, and those who misinterpret his ideas are completely mistaken.

The small strength and speed of man (he wrote), his want of natural weapons, etc., are more than counterbalanced, firstly, by his intellectual faculties (which, he remarked on another page, have been chiefly or even exclusively gained for the benefit of the community). and secondly, by his social qualities, which led him to give and receive aid from his fellow men.(44)

The limited strength and speed of humans (he wrote), along with their lack of natural weapons, are more than offset, first, by their intellectual abilities (which, he noted elsewhere, have been primarily or even solely developed for the benefit of society) and, second, by their social traits, which encourage them to both give and receive help from each other. (44)

In the last century the "savage" and his "life in the state of nature" were idealized. But now men of science have gone to the opposite extreme, especially since some of them, anxious to prove the animal origin of man, but not conversant with the social aspects of animal life, began to charge the savage with all imaginable "bestial" features. It is evident, however, that this exaggeration is even more unscientific than Rousseau's idealization. The savage is not an ideal of virtue, nor is he an ideal of "savagery." But the primitive man has one quality, elaborated and maintained by the very necessities of his hard struggle for life—he identifies his own existence with that of his tribe; and without that quality mankind never would have attained the level it has attained now.

In the last century, the "savage" and his "life in the state of nature" were romanticized. But now, scientists have swung to the other extreme, with some eager to prove that humans have an animal origin but lacking an understanding of the social aspects of animal life, leading them to attribute all sorts of "bestial" traits to the savage. However, it's clear that this exaggeration is even more unscientific than Rousseau's idealization. The savage is neither a perfect example of virtue nor an embodiment of "savagery." But primitive man possesses one important quality, shaped and sustained by the harsh realities of his struggle for survival—he sees his own existence as tied to that of his tribe; without that quality, humanity would never have reached its current level of development.

Primitive folk, as has been already said, so much identify their lives with that of the tribe, that each of their acts, however insignificant, is considered as a tribal affair. Their whole behaviour is regulated by an infinite series of unwritten rules of propriety which are the fruit of their common experience as to what is good or bad—that is, beneficial or harmful for their own tribe. Of course, the reasonings upon which their rules of propriety are based sometimes are absurd in the extreme. Many of them originate in superstition; and altogether, in whatever the savage does, he sees but the immediate consequences of his acts; he cannot foresee their indirect and ulterior consequences—thus simply exaggerating a defect with which Bentham reproached civilized legislators. But, absurd or not, the savage obeys the prescriptions of the common law, however inconvenient they may be. He obeys them even more blindly than the civilized man obeys the prescriptions of the written law. His common law is his religion; it is his very habit of living. The idea of the clan is always present to his mind, and self-restriction and self-sacrifice in the interest of the clan are of daily occurrence. If the savage has infringed one of the smaller tribal rules, he is prosecuted by the mockeries of the women. If the infringement is grave, he is tortured day and night by the fear of having called a calamity upon his tribe. If he has wounded by accident any one of his own clan, and thus has committed the greatest of all crimes, he grows quite miserable: he runs away in the woods, and is ready to commit suicide, unless the tribe absolves him by inflicting upon him a physical pain and sheds some of his own blood.(45) Within the tribe everything is shared in common; every morsel of food is divided among all present; and if the savage is alone in the woods, he does not begin eating before he has loudly shouted thrice an invitation to any one who may hear his voice to share his meal.(46)

Primitive people, as mentioned before, completely connect their lives to that of the tribe, so much so that every action, no matter how minor, is considered a tribal matter. Their behavior is governed by a vast array of unwritten rules of conduct that come from their shared experiences of what is good or bad—that is, what benefits or harms their tribe. Of course, the reasoning behind these rules can sometimes be completely ridiculous. Many stem from superstitions, and overall, whatever a person in the tribe does, they only see the immediate results of their actions; they can't predict the indirect or long-term consequences—essentially exaggerating a flaw that Bentham pointed out in civilized lawmakers. But, ridiculous or not, the tribesman follows the common laws, no matter how inconvenient they might be. He obeys them even more blindly than a civilized individual follows written laws. His common laws are his religion; they shape his way of life. The concept of the clan is always in his mind, and self-discipline and self-sacrifice for the clan are daily practices. If someone in the tribe breaks a minor rule, the women mock him. If the violation is serious, he is plagued day and night by the fear of bringing disaster to his tribe. If he accidentally injures someone from his own clan, thus committing the worst crime of all, he becomes deeply distressed: he hides in the woods and is prepared to take his own life unless the tribe forgives him by making him endure physical suffering and shedding some of his own blood. Within the tribe, everything is shared; every piece of food is divided among everyone present, and if someone is alone in the woods, they won't start eating until they have loudly called out three times inviting anyone who might hear to join in their meal.

In short, within the tribe the rule of "each for all" is supreme, so long as the separate family has not yet broken up the tribal unity. But that rule is not extended to the neighbouring clans, or tribes, even when they are federated for mutual protection. Each tribe, or clan, is a separate unity. Just as among mammals and birds, the territory is roughly allotted among separate tribes, and, except in times of war, the boundaries are respected. On entering the territory of his neighbours one must show that he has no bad intentions. The louder one heralds his coming, the more confidence he wins; and if he enters a house, he must deposit his hatchet at the entrance. But no tribe is bound to share its food with the others: it may do so or it may not. Therefore the life of the savage is divided into two sets of actions, and appears under two different ethical aspects: the relations within the tribe, and the relations with the outsiders; and (like our international law) the "inter-tribal" law widely differs from the common law. Therefore, when it comes to a war the most revolting cruelties may be considered as so many claims upon the admiration of the tribe. This double conception of morality passes through the whole evolution of mankind, and maintains itself until now. We Europeans have realized some progress—not immense, at any rate—in eradicating that double conception of ethics; but it also must be said that while we have in some measure extended our ideas of solidarity—in theory, at least—over the nation, and partly over other nations as well, we have lessened the bonds of solidarity within our own nations, and even within our own families.

In short, within the tribe, the rule of "each for all" is the highest law, as long as the individual family hasn't disrupted the tribal unity. However, that rule doesn't extend to neighboring clans or tribes, even if they are allied for mutual protection. Each tribe or clan is its own separate entity. Just like among mammals and birds, territories are roughly divided among different tribes, and except in wartime, the boundaries are honored. When entering a neighbor's territory, one must show that they have no bad intentions. The louder one announces their arrival, the more trust they gain; and if they enter a house, they must leave their hatchet at the entrance. But no tribe is obligated to share food with others: they can choose to share or not. Consequently, the life of the savage is split into two sets of actions, showing two different ethical views: the relationships within the tribe and the relationships with outsiders; and (like our international law) the "inter-tribal" law is quite different from common law. Therefore, in times of war, the most shocking cruelties may be seen as ways to earn the tribe's admiration. This dual idea of morality has been a part of human evolution and continues to this day. We Europeans have made some progress—not huge, but notable—in eliminating this dual view of ethics; however, it's also true that while we've somewhat broadened our ideas of solidarity—at least in theory—across the nation, and partially among other nations, we have weakened the bonds of solidarity within our own nations and even within our own families.

The appearance of a separate family amidst the clan necessarily disturbs the established unity. A separate family means separate property and accumulation of wealth. We saw how the Eskimos obviate its inconveniences; and it is one of the most interesting studies to follow in the course of ages the different institutions (village communities, guilds, and so on) by means of which the masses endeavoured to maintain the tribal unity, notwithstanding the agencies which were at work to break it down. On the other hand, the first rudiments of knowledge which appeared at an extremely remote epoch, when they confounded themselves with witchcraft, also became a power in the hands of the individual which could be used against the tribe. They were carefully kept in secrecy, and transmitted to the initiated only, in the secret societies of witches, shamans, and priests, which we find among all savages. By the same time, wars and invasions created military authority, as also castes of warriors, whose associations or clubs acquired great powers. However, at no period of man's life were wars the normal state of existence. While warriors exterminated each other, and the priests celebrated their massacres, the masses continued to live their daily life, they prosecuted their daily toil. And it is one of the most interesting studies to follow that life of the masses; to study the means by which they maintained their own social organization, which was based upon their own conceptions of equity, mutual aid, and mutual support—of common law, in a word, even when they were submitted to the most ferocious theocracy or autocracy in the State.

The emergence of a separate family within the clan inevitably disrupts the established unity. A separate family signifies separate property and the accumulation of wealth. We observed how the Eskimos dealt with its challenges; it's one of the most fascinating studies to explore the various institutions (like village communities, guilds, etc.) that people developed over time to maintain tribal unity, despite the forces working against it. On the flip side, the first signs of knowledge that appeared long ago, which mixed with witchcraft, also became a tool for the individual that could be used against the tribe. This knowledge was kept secret and passed only to the initiated members of secret societies like witches, shamans, and priests, which exist among all primitive cultures. At the same time, wars and invasions led to military authority and classes of warriors, whose groups gained significant power. Yet, at no point in human history were wars the normal state of existence. While warriors battled each other and priests celebrated their killings, the general population continued their daily lives, engaged in their routine work. It’s one of the most intriguing studies to follow the life of the masses, examining how they upheld their own social order based on their ideas of fairness, mutual aid, and support—essentially, common law—even when subjected to the harshest theocracy or autocracy in government.

NOTES:

1. Nineteenth Century, February 1888, p. 165.

1. Nineteenth Century, February 1888, p. 165.

2. The Descent of Man, end of ch. ii. pp. 63 and 64 of the 2nd edition.

2. The Descent of Man, end of ch. ii. pp. 63 and 64 of the 2nd edition.

3. Anthropologists who fully endorse the above views as regards man nevertheless intimate, sometimes, that the apes live in polygamous families, under the leadership of "a strong and jealous male." I do not know how far that assertion is based upon conclusive observation. But the passage from Brehm's Life of Animals, which is sometimes referred to, can hardly be taken as very conclusive. It occurs in his general description of monkeys; but his more detailed descriptions of separate species either contradict it or do not confirm it. Even as regards the cercopitheques, Brehm is affirmative in saying that they "nearly always live in bands, and very seldom in families" (French edition, p. 59). As to other species, the very numbers of their bands, always containing many males, render the "polygamous family" more than doubtful further observation is evidently wanted.

3. Anthropologists who fully support the views mentioned above about humans sometimes suggest that apes live in polygamous families led by "a strong and jealous male." I'm not sure how much of that claim is based on solid observations. However, the excerpt from Brehm's Life of Animals, which is often cited, can't really be considered very convincing. It's part of his general description of monkeys, but his more detailed descriptions of specific species either contradict it or don't support it. Even regarding the cercopitheques, Brehm clearly states that they "almost always live in groups, and very rarely in families" (French edition, p. 59). As for other species, the large number of their groups, which usually consist of many males, makes the idea of a "polygamous family" quite questionable; more observation is clearly needed.

4. Lubbock, Prehistoric Times, fifth edition, 1890.

4. Lubbock, Prehistoric Times, 5th edition, 1890.

5. That extension of the ice-cap is admitted by most of the geologists who have specially studied the glacial age. The Russian Geological Survey already has taken this view as regards Russia, and most German specialists maintain it as regards Germany. The glaciation of most of the central plateau of France will not fail to be recognized by the French geologists, when they pay more attention to the glacial deposits altogether.

5. Most geologists who have focused on the glacial age agree on the expansion of the ice cap. The Russian Geological Survey has already adopted this perspective about Russia, and many German experts support it for Germany. French geologists will eventually acknowledge the glaciation of much of the central plateau of France when they give more consideration to the glacial deposits in general.

6. Prehistoric Times, pp. 232 and 242.

6. Prehistoric Times, pp. 232 and 242.

7. Bachofen, Das Mutterrecht, Stuttgart, 1861; Lewis H. Morgan, Ancient Society, or Researches in the Lines of Human Progress from Savagery through Barbarism to Civilization, New York, 1877; J.F. MacLennan, Studies in Ancient History, 1st series, new edition, 1886; 2nd series, 1896; L. Fison and A.W. Howitt, Kamilaroi and Kurnai, Melbourne. These four writers—as has been very truly remarked by Giraud Teulon,—starting from different facts and different general ideas, and following different methods, have come to the same conclusion. To Bachofen we owe the notion of the maternal family and the maternal succession; to Morgan—the system of kinship, Malayan and Turanian, and a highly gifted sketch of the main phases of human evolution; to MacLennan—the law of exogeny; and to Fison and Howitt—the cuadro, or scheme, of the conjugal societies in Australia. All four end in establishing the same fact of the tribal origin of the family. When Bachofen first drew attention to the maternal family, in his epoch-making work, and Morgan described the clan-organization,—both concurring to the almost general extension of these forms and maintaining that the marriage laws lie at the very basis of the consecutive steps of human evolution, they were accused of exaggeration. However, the most careful researches prosecuted since, by a phalanx of students of ancient law, have proved that all races of mankind bear traces of having passed through similar stages of development of marriage laws, such as we now see in force among certain savages. See the works of Post, Dargun, Kovalevsky, Lubbock, and their numerous followers: Lippert, Mucke, etc.

7. Bachofen, Das Mutterrecht, Stuttgart, 1861; Lewis H. Morgan, Ancient Society, or Researches in the Lines of Human Progress from Savagery through Barbarism to Civilization, New York, 1877; J.F. MacLennan, Studies in Ancient History, 1st series, new edition, 1886; 2nd series, 1896; L. Fison and A.W. Howitt, Kamilaroi and Kurnai, Melbourne. These four writers—as Giraud Teulon rightly noted—started from different facts and ideas, and used different methods, yet arrived at the same conclusion. Bachofen introduced the idea of the maternal family and maternal succession; Morgan focused on kinship systems, specifically Malayan and Turanian, and provided a talented overview of key phases of human evolution; MacLennan put forward the law of exogeny; and Fison and Howitt mapped out the structure of conjugal societies in Australia. All four ultimately confirm the same fact: the tribal origins of the family. When Bachofen first highlighted the maternal family in his groundbreaking work, and Morgan described clan organization, both contributed to the widespread recognition of these forms and argued that marriage laws underlie the fundamental steps of human evolution. They faced accusations of exaggeration. However, extensive research conducted since then by a group of scholars studying ancient law has shown that all human races exhibit signs of having gone through similar stages of development in marriage laws, as seen in certain current savages. See the works of Post, Dargun, Kovalevsky, Lubbock, and their numerous followers: Lippert, Mucke, etc.

8. None

None

9. For the Semites and the Aryans, see especially Prof. Maxim Kovalevsky's Primitive Law (in Russian), Moscow, 1886 and 1887. Also his Lectures delivered at Stockholm (Tableau des origines et de l'evolution de la famille et de la propriete, Stockholm, 1890), which represents an admirable review of the whole question. Cf. also A. Post, Die Geschlechtsgenossenschaft der Urzeit, Oldenburg 1875.

9. For the Semites and the Aryans, check out Prof. Maxim Kovalevsky's Primitive Law (in Russian), Moscow, 1886 and 1887. Also, his Lectures given at Stockholm (Tableau des origines et de l'evolution de la famille et de la propriete, Stockholm, 1890), which provides an excellent overview of the entire topic. See also A. Post, Die Geschlechtsgenossenschaft der Urzeit, Oldenburg 1875.

10. It would be impossible to enter here into a discussion of the origin of the marriage restrictions. Let me only remark that a division into groups, similar to Morgan's Hawaian, exists among birds; the young broods live together separately from their parents. A like division might probably be traced among some mammals as well. As to the prohibition of relations between brothers and sisters, it is more likely to have arisen, not from speculations about the bad effects of consanguinity, which speculations really do not seem probable, but to avoid the too-easy precocity of like marriages. Under close cohabitation it must have become of imperious necessity. I must also remark that in discussing the origin of new customs altogether, we must keep in mind that the savages, like us, have their "thinkers" and savants-wizards, doctors, prophets, etc.—whose knowledge and ideas are in advance upon those of the masses. United as they are in their secret unions (another almost universal feature) they are certainly capable of exercising a powerful influence, and of enforcing customs the utility of which may not yet be recognized by the majority of the tribe.

10. It would be impossible to get into a discussion about the origins of marriage restrictions here. I’ll just point out that a division into groups, similar to Morgan's Hawaiian model, exists among birds; the young birds live separately from their parents. A similar division might also be found among some mammals. As for the ban on relationships between siblings, it's more likely that it developed not from concerns about the negative effects of inbreeding—those concerns really don’t seem plausible—but to prevent the too-easy precocity of similar marriages. Under close living conditions, it must have become absolutely necessary. I should also note that when discussing the origins of new customs in general, we need to remember that primitive people, like us, have their "thinkers" and experts—wizards, doctors, prophets, etc.—whose knowledge and ideas are more advanced than those of the general population. United in their secret societies (another nearly universal trait), they can certainly wield a powerful influence and enforce customs whose benefits might not yet be acknowledged by most members of the tribe.

11. Col. Collins, in Philips' Researches in South Africa, London, 1828. Quoted by Waitz, ii. 334.

11. Col. Collins, in Philips' Researches in South Africa, London, 1828. Quoted by Waitz, ii. 334.

12. Lichtenstein's Reisen im sudlichen Afrika, ii. Pp. 92, 97. Berlin, 1811.

12. Lichtenstein's Travels in Southern Africa, ii. Pp. 92, 97. Berlin, 1811.

13. Waitz, Anthropologie der Naturvölker, ii. pp. 335 seq. See also
Fritsch's Die Eingeboren Süd-Afrika's, Breslau, 1872, pp. 386 seq.; and
Drei Jahre in Süd-Afrika. Also W. Bleck, A Brief Account of Bushmen
Folklore, Capetown, 1875.

13. Waitz, Anthropology of Indigenous Peoples, vol. ii, pp. 335 and following. See also
Fritsch's The Natives of South Africa, Breslau, 1872, pp. 386 and following; and
Three Years in South Africa. Also W. Bleck, A Brief Account of Bushmen
Folklore, Cape Town, 1875.

14. Elisee Reclus, Geographie Universelle, xiii. 475.

14. Elisee Reclus, Universal Geography, xiii. 475.

15. P. Kolben, The Present State of the Cape of Good Hope, translated from the German by Mr. Medley, London, 1731, vol. i. pp. 59, 71, 333, 336, etc.

15. P. Kolben, The Present State of the Cape of Good Hope, translated from the German by Mr. Medley, London, 1731, vol. i. pp. 59, 71, 333, 336, etc.

16. Quoted in Waitz's Anthropologie, ii. 335 seq.

16. Quoted in Waitz's Anthropology, ii. 335 seq.

17. The natives living in the north of Sidney, and speaking the Kamilaroi language, are best known under this aspect, through the capital work of Lorimer Fison and A.W. Howitt, Kamilaroi and Kurnaii, Melbourne, 1880. See also A.W. Howitt's "Further Note on the Australian Class Systems," in Journal of the Anthropological Institute, 1889, vol. xviii. p. 31, showing the wide extension of the same organization in Australia.

17. The Indigenous people living north of Sydney, who speak the Kamilaroi language, are primarily recognized for their culture in the significant work by Lorimer Fison and A.W. Howitt, *Kamilaroi and Kurnaii*, Melbourne, 1880. Also, see A.W. Howitt's "Further Note on the Australian Class Systems" in the Journal of the Anthropological Institute, 1889, vol. xviii, p. 31, which highlights the extensive reach of this social structure across Australia.

18. The Folklore, Manners, etc., of Australian Aborigines, Adelaide, 1879, p. 11.

18. The Folklore, Manners, etc., of Australian Aborigines, Adelaide, 1879, p. 11.

19. Grey's Journals of Two Expeditions of Discovery in North-West and Western Australia, London, 1841, vol. ii. pp. 237, 298.

19. Grey's Journals of Two Expeditions of Discovery in North-West and Western Australia, London, 1841, vol. ii. pp. 237, 298.

20. Bulletin de la Societe d'Anthropologie, 1888, vol. xi. p. 652. I abridge the answers.

20. Bulletin de la Société d'Anthropologie, 1888, vol. xi. p. 652. I summarize the responses.

21. Bulletin de la Societe d'Anthropologie, 1888, vol. xi. p. 386.

21. Bulletin of the Society of Anthropology, 1888, vol. xi. p. 386.

22. The same is the practice with the Papuas of Kaimani Bay, who have a high reputation of honesty. "It never happens that the Papua be untrue to his promise," Finsch says in Neuguinea und seine Bewohner, Bremen, 1865, p. 829.

22. The same is true for the Papuas of Kaimani Bay, who are highly regarded for their honesty. "It never happens that a Papua goes back on his promise," Finsch says in Neuguinea und seine Bewohner, Bremen, 1865, p. 829.

23. Izvestia of the Russian Geographical Society, 1880, pp. 161 seq. Few books of travel give a better insight into the petty details of the daily life of savages than these scraps from Maklay's notebooks.

23. Izvestia of the Russian Geographical Society, 1880, pp. 161 seq. Few travel books provide a better glimpse into the everyday lives of indigenous people than these excerpts from Maklay's notebooks.

24. L.F. Martial, in Mission Scientifique au Cap Horn, Paris, 1883, vol. i. pp. 183-201.

24. L.F. Martial, in Mission Scientifique au Cap Horn, Paris, 1883, vol. i. pp. 183-201.

25. Captain Holm's Expedition to East Greenland.

25. Captain Holm's Expedition to East Greenland.

26. In Australia whole clans have been seen exchanging all their wives, in order to conjure a calamity (Post, Studien zur Entwicklungsgeschichte des Familienrechts, 1890, p. 342). More brotherhood is their specific against calamities.

26. In Australia, entire clans have been observed swapping all their wives to counter a disaster (Post, Studien zur Entwicklungsgeschichte des Familienrechts, 1890, p. 342). Brotherhood serves as their primary defense against calamities.

27. Dr. H. Rink, The Eskimo Tribes, p. 26 (Meddelelser om Gronland, vol. xi. 1887).

27. Dr. H. Rink, The Eskimo Tribes, p. 26 (Meddelelser om Gronland, vol. xi. 1887).

28. Dr. Rink, loc. cit. p. 24. Europeans, grown in the respect of Roman law, are seldom capable of understanding that force of tribal authority. "In fact," Dr. Rink writes, "it is not the exception, but the rule, that white men who have stayed for ten or twenty years among the Eskimo, return without any real addition to their knowledge of the traditional ideas upon which their social state is based. The white man, whether a missionary or a trader, is firm in his dogmatic opinion that the most vulgar European is better than the most distinguished native."—The Eskimo Tribes, p. 31.

28. Dr. Rink, loc. cit. p. 24. Europeans, taught to respect Roman law, often struggle to grasp the strength of tribal authority. "In fact," Dr. Rink writes, "it's not the exception, but the norm, that white men who have spent ten or twenty years among the Eskimo return without significantly increasing their understanding of the traditional ideas that underpin their social structure. The white man, whether a missionary or a trader, firmly believes that even the most ordinary European is superior to the most esteemed native."—The Eskimo Tribes, p. 31.

29. Dall, Alaska and its Resources, Cambridge, U.S., 1870.

29. Dall, Alaska and its Resources, Cambridge, USA, 1870.

30. Dall saw it in Alaska, Jacobsen at Ignitok in the vicinity of the Bering Strait. Gilbert Sproat mentions it among the Vancouver indians; and Dr. Rink, who describes the periodical exhibitions just mentioned, adds: "The principal use of the accumulation of personal wealth is for periodically distributing it." He also mentions (loc. cit. p. 31) "the destruction of property for the same purpose," (of maintaining equality).

30. Dall saw it in Alaska, and Jacobsen saw it at Ignitok near the Bering Strait. Gilbert Sproat mentions it among the Vancouver Indians; and Dr. Rink, who describes the periodic exhibitions just mentioned, adds: "The main purpose of accumulating personal wealth is for periodically distributing it." He also mentions (loc. cit. p. 31) "the destruction of property for the same reason," (to maintain equality).

31. See Appendix VIII.

See Appendix VIII.

32. Veniaminoff, Memoirs relative to the District of Unalashka (Russian), 3 vols. St. Petersburg, 1840. Extracts, in English, from the above are given in Dall's Alaska. A like description of the Australians' morality is given in Nature, xlii. p. 639.

32. Veniaminoff, Memoirs about the Unalashka District (Russian), 3 vols. St. Petersburg, 1840. English excerpts from this work are included in Dall's Alaska. A similar description of Australian morality can be found in Nature, xlii. p. 639.

33. It is most remarkable that several writers (Middendorff, Schrenk, O. Finsch) described the Ostyaks and Samoyedes in almost the same words. Even when drunken, their quarrels are insignificant. "For a hundred years one single murder has been committed in the tundra;" "their children never fight;" "anything may be left for years in the tundra, even food and gin, and nobody will touch it;" and so on. Gilbert Sproat "never witnessed a fight between two sober natives" of the Aht Indians of Vancouver Island. "Quarrelling is also rare among their children." (Rink, loc. cit.) And so on.

33. It’s quite remarkable that several writers (Middendorff, Schrenk, O. Finsch) described the Ostyaks and Samoyedes in almost identical terms. Even when they’re drunk, their arguments are trivial. “In the tundra, only one murder has happened in a hundred years;” “their kids never fight;” “you can leave anything out in the tundra for years, even food and gin, and no one will touch it;” and so on. Gilbert Sproat "never saw a fight between two sober natives" of the Aht Indians on Vancouver Island. "Arguing is also rare among their kids." (Rink, loc. cit.) And so on.

34. Gill, quoted in Gerland and Waitz's Anthropologie, v. 641. See also pp. 636-640, where many facts of parental and filial love are quoted.

34. Gill, cited in Gerland and Waitz's Anthropologie, v. 641. Also refer to pp. 636-640, which contain numerous examples of parental and filial love.

35. Primitive Folk, London, 1891.

35. Primitive People, London, 1891.

36. Gerland, loc. cit. v. 636.

36. Gerland, loc. cit. v. 636.

37. Erskine, quoted in Gerland and Waitz's Anthropologie, v. 640.

37. Erskine, cited in Gerland and Waitz's Anthropology, vol. 640.

38. W.T. Pritchard, Polynesian Reminiscences, London, 1866, p. 363.

38. W.T. Pritchard, Polynesian Reminiscences, London, 1866, p. 363.

39. It is remarkable, however, that in case of a sentence of death, nobody will take upon himself to be the executioner. Every one throws his stone, or gives his blow with the hatchet, carefully avoiding to give a mortal blow. At a later epoch, the priest will stab the victim with a sacred knife. Still later, it will be the king, until civilization invents the hired hangman. See Bastian's deep remarks upon this subject in Der Mensch in der Geschichte, iii. Die Blutrache, pp. 1-36. A remainder of this tribal habit, I am told by Professor E. Nys, has survived in military executions till our own times. In the middle portion of the nineteenth century it was the habit to load the rifles of the twelve soldiers called out for shooting the condemned victim, with eleven ball-cartridges and one blank cartridge. As the soldiers never knew who of them had the latter, each one could console his disturbed conscience by thinking that he was not one of the murderers.

39. It's interesting, though, that when it comes to a death sentence, no one wants to be the one to carry it out. Everyone throws their stone or swings their axe, making sure not to deliver a fatal blow. Later on, a priest will stab the victim with a sacred knife. Eventually, it will be the king who does it, until society creates the hired executioner. Check out Bastian's insightful comments on this topic in Der Mensch in der Geschichte, iii. Die Blutrache, pp. 1-36. A trace of this tribal practice, as Professor E. Nys points out, has persisted in military executions even today. In the mid-19th century, it was common for the twelve soldiers assigned to shoot the condemned person to load their rifles with eleven live rounds and one blank. Since the soldiers didn’t know who had the blank, each one could ease their guilty conscience by believing they weren't part of the killing.

40. In Africa, and elsewhere too, it is a widely-spread habit, that if a theft has been committed, the next clan has to restore the equivalent of the stolen thing, and then look itself for the thief. A. H. Post, Afrikanische Jurisprudenz, Leipzig, 1887, vol. i. p. 77.

40. In Africa and other places, it's a common practice that when a theft occurs, the neighboring clan has to replace what was stolen and then try to find the thief themselves. A. H. Post, Afrikanische Jurisprudenz, Leipzig, 1887, vol. i. p. 77.

41. See Prof. M. Kovalevsky's Modern Customs and Ancient Law (Russian), Moscow, 1886, vol. ii., which contains many important considerations upon this subject.

41. Check out Prof. M. Kovalevsky's Modern Customs and Ancient Law (Russian), Moscow, 1886, vol. ii., which includes many important thoughts on this topic.

42. See Carl Bock, The Head Hunters of Borneo, London, 1881. I am told, however, by Sir Hugh Law, who was for a long time Governor of Borneo, that the "head-hunting" described in this book is grossly exaggerated. Altogether, my informant speaks of the Dayaks in exactly the same sympathetic terms as Ida Pfeiffer. Let me add that Mary Kingsley speaks in her book on West Africa in the same sympathetic terms of the Fans, who had been represented formerly as the most "terrible cannibals."

42. See Carl Bock, The Head Hunters of Borneo, London, 1881. However, Sir Hugh Law, who was the Governor of Borneo for a long time, tells me that the "head-hunting" described in this book is highly exaggerated. Overall, my informant speaks of the Dayaks in the same sympathetic way as Ida Pfeiffer. Additionally, Mary Kingsley mentions the Fans in her book about West Africa in a similarly sympathetic light, despite them previously being portrayed as the most "terrible cannibals."

43. Ida Pfeiffer, Meine zweite Weltriese, Wien, 1856, vol. i. pp. 116 seq. See also Muller and Temminch's Dutch Possessions in Archipelagic India, quoted by Elisee Reclus, in Geographie Universelle, xiii.

43. Ida Pfeiffer, My Second World Journey, Vienna, 1856, vol. i. pp. 116 seq. See also Müller and Temminck's Dutch Possessions in Archipelagic India, referenced by Élisée Reclus, in Universal Geography, xiii.

44. Descent of Man, second ed., pp. 63, 64.

44. Descent of Man, 2nd ed., pp. 63, 64.

45. See Bastian's Mensch in der Geschichte, iii. p. 7. Also Grey, loc. cit. ii. p. 238.

45. See Bastian's Man in History, iii. p. 7. Also Grey, loc. cit. ii. p. 238.

46. Miklukho-Maclay, loc. cit. Same habit with the Hottentots.

46. Miklukho-Maclay, loc. cit. The same behavior can be observed with the Hottentots.

CHAPTER IV

MUTUAL AID AMONG THE BARBARIANS

The great migrations. New organization rendered necessary. The village
community. Communal work. Judicial procedure. Inter-tribal law.
Illustrations from the life of our contemporaries. Buryates. Kabyles.
Caucasian mountaineers. African stems.

The major migrations. New organization became essential. The village
community. Collective work. Legal processes. Inter-tribal law.
Examples from the lives of people today. Buryats. Kabyles.
Caucasian mountain tribes. African groups.

It is not possible to study primitive mankind without being deeply impressed by the sociability it has displayed since its very first steps in life. Traces of human societies are found in the relics of both the oldest and the later stone age; and, when we come to observe the savages whose manners of life are still those of neolithic man, we find them closely bound together by an extremely ancient clan organization which enables them to combine their individually weak forces, to enjoy life in common, and to progress. Man is no exception in nature. He also is subject to the great principle of Mutual Aid which grants the best chances of survival to those who best support each other in the struggle for life. These were the conclusions arrived at in the previous chapters.

It’s impossible to study early humans without being really struck by their sociability from the very beginning of their existence. Evidence of human societies can be found in artifacts from both the oldest and newer Stone Age. When we look at the tribes whose ways of life still mirror that of Neolithic people, we see that they are tightly connected through an ancient clan system that helps them combine their individually weak strengths, enjoy life together, and grow. Humans aren’t different from other species in nature. They are also governed by the important principle of Mutual Aid, which gives the best chances of survival to those who support each other most effectively in the struggle for existence. These were the conclusions reached in the previous chapters.

However, as soon as we come to a higher stage of civilization, and refer to history which already has something to say about that stage, we are bewildered by the struggles and conflicts which it reveals. The old bonds seem entirely to be broken. Stems are seen to fight against stems, tribes against tribes, individuals against individuals; and out of this chaotic contest of hostile forces, mankind issues divided into castes, enslaved to despots, separated into States always ready to wage war against each other. And, with this history of mankind in his hands, the pessimist philosopher triumphantly concludes that warfare and oppression are the very essence of human nature; that the warlike and predatory instincts of man can only be restrained within certain limits by a strong authority which enforces peace and thus gives an opportunity to the few and nobler ones to prepare a better life for humanity in times to come.

However, when we reach a more advanced stage of civilization and look at the history that has something to say about that period, we become confused by the struggles and conflicts it reveals. The old ties seem completely broken. Different groups fight against each other, tribes clash with tribes, and individuals battle other individuals; and from this chaotic contest of opposing forces, humanity emerges divided into classes, subjugated by tyrants, and split into nations that are always ready to go to war with one another. With this history of humanity in hand, the pessimistic philosopher concludes that war and oppression are fundamental aspects of human nature; that the aggressive and predatory instincts of humans can only be kept in check by a strong authority that enforces peace and provides the opportunity for a few noble individuals to prepare a better future for humanity.

And yet, as soon as the every-day life of man during the historical period is submitted to a closer analysis and so it has been, of late, by many patient students of very early institutions—it appears at once under quite a different aspect. Leaving aside the preconceived ideas of most historians and their pronounced predilection for the dramatic aspects of history, we see that the very documents they habitually peruse are such as to exaggerate the part of human life given to struggles and to underrate its peaceful moods. The bright and sunny days are lost sight of in the gales and storms. Even in our own time, the cumbersome records which we prepare for the future historian, in our Press, our law courts, our Government offices, and even in our fiction and poetry, suffer from the same one-sidedness. They hand down to posterity the most minute descriptions of every war, every battle and skirmish, every contest and act of violence, every kind of individual suffering; but they hardly bear any trace of the countless acts of mutual support and devotion which every one of us knows from his own experience; they hardly take notice of what makes the very essence of our daily life—our social instincts and manners. No wonder, then, if the records of the past were so imperfect. The annalists of old never failed to chronicle the petty wars and calamities which harassed their contemporaries; but they paid no attention whatever to the life of the masses, although the masses chiefly used to toil peacefully while the few indulged in fighting. The epic poems, the inscriptions on monuments, the treaties of peace—nearly all historical documents bear the same character; they deal with breaches of peace, not with peace itself. So that the best-intentioned historian unconsciously draws a distorted picture of the times he endeavours to depict; and, to restore the real proportion between conflict and union, we are now bound to enter into a minute analysis of thousands of small facts and faint indications accidentally preserved in the relics of the past; to interpret them with the aid of comparative ethnology; and, after having heard so much about what used to divide men, to reconstruct stone by stone the institutions which used to unite them.

And yet, when we take a closer look at everyday life throughout history—something that many dedicated scholars of ancient societies have been doing recently—we see a whole different picture. Ignoring the preconceived notions of most historians and their clear preference for the dramatic side of history, we find that the very documents they often examine tend to exaggerate the struggles of human life and downplay its peaceful moments. The bright and sunny days are overshadowed by the storms and gales. Even in our own time, the detailed records we prepare for future historians—through our media, courts, government offices, and even in our fiction and poetry—suffer from the same bias. They preserve meticulous accounts of every war, battle, and skirmish, every conflict and act of violence, every form of individual suffering; but they barely acknowledge the countless acts of mutual support and devotion that we all experience. They hardly reflect what truly forms the essence of our daily lives—our social instincts and interactions. It's no surprise, then, that records of the past are so incomplete. Chroniclers of old always recorded the small wars and disasters that affected their contemporaries, but they paid little attention to the lives of the masses, who mostly toiled in peace while a few engaged in combat. Epic poems, inscriptions on monuments, treaties of peace—almost all historical documents share this characteristic; they focus on disruptions of peace, not peace itself. Consequently, the most well-meaning historian unintentionally creates a warped image of the times they strive to represent; to restore a true balance between conflict and unity, we now have to carefully analyze thousands of small details and subtle signs preserved in the remnants of the past, interpret them using comparative ethnology, and after hearing so much about what divided people, start reconstructing step by step the institutions that once brought them together.

Ere long history will have to be re-written on new lines, so as to take into account these two currents of human life and to appreciate the part played by each of them in evolution. But in the meantime we may avail ourselves of the immense preparatory work recently done towards restoring the leading features of the second current, so much neglected. From the better-known periods of history we may take some illustrations of the life of the masses, in order to indicate the part played by mutual support during those periods; and, in so doing, we may dispense (for the sake of brevity) from going as far back as the Egyptian, or even the Greek and Roman antiquity. For, in fact, the evolution of mankind has not had the character of one unbroken series. Several times civilization came to an end in one given region, with one given race, and began anew elsewhere, among other races. But at each fresh start it began again with the same clan institutions which we have seen among the savages. So that if we take the last start of our own civilization, when it began afresh in the first centuries of our era, among those whom the Romans called the "barbarians," we shall have the whole scale of evolution, beginning with the gentes and ending in the institutions of our own time. To these illustrations the following pages will be devoted.

Soon, history will need to be rewritten along new lines to account for these two currents of human life and to recognize the role each has played in evolution. In the meantime, we can take advantage of the significant groundwork recently done to restore the key features of the second current, which has been largely overlooked. From the better-documented periods of history, we can draw examples of the lives of the masses to highlight the role of mutual support during those times; thus, we can skip going all the way back to Egyptian or even Greek and Roman antiquity for the sake of brevity. In reality, the evolution of humanity has not been a continuous process. Civilization has repeatedly collapsed in certain regions with specific races and restarted elsewhere among different races. However, at each new beginning, it was rooted in the same tribal institutions we observe among primitive societies. Therefore, if we examine the latest restart of our civilization, which began in the early centuries of our era among those the Romans referred to as "barbarians," we will see the entire spectrum of evolution, starting with clans and culminating in the institutions we have today. The following pages will be dedicated to these examples.

Men of science have not yet settled upon the causes which some two thousand years ago drove whole nations from Asia into Europe and resulted in the great migrations of barbarians which put an end to the West Roman Empire. One cause, however, is naturally suggested to the geographer as he contemplates the ruins of populous cities in the deserts of Central Asia, or follows the old beds of rivers now disappeared and the wide outlines of lakes now reduced to the size of mere ponds. It is desiccation: a quite recent desiccation, continued still at a speed which we formerly were not prepared to admit.(1) Against it man was powerless. When the inhabitants of North-West Mongolia and East Turkestan saw that water was abandoning them, they had no course open to them but to move down the broad valleys leading to the lowlands, and to thrust westwards the inhabitants of the plains.(2) Stems after stems were thus thrown into Europe, compelling other stems to move and to remove for centuries in succession, westwards and eastwards, in search of new and more or less permanent abodes. Races were mixing with races during those migrations, aborigines with immigrants, Aryans with Ural-Altayans; and it would have been no wonder if the social institutions which had kept them together in their mother countries had been totally wrecked during the stratification of races which took place in Europe and Asia. But they were not wrecked; they simply underwent the modification which was required by the new conditions of life.

Men of science still haven't agreed on the reasons that drove entire nations from Asia into Europe around two thousand years ago, leading to the massive migrations of barbarians that ended the Western Roman Empire. One obvious reason comes to mind for geographers as they look at the ruins of once-thriving cities in the Central Asian deserts or trace the old riverbeds that have vanished and the large outlines of lakes now shrunk to mere ponds. It's desiccation: a relatively recent drying out that's still happening at a pace we didn't used to recognize. Against it, humans were powerless. When the people of North-West Mongolia and East Turkestan realized that water was leaving them, their only option was to move down the wide valleys toward the lowlands and push westward against the plains' inhabitants. This led to waves of migration into Europe, forcing various groups to relocate for centuries, both west and east, in search of new, more stable homes. During these migrations, different races mixed together—indigenous people with newcomers, Aryans with Ural-Altayans—and it wouldn't have been surprising if the social systems that held them together in their homeland broke down during the mixing of races in Europe and Asia. But they didn't break down; they simply adapted to the new conditions of life.

The Teutons, the Celts, the Scandinavians, the Slavonians, and others, when they first came in contact with the Romans, were in a transitional state of social organization. The clan unions, based upon a real or supposed common origin, had kept them together for many thousands of years in succession. But these unions could answer their purpose so long only as there were no separate families within the gens or clan itself. However, for causes already mentioned, the separate patriarchal family had slowly but steadily developed within the clans, and in the long run it evidently meant the individual accumulation of wealth and power, and the hereditary transmission of both. The frequent migrations of the barbarians and the ensuing wars only hastened the division of the gentes into separate families, while the dispersing of stems and their mingling with strangers offered singular facilities for the ultimate disintegration of those unions which were based upon kinship. The barbarians thus stood in a position of either seeing their clans dissolved into loose aggregations of families, of which the wealthiest, especially if combining sacerdotal functions or military repute with wealth, would have succeeded in imposing their authority upon the others; or of finding out some new form of organization based upon some new principle.

The Teutons, the Celts, the Scandinavians, the Slavs, and others, when they first encountered the Romans, were in a changing phase of social organization. Clan unions, based on a real or assumed common origin, had kept them together for thousands of years. However, these unions could only serve their purpose as long as there were no separate families within the clan itself. Yet, for reasons already discussed, the separate patriarchal family had slowly but surely developed within the clans, ultimately leading to individual wealth and power accumulation and the hereditary passage of both. The frequent migrations of the barbarians and the wars that followed only sped up the division of the clans into distinct families. The scattering of groups and their intermingling with outsiders provided unique opportunities for the eventual breakdown of those unions based on kinship. The barbarians thus faced either the dissolution of their clans into loose collections of families, where the wealthiest—especially those with priestly roles or military prestige—could impose their authority over others, or the need to discover a new form of organization based on a different principle.

Many stems had no force to resist disintegration: they broke up and were lost for history. But the more vigorous ones did not disintegrate. They came out of the ordeal with a new organization—the village community—which kept them together for the next fifteen centuries or more. The conception of a common territory, appropriated or protected by common efforts, was elaborated, and it took the place of the vanishing conceptions of common descent. The common gods gradually lost their character of ancestors and were endowed with a local territorial character. They became the gods or saints of a given locality; "the land" was identified with its inhabitants. Territorial unions grew up instead of the consanguine unions of old, and this new organization evidently offered many advantages under the given circumstances. It recognized the independence of the family and even emphasized it, the village community disclaiming all rights of interference in what was going on within the family enclosure; it gave much more freedom to personal initiative; it was not hostile in principle to union between men of different descent, and it maintained at the same time the necessary cohesion of action and thought, while it was strong enough to oppose the dominative tendencies of the minorities of wizards, priests, and professional or distinguished warriors. Consequently it became the primary cell of future organization, and with many nations the village community has retained this character until now.

Many groups struggled to hold themselves together and fell apart, disappearing from history. However, the stronger ones survived the challenges and formed a new structure—the village community—that kept them united for the next fifteen centuries or more. They developed the idea of a shared territory, maintained through collective efforts, which replaced the fading notion of shared ancestry. The shared deities gradually transformed from ancestral figures to local gods or saints, and "the land" became synonymous with its people. Territorial alliances emerged instead of the old blood ties, and this new structure offered many benefits under the circumstances. It acknowledged the independence of families, even promoting it, as the village community had no say in family matters; it allowed for greater personal freedom; it was not fundamentally opposed to unions between people of different backgrounds, and it maintained necessary cohesion in action and thought. At the same time, it was strong enough to resist the dominating tendencies of minorities such as wizards, priests, and distinguished warriors. As a result, it became the fundamental unit of future organization, and the village community has kept this role in many cultures up to the present day.

It is now known, and scarcely contested, that the village community was not a specific feature of the Slavonians, nor even of the ancient Teutons. It prevailed in England during both the Saxon and Norman times, and partially survived till the last century;(3) it was at the bottom of the social organization of old Scotland, old Ireland, and old Wales. In France, the communal possession and the communal allotment of arable land by the village folkmote persisted from the first centuries of our era till the times of Turgot, who found the folkmotes "too noisy" and therefore abolished them. It survived Roman rule in Italy, and revived after the fall of the Roman Empire. It was the rule with the Scandinavians, the Slavonians, the Finns (in the pittaya, as also, probably, the kihla-kunta), the Coures, and the lives. The village community in India—past and present, Aryan and non-Aryan—is well known through the epoch-making works of Sir Henry Maine; and Elphinstone has described it among the Afghans. We also find it in the Mongolian oulous, the Kabyle thaddart, the Javanese dessa, the Malayan kota or tofa, and under a variety of names in Abyssinia, the Soudan, in the interior of Africa, with natives of both Americas, with all the small and large tribes of the Pacific archipelagoes. In short, we do not know one single human race or one single nation which has not had its period of village communities. This fact alone disposes of the theory according to which the village community in Europe would have been a servile growth. It is anterior to serfdom, and even servile submission was powerless to break it. It was a universal phase of evolution, a natural outcome of the clan organization, with all those stems, at least, which have played, or play still, some part in history.(4)

It is now widely accepted, and hardly disputed, that the village community was not unique to the Slavs or even to the ancient Germans. It existed in England during both Saxon and Norman periods, and partially lasted until the last century; it was foundational to the social structure of ancient Scotland, Ireland, and Wales. In France, the shared ownership and communal distribution of farmland by the village assembly continued from the early centuries AD until the time of Turgot, who deemed the assemblies "too noisy" and abolished them. It survived Roman control in Italy and reemerged after the fall of the Roman Empire. It was the norm among the Scandinavians, Slavs, Finns (in the pittaya, and likely the kihla-kunta), the Coures, and the lives. The village community in India—both past and present, Aryan and non-Aryan—is well documented in the groundbreaking works of Sir Henry Maine; Elphinstone also noted it among the Afghans. We also see it in the Mongolian oulous, the Kabyle thaddart, the Javanese dessas, the Malayan kota or tofa, and under various names in Abyssinia, the Sudan, the interior of Africa, among Indigenous peoples of both Americas, and with many small and large tribes of the Pacific islands. In short, there is no known human race or nation that hasn't experienced a period of village communities. This fact alone contradicts the theory that the village community in Europe arose as a servile development. It predates serfdom, and even serfdom's constraints could not dismantle it. It was a universal stage of development, a natural result of clan organization, at least among those groups that have played, or still play, a role in history.

It was a natural growth, and an absolute uniformity in its structure was therefore not possible. As a rule, it was a union between families considered as of common descent and owning a certain territory in common. But with some stems, and under certain circumstances, the families used to grow very numerous before they threw off new buds in the shape of new families; five, six, or seven generations continued to live under the same roof, or within the same enclosure, owning their joint household and cattle in common, and taking their meals at the common hearth. They kept in such case to what ethnology knows as the "joint family," or the "undivided household," which we still see all over China, in India, in the South Slavonian zadruga, and occasionally find in Africa, in America, in Denmark, in North Russia, and West France.(5) With other stems, or in other circumstances, not yet well specified, the families did not attain the same proportions; the grandsons, and occasionally the sons, left the household as soon as they were married, and each of them started a new cell of his own. But, joint or not, clustered together or scattered in the woods, the families remained united into village communities; several villages were grouped into tribes; and the tribes joined into confederations. Such was the social organization which developed among the so-called "barbarians," when they began to settle more or less permanently in Europe.

It was a natural development, and complete uniformity in its structure wasn't possible. Generally, it was a union of families considered to have a common ancestry and sharing a specific territory. However, with some lineages and under certain conditions, families could grow quite large before forming new branches as new families; five, six, or seven generations often lived under the same roof or within the same enclosure, sharing their household and livestock in common, and eating together at the communal hearth. In such cases, they adhered to what ethnology refers to as the "joint family" or the "undivided household," which we still observe throughout China, India, the South Slavonian zadruga, and occasionally in Africa, America, Denmark, North Russia, and West France. In contrast, with other lineages or under different circumstances, which are not yet well defined, families did not grow to the same size; grandsons, and sometimes sons, would leave the household as soon as they got married, each starting their own new family unit. Regardless of whether they were joint or separate, clustered together or spaced apart in the woods, families remained united in village communities; several villages formed tribes, and the tribes came together in confederations. This was the social organization that emerged among the so-called "barbarians" as they began to settle more or less permanently in Europe.

A very long evolution was required before the gentes, or clans, recognized the separate existence of a patriarchal family in a separate hut; but even after that had been recognized, the clan, as a rule, knew no personal inheritance of property. The few things which might have belonged personally to the individual were either destroyed on his grave or buried with him. The village community, on the contrary, fully recognized the private accumulation of wealth within the family and its hereditary transmission. But wealth was conceived exclusively in the shape of movable property, including cattle, implements, arms, and the dwelling house which—"like all things that can be destroyed by fire"—belonged to the same category(6). As to private property in land, the village community did not, and could not, recognize anything of the kind, and, as a rule, it does not recognize it now. The land was the common property of the tribe, or of the whole stem, and the village community itself owned its part of the tribal territory so long only as the tribe did not claim a re-distribution of the village allotments. The clearing of the woods and the breaking of the prairies being mostly done by the communities or, at least, by the joint work of several families—always with the consent of the community—the cleared plots were held by each family for a term of four, twelve, or twenty years, after which term they were treated as parts of the arable land owned in common. Private property, or possession "for ever" was as incompatible, with the very principles and the religious conceptions of the village community as it was with the principles of the gens; so that a long influence of the Roman law and the Christian Church, which soon accepted the Roman principles, were required to accustom the barbarians to the idea of private property in land being possible.(7) And yet, even when such property, or possession for an unlimited time, was recognized, the owner of a separate estate remained a co-proprietor in the waste lands, forests, and grazing-grounds. Moreover, we continually see, especially in the history of Russia, that when a few families, acting separately, had taken possession of some land belonging to tribes which were treated as strangers, they very soon united together, and constituted a village community which in the third or fourth generation began to profess a community of origin.

A long evolution was needed before the clans recognized the existence of a patriarchal family living in a separate hut. Even after that recognition, the clan generally didn’t accept personal inheritance of property. Any items that might belong to an individual were either destroyed at their grave or buried with them. In contrast, the village community fully acknowledged the private accumulation of wealth within a family and its hereditary transmission. However, wealth was viewed only in terms of movable property, including cattle, tools, weapons, and homes, which—"like all things that can be destroyed by fire"—were in the same category(6). As for private property in land, the village community did not recognize it, nor could it, and usually still does not. The land was considered common property of the tribe or the entire group. The village community owned its part of the tribal territory only as long as the tribe didn't demand a re-distribution of the village plots. Clearing the woods and breaking the prairies was mostly done by communities, or at least by the collective effort of several families—with the community's consent—where cleared plots were held by each family for a period of four, twelve, or twenty years, after which they were seen as part of the arable land owned in common. Private property, or possession "forever," was as incompatible with the principles and religious beliefs of the village community as it was with the principles of the clan; it took a long influence of Roman law and the Christian Church, which soon adopted Roman principles, to prepare the barbarians for the idea that private ownership of land was possible.(7) Yet, even when such property or unlimited possession was acknowledged, the owner of a separate estate remained a co-owner of the waste lands, forests, and grazing lands. Furthermore, we often see, particularly in Russian history, that when a few families acted individually to claim land belonging to tribes seen as outsiders, they quickly came together to form a village community, which in the third or fourth generation began to express a shared origin.

A whole series of institutions, partly inherited from the clan period, have developed from that basis of common ownership of land during the long succession of centuries which was required to bring the barbarians under the dominion of States organized upon the Roman or Byzantine pattern. The village community was not only a union for guaranteeing to each one his fair share in the common land, but also a union for common culture, for mutual support in all possible forms, for protection from violence, and for a further development of knowledge, national bonds, and moral conceptions; and every change in the judicial, military, educational, or economical manners had to be decided at the folkmotes of the village, the tribe, or the confederation. The community being a continuation of the gens, it inherited all its functions. It was the universitas, the mir—a world in itself.

A whole series of institutions, partly inherited from the clan period, have developed from the shared ownership of land over many centuries, which was necessary to bring the barbarians under the control of States organized like the Roman or Byzantine empires. The village community was not just a way to ensure everyone got their fair share of the common land, but also a way to support each other culturally, help one another in all possible ways, protect against violence, and further develop knowledge, national ties, and moral values. Every change in legal, military, educational, or economic practices had to be decided at the village, tribe, or confederation meetings. Since the community was a continuation of the gens, it inherited all its functions. It was the universitas, the mir—a world unto itself.

Common hunting, common fishing, and common culture of the orchards or the plantations of fruit trees was the rule with the old gentes. Common agriculture became the rule in the barbarian village communities. True, that direct testimony to this effect is scarce, and in the literature of antiquity we only have the passages of Diodorus and Julius Caesar relating to the inhabitants of the Lipari Islands, one of the Celt-Iberian tribes, and the Sueves. But there is no lack of evidence to prove that common agriculture was practised among some Teuton tribes, the Franks, and the old Scotch, Irish, and Welsh.(8) As to the later survivals of the same practice, they simply are countless. Even in perfectly Romanized France, common culture was habitual some five and twenty years ago in the Morbihan (Brittany).(9) The old Welsh cyvar, or joint team, as well as the common culture of the land allotted to the use of the village sanctuary are quite common among the tribes of Caucasus the least touched by civilization,(10) and like facts are of daily occurrence among the Russian peasants. Moreover, it is well known that many tribes of Brazil, Central America, and Mexico used to cultivate their fields in common, and that the same habit is widely spread among some Malayans, in New Caledonia, with several Negro stems, and so on.(11) In short, communal culture is so habitual with many Aryan, Ural-Altayan, Mongolian, Negro, Red Indian, Malayan, and Melanesian stems that we must consider it as a universal—though not as the only possible—form of primitive agriculture.(12)

Common hunting, fishing, and shared culture of orchards or fruit tree plantations were typical for the old tribes. Shared farming became the norm in barbarian village communities. True, direct evidence of this is limited, and in ancient literature, we only have references from Diodorus and Julius Caesar about the people of the Lipari Islands, one of the Celt-Iberian tribes, and the Sueves. However, there is ample evidence showing that shared farming was practiced among some Teutonic tribes, the Franks, and the ancient Scots, Irish, and Welsh. As for more recent examples of this practice, they are countless. Even in fully Romanized France, shared farming was common around twenty-five years ago in Morbihan (Brittany). The old Welsh cyvar, or joint team, along with the shared farming of land reserved for the village sanctuary, are also prevalent among the least civilized tribes in the Caucasus, and such practices occur daily among Russian peasants. Furthermore, it’s well-known that many tribes in Brazil, Central America, and Mexico used to farm their fields collectively, and this practice is widespread among some Malays, in New Caledonia, and several African tribes, among others. In short, communal farming is so common among many Aryan, Ural-Altayan, Mongolian, Black, Native American, Malayan, and Melanesian groups that we must view it as a universal—though not the only possible—form of primitive agriculture.

Communal cultivation does not, however, imply by necessity communal consumption. Already under the clan organization we often see that when the boats laden with fruits or fish return to the village, the food they bring in is divided among the huts and the "long houses" inhabited by either several families or the youth, and is cooked separately at each separate hearth. The habit of taking meals in a narrower circle of relatives or associates thus prevails at an early period of clan life. It became the rule in the village community. Even the food grown in common was usually divided between the households after part of it had been laid in store for communal use. However, the tradition of communal meals was piously kept alive; every available opportunity, such as the commemoration of the ancestors, the religious festivals, the beginning and the end of field work, the births, the marriages, and the funerals, being seized upon to bring the community to a common meal. Even now this habit, well known in this country as the "harvest supper," is the last to disappear. On the other hand, even when the fields had long since ceased to be tilled and sown in common, a variety of agricultural work continued, and continues still, to be performed by the community. Some part of the communal land is still cultivated in many cases in common, either for the use of the destitute, or for refilling the communal stores, or for using the produce at the religious festivals. The irrigation canals are digged and repaired in common. The communal meadows are mown by the community; and the sight of a Russian commune mowing a meadow—the men rivalling each other in their advance with the scythe, while the women turn the grass over and throw it up into heaps—is one of the most inspiring sights; it shows what human work might be and ought to be. The hay, in such case, is divided among the separate households, and it is evident that no one has the right of taking hay from a neighbour's stack without his permission; but the limitation of this last rule among the Caucasian Ossetes is most noteworthy. When the cuckoo cries and announces that spring is coming, and that the meadows will soon be clothed again with grass, every one in need has the right of taking from a neighbour's stack the hay he wants for his cattle.(13) The old communal rights are thus re-asserted, as if to prove how contrary unbridled individualism is to human nature.

Communal farming doesn’t necessarily mean communal eating. Even in clan structures, we often see that when boats filled with fruits or fish come back to the village, the food they bring is shared among the huts and "long houses" where several families or young people live, and everyone cooks separately at their own fire. The habit of having meals with a smaller group of relatives or friends starts early in clan life. This became the norm in village communities. Even food grown collectively is usually divided between households after some is set aside for communal use. However, the tradition of communal meals is still preserved; every chance to gather, like ancestor commemorations, religious festivals, the start and end of farming seasons, births, weddings, and funerals, is used to bring the community together for a meal. Even today, this practice, known as the "harvest supper," is one of the last traditions to fade away. On the other hand, even after fields have long stopped being farmed collectively, a range of agricultural tasks continues to be done by the community. In many cases, some communal land is still cultivated together, either to support the needy, replenish communal supplies, or provide produce for religious festivals. Irrigation canals are dug and maintained collectively. The community mows the communal meadows, and witnessing a Russian commune mowing a meadow—men competing with their scythes while women turn the grass and pile it—presents one of the most uplifting sights. It showcases what human labor can and should be. The hay is divided among the individual households, and it’s clear that no one has the right to take hay from a neighbor's stack without permission. However, the restriction of this rule among the Caucasian Ossetes is particularly noteworthy. When the cuckoo calls and signals the arrival of spring, and the meadows are about to be covered in grass again, anyone in need can take hay from a neighbor's stack for their cattle. The old communal rights are thus reaffirmed, highlighting how unrestrained individualism goes against human nature.

When the European traveller lands in some small island of the Pacific, and, seeing at a distance a grove of palm trees, walks in that direction, he is astonished to discover that the little villages are connected by roads paved with big stones, quite comfortable for the unshod natives, and very similar to the "old roads" of the Swiss mountains. Such roads were traced by the "barbarians" all over Europe, and one must have travelled in wild, thinly-peopled countries, far away from the chief lines of communication, to realize in full the immense work that must have been performed by the barbarian communities in order to conquer the woody and marshy wilderness which Europe was some two thousand years ago. Isolated families, having no tools, and weak as they were, could not have conquered it; the wilderness would have overpowered them. Village communities alone, working in common, could master the wild forests, the sinking marshes, and the endless steppes. The rough roads, the ferries, the wooden bridges taken away in the winter and rebuilt after the spring flood was over, the fences and the palisaded walls of the villages, the earthen forts and the small towers with which the territory was dottedall these were the work of the barbarian communities. And when a community grew numerous it used to throw off a new bud. A new community arose at a distance, thus step by step bringing the woods and the steppes under the dominion of man. The whole making of European nations was such a budding of the village communities. Even now-a-days the Russian peasants, if they are not quite broken down by misery, migrate in communities, and they till the soil and build the houses in com mon when they settle on the banks of the Amur, or in Manitoba. And even the English, when they first began to colonize America, used to return to the old system; they grouped into village communities.(14)

When a European traveler arrives on a small Pacific island and notices a grove of palm trees in the distance, walking towards it, they are surprised to find that the tiny villages are connected by roads made of large stones, which are quite comfortable for the barefoot locals and resemble the "old roads" of the Swiss mountains. These roads were built by the "barbarians" all over Europe, and one needs to have traveled through wild, sparsely populated areas, far from the main routes, to fully appreciate the tremendous work done by these barbarian communities to tame the dense forests and marshy lands that Europe was around two thousand years ago. Isolated families, without tools and facing weakness, wouldn’t have been able to conquer it; the wilderness would have overwhelmed them. Only village communities, working together, could conquer the wild woods, the sinking marshes, and the vast steppes. The rough roads, ferries, wooden bridges that were removed in winter and rebuilt after spring flooding, the fences, and the palisaded village walls, earthen forts, and small towers scattered throughout the territory—all these were the achievements of barbarian communities. When a community grew in size, it would branch out, leading to the formation of a new community at a distance, thus gradually bringing the forests and steppes under human control. The entire formation of European nations was akin to this budding of village communities. Even today, Russian peasants, if they haven’t been completely broken by hardship, migrate in groups, farming and building homes together when they settle along the banks of the Amur or in Manitoba. Even the English, when they first began to colonize America, reverted to this old system, forming village communities.

The village community was the chief arm of the barbarians in their hard struggle against a hostile nature. It also was the bond they opposed to oppression by the cunningest and the strongest which so easily might have developed during those disturbed times. The imaginary barbarian—the man who fights and kills at his mere caprice—existed no more than the "bloodthirsty" savage. The real barbarian was living, on the contrary, under a wide series of institutions, imbued with considerations as to what may be useful or noxious to his tribe or confederation, and these institutions were piously handed down from generation to generation in verses and songs, in proverbs or triads, in sentences and instructions. The more we study them the more we recognize the narrow bonds which united men in their villages. Every quarrel arising between two individuals was treated as a communal affair—even the offensive words that might have been uttered during a quarrel being considered as an offence to the community and its ancestors. They had to be repaired by amends made both to the individual and the community;(15) and if a quarrel ended in a fight and wounds, the man who stood by and did not interpose was treated as if he himself had inflicted the wounds.(16) The judicial procedure was imbued with the same spirit. Every dispute was brought first before mediators or arbiters, and it mostly ended with them, the arbiters playing a very important part in barbarian society. But if the case was too grave to be settled in this way, it came before the folkmote, which was bound "to find the sentence," and pronounced it in a conditional form; that is, "such compensation was due, if the wrong be proved," and the wrong had to be proved or disclaimed by six or twelve persons confirming or denying the fact by oath; ordeal being resorted to in case of contradiction between the two sets of jurors. Such procedure, which remained in force for more than two thousand years in succession, speaks volumes for itself; it shows how close were the bonds between all members of the community. Moreover, there was no other authority to enforce the decisions of the folkmote besides its own moral authority. The only possible menace was that the community might declare the rebel an outlaw, but even this menace was reciprocal. A man discontented with the folkmote could declare that he would abandon the tribe and go over to another tribe—a most dreadful menace, as it was sure to bring all kinds of misfortunes upon a tribe that might have been unfair to one of its members.(17) A rebellion against a right decision of the customary law was simply "inconceivable," as Henry Maine has so well said, because "law, morality, and fact" could not be separated from each other in those times.(18) The moral authority of the commune was so great that even at a much later epoch, when the village communities fell into submission to the feudal lord, they maintained their judicial powers; they only permitted the lord, or his deputy, to "find" the above conditional sentence in accordance with the customary law he had sworn to follow, and to levy for himself the fine (the fred) due to the commune. But for a long time, the lord himself, if he remained a co-proprietor in the waste land of the commune, submitted in communal affairs to its decisions. Noble or ecclesiastic, he had to submit to the folkmote—Wer daselbst Wasser und Weid genusst, muss gehorsam sein—"Who enjoys here the right of water and pasture must obey"—was the old saying. Even when the peasants became serfs under the lord, he was bound to appear before the folkmote when they summoned him.(19)

The village community was the main support for the barbarians in their tough fight against a hostile environment. It was also the bond they created to resist oppression from the cleverest and strongest individuals during those turbulent times. The fictional barbarian—the person who fights and kills purely on a whim—was no more real than the "bloodthirsty" savage. In reality, the barbarian lived under a broad range of institutions, guided by considerations of what could be beneficial or harmful to his tribe or confederation, and these institutions were carefully passed down through generations in verses and songs, proverbs or triads, and various teachings. The more we study them, the more we see the close ties that connected people in their villages. Any disagreement between two individuals was treated as a community issue—even the offensive remarks made during a dispute were seen as an offense to the community and its ancestors. They had to make amends both to the individual and to the community; and if a dispute escalated into a fight and resulted in injuries, a bystander who did not intervene was considered as culpable as the one causing the injuries. The judicial process was imbued with the same sentiment. Every dispute was initially brought before mediators or arbiters, and these matters usually concluded there, with arbiters playing a crucial role in barbarian society. However, if the issue was too serious to resolve this way, it went before the folkmote, which was responsible for “finding the sentence” and pronouncing it conditionally; that is, “compensation was owed if the wrongdoing is proven,” and proof of wrongdoing had to be established or denied by six or twelve people who would confirm or deny the fact with an oath, with an ordeal used in cases of conflicting testimony from the two groups of jurors. This system, which remained in place for over two thousand years, speaks volumes; it illustrates the strong connections among all members of the community. Furthermore, there was no other authority to enforce the decisions of the folkmote apart from its own moral authority. The only potential threat was that the community might declare the rebel an outlaw, but even this threat was mutual. A person unhappy with the folkmote could declare their intention to leave the tribe and join another—a most serious threat, as it was sure to bring all sorts of misfortunes on a tribe that had treated one of its members unfairly. A rebellion against a just decision of customary law was simply "inconceivable," as Henry Maine aptly stated, because "law, morality, and fact" could not be separated from one another in those times. The moral authority of the community was so strong that even later, when the village communities fell under the control of feudal lords, they retained their judicial powers; they only allowed the lord, or his representative, to issue the aforementioned conditional sentence according to the customary law he had sworn to uphold and to collect the fine (the fred) owed to the community. For a long time, the lord himself, if he remained a co-owner of the common land, complied with the decisions of the community in communal matters. Noble or ecclesiastic, he had to submit to the folkmote—Wer daselbst Wasser und Weid genusst, muss gehorsam sein—"Who enjoys here the right of water and pasture must obey"—was the old saying. Even when the peasants became serfs under the lord, he was required to appear before the folkmote when summoned.

In their conceptions of justice the barbarians evidently did not much differ from the savages. They also maintained the idea that a murder must be followed by putting the murderer to death; that wounds had to be punished by equal wounds, and that the wronged family was bound to fulfil the sentence of the customary law. This was a holy duty, a duty towards the ancestors, which had to be accomplished in broad daylight, never in secrecy, and rendered widely known. Therefore the most inspired passages of the sagas and epic poetry altogether are those which glorify what was supposed to be justice. The gods themselves joined in aiding it. However, the predominant feature of barbarian justice is, on the one hand, to limit the numbers of persons who may be involved in a feud, and, on the other hand, to extirpate the brutal idea of blood for blood and wounds for wounds, by substituting for it the system of compensation. The barbarian codes which were collections of common law rules written down for the use of judges—"first permitted, then encouraged, and at last enforced," compensation instead of revenge.(20) The compensation has, however, been totally misunderstood by those who represented it as a fine, and as a sort of carte blanche given to the rich man to do whatever he liked. The compensation money (wergeld), which was quite different from the fine or fred,(21) was habitually so high for all kinds of active offences that it certainly was no encouragement for such offences. In case of a murder it usually exceeded all the possible fortune of the murderer "Eighteen times eighteen cows" is the compensation with the Ossetes who do not know how to reckon above eighteen, while with the African tribes it attains 800 cows or 100 camels with their young, or 416 sheep in the poorer tribes.(22) In the great majority of cases, the compensation money could not be paid at all, so that the murderer had no issue but to induce the wronged family, by repentance, to adopt him. Even now, in the Caucasus, when feuds come to an end, the offender touches with his lips the breast of the oldest woman of the tribe, and becomes a "milk-brother" to all men of the wronged family.(23) With several African tribes he must give his daughter, or sister, in marriage to some one of the family; with other tribes he is bound to marry the woman whom he has made a widow; and in all cases he becomes a member of the family, whose opinion is taken in all important family matters.(24)

In their views on justice, the barbarians clearly didn't differ much from the savages. They also believed that a murder should be followed by executing the murderer; that injuries needed to be met with equal injuries, and that the harmed family had to carry out the sentence according to customary law. This was seen as a sacred duty, a responsibility to their ancestors, which had to be fulfilled in broad daylight, never secretly, and made widely known. Therefore, the most inspiring parts of the sagas and epic poetry celebrate what was thought to be justice. The gods themselves supported it. However, the main aspect of barbarian justice is, on one hand, to limit the number of people involved in a feud, and on the other hand, to eliminate the brutal notion of blood for blood and injury for injury, by replacing it with a system of compensation. The barbarian codes, which were collections of common law rules written for judges—"first permitted, then encouraged, and finally enforced," offered compensation instead of revenge. However, the concept of compensation has been completely misunderstood by those who portrayed it as a fine, and as a way for wealthy individuals to do whatever they wanted. The compensation money (wergeld), which was quite different from a fine or fred, was generally so high for all types of serious offenses that it clearly did not encourage such actions. In the case of murder, it usually exceeded any possible wealth of the murderer. "Eighteen times eighteen cows" is the compensation with the Ossetes, who don't count above eighteen, while with African tribes, it reaches 800 cows or 100 camels with their young, or 416 sheep in poorer tribes. In most cases, the compensation money couldn't be paid at all, so the murderer had no choice but to persuade the wronged family, through repentance, to accept him. Even today, in the Caucasus, when feuds are resolved, the offender touches his lips to the breast of the oldest woman of the tribe and becomes a "milk-brother" to all men of the harmed family. In several African tribes, he must give his daughter or sister in marriage to someone from the family; in other tribes, he is required to marry the woman he has made a widow; and in all cases, he becomes a member of the family, whose views are considered in all important family matters.

Far from acting with disregard to human life, the barbarians, moreover, knew nothing of the horrid punishments introduced at a later epoch by the laic and canonic laws under Roman and Byzantine influence. For, if the Saxon code admitted the death penalty rather freely even in cases of incendiarism and armed robbery, the other barbarian codes pronounced it exclusively in cases of betrayal of one's kin, and sacrilege against the community's gods, as the only means to appease the gods.

Far from being indifferent to human life, the barbarians actually had no idea about the terrible punishments that were later introduced by the secular and religious laws influenced by Rome and Byzantium. While the Saxon code allowed for the death penalty for crimes like arson and armed robbery, other barbarian codes only applied it in cases of betraying one's family or committing sacrilege against the gods of the community, viewing it as the only way to appease the gods.

All this, as seen is very far from the supposed "moral dissoluteness" of the barbarians. On the contrary, we cannot but admire the deeply moral principles elaborated within the early village communities which found their expression in Welsh triads, in legends about King Arthur, in Brehon commentaries,(25) in old German legends and so on, or find still their expression in the sayings of the modern barbarians. In his introduction to The Story of Burnt Njal, George Dasent very justly sums up as follows the qualities of a Northman, as they appear in the sagas:—

All of this is far from the supposed "moral decay" of the so-called barbarians. On the contrary, we can't help but admire the strong moral values developed in the early village communities, which are reflected in Welsh triads, legends about King Arthur, Brehon commentaries, old German legends, and even in the sayings of today's so-called barbarians. In his introduction to The Story of Burnt Njal, George Dasent rightly summarizes the qualities of a Northman as depicted in the sagas:—

To do what lay before him openly and like a man, without fear of either foes, fiends, or fate; … to be free and daring in all his deeds; to be gentle and generous to his friends and kinsmen; to be stern and grim to his foes [those who are under the lex talionis], but even towards them to fulfil all bounden duties…. To be no truce-breaker, nor tale-bearer, nor backbiter. To utter nothing against any man that he would not dare to tell him to his face. To turn no man from his door who sought food or shelter, even though he were a foe.(26)

To face whatever challenges come his way openly and like a true man, without fearing enemies, evil spirits, or destiny; … to act freely and boldly in everything he does; to be kind and generous to his friends and family; to be tough and unforgiving to his enemies [those who fall under the law of retaliation], but even with them, to meet all his obligations…. To never break a truce, spread rumors, or gossip behind anyone's back. To say nothing about anyone that he wouldn't be willing to say to their face. To never turn away anyone from his home who is seeking food or shelter, even if that person is an enemy.(26)

The same or still better principles permeate the Welsh epic poetry and triads. To act "according to the nature of mildness and the principles of equity," without regard to the foes or to the friends, and "to repair the wrong," are the highest duties of man; "evil is death, good is life," exclaims the poet legislator.(27) "The World would be fool, if agreements made on lips were not honourable"—the Brehon law says. And the humble Shamanist Mordovian, after having praised the same qualities, will add, moreover, in his principles of customary law, that "among neighbours the cow and the milking-jar are in common;" that, "the cow must be milked for yourself and him who may ask milk;" that "the body of a child reddens from the stroke, but the face of him who strikes reddens from shame;"(28) and so on. Many pages might be filled with like principles expressed and followed by the "barbarians."

The same, if not better, principles flow through Welsh epic poetry and triads. Acting "according to the nature of kindness and the principles of fairness," without caring about enemies or friends, and "making things right," are the highest responsibilities of a person; "evil is death, good is life," declares the poet-lawgiver. "The world would be foolish if agreements spoken weren't respected," says Brehon law. Additionally, the humble Shamanist Mordovian, after praising these same qualities, will state in his customary law that "among neighbors, the cow and the milking jar are shared;" that "the cow must be milked for yourself and for anyone who asks for milk;" that "the body of a child reddens from a blow, but the face of the one who strikes reddens from shame;" and so on. Many pages could be filled with similar principles expressed and followed by the "barbarians."

One feature more of the old village communities deserves a special mention. It is the gradual extension of the circle of men embraced by the feelings of solidarity. Not only the tribes federated into stems, but the stems as well, even though of different origin, joined together in confederations. Some unions were so close that, for instance, the Vandals, after part of their confederation had left for the Rhine, and thence went over to Spain and Africa, respected for forty consecutive years the landmarks and the abandoned villages of their confederates, and did not take possession of them until they had ascertained through envoys that their confederates did not intend to return. With other barbarians, the soil was cultivated by one part of the stem, while the other part fought on or beyond the frontiers of the common territory. As to the leagues between several stems, they were quite habitual. The Sicambers united with the Cherusques and the Sueves, the Quades with the Sarmates; the Sarmates with the Alans, the Carpes, and the Huns. Later on, we also see the conception of nations gradually developing in Europe, long before anything like a State had grown in any part of the continent occupied by the barbarians. These nations—for it is impossible to refuse the name of a nation to the Merovingian France, or to the Russia of the eleventh and twelfth century—were nevertheless kept together by nothing else but a community of language, and a tacit agreement of the small republics to take their dukes from none but one special family.

One notable aspect of the old village communities deserves special attention. It's the gradual expansion of the sense of solidarity among people. Not just the tribes that came together, but even those groups, despite their different origins, formed alliances. Some unions were so strong that, for example, the Vandals, after part of their coalition had moved to the Rhine and then to Spain and Africa, respected the boundaries and abandoned villages of their allies for forty years. They didn’t take over these lands until they confirmed through messengers that their allies had no plans to return. With other groups, one part of the tribe would farm the land while the other part fought on or beyond the borders of their shared territory. Alliances between different tribes were quite common. The Sicambrians joined with the Cheruscans and the Suevians, the Quadi with the Sarmatians; the Sarmatians with the Alans, the Carpians, and the Huns. Over time, we also see the idea of nations gradually taking shape in Europe, long before any form of a State emerged in regions occupied by the barbarians. These nations—because it’s hard to deny that Merovingian France or Russia in the eleventh and twelfth centuries can be called nations—were nonetheless held together solely by a shared language and a silent agreement among the small republics to choose their dukes from a single notable family.

Wars were certainly unavoidable; migration means war; but Sir Henry Maine has already fully proved in his remarkable study of the tribal origin of International Law, that "Man has never been so ferocious or so stupid as to submit to such an evil as war without some kind of effort to prevent it," and he has shown how exceedingly great is "the number of ancient institutions which bear the marks of a design to stand in the way of war, or to provide an alternative to it."(29) In reality, man is so far from the warlike being he is supposed to be, that when the barbarians had once settled they so rapidly lost the very habits of warfare that very soon they were compelled to keep special dukes followed by special scholae or bands of warriors, in order to protect them from possible intruders. They preferred peaceful toil to war, the very peacefulness of man being the cause of the specialization of the warrior's trade, which specialization resulted later on in serfdom and in all the wars of the "States period" of human history.

Wars were definitely unavoidable; migration leads to war; but Sir Henry Maine has already proven in his remarkable study on the tribal origins of International Law that "Man has never been so ferocious or so stupid as to submit to such an evil as war without some kind of effort to prevent it," and he has shown just how many ancient institutions were designed to prevent war or offer alternatives to it. In reality, humans are far from the warlike beings they are thought to be; when the barbarians settled down, they quickly lost their habits of warfare and soon had to appoint special dukes followed by bands of warriors to protect them from potential invaders. They preferred peaceful work over war, and the very peacefulness of humans led to the specialization of the warrior's role, which eventually resulted in serfdom and all the wars during the "States period" of human history.

History finds great difficulties in restoring to life the institutions of the barbarians. At every step the historian meets with some faint indication which he is unable to explain with the aid of his own documents only. But a broad light is thrown on the past as soon as we refer to the institutions of the very numerous tribes which are still living under a social organization almost identical with that of our barbarian ancestors. Here we simply have the difficulty of choice, because the islands of the Pacific, the steppes of Asia, and the tablelands of Africa are real historical museums containing specimens of all possible intermediate stages which mankind has lived through, when passing from the savage gentes up to the States' organization. Let us, then, examine a few of those specimens.

History struggles to bring the institutions of the barbarians back to life. At every turn, historians encounter vague clues that they can't fully explain using only their own documents. However, as soon as we look at the institutions of the many tribes that still operate under a social organization nearly identical to that of our barbarian ancestors, a clearer picture of the past emerges. The challenge lies in choosing which examples to examine, as the Pacific islands, the Asian steppes, and the African plateaus serve as real historical museums, showcasing various stages humanity has gone through while transitioning from primitive societies to organized states. Let's take a closer look at some of these examples.

If we take the village communities of the Mongol Buryates, especially those of the Kudinsk Steppe on the upper Lena which have better escaped Russian influence, we have fair representatives of barbarians in a transitional state, between cattle-breeding and agriculture.(30) These Buryates are still living in "joint families"; that is, although each son, when he is married, goes to live in a separate hut, the huts of at least three generations remain within the same enclosure, and the joint family work in common in their fields, and own in common their joint households and their cattle, as well as their "calves' grounds" (small fenced patches of soil kept under soft grass for the rearing of calves). As a rule, the meals are taken separately in each hut; but when meat is roasted, all the twenty to sixty members of the joint household feast together. Several joint households which live in a cluster, as well as several smaller families settled in the same village—mostly debris of joint households accidentally broken up—make the oulous, or the village community; several oulouses make a tribe; and the forty-six tribes, or clans, of the Kudinsk Steppe are united into one confederation. Smaller and closer confederations are entered into, as necessity arises for special wants, by several tribes. They know no private property in land—the land being held in common by the oulous, or rather by the confederation, and if it becomes necessary, the territory is re-allotted between the different oulouses at a folkmote of the tribe, and between the forty-six tribes at a folkmote of the confederation. It is worthy of note that the same organization prevails among all the 250,000 Buryates of East Siberia, although they have been for three centuries under Russian rule, and are well acquainted with Russian institutions.

If we look at the village communities of the Mongol Buryates, particularly those in the Kudinsk Steppe on the upper Lena that have largely avoided Russian influence, we find clear examples of societies in transition, between livestock farming and agriculture. These Buryates still live in “joint families”; meaning that while each son moves into his own separate hut when he gets married, the huts of at least three generations are located within the same area. The extended family works together in their fields and shares ownership of their households, cattle, and “calves' grounds” (small fenced patches of land kept grassy for raising calves). Generally, meals are eaten separately in each hut, but when meat is roasted, all twenty to sixty members of the joint household celebrate together. Several joint households clustered together, along with some smaller families that have broken off from joint households, form the oulous, or village community. Multiple oulouses create a tribe, and the forty-six tribes or clans of the Kudinsk Steppe come together to form one confederation. Smaller and tighter confederations are formed as needed by several tribes. They do not recognize private land ownership; the land is collectively owned by the oulous, or more accurately, by the confederation. If it becomes necessary, the territory is redistributed among the different oulouses during a tribe meeting, and between the forty-six tribes during a confederation meeting. It's noteworthy that this organization is consistent among all 250,000 Buryates of East Siberia, even though they have been under Russian rule for three centuries and are well familiar with Russian institutions.

With all that, inequalities of fortune rapidly develop among the Buryates, especially since the Russian Government is giving an exaggerated importance to their elected taishas (princes), whom it considers as responsible tax-collectors and representatives of the confederations in their administrative and even commercial relations with the Russians. The channels for the enrichment of the few are thus many, while the impoverishment of the great number goes hand in hand, through the appropriation of the Buryate lands by the Russians. But it is a habit with the Buryates, especially those of Kudinsk—and habit is more than law—that if a family has lost its cattle, the richer families give it some cows and horses that it may recover. As to the destitute man who has no family, he takes his meals in the huts of his congeners; he enters a hut, takes—by right, not for charity—his seat by the fire, and shares the meal which always is scrupulously divided into equal parts; he sleeps where he has taken his evening meal. Altogether, the Russian conquerors of Siberia were so much struck by the communistic practices of the Buryates, that they gave them the name of Bratskiye—"the Brotherly Ones"—and reported to Moscow. "With them everything is in common; whatever they have is shared in common." Even now, when the Lena Buryates sell their wheat, or send some of their cattle to be sold to a Russian butcher, the families of the oulous, or the tribe, put their wheat and cattle together, and sell it as a whole. Each oulous has, moreover, its grain store for loans in case of need, its communal baking oven (the four banal of the old French communities), and its blacksmith, who, like the blacksmith of the Indian communities,(31) being a member of the community, is never paid for his work within the community. He must make it for nothing, and if he utilizes his spare time for fabricating the small plates of chiselled and silvered iron which are used in Buryate land for the decoration of dress, he may occasionally sell them to a woman from another clan, but to the women of his own clan the attire is presented as a gift. Selling and buying cannot take place within the community, and the rule is so severe that when a richer family hires a labourer the labourer must be taken from another clan or from among the Russians. This habit is evidently not specific to the Buryates; it is so widely spread among the modern barbarians, Aryan and Ural-Altayan, that it must have been universal among our ancestors.

With all that, economic disparities quickly arise among the Buryates, especially since the Russian Government places exaggerated importance on their elected taishas (princes), whom they view as responsible tax collectors and representatives of the confederations in their administrative and even commercial dealings with the Russians. This creates many pathways for the few to get rich while the majority face poverty due to the appropriation of Buryate lands by the Russians. However, it's customary for the Buryates, particularly those from Kudinsk—and custom is stronger than law—that if a family loses its cattle, wealthier families will provide them with some cows and horses to help them recover. As for the person in need who has no family, they eat in the homes of their fellow community members; they enter a home, take their place by the fire as a right, not as an act of charity, and share a meal that is always divided into equal portions; they sleep where they had dinner. Overall, the Russian conquerors of Siberia were so impressed by the communal practices of the Buryates that they referred to them as Bratskiye—"the Brotherly Ones"—and reported back to Moscow, stating, "With them everything is shared; whatever they have is communal." Even now, when the Lena Buryates sell their wheat or send cattle to a Russian butcher, families of the oulous, or tribe, pool their wheat and cattle to sell together. Each oulous also has a grain store for loans in times of need, a communal baking oven (similar to the communal ovens of old French communities), and a blacksmith who, like the blacksmiths in Indian communities, is a member of the community and does not get paid for his work within it. He must work for free, and if he uses his spare time to make small plates of chiselled and silvered iron for decoration, he may occasionally sell them to women from other clans, but to women of his own clan, the attire is given as a gift. Selling and buying are not allowed within the community, and the rule is so strict that when a wealthier family hires a laborer, the laborer must come from another clan or from among the Russians. This practice is clearly not unique to the Buryates; it is so widespread among modern societies, both Aryan and Ural-Altayan, that it must have been universal among our ancestors.

The feeling of union within the confederation is kept alive by the common interests of the tribes, their folkmotes, and the festivities which are usually kept in connection with the folkmotes. The same feeling is, however, maintained by another institution, the aba, or common hunt, which is a reminiscence of a very remote past. Every autumn, the forty-six clans of Kudinsk come together for such a hunt, the produce of which is divided among all the families. Moreover, national abas, to assert the unity of the whole Buryate nation, are convoked from time to time. In such cases, all Buryate clans which are scattered for hundreds of miles west and east of Lake Baikal, are bound to send their delegate hunters. Thousands of men come together, each one bringing provisions for a whole month. Every one's share must be equal to all the others, and therefore, before being put together, they are weighed by an elected elder (always "with the hand": scales would be a profanation of the old custom). After that the hunters divide into bands of twenty, and the parties go hunting according to a well-settled plan. In such abas the entire Buryate nation revives its epic traditions of a time when it was united in a powerful league. Let me add that such communal hunts are quite usual with the Red Indians and the Chinese on the banks of the Usuri (the kada).(32)

The sense of unity within the confederation is kept alive by the shared interests of the tribes, their community gatherings, and the celebrations that usually occur alongside these gatherings. This feeling is also sustained by another institution, the aba, or common hunt, which is a reminder of a very distant past. Every autumn, the forty-six clans of Kudinsk come together for this hunt, and the game is shared among all the families. Additionally, national abas are held from time to time to reinforce the unity of the entire Buryate nation. In these cases, all Buryate clans scattered hundreds of miles to the west and east of Lake Baikal must send their representative hunters. Thousands of men gather, each bringing enough supplies for an entire month. Everyone’s share must be equal to everyone else's, so before they are combined, the provisions are weighed by an elected elder (always “by hand”: using scales would disrespect the old custom). After that, the hunters split into groups of twenty, and the teams follow a well-established plan for hunting. During these abas, the entire Buryate nation revives its epic traditions from a time when it was united in a powerful alliance. I should mention that communal hunts are also quite common among the Red Indians and the Chinese along the banks of the Usuri (the kada).(32)

With the Kabyles, whose manners of life have been so well described by two French explorers,(33) we have barbarians still more advanced in agriculture. Their fields, irrigated and manured, are well attended to, and in the hilly tracts every available plot of land is cultivated by the spade. The Kabyles have known many vicissitudes in their history; they have followed for sometime the Mussulman law of inheritance, but, being adverse to it, they have returned, 150 years ago, to the tribal customary law of old. Accordingly, their land-tenure is of a mixed character, and private property in land exists side by side with communal possession. Still, the basis of their present organization is the village community, the thaddart, which usually consists of several joint families (kharoubas), claiming a community of origin, as well as of smaller families of strangers. Several villages are grouped into clans or tribes (arch); several tribes make the confederation (thak'ebilt); and several confederations may occasionally enter into a league, chiefly for purposes of armed defence.

With the Kabyles, whose way of life has been thoroughly described by two French explorers,(33) we find a group of people who are even more advanced in agriculture. Their fields are well taken care of, with irrigation and fertilization, and in the hilly areas, every piece of land is carefully cultivated using a spade. The Kabyles have experienced many changes throughout their history; they once followed the Muslim inheritance laws, but 150 years ago, they moved away from that and returned to their traditional tribal customs. As a result, their land ownership is a mix of private property and communal land. However, the foundation of their society is the village community, known as the thaddart, which typically comprises several joint families (kharoubas) that share a common ancestry, along with smaller families of outsiders. Multiple villages come together to form clans or tribes (arch); several tribes make up a confederation (thak'ebilt); and occasionally, multiple confederations will join forces, primarily for defense.

The Kabyles know no authority whatever besides that of the djemmaa, or folkmote of the village community. All men of age take part in it, in the open air, or in a special building provided with stone seats. And the decisions of the djemmaa are evidently taken at unanimity: that is, the discussions continue until all present agree to accept, or to submit to, some decision. There being no authority in a village community to impose a decision, this system has been practised by mankind wherever there have been village communities, and it is practised still wherever they continue to exist, i.e. by several hundred million men all over the world. The djemmaa nominates its executive—the elder, the scribe, and the treasurer; it assesses its own taxes; and it manages the repartition of the common lands, as well as all kinds of works of public utility. A great deal of work is done in common: the roads, the mosques, the fountains, the irrigation canals, the towers erected for protection from robbers, the fences, and so on, are built by the village community; while the high-roads, the larger mosques, and the great market-places are the work of the tribe. Many traces of common culture continue to exist, and the houses continue to be built by, or with the aid of, all men and women of the village. Altogether, the "aids" are of daily occurrence, and are continually called in for the cultivation of the fields, for harvesting, and so on. As to the skilled work, each community has its blacksmith, who enjoys his part of the communal land, and works for the community; when the tilling season approaches he visits every house, and repairs the tools and the ploughs, without expecting any pay, while the making of new ploughs is considered as a pious work which can by no means be recompensed in money, or by any other form of salary.

The Kabyles recognize no authority apart from the djemmaa, or village assembly. All adult men participate in it, whether outside or in a dedicated building with stone seats. The decisions made by the djemmaa are clearly reached through consensus: discussions continue until everyone present agrees to accept or follow a decision. Since there's no authority in a village community to enforce decisions, this system has been practiced by humans wherever village communities exist, and it continues to be followed by several hundred million people around the world. The djemmaa appoints its leaders—the elder, the scribe, and the treasurer; it sets its own taxes; and it manages the distribution of common lands, as well as various public works. A lot of work is done collectively: the roads, mosques, fountains, irrigation canals, towers for protection against robbers, fences, and more are built by the village community, while main roads, larger mosques, and major marketplaces are the responsibility of the tribe. Many aspects of shared culture still exist, and houses are built by, or with the help of, all the men and women in the village. "Aid" is a regular occurrence and is continually called upon for field cultivation, harvesting, and similar tasks. As for skilled labor, each community has its blacksmith, who gets a share of the communal land and works for the community; as the planting season nears, he visits every home to repair tools and plows without expecting payment, while making new plows is seen as a charitable act that cannot be compensated with money or any other form of salary.

As the Kabyles already have private property, they evidently have both rich and poor among them. But like all people who closely live together, and know how poverty begins, they consider it as an accident which may visit every one. "Don't say that you will never wear the beggar's bag, nor go to prison," is a proverb of the Russian peasants; the Kabyles practise it, and no difference can be detected in the external behaviour between rich and poor; when the poor convokes an "aid," the rich man works in his field, just as the poor man does it reciprocally in his turn.(34) Moreover, the djemmaas set aside certain gardens and fields, sometimes cultivated in common, for the use of the poorest members. Many like customs continue to exist. As the poorer families would not be able to buy meat, meat is regularly bought with the money of the fines, or the gifts to the djemmaa, or the payments for the use of the communal olive-oil basins, and it is distributed in equal parts among those who cannot afford buying meat themselves. And when a sheep or a bullock is killed by a family for its own use on a day which is not a market day, the fact is announced in the streets by the village crier, in order that sick people and pregnant women may take of it what they want. Mutual support permeates the life of the Kabyles, and if one of them, during a journey abroad, meets with another Kabyle in need, he is bound to come to his aid, even at the risk of his own fortune and life; if this has not been done, the djemmaa of the man who has suffered from such neglect may lodge a complaint, and the djemmaa of the selfish man will at once make good the loss. We thus come across a custom which is familiar to the students of the mediaeval merchant guilds. Every stranger who enters a Kabyle village has right to housing in the winter, and his horses can always graze on the communal lands for twenty-four hours. But in case of need he can reckon upon an almost unlimited support. Thus, during the famine of 1867-68, the Kabyles received and fed every one who sought refuge in their villages, without distinction of origin. In the district of Dellys, no less than 12,000 people who came from all parts of Algeria, and even from Morocco, were fed in this way. While people died from starvation all over Algeria, there was not one single case of death due to this cause on Kabylian soil. The djemmaas, depriving themselves of necessaries, organized relief, without ever asking any aid from the Government, or uttering the slightest complaint; they considered it as a natural duty. And while among the European settlers all kind of police measures were taken to prevent thefts and disorder resulting from such an influx of strangers, nothing of the kind was required on the Kabyles' territory: the djemmaas needed neither aid nor protection from without.(35)

As the Kabyles already own private property, they clearly have both rich and poor members in their community. But like all communities that live close together and understand how poverty can arise, they see it as something that can happen to anyone. "Don't say you'll never wear the beggar's bag or end up in prison," is a saying among Russian peasants; the Kabyles live by this, and you can't tell any difference in how the rich and poor act externally. When the poor request help, the rich man works in his fields just like the poor man does in return. Moreover, the djemmaas set aside certain gardens and fields, sometimes farmed collectively, for the poorest members. Many such customs continue to thrive. Because poorer families can’t afford to buy meat, it is regularly purchased with money from fines, gifts to the djemmaa, or fees for using the communal olive-oil basins, and it is shared equally among those who can’t afford to buy meat themselves. When a family slaughters a sheep or bull for its own use on a non-market day, the village crier announces it in the streets so that sick people and pregnant women can take what they need. Mutual support is a fundamental part of Kabyle life, and if one Kabyle encounters another in need during a trip away, he is obligated to help, even at the risk of his own fortune and life; if he fails to do so, the djemmaa of the neglected person can file a complaint, and the djemmaa of the selfish individual will quickly make reparations. This custom is reminiscent of what students of medieval merchant guilds study. Any stranger who enters a Kabyle village has the right to shelter in winter, and their horses can graze on communal land for twenty-four hours. In times of need, they can count on almost unlimited support. For instance, during the famine of 1867-68, the Kabyles welcomed and fed everyone who sought refuge in their villages, regardless of their background. In the Dellys district alone, at least 12,000 people from all parts of Algeria and even Morocco were fed this way. While people were starving across Algeria, there wasn’t a single case of death from starvation on Kabyle soil. The djemmaas, sacrificing their own needs, organized relief without ever asking for help from the Government or making any complaints; they saw it as a natural obligation. And while European settlers implemented all sorts of policing measures to prevent theft and disorder arising from the influx of strangers, nothing of the sort was needed on Kabyle territory: the djemmaas required neither outside help nor protection.

I can only cursorily mention two other most interesting features of Kabyle life; namely, the anaya, or protection granted to wells, canals, mosques, marketplaces, some roads, and so on, in case of war, and the cofs. In the anaya we have a series of institutions both for diminishing the evils of war and for preventing conflicts. Thus the market-place is anaya, especially if it stands on a frontier and brings Kabyles and strangers together; no one dares disturb peace in the market, and if a disturbance arises, it is quelled at once by the strangers who have gathered in the market town. The road upon which the women go from the village to the fountain also is anaya in case of war; and so on. As to the cof it is a widely spread form of association, having some characters of the mediaeval Burgschaften or Gegilden, as well as of societies both for mutual protection and for various purposes—intellectual, political, and emotional—which cannot be satisfied by the territorial organization of the village, the clan, and the con federation. The cof knows no territorial limits; it recruits its members in various villages, even among strangers; and it protects them in all possible eventualities of life. Altogether, it is an attempt at supplementing the territorial grouping by an extra-territorial grouping intended to give an expression to mutual affinities of all kinds across the frontiers. The free international association of individual tastes and ideas, which we consider as one of the best features of our own life, has thus its origin in barbarian antiquity.

I can only briefly mention two other fascinating aspects of Kabyle life: the anaya, or protection given to wells, canals, mosques, marketplaces, some roads, and so on, during times of war, and the cofs. The anaya consists of a series of institutions aimed at reducing the harms of war and preventing conflicts. For example, the marketplace is considered an anaya, especially if it’s located on a border and brings together Kabyles and outsiders; no one dares disrupt the peace in the market, and if a disturbance does occur, it is quickly resolved by the outsiders present in the marketplace town. The road that women take from the village to the fountain is also considered an anaya in times of war, and so forth. The cof is a widespread form of association, sharing some characteristics with the medieval guilds, as well as being a society for mutual protection and various purposes—intellectual, political, and emotional—that cannot be fulfilled by the territorial organization of the village, clan, and confederation. The cof has no territorial boundaries; it recruits members from different villages, even among strangers, and provides protection for them in all possible life situations. Overall, it attempts to supplement territorial organization with a non-territorial structure that expresses various mutual affinities across borders. The free international association of individual tastes and ideas, which we view as one of the best aspects of our own lives, has its roots in ancient barbarian times.

The mountaineers of Caucasia offer another extremely instructive field for illustrations of the same kind. In studying the present customs of the Ossetes—their joint families and communes and their judiciary conceptions—Professor Kovalevsky, in a remarkable work on Modern Custom and Ancient Law was enabled step by step to trace the similar dispositions of the old barbarian codes and even to study the origins of feudalism. With other Caucasian stems we occasionally catch a glimpse into the origin of the village community in those cases where it was not tribal but originated from a voluntary union between families of distinct origin. Such was recently the case with some Khevsoure villages, the inhabitants of which took the oath of "community and fraternity."(36) In another part of Caucasus, Daghestan, we see the growth of feudal relations between two tribes, both maintaining at the same time their village communities (and even traces of the gentile "classes"), and thus giving a living illustration of the forms taken by the conquest of Italy and Gaul by the barbarians. The victorious race, the Lezghines, who have conquered several Georgian and Tartar villages in the Zakataly district, did not bring them under the dominion of separate families; they constituted a feudal clan which now includes 12,000 households in three villages, and owns in common no less than twenty Georgian and Tartar villages. The conquerors divided their own land among their clans, and the clans divided it in equal parts among the families; but they did not interfere with the djemmaas of their tributaries which still practise the habit mentioned by Julius Caesar; namely, the djemmaa decides each year which part of the communal territory must be cultivated, and this land is divided into as many parts as there are families, and the parts are distributed by lot. It is worthy of note that although proletarians are of common occurrence among the Lezghines (who live under a system of private property in land, and common ownership of serfs(37)) they are rare among their Georgian serfs, who continue to hold their land in common. As to the customary law of the Caucasian mountaineers, it is much the same as that of the Longobards or Salic Franks, and several of its dispositions explain a good deal the judicial procedure of the barbarians of old. Being of a very impressionable character, they do their best to prevent quarrels from taking a fatal issue; so, with the Khevsoures, the swords are very soon drawn when a quarrel breaks out; but if a woman rushes out and throws among them the piece of linen which she wears on her head, the swords are at once returned to their sheaths, and the quarrel is appeased. The head-dress of the women is anaya. If a quarrel has not been stopped in time and has ended in murder, the compensation money is so considerable that the aggressor is entirely ruined for his life, unless he is adopted by the wronged family; and if he has resorted to his sword in a trifling quarrel and has inflicted wounds, he loses for ever the consideration of his kin. In all disputes, mediators take the matter in hand; they select from among the members of the clan the judges—six in smaller affairs, and from ten to fifteen in more serious matters—and Russian observers testify to the absolute incorruptibility of the judges. An oath has such a significance that men enjoying general esteem are dispensed from taking it: a simple affirmation is quite sufficient, the more so as in grave affairs the Khevsoure never hesitates to recognize his guilt (I mean, of course, the Khevsoure untouched yet by civilization). The oath is chiefly reserved for such cases, like disputes about property, which require some sort of appreciation in addition to a simple statement of facts; and in such cases the men whose affirmation will decide in the dispute, act with the greatest circumspection. Altogether it is certainly not a want of honesty or of respect to the rights of the congeners which characterizes the barbarian societies of Caucasus.

The mountaineers of Caucasia provide another highly educational area for examples of similar concepts. By examining the current customs of the Ossetes—their extended families and communes, as well as their judicial beliefs—Professor Kovalevsky, in a remarkable work on Modern Custom and Ancient Law, was able to gradually trace the similarities to the old barbarian codes and even explore the roots of feudalism. With other groups in the Caucasus, we sometimes get a glimpse into the origins of the village community in cases where it wasn’t tribal, but instead arose from a voluntary association between families of different origins. This was recently seen in some Khevsoure villages, where the residents took an oath of "community and fraternity." In another part of the Caucasus, Daghestan, we observe the development of feudal relations between two tribes, both of which simultaneously maintain their village communities (and even remnants of the gentile "classes"), offering a real-life illustration of how the barbarians conquered Italy and Gaul. The victorious group, the Lezghines, conquered several Georgian and Tartar villages in the Zakataly district but did not place them under the control of individual families; instead, they formed a feudal clan that currently comprises 12,000 households in three villages and collectively owns no fewer than twenty Georgian and Tartar villages. The conquerors divided their own land among their clans, and the clans allocated it equally among their families; however, they did not interfere with the djemmaas of their tributaries, which still follow the practice mentioned by Julius Caesar: the djemmaa decides each year which portion of the communal land should be cultivated, and this land is divided into as many parts as there are families, with the portions distributed by lot. It is worth noting that while proletarians are commonly found among the Lezghines (who live under a system of private land ownership and common ownership of serfs), they are rare among their Georgian serfs, who continue to hold their land in common. Regarding the customary law of the Caucasian mountaineers, it closely resembles that of the Longobards or Salic Franks, and several of its rules clarify much of the judicial process of ancient barbarians. Due to their sensitive nature, they try to prevent quarrels from becoming deadly; for instance, with the Khevsoures, swords are quickly drawn when a dispute arises, but if a woman rushes out and throws down the linen cloth she wears on her head, the swords are instantly returned to their sheaths, and the argument is settled. The headscarf of the women is called anaya. If a quarrel isn't resolved in time and ends in murder, the compensation is so substantial that the offender is completely ruined for life unless he is adopted by the aggrieved family; and if he resorted to his sword in a minor argument and caused injuries, he loses the respect of his kin forever. In all conflicts, mediators step in; they choose judges from among clan members—six for smaller issues, and between ten and fifteen for more serious cases—and Russian observers have noted the absolute incorruptibility of these judges. An oath carries such weight that individuals widely respected are exempt from taking it: a simple affirmation suffices, especially since, in serious matters, a Khevsoure never hesitates to admit guilt (I mean, of course, the Khevsoure who has not yet been influenced by civilization). The oath is mainly reserved for disputes over property that require some evaluation alongside a simple presentation of facts; thus, the men whose affirmation will resolve the dispute proceed with utmost caution. Overall, it is clear that the barbarian societies of the Caucasus are not characterized by a lack of honesty or respect for the rights of their peers.

The stems of Africa offer such an immense variety of extremely interesting societies standing at all intermediate stages from the early village community to the despotic barbarian monarchies that I must abandon the idea of giving here even the chief results of a comparative study of their institutions.(38) Suffice it to say, that, even under the most horrid despotism of kings, the folkmotes of the village communities and their customary law remain sovereign in a wide circle of affairs. The law of the State allows the king to take any one's life for a simple caprice, or even for simply satisfying his gluttony; but the customary law of the people continues to maintain the same network of institutions for mutual support which exist among other barbarians or have existed among our ancestors. And with some better-favoured stems (in Bornu, Uganda, Abyssinia), and especially the Bogos, some of the dispositions of the customary law are inspired with really graceful and delicate feelings.

The cultures of Africa showcase a vast array of fascinating societies that range from early village communities to authoritarian monarchies, making it impossible for me to provide even a summary of a comparative study of their institutions. It's enough to say that, even under the harshest rule of kings, the gatherings of village communities and their traditional laws still hold significant power in many areas. While state law permits the king to take anyone's life on a whim, or simply to satisfy his desire, the people's customary law upholds a similar system of mutual support that can be found among other tribal groups or that existed among our ancestors. In some more favorable areas (like Bornu, Uganda, and Abyssinia), especially among the Bogos, the elements of customary law reflect genuinely graceful and sensitive sentiments.

The village communities of the natives of both Americas have the same character. The Tupi of Brazil were found living in "long houses" occupied by whole clans which used to cultivate their corn and manioc fields in common. The Arani, much more advanced in civilization, used to cultivate their fields in common; so also the Oucagas, who had learned under their system of primitive communism and "long houses" to build good roads and to carry on a variety of domestic industries,(39) not inferior to those of the early medieval times in Europe. All of them were also living under the same customary law of which we have given specimens on the preceding pages. At another extremity of the world we find the Malayan feudalism, but this feudalism has been powerless to unroot the negaria, or village community, with its common ownership of at least part of the land, and the redistribution of land among the several negarias of the tribe.(40) With the Alfurus of Minahasa we find the communal rotation of the crops; with the Indian stem of the Wyandots we have the periodical redistribution of land within the tribe, and the clan-culture of the soil; and in all those parts of Sumatra where Moslem institutions have not yet totally destroyed the old organization we find the joint family (suka) and the village community (kota) which maintains its right upon the land, even if part of it has been cleared without its authorization.(41) But to say this, is to say that all customs for mutual protection and prevention of feuds and wars, which have been briefly indicated in the preceding pages as characteristic of the village community, exist as well. More than that: the more fully the communal possession of land has been maintained, the better and the gentler are the habits. De Stuers positively affirms that wherever the institution of the village community has been less encroached upon by the conquerors, the inequalities of fortunes are smaller, and the very prescriptions of the lex talionis are less cruel; while, on the contrary, wherever the village community has been totally broken up, "the inhabitants suffer the most unbearable oppression from their despotic rulers."(42) This is quite natural. And when Waitz made the remark that those stems which have maintained their tribal confederations stand on a higher level of development and have a richer literature than those stems which have forfeited the old bonds of union, he only pointed out what might have been foretold in advance.

The village communities of the indigenous peoples of both Americas share similar characteristics. The Tupi of Brazil lived in "long houses" shared by entire clans that worked their corn and manioc fields together. The Arani, who were further along in their civilization, also cultivated their fields collectively; the Oucagas, who learned under their system of primitive communism and "long houses," developed efficient roads and engaged in various domestic industries that were comparable to those in early medieval Europe. All of them lived under the same customary laws that we described earlier. On the other side of the world, Malayan feudalism exists, but it has been unable to completely eliminate the negaria, or village community, which retains some common land ownership and the redistribution of land among different negarias in the tribe. With the Alfurus of Minahasa, we observe communal crop rotation; among the Wyandots, we see periodic land redistribution within the tribe and clan-based agriculture; and in areas of Sumatra where Islamic institutions have not entirely disrupted the traditional organization, we find the joint family (suka) and the village community (kota) that still claim rights to the land, even if some of it has been cleared without their permission. This indicates that all customs for mutual protection and preventing conflicts and wars, which we briefly mentioned earlier as characteristic of the village community, still exist. Moreover, the more intact the communal land ownership has remained, the better and kinder the societal behaviors tend to be. De Stuers firmly states that where the village community has faced less intrusion from conquerors, inequalities in wealth are reduced, and the principles of retaliation (lex talionis) are less harsh; conversely, where the village community has been completely dismantled, "the inhabitants endure the most unbearable oppression from their tyrannical rulers." This is quite understandable. Furthermore, when Waitz noted that those groups that have maintained their tribal confederations are at a higher level of development and possess richer literature than those that have lost their old ties, he merely highlighted what could have been anticipated.

More illustrations would simply involve me in tedious repetitions—so strikingly similar are the barbarian societies under all climates and amidst all races. The same process of evolution has been going on in mankind with a wonderful similarity. When the clan organization, assailed as it was from within by the separate family, and from without by the dismemberment of the migrating clans and the necessity of taking in strangers of different descent—the village community, based upon a territorial conception, came into existence. This new institution, which had naturally grown out of the preceding one—the clan—permitted the barbarians to pass through a most disturbed period of history without being broken into isolated families which would have succumbed in the struggle for life. New forms of culture developed under the new organization; agriculture attained the stage which it hardly has surpassed until now with the great number; the domestic industries reached a high degree of perfection. The wilderness was conquered, it was intersected by roads, dotted with swarms thrown off by the mother-communities. Markets and fortified centres, as well as places of public worship, were erected. The conceptions of a wider union, extended to whole stems and to several stems of various origin, were slowly elaborated. The old conceptions of justice which were conceptions of mere revenge, slowly underwent a deep modification—the idea of amends for the wrong done taking the place of revenge. The customary law which still makes the law of the daily life for two-thirds or more of mankind, was elaborated under that organization, as well as a system of habits intended to prevent the oppression of the masses by the minorities whose powers grew in proportion to the growing facilities for private accumulation of wealth. This was the new form taken by the tendencies of the masses for mutual support. And the progress—economical, intellectual, and moral—which mankind accomplished under this new popular form of organization, was so great that the States, when they were called later on into existence, simply took possession, in the interest of the minorities, of all the judicial, economical, and administrative functions which the village community already had exercised in the interest of all.

More examples would just drag me into boring repetitions—barbarian societies are so remarkably alike across different climates and races. Humanity has experienced a similar process of evolution in a strikingly similar way. As the clan system was challenged from within by individual families and from outside by the breakup of migrating clans and the need to include outsiders of various backgrounds, the village community, rooted in a territorial idea, emerged. This new institution, which naturally developed from the previous clan system, allowed barbarians to navigate a highly unstable period of history without fragmenting into isolated families that would have struggled to survive. New cultural forms evolved under this new organization; agriculture reached a level it hasn’t surpassed for the majority to this day, and domestic industries achieved a high level of skill. The wilderness was tamed, crisscrossed by roads, and filled with populations branching out from the main communities. Markets, fortified centers, and places for public worship were established. Ideas of broader unions, encompassing entire groups and various clans of different origins, were slowly developed. The old ideas of justice, which were mainly about revenge, gradually transformed into a deeper concept—the idea of compensation for the wrongs done took precedence over vengeance. The customary laws, which still govern the daily lives of two-thirds or more of humanity, were formulated within that system, along with practices designed to protect the masses from the growing power of minorities, who increased their influence in line with the accumulation of private wealth. This represented a new form of the masses' push for mutual support. The progress—economic, intellectual, and moral—that humanity achieved under this new, communal organization was so significant that when states eventually came into being, they essentially took control, in favor of the minorities, of all the judicial, economic, and administrative functions that the village community had already managed for the benefit of all.

NOTES:

1. Numberless traces of post-pliocene lakes, now disappeared, are found over Central, West, and North Asia. Shells of the same species as those now found in the Caspian Sea are scattered over the surface of the soil as far East as half-way to Lake Aral, and are found in recent deposits as far north as Kazan. Traces of Caspian Gulfs, formerly taken for old beds of the Amu, intersect the Turcoman territory. Deduction must surely be made for temporary, periodical oscillations. But with all that, desiccation is evident, and it progresses at a formerly unexpected speed. Even in the relatively wet parts of South-West Siberia, the succession of reliable surveys, recently published by Yadrintseff, shows that villages have grown up on what was, eighty years ago, the bottom of one of the lakes of the Tchany group; while the other lakes of the same group, which covered hundreds of square miles some fifty years ago, are now mere ponds. In short, the desiccation of North-West Asia goes on at a rate which must be measured by centuries, instead of by the geological units of time of which we formerly used to speak.

1. Countless remnants of post-pliocene lakes, which have now vanished, can be found across Central, West, and North Asia. Shells from the same species as those currently in the Caspian Sea are scattered over the ground as far east as halfway to Lake Aral, and are located in recent deposits as far north as Kazan. Evidence of former Caspian Gulfs, previously thought to be old beds of the Amu, intersects the Turcoman region. We must certainly account for temporary, periodic changes. However, despite this, desiccation is clear and is happening at a surprisingly rapid pace. Even in the relatively wet areas of South-West Siberia, a series of reliable surveys recently published by Yadrintseff shows that villages have formed on what was, eighty years ago, the bottom of one of the lakes in the Tchany group; while the other lakes in the same group, which covered hundreds of square miles about fifty years ago, are now just small ponds. In short, the drying out of North-West Asia is occurring at a speed that should be measured in centuries rather than by the geological timelines we used to discuss.

2. Whole civilizations had thus disappeared, as is proved now by the remarkable discoveries in Mongolia on the Orkhon and in the Lukchun depression (by Dmitri Clements).

2. Entire civilizations had vanished, as evidenced by the remarkable discoveries in Mongolia at the Orkhon and in the Lukchun depression (by Dmitri Clements).

3. If I follow the opinions of (to name modern specialists only) Nasse, Kovalevsky, and Vinogradov, and not those of Mr. Seebohm (Mr. Denman Ross can only be named for the sake of completeness), it is not only because of the deep knowledge and concordance of views of these three writers, but also on account of their perfect knowledge of the village community altogether—a knowledge the want of which is much felt in the otherwise remarkable work of Mr. Seebohm. The same remark applies, in a still higher degree, to the most elegant writings of Fustel de Coulanges, whose opinions and passionate interpretations of old texts are confined to himself.

3. If I lean towards the views of modern experts like Nasse, Kovalevsky, and Vinogradov, rather than Mr. Seebohm (I only mention Mr. Denman Ross for the sake of completeness), it's not just because these three authors have deep knowledge and similar perspectives, but also because they fully understand the village community as a whole—a depth of understanding that is noticeably absent in Mr. Seebohm's otherwise impressive work. The same comment applies even more strongly to the elegant writings of Fustel de Coulanges, whose views and emotional interpretations of old texts are uniquely his own.

4. The literature of the village community is so vast that but a few works can be named. Those of Sir Henry Maine, Mr. Seebohm, and Walter's Das alte Wallis (Bonn, 1859), are well-known popular sources of information about Scotland, Ireland, and Wales. For France, P. Viollet, Precis de l'histoire du droit francais. Droit prive, 1886, and several of his monographs in Bibl. de l'Ecole des Chartes; Babeau, Le Village sous l'ancien regime (the mir in the eighteenth century), third edition, 1887; Bonnemere, Doniol, etc. For Italy and Scandinavia, the chief works are named in Laveleye's Primitive Property, German version by K. Bucher. For the Finns, Rein's Forelasningar, i. 16; Koskinen, Finnische Geschichte, 1874, and various monographs. For the Lives and Coures, Prof. Lutchitzky in Severnyi Vestnil, 1891. For the Teutons, besides the well-known works of Maurer, Sohm (Altdeutsche Reichs-und Gerichts-Verfassung), also Dahn (Urzeit, Volkerwanderung, Langobardische Studien), Janssen, Wilh. Arnold, etc. For India, besides H. Maine and the works he names, Sir John Phear's Aryan Village. For Russia and South Slavonians, see Kavelin, Posnikoff, Sokolovsky, Kovalevsky, Efimenko, Ivanisheff, Klaus, etc. (copious bibliographical index up to 1880 in the Sbornik svedeniy ob obschinye of the Russ. Geog. Soc.). For general conclusions, besides Laveleye's Propriete, Morgan's Ancient Society, Lippert's Kulturgeschichte, Post, Dargun, etc., also the lectures of M. Kovalevsky (Tableau des origines et de l'evolution de la famille et de la propriete, Stockholm, 1890). Many special monographs ought to be mentioned; their titles may be found in the excellent lists given by P. Viollet in Droit prive and Droit public. For other races, see subsequent notes.

4. The literature on village communities is so extensive that only a few works can be mentioned. Those by Sir Henry Maine, Mr. Seebohm, and Walter’s Das alte Wallis (Bonn, 1859) are well-known popular sources of information about Scotland, Ireland, and Wales. For France, P. Viollet’s Precis de l'histoire du droit francais. Droit prive, 1886, and several of his monographs in Bibl. de l'Ecole des Chartes; Babeau’s Le Village sous l'ancien regime (the mir in the eighteenth century), third edition, 1887; Bonnemere, Doniol, etc. For Italy and Scandinavia, the main works are listed in Laveleye’s Primitive Property, German version by K. Bucher. For the Finns, see Rein’s Forelasningar, i. 16; Koskinen’s Finnische Geschichte, 1874, and various monographs. For the Lives and Courses, Prof. Lutchitzky in Severnyi Vestnil, 1891. For the Teutons, in addition to the well-known works of Maurer, Sohm (Altdeutsche Reichs-und Gerichts-Verfassung), also Dahn (Urzeit, Volkerwanderung, Langobardische Studien), Janssen, Wilh. Arnold, etc. For India, in addition to H. Maine and the works he mentions, Sir John Phear’s Aryan Village. For Russia and South Slavs, see Kavelin, Posnikoff, Sokolovsky, Kovalevsky, Efimenko, Ivanisheff, Klaus, etc. (detailed bibliographical index up to 1880 in the Sbornik svedeniy ob obschinye of the Russian Geographical Society). For general conclusions, in addition to Laveleye’s Propriete, Morgan’s Ancient Society, Lippert’s Kulturgeschichte, Post, Dargun, etc., also the lectures of M. Kovalevsky (Tableau des origines et de l'evolution de la famille et de la propriete, Stockholm, 1890). Many specialized monographs should be noted; their titles can be found in the excellent lists provided by P. Viollet in Droit prive and Droit public. For other races, see the subsequent notes.

5. Several authorities are inclined to consider the joint household as an intermediate stage between the clan and the village community; and there is no doubt that in very many cases village communities have grown up out of undivided families. Nevertheless, I consider the joint household as a fact of a different order. We find it within the gentes; on the other hand, we cannot affirm that joint families have existed at any period without belonging either to a gens or to a village community, or to a Gau. I conceive the early village communities as slowly originating directly from the gentes, and consisting, according to racial and local circumstances, either of several joint families, or of both joint and simple families, or (especially in the case of new settlements) of simple families only. If this view be correct, we should not have the right of establishing the series: gens, compound family, village community—the second member of the series having not the same ethnological value as the two others. See Appendix IX.

5. Several experts believe that the joint household is a middle stage between the clan and the village community; and there's no doubt that in many cases, village communities have developed from undivided families. However, I see the joint household as something different. We find it within the gentes; on the other hand, we can't say that joint families have ever existed without being part of either a gens or a village community, or a Gau. I imagine the early village communities as slowly forming directly from the gentes, consisting, based on racial and local factors, either of several joint families, or of both joint and simple families, or (especially in new settlements) of simple families only. If this perspective is correct, we shouldn't establish the sequence: gens, compound family, village community—the second part of the sequence doesn't have the same ethnological significance as the other two. See Appendix IX.

6. Stobbe, Beitrag zur Geschichte des deutschen Rechtes, p. 62.

6. Stobbe, Contribution to the History of German Law, p. 62.

7. The few traces of private property in land which are met with in the early barbarian period are found with such stems (the Batavians, the Franks in Gaul) as have been for a time under the influence of Imperial Rome. See Inama-Sternegg's Die Ausbildung der grossen Grundherrschaften in Deutschland, Bd. i. 1878. Also, Besseler, Neubruch nach dem alteren deutschen Recht, pp. 11-12, quoted by Kovalevsky, Modern Custom and Ancient Law, Moscow, 1886, i. 134.

7. The few signs of private land ownership that appear in the early barbarian period are associated with groups like the Batavians and the Franks in Gaul, who were influenced by Imperial Rome for a time. See Inama-Sternegg's *Die Ausbildung der grossen Grundherrschaften in Deutschland*, Bd. i. 1878. Also, Besseler's *Neubruch nach dem alteren deutschen Recht*, pp. 11-12, cited by Kovalevsky in *Modern Custom and Ancient Law*, Moscow, 1886, i. 134.

8. Maurer's Markgenossenschaft; Lamprecht's "Wirthschaft und Recht der Franken zur Zeit der Volksrechte," in Histor. Taschenbuch, 1883; Seebohm's The English Village Community, ch. vi, vii, and ix.

8. Maurer's Markgenossenschaft; Lamprecht's "Economy and Law of the Franks during the Time of Popular Rights," in Historical Annual, 1883; Seebohm's The English Village Community, ch. vi, vii, and ix.

9. Letourneau, in Bulletin de la Soc. d'Anthropologie, 1888, vol. xi. p. 476.

9. Letourneau, in Bulletin de la Soc. d'Anthropologie, 1888, vol. xi. p. 476.

10. Walter, Das alte Wallis, p. 323; Dm. Bakradze and N. Khoudadoff in Russian Zapiski of the Caucasian Geogr. Society, xiv. Part I.

10. Walter, The Old Valais, p. 323; Dm. Bakradze and N. Khoudadoff in Russian Notes of the Caucasian Geographic Society, xiv. Part I.

11. Bancroft's Native Races; Waitz, Anthropologie, iii. 423; Montrozier, in Bull. Soc. d'Anthropologie, 1870; Post's Studien, etc.

11. Bancroft's Native Races; Waitz, Anthropology, iii. 423; Montrozier, in Bulletin of the Society of Anthropology, 1870; Post's Studies, etc.

12. A number of works, by Ory, Luro, Laudes, and Sylvestre, on the village community in Annam, proving that it has had there the same forms as in Germany or Russia, is mentioned in a review of these works by Jobbe-Duval, in Nouvelle Revue historique de droit francais et etranger, October and December, 1896. A good study of the village community of Peru, before the establishment of the power of the Incas, has been brought out by Heinrich Cunow (Die Soziale Verfassung des Inka-Reichs, Stuttgart, 1896.) The communal possession of land and communal culture are described in that work.

12. A number of works by Ory, Luro, Laudes, and Sylvestre on the village community in Annam show that it has had similar forms as in Germany or Russia. This is discussed in a review of these works by Jobbe-Duval in the Nouvelle Revue historique de droit francais et etranger, October and December 1896. A solid study of the village community of Peru, before the power of the Incas was established, has been published by Heinrich Cunow (Die Soziale Verfassung des Inka-Reichs, Stuttgart, 1896). The work describes communal land ownership and communal agriculture.

13. Kovalevsky, Modern Custom and Ancient Law, i. 115.

13. Kovalevsky, Modern Custom and Ancient Law, p. 115.

14. Palfrey, History of New England, ii. 13; quoted in Maine's Village Communities, New York, 1876, p. 201.

14. Palfrey, History of New England, ii. 13; quoted in Maine's Village Communities, New York, 1876, p. 201.

15. Konigswarter, Etudes sur le developpement des societes humaines, Paris, 1850.

15. Konigswarter, Studies on the Development of Human Societies, Paris, 1850.

16. This is, at least, the law of the Kalmucks, whose customary law bears the closest resemblance to the laws of the Teutons, the old Slavonians, etc.

16. This is, at least, the law of the Kalmucks, whose customary law closely resembles the laws of the Teutons, the ancient Slavs, and others.

17. The habit is in force still with many African and other tribes.

17. The habit still exists among many African and other tribes.

18. Village Communities, pp. 65-68 and 199.

18. Village Communities, pp. 65-68 and 199.

19. Maurer (Gesch. der Markverfassung, sections 29, 97) is quite decisive upon this subject. He maintains that "All members of the community … the laic and clerical lords as well, often also the partial co-possessors (Markberechtigte), and even strangers to the Mark, were submitted to its jurisdiction" (p. 312). This conception remained locally in force up to the fifteenth century.

19. Maurer (Gesch. der Markverfassung, sections 29, 97) is very clear on this topic. He argues that "All members of the community … including both lay and clerical lords, often some co-owners (Markberechtigte), and even outsiders to the Mark, were subject to its jurisdiction" (p. 312). This understanding remained in effect locally until the fifteenth century.

20. Konigswarter, loc. cit. p. 50; J. Thrupp, Historical Law Tracts, London, 1843, p. 106.

20. Konigswarter, loc. cit. p. 50; J. Thrupp, Historical Law Tracts, London, 1843, p. 106.

21. Konigswarter has shown that the fred originated from an offering which had to be made to appease the ancestors. Later on, it was paid to the community, for the breach of peace; and still later to the judge, or king, or lord, when they had appropriated to themselves the rights of the community.

21. Konigswarter has shown that the fred started as a payment made to honor the ancestors. It later became a payment to the community for breaking the peace, and eventually went to the judge, king, or lord when they took on the rights of the community.

22. Post's Bausteine and Afrikanische Jurisprudenz, Oldenburg, 1887, vol. i. pp. 64 seq.; Kovalevsky, loc. cit. ii. 164-189.

22. Post's Bausteine and African Jurisprudence, Oldenburg, 1887, vol. i. pp. 64 seq.; Kovalevsky, loc. cit. ii. 164-189.

23. O. Miller and M. Kovalevsky, "In the Mountaineer Communities of Kabardia," in Vestnik Evropy, April, 1884. With the Shakhsevens of the Mugan Steppe, blood feuds always end by marriage between the two hostile sides (Markoff, in appendix to the Zapiski of the Caucasian Geogr. Soc. xiv. 1, 21).

23. O. Miller and M. Kovalevsky, "In the Mountain Communities of Kabardia," in Vestnik Evropy, April, 1884. Among the Shakhsevens of the Mugan Steppe, blood feuds always conclude with a marriage between the two opposing sides (Markoff, in appendix to the Zapiski of the Caucasian Geogr. Soc. xiv. 1, 21).

24. Post, in Afrik. Jurisprudenz, gives a series of facts illustrating the conceptions of equity inrooted among the African barbarians. The same may be said of all serious examinations into barbarian common law.

24. Post, in Afrik. Jurisprudenz, provides several facts that illustrate the ideas of equity deeply rooted among the African tribes. The same can be said for all serious studies of barbarian common law.

25. See the excellent chapter, "Le droit de La Vieille Irlande," (also "Le Haut Nord") in Etudes de droit international et de droit politique, by Prof. E. Nys, Bruxelles, 1896.

25. See the excellent chapter, "The Law of Old Ireland," (also "The Far North") in Studies of International Law and Political Law, by Prof. E. Nys, Brussels, 1896.

26. Introduction, p. xxxv.

26. Intro, p. xxxv.

27. Das alte Wallis, pp. 343-350.

27. The old Valais, pp. 343-350.

28. Maynoff, "Sketches of the Judicial Practices of the Mordovians," in the ethnographical Zapiski of the Russian Geographical Society, 1885, pp. 236, 257.

28. Maynoff, "Sketches of the Judicial Practices of the Mordovians," in the ethnographical notes of the Russian Geographical Society, 1885, pp. 236, 257.

29. Henry Maine, International Law, London, 1888, pp. 11-13. E. Nys, Les origines du droit international, Bruxelles, 1894.

29. Henry Maine, International Law, London, 1888, pp. 11-13. E. Nys, The Origins of International Law, Brussels, 1894.

30. A Russian historian, the Kazan Professor Schapoff, who was exiled in 1862 to Siberia, has given a good description of their institutions in the Izvestia of the East-Siberian Geographical Society, vol. v. 1874.

30. A Russian historian, Kazan Professor Schapoff, who was exiled to Siberia in 1862, provided a solid description of their institutions in the Izvestia of the East-Siberian Geographical Society, vol. v. 1874.

31. Sir Henry Maine's Village Communities, New York, 1876, pp. 193-196.

31. Sir Henry Maine's Village Communities, New York, 1876, pp. 193-196.

32. Nazaroff, The North Usuri Territory (Russian), St. Petersburg, 1887, p. 65.

32. Nazaroff, The North Usuri Territory (Russian), St. Petersburg, 1887, p. 65.

33. Hanoteau et Letourneux, La Kabylie, 3 vols. Paris, 1883.

33. Hanoteau and Letourneux, La Kabylie, 3 volumes. Paris, 1883.

34. To convoke an "aid" or "bee," some kind of meal must be offered to the community. I am told by a Caucasian friend that in Georgia, when the poor man wants an "aid," he borrows from the rich man a sheep or two to prepare the meal, and the community bring, in addition to their work, so many provisions that he may repay the debt. A similar habit exists with the Mordovians.

34. To call for an "aid" or "bee," a meal needs to be offered to the community. A Caucasian friend told me that in Georgia, when a poor person wants an "aid," they borrow a sheep or two from a wealthy person to prepare the meal, and the community brings enough food so that they can repay the debt. A similar tradition exists among the Mordovians.

35. Hanoteau et Letourneux, La kabylie, ii. 58. The same respect to strangers is the rule with the Mongols. The Mongol who has refused his roof to a stranger pays the full blood-compensation if the stranger has suffered therefrom (Bastian, Der Mensch in der Geschichte, iii. 231).

35. Hanoteau and Letourneux, La kabylie, ii. 58. The same respect for strangers is the rule among the Mongols. A Mongol who denies shelter to a stranger must pay full blood compensation if the stranger suffers as a result (Bastian, Der Mensch in der Geschichte, iii. 231).

36. N. Khoudadoff, "Notes on the Khevsoures," in Zapiski of the Caucasian Geogr. Society, xiv. 1, Tiflis, 1890, p. 68. They also took the oath of not marrying girls from their own union, thus displaying a remarkable return to the old gentile rules.

36. N. Khoudadoff, "Notes on the Khevsoures," in Zapiski of the Caucasian Geogr. Society, xiv. 1, Tiflis, 1890, p. 68. They also took an oath not to marry girls from their own group, which shows a notable return to the old tribal customs.

37. Dm. Bakradze, "Notes on the Zakataly District," in same Zapiski, xiv. 1, p. 264. The "joint team" is as common among the Lezghines as it is among the Ossetes.

37. Dm. Bakradze, "Notes on the Zakataly District," in same Zapiski, xiv. 1, p. 264. The "joint team" is just as prevalent among the Lezghines as it is among the Ossetes.

38. See Post, Afrikanische Jurisprudenz, Oldenburg, 1887. Munzinger, Ueber das Recht und Sitten der Bogos, Winterthur 1859; Casalis, Les Bassoutos, Paris, 1859; Maclean, Kafir Laws and Customs, Mount Coke, 1858, etc.

38. See Post, African Jurisprudence, Oldenburg, 1887. Munzinger, On the Law and Customs of the Bogos, Winterthur 1859; Casalis, The Basutos, Paris, 1859; Maclean, Kafir Laws and Customs, Mount Coke, 1858, etc.

39. Waitz, iii. 423 seq.

39. Waitz, III. 423 et seq.

40. Post's Studien zur Entwicklungsgeschichte des Familien Rechts Oldenburg, 1889, pp. 270 seq.

40. Post's Studies on the Development of Family Law Oldenburg, 1889, pp. 270 and following.

41. Powell, Annual Report of the Bureau of Ethnography, Washington, 1881, quoted in Post's Studien, p. 290; Bastian's Inselgruppen in Oceanien, 1883, p. 88.

41. Powell, Annual Report of the Bureau of Ethnography, Washington, 1881, quoted in Post's Studien, p. 290; Bastian's Inselgruppen in Oceanien, 1883, p. 88.

42. De Stuers, quoted by Waitz, v. 141.

42. De Stuers, as quoted by Waitz, p. 141.

CHAPTER V

MUTUAL AID IN THE MEDIAEVAL CITY

Growth of authority in Barbarian Society. Serfdom in the villages. Revolt of fortified towns: their liberation; their charts. The guild. Double origin of the free medieval city. Self-jurisdiction, self-administration. Honourable position of labour. Trade by the guild and by the city.

Growth of authority in Barbarian Society. Serfdom in the villages. Revolt of fortified towns: their liberation; their charters. The guild. Dual origin of the free medieval city. Self-governance, self-management. Respectable status of labor. Trade by the guild and by the city.

Sociability and need of mutual aid and support are such inherent parts of human nature that at no time of history can we discover men living in small isolated families, fighting each other for the means of subsistence. On the contrary, modern research, as we saw it in the two preceding chapters, proves that since the very beginning of their prehistoric life men used to agglomerate into gentes, clans, or tribes, maintained by an idea of common descent and by worship of common ancestors. For thousands and thousands of years this organization has kept men together, even though there was no authority whatever to impose it. It has deeply impressed all subsequent development of mankind; and when the bonds of common descent had been loosened by migrations on a grand scale, while the development of the separated family within the clan itself had destroyed the old unity of the clan, a new form of union, territorial in its principle—the village community—was called into existence by the social genius of man. This institution, again, kept men together for a number of centuries, permitting them to further develop their social institutions and to pass through some of the darkest periods of history, without being dissolved into loose aggregations of families and individuals, to make a further step in their evolution, and to work out a number of secondary social institutions, several of which have survived down to the present time. We have now to follow the further developments of the same ever-living tendency for mutual aid. Taking the village communities of the so-called barbarians at a time when they were making a new start of civilization after the fall of the Roman Empire, we have to study the new aspects taken by the sociable wants of the masses in the middle ages, and especially in the medieval guilds and the medieval city.

Sociability and the need for mutual aid and support are fundamental aspects of human nature, so throughout history, we can't find people living in small, isolated families, fighting among themselves for basic survival. Instead, as we discussed in the previous two chapters, modern research shows that from the very start of their prehistoric existence, humans formed groups like clans or tribes, connected by a shared sense of ancestry and the veneration of common ancestors. For thousands of years, this organization kept people together, even without any authority enforcing it. It has significantly shaped the development of humanity. When migration weakened the bonds of common ancestry and the evolving family structure within clans diminished their unity, a new form of community based on territory—the village community—was created by human social ingenuity. This institution maintained unity for several centuries, allowing people to further develop their social systems and navigate some of the darkest times in history without breaking apart into loose groups of families and individuals. This enabled them to advance further in their evolution and establish various secondary social institutions, many of which still exist today. We now need to explore the ongoing developments of this enduring tendency for mutual aid. Focusing on the village communities of so-called barbarians at a time when they were beginning a new phase of civilization after the fall of the Roman Empire, we will examine how the social needs of the masses evolved during the Middle Ages, particularly within medieval guilds and cities.

Far from being the fighting animals they have often been compared to, the barbarians of the first centuries of our era (like so many Mongolians, Africans, Arabs, and so on, who still continue in the same barbarian stage) invariably preferred peace to war. With the exception of a few tribes which had been driven during the great migrations into unproductive deserts or highlands, and were thus compelled periodically to prey upon their better-favoured neighbours—apart from these, the great bulk of the Teutons, the Saxons, the Celts, the Slavonians, and so on, very soon after they had settled in their newly-conquered abodes, reverted to the spade or to their herds. The earliest barbarian codes already represent to us societies composed of peaceful agricultural communities, not hordes of men at war with each other. These barbarians covered the country with villages and farmhouses;(1) they cleared the forests, bridged the torrents, and colonized the formerly quite uninhabited wilderness; and they left the uncertain warlike pursuits to brotherhoods, scholae, or "trusts" of unruly men, gathered round temporary chieftains, who wandered about, offering their adventurous spirit, their arms, and their knowledge of warfare for the protection of populations, only too anxious to be left in peace. The warrior bands came and went, prosecuting their family feuds; but the great mass continued to till the soil, taking but little notice of their would-be rulers, so long as they did not interfere with the independence of their village communities.(2) The new occupiers of Europe evolved the systems of land tenure and soil culture which are still in force with hundreds of millions of men; they worked out their systems of compensation for wrongs, instead of the old tribal blood-revenge; they learned the first rudiments of industry; and while they fortified their villages with palisaded walls, or erected towers and earthen forts whereto to repair in case of a new invasion, they soon abandoned the task of defending these towers and forts to those who made of war a speciality.

Far from being the fighting beasts they’re often compared to, the so-called barbarians from the early centuries of our era (like many Mongolians, Africans, Arabs, and others who still exist in a similar state) generally preferred peace over war. Aside from a few tribes that were pushed into barren deserts or rugged highlands during significant migrations and were forced to prey on their more fortunate neighbors periodically—most of the Teutons, Saxons, Celts, and Slavs quickly returned to farming or tending their livestock after settling in their newly-conquered lands. The earliest barbarian codes show us societies made up of peaceful farming communities rather than groups of men constantly at war. These barbarians spread across the land, building villages and farmhouses; they cleared forests, bridged rivers, and settled in previously uninhabited wilderness. They left the uncertain, aggressive pursuits to groups of unruly men, gathered around temporary leaders, who roamed about, offering their adventurous nature, weapons, and knowledge of combat in exchange for protecting communities eager for peace. The warrior bands came and went, fueling their family feuds, but the majority continued to cultivate the land, hardly paying attention to their would-be rulers as long as they didn't disrupt the independence of their village communities. The new inhabitants of Europe developed systems of land ownership and agricultural practices that still exist today for hundreds of millions of people; they created systems of compensation for wrongs, replacing the old tribal blood feuds; they learned the basics of industry; and while they fortified their villages with wooden walls, or built towers and earthen forts to retreat to in case of new invasions, they soon left the duty of defending these structures to those who specialized in warfare.

The very peacefulness of the barbarians, certainly not their supposed warlike instincts, thus became the source of their subsequent subjection to the military chieftains. It is evident that the very mode of life of the armed brotherhoods offered them more facilities for enrichment than the tillers of the soil could find in their agricultural communities. Even now we see that armed men occasionally come together to shoot down Matabeles and to rob them of their droves of cattle, though the Matabeles only want peace and are ready to buy it at a high price. The scholae of old certainly were not more scrupulous than the scholae of our own time. Droves of cattle, iron (which was extremely costly at that time(3)), and slaves were appropriated in this way; and although most acquisitions were wasted on the spot in those glorious feasts of which epic poetry has so much to say—still some part of the robbed riches was used for further enrichment. There was plenty of waste land, and no lack of men ready to till it, if only they could obtain the necessary cattle and implements. Whole villages, ruined by murrains, pests, fires, or raids of new immigrants, were often abandoned by their inhabitants, who went anywhere in search of new abodes. They still do so in Russia in similar circumstances. And if one of the hirdmen of the armed brotherhoods offered the peasants some cattle for a fresh start, some iron to make a plough, if not the plough itself, his protection from further raids, and a number of years free from all obligations, before they should begin to repay the contracted debt, they settled upon the land. And when, after a hard fight with bad crops, inundations and pestilences, those pioneers began to repay their debts, they fell into servile obligations towards the protector of the territory. Wealth undoubtedly did accumulate in this way, and power always follows wealth.(4) And yet, the more we penetrate into the life of those times, the sixth and seventh centuries of our era, the more we see that another element, besides wealth and military force, was required to constitute the authority of the few. It was an element of law and tight, a desire of the masses to maintain peace, and to establish what they considered to be justice, which gave to the chieftains of the scholae—kings, dukes, knyazes, and the like—the force they acquired two or three hundred years later. That same idea of justice, conceived as an adequate revenge for the wrong done, which had grown in the tribal stage, now passed as a red thread through the history of subsequent institutions, and, much more even than military or economic causes, it became the basis upon which the authority of the kings and the feudal lords was founded.

The very calm of the barbarians, definitely not their supposed warrior instincts, became the reason for their later domination by military leaders. It's clear that the way of life of armed groups gave them more opportunities for wealth than the farmers could find in their agricultural communities. Even today, we see armed men occasionally banding together to hunt down the Matabeles and steal their cattle, even though the Matabeles only want peace and are willing to pay a high price for it. The military groups of old were certainly no more principled than those of our time. Cattle, iron (which was very expensive back then), and slaves were taken this way; and although most of what was acquired was wasted in those extravagant feasts of which epic poetry speaks so much—still, some of the stolen riches were used for further gain. There was plenty of unclaimed land, and many people were ready to farm it, if only they could get the necessary cattle and tools. Whole villages, destroyed by disease, pests, fires, or invasions by new immigrants, were often left by their inhabitants, who sought new homes. This still happens in Russia under similar circumstances. If one of the warriors from the armed groups offered the peasants some cattle to start over, some iron to make a plow, if not the plow itself, his protection from further attacks, and several years free of obligations before they were expected to repay their debts, they settled on the land. And when, after struggling through bad harvests, floods, and plagues, those pioneers began to pay off their debts, they found themselves in servile relationships with the protector of the land. Wealth certainly accumulated in this way, and power always follows wealth. Yet, the deeper we dive into the life of those times, the sixth and seventh centuries of our era, the more we realize that another element, besides wealth and military might, was needed to establish the authority of the few. It was an element of law and order, a desire from the masses to maintain peace, and to establish what they viewed as justice, which provided the military leaders—kings, dukes, princes, and so on—the strength they gained two or three hundred years later. That same concept of justice, seen as fitting revenge for wrongs done, which developed during the tribal stage, now ran like a common thread through the history of later institutions, and more than military or economic reasons, it became the foundation upon which the power of kings and feudal lords was built.

In fact, one of the chief preoccupations of the barbarian village community always was, as it still is with our barbarian contemporaries, to put a speedy end to the feuds which arose from the then current conception of justice. When a quarrel took place, the community at once interfered, and after the folkmote had heard the case, it settled the amount of composition (wergeld) to be paid to the wronged person, or to his family, as well as the fred, or fine for breach of peace, which had to be paid to the community. Interior quarrels were easily appeased in this way. But when feuds broke out between two different tribes, or two confederations of tribes, notwithstanding all measures taken to prevent them,(5) the difficulty was to find an arbiter or sentence-finder whose decision should be accepted by both parties alike, both for his impartiality and for his knowledge of the oldest law. The difficulty was the greater as the customary laws of different tribes and confederations were at variance as to the compensation due in different cases. It therefore became habitual to take the sentence-finder from among such families, or such tribes, as were reputed for keeping the law of old in its purity; of being versed in the songs, triads, sagas, etc., by means of which law was perpetuated in memory; and to retain law in this way became a sort of art, a "mystery," carefully transmitted in certain families from generation to generation. Thus in Iceland, and in other Scandinavian lands, at every A11thing, or national folkmote, a lövsögmathr used to recite the whole law from memory for the enlightening of the assembly; and in Ireland there was, as is known, a special class of men reputed for the knowledge of the old traditions, and therefore enjoying a great authority as judges.(6) Again, when we are told by the Russian annals that some stems of North-West Russia, moved by the growing disorder which resulted from "clans rising against clans," appealed to Norman varingiar to be their judges and commanders of warrior scholae; and when we see the knyazes, or dukes, elected for the next two hundred years always from the same Norman family, we cannot but recognize that the Slavonians trusted to the Normans for a better knowledge of the law which would be equally recognized as good by different Slavonian kins. In this case the possession of runes, used for the transmission of old customs, was a decided advantage in favour of the Normans; but in other cases there are faint indications that the "eldest" branch of the stem, the supposed motherbranch, was appealed to to supply the judges, and its decisions were relied upon as just;(7) while at a later epoch we see a distinct tendency towards taking the sentence-finders from the Christian clergy, which, at that time, kept still to the fundamental, now forgotten, principle of Christianity, that retaliation is no act of justice. At that time the Christian clergy opened the churches as places of asylum for those who fled from blood revenge, and they willingly acted as arbiters in criminal cases, always opposing the old tribal principle of life for life and wound for wound. In short, the deeper we penetrate into the history of early institutions, the less we find grounds for the military theory of origin of authority. Even that power which later on became such a source of oppression seems, on the contrary, to have found its origin in the peaceful inclinations of the masses.

In fact, one of the main concerns of the barbarian village community was, and still is for our barbarian contemporaries, to quickly resolve the feuds that arose from their understanding of justice. Whenever a quarrel occurred, the community immediately got involved, and after the folkmote heard the case, it determined the compensation (wergeld) to be paid to the injured person or their family, as well as the fred, or fine for breaking the peace, which had to be paid to the community. Internal disputes were easily settled this way. However, when feuds erupted between different tribes or confederations of tribes, despite all efforts to prevent them, the challenge was finding an arbiter or judge whose decision both sides would accept, based on his impartiality and knowledge of the oldest laws. This was made more difficult by the fact that the customary laws of various tribes and confederations differed regarding compensation for different cases. It thus became common to choose judges from families or tribes known for maintaining the law in its purest form; those well-versed in songs, triads, sagas, and other means by which the law was preserved in memory. Keeping the law in this way became a sort of art, a "mystery," carefully passed down in certain families from generation to generation. Therefore, in Iceland and other Scandinavian countries, at every Althing, or national folkmote, a lövsögmathr would recite the entire law from memory to inform the assembly. In Ireland, there was a well-known class of individuals respected for their knowledge of old traditions, and they held significant power as judges. Furthermore, when the Russian annals inform us that some tribes in Northwest Russia, faced with disorder from "clans rising against clans," sought Norman varingiar to act as their judges and leaders of warrior bands, and when we see that the knyazes, or dukes, were elected from the same Norman family for the next two centuries, we recognize that the Slavonians placed their trust in the Normans for a better understanding of the law, which would be equally acknowledged as just by different Slavonian kin. In this context, the possession of runes, used to transmit ancient customs, was a clear advantage for the Normans. Yet, in other instances, there are slight indications that the "eldest" branch of a lineage, the supposed mother branch, was sought to provide judges, and its decisions were considered fair; while in a later period, we notice a distinct trend toward selecting judges from the Christian clergy, who, at that time, still adhered to the fundamental, now-forgotten principle of Christianity that retaliation is not an act of justice. At that time, the Christian clergy opened churches as safe havens for those fleeing from blood vengeance, and they willingly served as arbitrators in criminal cases, consistently opposing the old tribal principle of life for life and wound for wound. In short, as we delve deeper into the history of early institutions, we find less support for the military theory of the origin of authority. Even the power that later became a source of oppression seems to have originated from the peaceful inclinations of the masses.

In all these cases the fred, which often amounted to half the compensation, went to the folkmote, and from times immemorial it used to be applied to works of common utility and defence. It has still the same destination (the erection of towers) among the Kabyles and certain Mongolian stems; and we have direct evidence that even several centuries later the judicial fines, in Pskov and several French and German cities, continued to be used for the repair of the city walls.(8) It was thus quite natural that the fines should be handed over to the sentence-finder, who was bound, in return, both to maintain the schola of armed men to whom the defence of the territory was trusted, and to execute the sentences. This became a universal custom in the eighth and ninth centuries, even when the sentence-finder was an elected bishop. The germ of a combination of what we should now call the judicial power and the executive thus made its appearance. But to these two functions the attributions of the duke or king were strictly limited. He was no ruler of the people—the supreme power still belonging to the folkmote—not even a commander of the popular militia; when the folk took to arms, it marched under a separate, also elected, commander, who was not a subordinate, but an equal to the king.(9) The king was a lord on his personal domain only. In fact, in barbarian language, the word konung, koning, or cyning synonymous with the Latin rex, had no other meaning than that of a temporary leader or chieftain of a band of men. The commander of a flotilla of boats, or even of a single pirate boat, was also a konung, and till the present day the commander of fishing in Norway is named Not-kong—"the king of the nets."(10) The veneration attached later on to the personality of a king did not yet exist, and while treason to the kin was punished by death, the slaying of a king could be recouped by the payment of compensation: a king simply was valued so much more than a freeman.(11) And when King Knu (or Canute) had killed one man of his own schola, the saga represents him convoking his comrades to a thing where he stood on his knees imploring pardon. He was pardoned, but not till he had agreed to pay nine times the regular composition, of which one-third went to himself for the loss of one of his men, one-third to the relatives of the slain man, and one-third (the fred) to the schola.(12) In reality, a complete change had to be accomplished in the current conceptions, under the double influence of the Church and the students of Roman law, before an idea of sanctity began to be attached to the personality of the king.

In all these cases, the fred, which often made up half the compensation, went to the folkmote and had historically been used for public works and defense. It still serves the same purpose (the building of towers) among the Kabyles and some Mongolian tribes; we even have direct evidence that several centuries later, judicial fines in Pskov and various French and German cities continued to fund the repair of city walls. It was therefore quite natural that the fines would be given to the sentence-finder, who was required to maintain the schola of armed men tasked with the territory's defense and to carry out the sentences. This practice became common in the eighth and ninth centuries, even when the sentence-finder was an elected bishop. The beginnings of what we would now call the judicial power and the executive emerged at this time. However, the powers of the duke or king were still strictly limited. He was not a ruler of the people—the supreme power still belonged to the folkmote—not even the commander of the popular militia; when the folk went to war, they marched under a separate, also elected, commander who was equal to the king, not subordinate to him. The king was a lord only over his personal domain. In barbarian language, the words konung, koning, or cyning, synonymous with the Latin rex, meant nothing more than a temporary leader or chieftain of a band of men. The commander of a flotilla of boats, or even a single pirate vessel, was also called a konung, and to this day, the leader of fishing in Norway is referred to as Not-kong—"the king of the nets." The reverence for the king's personality had not yet developed, and while treason against kin was punishable by death, killing a king could be compensated financially: a king was simply valued much more than a freeman. When King Knu (or Canute) had killed a member of his own schola, the saga describes him gathering his comrades for a meeting where he knelt and begged for forgiveness. He was pardoned, but only after agreeing to pay nine times the usual compensation, with one-third going to himself for the loss of his man, one-third to the relatives of the slain, and one-third (the fred) to the schola. In reality, a complete shift in contemporary beliefs was necessary, influenced by both the Church and Roman law scholars, before any notion of the king’s sanctity emerged.

However, it lies beyond the scope of these essays to follow the gradual development of authority out of the elements just indicated. Historians, such as Mr. and Mrs. Green for this country, Augustin Thierry, Michelet, and Luchaire for France, Kaufmann, Janssen, W. Arnold, and even Nitzsch, for Germany, Leo and Botta for Italy, Byelaeff, Kostomaroff, and their followers for Russia, and many others, have fully told that tale. They have shown how populations, once free, and simply agreeing "to feed" a certain portion of their military defenders, gradually became the serfs of these protectors; how "commendation" to the Church, or to a lord, became a hard necessity for the freeman; how each lord's and bishop's castle became a robber's nest—how feudalism was imposed, in a word—and how the crusades, by freeing the serfs who wore the cross, gave the first impulse to popular emancipation. All this need not be retold in this place, our chief aim being to follow the constructive genius of the masses in their mutual-aid institutions.

However, it's beyond the scope of these essays to trace the gradual development of authority from the elements just mentioned. Historians like Mr. and Mrs. Green for this country, Augustin Thierry, Michelet, and Luchaire for France, Kaufmann, Janssen, W. Arnold, and even Nitzsch for Germany, and Leo and Botta for Italy, as well as Byelaeff, Kostomaroff, and their followers for Russia—and many others—have fully documented that story. They have illustrated how populations, once free and simply agreeing to "support" a specific number of their military defenders, gradually became the serfs of these protectors; how "commendation" to the Church or to a lord became a crucial necessity for the free person; how each lord's and bishop's castle turned into a den of robbery—how feudalism was enforced, in short—and how the crusades, by liberating the serfs who bore the cross, sparked the first push toward popular emancipation. All this doesn’t need to be reiterated here, as our main goal is to follow the innovative spirit of the masses in their mutual-aid institutions.

At a time when the last vestiges of barbarian freedom seemed to disappear, and Europe, fallen under the dominion of thousands of petty rulers, was marching towards the constitution of such theocracies and despotic States as had followed the barbarian stage during the previous starts of civilization, or of barbarian monarchies, such as we see now in Africa, life in Europe took another direction. It went on on lines similar to those it had once taken in the cities of antique Greece. With a unanimity which seems almost incomprehensible, and for a long time was not understood by historians, the urban agglomerations, down to the smallest burgs, began to shake off the yoke of their worldly and clerical lords. The fortified village rose against the lord's castle, defied it first, attacked it next, and finally destroyed it. The movement spread from spot to spot, involving every town on the surface of Europe, and in less than a hundred years free cities had been called into existence on the coasts of the Mediterranean, the North Sea, the Baltic, the Atlantic Ocean, down to the fjords of Scandinavia; at the feet of the Apennines, the Alps, the Black Forest, the Grampians, and the Carpathians; in the plains of Russia, Hungary, France and Spain. Everywhere the same revolt took place, with the same features, passing through the same phases, leading to the same results. Wherever men had found, or expected to find, some protection behind their town walls, they instituted their "co-jurations," their "fraternities," their "friendships," united in one common idea, and boldly marching towards a new life of mutual support and liberty. And they succeeded so well that in three or four hundred years they had changed the very face of Europe. They had covered the country with beautiful sumptuous buildings, expressing the genius of free unions of free men, unrivalled since for their beauty and expressiveness; and they bequeathed to the following generations all the arts, all the industries, of which our present civilization, with all its achievements and promises for the future, is only a further development. And when we now look to the forces which have produced these grand results, we find them—not in the genius of individual heroes, not in the mighty organization of huge States or the political capacities of their rulers, but in the very same current of mutual aid and support which we saw at work in the village community, and which was vivified and reinforced in the Middle Ages by a new form of unions, inspired by the very same spirit but shaped on a new model—the guilds.

At a time when the last remnants of barbarian freedom seemed to fade away, and Europe, under the control of countless petty rulers, was heading toward the formation of theocracies and despotic states similar to those that had followed the barbarian era in earlier stages of civilization, or barbarian monarchies like those we see today in Africa, life in Europe took a different turn. It followed a path reminiscent of the one it had taken in the ancient cities of Greece. With an almost unbelievable unity, which for a long time baffled historians, urban areas, even the smallest towns, began to shake off the control of their worldly and clerical lords. The fortified villages rose against the lord's castle, first challenging it, then attacking it, and finally destroying it. The movement spread from place to place, involving every town across Europe, and in less than a century, free cities had emerged along the Mediterranean, the North Sea, the Baltic, the Atlantic Ocean, down to the fjords of Scandinavia; at the base of the Apennines, the Alps, the Black Forest, the Grampians, and the Carpathians; in the plains of Russia, Hungary, France, and Spain. Everywhere the same uprising occurred, with the same characteristics, going through the same stages, leading to the same outcomes. Wherever people found, or hoped to find, some protection behind their town walls, they formed their "co-jurations," their "fraternities," their "friendships," united by a common goal, boldly moving toward a new life of mutual support and freedom. And they succeeded so remarkably that in three or four hundred years, they transformed the very landscape of Europe. They adorned the land with beautiful, grand buildings, showcasing the creativity of free unions of free men, unmatched in their beauty and expressiveness; and they handed down to future generations all the arts and industries that our current civilization, with all its achievements and hopes for the future, is simply a further development of. Now, when we look at the forces that created these remarkable outcomes, we find them—not in the genius of individual heroes, not in the powerful organization of large states or the political skills of their rulers, but in the same current of mutual aid and support that we saw in the village communities, which was energized and enriched in the Middle Ages by a new form of unions, inspired by the same spirit but organized in a new way—the guilds.

It is well known by this time that feudalism did not imply a dissolution of the village community. Although the lord had succeeded in imposing servile labour upon the peasants, and had appropriated for himself such rights as were formerly vested in the village community alone (taxes, mortmain, duties on inheritances and marriages), the peasants had, nevertheless, maintained the two fundamental rights of their communities: the common possession of the land, and self-jurisdiction. In olden times, when a king sent his vogt to a village, the peasants received him with flowers in one hand and arms in the other, and asked him—which law he intended to apply: the one he found in the village, or the one he brought with him? And, in the first case, they handed him the flowers and accepted him; while in the second case they fought him.(13) Now, they accepted the king's or the lord's official whom they could not refuse; but they maintained the folkmote's jurisdiction, and themselves nominated six, seven, or twelve judges, who acted with the lord's judge, in the presence of the folkmote, as arbiters and sentence-finders. In most cases the official had nothing left to him but to confirm the sentence and to levy the customary fred. This precious right of self-jurisdiction, which, at that time, meant self-administration and self-legislation, had been maintained through all the struggles; and even the lawyers by whom Karl the Great was surrounded could not abolish it; they were bound to confirm it. At the same time, in all matters concerning the community's domain, the folkmote retained its supremacy and (as shown by Maurer) often claimed submission from the lord himself in land tenure matters. No growth of feudalism could break this resistance; the village community kept its ground; and when, in the ninth and tenth centuries, the invasions of the Normans, the Arabs, and the Ugrians had demonstrated that military scholae were of little value for protecting the land, a general movement began all over Europe for fortifying the villages with stone walls and citadels. Thousands of fortified centres were then built by the energies of the village communities; and, once they had built their walls, once a common interest had been created in this new sanctuary—the town walls—they soon understood that they could henceforward resist the encroachments of the inner enemies, the lords, as well as the invasions of foreigners. A new life of freedom began to develop within the fortified enclosures. The medieval city was born.(14)

It is now well understood that feudalism didn’t mean the end of the village community. Even though the lord managed to impose forced labor on the peasants and claimed rights that were previously exclusive to the village community (like taxes, mortmain, and duties on inheritances and marriages), the peasants still upheld two essential rights of their communities: shared land ownership and self-governance. Back in the day, when a king sent his bailiff to a village, the peasants welcomed him with flowers in one hand and weapons in the other, asking him which law he intended to apply: the one established in the village or the one he brought with him? If he chose the village law, they offered him flowers and accepted him; if he chose his own, they fought him. Nowadays, they accepted the king's or lord's representative, whom they couldn’t refuse, but they held on to the folkmote's authority, electing six, seven, or twelve judges to work alongside the lord's judge, in front of the folkmote, as arbiters and decision-makers. In most cases, the official had little to do except confirm the verdict and collect the customary fees. This valuable right of self-governance, which at that time meant self-administration and self-legislation, had survived all the struggles; even the lawyers surrounding Charlemagne couldn’t abolish it; they had to recognize it. At the same time, in issues regarding the community's land, the folkmote retained its authority and often insisted on submission from the lord himself regarding land ownership issues, as Maurer noted. No expansion of feudalism could undermine this resistance; the village community held its ground. When, in the ninth and tenth centuries, invasions by the Normans, Arabs, and Ugrians showed that military schools were ineffective for land protection, a widespread movement started across Europe to fortify villages with stone walls and citadels. Thousands of fortified centers were constructed by the efforts of the village communities; once they built their walls and established a collective interest in this new sanctuary—the town walls—they quickly recognized their ability to resist encroachments from internal enemies, the lords, as well as foreign invasions. A new era of freedom began to flourish within the fortified enclosures. The medieval city was born.

No period of history could better illustrate the constructive powers of the popular masses than the tenth and eleventh centuries, when the fortified villages and market-places, representing so many "oases amidst the feudal forest," began to free themselves from their lord's yoke, and slowly elaborated the future city organization; but, unhappily, this is a period about which historical information is especially scarce: we know the results, but little has reached us about the means by which they were achieved. Under the protection of their walls the cities' folkmotes—either quite independent, or led by the chief noble or merchant families—conquered and maintained the right of electing the military defensor and supreme judge of the town, or at least of choosing between those who pretended to occupy this position. In Italy the young communes were continually sending away their defensors or domini, fighting those who refused to go. The same went on in the East. In Bohemia, rich and poor alike (Bohemicae gentis magni et parvi, nobiles et ignobiles) took part in the election;(15) while, the vyeches (folkmotes) of the Russian cities regularly elected their dukes—always from the same Rurik family—covenanted with them, and sent the knyaz away if he had provoked discontent.(16) At the same time in most cities of Western and Southern Europe, the tendency was to take for defensor a bishop whom the city had elected itself; and so many bishops took the lead in protecting the "immunities" of the towns and in defending their liberties, that numbers of them were considered, after their death, as saints and special patrons of different cities. St. Uthelred of Winchester, St. Ulrik of Augsburg, St. Wolfgang of Ratisbon, St. Heribert of Cologne, St. Adalbert of Prague, and so on, as well as many abbots and monks, became so many cities' saints for having acted in defence of popular rights.(17) And under the new defensors, whether laic or clerical, the citizens conquered full self-jurisdiction and self-administration for their folkmotes.(18)

No period of history illustrates the creative power of the common people better than the 10th and 11th centuries, when fortified villages and marketplaces, seen as "oases in the feudal forest," began to break free from their lords' control and slowly developed the future city structure. Unfortunately, this is a time about which we have very little historical information: we know the outcomes, but not much about how they were achieved. Protected by their walls, the cities’ folk assemblies—either completely independent or led by the chief nobles or merchant families—struggled for and secured the right to elect the military defender and the chief judge of the town, or at least to choose among those vying for these roles. In Italy, the emerging communes consistently sent away their defenders or domini, often battling those who refused to leave. The same was happening in the East. In Bohemia, both the rich and the poor (Bohemicae gentis magni et parvi, nobiles et ignobiles) participated in the elections; while the vyaches (folk assemblies) of the Russian cities regularly elected their dukes—always from the same Rurik family—made agreements with them, and dismissed the knyaz if he caused dissatisfaction. Meanwhile, in most cities of Western and Southern Europe, there was a trend to choose a bishop, whom the city had elected, as their defender; many bishops took the lead in protecting the towns' "immunities" and defending their liberties, so much so that numerous bishops were regarded as saints and special patrons of various cities after their deaths. St. Uthelred of Winchester, St. Ulrik of Augsburg, St. Wolfgang of Ratisbon, St. Heribert of Cologne, St. Adalbert of Prague, and many abbots and monks became the patron saints of these cities for their defense of popular rights. Under the new defenders, whether lay or clerical, the citizens gained full self-jurisdiction and self-administration for their folk assemblies.

The whole process of liberation progressed by a series of imperceptible acts of devotion to the common cause, accomplished by men who came out of the masses—by unknown heroes whose very names have not been preserved by history. The wonderful movement of the God's peace (treuga Dei) by which the popular masses endeavoured to put a limit to the endless family feuds of the noble families, was born in the young towns, the bishops and the citizens trying to extend to the nobles the peace they had established within their town walls.(19) Already at that period, the commercial cities of Italy, and especially Amalfi (which had its elected consuls since 844, and frequently changed its doges in the tenth century)(20) worked out the customary maritime and commercial law which later on became a model for all Europe; Ravenna elaborated its craft organization, and Milan, which had made its first revolution in 980, became a great centre of commerce, its trades enjoying a full independence since the eleventh century.(21) So also Brugge and Ghent; so also several cities of France in which the Mahl or forum had become a quite independent institution.(22) And already during that period began the work of artistic decoration of the towns by works of architecture, which we still admire and which loudly testify of the intellectual movement of the times. "The basilicae were then renewed in almost all the universe," Raoul Glaber wrote in his chronicle, and some of the finest monuments of medieval architecture date from that period: the wonderful old church of Bremen was built in the ninth century, Saint Marc of Venice was finished in 1071, and the beautiful dome of Pisa in 1063. In fact, the intellectual movement which has been described as the Twelfth Century Renaissance(23) and the Twelfth Century Rationalism—the precursor of the Reform(24) date from that period, when most cities were still simple agglomerations of small village communities enclosed by walls.

The whole process of liberation progressed through a series of subtle acts of commitment to the common cause, carried out by ordinary people—unknown heroes whose names history hasn’t preserved. The remarkable movement of God’s peace (treuga Dei), where the common people tried to limit the endless family feuds of noble families, emerged in the young towns, with bishops and citizens attempting to extend the peace they had found within their town walls to the nobles. During that time, the commercial cities of Italy, especially Amalfi (which had elected consuls since 844 and frequently changed its doges in the tenth century), developed customary maritime and commercial law that would later serve as a model for all of Europe. Ravenna crafted its craft organization, while Milan, which had its first revolution in 980, became a major commerce hub, with its trades enjoying full independence since the eleventh century. This was also true for Brugge and Ghent, as well as several cities in France where the Mahl or forum had become a completely independent institution. During this period, the artistic decoration of towns began, featuring architectural works that we still admire today, which powerfully reflect the intellectual movement of the times. "The basilicas were then renewed all over the world," Raoul Glaber wrote in his chronicle, and some of the finest examples of medieval architecture date back to this period: the remarkable old church of Bremen was built in the ninth century, Saint Mark's in Venice was completed in 1071, and the beautiful dome of Pisa was constructed in 1063. Indeed, the intellectual movement known as the Twelfth Century Renaissance and Twelfth Century Rationalism—the precursor to the Reform—originated during this time, when most cities were still simple clusters of small village communities surrounded by walls.

However, another element, besides the village-community principle, was required to give to these growing centres of liberty and enlightenment the unity of thought and action, and the powers of initiative, which made their force in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. With the growing diversity of occupations, crafts and arts, and with the growing commerce in distant lands, some new form of union was required, and this necessary new element was supplied by the guilds. Volumes and volumes have been written about these unions which, under the name of guilds, brotherhoods, friendships and druzhestva, minne, artels in Russia, esnaifs in Servia and Turkey, amkari in Georgia, and so on, took such a formidable development in medieval times and played such an important part in the emancipation of the cities. But it took historians more than sixty years before the universality of this institution and its true characters were understood. Only now, when hundreds of guild statutes have been published and studied, and their relationship to the Roman collegiae, and the earlier unions in Greece and in India,(25) is known, can we maintain with full confidence that these brotherhoods were but a further development of the same principles which we saw at work in the gens and the village community.

However, another element, besides the village-community principle, was needed to give these growing centers of liberty and enlightenment the unity of thought and action, and the initiative that made them powerful in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. With the increasing diversity of occupations, crafts, and arts, along with expanding trade in distant lands, a new form of union was necessary, and this essential new element was provided by the guilds. Many volumes have been written about these unions, which, under names like guilds, brotherhoods, friendships, and druzhestva, minne, artels in Russia, esnaifs in Serbia and Turkey, and amkari in Georgia, developed significantly in medieval times and played an important role in the cities' liberation. Yet, it took historians over sixty years to grasp the universality of this institution and its true nature. Only now, as hundreds of guild statutes have been published and studied, and their connections to the Roman collegiae, as well as earlier unions in Greece and India, are understood, can we confidently assert that these brotherhoods were simply an extension of the same principles we observed in the gens and the village community.

Nothing illustrates better these medieval brother hoods than those temporary guilds which were formed on board ships. When a ship of the Hansa had accomplished her first half-day passage after having left the port, the captain (Schiffer) gathered all crew and passengers on the deck, and held the following language, as reported by a contemporary:—

Nothing illustrates these medieval brotherhoods better than the temporary guilds formed on board ships. When a Hansa ship had completed its first half-day journey after leaving port, the captain (Schiffer) gathered all the crew and passengers on deck and said the following, as noted by a contemporary:—

"'As we are now at the mercy of God and the waves,' he said, 'each one must be equal to each other. And as we are surrounded by storms, high waves, pirates and other dangers, we must keep a strict order that we may bring our voyage to a good end. That is why we shall pronounce the prayer for a good wind and good success, and, according to marine law, we shall name the occupiers of the judges' seats (Schoffenstellen).' Thereupon the crew elected a Vogt and four scabini, to act as their judges. At the end of the voyage the Vogt and the scabini abdicated their functions and addressed the crew as follows:—'What has happened on board ship, we must pardon to each other and consider as dead (todt und ab sein lassen). What we have judged right, was for the sake of justice. This is why we beg you all, in the name of honest justice, to forget all the animosity one may nourish against another, and to swear on bread and salt that he will not think of it in a bad spirit. If any one, however, considers himself wronged, he must appeal to the land Vogt and ask justice from him before sunset.' On landing, the Stock with the fredfines was handed over to the Vogt of the sea-port for distribution among the poor."(26)

"'As we are now at the mercy of God and the waves,' he said, 'everyone must be equal to one another. And since we are surrounded by storms, high waves, pirates, and other dangers, we need to maintain strict order to ensure our voyage ends well. That's why we will say the prayer for good wind and success, and, according to maritime law, we will appoint the judges (Schoffenstellen).' Then, the crew elected a Vogt and four scabini to act as their judges. At the end of the voyage, the Vogt and the scabini stepped down from their roles and addressed the crew as follows:—'What has happened on board, we must forgive each other and consider as forgotten. What we deemed right was for the sake of justice. That is why we ask you all, in the name of honest justice, to let go of any animosity you may feel toward one another and to swear on bread and salt that you will not harbor any ill will. However, if anyone feels wronged, they must appeal to the land Vogt and seek justice from him before sunset.' Upon landing, the Stock with the fredfines was handed over to the Vogt of the sea-port for distribution among the poor."

This simple narrative, perhaps better than anything else, depicts the spirit of the medieval guilds. Like organizations came into existence wherever a group of men—fishermen, hunters, travelling merchants, builders, or settled craftsmen—came together for a common pursuit. Thus, there was on board ship the naval authority of the captain; but, for the very success of the common enterprise, all men on board, rich and poor, masters and crew, captain and sailors, agreed to be equals in their mutual relations, to be simply men, bound to aid each other and to settle their possible disputes before judges elected by all of them. So also when a number of craftsmen—masons, carpenters, stone-cutters, etc.—came together for building, say, a cathedral, they all belonged to a city which had its political organization, and each of them belonged moreover to his own craft; but they were united besides by their common enterprise, which they knew better than any one else, and they joined into a body united by closer, although temporary, bonds; they founded the guild for the building of the cathedral.(27) We may see the same till now in the Kabylian. cof:(28) the Kabyles have their village community; but this union is not sufficient for all political, commercial, and personal needs of union, and the closer brotherhood of the cof is constituted.

This straightforward story illustrates the essence of medieval guilds more clearly than anything else. Similar organizations emerged wherever groups of people—fishermen, hunters, traveling merchants, builders, or settled artisans—came together for a shared goal. On board a ship, the captain held naval authority; however, for the success of the common venture, everyone on board, regardless of wealth or position—masters and crew, captain and sailors—agreed to regard each other as equals, simply human beings committed to supporting one another and resolving any disputes before judges they all elected. Likewise, when a group of artisans—masons, carpenters, stone-cutters, etc.—came together to construct, say, a cathedral, they all belonged to a city with its own political structure, and each was also part of his specific craft; but they were additionally united by their shared project, which they understood better than anyone else, forming a community bonded by closer, albeit temporary, ties; they established a guild dedicated to the cathedral's construction. We can still see something similar today in the Kabylian cof: the Kabyles have their village community; however, this union alone is not enough to address all political, commercial, and personal needs, so they create the closer brotherhood of the cof.

As to the social characters of the medieval guild, any guild-statute may illustrate them. Taking, for instance, the skraa of some early Danish guild, we read in it, first, a statement of the general brotherly feelings which must reign in the guild; next come the regulations relative to self-jurisdiction in cases of quarrels arising between two brothers, or a brother and a stranger; and then, the social duties of the brethren are enumerated. If a brother's house is burned, or he has lost his ship, or has suffered on a pilgrim's voyage, all the brethren must come to his aid. If a brother falls dangerously ill, two brethren must keep watch by his bed till he is out of danger, and if he dies, the brethren must bury him—a great affair in those times of pestilences—and follow him to the church and the grave. After his death they must provide for his children, if necessary; very often the widow becomes a sister to the guild.(29)

As for the social aspects of medieval guilds, any guild statute can illustrate them. For example, in the rules of an early Danish guild, we first see a statement about the brotherly feelings that should exist within the guild; following that are the rules regarding self-jurisdiction in disputes between two members or between a member and an outsider; and finally, the social responsibilities of the members are listed. If a member’s house burns down, he loses his ship, or faces hardships on a pilgrimage, all members must come to help him. If a member becomes seriously ill, two members must keep vigil by his bedside until he recovers, and if he passes away, the members must bury him—a significant event during those times of plagues—and accompany him to the church and the grave. After his death, they must take care of his children if needed; often, the widow becomes a sister to the guild.

These two leading features appeared in every brotherhood formed for any possible purpose. In each case the members treated each other as, and named each other, brother and sister;(30) all were equals before the guild. They owned some "chattel" (cattle, land, buildings, places of worship, or "stock") in common. All brothers took the oath of abandoning all feuds of old; and, without imposing upon each other the obligation of never quarrelling again, they agreed that no quarrel should degenerate into a feud, or into a law-suit before another court than the tribunal of the brothers themselves. And if a brother was involved in a quarrel with a stranger to the guild, they agreed to support him for bad and for good; that is, whether he was unjustly accused of aggression, or really was the aggressor, they had to support him, and to bring things to a peaceful end. So long as his was not a secret aggression—in which case he would have been treated as an outlaw—the brotherhood stood by him.(31) If the relatives of the wronged man wanted to revenge the offence at once by a new aggression, the brother-hood supplied him with a horse to run away, or with a boat, a pair of oars, a knife and a steel for striking light; if he remained in town, twelve brothers accompanied him to protect him; and in the meantime they arranged the composition. They went to court to support by oath the truthfulness of his statements, and if he was found guilty they did not let him go to full ruin and become a slave through not paying the due compensation: they all paid it, just as the gens did in olden times. Only when a brother had broken the faith towards his guild-brethren, or other people, he was excluded from the brotherhood "with a Nothing's name" (tha scal han maeles af brodrescap met nidings nafn).(32)

These two main features were present in every brotherhood formed for any purpose. In each case, the members treated each other as brother and sister, and referred to each other as such; all were equal within the guild. They shared some "chattel" (cattle, land, buildings, places of worship, or stock) in common. All brothers took an oath to abandon all past feuds; and, without making each other promise to never argue again, they agreed that no argument should escalate into a feud or be taken to any court other than the brothers' own tribunal. If a brother found himself in a conflict with someone outside the guild, they agreed to support him, whether he was wrongfully accused of aggression or actually was the aggressor, with the aim of resolving things peacefully. As long as his aggression wasn’t secret—otherwise he would be treated as an outlaw—the brotherhood stood by him. If the relatives of the wronged person wanted to take immediate revenge through new aggression, the brotherhood provided him with a horse to escape, or with a boat, a pair of oars, a knife, and a flint; if he stayed in town, twelve brothers accompanied him for his protection; and in the meantime, they arranged for a settlement. They went to court to affirm the truth of his statements under oath, and if he was found guilty, they ensured he didn't end up in complete ruin or become a slave for failing to pay the required compensation: they all contributed, just like the gens did in ancient times. Only when a brother betrayed the trust of his guild-mates or others was he expelled from the brotherhood "with a Nothing's name."

Such were the leading ideas of those brotherhoods which gradually covered the whole of medieval life. In fact, we know of guilds among all possible professions: guilds of serfs,(33) guilds of freemen, and guilds of both serfs and freemen; guilds called into life for the special purpose of hunting, fishing, or a trading expedition, and dissolved when the special purpose had been achieved; and guilds lasting for centuries in a given craft or trade. And, in proportion as life took an always greater variety of pursuits, the variety in the guilds grew in proportion. So we see not only merchants, craftsmen, hunters, and peasants united in guilds; we also see guilds of priests, painters, teachers of primary schools and universities, guilds for performing the passion play, for building a church, for developing the "mystery" of a given school of art or craft, or for a special recreation—even guilds among beggars, executioners, and lost women, all organized on the same double principle of self-jurisdiction and mutual support.(34) For Russia we have positive evidence showing that the very "making of Russia" was as much the work of its hunters', fishermen's, and traders' artels as of the budding village communities, and up to the present day the country is covered with artels.(35)

These were the main ideas behind the brotherhoods that gradually encompassed all aspects of medieval life. In fact, we know there were guilds for every type of profession: guilds of serfs, guilds of freemen, and guilds that included both serfs and freemen; guilds formed specifically for hunting, fishing, or trading expeditions that dissolved once their goals were met; and guilds that lasted for centuries in specific crafts or trades. As life expanded to include a wider variety of activities, the diversity among the guilds grew as well. We see not just merchants, craftsmen, hunters, and peasants united in guilds, but also guilds for priests, painters, teachers at primary and university levels, guilds for performing passion plays, for building churches, for developing the "mystique" of a particular art or craft, or for specific recreation—even guilds among beggars, executioners, and marginalized women, all organized around the same principles of self-governance and mutual support. In Russia, there is clear evidence that the very foundation of Russia was built as much by the efforts of its hunter, fisherman, and trader artels as by the emerging village communities, and even today the country is filled with artels.

These few remarks show how incorrect was the view taken by some early explorers of the guilds when they wanted to see the essence of the institution in its yearly festival. In reality, the day of the common meal was always the day, or the morrow of the day, of election of aldermen, of discussion of alterations in the statutes, and very often the day of judgment of quarrels that had risen among the brethren,(36) or of renewed allegiance to the guild. The common meal, like the festival at the old tribal folkmote—the mahl or malum—or the Buryate aba, or the parish feast and the harvest supper, was simply an affirmation of brotherhood. It symbolized the times when everything was kept in common by the clan. This day, at least, all belonged to all; all sate at the same table and partook of the same meal. Even at a much later time the inmate of the almshouse of a London guild sat this day by the side of the rich alderman. As to the distinction which several explorers have tried to establish between the old Saxon "frith guild" and the so-called "social" or "religious" guilds—all were frith guilds in the sense above mentioned,(37) and all were religious in the sense in which a village community or a city placed under the protection of a special saint is social and religious. If the institution of the guild has taken such an immense extension in Asia, Africa, and Europe, if it has lived thousands of years, reappearing again and again when similar conditions called it into existence, it is because it was much more than an eating association, or an association for going to church on a certain day, or a burial club. It answered to a deeply inrooted want of human nature; and it embodied all the attributes which the State appropriated later on for its bureaucracy and police, and much more than that. It was an association for mutual support in all circumstances and in all accidents of life, "by deed and advise," and it was an organization for maintaining justice—with this difference from the State, that on all these occasions a humane, a brotherly element was introduced instead of the formal element which is the essential characteristic of State interference. Even when appearing before the guild tribunal, the guild-brother answered before men who knew him well and had stood by him before in their daily work, at the common meal, in the performance of their brotherly duties: men who were his equals and brethren indeed, not theorists of law nor defenders of some one else's interests.(38)

These few comments illustrate how misguided some early explorers were in their view of guilds when they believed the core of the institution was its annual festival. In truth, the day of the shared meal was always on the day of, or the day after, the election of aldermen, discussions about changes to the rules, and often the day for resolving disputes that had arisen among the members, or for renewing loyalty to the guild. The common meal, like the festival at the old tribal gathering—the mahl or malum—or the Buryate aba, or the parish feast and the harvest supper, was simply a celebration of brotherhood. It represented times when everything was shared by the community. On this day, at least, everyone belonged to everyone; all sat at the same table and shared the same meal. Even much later, the resident of a London guild's almshouse would sit alongside a wealthy alderman on this day. Regarding the distinction that various explorers have tried to make between the old Saxon "frith guild" and the so-called "social" or "religious" guilds—all of them were frith guilds in the aforementioned sense, and all were religious in the way a village community or a city protected by a specific saint is both social and religious. If the guild institution has expanded so significantly in Asia, Africa, and Europe, if it has endured for thousands of years, reappearing time and again under similar circumstances, it’s because it was much more than just a dining club, or a group that went to church on a particular day, or a burial society. It fulfilled a deeply rooted need in human nature and included all the qualities that the State later claimed for its bureaucracy and police, and much more. It was an association for mutual aid in all situations and life’s challenges, "by deed and advice," and it was an organization for upholding justice—with the distinction from the State that in all these instances, a compassionate, brotherly aspect was introduced instead of the formal element that characterizes State intervention. Even when appearing before the guild tribunal, the guild member was judged by people who knew him well and had supported him in their daily activities, at the shared meal, and in fulfilling their brotherly responsibilities: people who were his equals and true brothers, not legal theorists or defenders of someone else's interests.

It is evident that an institution so well suited to serve the need of union, without depriving the individual of his initiative, could but spread, grow, and fortify. The difficulty was only to find such form as would permit to federate the unions of the guilds without interfering with the unions of the village communities, and to federate all these into one harmonious whole. And when this form of combination had been found, and a series of favourable circumstances permitted the cities to affirm their independence, they did so with a unity of thought which can but excite our admiration, even in our century of railways, telegraphs, and printing. Hundreds of charters in which the cities inscribed their liberation have reached us, and through all of them—notwithstanding the infinite variety of details, which depended upon the more or less greater fulness of emancipation—the same leading ideas run. The city organized itself as a federation of both small village communities and guilds.

It’s clear that an institution designed to meet the need for unity while allowing individuals to retain their initiative could only expand, grow, and strengthen. The challenge was to find a structure that would enable the unions of the guilds to come together without disrupting the unions of the village communities, and to unite all of these into one cohesive entity. Once this form of combination was discovered, and a series of favorable conditions allowed the cities to assert their independence, they did so with a unity of purpose that is truly admirable, even in our age of railways, telegraphs, and printing. We’ve received hundreds of charters in which the cities recorded their liberation, and despite the countless variations in details, influenced by how fully they achieved emancipation, the same core ideas are present throughout. The city organized itself as a federation of both small village communities and guilds.

"All those who belong to the friendship of the town"—so runs a charter given in 1188 to the burghesses of Aire by Philip, Count of Flanders—"have promised and confirmed by faith and oath that they will aid each other as brethren, in whatever is useful and honest. That if one commits against another an offence in words or in deeds, the one who has suffered there from will not take revenge, either himself or his people … he will lodge a complaint and the offender will make good for his offence, according to what will be pronounced by twelve elected judges acting as arbiters, And if the offender or the offended, after having been warned thrice, does not submit to the decision of the arbiters, he will be excluded from the friendship as a wicked man and a perjuror.(39)

"All those who are part of the town's friendships"—this is stated in a charter given in 1188 to the citizens of Aire by Philip, Count of Flanders—"have promised and confirmed by their faith and oath that they will support each other as brothers in whatever is useful and honest. If one person commits an offense against another in words or deeds, the one who has been wronged will not seek revenge, either personally or through their people … they will report the issue, and the offender will make amends for their offense, based on what will be decided by twelve elected judges serving as arbiters. And if either the offender or the one wronged does not agree to the arbiters' decision after being warned three times, they will be excluded from the friendship for being wicked and perjurious."

"Each one of the men of the commune will be faithful to his con-juror, and will give him aid and advice, according to what justice will dictate him"—the Amiens and Abbeville charters say. "All will aid each other, according to their powers, within the boundaries of the Commune, and will not suffer that any one takes anything from any one of them, or makes one pay contributions"—do we read in the charters of Soissons, Compiegne, Senlis, and many others of the same type.(40) And so on with countless variations on the same theme.

"Each person in the community will be loyal to their fellow member and will offer support and advice as justice requires," say the charters of Amiens and Abbeville. "Everyone will assist each other to the best of their abilities within the limits of the community, and will not allow anyone to take anything from any of them or impose payments," we read in the charters of Soissons, Compiègne, Senlis, and many others like them. And so on with countless variations on the same theme.

"The Commune," Guilbert de Nogent wrote, "is an oath of mutual aid (mutui adjutorii conjuratio) … A new and detestable word. Through it the serfs (capite sensi) are freed from all serfdom; through it, they can only be condemned to a legally determined fine for breaches of the law; through it, they cease to be liable to payments which the serfs always used to pay."(41)

"The Commune," Guilbert de Nogent wrote, "is an oath of mutual assistance (mutui adjutorii conjuratio) … A new and terrible term. Through it, the serfs (capite sensi) are freed from all servitude; through it, they can only be penalized with a legally set fine for violating the law; through it, they no longer have to make the payments that the serfs always had to pay."(41)

The same wave of emancipation ran, in the twelfth century, through all parts of the continent, involving both rich cities and the poorest towns. And if we may say that, as a rule, the Italian cities were the first to free themselves, we can assign no centre from which the movement would have spread. Very often a small burg in central Europe took the lead for its region, and big agglomerations accepted the little town's charter as a model for their own. Thus, the charter of a small town, Lorris, was adopted by eighty-three towns in south-west France, and that of Beaumont became the model for over five hundred towns and cities in Belgium and France. Special deputies were dispatched by the cities to their neighbours to obtain a copy from their charter, and the constitution was framed upon that model. However, they did not simply copy each other: they framed their own charters in accordance with the concessions they had obtained from their lords; and the result was that, as remarked by an historian, the charters of the medieval communes offer the same variety as the Gothic architecture of their churches and cathedrals. The same leading ideas in all of them—the cathedral symbolizing the union of parish and guild in the, city—and the same infinitely rich variety of detail.

The same wave of freedom swept across the continent in the twelfth century, affecting both wealthy cities and the poorest towns. While it's fair to say that Italian cities were generally the first to gain their independence, there's no specific center from which this movement originated. Often, a small town in central Europe would take the lead in its area, and larger cities would adopt the smaller town's charter as a template for their own. For example, the charter of a small town, Lorris, was embraced by eighty-three towns in southwest France, and Beaumont's charter became the model for over five hundred towns and cities in Belgium and France. Special representatives were sent from these cities to their neighbors to request a copy of their charters, and the constitutions were based on that framework. However, they didn’t just copy each other; they created their own charters based on the rights they had negotiated with their lords. As a historian noted, the charters of the medieval communes provide the same diversity as the Gothic architecture of their churches and cathedrals, featuring the same main themes—the cathedral representing the unity of the parish and guild in the city—and the same endless variety of details.

Self-jurisdiction was the essential point, and self-jurisdiction meant self-administration. But the commune was not simply an "autonomous" part of the State—such ambiguous words had not yet been invented by that time—it was a State in itself. It had the right of war and peace, of federation and alliance with its neighbours. It was sovereign in its own affairs, and mixed with no others. The supreme political power could be vested entirely in a democratic forum, as was the case in Pskov, whose vyeche sent and received ambassadors, concluded treaties, accepted and sent away princes, or went on without them for dozens of years; or it was vested in, or usurped by, an aristocracy of merchants or even nobles, as was the case in hundreds of Italian and middle European cities. The principle, nevertheless, remained the same: the city was a State and—what was perhaps still more remarkable—when the power in the city was usurped by an aristocracy of merchants or even nobles, the inner life of the city and the democratism of its daily life did not disappear: they depended but little upon what may be called the political form of the State.

Self-jurisdiction was the key issue, and self-jurisdiction meant self-management. But the commune wasn’t just an "autonomous" part of the State—those vague terms hadn’t been created yet—it was a State on its own. It had the authority to declare war and peace, form federations, and create alliances with its neighbors. It was sovereign in its own matters, without interference from others. The ultimate political power could entirely rest with a democratic assembly, like in Pskov, where the vyeche sent and received ambassadors, made treaties, welcomed and sent away princes, or carried on without them for years; or it could be held or taken over by a merchant or noble aristocracy, as happened in many Italian and central European cities. The principle, however, remained constant: the city was a State and—perhaps even more interesting—when power in the city was taken over by a merchant or noble aristocracy, the city's internal life and the democratic nature of everyday life didn’t vanish; they were largely unaffected by what might be referred to as the political structure of the State.

The secret of this seeming anomaly lies in the fact that a medieval city was not a centralized State. During the first centuries of its existence, the city hardly could be named a State as regards its interior organization, because the middle ages knew no more of the present centralization of functions than of the present territorial centralization. Each group had its share of sovereignty. The city was usually divided into four quarters, or into five to seven sections radiating from a centre, each quarter or section roughly corresponding to a certain trade or profession which prevailed in it, but nevertheless containing inhabitants of different social positions and occupations—nobles, merchants, artisans, or even half-serfs; and each section or quarter constituted a quite independent agglomeration. In Venice, each island was an independent political community. It had its own organized trades, its own commerce in salt, its own jurisdiction and administration, its own forum; and the nomination of a doge by the city changed nothing in the inner independence of the units.(42) In Cologne, we see the inhabitants divided into Geburschaften and Heimschaften (viciniae), i.e. neighbour guilds, which dated from the Franconian period. Each of them had its judge (Burrichter) and the usual twelve elected sentence-finders (Schoffen), its Vogt, and its greve or commander of the local militia.(43) The story of early London before the Conquest—Mr. Green says—is that "of a number of little groups scattered here and there over the area within the walls, each growing up with its own life and institutions, guilds, sokes, religious houses and the like, and only slowly drawing together into a municipal union."(44) And if we refer to the annals of the Russian cities, Novgorod and Pskov, both of which are relatively rich in local details, we find the section (konets) consisting of independent streets (ulitsa), each of which, though chiefly peopled with artisans of a certain craft, had also merchants and landowners among its inhabitants, and was a separate community. It had the communal responsibility of all members in case of crime, its own jurisdiction and administration by street aldermen (ulichanskiye starosty), its own seal and, in case of need, its own forum; its own militia, as also its self-elected priests and its, own collective life and collective enterprise.(45)

The secret to this apparent anomaly lies in the fact that a medieval city wasn’t a centralized state. During its early years, the city couldn’t really be called a state in terms of its internal organization, as the Middle Ages didn’t have the same level of centralization of functions or territory that we see today. Each group shared its own sovereignty. The city was typically divided into four quarters or into five to seven sections radiating from a center, with each quarter or section roughly corresponding to a specific trade or profession prevalent there, but still containing residents from various social backgrounds and occupations—nobles, merchants, artisans, or even semi-serfs. Each section or quarter functioned as an independent community. In Venice, each island was its own political entity, complete with organized trades, salt commerce, its own legal and administrative systems, and its own marketplace; the election of a doge did not change the internal independence of these units. In Cologne, the inhabitants were divided into Geburschaften and Heimschaften (neighbor guilds), which dated back to the Franconian period. Each had its own judge (Burrichter) and the usual twelve elected assessors (Schoffen), a Vogt, and a greve or local militia commander. The early history of London before the Conquest, as Mr. Green describes, involved “a number of little groups scattered throughout the area within the walls, each developing its own life and institutions, guilds, sokes, religious houses, and so on, and only gradually coming together into a municipal union.” And in the records of the Russian cities, Novgorod and Pskov, which have rich local details, we find sections (konets) made up of independent streets (ulitsa), each primarily inhabited by artisans of a particular craft but also including merchants and landowners. Each street was a separate community with collective responsibility for crimes, its own legal system and administration by street elders (ulichanskiye starosty), its own seal, and when needed, its own marketplace; it had its own militia, self-elected priests, and a shared community life and enterprises.

The medieval city thus appears as a double federation: of all householders united into small territorial unions—the street, the parish, the section—and of individuals united by oath into guilds according to their professions; the former being a produce of the village-community origin of the city, while the second is a subsequent growth called to life by new conditions.

The medieval city can be seen as a dual federation: all homeowners grouped into small territorial unions—the street, the parish, the section—and individuals bonded by oath into guilds based on their professions; the former arises from the village-community roots of the city, while the latter is a later development brought about by new circumstances.

To guarantee liberty, self-administration, and peace was the chief aim of the medieval city; and labour, as we shall presently see when speaking of the craft guilds, was its chief foundation. But "production" did not absorb the whole attention of the medieval economist. With his practical mind, he understood that "consumption" must be guaranteed in order to obtain production; and therefore, to provide for "the common first food and lodging of poor and rich alike" (gemeine notdurft und gemach armer und richer(46)) was the fundamental principle in each city. The purchase of food supplies and other first necessaries (coal, wood, etc.) before they had reached the market, or altogether in especially favourable conditions from which others would be excluded—the preempcio, in a word—was entirely prohibited. Everything had to go to the market and be offered there for every one's purchase, till the ringing of the bell had closed the market. Then only could the retailer buy the remainder, and even then his profit should be an "honest profit" only.(47) Moreover, when corn was bought by a baker wholesale after the close of the market, every citizen had the right to claim part of the corn (about half-a-quarter) for his own use, at wholesale price, if he did so before the final conclusion of the bargain; and reciprocally, every baker could claim the same if the citizen purchased corn for re-selling it. In the first case, the corn had only to be brought to the town mill to be ground in its proper turn for a settled price, and the bread could be baked in the four banal, or communal oven.(48) In short, if a scarcity visited the city, all had to suffer from it more or less; but apart from the calamities, so long as the free cities existed no one could die in their midst from starvation, as is unhappily too often the case in our own times.

To ensure freedom, self-governance, and peace was the main goal of the medieval city; and labor, as we'll see shortly when discussing the craft guilds, was its primary foundation. However, "production" didn't consume the entire focus of the medieval economist. With his practical mindset, he recognized that "consumption" needed to be secured to achieve production. Therefore, providing for "the common basic needs and shelter of both the poor and the rich" was the essential principle in each city. The purchase of food supplies and other essentials (coal, wood, etc.) before they reached the market, or altogether under especially favorable conditions that excluded others—the preemption, in simple terms—was completely prohibited. Everything had to go to the market and be offered there for anyone to buy, until the bell rang to close the market. Only then could the retailer buy the leftovers, and even then, his profit had to be an "honest profit." Moreover, if a baker bought grain in bulk after the market closed, any citizen had the right to claim a portion of the grain (about half a quarter) for personal use at the wholesale price, as long as he did so before the deal was finalized; reciprocally, every baker could do the same if the citizen purchased grain for resale. In that case, the grain simply had to be taken to the town mill to be ground at a set price, and the bread could be baked in the communal oven. In short, if scarcity struck the city, everyone had to endure it to some degree; but aside from emergencies, as long as the free cities existed, no one died from starvation in their midst, which is unfortunately too common in our own time.

However, all such regulations belong to later periods of the cities' life, while at an earlier period it was the city itself which used to buy all food supplies for the use of the citizens. The documents recently published by Mr. Gross are quite positive on this point and fully support his conclusion to the effect that the cargoes of subsistences "were purchased by certain civic officials in the name of the town, and then distributed in shares among the merchant burgesses, no one being allowed to buy wares landed in the port unless the municipal authorities refused to purchase them. This seem—she adds—to have been quite a common practice in England, Ireland, Wales and Scotland."(49) Even in the sixteenth century we find that common purchases of corn were made for the "comoditie and profitt in all things of this…. Citie and Chamber of London, and of all the Citizens and Inhabitants of the same as moche as in us lieth"—as the Mayor wrote in 1565.(50) In Venice, the whole of the trade in corn is well known to have been in the hands of the city; the "quarters," on receiving the cereals from the board which administrated the imports, being bound to send to every citizen's house the quantity allotted to him.(51) In France, the city of Amiens used to purchase salt and to distribute it to all citizens at cost price;(52) and even now one sees in many French towns the halles which formerly were municipal depots for corn and salt.(53) In Russia it was a regular custom in Novgorod and Pskov.

However, all such regulations belong to later periods in the cities' history, while in earlier times, it was the city itself that purchased all food supplies for its citizens. The documents recently published by Mr. Gross are quite clear on this point and fully support his conclusion that the cargoes of provisions "were bought by certain civic officials in the name of the town, and then distributed in shares among the merchant burgesses, with no one allowed to buy goods landed in the port unless the municipal authorities chose not to purchase them. This seems—she adds—to have been a common practice in England, Ireland, Wales, and Scotland." Even in the sixteenth century, we see that common purchases of grain were made for the "benefit and profit in all things of this... City and Chamber of London, and of all the Citizens and Inhabitants of the same as much as is in our power"—as the Mayor wrote in 1565. In Venice, the entire trade in grain is well known to have been managed by the city; the "quarters," upon receiving the grains from the board that oversaw imports, were required to deliver to each citizen's house the amount assigned to them. In France, the city of Amiens used to buy salt and distribute it to all citizens at cost price; and even now, many French towns have the halles that used to serve as municipal depots for grain and salt. In Russia, it was a regular custom in Novgorod and Pskov.

The whole matter relative to the communal purchases for the use of the citizens, and the manner in which they used to be made, seems not to have yet received proper attention from the historians of the period; but there are here and there some very interesting facts which throw a new light upon it. Thus there is, among Mr. Gross's documents, a Kilkenny ordinance of the year 1367, from which we learn how the prices of the goods were established. "The merchants and the sailors," Mr. Gross writes, "were to state on oath the first cost of the goods and the expenses of transportation. Then the mayor of the town and two discreet men were to name the price at which the wares were to be sold." The same rule held good in Thurso for merchandise coming "by sea or land." This way of "naming the price" so well answers to the very conceptions of trade which were current in medieval times that it must have been all but universal. To have the price established by a third person was a very old custom; and for all interchange within the city it certainly was a widely-spread habit to leave the establishment of prices to "discreet men"—to a third party—and not to the vendor or the buyer. But this order of things takes us still further back in the history of trade—namely, to a time when trade in staple produce was carried on by the whole city, and the merchants were only the commissioners, the trustees, of the city for selling the goods which it exported. A Waterford ordinance, published also by Mr. Gross, says "that all manere of marchandis what so ever kynde thei be of … shal be bought by the Maire and balives which bene commene biers [common buyers, for the town] for the time being, and to distribute the same on freemen of the citie (the propre goods of free citisains and inhabitants only excepted)." This ordinance can hardly be explained otherwise than by admitting that all the exterior trade of the town was carried on by its agents. Moreover, we have direct evidence of such having been the case for Novgorod and Pskov. It was the Sovereign Novgorod and the Sovereign Pskov who sent their caravans of merchants to distant lands.

The entire issue regarding the communal purchases for the citizens' use, and how they used to be conducted, doesn't seem to have been properly addressed by historians of that time; however, there are some very interesting facts scattered throughout that shed new light on it. For example, among Mr. Gross's documents is a Kilkenny ordinance from 1367, which reveals how the prices of goods were set. "The merchants and sailors," Mr. Gross writes, "were obligated to declare under oath the original cost of the goods and the transportation expenses. Then, the mayor of the town and two trustworthy individuals were to determine the selling price of the goods." The same principle applied in Thurso for merchandise arriving "by sea or land." This method of "setting the price" aligns well with the trading concepts prevalent in medieval times, suggesting it was nearly universal. Having the price determined by a third party was a very old practice; in the city's trade, it was certainly common to entrust the price-setting to "trustworthy men"—a third party—not the seller or the buyer. However, this practice also takes us further back in trade history—to a time when the entire city was involved in trading staple products, and the merchants acted merely as agents or trustees of the city for selling the goods that it exported. A Waterford ordinance, also published by Mr. Gross, states "that all types of merchandise, whatever kind they may be... shall be purchased by the Mayor and bailiffs who are the common buyers for the time being, and to distribute the same among the freemen of the city (except for the personal goods of free citizens and inhabitants)." This ordinance can hardly be understood without acknowledging that all external trade of the town was conducted by its representatives. Additionally, we have direct evidence that this was also the case for Novgorod and Pskov. It was the Sovereign Novgorod and the Sovereign Pskov that sent their caravans of merchants to far-off lands.

We know also that in nearly all medieval cities of Middle and Western Europe, the craft guilds used to buy, as a body, all necessary raw produce, and to sell the produce of their work through their officials, and it is hardly possible that the same should not have been done for exterior trade—the more so as it is well known that up to the thirteenth century, not only all merchants of a given city were considered abroad as responsible in a body for debts contracted by any one of them, but the whole city as well was responsible for the debts of each one of its merchants. Only in the twelfth and thirteenth century the towns on the Rhine entered into special treaties abolishing this responsibility.(54) And finally we have the remarkable Ipswich document published by Mr. Gross, from which document we learn that the merchant guild of this town was constituted by all who had the freedom of the city, and who wished to pay their contribution ("their hanse") to the guild, the whole community discussing all together how better to maintain the merchant guild, and giving it certain privileges. The merchant guild of Ipswich thus appears rather as a body of trustees of the town than as a common private guild.

We also know that in almost all medieval cities in Central and Western Europe, craft guilds would collectively purchase all necessary raw materials and sell the products of their labor through their representatives. It's unlikely that the same wasn't true for external trade, especially since it's well-known that until the thirteenth century, all merchants from a city were viewed collectively as responsible for any debts incurred by any member of their group. Additionally, the entire city was held accountable for the debts of each of its merchants. It was only in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries that towns along the Rhine entered into specific agreements to eliminate this liability.(54) Finally, we have the notable Ipswich document published by Mr. Gross, which reveals that the merchant guild in this town was made up of everyone who held the freedom of the city and wanted to contribute ("their hanse") to the guild. The entire community would discuss how to best support the merchant guild together and grant it certain privileges. Thus, the merchant guild of Ipswich seems more like a group of trustees for the town rather than a typical private guild.

In short, the more we begin to know the mediaeval city the more we see that it was not simply a political organization for the protection of certain political liberties. It was an attempt at organizing, on a much grander scale than in a village community, a close union for mutual aid and support, for consumption and production, and for social life altogether, without imposing upon men the fetters of the State, but giving full liberty of expression to the creative genius of each separate group of individuals in art, crafts, science, commerce, and political organization. How far this attempt has been successful will be best seen when we have analyzed in the next chapter the organization of labour in the medieval city and the relations of the cities with the surrounding peasant population.

In short, the more we learn about the medieval city, the more we realize that it wasn’t just a political system meant to protect certain freedoms. It was an effort to create, on a much larger scale than a village, a close-knit community for mutual aid and support, for production and consumption, and for social life overall, without tying people down with the restrictions of the State. It allowed each group of individuals to fully express their creativity in art, crafts, science, commerce, and political organization. We’ll better understand how successful this effort was once we analyze the organization of labor in the medieval city and the relationship between the cities and the surrounding peasant population in the next chapter.

NOTES:

1. W. Arnold, in his Wanderungen und Ansiedelungen der deutschen Stamme, p. 431, even maintains that one-half of the now arable area in middle Germany must have been reclaimed from the sixth to the ninth century. Nitzsch (Geschichte des deutschen Volkes, Leipzig, 1883, vol. i.) shares the same opinion.

1. W. Arnold, in his Wanderungen und Ansiedelungen der deutschen Stamme, p. 431, even argues that half of the currently usable farmland in central Germany must have been restored between the sixth and ninth centuries. Nitzsch (Geschichte des deutschen Volkes, Leipzig, 1883, vol. i.) holds the same view.

2. Leo and Botta, Histoire d'Italie, French edition, 1844, t. i., p. 37.

2. Leo and Botta, History of Italy, French edition, 1844, vol. 1, p. 37.

3. The composition for the stealing of a simple knife was 15 solidii and of the iron parts of a mill, 45 solidii (See on this subject Lamprecht's Wirthschaft und Recht der Franken in Raumer's Historisches Taschenbuch, 1883, p. 52.) According to the Riparian law, the sword, the spear, and the iron armour of a warrior attained the value of at least twenty-five cows, or two years of a freeman's labour. A cuirass alone was valued in the Salic law (Desmichels, quoted by Michelet) at as much as thirty-six bushels of wheat.

3. The cost for stealing a simple knife was 15 solidii, and for the iron parts of a mill, it was 45 solidii (See on this subject Lamprecht's Wirthschaft und Recht der Franken in Raumer's Historisches Taschenbuch, 1883, p. 52.) According to the Riparian law, a warrior's sword, spear, and iron armor were valued at least at twenty-five cows or two years of a free person's work. In the Salic law, a cuirass alone was valued (Desmichels, quoted by Michelet) at as much as thirty-six bushels of wheat.

4. The chief wealth of the chieftains, for a long time, was in their personal domains peopled partly with prisoner slaves, but chiefly in the above way. On the origin of property see Inama Sternegg's Die Ausbildung der grossen Grundherrschaften in Deutschland, in Schmoller's Forschungen, Bd. I., 1878; F. Dahn's Urgeschichte der germanischen und romanischen Volker, Berlin, 1881; Maurer's Dorfverfassung; Guizot's Essais sur l'histoire de France; Maine's Village Community; Botta's Histoire d'Italie; Seebohm, Vinogradov, J. R. Green, etc.

4. For a long time, the main wealth of the chieftains was found in their personal territories, which were partly populated by prisoner slaves but mostly came from the sources mentioned above. For more on the origins of property, see Inama Sternegg's *Die Ausbildung der grossen Grundherrschaften in Deutschland*, in Schmoller's *Forschungen*, Vol. I, 1878; F. Dahn's *Urgeschichte der germanischen und romanischen Volker*, Berlin, 1881; Maurer's *Dorfverfassung*; Guizot's *Essais sur l'histoire de France*; Maine's *Village Community*; Botta's *Histoire d'Italie*; Seebohm, Vinogradov, J. R. Green, etc.

5. See Sir Henry Maine's International Law, London, 1888.

5. See Sir Henry Maine's International Law, London, 1888.

6. Ancient Laws of Ireland, Introduction; E. Nys, Etudes de droit international, t. i., 1896, pp. 86 seq. Among the Ossetes the arbiters from three oldest villages enjoy a special reputation (M. Kovalevsky's Modern Custom and Old Law, Moscow, 1886, ii. 217, Russian).

6. Ancient Laws of Ireland, Introduction; E. Nys, Studies in International Law, vol. I, 1896, pp. 86 and following. Among the Ossetians, the arbiters from the three oldest villages are well-respected (M. Kovalevsky's Modern Custom and Old Law, Moscow, 1886, II. 217, Russian).

7. It is permissible to think that this conception (related to the conception of tanistry) played an important part in the life of the period; but research has not yet been directed that way.

7. It's acceptable to believe that this idea (connected to the idea of tanistry) was significant during that time; however, research has not yet focused on this aspect.

8. It was distinctly stated in the charter of St. Quentin of the year 1002 that the ransom for houses which had to be demolished for crimes went for the city walls. The same destination was given to the Ungeld in German cities. At Pskov the cathedral was the bank for the fines, and from this fund money was taken for the wails.

8. The charter of St. Quentin from the year 1002 clearly stated that the money collected for houses that had to be torn down due to crimes was used for the city walls. A similar practice was applied to the Ungeld in German cities. In Pskov, the cathedral served as the bank for the fines, and money from this fund was used for the walls.

9. Sohm, Frankische Rechts-und Gerichtsverfassung, p. 23; also Nitzsch, Geschichte des deutschen Volkes, i. 78.

9. Sohm, Franconian Law and Court System, p. 23; also Nitzsch, History of the German People, i. 78.

10. See the excellent remarks on this subject in Augustin Thierry's Lettres sur l'histoire de France. 7th Letter. The barbarian translations of parts of the Bible are extremely instructive on this point.

10. Check out the insightful comments on this topic in Augustin Thierry's Lettres sur l'histoire de France. 7th Letter. The barbarian translations of parts of the Bible are very enlightening on this matter.

11. Thirty-six times more than a noble, according to the Anglo-Saxon law. In the code of Rothari the slaying of a king is, however, punished by death; but (apart from Roman influence) this new disposition was introduced (in 646) in the Lombardian law—as remarked by Leo and Botta—to cover the king from blood revenge. The king being at that time the executioner of his own sentences (as the tribe formerly was of its own sentences), he had to be protected by a special disposition, the more so as several Lombardian kings before Rothari had been slain in succession (Leo and Botta, l.c., i. 66-90).

11. Thirty-six times more than a noble, according to Anglo-Saxon law. In Rothari's code, killing a king is punished by death; however, aside from Roman influence, this new rule was introduced in Lombard law in 646— as noted by Leo and Botta— to protect the king from blood vengeance. At that time, the king carried out his own sentences (just as the tribe did with its own judgments), so he needed special protection, especially since several Lombard kings before Rothari had been killed in succession (Leo and Botta, l.c., i. 66-90).

12. Kaufmann, Deutsche Geschichte, Bd. I. "Die Germanen der Urzeit," p. 133.

12. Kaufmann, German History, Vol. I. "The Germani in Ancient Times," p. 133.

13. Dr. F. Dahn, Urgeschichte der germanischen und romanischen Volker, Berlin, 1881, Bd. I. 96.

13. Dr. F. Dahn, The Prehistory of Germanic and Romance Peoples, Berlin, 1881, Vol. I. 96.

14. If I thus follow the views long since advocated by Maurer (Geschichte der Stadteverfassung in Deutschland, Erlangen, 1869), it is because he has fully proved the uninterrupted evolution from the village community to the mediaeval city, and that his views alone can explain the universality of the communal movement. Savigny and Eichhorn and their followers have certainly proved that the traditions of the Roman municipia had never totally disappeared. But they took no account of the village community period which the barbarians lived through before they had any cities. The fact is, that whenever mankind made a new start in civilization, in Greece, Rome, or middle Europe, it passed through the same stages—the tribe, the village community, the free city, the state—each one naturally evolving out of the preceding stage. Of course, the experience of each preceding civilization was never lost. Greece (itself influenced by Eastern civilizations) influenced Rome, and Rome influenced our civilization; but each of them begin from the same beginning—the tribe. And just as we cannot say that our states are continuations of the Roman state, so also can we not say that the mediaeval cities of Europe (including Scandinavia and Russia) were a continuation of the Roman cities. They were a continuation of the barbarian village community, influenced to a certain extent by the traditions of the Roman towns.

14. If I follow the ideas that Maurer proposed long ago (Geschichte der Stadteverfassung in Deutschland, Erlangen, 1869), it's because he has convincingly demonstrated the continuous evolution from the village community to the medieval city, and that his theories alone can clarify the widespread communal movement. Savigny, Eichhorn, and their followers have indeed shown that the traditions of Roman municipalities never completely vanished. However, they overlooked the period of the village community that the barbarians experienced before they established cities. The reality is that whenever civilization took a new turn, whether in Greece, Rome, or Central Europe, it went through the same stages—the tribe, the village community, the free city, and the state—each naturally evolving from the previous stage. Of course, the knowledge from each prior civilization was never entirely lost. Greece (itself influenced by Eastern civilizations) impacted Rome, and Rome in turn influenced our civilization; but all of them began from the same starting point—the tribe. Just as we cannot claim that our states are direct continuations of the Roman state, we also cannot say that the medieval cities of Europe (including Scandinavia and Russia) were continuations of the Roman cities. They were continuations of the barbarian village community, influenced to some extent by the traditions of Roman towns.

15. M. Kovalevsky, Modern Customs and Ancient Laws of Russia (Ilchester Lectures, London, 1891, Lecture 4).

15. M. Kovalevsky, Modern Customs and Ancient Laws of Russia (Ilchester Lectures, London, 1891, Lecture 4).

16. A considerable amount of research had to be done before this character of the so-called udyelnyi period was properly established by the works of Byelaeff (Tales from Russian History), Kostomaroff (The Beginnings of Autocracy in Russia), and especially Professor Sergievich (The Vyeche and the Prince). The English reader may find some information about this period in the just-named work of M. Kovalevsky, in Rambaud's History of Russia, and, in a short summary, in the article "Russia" of the last edition of Chambers's Encyclopaedia.

16. A lot of research needed to be done before the character of the so-called udyelnyi period was properly established by the works of Byelaeff (Tales from Russian History), Kostomaroff (The Beginnings of Autocracy in Russia), and especially Professor Sergievich (The Vyeche and the Prince). The English reader may find information about this period in the previously mentioned work by M. Kovalevsky, in Rambaud's History of Russia, and in a brief summary in the article "Russia" in the latest edition of Chambers's Encyclopaedia.

17. Ferrari, Histoire des revolutions d'Italie, i. 257; Kallsen, Die deutschen Stadte im Mittelalter, Bd. I. (Halle, 1891).

17. Ferrari, History of the Revolutions in Italy, i. 257; Kallsen, The German Cities in the Middle Ages, Vol. I. (Halle, 1891).

18. See the excellent remarks of Mr. G.L. Gomme as regards the folkmote of London (The Literature of Local Institutions, London, 1886, p. 76). It must, however, be remarked that in royal cities the folkmote never attained the independence which it assumed elsewhere. It is even certain that Moscow and Paris were chosen by the kings and the Church as the cradles of the future royal authority in the State, because they did not possess the tradition of folkmotes accustomed to act as sovereign in all matters.

18. Check out the insightful comments made by Mr. G.L. Gomme about the folkmote of London (The Literature of Local Institutions, London, 1886, p. 76). However, it's important to note that in royal cities, the folkmote never gained the independence it had in other places. It's also clear that Moscow and Paris were chosen by the kings and the Church as the foundations of future royal authority in the State because they didn't have a tradition of folkmotes that acted independently in all matters.

19. A. Luchaire, Les Communes francaises; also Kluckohn, Geschichte des Gottesfrieden, 1857. L. Semichon (La paix et la treve de Dieu, 2 vols., Paris, 1869) has tried to represent the communal movement as issued from that institution. In reality, the treuga Dei, like the league started under Louis le Gros for the defence against both the robberies of the nobles and the Norman invasions, was a thoroughly popular movement. The only historian who mentions this last league—that is, Vitalis—describes it as a "popular community" ("Considerations sur l'histoire de France," in vol. iv. of Aug. Thierry's OEuvres, Paris, 1868, p. 191 and note).

19. A. Luchaire, Les Communes francaises; also Kluckohn, Geschichte des Gottesfrieden, 1857. L. Semichon (La paix et la treve de Dieu, 2 vols., Paris, 1869) has attempted to portray the communal movement as arising from that institution. In reality, the treuga Dei, like the league initiated under Louis le Gros for the protection against both the nobles' robberies and the Norman invasions, was a genuinely grassroots movement. The only historian who mentions this last league—Vitalis—describes it as a "popular community" ("Considerations sur l'histoire de France," in vol. iv. of Aug. Thierry's OEuvres, Paris, 1868, p. 191 and note).

20. Ferrari, i. 152, 263, etc.

20. Ferrari, i. 152, 263, etc.

21. Perrens, Histoire de Florence, i. 188; Ferrari, l.c., i. 283.

21. Perrens, History of Florence, i. 188; Ferrari, l.c., i. 283.

22. Aug. Thierry, Essai sur l'histoire du Tiers Etat, Paris, 1875, p. 414, note.

22. Aug. Thierry, Essay on the History of the Third Estate, Paris, 1875, p. 414, note.

23. F. Rocquain, "La Renaissance au XIIe siecle," in Etudes sur l'histoire de France, Paris, 1875, pp. 55-117.

23. F. Rocquain, "The Renaissance in the 12th Century," in Studies on the History of France, Paris, 1875, pp. 55-117.

24. N. Kostomaroff, "The Rationalists of the Twelfth Century," in his Monographies and Researches (Russian).

24. N. Kostomaroff, "The Rationalists of the Twelfth Century," in his Monographies and Researches (Russian).

25. Very interesting facts relative to the universality of guilds will be found in "Two Thousand Years of Guild Life," by Rev. J. M. Lambert, Hull, 1891. On the Georgian amkari, see S. Eghiazarov, Gorodskiye Tsekhi ("Organization of Transcaucasian Amkari"), in Memoirs of the Caucasian Geographical Society, xiv. 2, 1891.

25. You can find some very interesting facts about the universality of guilds in "Two Thousand Years of Guild Life" by Rev. J. M. Lambert, Hull, 1891. For information on the Georgian amkari, check out S. Eghiazarov's Gorodskiye Tsekhi ("Organization of Transcaucasian Amkari") in the Memoirs of the Caucasian Geographical Society, xiv. 2, 1891.

26. J.D. Wunderer's "Reisebericht" in Fichard's Frankfurter Archiv, ii. 245; quoted by Janssen, Geschichte des deutschen Volkes, i. 355.

26. J.D. Wunderer's "Travel Report" in Fichard's Frankfurt Archive, ii. 245; quoted by Janssen, History of the German People, i. 355.

27. Dr. Leonard Ennen, Der Dom zu Koln, Historische Einleitung, Koln, 1871, pp. 46, 50.

27. Dr. Leonard Ennen, The Cathedral of Cologne, Historical Introduction, Cologne, 1871, pp. 46, 50.

28. See previous chapter.

28. Refer to the previous chapter.

29. Kofod Ancher, Om gamle Danske Gilder og deres Undergang, Copenhagen, 1785. Statutes of a Knu guild.

29. Kofod Ancher, On Old Danish Guilds and Their Decline, Copenhagen, 1785. Rules of a Knu guild.

30. Upon the position of women in guilds, see Miss Toulmin Smith's introductory remarks to the English Guilds of her father. One of the Cambridge statutes (p. 281) of the year 1503 is quite positive in the following sentence: "Thys statute is made by the comyne assent of all the bretherne and sisterne of alhallowe yelde."

30. For information on the role of women in guilds, check out Miss Toulmin Smith's introductory remarks to the English Guilds written by her father. One of the Cambridge statutes (p. 281) from the year 1503 clearly states: "This statute is made by the common agreement of all the brothers and sisters of All Hallows Guild."

31. In medieval times, only secret aggression was treated as a murder. Blood-revenge in broad daylight was justice; and slaying in a quarrel was not murder, once the aggressor showed his willingness to repent and to repair the wrong he had done. Deep traces of this distinction still exist in modern criminal law, especially in Russia.

31. In medieval times, only hidden aggression was considered murder. Blood revenge in plain sight was seen as justice, and killing in a fight wasn’t regarded as murder, as long as the attacker showed a willingness to repent and make amends for the wrong he had done. Significant remnants of this distinction still exist in modern criminal law, especially in Russia.

32. Kofod Ancher, l.c. This old booklet contains much that has been lost sight of by later explorers.

32. Kofod Ancher, l.c. This old booklet has a lot of information that later explorers overlooked.

33. They played an important part in the revolts of the serfs, and were therefore prohibited several times in succession in the second half of the ninth century. Of course, the king's prohibitions remained a dead letter.

33. They played a significant role in the serfs' revolts and were therefore banned multiple times in the latter half of the ninth century. Naturally, the king's bans were largely ignored.

34. The medieval Italian painters were also organized in guilds, which became at a later epoch Academies of art. If the Italian art of those times is impressed with so much individuality that we distinguish, even now, between the different schools of Padua, Bassano, Treviso, Verona, and so on, although all these cities were under the sway of Venice, this was due—J. Paul Richter remarks—to the fact that the painters of each city belonged to a separate guild, friendly with the guilds of other towns, but leading a separate existence. The oldest guild-statute known is that of Verona, dating from 1303, but evidently copied from some much older statute. "Fraternal assistance in necessity of whatever kind," "hospitality towards strangers, when passing through the town, as thus information may be obtained about matters which one may like to learn," and "obligation of offering comfort in case of debility" are among the obligations of the members (Nineteenth Century, Nov. 1890, and Aug. 1892).

34. The medieval Italian painters were also organized into guilds, which later evolved into art academies. The Italian art of that time is marked by so much individuality that we can still distinguish between the different schools of Padua, Bassano, Treviso, Verona, and others, even though all these cities were under Venice's control. This was due— as J. Paul Richter points out—to the fact that the painters from each city belonged to separate guilds. While these guilds were friendly with each other, they operated independently. The oldest known guild statute is from Verona, dating back to 1303, but it clearly derives from an even older statute. Among the obligations of the members are "fraternal assistance in times of need," "hospitality towards travelers passing through town, as this allows for the exchange of information on matters one might want to learn," and "the duty to provide comfort in cases of illness" (Nineteenth Century, Nov. 1890, and Aug. 1892).

35. The chief works on the artels are named in the article "Russia" of the Encyclopaedia Britannica, 9th edition, p. 84.

35. The main works on the artels are listed in the article "Russia" from the Encyclopaedia Britannica, 9th edition, p. 84.

36. See, for instance, the texts of the Cambridge guilds given by Toulmin Smith (English Guilds, London, 1870, pp. 274-276), from which it appears that the "generall and principall day" was the "eleccioun day;" or, Ch. M. Clode's The Early History of the Guild of the Merchant Taylors, London, 1888, i. 45; and so on. For the renewal of allegiance, see the Jomsviking saga, mentioned in Pappenheim's Altdanische Schutzgilden, Breslau, 1885, p. 67. It appears very probable that when the guilds began to be prosecuted, many of them inscribed in their statutes the meal day only, or their pious duties, and only alluded to the judicial function of the guild in vague words; but this function did not disappear till a very much later time. The question, "Who will be my judge?" has no meaning now, since the State has appropriated for its bureaucracy the organization of justice; but it was of primordial importance in medieval times, the more so as self-jurisdiction meant self-administration. It must also be remarked that the translation of the Saxon and Danish "guild-bretheren," or "brodre," by the Latin convivii must also have contributed to the above confusion.

36. For example, check out the texts of the Cambridge guilds provided by Toulmin Smith (English Guilds, London, 1870, pp. 274-276), which show that the "general and principal day" was "election day;" or, Ch. M. Clode's The Early History of the Guild of the Merchant Taylors, London, 1888, i. 45; and more. For the renewal of loyalty, refer to the Jomsviking saga, mentioned in Pappenheim's Altdanische Schutzgilden, Breslau, 1885, p. 67. It seems likely that when the guilds faced prosecution, many of them only included their meal day or their religious duties in their statutes, and only vaguely referenced their judicial role; however, this role didn’t disappear until much later. The question, "Who will be my judge?" has no significance now since the State has taken over the organization of justice for its bureaucracy; but it was critically important in medieval times, especially since self-jurisdiction meant self-management. It’s also worth noting that translating the Saxon and Danish "guild-bretheren," or "brodre," as the Latin convivii likely contributed to this confusion.

37. See the excellent remarks upon the frith guild by J.R. Green and Mrs. Green in The Conquest of England, London, 1883, pp. 229-230.

37. Check out the great comments on the frith guild by J.R. Green and Mrs. Green in The Conquest of England, London, 1883, pp. 229-230.

38. None

None

39. Recueil des ordonnances des rois de France, t. xii. 562; quoted by Aug. Thierry in Considerations sur l'histoire de France, p. 196, ed. 12mo.

39. Collection of the ordinances of the kings of France, vol. xii. 562; cited by Aug. Thierry in Reflections on the History of France, p. 196, 12mo ed.

40. A. Luchaire, Les Communes francaises, pp, 45-46.

40. A. Luchaire, The French Municipalities, pp. 45-46.

41. Guilbert de Nogent, De vita sua, quoted by Luchaire, l.c., p. 14.

41. Guilbert de Nogent, De vita sua, cited by Luchaire, l.c., p. 14.

42. Lebret, Histoire de Venise, i. 393; also Marin, quoted by Leo and Botta in Histoire de l'Italie, French edition, 1844, t. i 500.

42. Lebret, Histoire de Venise, i. 393; also Marin, quoted by Leo and Botta in Histoire de l'Italie, French edition, 1844, t. i 500.

43. Dr. W. Arnold, Verfassungsgeschichte der deutschen Freistadte, 1854, Bd. ii. 227 seq.; Ennen, Geschichte der Stadt Koeln, Bd. i. 228-229; also the documents published by Ennen and Eckert.

43. Dr. W. Arnold, Constitutional History of the German Free Cities, 1854, Vol. ii. 227 seq.; Ennen, History of the City of Cologne, Vol. i. 228-229; also the documents published by Ennen and Eckert.

44. Conquest of England, 1883, p. 453.

44. Conquest of England, 1883, p. 453.

45. Byelaeff, Russian History, vols. ii. and iii.

45. Byelaeff, Russian History, vols. 2 and 3.

46. W. Gramich, Verfassungs und Verwaltungsgeschichte der Stadt Wurzburg im 13. bis zum 15. Jahrhundert, Wurzburg, 1882, p. 34.

46. W. Gramich, Constitutional and Administrative History of the City of Würzburg from the 13th to the 15th Century, Würzburg, 1882, p. 34.

47. When a boat brought a cargo of coal to Wurzburg, coal could only be sold in retail during the first eight days, each family being entitled to no more than fifty basketfuls. The remaining cargo could be sold wholesale, but the retailer was allowed to raise a zittlicher profit only, the unzittlicher, or dishonest profit, being strictly forbidden (Gramich, l.c.). Same in London (Liber albus, quoted by Ochenkowski, p. 161), and, in fact, everywhere.

47. When a boat delivered a load of coal to Wurzburg, coal could only be sold in small quantities during the first eight days, with each family allowed a maximum of fifty baskets. The leftover cargo could be sold in bulk, but the retailer was only permitted to earn a reasonable profit; any kind of dishonest profit was strictly prohibited (Gramich, l.c.). The same rule applied in London (Liber albus, quoted by Ochenkowski, p. 161), and really, everywhere.

48. See Fagniez, Etudes sur l'industrie et la classe industrielle a Paris au XIIIme et XIVme siecle, Paris, 1877, pp. 155 seq. It hardly need be added that the tax on bread, and on beer as well, was settled after careful experiments as to the quantity of bread and beer which could be obtained from a given amount of corn. The Amiens archives contain the minutes of such experiences (A. de Calonne, l.c. pp. 77, 93). Also those of London (Ochenkowski, England's wirthschaftliche Entwickelung, etc., Jena, 1879, p. 165).

48. See Fagniez, Studies on Industry and the Industrial Class in Paris in the 13th and 14th Centuries, Paris, 1877, pp. 155 seq. It hardly needs to be mentioned that the tax on bread and beer was determined after careful experiments to figure out how much bread and beer could be produced from a specific amount of grain. The Amiens archives hold the records of these experiments (A. de Calonne, l.c. pp. 77, 93). The same goes for those in London (Ochenkowski, England's Economic Development, etc., Jena, 1879, p. 165).

49. Ch. Gross, The Guild Merchant, Oxford, 1890, i. 135. His documents prove that this practice existed in Liverpool (ii. 148-150), Waterford in Ireland, Neath in Wales, and Linlithgow and Thurso in Scotland. Mr. Gross's texts also show that the purchases were made for distribution, not only among the merchant burgesses, but "upon all citsains and commynalte" (p. 136, note), or, as the Thurso ordinance of the seventeenth century runs, to "make offer to the merchants, craftsmen, and inhabitants of the said burgh, that they may have their proportion of the same, according to their necessitys and ability."

49. Ch. Gross, The Guild Merchant, Oxford, 1890, i. 135. His documents show that this practice existed in Liverpool (ii. 148-150), Waterford in Ireland, Neath in Wales, and Linlithgow and Thurso in Scotland. Mr. Gross's texts also indicate that the purchases were made for distribution, not just among the merchant burgesses, but "to all citizens and the community" (p. 136, note), or as the Thurso ordinance of the seventeenth century states, to "offer to the merchants, craftsmen, and residents of the said burgh, so they can receive their share of it based on their needs and capabilities."

50. The Early History of the Guild of Merchant Taylors, by Charles M. Clode, London, 1888, i. 361, appendix 10; also the following appendix which shows that the same purchases were made in 1546.

50. The Early History of the Guild of Merchant Taylors, by Charles M. Clode, London, 1888, i. 361, appendix 10; also the following appendix that shows the same purchases were made in 1546.

51. Cibrario, Les conditions economiques de l'Italie au temps de Dante, Paris, 1865, p. 44.

51. Cibrario, The Economic Conditions of Italy in Dante's Time, Paris, 1865, p. 44.

52. A. de Calonne, La vie municipale au XVme siecle dans le Nord de la France, Paris, 1880, pp. 12-16. In 1485 the city permitted the export to Antwerp of a certain quantity of corn, "the inhabitants of Antwerp being always ready to be agreeable to the merchants and burgesses of Amiens" (ibid., pp. 75-77 and texts).

52. A. de Calonne, Life in Municipalities in the 15th Century in Northern France, Paris, 1880, pp. 12-16. In 1485, the city allowed the export of a certain amount of corn to Antwerp, "the people of Antwerp always being eager to accommodate the merchants and citizens of Amiens" (ibid., pp. 75-77 and texts).

53. A. Babeau, La ville sous l'ancien regime, Paris, 1880.

53. A. Babeau, The City Under the Old Regime, Paris, 1880.

54. Ennen, Geschichte der Stadt Koln, i. 491, 492, also texts.

54. Ennen, History of the City of Cologne, i. 491, 492, also texts.

CHAPTER VI

MUTUAL AID IN THE MEDIAEVAL CITY (continued)

MUTUAL AID IN THE MEDIEVAL CITY (continued)

Likeness and diversity among the medieval cities. The craftguilds: State-attributes in each of them. Attitude of the city towards the peasants; attempts to free them. The lords. Results achieved by the medieval city: in arts, in learning. Causes of decay.

Likeness and diversity among the medieval cities. The craft guilds: State attributes in each of them. The city's attitude towards the peasants; efforts to free them. The lords. Achievements of the medieval city: in arts, in education. Causes of decline.

The medieval cities were not organized upon some preconceived plan in obedience to the will of an outside legislator. Each of them was a natural growth in the full sense of the word—an always varying result of struggle between various forces which adjusted and re-adjusted themselves in conformity with their relative energies, the chances of their conflicts, and the support they found in their surroundings. Therefore, there are not two cities whose inner organization and destinies would have been identical. Each one, taken separately, varies from century to century. And yet, when we cast a broad glance upon all the cities of Europe, the local and national unlikenesses disappear, and we are struck to find among all of them a wonderful resemblance, although each has developed for itself, independently from the others, and in different conditions. A small town in the north of Scotland, with its population of coarse labourers and fishermen; a rich city of Flanders, with its world-wide commerce, luxury, love of amusement and animated life; an Italian city enriched by its intercourse with the East, and breeding within its walls a refined artistic taste and civilization; and a poor, chiefly agricultural, city in the marsh and lake district of Russia, seem to have little in common. And nevertheless, the leading lines of their organization, and the spirit which animates them, are imbued with a strong family likeness. Everywhere we see the same federations of small communities and guilds, the same "sub-towns" round the mother city, the same folkmote, and the same insigns of its independence. The defensor of the city, under different names and in different accoutrements, represents the same authority and interests; food supplies, labour and commerce, are organized on closely similar lines; inner and outer struggles are fought with like ambitions; nay, the very formulae used in the struggles, as also in the annals, the ordinances, and the rolls, are identical; and the architectural monuments, whether Gothic, Roman, or Byzantine in style, express the same aspirations and the same ideals; they are conceived and built in the same way. Many dissemblances are mere differences of age, and those disparities between sister cities which are real are repeated in different parts of Europe. The unity of the leading idea and the identity of origin make up for differences of climate, geographical situation, wealth, language and religion. This is why we can speak of the medieval city as of a well-defined phase of civilization; and while every research insisting upon local and individual differences is most welcome, we may still indicate the chief lines of development which are common to all cities.(1)

The medieval cities weren't planned according to a specific design set by an outside authority. Each city grew naturally, shaped by a constant struggle between various forces that adapted to their strengths, the outcomes of their conflicts, and the support they received from their environment. Because of this, there are no two cities with the same structure and fate. Each city, when considered on its own, changes from century to century. However, when we take a broad view of all the cities in Europe, the local and national differences fade away, revealing a striking similarity among them. Even though each city developed independently under different conditions, a small town in northern Scotland, populated by rough laborers and fishermen; a wealthy city in Flanders, known for its global trade, luxury, enjoyment, and lively atmosphere; an Italian city enriched by trade with the East, fostering a refined artistic taste and culture; and a poor, mainly agricultural city in the marshy and lake regions of Russia all seem quite different. Yet, the fundamental structures and the spirit that animates them reveal a strong family resemblance. We can observe the same associations of small communities and guilds everywhere, the same "sub-towns" surrounding the main city, the same assemblies, and the same symbols of independence. The defender of the city, under various names and forms, represents the same authority and interests; food supplies, labor, and commerce are organized similarly; internal and external conflicts are pursued with comparable motivations; indeed, the very language used in these battles, as well as in records, regulations, and documents, is the same; and the architectural monuments, whether Gothic, Roman, or Byzantine, convey the same aspirations and ideals—they are designed and constructed in the same manner. Many differences are just variances in age, and the genuine disparities between sister cities are reflected in various parts of Europe. The unity of the underlying concept and the shared origins compensate for differences in climate, geography, wealth, language, and religion. This is why we can refer to the medieval city as a distinct phase of civilization; while every research highlighting local and individual differences is valuable, we can still outline the main lines of development that are common to all cities.

There is no doubt that the protection which used to be accorded to the market-place from the earliest barbarian times has played an important, though not an exclusive, part in the emancipation of the medieval city. The early barbarians knew no trade within their village communities; they traded with strangers only, at certain definite spots, on certain determined days. And, in order that the stranger might come to the barter-place without risk of being slain for some feud which might be running between two kins, the market was always placed under the special protection of all kins. It was inviolable, like the place of worship under the shadow of which it was held. With the Kabyles it is still annaya, like the footpath along which women carry water from the well; neither must be trodden upon in arms, even during inter-tribal wars. In medieval times the market universally enjoyed the same protection.(2) No feud could be prosecuted on the place whereto people came to trade, nor within a certain radius from it; and if a quarrel arose in the motley crowd of buyers and sellers, it had to be brought before those under whose protection the market stood—the community's tribunal, or the bishop's, the lord's, or the king's judge. A stranger who came to trade was a guest, and he went on under this very name. Even the lord who had no scruples about robbing a merchant on the high road, respected the Weichbild, that is, the pole which stood in the market-place and bore either the king's arms, or a glove, or the image of the local saint, or simply a cross, according to whether the market was under the protection of the king, the lord, the local church, or the folkmote—the vyeche.(3)

There’s no doubt that the protection once given to the marketplace from the earliest barbarian times has played an important, though not exclusive, role in the freedom of the medieval city. The early barbarians didn’t engage in trade within their village communities; instead, they only traded with outsiders at specific locations on certain designated days. To ensure that visitors could come to the barter area without the risk of being harmed due to any feuds between families, the market was always placed under the special protection of all families. It was sacred, much like the place of worship where it was held. With the Kabyles, it is still considered inviolable, like the path women use to fetch water from the well; neither can be crossed with weapons, even during inter-tribal conflicts. In medieval times, the market universally enjoyed the same protection. No feud could be fought out in the space where people came to trade, nor within a specific radius around it; if a dispute arose in the bustling crowd of buyers and sellers, it had to be resolved before the authority protecting the market—the community’s tribunal, or the bishop's, lord's, or king’s judge. A trader was considered a guest, and he continued to be referred to as such. Even a lord who had no qualms about robbing a merchant on the highway respected the Weichbild, which was the pole that stood in the marketplace and displayed either the king’s coat of arms, a glove, the image of the local saint, or simply a cross, depending on whether the market was protected by the king, the lord, the local church, or the folkmote—the vyeche.

It is easy to understand how the self-jurisdiction of the city could develop out of the special jurisdiction in the market-place, when this last right was conceded, willingly or not, to the city itself. And such an origin of the city's liberties, which can be traced in very many cases, necessarily laid a special stamp upon their subsequent development. It gave a predominance to the trading part of the community. The burghers who possessed a house in the city at the time being, and were co-owners in the town-lands, constituted very often a merchant guild which held in its hands the city's trade; and although at the outset every burgher, rich and poor, could make part of the merchant guild, and the trade itself seems to have been carried on for the entire city by its trustees, the guild gradually became a sort of privileged body. It jealously prevented the outsiders who soon began to flock into the free cities from entering the guild, and kept the advantages resulting from trade for the few "families" which had been burghers at the time of the emancipation. There evidently was a danger of a merchant oligarchy being thus constituted. But already in the tenth, and still more during the two next centuries, the chief crafts, also organized in guilds, were powerful enough to check the oligarchic tendencies of the merchants.

It’s easy to see how the city’s self-governance could grow from the special authority in the marketplace, especially when this right was granted, whether willingly or not, to the city itself. This origin of the city’s freedoms, which can be observed in many cases, inevitably influenced their later development. It favored the trading sector of the community. The burghers who owned a house in the city at that time, and who were co-owners of the town lands, often formed a merchant guild that controlled the city’s trade. Although initially, every burgher, rich and poor, could join the merchant guild, and the trade was thought to be conducted for the whole city by its trustees, the guild gradually became a privileged group. It carefully blocked outsiders—who soon started moving to the free cities—from joining the guild, keeping the benefits of trade for the few "families" who had been burghers at the time of their liberation. Clearly, there was a risk of a merchant oligarchy forming. However, by the tenth century, and even more so in the following two centuries, the main crafts, also organized into guilds, were strong enough to counteract the oligarchic tendencies of the merchants.

The craft guild was then a common seller of its produce and a common buyer of the raw materials, and its members were merchants and manual workers at the same time. Therefore, the predominance taken by the old craft guilds from the very beginnings of the free city life guaranteed to manual labour the high position which it afterwards occupied in the city.(4) In fact, in a medieval city manual labour was no token of inferiority; it bore, on the contrary, traces of the high respect it had been kept in in the village community. Manual labour in a "mystery" was considered as a pious duty towards the citizens: a public function (Amt), as honourable as any other. An idea of "justice" to the community, of "right" towards both producer and consumer, which would seem so extravagant now, penetrated production and exchange. The tanner's, the cooper's, or the shoemaker's work must be "just," fair, they wrote in those times. Wood, leather or thread which are used by the artisan must be "right"; bread must be baked "in justice," and so on. Transport this language into our present life, and it would seem affected and unnatural; but it was natural and unaffected then, because the medieval artisan did not produce for an unknown buyer, or to throw his goods into an unknown market. He produced for his guild first; for a brotherhood of men who knew each other, knew the technics of the craft, and, in naming the price of each product, could appreciate the skill displayed in its fabrication or the labour bestowed upon it. Then the guild, not the separate producer, offered the goods for sale in the community, and this last, in its turn, offered to the brotherhood of allied communities those goods which were exported, and assumed responsibility for their quality. With such an organization, it was the ambition of each craft not to offer goods of inferior quality, and technical defects or adulterations became a matter concerning the whole community, because, an ordinance says, "they would destroy public confidence."(5) Production being thus a social duty, placed under the control of the whole amitas, manual labour could not fall into the degraded condition which it occupies now, so long as the free city was living.

The craft guild acted as a common seller of its products and a common buyer of raw materials, with its members serving as both merchants and manual workers at the same time. As a result, the influence of the old craft guilds from the early days of free city life ensured that manual labor maintained a high status in the city. In fact, in a medieval city, manual labor wasn't seen as inferior; instead, it reflected the high regard it held in the village community. Manual labor in a "mystery" was viewed as a duty to the citizens: a public function (Amt) that was just as honorable as any other. An idea of "justice" in relation to the community, and "rights" for both producers and consumers, which might seem outrageous today, permeated production and exchange. The work of the tanner, the cooper, or the shoemaker had to be "just" and fair, as people wrote back then. The wood, leather, or thread an artisan used had to be "right"; bread had to be baked "in justice," and so on. If we were to use that language today, it might feel pretentious and awkward, but back then it was natural and straightforward because the medieval artisan didn't produce for an unknown buyer or throw goods into an unfamiliar market. They produced first for their guild; for a community of men who knew one another, understood the craft, and could assess the skill involved in making each product and the labor put into it when setting prices. Then the guild, not individual producers, sold the goods to the community, which in turn offered those products to other allied communities for export and took responsibility for their quality. With this kind of organization, each craft aimed to offer high-quality goods, and any technical flaws or tampering were seen as issues affecting the entire community because, as an ordinance stated, "they would destroy public confidence." With production considered a social duty, overseen by the whole amitas, manual labor couldn't fall into the degraded state it finds itself in today, as long as the free city was thriving.

A difference between master and apprentice, or between master and worker (compayne, Geselle), existed but in the medieval cities from their very beginnings; this was at the outset a mere difference of age and skill, not of wealth and power. After a seven years' apprenticeship, and after having proved his knowledge and capacities by a work of art, the apprentice became a master himself. And only much later, in the sixteenth century, after the royal power had destroyed the city and the craft organization, was it possible to become master in virtue of simple inheritance or wealth. But this was also the time of a general decay in medieval industries and art.

A distinction between master and apprentice, or between master and worker (compayne, Geselle), has existed in medieval cities since their beginnings; initially, this was simply a difference in age and skill, not in wealth and power. After a seven-year apprenticeship and proving his knowledge and skills through a piece of art, the apprentice became a master. It wasn’t until much later, in the sixteenth century, when royal power had dismantled the city and the craft organization, that it became possible to become a master solely through inheritance or wealth. However, this was also a time marked by the decline of medieval industries and art.

There was not much room for hired work in the early flourishing periods of the medieval cities, still less for individual hirelings. The work of the weavers, the archers, the smiths, the bakers, and so on, was performed for the craft and the city; and when craftsmen were hired in the building trades, they worked as temporary corporations (as they still do in the Russian artels), whose work was paid en bloc. Work for a master began to multiply only later on; but even in this case the worker was paid better than he is paid now, even in this country, and very much better than he used to be paid all over Europe in the first half of this century. Thorold Rogers has familiarized English readers with this idea; but the same is true for the Continent as well, as is shown by the researches of Falke and Schonberg, and by many occasional indications. Even in the fifteenth century a mason, a carpenter, or a smith worker would be paid at Amiens four sols a day, which corresponded to forty-eight pounds of bread, or to the eighth part of a small ox (bouvard). In Saxony, the salary of the Geselle in the building trade was such that, to put it in Falke's words, he could buy with his six days' wages three sheep and one pair of shoes.(6) The donations of workers (Geselle) to cathedrals also bear testimony of their relative well-being, to say nothing of the glorious donations of certain craft guilds nor of what they used to spend in festivities and pageants.(7) In fact, the more we learn about the medieval city, the more we are convinced that at no time has labour enjoyed such conditions of prosperity and such respect as when city life stood at its highest.

There wasn't much opportunity for hired work during the early thriving periods of medieval cities, even less for individual laborers. The work of weavers, archers, blacksmiths, bakers, and others was done for the craft and the city; when craftsmen were hired in construction, they worked as temporary groups (like they still do in Russian artels), and their pay was made collectively. The demand for workers under a master started to grow only later; but even then, workers were paid better than they are today, even in this country, and much better than they were paid across Europe in the first half of this century. Thorold Rogers has brought this idea to the attention of English readers; however, the same applies to the Continent, as shown by the research of Falke and Schonberg, along with various other indications. Even in the fifteenth century, a mason, carpenter, or blacksmith in Amiens would earn four sols a day, which was equivalent to forty-eight pounds of bread or one-eighth of a small ox (bouvard). In Saxony, the salary of the Geselle in construction was such that, in Falke's words, he could buy three sheep and a pair of shoes with just six days’ wages.(6) The donations from workers (Geselle) to cathedrals also reflect their relative wealth, not to mention the generous donations from certain craft guilds and their spending on festivals and parades.(7) In fact, the more we learn about medieval cities, the more we realize that labor has never enjoyed such prosperous conditions and respect as when city life was at its peak.

More than that; not only many aspirations of our modern radicals were already realized in the middle ages, but much of what is described now as Utopian was accepted then as a matter of fact. We are laughed at when we say that work must be pleasant, but—"every one must be pleased with his work," a medieval Kuttenberg ordinance says, "and no one shall, while doing nothing (mit nichts thun), appropriate for himself what others have produced by application and work, because laws must be a shield for application and work."(8) And amidst all present talk about an eight hours' day, it may be well to remember an ordinance of Ferdinand the First relative to the Imperial coal mines, which settled the miner's day at eight hours, "as it used to be of old" (wie vor Alters herkommen), and work on Saturday afternoon was prohibited. Longer hours were very rare, we are told by Janssen, while shorter hours were of common occurrence. In this country, in the fifteenth century, Rogers says, "the workmen worked only forty-eight hours a week."(9) The Saturday half-holiday, too, which we consider as a modern conquest, was in reality an old medieval institution; it was bathing-time for a great part of the community, while Wednesday afternoon was bathing-time for the Geselle.(10) And although school meals did not exist—probably because no children went hungry to school—a distribution of bath-money to the children whose parents found difficulty in providing it was habitual in several places. As to Labour Congresses, they also were a regular Feature of the middles ages. In some parts of Germany craftsmen of the same trade, belonging to different communes, used to come together every year to discuss questions relative to their trade, the years of apprenticeship, the wandering years, the wages, and so on; and in 1572, the Hanseatic towns formally recognized the right of the crafts to come together at periodical congresses, and to take any resolutions, so long as they were not contrary to the cities' rolls, relative to the quality of goods. Such Labour Congresses, partly international like the Hansa itself, are known to have been held by bakers, founders, smiths, tanners, sword-makers and cask-makers.(11)

More than that, not only were many aspirations of our modern radicals already achieved in the Middle Ages, but a lot of what we now refer to as Utopian was accepted back then as a matter of fact. We're laughed at when we say that work should be enjoyable, but—"everyone must be happy with their work," a medieval Kuttenberg ordinance states, "and no one shall, while doing nothing, take for themselves what others have created through effort and labor because laws must protect effort and work." And amidst all the current discussions about an eight-hour workday, it's worth mentioning an ordinance from Ferdinand the First regarding the Imperial coal mines, which established the miner's day at eight hours, "as it used to be in the past," and work on Saturday afternoons was banned. Longer hours were quite rare, as noted by Janssen, while shorter hours were common. In this country, during the fifteenth century, Rogers mentions, "the workers only worked forty-eight hours a week." The Saturday half-holiday, which we see as a modern achievement, was actually an old medieval practice; it was bath time for a large portion of the community, while Wednesday afternoons were for the Geselle's bath time. Although school meals didn't exist—probably because no children went hungry to school—a distribution of bath money to the children whose parents struggled to provide it was commonplace in several areas. As for Labor Congresses, they were also a regular part of the Middle Ages. In some regions of Germany, craftsmen of the same trade from different communities would gather every year to discuss issues related to their trade, the years of apprenticeship, the wandering years, wages, and more; and in 1572, the Hanseatic towns formally acknowledged the right of the craftsmen to meet for periodic congresses and to make any resolutions, as long as they didn't contradict the cities' regulations concerning the quality of goods. Such Labor Congresses, partly international like the Hanse itself, were known to have been held by bakers, founders, blacksmiths, tanners, sword makers, and coopers.

The craft organization required, of course, a close supervision of the craftsmen by the guild, and special jurates were always nominated for that purpose. But it is most remarkable that, so long as the cities lived their free life, no complaints were heard about the supervision; while, after the State had stepped in, confiscating the property of the guilds and destroying their independence in favour of its own bureaucracy, the complaints became simply countless.(12) On the other hand, the immensity of progress realized in all arts under the mediaeval guild system is the best proof that the system was no hindrance to individual initiative.(13) The fact is, that the medieval guild, like the medieval parish, "street," or "quarter," was not a body of citizens, placed under the control of State functionaries; it was a union of all men connected with a given trade: jurate buyers of raw produce, sellers of manufactured goods, and artisans—masters, "compaynes," and apprentices. For the inner organization of the trade its assembly was sovereign, so long as it did not hamper the other guilds, in which case the matter was brought before the guild of the guilds—the city. But there was in it something more than that. It had its own self-jurisdiction, its own military force, its own general assemblies, its own traditions of struggles, glory, and independence, its own relations with other guilds of the same trade in other cities: it had, in a word, a full organic life which could only result from the integrality of the vital functions. When the town was called to arms, the guild appeared as a separate company (Schaar), armed with its own arms (or its own guns, lovingly decorated by the guild, at a subsequent epoch), under its own self-elected commanders. It was, in a word, as independent a unit of the federation as the republic of Uri or Geneva was fifty years ago in the Swiss Confederation. So that, to compare it with a modern trade union, divested of all attributes of State sovereignty, and reduced to a couple of functions of secondary importance, is as unreasonable as to compare Florence or Brugge with a French commune vegetating under the Code Napoleon, or with a Russian town placed under Catherine the Second's municipal law. Both have elected mayors, and the latter has also its craft corporations; but the difference is—all the difference that exists between Florence and Fontenay-les-Oies or Tsarevokokshaisk, or between a Venetian doge and a modern mayor who lifts his hat before the sous-prefet's clerk.

The craft organization obviously needed close supervision of the craftsmen by the guild, and special jurates were always appointed for that job. However, it’s remarkable that as long as the cities enjoyed their independence, no complaints were made about the supervision; once the State intervened, seizing the property of the guilds and undermining their autonomy for the sake of its own bureaucracy, complaints skyrocketed. On the other hand, the significant advances achieved in all arts under the medieval guild system clearly show that this system didn't inhibit individual initiative. Essentially, the medieval guild, like the medieval parish, "street," or "quarter," wasn’t merely a group of citizens controlled by State officials; it was a union of all individuals involved in a specific trade: jurate buyers of raw materials, sellers of finished products, and craftsmen—masters, “companions,” and apprentices. For trade matters, its assembly held authority, as long as it didn’t impede other guilds, in which case the issue would be taken to the guild of guilds—the city. But there was more to it than that. It had its own self-governance, military force, general assemblies, traditions of struggles, glory, and independence, and connections with other guilds of the same trade in other cities: in short, it had a complete organic life stemming from the full function of its vital processes. When the town went to war, the guild appeared as a separate company (Schaar), armed with its own weapons (or its own guns, lovingly decorated by the guild in later times), under its own elected leaders. In essence, it was as independent a unit of the federation as the republic of Uri or Geneva had been fifty years earlier in the Swiss Confederation. Therefore, comparing it to a modern trade union, stripped of all elements of State sovereignty, and reduced to a couple of secondary functions, is as unreasonable as comparing Florence or Bruges to a French commune surviving under the Code Napoleon, or a Russian town governed by Catherine the Second's municipal law. Both have elected mayors, and the latter also has craft corporations; but the difference is all the difference that exists between Florence and Fontenay-les-Oies or Tsarevokokshaisk, or between a Venetian doge and a modern mayor who tips his hat to the sous-prefet's clerk.

The medieval guilds were capable of maintaining their independence; and, later on, especially in the fourteenth century, when, in consequence of several causes which shall presently be indicated, the old municipal life underwent a deep modification, the younger crafts proved strong enough to conquer their due share in the management of the city affairs. The masses, organized in "minor" arts, rose to wrest the power out of the hands of a growing oligarchy, and mostly succeeded in this task, opening again a new era of prosperity. True, that in some cities the uprising was crushed in blood, and mass decapitations of workers followed, as was the case in Paris in 1306, and in Cologne in 1371. In such cases the city's liberties rapidly fell into decay, and the city was gradually subdued by the central authority. But the majority of the towns had preserved enough of vitality to come out of the turmoil with a new life and vigour.(14) A new period of rejuvenescence was their reward. New life was infused, and it found its expression in splendid architectural monuments, in a new period of prosperity, in a sudden progress of technics and invention, and in a new intellectual movement leading to the Renaissance and to the Reformation.

The medieval guilds managed to keep their independence; and later, especially in the fourteenth century, when several factors started changing the old municipal life, the younger crafts proved strong enough to claim their rightful share in running the city's affairs. The masses, organized in "minor" arts, rose up to take power from a growing oligarchy, and they mostly succeeded, ushering in a new era of prosperity. It's true that in some cities the uprising was violently suppressed, leading to mass executions of workers, as happened in Paris in 1306 and in Cologne in 1371. In those cases, the city’s freedoms quickly declined, and the central authority gradually took control. However, most towns had enough resilience to emerge from the chaos revitalized. They were rewarded with a new period of renewal. Fresh life was infused, expressing itself in magnificent architectural monuments, a resurgence in prosperity, rapid advancements in technology and invention, and a new intellectual movement that paved the way for the Renaissance and the Reformation.

The life of a mediaeval city was a succession of hard battles to conquer liberty and to maintain it. True, that a strong and tenacious race of burghers had developed during those fierce contests; true, that love and worship of the mother city had been bred by these struggles, and that the grand things achieved by the mediaeval communes were a direct outcome of that love. But the sacrifices which the communes had to sustain in the battle for freedom were, nevertheless, cruel, and left deep traces of division on their inner life as well. Very few cities had succeeded, under a concurrence of favourable circumstances, in obtaining liberty at one stroke, and these few mostly lost it equally easily; while the great number had to fight fifty or a hundred years in succession, often more, before their rights to free life had been recognized, and another hundred years to found their liberty on a firm basis—the twelfth century charters thus being but one of the stepping-stones to freedom.(15) In reality, the mediaeval city was a fortified oasis amidst a country plunged into feudal submission, and it had to make room for itself by the force of its arms. In consequence of the causes briefly alluded to in the preceding chapter, each village community had gradually fallen under the yoke of some lay or clerical lord. His house had grown to be a castle, and his brothers-in-arms were now the scum of adventurers, always ready to plunder the peasants. In addition to three days a week which the peasants had to work for the lord, they had also to bear all sorts of exactions for the right to sow and to crop, to be gay or sad, to live, to marry, or to die. And, worst of all, they were continually plundered by the armed robbers of some neighbouring lord, who chose to consider them as their master's kin, and to take upon them, and upon their cattle and crops, the revenge for a feud he was fighting against their owner. Every meadow, every field, every river, and road around the city, and every man upon the land was under some lord.

The life of a medieval city was a series of tough struggles to gain and keep freedom. It's true that a strong and determined group of citizens emerged from those intense conflicts; it’s also true that love and pride for the hometown grew from these battles, and the great achievements of the medieval towns were a direct result of that love. However, the sacrifices the towns had to make for their freedom were harsh, leaving deep divisions in their internal life as well. Very few cities managed to gain freedom all at once under favorable circumstances, and those that did often lost it just as quickly; while the vast majority had to fight for fifty or a hundred years, sometimes even longer, before their rights to freedom were recognized, and another hundred years to establish their liberty on solid ground—the charters of the twelfth century being just one of the stepping stones to that freedom. In reality, the medieval city was a fortified oasis in a region steeped in feudal subjugation, and it had to assert itself through military might. As mentioned in the previous chapter, each village community had gradually fallen under the control of some noble or clerical lord. His residence became a castle, and his warriors turned into the dregs of society, always ready to raid the peasants. Besides the three days a week that the peasants had to work for the lord, they also had to endure all kinds of fees just to sow and harvest, to be happy or sad, to live, to marry, or to die. And, worst of all, they were constantly plundered by the armed robbers of neighboring lords, who considered them part of their master's property and took revenge for feuds against their owner on them, their livestock, and their crops. Every meadow, every field, every river, every road around the city, and every man on the land was under the control of some lord.

The hatred of the burghers towards the feudal barons has found a most characteristic expression in the wording of the different charters which they compelled them to sign. Heinrich V. is made to sign in the charter granted to Speier in 1111, that he frees the burghers from "the horrible and execrable law of mortmain, through which the town has been sunk into deepest poverty" (von dem scheusslichen und nichtswurdigen Gesetze, welches gemein Budel genannt wird, Kallsen, i. 307). The coutume of Bayonne, written about 1273, contains such passages as these: "The people is anterior to the lords. It is the people, more numerous than all others, who, desirous of peace, has made the lords for bridling and knocking down the powerful ones," and so on (Giry, Etablissements de Rouen, i. 117, Quoted by Luchaire, p. 24). A charter submitted for King Robert's signature is equally characteristic. He is made to say in it: "I shall rob no oxen nor other animals. I shall seize no merchants, nor take their moneys, nor impose ransom. From Lady Day to the All Saints' Day I shall seize no horse, nor mare, nor foals, in the meadows. I shall not burn the mills, nor rob the flour … I shall offer no protection to thieves," etc. (Pfister has published that document, reproduced by Luchaire). The charter "granted" by the Besancon Archbishop Hugues, in which he has been compelled to enumerate all the mischiefs due to his mortmain rights, is equally characteristic.(16) And so on.

The resentment of the townspeople toward the feudal lords is clearly reflected in the language of the various charters they forced them to sign. Heinrich V. is made to declare in the charter granted to Speyer in 1111 that he frees the townspeople from "the horrible and disgusting law of mortmain, through which the town has fallen into the deepest poverty" (von dem scheusslichen und nichtswurdigen Gesetze, welches gemein Budel genannt wird, Kallsen, i. 307). The customs of Bayonne, written around 1273, include statements like: "The people come before the lords. It is the people, who are more numerous than all others, desiring peace, who have made the lords to control and bring down the powerful," and so on (Giry, Etablissements de Rouen, i. 117, quoted by Luchaire, p. 24). A charter submitted for King Robert's signature is equally telling. In it, he is made to say: "I will not steal any oxen or other animals. I will not seize merchants, nor take their money, nor impose ransom. From Lady Day to All Saints' Day, I will not take any horses, mares, or foals in the meadows. I will not burn the mills, nor take the flour... I will not offer any protection to thieves," etc. (Pfister has published that document, reproduced by Luchaire). The charter "granted" by the Archbishop of Besançon, Hugues, in which he has been forced to list all the damages caused by his mortmain rights, is similarly revealing. (16) And so on.

Freedom could not be maintained in such surroundings, and the cities were compelled to carry on the war outside their walls. The burghers sent out emissaries to lead revolt in the villages; they received villages into their corporations, and they waged direct war against the nobles. It Italy, where the land was thickly sprinkled with feudal castles, the war assumed heroic proportions, and was fought with a stern acrimony on both sides. Florence sustained for seventy-seven years a succession of bloody wars, in order to free its contado from the nobles; but when the conquest had been accomplished (in 1181) all had to begin anew. The nobles rallied; they constituted their own leagues in opposition to the leagues of the towns, and, receiving fresh support from either the Emperor or the Pope, they made the war last for another 130 years. The same took place in Rome, in Lombardy, all over Italy.

Freedom couldn’t survive in such conditions, so the cities had to continue the fight outside their walls. The townspeople sent out messengers to incite rebellion in the villages; they brought villages into their groups and waged direct war against the nobles. In Italy, where the land was dotted with feudal castles, the conflict took on heroic proportions and was fought with fierce intensity on both sides. Florence endured a series of bloody wars for seventy-seven years to free its countryside from the nobles; but once the victory was achieved (in 1181), everything had to start over. The nobles regrouped; they formed their own alliances against the towns' leagues, and with new support from either the Emperor or the Pope, they dragged the war on for another 130 years. The same happened in Rome, Lombardy, and all over Italy.

Prodigies of valour, audacity, and tenaciousness were displayed by the citizens in these wars. But the bows and the hatchets of the arts and crafts had not always the upper hand in their encounters with the armour-clad knights, and many castles withstood the ingenious siege-machinery and the perseverance of the citizens. Some cities, like Florence, Bologna, and many towns in France, Germany, and Bohemia, succeeded in emancipating the surrounding villages, and they were rewarded for their efforts by an extraordinary prosperity and tranquillity. But even here, and still more in the less strong or less impulsive towns, the merchants and artisans, exhausted by war, and misunderstanding their own interests, bargained over the peasants' heads. They compelled the lord to swear allegiance to the city; his country castle was dismantled, and he agreed to build a house and to reside in the city, of which he became a co-burgher (com-bourgeois, con-cittadino); but he maintained in return most of his rights upon the peasants, who only won a partial relief from their burdens. The burgher could not understand that equal rights of citizenship might be granted to the peasant upon whose food supplies he had to rely, and a deep rent was traced between town and village. In some cases the peasants simply changed owners, the city buying out the barons' rights and selling them in shares to her own citizens.(17) Serfdom was maintained, and only much later on, towards the end of the thirteenth century, it was the craft revolution which undertook to put an end to it, and abolished personal servitude, but dispossessed at the same time the serfs of the land.(18) It hardly need be added that the fatal results of such policy were soon felt by the cities themselves; the country became the city's enemy.

The citizens showed incredible bravery, boldness, and determination in these wars. However, their tools and crafts often struggled against the heavily armed knights, and many castles stood firm against their clever siege equipment and resolve. Some cities, like Florence, Bologna, and many towns in France, Germany, and Bohemia, managed to free the surrounding villages, and they were rewarded with remarkable prosperity and peace. But even there, especially in the weaker or less driven towns, the merchants and artisans, worn out by war and misunderstanding their own interests, made deals without considering the peasants. They forced the lord to pledge loyalty to the city; his country castle was torn down, and he agreed to build a house and live in the city, becoming a fellow citizen; however, he still kept most of his rights over the peasants, who only got a bit of relief from their burdens. The townspeople struggled to understand that equal citizenship rights could be given to the peasants who provided their food, creating a significant divide between town and village. In some cases, the peasants merely changed owners, with the city buying out the barons' rights and selling them in shares to its own citizens. Serfdom remained, and it wasn’t until later, towards the end of the thirteenth century, when the craft revolution stepped in to end it, abolishing personal servitude but also taking the land away from the serfs. It hardly needs to be said that the disastrous consequences of such policies were soon felt by the cities themselves; the countryside turned into the city's enemy.

The war against the castles had another bad effect. It involved the cities in a long succession of mutual wars, which have given origin to the theory, till lately in vogue, namely, that the towns lost their independence through their own jealousies and mutual fights. The imperialist historians have especially supported this theory, which, however, is very much undermined now by modern research. It is certain that in Italy cities fought each other with a stubborn animosity, but nowhere else did such contests attain the same proportions; and in Italy itself the city wars, especially those of the earlier period, had their special causes. They were (as was already shown by Sismondi and Ferrari) a mere continuation of the war against the castles—the free municipal and federative principle unavoidably entering into a fierce contest with feudalism, imperialism, and papacy. Many towns which had but partially shaken off the yoke of the bishop, the lord, or the Emperor, were simply driven against the free cities by the nobles, the Emperor, and Church, whose policy was to divide the cities and to arm them against each other. These special circumstances (partly reflected on to Germany also) explain why the Italian towns, some of which sought support with the Emperor to combat the Pope, while the others sought support from the Church to resist the Emperor, were soon divided into a Gibelin and a Guelf camp, and why the same division appeared in each separate city.(19)

The war against the castles had another negative impact. It dragged the cities into a long series of mutual conflicts, leading to the idea, which was popular until recently, that the towns lost their independence due to their own rivalries and infighting. Imperialist historians especially promoted this view, but it has been significantly challenged by modern research. It's clear that in Italy, cities fought each other with intense hostility, but nowhere else did these struggles reach the same level; even within Italy, the city wars, especially those in the earlier period, had specific causes. As Sismondi and Ferrari already pointed out, they were just a continuation of the war against the castles—the free municipal and federative mindset inevitably clashing with feudalism, imperialism, and the papacy. Many towns that had only partially freed themselves from the control of bishops, lords, or the Emperor were simply pushed against the free cities by the nobles, the Emperor, and the Church, whose strategy was to divide the cities and incite them to fight each other. These unique conditions (which also partially influenced Germany) explain why some Italian towns sought support from the Emperor to fight against the Pope, while others looked to the Church for help against the Emperor, quickly dividing into Gibelin and Guelf factions, with the same division appearing in each individual city.(19)

The immense economical progress realized by most italian cities just at the time when these wars were hottest,(20) and the alliances so easily concluded between towns, still better characterize those struggles and further undermine the above theory. Already in the years 1130-1150 powerful leagues came into existence; and a few years later, when Frederick Barbarossa invaded Italy and, supported by the nobles and some retardatory cities, marched against Milan, popular enthusiasm was roused in many towns by popular preachers. Crema, Piacenza, Brescia, Tortona, etc., went to the rescue; the banners of the guilds of Verona, Padua, Vicenza, and Trevisa floated side by side in the cities' camp against the banners of the Emperor and the nobles. Next year the Lombardian League came into existence, and sixty years later we see it reinforced by many other cities, and forming a lasting organization which had half of its federal war-chest in Genoa and the other half in Venice.(21) In Tuscany, Florence headed another powerful league, to which Lucca, Bologna, Pistoia, etc., belonged, and which played an important part in crushing down the nobles in middle Italy, while smaller leagues were of common occurrence. It is thus certain that although petty jealousies undoubtedly existed, and discord could be easily sown, they did not prevent the towns from uniting together for the common defence of liberty. Only later on, when separate cities became little States, wars broke out between them, as always must be the case when States struggle for supremacy or colonies.

The significant economic growth experienced by most Italian cities during the height of these wars, along with the easy alliances formed between towns, better illustrates those struggles and further challenges the theory mentioned earlier. Between 1130 and 1150, powerful leagues started to emerge; a few years later, when Frederick Barbarossa invaded Italy and marched against Milan with the support of the nobles and some opposing cities, many towns were stirred by popular preachers. Crema, Piacenza, Brescia, and Tortona, among others, came to help; the banners of the guilds from Verona, Padua, Vicenza, and Treviso flew together in the cities' camp against the banners of the Emperor and the nobles. The following year, the Lombard League was formed, which sixty years later was strengthened by many other cities, creating a lasting organization with half of its federal war fund in Genoa and the other half in Venice. In Tuscany, Florence led another strong league that included Lucca, Bologna, and Pistoia, playing a crucial role in breaking down the power of the nobles in central Italy, while smaller leagues were quite common. It is clear that although small rivalries existed and discord could easily be provoked, they did not stop the towns from coming together to defend their freedom. Only later, when individual cities became small states, did wars break out between them, as inevitably happens when states compete for dominance or territories.

Similar leagues were formed in Germany for the same purpose. When, under the successors of Conrad, the land was the prey of interminable feuds between the nobles, the Westphalian towns concluded a league against the knights, one of the clauses of which was never to lend money to a knight who would continue to conceal stolen goods.(22) When "the knights and the nobles lived on plunder, and murdered whom they chose to murder," as the Wormser Zorn complains, the cities on the Rhine (Mainz, Cologne, Speier, Strasburg, and Basel) took the initiative of a league which soon numbered sixty allied towns, repressed the robbers, and maintained peace. Later on, the league of the towns of Suabia, divided into three "peace districts" (Augsburg, Constance, and Ulm), had the same purpose. And even when such leagues were broken,(23) they lived long enough to show that while the supposed peacemakers—the kings, the emperors, and the Church-fomented discord, and were themselves helpless against the robber knights, it was from the cities that the impulse came for re-establishing peace and union. The cities—not the emperors—were the real makers of the national unity.(24)

Similar leagues were created in Germany for the same purpose. When, under the successors of Conrad, the region was plagued by endless conflicts among the nobles, the Westphalian towns formed a league against the knights, one of the rules being that they would never lend money to a knight who continued to hide stolen goods. When "the knights and the nobles lived off loot and killed whomever they wanted," as the Wormser Zorn criticizes, the cities along the Rhine (Mainz, Cologne, Speier, Strasburg, and Basel) took the lead in a league that quickly included sixty allied towns, which suppressed the robbers and maintained peace. Later, the league of the towns in Suabia, divided into three "peace districts" (Augsburg, Constance, and Ulm), had the same goal. Even when such leagues fell apart, they lasted long enough to demonstrate that while the supposed peacemakers—the kings, emperors, and the Church—created discord and were powerless against the robber knights, it was the cities that sparked the drive to restore peace and unity. The cities—not the emperors—were the true architects of national unity.

Similar federations were organized for the same purpose among small villages, and now that attention has been drawn to this subject by Luchaire we may expect soon to learn much more about them. Villages joined into small federations in the contado of Florence, so also in the dependencies of Novgorod and Pskov. As to France, there is positive evidence of a federation of seventeen peasant villages which has existed in the Laonnais for nearly a hundred years (till 1256), and has fought hard for its independence. Three more peasant republics, which had sworn charters similar to those of Laon and Soissons, existed in the neighbourhood of Laon, and, their territories being contiguous, they supported each other in their liberation wars. Altogether, Luchaire is of the opinion that many such federations must have come into existence in France in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, but that documents relative to them are mostly lost. Of course, being unprotected by walls, they could easily be crushed down by the kings and the lords; but in certain favourable circumstances, when they found support in a league of towns and protection in their mountains, such peasant republics became independent units of the Swiss Confederation.(25)

Similar federations were formed for the same reason among small villages, and now that Luchaire has highlighted this topic, we can expect to learn a lot more about them soon. Villages banded together into small federations in the Florence area, as well as in the territories of Novgorod and Pskov. In France, there’s clear evidence of a federation of seventeen peasant villages that existed in Laonnais for almost a hundred years (until 1256) and fought hard for their independence. Three additional peasant republics, which had signed charters similar to those of Laon and Soissons, were located near Laon and supported each other in their wars for freedom, as their territories were adjacent. Overall, Luchaire believes that many such federations must have existed in France during the twelfth and thirteenth centuries, but most documents about them have been lost. Of course, being defenseless without walls, they could easily be suppressed by kings and lords; however, under certain favorable conditions, when they received support from a league of towns and protection from their mountains, such peasant republics became independent parts of the Swiss Confederation.

As to unions between cities for peaceful purposes, they were of quite common occurrence. The intercourse which had been established during the period of liberation was not interrupted afterwards. Sometimes, when the scabini of a German town, having to pronounce judgment in a new or complicated case, declared that they knew not the sentence (des Urtheiles nicht weise zu sein), they sent delegates to another city to get the sentence. The same happened also in France;(26) while Forli and Ravenna are known to have mutually naturalized their citizens and granted them full rights in both cities. To submit a contest arisen between two towns, or within a city, to another commune which was invited to act as arbiter, was also in the spirit of the times.(27) As to commercial treaties between cities, they were quite habitual.(28) Unions for regulating the production and the sizes of casks which were used for the commerce in wine, "herring unions," and so on, were mere precursors of the great commercial federations of the Flemish Hansa, and, later on, of the great North German Hansa, the history of which alone might contribute pages and pages to illustrate the federation spirit which permeated men at that time. It hardly need be added, that through the Hanseatic unions the medieval cities have contributed more to the development of international intercourse, navigation, and maritime discovery than all the States of the first seventeen centuries of our era.

As for alliances between cities for peaceful purposes, they were quite common. The connections established during the liberation period continued afterwards. Sometimes, when the leaders of a German town faced a new or complicated case and admitted they didn’t know the ruling, they would send delegates to another city to get the verdict. The same was true in France; while Forli and Ravenna were known to have mutually granted citizenship to each other’s residents, giving them full rights in both cities. Submitting disputes between two towns, or within a city, to another town invited to act as an arbiter was also common at that time. Commercial treaties between cities were quite routine. Alliances to regulate the production and sizes of casks used in the wine trade, "herring unions," and similar agreements were just the early steps toward the major commercial federations of the Flemish Hansa, and later, the large North German Hansa, the history of which could fill pages illustrating the spirit of federation that permeated society then. It’s worth noting that through the Hanseatic unions, medieval cities significantly advanced international commerce, navigation, and maritime discovery more than all the States of the first seventeen centuries of our era combined.

In a word, federations between small territorial units, as well as among men united by common pursuits within their respective guilds, and federations between cities and groups of cities constituted the very essence of life and thought during that period. The first five of the second decade of centuries of our era may thus be described as an immense attempt at securing mutual aid and support on a grand scale, by means of the principles of federation and association carried on through all manifestations of human life and to all possible degrees. This attempt was attended with success to a very great extent. It united men formerly divided; it secured them a very great deal of freedom, and it tenfolded their forces. At a time when particularism was bred by so many agencies, and the causes of discord and jealousy might have been so numerous, it is gratifying to see that cities scattered over a wide continent had so much in common, and were so ready to confederate for the prosecution of so many common aims. They succumbed in the long run before powerful enemies; not having understood the mutual-aid principle widely enough, they themselves committed fatal faults; but they did not perish through their own jealousies, and their errors were not a want of federation spirit among themselves.

In short, alliances between small regions, as well as among people united by shared interests within their guilds, and partnerships between cities and groups of cities were the core of life and thought during that time. The first five years of the second decade of our era can be described as a massive effort to secure mutual help and support on a grand scale, through the principles of federation and collaboration evident in all aspects of human life and to every possible extent. This effort was largely successful. It brought together people who were once divided; it granted them a significant amount of freedom and multiplied their strength tenfold. At a time when localism was fueled by various factors, and there were many potential causes for conflict and jealousy, it's encouraging to see that cities spread across a vast continent had so much in common and were eager to unite for many shared goals. In the end, they were overcome by powerful foes; having not fully grasped the principle of mutual aid, they made serious mistakes; but they didn’t fall apart because of their own jealousies, and their failures weren’t due to a lack of a spirit of federation among themselves.

The results of that new move which mankind made in the medieval city were immense. At the beginning of the eleventh century the towns of Europe were small clusters of miserable huts, adorned but with low clumsy churches, the builders of which hardly knew how to make an arch; the arts, mostly consisting of some weaving and forging, were in their infancy; learning was found in but a few monasteries. Three hundred and fifty years later, the very face of Europe had been changed. The land was dotted with rich cities, surrounded by immense thick walls which were embellished by towers and gates, each of them a work of art in itself. The cathedrals, conceived in a grand style and profusely decorated, lifted their bell-towers to the skies, displaying a purity of form and a boldness of imagination which we now vainly strive to attain. The crafts and arts had risen to a degree of perfection which we can hardly boast of having superseded in many directions, if the inventive skill of the worker and the superior finish of his work be appreciated higher than rapidity of fabrication. The navies of the free cities furrowed in all directions the Northern and the Southern Mediterranean; one effort more, and they would cross the oceans. Over large tracts of land well-being had taken the place of misery; learning had grown and spread. The methods of science had been elaborated; the basis of natural philosophy had been laid down; and the way had been paved for all the mechanical inventions of which our own times are so proud. Such were the magic changes accomplished in Europe in less than four hundred years. And the losses which Europe sustained through the loss of its free cities can only be understood when we compare the seventeenth century with the fourteenth or the thirteenth. The prosperity which formerly characterized Scotland, Germany, the plains of Italy, was gone. The roads had fallen into an abject state, the cities were depopulated, labour was brought into slavery, art had vanished, commerce itself was decaying.(29)

The impact of that new change made by humanity in the medieval city was immense. At the start of the eleventh century, the towns of Europe were just small clusters of run-down huts, featuring only low, awkward churches whose builders barely knew how to construct an arch; the arts, mostly limited to some weaving and metalworking, were in their early stages; and learning was confined to a few monasteries. Three hundred and fifty years later, the entire landscape of Europe had transformed. The land was filled with prosperous cities, surrounded by massive, sturdy walls adorned with towers and gates, each a work of art in itself. The cathedrals, designed in a grand style and richly decorated, stretched their bell towers skyward, showcasing a purity of design and bold imagination that we now strive to achieve in vain. The crafts and arts had reached a level of perfection that we can hardly claim to have surpassed in many areas, provided we value the skill of the craftsman and the high quality of his work over the speed of production. The navies of the free cities navigated all over the Northern and Southern Mediterranean; with just one more effort, they would have crossed the oceans. Great stretches of land had seen prosperity replace suffering; learning had flourished and expanded. Scientific methods had been refined; the foundations of natural philosophy had been established; and the groundwork was laid for all the mechanical inventions that our times so proudly showcase. Such were the remarkable transformations in Europe in less than four hundred years. The losses Europe suffered due to the decline of its free cities become clear when we compare the seventeenth century with the fourteenth or thirteenth. The prosperity that once characterized Scotland, Germany, and the plains of Italy was lost. The roads had deteriorated, cities were left deserted, labor was reduced to slavery, art had disappeared, and commerce itself was in decline.(29)

If the medieval cities had bequeathed to us no written documents to testify of their splendour, and left nothing behind but the monuments of building art which we see now all over Europe, from Scotland to Italy, and from Gerona in Spain to Breslau in Slavonian territory, we might yet conclude that the times of independent city life were times of the greatest development of human intellect during the Christian era down to the end of the eighteenth century. On looking, for instance, at a medieval picture representing Nuremberg with its scores of towers and lofty spires, each of which bore the stamp of free creative art, we can hardly conceive that three hundred years before the town was but a collection of miserable hovels. And our admiration grows when we go into the details of the architecture and decorations of each of the countless churches, bell-towers, gates, and communal houses which are scattered all over Europe as far east as Bohemia and the now dead towns of Polish Galicia. Not only Italy, that mother of art, but all Europe is full of such monuments. The very fact that of all arts architecture—a social art above all—had attained the highest development, is significant in itself. To be what it was, it must have originated from an eminently social life.

If medieval cities hadn’t left us any written records to showcase their splendor, and had only given us the architectural monuments we find all over Europe, from Scotland to Italy, and from Gerona in Spain to Breslau in present-day Poland, we could still conclude that the era of independent city life was a time of immense growth for human intellect during the Christian era, lasting until the end of the eighteenth century. For example, when we look at a medieval painting of Nuremberg with its many towers and tall spires, each reflecting unique creative art, it’s hard to imagine that three hundred years prior, the town was just a cluster of shabby huts. Our admiration deepens as we explore the details of the architecture and decorations of the countless churches, bell towers, gates, and community buildings found all over Europe, reaching as far east as Bohemia and the now-gone towns of Polish Galicia. Not just Italy, the birthplace of art, but all of Europe brims with these monuments. The fact that architecture—an art deeply rooted in social connection—achieved such high levels of development is significant in itself. To have been what it was, it must have arisen from a vibrant social life.

Medieval architecture attained its grandeur—not only because it was a natural development of handicraft; not only because each building, each architectural decoration, had been devised by men who knew through the experience of their own hands what artistic effects can be obtained from stone, iron, bronze, or even from simple logs and mortar; not only because, each monument was a result of collective experience, accumulated in each "mystery" or craft(30)—it was grand because it was born out of a grand idea. Like Greek art, it sprang out of a conception of brotherhood and unity fostered by the city. It had an audacity which could only be won by audacious struggles and victories; it had that expression of vigour, because vigour permeated all the life of the city. A cathedral or a communal house symbolized the grandeur of an organism of which every mason and stone-cutter was the builder, and a medieval building appears—not as a solitary effort to which thousands of slaves would have contributed the share assigned them by one man's imagination; all the city contributed to it. The lofty bell-tower rose upon a structure, grand in itself, in which the life of the city was throbbing—not upon a meaningless scaffold like the Paris iron tower, not as a sham structure in stone intended to conceal the ugliness of an iron frame, as has been done in the Tower Bridge. Like the Acropolis of Athens, the cathedral of a medieval city was intended to glorify the grandeur of the victorious city, to symbolize the union of its crafts, to express the glory of each citizen in a city of his own creation. After having achieved its craft revolution, the city often began a new cathedral in order to express the new, wider, and broader union which had been called into life.

Medieval architecture achieved its greatness—not just because it was a natural progression of craftsmanship; not just because each building and architectural detail was designed by people who understood through hands-on experience the artistic possibilities of stone, iron, bronze, or even basic logs and mortar; not just because each monument was the outcome of collective knowledge accumulated in each "mystery" or craft(30)—it was grand because it originated from a significant idea. Like Greek art, it emerged from a vision of brotherhood and unity nurtured by the city. It had a boldness that could only be earned through courageous struggles and victories; it reflected a sense of energy because that energy infused the entire life of the city. A cathedral or a communal building symbolized the greatness of an entity where every mason and stone-cutter played a role, and a medieval structure appears—not as a solitary endeavor where thousands of workers contributed their piece as assigned by one person's imagination; the whole city contributed to it. The towering bell tower stood atop a magnificent structure, reflecting the vibrant life of the city—not on a meaningless scaffold like the Paris iron tower, nor as a superficial stone façade meant to hide the ugly iron framework, as seen in the Tower Bridge. Like the Acropolis of Athens, the cathedral of a medieval city was meant to celebrate the glory of the victorious city, symbolize the unity of its crafts, and express the pride of each citizen in a city of their own making. After achieving its craft revolution, the city often started a new cathedral to represent the new, wider, and broader unity that had come to life.

The means at hand for these grand undertakings were disproportionately small. Cologne Cathedral was begun with a yearly outlay of but 500 marks; a gift of 100 marks was inscribed as a grand donation;(31) and even when the work approached completion, and gifts poured in in proportion, the yearly outlay in money stood at about 5,000 marks, and never exceeded 14,000. The cathedral of Basel was built with equally small means. But each corporation contributed its part of stone, work, and decorative genius to their common monument. Each guild expressed in it its political conceptions, telling in stone or in bronze the history of the city, glorifying the principles of "Liberty, equality, and fraternity,"(32) praising the city's allies, and sending to eternal fire its enemies. And each guild bestowed its love upon the communal monument by richly decorating it with stained windows, paintings, "gates, worthy to be the gates of Paradise," as Michel Angelo said, or stone decorations of each minutest corner of the building.(33) Small cities, even small parishes,(34) vied with the big agglomerations in this work, and the cathedrals of Laon and St. Ouen hardly stand behind that of Rheims, or the Communal House of Bremen, or the folkmote's bell-tower of Breslau. "No works must be begun by the commune but such as are conceived in response to the grand heart of the commune, composed of the hearts of all citizens, united in one common will"—such were the words of the Council of Florence; and this spirit appears in all communal works of common utility, such as the canals, terraces, vineyards, and fruit gardens around Florence, or the irrigation canals which intersected the plains of Lombardy, or the port and aqueduct of Genoa, or, in fact, any works of the kind which were achieved by almost every city.(35)

The resources available for these ambitious projects were surprisingly limited. Cologne Cathedral started with an annual budget of just 500 marks; a donation of 100 marks was labeled as a significant contribution; and even as the project neared completion, with donations increasing, the yearly budget remained around 5,000 marks, never exceeding 14,000. The cathedral in Basel was built under similar financial constraints. However, every guild contributed its share of materials, labor, and artistic talent to this communal effort. Each guild reflected its political beliefs, depicting the city's history in stone or bronze, celebrating the ideals of "Liberty, equality, and fraternity," honoring the city's allies, and casting its adversaries into the flames of historical memory. Each guild expressed its dedication to the shared monument by adorning it with stained glass, paintings, "gates worthy to be the gates of Paradise," as Michelangelo put it, or intricate stone carvings on every corner of the structure. Smaller towns, and even small parishes, competed with larger cities in this endeavor, and the cathedrals of Laon and St. Ouen are hardly less impressive than those of Rheims, the Town Hall of Bremen, or the bell tower of Breslau. "No projects should be initiated by the community unless they arise from the collective spirit of the community, made up of the hearts of all citizens, united in a common purpose"—this was the message from the Council of Florence, and this ethos is evident in all communal undertakings for public benefit, like the canals, terraces, vineyards, and orchards surrounding Florence, or the irrigation ditches that crisscrossed the plains of Lombardy, or the port and aqueduct of Genoa, indeed, in nearly every city’s similar efforts.

All arts had progressed in the same way in the medieval cities, those of our own days mostly being but a continuation of what had grown at that time. The prosperity of the Flemish cities was based upon the fine woollen cloth they fabricated. Florence, at the beginning of the fourteenth century, before the black death, fabricated from 70,000 to 100,000 panni of woollen stuffs, which were valued at 1,200,000 golden florins.(36) The chiselling of precious metals, the art of casting, the fine forging of iron, were creations of the mediaeval "mysteries" which had succeeded in attaining in their own domains all that could be made by the hand, without the use of a powerful prime motor. By the hand and by invention, because, to use Whewell's words:

All arts progressed similarly in medieval cities, and many of our current practices are just a continuation of what developed during that time. The wealth of Flemish cities depended on the high-quality woolen cloth they produced. In Florence, at the start of the fourteenth century, before the Black Death, they produced between 70,000 and 100,000 woolen pieces, valued at 1,200,000 golden florins. The craftsmanship of precious metals, the art of casting, and the fine forging of iron were products of the medieval "mysteries" that achieved remarkable results in their fields without relying on powerful machinery. Through craftsmanship and innovation, because, to quote Whewell:

"Parchment and paper, printing and engraving, improved glass and steel, gunpowder, clocks, telescopes, the mariner's compass, the reformed calendar, the decimal notation; algebra, trigonometry, chemistry, counterpoint (an invention equivalent to a new creation of music); these are all possessions which we inherit from that which has so disparagingly been termed the Stationary Period" (History of Inductive Sciences, i. 252).

"Parchment and paper, printing and engraving, improved glass and steel, gunpowder, clocks, telescopes, the mariner's compass, the updated calendar, decimal notation; algebra, trigonometry, chemistry, counterpoint (an invention as significant as a new creation of music); these are all benefits we inherit from what has been unfairly called the Stationary Period" (History of Inductive Sciences, i. 252).

True that no new principle was illustrated by any of these discoveries, as Whewell said; but medieval science had done something more than the actual discovery of new principles. It had prepared the discovery of all the new principles which we know at the present time in mechanical sciences: it had accustomed the explorer to observe facts and to reason from them. It was inductive science, even though it had not yet fully grasped the importance and the powers of induction; and it laid the foundations of both mechanics and natural philosophy. Francis Bacon, Galileo, and Copernicus were the direct descendants of a Roger Bacon and a Michael Scot, as the steam engine was a direct product of the researches carried on in the Italian universities on the weight of the atmosphere, and of the mathematical and technical learning which characterized Nuremberg.

It's true that none of these discoveries illustrated any new principles, as Whewell pointed out; but medieval science contributed more than just the actual discovery of new principles. It set the stage for the discovery of all the new principles we currently understand in mechanical sciences: it trained explorers to observe facts and reason from them. It was inductive science, even if it hadn't fully realized the importance and power of induction yet; and it established the foundations of both mechanics and natural philosophy. Francis Bacon, Galileo, and Copernicus were the direct heirs of Roger Bacon and Michael Scot, just as the steam engine was a direct result of the research conducted in the Italian universities on atmospheric weight, along with the mathematical and technical knowledge that defined Nuremberg.

But why should one take trouble to insist upon the advance of science and art in the medieval city? Is it not enough to point to the cathedrals in the domain of skill, and to the Italian language and the poem of Dante in the domain of thought, to give at once the measure of what the medieval city created during the four centuries it lived?

But why should anyone bother to emphasize the progress of science and art in the medieval city? Isn’t it enough to point to the cathedrals as a testament to skill, and to the Italian language and Dante’s poem as examples of thought, to immediately show what the medieval city accomplished during its four centuries of existence?

The medieval cities have undoubtedly rendered an immense service to European civilization. They have prevented it from being drifted into the theocracies and despotical states of old; they have endowed it with the variety, the self-reliance, the force of initiative, and the immense intellectual and material energies it now possesses, which are the best pledge for its being able to resist any new invasion of the East. But why did these centres of civilization, which attempted to answer to deeply-seated needs of human nature, and were so full of life, not live further on? Why were they seized with senile debility in the sixteenth century? and, after having repulsed so many assaults from without, and only borrowed new vigour from their interior struggles, why did they finally succumb to both?

The medieval cities played a crucial role in shaping European civilization. They kept it from falling into the old theocracies and tyrannical states; they gave it diversity, self-reliance, the drive for innovation, and the immense intellectual and material resources it has today, which are the best guarantee for its ability to resist any new invasions from the East. But why did these centers of civilization, which sought to meet the deep needs of human nature and were full of vitality, not continue? Why did they fall into a state of decline in the sixteenth century? After fending off numerous external attacks and drawing new strength from their internal conflicts, why did they ultimately fail against both?

Various causes contributed to this effect, some of them having their roots in the remote past, while others originated in the mistakes committed by the cities themselves. Towards the end of the fifteenth century, mighty States, reconstructed on the old Roman pattern, were already coming into existence. In each country and each region some feudal lord, more cunning, more given to hoarding, and often less scrupulous than his neighbours, had succeeded in appropriating to himself richer personal domains, more peasants on his lands, more knights in his following, more treasures in his chest. He had chosen for his seat a group of happily-situated villages, not yet trained into free municipal life—Paris, Madrid, or Moscow—and with the labour of his serfs he had made of them royal fortified cities, whereto he attracted war companions by a free distribution of villages, and merchants by the protection he offered to trade. The germ of a future State, which began gradually to absorb other similar centres, was thus laid. Lawyers, versed in the study of Roman law, flocked into such centres; a tenacious and ambitious race of men issued from among the burgesses, who equally hated the naughtiness of the lords and what they called the lawlessness of the peasants. The very forms of the village community, unknown to their code, the very principles of federalism were repulsive to them as "barbarian" inheritances. Caesarism, supported by the fiction of popular consent and by the force of arms, was their ideal, and they worked hard for those who promised to realize it.(37)

Various factors played a role in this situation, some tracing back to the distant past, while others stemmed from the errors the cities themselves made. By the end of the fifteenth century, powerful states, rebuilt on the old Roman model, were starting to emerge. In each country and region, some feudal lord, more cunning, more inclined to hoard wealth, and often less ethical than his neighbors, had succeeded in seizing richer lands for himself, gaining more peasants on his estates, more knights in his retinue, and more treasures in his vault. He had chosen a cluster of well-located villages that had not yet developed into free municipal life—like Paris, Madrid, or Moscow—and through the labor of his serfs, he transformed them into fortified royal cities, attracting warriors with the promise of land and merchants by protecting their trade. This laid the groundwork for a future state that would gradually absorb other similar centers. Lawyers experienced in Roman law flocked to these centers; a determined and ambitious group emerged from among the townsfolk, who despised both the mischief of the lords and what they viewed as the chaos of the peasants. The very structures of the village community, unknown to their legal system, and the basic principles of federalism were repugnant to them as "barbaric" legacies. They aspired to a form of Caesarism, backed by the illusion of popular consent and military force, and they worked diligently for those who promised to bring it to fruition.

The Christian Church, once a rebel against Roman law and now its ally, worked in the same direction. The attempt at constituting the theocratic Empire of Europe having proved a failure, the more intelligent and ambitious bishops now yielded support to those whom they reckoned upon for reconstituting the power of the Kings of Israel or of the Emperors of Constantinople. The Church bestowed upon the rising rulers her sanctity, she crowned them as God's representatives on earth, she brought to their service the learning and the statesmanship of her ministers, her blessings and maledictions, her riches, and the sympathies she had retained among the poor. The peasants, whom the cities had failed or refused to free, on seeing the burghers impotent to put an end to the interminable wars between the knights—which wars they had so dearly to pay for—now set their hopes upon the King, the Emperor, or the Great Prince; and while aiding them to crush down the mighty feudal owners, they aided them to constitute the centralized State. And finally, the invasions of the Mongols and the Turks, the holy war against the Maures in Spain, as well as the terrible wars which soon broke out between the growing centres of sovereignty—Ile de France and Burgundy, Scotland and England, England and France, Lithuania and Poland, Moscow and Tver, and so on—contributed to the same end. Mighty States made their appearance; and the cities had now to resist not only loose federations of lords, but strongly-organized centres, which had armies of serfs at their disposal.

The Christian Church, once a rebel against Roman law and now its ally, moved in the same direction. Since the attempt to create a theocratic Empire of Europe had failed, the more intelligent and ambitious bishops began to support those they saw as capable of restoring the power of the Kings of Israel or the Emperors of Constantinople. The Church granted the emerging rulers its sanctity, crowned them as God’s representatives on earth, and provided them with the knowledge and statesmanship of its ministers, along with its blessings and curses, wealth, and the support it had among the poor. The peasants, who cities had failed or refused to liberate, seeing the townspeople powerless to end the endless wars among the knights—which they had to pay so dearly for—now placed their hopes in the King, the Emperor, or the Great Prince; and while helping them to suppress the powerful feudal lords, they also helped to establish the centralized state. Ultimately, the invasions of the Mongols and Turks, the holy war against the Moors in Spain, as well as the brutal wars that soon broke out between the rising centers of power—Île-de-France and Burgundy, Scotland and England, England and France, Lithuania and Poland, Moscow and Tver, and so on—contributed to the same outcome. Powerful states emerged; and the cities now had to contend not only with loose federations of lords but also with well-organized centers that had armies of serfs at their command.

The worst was, that the growing autocracies found support in the divisions which had grown within the cities themselves. The fundamental idea of the medieval city was grand, but it was not wide enough. Mutual aid and support cannot be limited to a small association; they must spread to its surroundings, or else the surroundings will absorb the association. And in this respect the medieval citizen had committed a formidable mistake at the outset. Instead of looking upon the peasants and artisans who gathered under the protection of his walls as upon so many aids who would contribute their part to the making of the city—as they really did—a sharp division was traced between the "families" of old burghers and the newcomers. For the former, all benefits from communal trade and communal lands were reserved, and nothing was left for the latter but the right of freely using the skill of their own hands. The city thus became divided into "the burghers" or "the commonalty," and "the inhabitants."(38) The trade, which was formerly communal, now became the privilege of the merchant and artisan "families," and the next step—that of becoming individual, or the privilege of oppressive trusts—was unavoidable.

The worst part was that the rising autocracies found support in the divisions that had developed within the cities themselves. The basic idea of the medieval city was impressive, but it wasn’t broad enough. Mutual aid and support can’t be limited to a small group; they have to extend to the surrounding areas, or else those areas will overtake the group. In this regard, the medieval citizen made a significant mistake from the beginning. Instead of viewing the peasants and artisans who came under the protection of his walls as valuable contributors to the city's development—as they indeed were—a strict divide was drawn between the "families" of established citizens and the newcomers. For the former, all benefits from community trade and shared lands were reserved, leaving the latter with nothing but the right to use their own skills. As a result, the city became split into "the burghers" or "the commonalty," and "the inhabitants." The trade that used to be communal turned into the privilege of merchant and artisan "families," and the next step—becoming individual, or a privilege of oppressive monopolies—was inevitable.

The same division took place between the city proper and the surrounding villages. The commune had well tried to free the peasants, but her wars against the lords became, as already mentioned, wars for freeing the city itself from the lords, rather than for freeing the peasants. She left to the lord his rights over the villeins, on condition that he would molest the city no more and would become co-burgher. But the nobles "adopted" by the city, and now residing within its walls, simply carried on the old war within the very precincts of the city. They disliked to submit to a tribunal of simple artisans and merchants, and fought their old feuds in the streets. Each city had now its Colonnas and Orsinis, its Overstolzes and Wises. Drawing large incomes from the estates they had still retained, they surrounded themselves with numerous clients and feudalized the customs and habits of the city itself. And when discontent began to be felt in the artisan classes of the town, they offered their sword and their followers to settle the differences by a free fight, instead of letting the discontent find out the channels which it did not fail to secure itself in olden times.

The same split happened between the city itself and the nearby villages. The commune tried hard to free the peasants, but as mentioned earlier, its wars against the lords turned into wars to liberate the city from the lords instead of focusing on the peasants. The lord kept his rights over the villeins, as long as he no longer troubled the city and agreed to become a fellow citizen. However, the nobles who had been "adopted" by the city and now lived within its walls just continued the old battles right within the city limits. They didn’t want to answer to a court made up of ordinary artisans and merchants, and continued their old conflicts in the streets. Every city now had its Colonnas and Orsinis, its Overstolzes and Wises. Drawing significant incomes from the estates they still owned, they built a network of followers and feudalized the city’s customs and ways of life. And when dissatisfaction started brewing among the artisans in town, they offered their swords and followers to resolve the conflicts through direct combat, rather than allowing that dissatisfaction to find the resolutions that it had historically managed to secure.

The greatest and the most fatal error of most cities was to base their wealth upon commerce and industry, to the neglect of agriculture. They thus repeated the error which had once been committed by the cities of antique Greece, and they fell through it into the same crimes.(39) The estrangement of so many cities from the land necessarily drew them into a policy hostile to the land, which became more and more evident in the times of Edward the Third,(40) the French Jacqueries, the Hussite wars, and the Peasant War in Germany. On the other hand, a commercial policy involved them in distant enterprises. Colonies were founded by the Italians in the south-east, by German cities in the east, by Slavonian cities in the far northeast. Mercenary armies began to be kept for colonial wars, and soon for local defence as well. Loans were contacted to such an extent as to totally demoralize the citizens; and internal contests grew worse and worse at each election, during which the colonial politics in the interest of a few families was at stake. The division into rich and poor grew deeper, and in the sixteenth century, in each city, the royal authority found ready allies and support among the poor.

The biggest and most dangerous mistake of many cities was relying on commerce and industry while neglecting agriculture. This echoed the mistake made by the cities of ancient Greece, leading them into the same issues. The separation of so many cities from the land naturally pushed them into a policy that opposed agriculture, which became increasingly clear during the times of Edward the Third, the French Jacqueries, the Hussite wars, and the Peasant War in Germany. Meanwhile, a focus on trade led them into far-reaching endeavors. Colonies were established by Italians in the southeast, by German cities in the east, and by Slavic cities in the far northeast. Mercenary armies began to be maintained for colonial wars, and soon for local defense as well. Loans were taken out to such an extent that it completely undermined the citizens; internal conflicts worsened with each election, where colonial politics benefiting a few families were at stake. The divide between the rich and poor grew wider, and in the sixteenth century, in every city, the royal authority found allies and support among the poor.

And there is yet another cause of the decay of communal institutions, which stands higher and lies deeper than all the above. The history of the medieval cities offers one of the most striking illustrations of the power of ideas and principles upon the destinies of mankind, and of the quite opposed results which are obtained when a deep modification of leading ideas has taken place. Self-reliance and federalism, the sovereignty of each group, and the construction of the political body from the simple to the composite, were the leading ideas in the eleventh century. But since that time the conceptions had entirely changed. The students of Roman law and the prelates of the Church, closely bound together since the time of Innocent the Third, had succeeded in paralyzing the idea—the antique Greek idea—which presided at the foundation of the cities. For two or three hundred years they taught from the pulpit, the University chair, and the judges' bench, that salvation must be sought for in a strongly-centralized State, placed under a semi-divine authority;(41) that one man can and must be the saviour of society, and that in the name of public salvation he can commit any violence: burn men and women at the stake, make them perish under indescribable tortures, plunge whole provinces into the most abject misery. Nor did they fail to give object lessons to this effect on a grand scale, and with an unheard-of cruelty, wherever the king's sword and the Church's fire, or both at once, could reach. By these teachings and examples, continually repeated and enforced upon public attention, the very minds of the citizens had been shaped into a new mould. They began to find no authority too extensive, no killing by degrees too cruel, once it was "for public safety." And, with this new direction of mind and this new belief in one man's power, the old federalist principle faded away, and the very creative genius of the masses died out. The Roman idea was victorious, and in such circumstances the centralized State had in the cities a ready prey.

And there’s another reason for the decline of community institutions that goes beyond everything mentioned before. The history of medieval cities provides a striking example of how ideas and principles can influence the fate of humanity, and how drastically different outcomes arise when fundamental ideas shift. In the eleventh century, self-reliance and federalism, the sovereignty of each group, and the creation of the political body from simple structures to more complex ones were the guiding principles. However, since then, these ideas completely changed. The students of Roman law and the church leaders, closely allied since the time of Innocent the Third, managed to undermine the ancient Greek idea that originally formed the foundation of the cities. For two or three hundred years, they preached from the pulpit, lectured at universities, and ruled from the bench that salvation should be found in a highly centralized state ruled by semi-divine authority; that one person can and must be the savior of society, and that in the name of public salvation, he can commit any atrocities: burn men and women at the stake, subject them to unimaginable torture, and plunge entire regions into extreme misery. They didn’t hesitate to present large-scale demonstrations of this doctrine with unprecedented cruelty wherever the king's sword and the church's fire, or both, could reach. Through these teachings and examples, which were constantly repeated and forced upon public awareness, citizens' minds were reshaped. They started to believe that no authority was too vast, no gradual killing too cruel, as long as it was "for public safety." With this new mindset and faith in one man's power, the old federalist principle disappeared, and the creative spirit of the masses extinguished. The Roman idea triumphed, and in that context, the centralized state easily preyed upon the cities.

Florence in the fifteenth century is typical of this change. Formerly a popular revolution was the signal of a new departure. Now, when the people, brought to despair, insurged, it had constructive ideas no more; no fresh idea came out of the movement. A thousand representatives were put into the Communal Council instead of 400; 100 men entered the signoria instead of 80. But a revolution of figures could be of no avail. The people's discontent was growing up, and new revolts followed. A saviour—the "tyran"—was appealed to; he massacred the rebels, but the disintegration of the communal body continued worse than ever. And when, after a new revolt, the people of Florence appealed to their most popular man, Gieronimo Savonarola, for advice, the monk's answer was:—"Oh, people mine, thou knowest that I cannot go into State affairs … purify thy soul, and if in such a disposition of mind thou reformest thy city, then, people of Florence, thou shalt have inaugurated the reform in all Italy!" Carnival masks and vicious books were burned, a law of charity and another against usurers were passed—and the democracy of Florence remained where it was. The old spirit had gone. By too much trusting to government, they had ceased to trust to themselves; they were unable to open new issues. The State had only to step in and to crush down their last liberties.

Florence in the fifteenth century exemplifies this shift. In the past, a popular uprising marked the beginning of something new. Now, when the people, driven to despair, rose up, they had no constructive ideas; no fresh concepts emerged from the movement. A thousand representatives were added to the Communal Council instead of 400; 100 men filled the signoria instead of 80. But a mere change in numbers didn’t help. The people's dissatisfaction grew, leading to new revolts. They turned to a savior—the "tyran"—who massacred the rebels, but the breakdown of the communal structure continued worse than ever. And when, after another uprising, the people of Florence sought guidance from their most popular figure, Gieronimo Savonarola, the monk replied:—"Oh, my people, you know I cannot get involved in State affairs… purify your souls, and if you reform your city with that mindset, then, people of Florence, you will have set off a reform throughout all Italy!" Carnival masks and immoral books were burned, laws promoting charity and banning usury were enacted—and the democracy of Florence remained stagnant. The old spirit was lost. By relying too much on the government, they stopped trusting themselves; they were unable to create new solutions. The State simply stepped in and crushed their last liberties.

And yet, the current of mutual aid and support did not die out in the masses, it continued to flow even after that defeat. It rose up again with a formidable force, in answer to the communist appeals of the first propagandists of the reform, and it continued to exist even after the masses, having failed to realize the life which they hoped to inaugurate under the inspiration of a reformed religion, fell under the dominions of an autocratic power. It flows still even now, and it seeks its way to find out a new expression which would not be the State, nor the medieval city, nor the village community of the barbarians, nor the savage clan, but would proceed from all of them, and yet be superior to them in its wider and more deeply humane conceptions.

And still, the spirit of mutual aid and support didn’t fade away in the people; it kept going even after that defeat. It emerged with great strength in response to the communist calls from the early reform propagandists, and it continued to exist even after the people, having not achieved the life they wanted under the influence of a reformed religion, fell under the rule of an authoritarian regime. It still flows now, seeking a new form that is not the State, nor the medieval city, nor the village community of the barbarians, nor the primitive clan, but something that draws from all of them and is superior to them through broader and more deeply humane ideas.

NOTES:

1. The literature of the subject is immense; but there is no work yet which treats of the medieval city as of a whole. For the French Communes, Augustin Thierry's Lettres and Considerations sur l'histoire de France still remain classical, and Luchaire's Communes francaises is an excellent addition on the same lines. For the cities of Italy, the great work of Sismondi (Histoire des republiques italiennes du moyen age, Paris, 1826, 16 vols.), Leo and Botta's History of Italy, Ferrari's Revolutions d'Italie, and Hegel's Geschichte der Stadteverfassung in Italien, are the chief sources of general information. For Germany we have Maurer's Stadteverfassung, Barthold's Geschichte der deutschen Stadte, and, of recent works, Hegel's Stadte und Gilden der germanischen Volker (2 vols. Leipzig, 1891), and Dr. Otto Kallsen's Die deutschen Stadte im Mittelalter (2 vols. Halle, 1891), as also Janssen's Geschichte des deutschen Volkes (5 vols. 1886), which, let us hope, will soon be translated into English (French translation in 1892). For Belgium, A. Wauters, Les Libertes communales (Bruxelles, 1869-78, 3 vols.). For Russia, Byelaeff's, Kostomaroff's and Sergievich's works. And finally, for England, we posses one of the best works on cities of a wider region in Mrs. J.R. Green's Town Life in the Fifteenth Century (2 vols. London, 1894). We have, moreover, a wealth of well-known local histories, and several excellent works of general or economical history which I have so often mentioned in this and the preceding chapter. The richness of literature consists, however, chiefly in separate, sometimes admirable, researches into the history of separate cities, especially Italian and German; the guilds; the land question; the economical principles of the time; the economical importance of guilds and crafts; the leagues between, cities (the Hansa); and communal art. An incredible wealth of information is contained in works of this second category, of which only some of the more important are named in these pages.

1. The literature on this topic is vast, but there isn't a single work that covers the medieval city as a whole. For the French communes, Augustin Thierry's *Lettres* and *Considerations sur l'histoire de France* remain classics, and Luchaire's *Communes françaises* is a great addition along the same lines. Regarding the cities of Italy, the significant work by Sismondi (*Histoire des républiques italiennes du moyen âge*, Paris, 1826, 16 vols.), along with Leo and Botta's *History of Italy*, Ferrari's *Revolutions d'Italie*, and Hegel's *Geschichte der Städteverfassung in Italien*, are key sources of general information. For Germany, we have Maurer's *Städteverfassung*, Barthold's *Geschichte der deutschen Städte*, and more recent works like Hegel's *Städte und Gilden der germanischen Völker* (2 vols. Leipzig, 1891), as well as Dr. Otto Kallsen's *Die deutschen Städte im Mittelalter* (2 vols. Halle, 1891), along with Janssen's *Geschichte des deutschen Volkes* (5 vols. 1886), which we hope will soon be translated into English (French translation in 1892). For Belgium, A. Wauters' *Les Libertés communales* (Bruxelles, 1869-78, 3 vols.). For Russia, works by Byelaeff, Kostomaroff, and Sergievich. Lastly, for England, we have one of the best works on cities from a broader region in Mrs. J.R. Green's *Town Life in the Fifteenth Century* (2 vols. London, 1894). Additionally, there's a wealth of well-known local histories and several excellent general or economic history works that I've frequently mentioned in this and the previous chapter. However, the richness of the literature mainly lies in individual, sometimes remarkable, studies into the history of specific cities, especially in Italy and Germany; the guilds; land issues; the economic principles of the time; the economic significance of guilds and crafts; the alliances among cities (the Hansa); and communal art. An incredible amount of information is contained in works from this second category, of which only a few of the more important are mentioned in these pages.

2. Kulischer, in an excellent essay on primitive trade (Zeitschrift für Volkerpsychologie, Bd. x. 380), also points out that, according to Herodotus, the Argippaeans were considered inviolable, because the trade between the Scythians and the northern tribes took place on their territory. A fugitive was sacred on their territory, and they were often asked to act as arbiters for their neighbours. See Appendix XI.

2. Kulischer, in a great essay on primitive trade (Journal of Ethnopsychology, Vol. x. 380), also notes that, according to Herodotus, the Argippaeans were seen as untouchable because the trade between the Scythians and the northern tribes happened on their land. A runaway was considered sacred in their territory, and they were frequently asked to mediate for their neighbors. See Appendix XI.

3. Some discussion has lately taken place upon the Weichbild and the Weichbild-law, which still remain obscure (see Zopfl, Alterthumer des deutschen Reichs und Rechts, iii. 29; Kallsen, i. 316). The above explanation seems to be the more probable, but, of course, it must be tested by further research. It is also evident that, to use a Scotch expression, the "mercet cross" could be considered as an emblem of Church jurisdiction, but we find it both in bishop cities and in those in which the folkmote was sovereign.

3. Recently, there has been some discussion about the Weichbild and the Weichbild law, which still remain unclear (see Zopfl, Alterthumer des deutschen Reichs und Rechts, iii. 29; Kallsen, i. 316). The explanation provided above seems to be the most likely, but, of course, it needs to be validated through further research. It is also clear that, to use a Scottish term, the "mercet cross" could be seen as a symbol of Church authority, but we find it both in bishop cities and in those where the folkmote held power.

4. For all concerning the merchant guild see Mr. Gross's exhaustive work, The Guild Merchant (Oxford, 1890, 2 vols.); also Mrs. Green's remarks in Town Life in the Fifteenth Century, vol. ii. chaps. v. viii. x; and A. Doren's review of the subject in Schmoller's Forschungen, vol. xii. If the considerations indicated in the previous chapter (according to which trade was communal at its beginnings) prove to be correct, it will be permissible to suggest as a probable hypothesis that the guild merchant was a body entrusted with commerce in the interest of the whole city, and only gradually became a guild of merchants trading for themselves; while the merchant adventurers of this country, the Novgorod povolniki (free colonizers and merchants) and the mercati personati, would be those to whom it was left to open new markets and new branches of commerce for themselves. Altogether, it must be remarked that the origin of the mediaeval city can be ascribed to no separate agency. It was a result of many agencies in different degrees.

4. For everything related to the merchant guild, see Mr. Gross's detailed work, The Guild Merchant (Oxford, 1890, 2 vols.); also check out Mrs. Green's insights in Town Life in the Fifteenth Century, vol. ii. chaps. v. viii. x; and A. Doren's review of the topic in Schmoller's Forschungen, vol. xii. If the ideas mentioned in the previous chapter (suggesting that trade was communal at its start) are correct, it’s reasonable to propose that the guild merchant was initially set up to handle commerce for the entire city and only gradually became a guild of merchants trading for their own gain; while the merchant adventurers from this country, the Novgorod povolniki (independent settlers and traders), and the mercati personati, were tasked with exploring new markets and business opportunities for themselves. Overall, it should be noted that the origins of the medieval city cannot be attributed to a single entity. It was the result of many factors working together in various ways.

5. Janssen's Geschichte des deutschen Volkes, i. 315; Gramich's Wurzburg; and, in fact, any collection of ordinances.

5. Janssen's History of the German People, i. 315; Gramich's Würzburg; and, in fact, any collection of regulations.

6. Falke, Geschichtliche Statistik, i. 373-393, and ii. 66; quoted in Janssen's Geschichte, i. 339; J.D. Blavignac, in Comptes et depenses de la construction du clocher de Saint-Nicolas a Fribourg en Suisse, comes to a similar conclusion. For Amiens, De Calonne's Vie Municipale, p. 99 and Appendix. For a thorough appreciation and graphical representation of the medieval wages in England and their value in bread and meat, see G. Steffen's excellent article and curves in The Nineteenth Century for 1891, and Studier ofver lonsystemets historia i England, Stockholm, 1895.

6. Falke, Historical Statistics, i. 373-393, and ii. 66; quoted in Janssen's History, i. 339; J.D. Blavignac, in Accounts and Expenses of the Construction of the Bell Tower of Saint-Nicolas in Fribourg, Switzerland, reaches a similar conclusion. For Amiens, De Calonne's Municipal Life, p. 99 and Appendix. For a detailed understanding and graphical representation of medieval wages in England and their equivalent in bread and meat, see G. Steffen's excellent article and graphs in The Nineteenth Century from 1891, and Studies on the History of the Wage System in England, Stockholm, 1895.

7. To quote but one example out of many which may be found in Schonberg's and Falke's works, the sixteen shoemaker workers (Schusterknechte) of the town Xanten, on the Rhine, gave, for erecting a screen and an altar in the church, 75 guldens of subscriptions, and 12 guldens out of their box, which money was worth, according to the best valuations, ten times its present value.

7. To give just one example among many found in Schonberg's and Falke's works, the sixteen shoemaker workers from the town of Xanten on the Rhine contributed 75 guilders in subscriptions and 12 guilders from their savings to build a screen and an altar in the church, which was valued at around ten times its worth today according to the best estimates.

8. Quoted by Janssen, l.c. i. 343.

8. Quoted by Janssen, l.c. i. 343.

9. The Economical Interpretation of History, London, 1891, p. 303.

9. The Economic Interpretation of History, London, 1891, p. 303.

10. Janssen, l.c. See also Dr. Alwin Schultz, Deutsches Leben im XIV und XV Jahrhundert, grosse Ausgabe, Wien, 1892, pp. 67 seq. At Paris, the day of labour varied from seven to eight hours in the winter to fourteen hours in summer in certain trades, while in others it was from eight to nine hours in winter, to from ten to twelve in Summer. All work was stopped on Saturdays and on about twenty-five other days (jours de commun de vile foire) at four o'clock, while on Sundays and thirty other holidays there was no work at all. The general conclusion is, that the medieval worker worked less hours, all taken, than the present-day worker (Dr. E. Martin Saint-Leon, Histoire des corporations, p. 121).

10. Janssen, l.c. See also Dr. Alwin Schultz, Deutsches Leben im XIV und XV Jahrhundert, große Ausgabe, Wien, 1892, pp. 67 seq. In Paris, the workday ranged from seven to eight hours in winter to fourteen hours in summer for some trades, while for others it was from eight to nine hours in winter, and from ten to twelve in summer. All work stopped at four o'clock on Saturdays and on about twenty-five other days (jours de commun de vile foire), while there was no work at all on Sundays and thirty other holidays. The general conclusion is that the medieval worker worked fewer hours overall than the modern worker (Dr. E. Martin Saint-Leon, Histoire des corporations, p. 121).

11. W. Stieda, "Hansische Vereinbarungen uber stadtisches Gewerbe im XIV und XV Jahrhundert," in Hansische Geschichtsblatter, Jahrgang 1886, p. 121. Schonberg's Wirthschaftliche Bedeutung der Zunfte; also, partly, Roscher.

11. W. Stieda, "Hansea Agreements on Urban Trade in the 14th and 15th Century," in Hanseatic Historical Papers, Volume 1886, p. 121. Schonberg's Economic Significance of the Guilds; also, in part, Roscher.

12. See Toulmin Smith's deeply-felt remarks about the royal spoliation of the guilds, in Miss Smith's Introduction to English Guilds. In France the same royal spoliation and abolition of the guilds' jurisdiction was begun from 1306, and the final blow was struck in 1382 (Fagniez, l.c. pp. 52-54).

12. Check out Toulmin Smith's heartfelt comments on the royal plundering of the guilds in Miss Smith's Introduction to English Guilds. In France, the same royal plundering and dismantling of the guilds' authority started in 1306, and the final blow was delivered in 1382 (Fagniez, l.c. pp. 52-54).

13. Adam Smith and his contemporaries knew well what they were condemning when they wrote against the State interference in trade and the trade monopolies of State creation. Unhappily, their followers, with their hopeless superficiality, flung medieval guilds and State interference into the same sack, making no distinction between a Versailles edict and a guild ordinance. It hardly need be said that the economists who have seriously studied the subject, like Schonberg (the editor of the well-known course of Political Economy), never fell into such an error. But, till lately, diffuse discussions of the above type went on for economical "science."

13. Adam Smith and his contemporaries clearly understood what they were criticizing when they wrote against government interference in trade and state-created trade monopolies. Unfortunately, their followers, with their lack of depth, lumped medieval guilds and government intervention together, failing to distinguish between a Versailles edict and a guild ordinance. It's worth noting that economists who have thoroughly studied the topic, like Schonberg (the editor of the well-known Political Economy course), never made such a mistake. However, until recently, vague discussions like this were considered part of economic "science."

14. In Florence the seven minor arts made their revolution in 1270-82, and its results are fully described by Perrens (Histoire de Florence, Paris, 1877, 3 vols.), and especially by Gino Capponi (Storia della repubblica di Firenze, 2da edizione, 1876, i. 58-80; translated into German). In Lyons, on the contrary, where the movement of the minor crafts took place in 1402, the latter were defeated and lost the right of themselves nominating their own judges. The two parties came apparently to a compromise. In Rostock the same movement took place in 1313; in Zurich in 1336; in Bern in 1363; in Braunschweig in 1374, and next year in Hamburg; in Lubeck in 1376-84; and so on. See Schmoller's Strassburg zur Zeit der Zunftkampfe and Strassburg's Bluthe; Brentano's Arbeitergilden der Gegenwart, 2 vols., Leipzig, 1871-72; Eb. Bain's Merchant and Craft Guilds, Aberdeen, 1887, pp. 26-47, 75, etc. As to Mr. Gross's opinion relative to the same struggles in England, see Mrs. Green's remarks in her Town Life in the Fifteenth Century, ii. 190-217; also the chapter on the Labour Question, and, in fact, the whole of this extremely interesting volume. Brentano's views on the crafts' struggles, expressed especially in iii. and iv. of his essay "On the History and Development of Guilds," in Toulmin Smith's English Guilds remain classical for the subject, and may be said to have been again and again confirmed by subsequent research.

14. In Florence, the seven minor arts went through their revolution from 1270 to 1282, and the results are thoroughly detailed by Perrens (Histoire de Florence, Paris, 1877, 3 vols.), especially by Gino Capponi (Storia della repubblica di Firenze, 2nd edition, 1876, i. 58-80; translated into German). In Lyons, on the other hand, the movement of the minor crafts occurred in 1402, but they were defeated and lost the right to nominate their own judges. Both sides seemed to reach a compromise. The same movement happened in Rostock in 1313; in Zurich in 1336; in Bern in 1363; in Braunschweig in 1374, and the following year in Hamburg; in Lubeck from 1376 to 1384; and so on. See Schmoller's Strassburg zur Zeit der Zunftkämpfe and Strassburg's Bluthe; Brentano's Arbeitergilden der Gegenwart, 2 vols., Leipzig, 1871-72; Eb. Bain's Merchant and Craft Guilds, Aberdeen, 1887, pp. 26-47, 75, etc. As for Mr. Gross's views on the same struggles in England, refer to Mrs. Green's comments in her Town Life in the Fifteenth Century, ii. 190-217; also the chapter on the Labour Question, and indeed, the entire volume, which is extremely interesting. Brentano's insights on the struggles of crafts, particularly in iii. and iv. of his essay "On the History and Development of Guilds," in Toulmin Smith's English Guilds remain foundational for the topic and have been consistently validated by further research.

15. To give but one example—Cambrai made its first revolution in 907, and, after three or four more revolts, it obtained its charter in 1076. This charter was repealed twice (1107 and 1138), and twice obtained again (in 1127 and 1180). Total, 223 years of struggles before conquering the right to independence. Lyons—from 1195 to 1320.

15. To give just one example—Cambrai had its first revolution in 907, and after three or four more uprisings, it got its charter in 1076. This charter was canceled twice (in 1107 and 1138) and was restored twice (in 1127 and 1180). In total, it took 223 years of struggles to win the right to independence. Lyons—from 1195 to 1320.

16. See Tuetey, "Etude sur Le droit municipal … en Franche-Comte," in Memoires de la Societe d'emulation de Montbeliard, 2e serie, ii. 129 seq.

16. See Tuetey, "Study on Municipal Law … in Franche-Comté," in Memoirs of the Society of Emulation of Montbéliard, 2nd series, ii. 129 seq.

17. This seems to have been often the case in Italy. In Switzerland, Bern bought even the towns of Thun and Burgdorf.

17. This seems to have often been the case in Italy. In Switzerland, Bern even acquired the towns of Thun and Burgdorf.

18. Such was, at least, the case in the cities of Tuscany (Florence, Lucca, Sienna, Bologna, etc.), for which the relations between city and peasants are best known. (Luchitzkiy, "Slavery and Russian Slaves in Florence," in Kieff University Izvestia for 1885, who has perused Rumohr's Ursprung der Besitzlosigkeit der Colonien in Toscana, 1830.) The whole matter concerning the relations between the cities and the peasants requires much more study than has hitherto been done.

18. This was especially true in the cities of Tuscany (Florence, Lucca, Sienna, Bologna, etc.), where the relationships between the city and the peasants are the most documented. (Luchitzkiy, "Slavery and Russian Slaves in Florence," in Kieff University Izvestia for 1885, who has reviewed Rumohr's Ursprung der Besitzlosigkeit der Colonien in Toscana, 1830.) The entire topic regarding the relationships between the cities and the peasants needs a lot more research than what has been done so far.

19. Ferrari's generalizations are often too theoretical to be always correct; but his views upon the part played by the nobles in the city wars are based upon a wide range of authenticated facts.

19. Ferrari's generalizations are often too theoretical to be consistently accurate; however, his insights on the role of the nobles in the city wars are grounded in a broad array of verified facts.

20. Only such cities as stubbornly kept to the cause of the barons, like Pisa or Verona, lost through the wars. For many towns which fought on the barons' side, the defeat was also the beginning of liberation and progress.

20. Only cities that stubbornly supported the barons, like Pisa or Verona, suffered losses in the wars. For many towns that fought alongside the barons, their defeat was actually the start of their liberation and progress.

21. Ferrari, ii. 18, 104 seq.; Leo and Botta, i. 432.

21. Ferrari, ii. 18, 104 seq.; Leo and Botta, i. 432.

22. Joh. Falke, Die Hansa Als Deutsche See-und Handelsmacht, Berlin, 1863, pp. 31, 55.

22. Joh. Falke, The Hanseatic League as a German Maritime and Trading Power, Berlin, 1863, pp. 31, 55.

23. For Aachen and Cologne we have direct testimony that the bishops of these two cities—one of them bought by the enemy opened to him the gates.

23. For Aachen and Cologne, we have direct evidence that the bishops of these two cities—one of whom was bought off by the enemy—opened the gates for him.

24. See the facts, though not always the conclusions, of Nitzsch, iii. 133 seq.; also Kallsen, i. 458, etc.

24. Check the facts, though not always the conclusions, of Nitzsch, iii. 133 seq.; also Kallsen, i. 458, etc.

25. On the Commune of the Laonnais, which, until Melleville's researches (Histoire de la Commune du Laonnais, Paris, 1853), was confounded with the Commune of Laon, see Luchaire, pp. 75 seq. For the early peasants' guilds and subsequent unions see R. Wilman's "Die landlichen Schutzgilden Westphaliens," in Zeitschrift für Kulturgeschichte, neue Folge, Bd. iii., quoted in Henne-am-Rhyn's Kulturgeschichte, iii. 249.

25. For the Commune of the Laonnais, which was previously mistaken for the Commune of Laon until Melleville's research (Histoire de la Commune du Laonnais, Paris, 1853), see Luchaire, pp. 75 seq. For information on the early peasants' guilds and later unions, refer to R. Wilman's "Die landlichen Schutzgilden Westphaliens," in Zeitschrift für Kulturgeschichte, neue Folge, Bd. iii., as cited in Henne-am-Rhyn's Kulturgeschichte, iii. 249.

26. Luchaire, p. 149.

Luchaire, p. 149.

27. Two important cities, like Mainz and Worms, would settle a political contest by means of arbitration. After a civil war broken out in Abbeville, Amiens would act, in 1231, as arbiter (Luchaire, 149); and so on.

27. Two significant cities, like Mainz and Worms, would resolve a political dispute through arbitration. After a civil war broke out in Abbeville, Amiens would serve as the arbitrator in 1231 (Luchaire, 149); and so on.

28. See, for instance, W. Stieda, Hansische Vereinbarungen, l.c., p. 114.

28. Check out W. Stieda, Hansische Vereinbarungen, l.c., p. 114.

29. Cosmo Innes's Early Scottish History and Scotland in Middle Ages, quoted by Rev. Denton, l.c., pp. 68, 69; Lamprecht's Deutsches wirthschaftliche Leben im Mittelalter, review by Schmoller in his Jahrbuch, Bd. xii.; Sismondi's Tableau de l'agriculture toscane, pp. 226 seq. The dominions of Florence could be recognized at a glance through their prosperity.

29. Cosmo Innes's Early Scottish History and Scotland in the Middle Ages, quoted by Rev. Denton, l.c., pp. 68, 69; Lamprecht's Deutsches wirtschaftliche Leben im Mittelalter, review by Schmoller in his Jahrbuch, Bd. xii.; Sismondi's Tableau de l'agriculture toscane, pp. 226 seq. The regions of Florence were easily recognizable because of their prosperity.

30. Mr. John J. Ennett (Six Essays, London, 1891) has excellent pages on this aspect of medieval architecture. Mr. Willis, in his appendix to Whewell's History of Inductive Sciences (i. 261-262), has pointed out the beauty of the mechanical relations in medieval buildings. "A new decorative construction was matured," he writes, "not thwarting and controlling, but assisting and harmonizing with the mechanical construction. Every member, every moulding, becomes a sustainer of weight; and by the multiplicity of props assisting each other, and the consequent subdivision of weight, the eye was satisfied of the stability of the structure, notwithstanding curiously slender aspects of the separate parts." An art which sprang out of the social life of the city could not be better characterized.

30. Mr. John J. Ennett (Six Essays, London, 1891) has great insights on this part of medieval architecture. Mr. Willis, in his appendix to Whewell's History of Inductive Sciences (i. 261-262), highlights the beauty of the mechanical relationships in medieval buildings. "A new decorative construction was developed," he writes, "that didn't obstruct or control, but rather supported and harmonized with the mechanical construction. Every element, every molding, became a weight bearer; and through the multiple supports working together, along with the resulting division of weight, the eye was assured of the stability of the structure, even with the intriguingly slender appearance of the individual parts." An art that emerged from the city's social life could not be described better.

31. Dr. L. Ennen, Der Dom zu Koln, seine Construction und Anstaltung, Koln, 1871.

31. Dr. L. Ennen, The Cologne Cathedral, Its Construction and Design, Cologne, 1871.

32. The three statues are among the outer decorations of Notre Dame de Paris.

32. The three statues are part of the exterior decorations of Notre Dame de Paris.

33. Mediaeval art, like Greek art, did not know those curiosity shops which we call a National Gallery or a Museum. A picture was painted, a statue was carved, a bronze decoration was cast to stand in its proper place in a monument of communal art. It lived there, it was part of a whole, and it contributed to give unity to the impression produced by the whole.

33. Medieval art, similar to Greek art, didn't have those curiosity shops we refer to as a National Gallery or a Museum. A painting was created, a statue was carved, and a bronze decoration was cast to fit into its rightful place in a community artwork. It existed there, it was part of a whole, and it played a role in creating unity in the impression made by that whole.

34. Cf. J. T. Ennett's "Second Essay," p. 36.

34. Cf. J. T. Ennett's "Second Essay," p. 36.

35. Sismondi, iv. 172; xvi. 356. The great canal, Naviglio Grande, which brings the water from the Tessino, was begun in 1179, i.e. after the conquest of independence, and it was ended in the thirteenth century. On the subsequent decay, see xvi. 355.

35. Sismondi, iv. 172; xvi. 356. The large canal, Naviglio Grande, which brings the water from the Tessino, was started in 1179, after the conquest of independence, and it was completed in the thirteenth century. For information on the later decline, see xvi. 355.

36. In 1336 it had 8,000 to 10,000 boys and girls in its primary schools, 1,000 to 1,200 boys in its seven middle schools, and from 550 to 600 students in its four universities. The thirty communal hospitals contained over 1,000 beds for a population of 90,000 inhabitants (Capponi, ii. 249 seq.). It has more than once been suggested by authoritative writers that education stood, as a rule, at a much higher level than is generally supposed. Certainly so in democratic Nuremberg.

36. In 1336, there were 8,000 to 10,000 boys and girls in its primary schools, 1,000 to 1,200 boys in its seven middle schools, and about 550 to 600 students in its four universities. The thirty community hospitals had more than 1,000 beds for a population of 90,000 residents (Capponi, ii. 249 seq.). It has been suggested by credible authors that education was generally at a much higher standard than people usually think. This was definitely the case in democratic Nuremberg.

37. Cf. L. Ranke's excellent considerations upon the essence of Roman Law in his Weltgeschichte, Bd. iv. Abth. 2, pp. 20-31. Also Sismondi's remarks upon the part played by the legistes in the constitution of royal authority, Histoire des Francais, Paris, 1826, viii. 85-99. The popular hatred against these "weise Doktoren und Beutelschneider des Volks" broke out with full force in the first years of the sixteenth century in the sermons of the early Reform movement.

37. See L. Ranke's excellent thoughts on the essence of Roman Law in his "World History," Vol. IV, Part 2, pp. 20-31. Also, Sismondi's comments on the role of the legal scholars in establishing royal authority, "History of the French," Paris, 1826, viii. 85-99. The public's anger towards these "wise doctors and common thieves of the people" emerged strongly in the early years of the sixteenth century in the sermons of the early Reformation movement.

38. Brentano fully understood the fatal effects of the struggle between the "old burghers" and the new-comers. Miaskowski, in his work on the village communities of Switzerland, has indicated the same for village communities.

38. Brentano completely understood the disastrous effects of the conflict between the "old residents" and the newcomers. Miaskowski, in his study of the village communities in Switzerland, has pointed out the same for these communities.

39. The trade in slaves kidnapped in the East was never discontinued in the Italian republics till the fifteenth century. Feeble traces of it are found also in Germany and elsewhere. See Cibrario. Della schiavitu e del servaggio, 2 vols. Milan, 1868; Professor Luchitzkiy, "Slavery and Russian Slaves in Florence in the Fourteenth and Fifteenth Centuries," in Izvestia of the Kieff University, 1885.

39. The trade in slaves taken from the East continued in the Italian republics until the fifteenth century. Weak signs of it are also found in Germany and other places. See Cibrario. Della schiavitu e del servaggio, 2 vols. Milan, 1868; Professor Luchitzkiy, "Slavery and Russian Slaves in Florence in the Fourteenth and Fifteenth Centuries," in Izvestia of the Kieff University, 1885.

40. J.R. Green's History of the English People, London, 1878, i. 455.

40. J.R. Green's History of the English People, London, 1878, i. 455.

41. See the theories expressed by the Bologna lawyers, already at the Congress of Roncaglia in 1158.

41. Check out the theories presented by the Bologna lawyers during the Congress of Roncaglia in 1158.

CHAPTER VII

MUTUAL AID AMONGST OURSELVES

Popular revolts at the beginning of the State-period. Mutual Aid institutions of the present time. The village community; its struggles for resisting its abolition by the State. Habits derived from the village-community life, retained in our modern villages. Switzerland, France, Germany, Russia.

Popular uprisings at the start of the State period. Mutual Aid organizations today. The village community; its efforts to fight against its elimination by the State. Traditions from village-community life, still present in our modern villages. Switzerland, France, Germany, Russia.

The mutual-aid tendency in man has so remote an origin, and is so deeply interwoven with all the past evolution of the human race, that it has been maintained by mankind up to the present time, notwithstanding all vicissitudes of history. It was chiefly evolved during periods of peace and prosperity; but when even the greatest calamities befell men—when whole countries were laid waste by wars, and whole populations were decimated by misery, or groaned under the yoke of tyranny—the same tendency continued to live in the villages and among the poorer classes in the towns; it still kept them together, and in the long run it reacted even upon those ruling, fighting, and devastating minorities which dismissed it as sentimental nonsense. And whenever mankind had to work out a new social organization, adapted to a new phasis of development, its constructive genius always drew the elements and the inspiration for the new departure from that same ever-living tendency. New economical and social institutions, in so far as they were a creation of the masses, new ethical systems, and new religions, all have originated from the same source, and the ethical progress of our race, viewed in its broad lines, appears as a gradual extension of the mutual-aid principles from the tribe to always larger and larger agglomerations, so as to finally embrace one day the whole of mankind, without respect to its divers creeds, languages, and races.

The instinct for mutual aid in humans has such ancient roots and is so deeply connected to the entire evolution of the human race that it has persisted through history's ups and downs. It primarily developed during times of peace and prosperity; yet even when the biggest disasters struck—when entire nations were ravaged by wars, and populations were devastated by suffering or oppressed by tyranny—this tendency continued to thrive in villages and among the poorer communities in cities. It kept people united, and over time, it impacted even those in power who dismissed it as mere sentimental nonsense. Whenever humanity needed to create a new social structure suited to a new stage of development, its creative energy always drew from this enduring instinct. New economic and social institutions, as far as they were created by the masses, new ethical systems, and new religions all came from the same source. The ethical progress of our species, when viewed broadly, appears as a gradual expansion of mutual aid principles from small tribes to increasingly larger groups, ultimately aiming to encompass all of humanity, regardless of its various beliefs, languages, and races.

After having passed through the savage tribe, and next through the village community, the Europeans came to work out in medieval times a new form of organization, which had the advantage of allowing great latitude for individual initiative, while it largely responded at the same time to man's need of mutual support. A federation of village communities, covered by a network of guilds and fraternities, was called into existence in the medieval cities. The immense results achieved under this new form of union—in well-being for all, in industries, art, science, and commerce—were discussed at some length in two preceding chapters, and an attempt was also made to show why, towards the end of the fifteenth century, the medieval republics—surrounded by domains of hostile feudal lords, unable to free the peasants from servitude, and gradually corrupted by ideas of Roman Caesarism—were doomed to become a prey to the growing military States.

After going through the savage tribe and then the village community, Europeans developed a new form of organization during medieval times. This structure allowed for significant individual initiative while still meeting people’s need for mutual support. A federation of village communities emerged, supported by a network of guilds and fraternities, in the medieval cities. The tremendous achievements of this new form of unity—in terms of well-being for everyone, as well as advancements in industry, art, science, and commerce—were discussed in detail in the two earlier chapters. An attempt was also made to explain why, by the end of the fifteenth century, the medieval republics—surrounded by hostile feudal lords, unable to free the peasants from servitude, and gradually corrupted by ideas of Roman Caesarism—were destined to fall prey to the rising military states.

However, before submitting for three centuries to come, to the all-absorbing authority of the State, the masses of the people made a formidable attempt at reconstructing society on the old basis of mutual aid and support. It is well known by this time that the great movement of the reform was not a mere revolt against the abuses of the Catholic Church. It had its constructive ideal as well, and that ideal was life in free, brotherly communities. Those of the early writings and sermons of the period which found most response with the masses were imbued with ideas of the economical and social brotherhood of mankind. The "Twelve Articles" and similar professions of faith, which were circulated among the German and Swiss peasants and artisans, maintained not only every one's right to interpret the Bible according to his own understanding, but also included the demand of communal lands being restored to the village communities and feudal servitudes being abolished, and they always alluded to the "true" faith—a faith of brotherhood. At the same time scores of thousands of men and women joined the communist fraternities of Moravia, giving them all their fortune and living in numerous and prosperous settlements constructed upon the principles of communism.(1) Only wholesale massacres by the thousand could put a stop to this widely-spread popular movement, and it was by the sword, the fire, and the rack that the young States secured their first and decisive victory over the masses of the people.(2)

However, before submitting to the all-consuming authority of the State for the next three centuries, the masses of people made a strong attempt to rebuild society based on mutual aid and support. It's now well known that the significant reform movement was not just a rebellion against the abuses of the Catholic Church. It had its own constructive vision, which was life in free, brotherly communities. The early writings and sermons from that time that resonated most with the masses were filled with ideas of economic and social brotherhood among humanity. The "Twelve Articles" and similar declarations, which were distributed among German and Swiss peasants and artisans, asserted everyone’s right to interpret the Bible in their own way and included demands for restoring communal lands to village communities and abolishing feudal obligations. They consistently referred to the "true" faith—a faith of brotherhood. At the same time, countless men and women joined the communist brotherhoods of Moravia, donating their entire fortunes and living in numerous thriving settlements built on communist principles. Only mass killings by the thousands could halt this widespread popular movement, and it was through violence, fire, and torture that the young States achieved their first major victory over the masses.

For the next three centuries the States, both on the Continent and in these islands, systematically weeded out all institutions in which the mutual-aid tendency had formerly found its expression. The village communities were bereft of their folkmotes, their courts and independent administration; their lands were confiscated. The guilds were spoliated of their possessions and liberties, and placed under the control, the fancy, and the bribery of the State's official. The cities were divested of their sovereignty, and the very springs of their inner life—the folkmote, the elected justices and administration, the sovereign parish and the sovereign guild—were annihilated; the State's functionary took possession of every link of what formerly was an organic whole. Under that fatal policy and the wars it engendered, whole regions, once populous and wealthy, were laid bare; rich cities became insignificant boroughs; the very roads which connected them with other cities became impracticable. Industry, art, and knowledge fell into decay. Political education, science, and law were rendered subservient to the idea of State centralization. It was taught in the Universities and from the pulpit that the institutions in which men formerly used to embody their needs of mutual support could not be tolerated in a properly organized State; that the State alone could represent the bonds of union between its subjects; that federalism and "particularism" were the enemies of progress, and the State was the only proper initiator of further development. By the end of the last century the kings on the Continent, the Parliament in these isles, and the revolutionary Convention in France, although they were at war with each other, agreed in asserting that no separate unions between citizens must exist within the State; that hard labour and death were the only suitable punishments to workers who dared to enter into "coalitions." "No state within the State!" The State alone, and the State's Church, must take care of matters of general interest, while the subjects must represent loose aggregations of individuals, connected by no particular bonds, bound to appeal to the Government each time that they feel a common need. Up to the middle of this century this was the theory and practice in Europe. Even commercial and industrial societies were looked at with suspicion. As to the workers, their unions were treated as unlawful almost within our own lifetime in this country and within the last twenty years on the Continent. The whole system of our State education was such that up to the present time, even in this country, a notable portion of society would treat as a revolutionary measure the concession of such rights as every one, freeman or serf, exercised five hundred years ago in the village folkmote, the guild, the parish, and the city.

For the next three centuries, the States, both on the Continent and in these islands, systematically eliminated all institutions where the mutual-aid spirit had previously expressed itself. The village communities lost their folk meetings, courts, and independent administrations; their lands were seized. The guilds were stripped of their assets and freedoms and placed under the control, whims, and corruption of State officials. The cities lost their sovereignty, and the very foundations of their internal life—the folk assemblies, the elected justices and administrators, the self-governing parishes, and the independent guilds—were destroyed; the State's functionary took over every part of what was once an organic whole. Under that destructive policy and the wars it caused, entire regions that were once populated and prosperous were decimated; wealthy cities became insignificant towns; the roads connecting them to other cities became impassable. Industry, art, and knowledge declined. Political education, science, and law became subordinate to the idea of State centralization. It was taught in universities and from the pulpit that the institutions where people once fulfilled their needs for mutual support could not be allowed in a properly organized State; that only the State could represent the bonds of unity among its citizens; that federalism and “particularism” were the enemies of progress, and the State was the only legitimate initiator of further development. By the end of the last century, the kings on the Continent, the Parliament in these islands, and the revolutionary Convention in France, even though they were at war with each other, agreed that no separate unions between citizens should exist within the State; that hard labor and death were the only appropriate punishments for workers who dared to form “coalitions.” “No state within the State!” The State alone, and the State’s Church, must handle matters of general interest, while citizens must exist as loose groups of individuals, connected by no particular ties, and must appeal to the Government whenever they feel a common need. Up to the middle of this century, this was the theory and practice in Europe. Even commercial and industrial societies were viewed with suspicion. As for the workers, their unions were nearly treated as illegal during our own lifetime in this country and in the last twenty years on the Continent. The entire framework of our State education was such that to this day, even in this country, a significant portion of society would see as revolutionary any concession of rights that everyone, free or serf, enjoyed five hundred years ago in the village folk meeting, the guild, the parish, and the city.

The absorption of all social functions by the State necessarily favoured the development of an unbridled, narrow-minded individualism. In proportion as the obligations towards the State grew in numbers the citizens were evidently relieved from their obligations towards each other. In the guild—and in medieval times every man belonged to some guild or fraternity two "brothers" were bound to watch in turns a brother who had fallen ill; it would be sufficient now to give one's neighbour the address of the next paupers' hospital. In barbarian society, to assist at a fight between two men, arisen from a quarrel, and not to prevent it from taking a fatal issue, meant to be oneself treated as a murderer; but under the theory of the all-protecting State the bystander need not intrude: it is the policeman's business to interfere, or not. And while in a savage land, among the Hottentots, it would be scandalous to eat without having loudly called out thrice whether there is not somebody wanting to share the food, all that a respectable citizen has to do now is to pay the poor tax and to let the starving starve. The result is, that the theory which maintains that men can, and must, seek their own happiness in a disregard of other people's wants is now triumphant all round in law, in science, in religion. It is the religion of the day, and to doubt of its efficacy is to be a dangerous Utopian. Science loudly proclaims that the struggle of each against all is the leading principle of nature, and of human societies as well. To that struggle Biology ascribes the progressive evolution of the animal world. History takes the same line of argument; and political economists, in their naive ignorance, trace all progress of modern industry and machinery to the "wonderful" effects of the same principle. The very religion of the pulpit is a religion of individualism, slightly mitigated by more or less charitable relations to one's neighbours, chiefly on Sundays. "Practical" men and theorists, men of science and religious preachers, lawyers and politicians, all agree upon one thing—that individualism may be more or less softened in its harshest effects by charity, but that it is the only secure basis for the maintenance of society and its ulterior progress.

The State taking over all social functions has led to a wild, selfish individualism. As people's responsibilities to the State increased, they were clearly relieved of their responsibilities to one another. In guilds, which everyone belonged to during medieval times, two "brothers" had to take turns looking after a sick member; now, it's enough to just give a neighbor the address of the nearest homeless shelter. In barbarian societies, witnessing a fight between two people due to a quarrel and not stopping it from turning deadly would make you seen as a murderer; but with the all-protecting State idea, bystanders don't need to get involved—it's up to the police to act, or not. While in savage lands, like among the Hottentots, it would be disgraceful to eat without loudly asking three times if anyone wants to share the food, a respectable citizen today just has to pay a poor tax and can ignore the starving. The result is that the belief that people can and should pursue their own happiness without considering the needs of others is now overwhelmingly accepted in law, science, and religion. It's the belief of the day, and questioning its effectiveness makes you a dangerous dreamer. Science loudly states that the struggle of each person against all is the fundamental principle of nature and human societies. Biology links this struggle to the evolution of the animal kingdom. History follows the same reasoning, and political economists, in their naive understanding, attribute all advancements in modern industry and machinery to the "amazing" effects of this principle. The very religion preached from the pulpit centers on individualism, softened only by occasional charity towards neighbors, mostly on Sundays. "Practical" people, theorists, scientists, religious leaders, lawyers, and politicians all agree on one thing—that individualism can be somewhat softened by charity, but it is the only stable foundation for maintaining society and ensuring its future progress.

It seems, therefore, hopeless to look for mutual-aid institutions and practices in modern society. What could remain of them? And yet, as soon as we try to ascertain how the millions of human beings live, and begin to study their everyday relations, we are struck with the immense part which the mutual-aid and mutual-support principles play even now-a-days in human life. Although the destruction of mutual-aid institutions has been going on in practice and theory, for full three or four hundred years, hundreds of millions of men continue to live under such institutions; they piously maintain them and endeavour to reconstitute them where they have ceased to exist. In our mutual relations every one of us has his moments of revolt against the fashionable individualistic creed of the day, and actions in which men are guided by their mutual aid inclinations constitute so great a part of our daily intercourse that if a stop to such actions could be put all further ethical progress would be stopped at once. Human society itself could not be maintained for even so much as the lifetime of one single generation. These facts, mostly neglected by sociologists and yet of the first importance for the life and further elevation of mankind, we are now going to analyze, beginning with the standing institutions of mutual support, and passing next to those acts of mutual aid which have their origin in personal or social sympathies.

It seems hopeless to search for mutual-aid institutions and practices in modern society. What could possibly be left of them? Yet, as soon as we try to understand how millions of people live and start studying their daily interactions, we're amazed by the significant role that mutual-aid and mutual-support principles still play in human life today. Although mutual-aid institutions have been systematically dismantled in practice and theory for three to four hundred years, hundreds of millions of people continue to live under such systems; they actively preserve them and strive to recreate them where they have disappeared. In our interactions, each of us experiences moments where we push back against the trending individualistic mindset of the day, and actions guided by our inclinations toward mutual aid make up such a large part of our daily exchanges that if those actions were to cease, all further ethical progress would halt immediately. Human society itself could not sustain itself for even a single generation. These facts, often overlooked by sociologists yet crucial for the life and advancement of humanity, will now be analyzed, starting with established institutions of mutual support and then moving on to acts of mutual aid that arise from personal or social sympathies.

When we cast a broad glance on the present constitution of European society we are struck at once with the fact that, although so much has been done to get rid of the village community, this form of union continues to exist to the extent we shall presently see, and that many attempts are now made either to reconstitute it in some shape or another or to find some substitute for it. The current theory as regards the village community is, that in Western Europe it has died out by a natural death, because the communal possession of the soil was found inconsistent with the modern requirements of agriculture. But the truth is that nowhere did the village community disappear of its own accord; everywhere, on the contrary, it took the ruling classes several centuries of persistent but not always successful efforts to abolish it and to confiscate the communal lands.

When we take a broad look at the current structure of European society, it's clear that even though a lot has been done to eliminate the village community, this type of organization still exists to a degree that we will soon discuss. Many efforts are now being made either to recreate it in one form or another or to find an alternative to it. The prevailing theory about the village community is that in Western Europe, it has naturally faded away because communal land ownership doesn't fit with the modern needs of agriculture. However, the reality is that the village community never disappeared on its own; rather, it took the ruling classes several centuries of ongoing, but not always successful, attempts to dismantle it and seize communal lands.

In France, the village communities began to be deprived of their independence, and their lands began to be plundered, as early as the sixteenth century. However, it was only in the next century, when the mass of the peasants was brought, by exactions and wars, to the state of subjection and misery which is vividly depicted by all historians, that the plundering of their lands became easy and attained scandalous proportions. "Every one has taken of them according to his powers … imaginary debts have been claimed, in order to seize upon their lands;" so we read in an edict promulgated by Louis the Fourteenth in 1667.(3) Of course the State's remedy for such evils was to render the communes still more subservient to the State, and to plunder them itself. In fact, two years later all money revenue of the communes was confiscated by the King. As to the appropriation of communal lands, it grew worse and worse, and in the next century the nobles and the clergy had already taken possession of immense tracts of land—one-half of the cultivated area, according to certain estimates—mostly to let it go out of culture.(4) But the peasants still maintained their communal institutions, and until the year 1787 the village folkmotes, composed of all householders, used to come together in the shadow of the bell-tower or a tree, to allot and re-allot what they had retained of their fields, to assess the taxes, and to elect their executive, just as the Russian mir does at the present time. This is what Babeau's researches have proved to demonstration.(5)

In France, village communities started losing their independence and their lands were being taken away as early as the sixteenth century. However, it wasn't until the next century that the majority of peasants, through exploitation and wars, fell into a state of oppression and misery vividly described by historians, making it easier for their lands to be seized in outrageous ways. "Everyone has taken from them according to their abilities… imaginary debts have been claimed in order to take over their lands," as stated in an edict issued by Louis the Fourteenth in 1667.(3) Naturally, the State's solution to these issues was to make the communes even more subordinate and to plunder them directly. In fact, two years later, the King confiscated all the monetary income of the communes. The appropriation of communal lands only worsened, and by the following century, nobles and clergy had already taken control of vast areas of land—estimated to be half of the cultivated land—mostly allowing it to go uncultivated.(4) Nonetheless, the peasants continued to uphold their communal institutions, and until 1787, local assemblies, consisting of all householders, would gather in the shade of the bell tower or a tree to manage and redistribute what they had left of their fields, assess taxes, and elect their leaders, just like the Russian mir does today. This has been clearly demonstrated by Babeau's research.(5)

The Government found, however, the folkmotes "too noisy," too disobedient, and in 1787, elected councils, composed of a mayor and three to six syndics, chosen from among the wealthier peasants, were introduced instead. Two years later the Revolutionary Assemblee Constituante, which was on this point at one with the old regime, fully confirmed this law (on the 14th of December, 1789), and the bourgeois du village had now their turn for the plunder of communal lands, which continued all through the Revolutionary period. Only on the 16th of August, 1792, the Convention, under the pressure of the peasants' insurrections, decided to return the enclosed lands to the communes;(6) but it ordered at the same time that they should be divided in equal parts among the wealthier peasants only—a measure which provoked new insurrections and was abrogated next year, in 1793, when the order came to divide the communal lands among all commoners, rich and poor alike, "active" and "inactive."

The Government found the folkmotes "too noisy" and too disobedient, so in 1787, they introduced elected councils made up of a mayor and three to six syndics, selected from the wealthier peasants. Two years later, the Revolutionary Assembly (Assemblee Constituante), which aligned with the old regime on this issue, officially confirmed this law on December 14, 1789. Now, the wealthy villagers had their chance to exploit communal lands, and this continued throughout the Revolutionary period. However, on August 16, 1792, the Convention, responding to peasant uprisings, decided to return the enclosed lands to the communes; but at the same time, they mandated that these lands be divided equally among the wealthier peasants only. This decision led to further uprisings and was reversed the following year, in 1793, when the order was given to divide the communal lands among all commoners, both rich and poor, "active" and "inactive."

These two laws, however, ran so much against the conceptions of the peasants that they were not obeyed, and wherever the peasants had retaken possession of part of their lands they kept them undivided. But then came the long years of wars, and the communal lands were simply confiscated by the State (in 1794) as a mortgage for State loans, put up for sale, and plundered as such; then returned again to the communes and confiscated again (in 1813); and only in 1816 what remained of them, i.e. about 15,000,000 acres of the least productive land, was restored to the village communities.(7) Still this was not yet the end of the troubles of the communes. Every new regime saw in the communal lands a means for gratifying its supporters, and three laws (the first in 1837 and the last under Napoleon the Third) were passed to induce the village communities to divide their estates. Three times these laws had to be repealed, in consequence of the opposition they met with in the villages; but something was snapped up each time, and Napoleon the Third, under the pretext of encouraging perfected methods of agriculture, granted large estates out of the communal lands to some of his favourites.

These two laws, however, went against what the peasants believed, so they weren't followed. Wherever the peasants regained parts of their land, they kept it as a whole. But then the long years of war came, and in 1794, the State simply confiscated the communal lands as collateral for State loans, sold them off, and looted them. They were then returned to the communes and confiscated again in 1813, and it wasn't until 1816 that what was left—about 15 million acres of the least productive land—was restored to the village communities. Still, this didn’t put an end to the communes' troubles. Every new government viewed the communal lands as a way to reward its supporters, so three laws were passed (the first in 1837 and the last under Napoleon the Third) to encourage village communities to divide their estates. Each time these laws faced opposition in the villages, they were repealed, but some land was taken each time. Napoleon the Third, claiming to promote better agricultural practices, awarded large estates from the communal lands to some of his favorites.

As to the autonomy of the village communities, what could be retained of it after so many blows? The mayor and the syndics were simply looked upon as unpaid functionaries of the State machinery. Even now, under the Third Republic, very little can be done in a village community without the huge State machinery, up to the prefet and the ministries, being set in motion. It is hardly credible, and yet it is true, that when, for instance, a peasant intends to pay in money his share in the repair of a communal road, instead of himself breaking the necessary amount of stones, no fewer than twelve different functionaries of the State must give their approval, and an aggregate of fifty-two different acts must be performed by them, and exchanged between them, before the peasant is permitted to pay that money to the communal council. All the remainder bears the same character.(8)

As for the independence of the village communities, what could possibly be left of it after so many setbacks? The mayor and the local officials were basically seen as unpaid employees of the State system. Even now, under the Third Republic, very little can happen in a village community without the massive State machinery, all the way up to the prefect and the ministries, being set in motion. It's hard to believe, but it's true that when a farmer wants to pay for his share of repairing a communal road, instead of just breaking the necessary amount of stones himself, at least twelve different State officials must approve it, and a total of fifty-two different actions must be completed and exchanged between them before the farmer is allowed to pay that money to the communal council. Everything else follows the same pattern.

What took place in France took place everywhere in Western and Middle Europe. Even the chief dates of the great assaults upon the peasant lands are the same. For England the only difference is that the spoliation was accomplished by separate acts rather than by general sweeping measures—with less haste but more thoroughly than in France. The seizure of the communal lands by the lords also began in the fifteenth century, after the defeat of the peasant insurrection of 1380—as seen from Rossus's Historia and from a statute of Henry the Seventh, in which these seizures are spoken of under the heading of "enormitees and myschefes as be hurtfull … to the common wele."(9) Later on the Great Inquest, under Henry the Eighth, was begun, as is known, in order to put a stop to the enclosure of communal lands, but it ended in a sanction of what had been done.(10) The communal lands continued to be preyed upon, and the peasants were driven from the land. But it was especially since the middle of the eighteenth century that, in England as everywhere else, it became part of a systematic policy to simply weed out all traces of communal ownership; and the wonder is not that it has disappeared, but that it could be maintained, even in England, so as to be "generally prevalent so late as the grandfathers of this generation."(11) The very object of the Enclosure Acts, as shown by Mr. Seebohm, was to remove this system,(12) and it was so well removed by the nearly four thousand Acts passed between 1760 and 1844 that only faint traces of it remain now. The land of the village communities was taken by the lords, and the appropriation was sanctioned by Parliament in each separate case.

What happened in France happened everywhere in Western and Central Europe. Even the key dates of the major assaults on peasant lands are the same. For England, the only difference is that the dispossession was carried out through individual actions instead of broad sweeping measures—done more slowly but more thoroughly than in France. The seizure of communal lands by the lords also started in the fifteenth century, after the defeat of the peasant uprising in 1380—as noted in Rossus's Historia and in a statute by Henry the Seventh, which refers to these seizures under the title of "enormities and mischiefs that are harmful ... to the common good." Later, the Great Inquest, initiated under Henry the Eighth, was meant to stop the enclosure of communal lands, but it ultimately ended up supporting what had already been done. The communal lands continued to be exploited, and the peasants were pushed off the land. However, especially since the mid-eighteenth century, in England as in other places, it became a part of a systematic policy to completely eliminate all signs of communal ownership; and the surprising thing isn't that it has vanished, but that it could persist, even in England, to be "generally prevalent as late as the grandfathers of this generation." The very aim of the Enclosure Acts, as Mr. Seebohm pointed out, was to abolish this system, and it was so effectively removed by the nearly four thousand Acts passed between 1760 and 1844 that only faint traces of it remain today. The land of the village communities was taken by the lords, and the appropriation was approved by Parliament in each individual case.

In Germany, in Austria, in Belgium the village community was also destroyed by the State. Instances of commoners themselves dividing their lands were rare,(13) while everywhere the States coerced them to enforce the division, or simply favoured the private appropriation of their lands. The last blow to communal ownership in Middle Europe also dates from the middle of the eighteenth century. In Austria sheer force was used by the Government, in 1768, to compel the communes to divide their lands—a special commission being nominated two years later for that purpose. In Prussia Frederick the Second, in several of his ordinances (in 1752, 1763, 1765, and 1769), recommended to the Justizcollegien to enforce the division. In Silesia a special resolution was issued to serve that aim in 1771. The same took place in Belgium, and, as the communes did not obey, a law was issued in 1847 empowering the Government to buy communal meadows in order to sell them in retail, and to make a forced sale of the communal land when there was a would-be buyer for it.(14)

In Germany, Austria, and Belgium, the village community was also dismantled by the State. Cases of commoners dividing their lands themselves were uncommon, while the States everywhere pressured them to enforce the division or simply supported the private takeover of their lands. The final blow to communal ownership in Central Europe also occurred in the mid-eighteenth century. In Austria, the Government used sheer force in 1768 to pressure the communes to divide their lands—a special commission was appointed two years later for this purpose. In Prussia, Frederick the Second, in several of his orders (in 1752, 1763, 1765, and 1769), urged the Justizcollegien to enforce the division. In Silesia, a special resolution was issued for this purpose in 1771. The same happened in Belgium, and when the communes did not comply, a law was enacted in 1847 giving the Government the power to buy communal meadows to sell them individually and to compel the sale of communal land when there was a prospective buyer for it.

In short, to speak of the natural death of the village communities in virtue of economical laws is as grim a joke as to speak of the natural death of soldiers slaughtered on a battlefield. The fact was simply this: The village communities had lived for over a thousand years; and where and when the peasants were not ruined by wars and exactions they steadily improved their methods of culture. But as the value of land was increasing, in consequence of the growth of industries, and the nobility had acquired, under the State organization, a power which it never had had under the feudal system, it took possession of the best parts of the communal lands, and did its best to destroy the communal institutions.

In short, saying that the village communities died a natural death due to economic forces is as darkly amusing as saying that soldiers killed on a battlefield died of natural causes. The reality was this: The village communities had thrived for over a thousand years; where peasants weren't devastated by wars and taxes, they consistently improved their farming methods. However, as land values rose due to industrial growth, the nobility gained a level of power through state organization that they never had under the feudal system. They seized the best parts of communal land and did their utmost to dismantle communal institutions.

However, the village-community institutions so well respond to the needs and conceptions of the tillers of the soil that, in spite of all, Europe is up to this date covered with living survivals of the village communities, and European country life is permeated with customs and habits dating from the community period. Even in England, notwithstanding all the drastic measures taken against the old order of things, it prevailed as late as the beginning of the nineteenth century. Mr. Gomme—one of the very few English scholars who have paid attention to the subject—shows in his work that many traces of the communal possession of the soil are found in Scotland, "runrig" tenancy having been maintained in Forfarshire up to 1813, while in certain villages of Inverness the custom was, up to 1801, to plough the land for the whole community, without leaving any boundaries, and to allot it after the ploughing was done. In Kilmorie the allotment and re-allotment of the fields was in full vigour "till the last twenty-five years," and the Crofters' Commission found it still in vigour in certain islands.(15) In Ireland the system prevailed up to the great famine; and as to England, Marshall's works, which passed unnoticed until Nasse and Sir Henry Maine drew attention to them, leave no doubt as to the village-community system having been widely spread, in nearly all English counties, at the beginning of the nineteenth century.(16) No more than twenty years ago Sir Henry Maine was "greatly surprised at the number of instances of abnormal property rights, necessarily implying the former existence of collective ownership and joint cultivation," which a comparatively brief inquiry brought under his notice.(17) And, communal institutions having persisted so late as that, a great number of mutual-aid habits and customs would undoubtedly be discovered in English villages if the writers of this country only paid attention to village life.(18)

However, the village-community institutions respond so well to the needs and views of farmers that, despite everything, Europe is still filled with living remnants of village communities, and rural life is infused with customs and habits dating back to the community era. Even in England, despite all the drastic measures taken against the old ways, this system lasted as late as the early nineteenth century. Mr. Gomme—one of the few English scholars who have studied this topic—shows in his work that many signs of communal land ownership can be found in Scotland, with "runrig" tenancy still in practice in Forfarshire until 1813. In certain villages in Inverness, the custom was to plow the land for the entire community, without leaving any boundaries, and then assign it after plowing was completed, a practice that continued until 1801. In Kilmorie, the process of allotting and reallocating fields was active "until the last twenty-five years," and the Crofters' Commission found it still in practice on certain islands. In Ireland, this system persisted until the great famine; and in England, Marshall's works, which went largely unnoticed until Nasse and Sir Henry Maine highlighted them, clearly indicate that the village-community system was widespread in nearly all English counties at the beginning of the nineteenth century. Just twenty years ago, Sir Henry Maine was "greatly surprised by the number of examples of abnormal property rights, which necessarily suggest the former existence of collective ownership and joint cultivation," that a relatively brief inquiry revealed. Given that communal institutions lasted that long, a significant number of mutual aid habits and customs would undoubtedly be found in English villages if the writers in this country paid more attention to rural life.

As to the Continent, we find the communal institutions fully alive in many parts of France, Switzerland, Germany, Italy, the Scandinavian lands, and Spain, to say nothing of Eastern Europe; the village life in these countries is permeated with communal habits and customs; and almost every year the Continental literature is enriched by serious works dealing with this and connected subjects. I must, therefore, limit my illustrations to the most typical instances. Switzerland is undoubtedly one of them. Not only the five republics of Uri, Schwytz, Appenzell, Glarus, and Unterwalden hold their lands as undivided estates, and are governed by their popular folkmotes, but in all other cantons too the village communities remain in possession of a wide self-government, and own large parts of the Federal territory.(19) Two-thirds of all the Alpine meadows and two-thirds of all the forests of Switzerland are until now communal land; and a considerable number of fields, orchards, vineyards, peat bogs, quarries, and so on, are owned in common. In the Vaud, where all the householders continue to take part in the deliberations of their elected communal councils, the communal spirit is especially alive. Towards the end of the winter all the young men of each village go to stay a few days in the woods, to fell timber and to bring it down the steep slopes tobogganing way, the timber and the fuel wood being divided among all households or sold for their benefit. These excursions are real fetes of manly labour. On the banks of Lake Leman part of the work required to keep up the terraces of the vineyards is still done in common; and in the spring, when the thermometer threatens to fall below zero before sunrise, the watchman wakes up all householders, who light fires of straw and dung and protect their vine-trees from the frost by an artificial cloud. In nearly all cantons the village communities possess so-called. Burgernutzen—that is, they hold in common a number of cows, in order to supply each family with butter; or they keep communal fields or vineyards, of which the produce is divided between the burghers, or they rent their land for the benefit of the community.(20)

As for the continent, we see community institutions thriving in many areas of France, Switzerland, Germany, Italy, the Scandinavian countries, and Spain, not to mention Eastern Europe. The village life in these countries is filled with community habits and customs, and almost every year, continental literature grows richer with serious works on this and related topics. Therefore, I will limit my examples to the most typical cases. Switzerland is undoubtedly one of them. The five republics of Uri, Schwytz, Appenzell, Glarus, and Unterwalden not only maintain their lands as undivided estates but are also governed by local assemblies. Additionally, in all other cantons, village communities enjoy significant self-government and own large parts of the Federal territory. Two-thirds of all Alpine meadows and two-thirds of all the forests in Switzerland are still communal land, and a considerable amount of fields, orchards, vineyards, peat bogs, quarries, and so forth, are owned collectively. In Vaud, where all householders continue to participate in discussions of their elected community councils, the communal spirit is particularly vibrant. At the end of winter, all the young men from each village spend a few days in the woods cutting down trees and bringing the timber down steep slopes on sleds, with the wood being shared among all households or sold for their benefit. These outings are true celebrations of hard work. On the shores of Lake Geneva, part of the work required to maintain the vineyard terraces is still done collectively; and in the spring, when the temperature threatens to drop below freezing before sunrise, the watchman wakes up all the householders, who ignite fires made of straw and dung to protect their vines from frost by creating an artificial cloud. In nearly all cantons, village communities have what's called Burgernutzen—that is, they collectively own a number of cows to provide each family with butter; they also maintain communal fields or vineyards, with the produce divided among the community members, or they rent their land for the benefit of the community.

It may be taken as a rule that where the communes have retained a wide sphere of functions, so as to be living parts of the national organism, and where they have not been reduced to sheer misery, they never fail to take good care of their lands. Accordingly the communal estates in Switzerland strikingly contrast with the miserable state of "commons" in this country. The communal forests in the Vaud and the Valais are admirably managed, in conformity with the rules of modern forestry. Elsewhere the "strips" of communal fields, which change owners under the system of re-allotment, are very well manured, especially as there is no lack of meadows and cattle. The high level meadows are well kept as a rule, and the rural roads are excellent.(21) And when we admire the Swiss chalet, the mountain road, the peasants' cattle, the terraces of vineyards, or the school-house in Switzer land, we must keep in mind that without the timber for the chalet being taken from the communal woods and the stone from the communal quarries, without the cows being kept on the communal meadows, and the roads being made and the school-houses built by communal work, there would be little to admire.

It can be said that where communities have maintained a broad range of responsibilities, making them active parts of the national system, and where they haven't been reduced to extreme poverty, they always take great care of their land. This is why the community-owned estates in Switzerland stand in sharp contrast to the poor condition of "commons" in this country. The community forests in Vaud and Valais are well-managed, following modern forestry practices. In other areas, the "strips" of communal fields, which change hands through re-allotment, are well-fertilized, especially since there are plenty of meadows and cattle. The higher meadows are typically well-maintained, and the rural roads are excellent.(21) When we admire the Swiss chalet, the mountain roads, the farmers' cattle, the terraced vineyards, or the schoolhouse in Switzerland, we must remember that without the wood for the chalet coming from community forests and the stone from community quarries, without the cows grazing on community meadows, and the roads being built and the schoolhouses constructed through community effort, there would be little to admire.

It hardly need be said that a great number of mutual-aid habits and customs continue to persist in the Swiss villages. The evening gatherings for shelling walnuts, which take place in turns in each household; the evening parties for sewing the dowry of the girl who is going to marry; the calling of "aids" for building the houses and taking in the crops, as well as for all sorts of work which may be required by one of the commoners; the custom of exchanging children from one canton to the other, in order to make them learn two languages, French and German; and so on—all these are quite habitual;(22) while, on the other side, divers modern requirements are met in the same spirit. Thus in Glarus most of the Alpine meadows have been sold during a time of calamity; but the communes still continue to buy field land, and after the newly-bought fields have been left in the possession of separate commoners for ten, twenty, or thirty years, as the case might be, they return to the common stock, which is re-allotted according to the needs of all. A great number of small associations are formed to produce some of the necessaries for life—bread, cheese, and wine—by common work, be it only on a limited scale; and agricultural co-operation altogether spreads in Switzerland with the greatest ease. Associations formed between ten to thirty peasants, who buy meadows and fields in common, and cultivate them as co-owners, are of common occurrence; while dairy associations for the sale of milk, butter, and cheese are organized everywhere. In fact, Switzerland was the birthplace of that form of co-operation. It offers, moreover, an immense field for the study of all sorts of small and large societies, formed for the satisfaction of all sorts of modern wants. In certain parts of Switzerland one finds in almost every village a number of associations—for protection from fire, for boating, for maintaining the quays on the shores of a lake, for the supply of water, and so on; and the country is covered with societies of archers, sharpshooters, topographers, footpath explorers, and the like, originated from modern militarism.

It hardly needs to be mentioned that many mutual aid habits and customs still exist in Swiss villages. The evening gatherings for shelling walnuts, which rotate among households; the evening parties for sewing the dowry of the bride-to-be; the calling of "aids" for building houses and harvesting crops, as well as for various tasks that may be needed by one of the community members; the practice of exchanging children between cantons to help them learn both French and German; and so on—all these are quite common. Meanwhile, several modern needs are also addressed in this same spirit. For example, in Glarus, many Alpine meadows were sold during a time of crisis, but the communities still continue to purchase farmland. After the newly acquired fields are held by individual commoners for ten, twenty, or thirty years, they revert to the common stock, which is reallocated based on everyone’s needs. Numerous small associations are formed to produce essential items like bread, cheese, and wine through collective effort, even if it’s on a limited scale; and agricultural cooperation is thriving in Switzerland. It’s quite common for groups of ten to thirty farmers to buy and cultivate meadows and fields together as co-owners, while dairy associations for selling milk, butter, and cheese are found everywhere. In fact, Switzerland was the birthplace of this form of cooperation. It also provides a vast area for studying various small and large societies created to meet all kinds of modern needs. In certain regions of Switzerland, you can find many associations in almost every village—for fire protection, boating, maintaining lakefront quays, water supply, and more; and the country is filled with societies for archers, sharpshooters, topographers, trailblazers, and similar groups, stemming from modern militarism.

Switzerland is, however, by no means an exception in Europe, because the same institutions and habits are found in the villages of France, of Italy, of Germany, of Denmark, and so on. We have just seen what has been done by the rulers of France in order to destroy the village community and to get hold of its lands; but notwithstanding all that one-tenth part of the whole territory available for culture, i.e. 13,500,000 acres, including one-half of all the natural meadows and nearly a fifth part of all the forests of the country, remain in communal possession. The woods supply the communers with fuel, and the timber wood is cut, mostly by communal work, with all desirable regularity; the grazing lands are free for the commoners' cattle; and what remains of communal fields is allotted and re-allotted in certain parts Ardennes—in the usual of France—namely, in the way.(23)

Switzerland isn’t unique in Europe; similar institutions and practices can be found in the villages of France, Italy, Germany, Denmark, and so on. We’ve just seen how the rulers of France have tried to dismantle the village community to take control of its land. Despite their efforts, one-tenth of the entire land available for cultivation, which is about 13,500,000 acres, including half of all the natural meadows and nearly a fifth of all the forests in the country, still belongs to the community. The forests provide firewood for the community members, and the timber is harvested mainly through communal efforts, all done regularly. The grazing lands are open for the commoners' livestock, and what remains of the communal fields is divided and redivided in certain areas of the Ardennes, as is typical in France.

These additional sources of supply, which aid the poorer peasants to pass through a year of bad crops without parting with their small plots of land and without running into irredeemable debts, have certainly their importance for both the agricultural labourers and the nearly three millions of small peasant proprietors. It is even doubtful whether small peasant proprietorship could be maintained without these additional resources. But the ethical importance of the communal possessions, small as they are, is still greater than their economical value. They maintain in village life a nucleus of customs and habits of mutual aid which undoubtedly acts as a mighty check upon the development of reckless individualism and greediness, which small land-ownership is only too prone to develop. Mutual aid in all possible circumstances of village life is part of the routine life in all parts of the country. Everywhere we meet, under different names, with the charroi, i.e. the free aid of the neighbours for taking in a crop, for vintage, or for building a house; everywhere we find the same evening gatherings as have just been mentioned in Switzerland; and everywhere the commoners associate for all sorts of work. Such habits are mentioned by nearly all those who have written upon French village life. But it will perhaps be better to give in this place some abstracts from letters which I have just received from a friend of mine whom I have asked to communicate to me his observations on this subject. They come from an aged man who for years has been the mayor of his commune in South France (in Ariege); the facts he mentions are known to him from long years of personal observation, and they have the advantage of coming from one neighbourhood instead of being skimmed from a large area. Some of them may seem trifling, but as a whole they depict quite a little world of village life.

These extra sources of support help poorer farmers get through a bad crop year without having to sell their small plots of land or falling into unmanageable debt. They are definitely important for both agricultural workers and the nearly three million small landowners. It's even questionable whether small land ownership could survive without these additional resources. However, the ethical significance of communal possessions, despite their size, outweighs their economic value. They foster a set of customs and habits of mutual support in village life that clearly curbs the rise of reckless individualism and greed, tendencies that small land ownership often encourages. Mutual aid in various aspects of village life is a regular part of daily existence across the country. Everywhere we see what’s known as charroi, which is the free help from neighbors for harvesting crops, winemaking, or building a house; we also find the same evening gatherings mentioned in Switzerland; and commoners come together for all sorts of tasks. These practices are noted by nearly everyone who has written about French village life. However, it may be better to share some excerpts from letters I received from a friend I asked to share his observations on this topic. They are from an elderly man who has been the mayor of his community in southern France (in Ariege) for many years; the insights he provides come from extensive personal experience and offer the benefit of being drawn from a single area rather than a broad region. Some of his points may seem trivial, but together they paint a picture of village life.

"In several communes in our neighbourhood," my friend writes, "the old custom of l'emprount is in vigour. When many hands are required in a metairie for rapidly making some work—dig out potatoes or mow the grass—the youth of the neighbourhood is convoked; young men and girls come in numbers, make it gaily and for nothing; and in the evening, after a gay meal, they dance.

"In several communities nearby," my friend writes, "the old custom of l'emprount is still alive. When a lot of help is needed at a farm to quickly get some work done—digging up potatoes or mowing the grass—the local youth gathers; young men and women come in groups, have fun, and do it for free; and in the evening, after a cheerful meal, they dance."

"In the same communes, when a girl is going to marry, the girls of the neighbourhood come to aid in sewing the dowry. In several communes the women still continue to spin a good deal. When the winding off has to be done in a family it is done in one evening—all friends being convoked for that work. In many communes of the Ariege and other parts of the south-west the shelling of the Indian corn-sheaves is also done by all the neighbours. They are treated with chestnuts and wine, and the young people dance after the work has been done. The same custom is practised for making nut oil and crushing hemp. In the commune of L. the same is done for bringing in the corn crops. These days of hard work become fete days, as the owner stakes his honour on serving a good meal. No remuneration is given; all do it for each other.(24)

"In the same communities, when a girl is about to get married, the girls from the neighborhood come together to help sew the dowry. In several areas, women still do a lot of spinning. When it's time to wind off thread in a family, it's done in one evening—everyone gathers to help with the task. In many communities in the Ariege and other parts of the southwest, the neighbors also come together to shell the Indian corn sheaves. They are treated to chestnuts and wine, and the young people dance after the work is done. The same custom is followed for making nut oil and processing hemp. In the community of L., the same practice is observed for harvesting corn crops. These days of hard work turn into festive occasions, as the owner takes pride in serving a good meal. No payment is involved; everyone does it for one another.(24)”

"In the commune of S. the common grazing-land is every year increased, so that nearly the whole of the land of the commune is now kept in common. The shepherds are elected by all owners of the cattle, including women. The bulls are communal.

"In the commune of S., the common grazing land expands every year, so that nearly all the land in the commune is now shared. The shepherds are chosen by all the cattle owners, including women. The bulls are shared as well."

"In the commune of M. the forty to fifty small sheep flocks of the commoners are brought together and divided into three or four flocks before being sent to the higher meadows. Each owner goes for a week to serve as shepherd.

"In the community of M., the forty to fifty small sheep flocks belonging to the commoners are gathered and split into three or four flocks before they are taken to the higher pastures. Each owner goes for a week to act as the shepherd."

"In the hamlet of C. a threshing machine has been bought in common by several households; the fifteen to twenty persons required to serve the machine being supplied by all the families. Three other threshing machines have been bought and are rented out by their owners, but the work is performed by outside helpers, invited in the usual way.

"In the village of C., several households have pooled their resources to buy a threshing machine; the fifteen to twenty people needed to operate the machine are provided by all the families. Three other threshing machines have been purchased and are rented out by their owners, but the work is done by outside helpers, brought in as usual."

"In our commune of R. we had to raise the wall of the cemetery. Half of the money which was required for buying lime and for the wages of the skilled workers was supplied by the county council, and the other half by subscription. As to the work of carrying sand and water, making mortar, and serving the masons, it was done entirely by volunteers [just as in the Kabyle djemmaa]. The rural roads were repaired in the same way, by volunteer days of work given by the commoners. Other communes have built in the same way their fountains. The wine-press and other smaller appliances are frequently kept by the commune."

"In our community of R., we had to raise the wall of the cemetery. Half of the money needed for buying lime and paying skilled workers came from the county council, and the other half was raised through donations. As for carrying sand and water, mixing mortar, and assisting the masons, that was done entirely by volunteers [just like in the Kabyle djemmaa]. The rural roads were fixed in the same way, with the locals contributing volunteer work. Other communities have built their fountains in the same manner. The commune often maintains the wine press and other smaller tools."

Two residents of the same neighbourhood, questioned by my friend, add the following:—

Two people from the same neighborhood, asked by my friend, add the following:—

"At O. a few years ago there was no mill. The commune has built one, levying a tax upon the commoners. As to the miller, they decided, in order to avoid frauds and partiality, that he should be paid two francs for each bread-eater, and the corn be ground free.

"At O. a few years ago there was no mill. The community built one, charging a tax on the residents. As for the miller, they decided that to prevent cheating and favoritism, he would be paid two francs for each person who eats bread, and the grain would be ground for free."

"At St. G. few peasants are insured against fire. When a conflagration has taken place—so it was lately—all give something to the family which has suffered from it—a chaldron, a bed-cloth, a chair, and so on—and a modest household is thus reconstituted. All the neighbours aid to build the house, and in the meantime the family is lodged free by the neighbours."

"At St. G, very few farmers have fire insurance. When a fire breaks out—like it did recently—everyone contributes something to the affected family—a load of grain, a blanket, a chair, and so on—and this helps the family get back on their feet. All the neighbors pitch in to rebuild the house, and in the meantime, the family stays with the neighbors for free."

Such habits of mutual support—of which many more examples could be given—undoubtedly account for the easiness with which the French peasants associate for using, in turn, the plough with its team of horses, the wine-press, and the threshing machine, when they are kept in the village by one of them only, as well as for the performance of all sorts of rural work in common. Canals were maintained, forests were cleared, trees were planted, and marshes were drained by the village communities from time immemorial; and the same continues still. Quite lately, in La Borne of Lozere barren hills were turned into rich gardens by communal work. "The soil was brought on men's backs; terraces were made and planted with chestnut trees, peach trees, and orchards, and water was brought for irrigation in canals two or three miles long." Just now they have dug a new canal, eleven miles in length.(25)

Such habits of mutual support—there are many more examples—definitely explain how easily French peasants cooperate to share the plough and its team of horses, the wine-press, and the threshing machine when only one of them owns it. They also work together on all kinds of rural tasks. Village communities have maintained canals, cleared forests, planted trees, and drained marshes for ages, and they still do. Recently, in La Borne of Lozere, barren hills were transformed into thriving gardens through communal effort. "The soil was carried on men’s backs; terraces were built and planted with chestnut trees, peach trees, and orchards, and water for irrigation was brought in canals two or three miles long." They have just dug a new canal that’s eleven miles long. (25)

To the same spirit is also due the remarkable success lately obtained by the syndicats agricoles, or peasants' and farmers' associations. It was not until 1884 that associations of more than nineteen persons were permitted in France, and I need not say that when this "dangerous experiment" was ventured upon—so it was styled in the Chambers—all due "precautions" which functionaries can invent were taken. Notwithstanding all that, France begins to be covered with syndicates. At the outset they were only formed for buying manures and seeds, falsification having attained colossal proportions in these two branches;(26) but gradually they extended their functions in various directions, including the sale of agricultural produce and permanent improvements of the land. In South France the ravages of the phylloxera have called into existence a great number of wine-growers' associations. Ten to thirty growers form a syndicate, buy a steam-engine for pumping water, and make the necessary arrangements for inundating their vineyards in turn.(27) New associations for protecting the land from inundations, for irrigation purposes, and for maintaining canals are continually formed, and the unanimity of all peasants of a neighbourhood, which is required by law, is no obstacle. Elsewhere we have the fruitieres, or dairy associations, in some of which all butter and cheese is divided in equal parts, irrespective of the yield of each cow. In the Ariege we find an association of eight separate communes for the common culture of their lands, which they have put together; syndicates for free medical aid have been formed in 172 communes out of 337 in the same department; associations of consumers arise in connection with the syndicates; and so on.(28) "Quite a revolution is going on in our villages," Alfred Baudrillart writes, "through these associations, which take in each region their own special characters."

To the same spirit, we owe the impressive success recently achieved by the agricultural unions, or associations of peasants and farmers. It wasn't until 1884 that groups of more than nineteen people were allowed in France, and I should mention that when this "dangerous experiment" was attempted—so it was referred to in the Chambers—all necessary "precautions" that officials could come up with were implemented. Despite all that, France is starting to be filled with unions. Initially, they were only formed for purchasing fertilizers and seeds, as fraud in these two areas had reached massive levels; but gradually, they expanded their roles in various ways, including the sale of agricultural products and long-term improvements to the land. In southern France, the devastation caused by phylloxera has led to the creation of many associations for wine-growers. Groups of ten to thirty growers form unions, buy a steam engine for pumping water, and organize to flood their vineyards in turns. New associations for protecting land from flooding, for irrigation, and for maintaining canals are being formed all the time, and the requirement for unanimous agreement among all farmers in a neighborhood, as mandated by law, does not pose a barrier. Elsewhere, we have the fruitières, or dairy associations, where all butter and cheese is divided equally, regardless of how much each cow produces. In Ariege, there's an association of eight separate communities for the joint cultivation of their lands, which they have combined; unions for free medical assistance have been created in 172 out of 337 communes in the same area; consumer associations are emerging in connection with the unions; and so on. "A significant revolution is happening in our villages," writes Alfred Baudrillart, "through these associations, which each region shapes with its unique character."

Very much the same must be said of Germany. Wherever the peasants could resist the plunder of their lands, they have retained them in communal ownership, which largely prevails in Wurttemberg, Baden, Hohenzollern, and in the Hessian province of Starkenberg.(29) The communal forests are kept, as a rule, in an excellent state, and in thousands of communes timber and fuel wood are divided every year among all inhabitants; even the old custom of the Lesholztag is widely spread: at the ringing of the village bell all go to the forest to take as much fuel wood as they can carry.(30) In Westphalia one finds communes in which all the land is cultivated as one common estate, in accordance with all requirements of modern agronomy. As to the old communal customs and habits, they are in vigour in most parts of Germany. The calling in of aids, which are real fetes of labour, is known to be quite habitual in Westphalia, Hesse, and Nassau. In well-timbered regions the timber for a new house is usually taken from the communal forest, and all the neighbours join in building the house. Even in the suburbs of Frankfort it is a regular custom among the gardeners that in case of one of them being ill all come on Sunday to cultivate his garden.(31)

A similar situation exists in Germany. Wherever the farmers could fend off the invasion of their lands, they have kept them in communal ownership, which is largely the case in Wurttemberg, Baden, Hohenzollern, and the Hessian province of Starkenberg.(29) The communal forests are typically well-maintained, and in thousands of communities, timber and firewood are shared every year among all residents; the old tradition of the Lesholztag is still common: when the village bell rings, everyone goes to the forest to gather as much firewood as they can carry.(30) In Westphalia, there are communities where all the land is farmed as a single shared estate, following modern agricultural practices. Old customs and traditions remain strong in many parts of Germany. Organizing workdays, which are true celebrations of labor, is quite common in Westphalia, Hesse, and Nassau. In well-wooded areas, wood for a new house is usually sourced from the communal forest, and all the neighbors come together to help build the house. Even in the suburbs of Frankfurt, it's customary among the gardeners that when one of them is sick, everyone comes on Sunday to tend to his garden.(31)

In Germany, as in France, as soon as the rulers of the people repealed their laws against the peasant associations—that was only in 1884-1888—these unions began to develop with a wonderful rapidity, notwithstanding all legal obstacles which were put in their way(32) "It is a fact," Buchenberger says, "that in thousands of village communities, in which no sort of chemical manure or rational fodder was ever known, both have become of everyday use, to a quite unforeseen extent, owing to these associations" (vol. ii. p. 507). All sorts of labour-saving implements and agricultural machinery, and better breeds of cattle, are bought through the associations, and various arrangements for improving the quality of the produce begin to be introduced. Unions for the sale of agricultural produce are also formed, as well as for permanent improvements of the land.(33)

In Germany, just like in France, once the leaders lifted their restrictions on peasant associations—this happened between 1884 and 1888—these unions began to grow at an amazing pace, despite all the legal challenges they faced. "It’s a fact," Buchenberger notes, "that in thousands of village communities, where neither chemical fertilizers nor modern feed were ever utilized, both have become commonly used to an unexpected degree, thanks to these associations" (vol. ii. p. 507). Various labor-saving tools and farm machinery, as well as better livestock breeds, are purchased through these associations, and new methods for enhancing the quality of the produce start to be implemented. Unions for selling agricultural products are also created, along with groups focused on improving the land over the long term.

From the point of view of social economics all these efforts of the peasants certainly are of little importance. They cannot substantially, and still less permanently, alleviate the misery to which the tillers of the soil are doomed all over Europe. But from the ethical point of view, which we are now considering, their importance cannot be overrated. They prove that even under the system of reckless individualism which now prevails the agricultural masses piously maintain their mutual-support inheritance; and as soon as the States relax the iron laws by means of which they have broken all bonds between men, these bonds are at once reconstituted, notwithstanding the difficulties, political, economical, and social, which are many, and in such forms as best answer to the modern requirements of production. They indicate in which direction and in which form further progress must be expected.

From a social economics perspective, all these efforts of the peasants are certainly of little significance. They can’t really, and even less permanently, relieve the suffering that farmers face across Europe. However, from the ethical perspective we’re examining now, their significance cannot be overstated. They show that even in the current system of reckless individualism, the agricultural masses sincerely uphold their mutual-support inheritance; and as soon as the States ease the strict rules that have torn apart the bonds between people, these connections are quickly rebuilt, despite the numerous political, economic, and social challenges. They point to the direction and form that future progress should take.

I might easily multiply such illustrations, taking them from Italy, Spain, Denmark, and so on, and pointing out some interesting features which are proper to each of these countries. The Slavonian populations of Austria and the Balkan peninsula, among whom the "compound family," or "undivided household," is found in existence, ought also to be mentioned.(34) But I hasten to pass on to Russia, where the same mutual-support tendency takes certain new and unforeseen forms. Moreover, in dealing with the village community in Russia we have the advantage: of possessing an immense mass of materials, collected during the colossal house-to-house inquest which was lately made by several zemstvos (county councils), and which embraces a population of nearly 20,000,000 peasants in different parts of the country.(35)

I could easily provide more examples from Italy, Spain, Denmark, and other countries, highlighting some unique features specific to each. The Slavic populations in Austria and the Balkans, where the "compound family" or "undivided household" exists, should also be noted.(34) However, I will quickly move on to Russia, where the same trend of mutual support takes on new and unexpected forms. Additionally, when examining the village community in Russia, we benefit from an extensive collection of data gathered during a massive house-to-house survey recently conducted by several zemstvos (county councils), covering a population of nearly 20 million peasants across different regions of the country.(35)

Two important conclusions may be drawn from the bulk of evidence collected by the Russian inquests. In Middle Russia, where fully one-third of the peasants have been brought to utter ruin (by heavy taxation, small allotments of unproductive land, rack rents, and very severe tax-collecting after total failures of crops), there was, during the first five-and-twenty years after the emancipation of the serfs, a decided tendency towards the constitution of individual property in land within the village communities. Many impoverished "horseless" peasants abandoned their allotments, and this land often became the property of those richer peasants, who borrow additional incomes from trade, or of outside traders, who buy land chiefly for exacting rack rents from the peasants. It must also be added that a flaw in the land redemption law of 1861 offered great facilities for buying peasants' lands at a very small expense,(36) and that the State officials mostly used their weighty influence in favour of individual as against communal ownership. However, for the last twenty years a strong wind of opposition to the individual appropriation of the land blows again through the Middle Russian villages, and strenuous efforts are being made by the bulk of those peasants who stand between the rich and the very poor to uphold the village community. As to the fertile steppes of the South, which are now the most populous and the richest part of European Russia, they were mostly colonized, during the present century, under the system of individual ownership or occupation, sanctioned in that form by the State. But since improved methods of agriculture with the aid of machinery have been introduced in the region, the peasant owners have gradually begun themselves to transform their individual ownership into communal possession, and one finds now, in that granary of Russia, a very great number of spontaneously formed village communities of recent origin.(37)

Two key conclusions can be drawn from the extensive evidence gathered by the Russian investigations. In Middle Russia, where a full third of the peasants have been pushed into complete poverty (due to high taxes, small plots of unproductive land, exploitative rents, and very strict tax collection following total crop failures), there was a clear trend during the first 25 years after the serfs were freed, toward the establishment of individual land ownership within village communities. Many poor "horseless" peasants abandoned their land, which often ended up in the hands of wealthier peasants who were able to supplement their income through trade, or outside investors who bought the land primarily to charge high rents to the peasants. Additionally, it's important to note that a flaw in the 1861 land redemption law made it easier to purchase peasants' lands at minimal cost, and that state officials often used their considerable influence to support individual ownership over communal ownership. However, for the past 20 years, there has been a strong resurgence of opposition to individual land ownership in the villages of Middle Russia, with many peasants caught between the wealthy and the very poor working hard to maintain the village community. In the fertile southern steppes, which are now the most populated and richest part of European Russia, land was mainly settled under a system of individual ownership or occupation approved by the State during this century. But with the introduction of advanced agricultural techniques and machinery, peasant owners have gradually started to shift their individual holdings toward communal ownership, leading to a significant number of spontaneously formed village communities of recent origin in that granary of Russia.

The Crimea and the part of the mainland which lies to the north of it (the province of Taurida), for which we have detailed data, offer an excellent illustration of that movement. This territory began to be colonized, after its annexation in 1783, by Great, Little, and White Russians—Cossacks, freemen, and runaway serfs—who came individually or in small groups from all corners of Russia. They took first to cattle-breeding, and when they began later on to till the soil, each one tilled as much as he could afford to. But when—immigration continuing, and perfected ploughs being introduced—land stood in great demand, bitter disputes arose among the settlers. They lasted for years, until these men, previously tied by no mutual bonds, gradually came to the idea that an end must be put to disputes by introducing village-community ownership. They passed decisions to the effect that the land which they owned individually should henceforward be their common property, and they began to allot and to re-allot it in accordance with the usual village-community rules. The movement gradually took a great extension, and on a small territory, the Taurida statisticians found 161 villages in which communal ownership had been introduced by the peasant proprietors themselves, chiefly in the years 1855-1885, in lieu of individual ownership. Quite a variety of village-community types has been freely worked out in this way by the settlers.(38) What adds to the interest of this transformation is that it took place, not only among the Great Russians, who are used to village-community life, but also among Little Russians, who have long since forgotten it under Polish rule, among Greeks and Bulgarians, and even among Germans, who have long since worked out in their prosperous and half-industrial Volga colonies their own type of village community.(39) It is evident that the Mussulman Tartars of Taurida hold their land under the Mussulman customary law, which is limited personal occupation; but even with them the European village community has been introduced in a few cases. As to other nationalities in Taurida, individual ownership has been abolished in six Esthonian, two Greek, two Bulgarian, one Czech, and one German village. This movement is characteristic for the whole of the fertile steppe region of the south. But separate instances of it are also found in Little Russia. Thus in a number of villages of the province of Chernigov the peasants were formerly individual owners of their plots; they had separate legal documents for their plots and used to rent and to sell their land at will. But in the fifties of the nineteenth century a movement began among them in favour of communal possession, the chief argument being the growing number of pauper families. The initiative of the reform was taken in one village, and the others followed suit, the last case on record dating from 1882. Of course there were struggles between the poor, who usually claim for communal possession, and the rich, who usually prefer individual ownership; and the struggles often lasted for years. In certain places the unanimity required then by the law being impossible to obtain, the village divided into two villages, one under individual ownership and the other under communal possession; and so they remained until the two coalesced into one community, or else they remained divided still. As to Middle Russia, its a fact that in many villages which were drifting towards individual ownership there began since 1880 a mass movement in favour of re-establishing the village community. Even peasant proprietors who had lived for years under the individualist system returned en masse to the communal institutions. Thus, there is a considerable number of ex-serfs who have received one-fourth part only of the regulation allotments, but they have received them free of redemption and in individual ownership. There was in 1890 a wide-spread movement among them (in Kursk, Ryazan, Tambov, Orel, etc.) towards putting their allotments together and introducing the village community. The "free agriculturists" (volnyie khlebopashtsy), who were liberated from serfdom under the law of 1803, and had bought their allotments—each family separately—are now nearly all under the village-community system, which they have introduced themselves. All these movements are of recent origin, and non-Russians too join them. Thus the Bulgares in the district of Tiraspol, after having remained for sixty years under the personal-property system, introduced the village community in the years 1876-1882. The German Mennonites of Berdyansk fought in 1890 for introducing the village community, and the small peasant proprietors (Kleinwirthschaftliche) among the German Baptists were agitating in their villages in the same direction. One instance more: In the province of Samara the Russian government created in the forties, by way of experiment, 103 villages on the system of individual ownership. Each household received a splendid property of 105 acres. In 1890, out of the 103 villages the peasants in 72 had already notified the desire of introducing the village community. I take all these facts from the excellent work of V.V., who simply gives, in a classified form, the facts recorded in the above-mentioned house-to-house inquest.

The Crimea and the nearby mainland area known as Taurida provide a great example of this trend. After its annexation in 1783, this region began to be settled by Great, Little, and White Russians—Cossacks, free people, and escaped serfs—who came individually or in small groups from all over Russia. Initially, they focused on cattle farming, and when they later began to farm the land, each person cultivated as much as they could manage. However, as immigration continued and better plowing tools were introduced, the demand for land increased dramatically, leading to intense disputes among the settlers. These arguments persisted for years until these individuals, who previously had no connections with each other, agreed that they needed to resolve their disagreements by establishing community land ownership. They decided that the land they owned individually would now be considered communal property and began to allocate and reallocate it according to traditional community rules. This movement expanded significantly, and in a small area, officials found 161 villages where peasants themselves had adopted communal ownership between 1855 and 1885, replacing individual ownership. A variety of community models emerged from this process. What makes this change particularly interesting is that it happened not only among Great Russians, who were accustomed to community living, but also among Little Russians, who had forgotten about it under Polish rule, as well as among Greeks, Bulgarians, and even Germans, who had developed their own version of community living in their prosperous Volga colonies. It's clear that the Muslim Tatars of Taurida adhere to customary Muslim land use, which is based on limited personal ownership; however, in a few instances, a European-style community has been introduced among them. Other nationalities in Taurida have also seen individual ownership abolished, including in six Estonian villages, two Greek, two Bulgarian, one Czech, and one German village. This trend is typical across the fertile southern steppe region, though there are isolated cases in Little Russia as well. For instance, in several villages in Chernigov province, peasants previously owned their land individually and had separate deeds, allowing them to rent or sell their plots freely. In the 1850s, however, a movement emerged advocating for communal ownership, primarily driven by the increasing number of impoverished families. One village initiated the reform, and others followed, with the last documented case occurring in 1882. Naturally, conflicts arose between the poorer peasants, who generally supported communal ownership, and the wealthier ones, who preferred individual ownership. These conflicts often lasted for years. In some areas, due to the legal requirement for unanimous agreement being unachievable, villages split into two—one practicing individual ownership and the other communal. They remained either separate or eventually merged back into a single community. In Central Russia, starting around 1880, a significant movement began among many villages that were leaning towards individual ownership, working to restore village community systems. Even peasant landowners who had been living under individualistic practices for years returned en masse to communal institutions. Many former serfs received only a quarter of the standard allotments but owned them outright without any constraints. In 1890, a widespread effort emerged among these ex-serfs (in regions like Kursk, Ryazan, Tambov, Orel, etc.) to consolidate their land and establish communities. The "free farmers" who were liberated from serfdom under the 1803 law and purchased their allotments as individual families are now almost entirely organized into the village community structure that they formed themselves. These movements are relatively recent, and non-Russians are joining in as well. For example, Bulgarians in Tiraspol, after living under a personal-property system for sixty years, established village communities between 1876 and 1882. The German Mennonites in Berdyansk advocated for community living in 1890, and the small-scale peasant owners among the German Baptists pushed for similar changes in their villages. Another example: In the 1840s, the Russian government created 103 villages in Samara as an experiment with individual ownership, where each household received 105 acres. By 1890, out of those original 103 villages, the residents in 72 had expressed a desire to shift to a village community model. All of these facts are sourced from the outstanding work of V.V., who provides a well-organized account of the data collected from the previously mentioned household surveys.

This movement in favour of communal possession runs badly against the current economical theories, according to which intensive culture is incompatible with the village community. But the most charitable thing that can be said of these theories is that they have never been submitted to the test of experiment: they belong to the domain of political metaphysics. The facts which we have before us show, on the contrary, that wherever the Russian peasants, owing to a concurrence of favourable circumstances, are less miserable than they are on the average, and wherever they find men of knowledge and initiative among their neighbours, the village community becomes the very means for introducing various improvements in agriculture and village life altogether. Here, as elsewhere, mutual aid is a better leader to progress than the war of each against all, as may be seen from the following facts.

This movement for communal ownership clashes sharply with current economic theories, which claim that intensive farming doesn't work with village communities. However, the most generous thing you could say about these theories is that they've never been tested in real life; they fall into the realm of political philosophy. The evidence shows that wherever Russian peasants, due to a combination of favorable conditions, experience less misery than usual, and where they have knowledgeable and proactive neighbors, the village community actually becomes a way to introduce various improvements in farming and overall village life. Here, as in other situations, cooperation leads to progress better than the struggle of individuals against one another, as evidenced by the following facts.

Under Nicholas the First's rule many Crown officials and serf-owners used to compel the peasants to introduce the communal culture of small plots of the village lands, in order to refill the communal storehouses after loans of grain had been granted to the poorest commoners. Such cultures, connected in the peasants' minds with the worst reminiscences of serfdom, were abandoned as soon as serfdom was abolished but now the peasants begin to reintroduce them on their own account. In one district (Ostrogozhsk, in Kursk) the initiative of one person was sufficient to call them to life in four-fifths of all the villages. The same is met with in several other localities. On a given day the commoners come out, the richer ones with a plough or a cart and the poorer ones single-handed, and no attempt is made to discriminate one's share in the work. The crop is afterwards used for loans to the poorer commoners, mostly free grants, or for the orphans and widows, or for the village church, or for the school, or for repaying a communal debt.(40)

Under Nicholas I's rule, many Crown officials and landowners forced the peasants to cultivate small plots of village land to refill the communal storehouses after grain loans were given to the poorest members of the community. These types of cultivation, associated in the peasants' minds with the worst memories of serfdom, were abandoned once serfdom ended, but now the peasants are starting to reintroduce them on their own. In one area (Ostrogozhsk, in Kursk), the efforts of just one person were enough to revive these practices in four-fifths of all the villages. Similar situations are happening in several other areas. On a particular day, the commoners come out to work, with the wealthier ones bringing a plough or a cart, while the poorer ones work alone, and there’s no attempt to differentiate each person's contribution. The harvest is later used for loans to the poorer commoners, mostly as free grants, or for orphans and widows, or for the village church, or for the school, or to repay a communal debt.(40)

That all sorts of work which enters, so to say, in the routine of village life (repair of roads and bridges, dams, drainage, supply of water for irrigation, cutting of wood, planting of trees, etc.) are made by whole communes, and that land is rented and meadows are mown by whole communes—the work being accomplished by old and young, men and women, in the way described by Tolstoi—is only what one may expect from people living under the village-community system.(41) They are of everyday occurrence all over the country. But the village community is also by no means averse to modern agricultural improvements, when it can stand the expense, and when knowledge, hitherto kept for the rich only, finds its way into the peasant's house.

That all kinds of work that are part of village life (like repairing roads and bridges, building dams, drainage, providing water for irrigation, cutting wood, planting trees, etc.) is done by entire communities, and that land is rented and meadows are mowed by whole communities—the work being carried out by old and young, men and women, as described by Tolstoi—is exactly what you’d expect from people living in a village-community system. These activities are common throughout the country. However, the village community isn't against modern agricultural improvements, especially when they can afford it, and when knowledge that was previously only available to the wealthy becomes accessible to the peasants.

It has just been said that perfected ploughs rapidly spread in South Russia, and in many cases the village communities were instrumental in spreading their use. A plough was bought by the community, experimented upon on a portion of the communal land, and the necessary improvements were indicated to the makers, whom the communes often aided in starting the manufacture of cheap ploughs as a village industry. In the district of Moscow, where 1,560 ploughs were lately bought by the peasants during five years, the impulse came from those communes which rented lands as a body for the special purpose of improved culture.

It has just been mentioned that upgraded ploughs quickly became popular in South Russia, often thanks to the village communities promoting their use. A plough was purchased by the community, tested on part of the communal land, and any necessary improvements were suggested to the manufacturers, whom the communes frequently assisted in starting the production of affordable ploughs as a local industry. In the Moscow region, where 1,560 ploughs were recently purchased by the peasants over five years, the drive came from those communities that collectively rented land specifically to enhance agricultural practices.

In the north-east (Vyatka) small associations of peasants, who travel with their winnowing machines (manufactured as a village industry in one of the iron districts), have spread the use of such machines in the neighbouring governments. The very wide spread of threshing machines in Samara, Saratov, and Kherson is due to the peasant associations, which can afford to buy a costly engine, while the individual peasant cannot. And while we read in nearly all economical treatises that the village community was doomed to disappear when the three-fields system had to be substituted by the rotation of crops system, we see in Russia many village communities taking the initiative of introducing the rotation of crops. Before accepting it the peasants usually set apart a portion of the communal fields for an experiment in artificial meadows, and the commune buys the seeds.(42) If the experiment proves successful they find no difficulty whatever in re-dividing their fields, so as to suit the five or six fields system.

In the northeast (Vyatka), small groups of farmers who travel with their winnowing machines (produced as a local industry in one of the iron regions) have promoted the use of such machines in the neighboring regions. The widespread use of threshing machines in Samara, Saratov, and Kherson can be attributed to these farmers' associations, which can afford to invest in expensive equipment, unlike individual farmers. While many economic writings claim that the village community was bound to decline when the three-field system was replaced by crop rotation, we see that in Russia, many village communities are taking the lead in adopting crop rotation. Before they agree to it, the farmers typically set aside part of the communal fields to experiment with artificial meadows, and the community purchases the seeds. If the experiment is successful, they easily re-allocate their fields to fit the five or six-field system.

This system is now in use in hundreds of villages of Moscow, Tver, Smolensk, Vyatka, and Pskov.(43) And where land can be spared the communities give also a portion of their domain to allotments for fruit-growing. Finally, the sudden extension lately taken in Russia by the little model farms, orchards, kitchen gardens, and silkworm-culture grounds—which are started at the village school-houses, under the conduct of the school-master, or of a village volunteer—is also due to the support they found with the village communities.

This system is now being used in hundreds of villages in Moscow, Tver, Smolensk, Vyatka, and Pskov.(43) Wherever land is available, communities also dedicate some of their land for fruit-growing plots. Finally, the recent rapid growth of small model farms, orchards, kitchen gardens, and silkworm cultivation areas—initiated at village schools under the guidance of the schoolmaster or a village volunteer—can also be attributed to the backing they received from the village communities.

Moreover, such permanent improvements as drainage and irrigation are of frequent occurrence. For instance, in three districts of the province of Moscow—industrial to a great extent—drainage works have been accomplished within the last ten years on a large scale in no less than 180 to 200 different villages—the commoners working themselves with the spade. At another extremity of Russia, in the dry Steppes of Novouzen, over a thousand dams for ponds were built and several hundreds of deep wells were sunk by the communes; while in a wealthy German colony of the south-east the commoners worked, men and women alike, for five weeks in succession, to erect a dam, two miles long, for irrigation purposes. What could isolated men do in that struggle against the dry climate? What could they obtain through individual effort when South Russia was struck with the marmot plague, and all people living on the land, rich and poor, commoners and individualists, had to work with their hands in order to conjure the plague? To call in the policeman would have been of no use; to associate was the only possible remedy.

Moreover, permanent improvements like drainage and irrigation happen quite often. For example, in three districts of the Moscow region—mostly industrial—drainage projects have been carried out over the last ten years on a large scale in at least 180 to 200 different villages, with locals working with shovels. At the other end of Russia, in the dry Steppes of Novouzen, over a thousand ponds were created and several hundred deep wells were dug by the communities; meanwhile, in a prosperous German colony in the southeast, both men and women worked together for five consecutive weeks to build a two-mile-long dam for irrigation. What could isolated individuals do in that struggle against the dry climate? What could they achieve through individual effort when South Russia faced a marmot plague, forcing everyone who lived on the land—rich and poor, commoners and individualists alike—to work together to overcome the crisis? Calling in the police wouldn't have helped; collaboration was the only effective solution.

And now, after having said so much about mutual aid and support which are practised by the tillers of the soil in "civilized" countries, I see that I might fill an octavo volume with illustrations taken from the life of the hundreds of millions of men who also live under the tutorship of more or less centralized States, but are out of touch with modern civilization and modern ideas. I might describe the inner life of a Turkish village and its network of admirable mutual-aid customs and habits. On turning over my leaflets covered with illustrations from peasant life in Caucasia, I come across touching facts of mutual support. I trace the same customs in the Arab djemmaa and the Afghan purra, in the villages of Persia, India, and Java, in the undivided family of the Chinese, in the encampments of the semi-nomads of Central Asia and the nomads of the far North. On consulting notes taken at random in the literature of Africa, I find them replete with similar facts—of aids convoked to take in the crops, of houses built by all inhabitants of the village—sometimes to repair the havoc done by civilized filibusters—of people aiding each other in case of accident, protecting the traveller, and so on. And when I peruse such works as Post's compendium of African customary law I understand why, notwithstanding all tyranny, oppression, robberies and raids, tribal wars, glutton kings, deceiving witches and priests, slave-hunters, and the like, these populations have not gone astray in the woods; why they have maintained a certain civilization, and have remained men, instead of dropping to the level of straggling families of decaying orang-outans. The fact is, that the slave-hunters, the ivory robbers, the fighting kings, the Matabele and the Madagascar "heroes" pass away, leaving their traces marked with blood and fire; but the nucleus of mutual-aid institutions, habits, and customs, grown up in the tribe and the village community, remains; and it keeps men united in societies, open to the progress of civilization, and ready to receive it when the day comes that they shall receive civilization instead of bullets.

And now, after discussing so much about mutual aid and support practiced by farmers in "civilized" countries, I realize that I could easily fill an entire book with examples from the lives of the hundreds of millions of people who also live under centralized states but are disconnected from modern civilization and ideas. I could describe the inner workings of a Turkish village and its impressive network of mutual aid customs and practices. As I flip through my notes filled with illustrations of peasant life in Caucasia, I come across heartwarming stories of mutual support. I see the same customs in the Arab djemmaa and the Afghan purra, in villages across Persia, India, and Java, in the extended families of China, and in the camps of the semi-nomads of Central Asia and the nomads of the far North. When I check notes I've taken from various African literature, I find a wealth of similar stories—of collective efforts to bring in crops, of houses built by all villagers—sometimes to fix the damage caused by civilized raiders—of people helping one another in times of accidents, protecting travelers, and so on. And as I read works like Post's compendium of African customary law, I understand why, despite all the tyranny, oppression, theft, raids, tribal wars, selfish kings, deceitful witches and priests, slave hunters, and the like, these communities have not lost their way; why they have preserved a certain level of civilization and remained human, instead of sinking to the state of wandering families of decaying orangutans. The truth is, that slave hunters, ivory thieves, warring kings, the Matabele, and the Madagascar "heroes" may fade away, leaving behind their bloody and fiery legacies; but the core of mutual aid institutions, habits, and customs that have developed within tribes and village communities endures; it keeps people united in societies, open to the progress of civilization, and ready to embrace it when the time comes for them to receive civilization instead of bullets.

The same applies to our civilized world. The natural and social calamities pass away. Whole populations are periodically reduced to misery or starvation; the very springs of life are crushed out of millions of men, reduced to city pauperism; the understanding and the feelings of the millions are vitiated by teachings worked out in the interest of the few. All this is certainly a part of our existence. But the nucleus of mutual-support institutions, habits, and customs remains alive with the millions; it keeps them together; and they prefer to cling to their customs, beliefs, and traditions rather than to accept the teachings of a war of each against all, which are offered to them under the title of science, but are no science at all.

The same goes for our modern world. Natural and social disasters come and go. Entire populations are regularly pushed into poverty or starvation; the very essence of life is destroyed for millions, who are left in urban destitution; the understanding and emotions of the masses are distorted by lessons crafted solely for the benefit of a few. All of this is definitely a part of our reality. But the core of mutual-support systems, habits, and traditions remains strong among the millions; it unites them; and they choose to hold on to their customs, beliefs, and traditions instead of accepting the ideas of a dog-eat-dog mentality, which are presented to them as science, but aren't science at all.

NOTES:

1. A bulky literature, dealing with this formerly much neglected subject, is now growing in Germany. Keller's works, Ein Apostel der Wiedertaufer and Geschichte der Wiedertaufer, Cornelius's Geschichte des munsterischen Aufruhrs, and Janssen's Geschichte des deutschen Volkes may be named as the leading sources. The first attempt at familiarizing English readers with the results of the wide researches made in Germany in this direction has been made in an excellent little work by Richard Heath—"Anabaptism from its Rise at Zwickau to its Fall at Munster, 1521-1536," London, 1895 (Baptist Manuals, vol. i.)—where the leading features of the movement are well indicated, and full bibliographical information is given. Also K. Kautsky's Communism in Central Europe in the Time of the Reformation, London, 1897.

1. A substantial amount of literature about this previously ignored subject is now emerging in Germany. Works by Keller, such as *Ein Apostel der Wiedertaufer* and *Geschichte der Wiedertaufer*, Cornelius's *Geschichte des münsterischen Aufruhrs*, and Janssen's *Geschichte des deutschen Volkes* can be considered the main sources. The first effort to introduce English readers to the findings of extensive research conducted in Germany on this topic was made in an excellent short book by Richard Heath—*Anabaptism from its Rise at Zwickau to its Fall at Munster, 1521-1536,* London, 1895 (Baptist Manuals, vol. i.)—where the key aspects of the movement are clearly outlined, along with comprehensive bibliographical details. Additionally, K. Kautsky's *Communism in Central Europe in the Time of the Reformation*, London, 1897.

2. Few of our contemporaries realize both the extent of this movement and the means by which it was suppressed. But those who wrote immediately after the great peasant war estimated at from 100,000 to 150,000 men the number of peasants slaughtered after their defeat in Germany. See Zimmermann's Allgemeine Geschichte des grossen Bauernkrieges. For the measures taken to suppress the movement in the Netherlands see Richard Heath's Anabaptism.

2. Few people today understand how widespread this movement was and how it was put down. However, those who wrote right after the major peasant war estimated that between 100,000 and 150,000 peasants were killed after their defeat in Germany. See Zimmermann's Allgemeine Geschichte des grossen Bauernkrieges. For the actions taken to crush the movement in the Netherlands, see Richard Heath's Anabaptism.

3. "Chacun s'en est accommode selon sa bienseance … on les a partages.. pour depouiller les communes, on s'est servi de dettes simulees" (Edict of Louis the Fourteenth, of 1667, quoted by several authors. Eight years before that date the communes had been taken under State management).

3. "Everyone has adapted to it according to their sense of propriety... they have been divided... to strip the communities, fake debts were used" (Edict of Louis the Fourteenth, of 1667, quoted by several authors. Eight years before that date, the communities had come under State control).

4. "On a great landlord's estate, even if he has millions of revenue, you are sure to find the land uncultivated" (Arthur Young). "One-fourth part of the soil went out of culture;" "for the last hundred years the land has returned to a savage state;" "the formerly flourishing Sologne is now a big marsh;" and so on (Theron de Montauge, quoted by Taine in Origines de la France Contemporaine, tome i. p. 441).

4. "On a wealthy landlord's estate, even if he has millions in income, you will definitely find the land uncultivated" (Arthur Young). "One-fourth of the land is out of cultivation;" "for the past hundred years, the land has gone back to a wild state;" "the once-thriving Sologne is now a large marsh;" and so on (Theron de Montauge, quoted by Taine in Origines de la France Contemporaine, tome i. p. 441).

5. A. Babeau, Le Village sous l'Ancien Regime, 3e edition. Paris, 1892.

5. A. Babeau, The Village in the Old Regime, 3rd edition. Paris, 1892.

6. In Eastern France the law only confirmed what the peasants had already done themselves. See my work, The Great French Revolution, chaps. xlvii and xlviii, London (Heinemann), 1909.

6. In Eastern France, the law just recognized what the peasants had already accomplished on their own. See my work, The Great French Revolution, chaps. xlvii and xlviii, London (Heinemann), 1909.

7. After the triumph of the middle-class reaction the communal lands were declared (August 24, 1794) the States domains, and, together with the lands confiscated from the nobility, were put up for sale, and pilfered by the bandes noires of the small bourgeoisie. True that a stop to this pilfering was put next year (law of 2 Prairial, An V), and the preceding law was abrogated; but then the village Communities were simply abolished, and cantonal councils were introduced instead. Only seven years later (9 Prairial, An XII), i.e. in 1801, the village communities were reintroduced, but not until after having been deprived of all their rights, the mayor and syndics being nominated by the Government in the 36,000 communes of France! This system was maintained till after the revolution of 1830, when elected communal councils were reintroduced under the law of 1787. As to the communal lands, they were again seized upon by the State in 1813, plundered as such, and only partly restored to the communes in 1816. See the classical collection of French laws, by Dalloz, Repertoire de Jurisprudence; also the works of Doniol, Dareste, Bonnemere, Babeau, and many others.

7. After the victory of the middle class, the communal lands were declared the States' domains on August 24, 1794, and along with the lands taken from the nobility, they were put up for sale and looted by the small bourgeoisie's bandes noires. True, this looting was stopped the following year (law of 2 Prairial, Year V), and the previous law was repealed; however, the village communities were simply abolished, and cantonal councils were set up instead. It wasn't until seven years later (9 Prairial, Year XII), in 1801, that the village communities were reestablished, but by then they had been stripped of all their rights, with the mayor and syndics being appointed by the Government in the 36,000 communes of France! This system continued until after the revolution of 1830 when elected communal councils were reinstated under the law of 1787. As for the communal lands, they were once again seized by the State in 1813, looted as such, and only partially returned to the communes in 1816. See the classical collection of French laws by Dalloz, Repertoire de Jurisprudence; also, the works of Doniol, Dareste, Bonnemere, Babeau, and many others.

8. This procedure is so absurd that one would not believe it possible if the fifty-two different acts were not enumerated in full by a quite authoritative writer in the Journal des Economistes (1893, April, p. 94), and several similar examples were not given by the same author.

8. This procedure is so ridiculous that you wouldn’t believe it's real if the fifty-two different acts weren’t listed in detail by a very credible writer in the Journal des Economistes (1893, April, p. 94), and if the same author didn't provide several similar examples.

9. Dr. Ochenkowski, Englands wirthschaftliche Entwickelung im Ausgange des Mittelalters (Jena, 1879), pp. 35 seq., where the whole question is discussed with full knowledge of the texts.

9. Dr. Ochenkowski, England's economic development at the end of the Middle Ages (Jena, 1879), pp. 35 seq., where the entire issue is discussed with a thorough understanding of the texts.

10. Nasse, Ueber die mittelalterliche Feldgemeinschaft und die Einhegungen des XVI. Jahrhunderts in England (Bonn, 1869), pp. 4, 5; Vinogradov, Villainage in England (Oxford, 1892).

10. Nasse, On the Medieval Field Community and the Enclosures of the 16th Century in England (Bonn, 1869), pp. 4, 5; Vinogradov, Villainage in England (Oxford, 1892).

11. Fr. Seebohm, The English Village Community, 3rd ed., 1884, pp. 13-15.

11. Fr. Seebohm, The English Village Community, 3rd ed., 1884, pp. 13-15.

12. "An examination into the details of an Enclosure Act will make clear the point that the system as above described [communal ownership] is the system which it was the object of the Enclosure Act to remove" (Seebohm, l.c. p. 13). And further on, "They were generally drawn in the same form, commencing with the recital that the open and common fields lie dispersed in small pieces, intermixed with each other and inconveniently situated; that divers persons own parts of them, and are entitled to rights of common on them … and that it is desired that they may be divided and enclosed, a specific share being let out and allowed to each owner" (p. 14). Porter's list contained 3867 such Acts, of which the greatest numbers fall upon the decades of 1770-1780 and 1800-1820, as in France.

12. "Looking closely at the details of an Enclosure Act reveals that the system described above [communal ownership] was the very system the Enclosure Act aimed to eliminate" (Seebohm, l.c. p. 13). Furthermore, "They were typically drafted in the same way, starting with the statement that the open and common fields are scattered in small pieces, mixed together and poorly located; that various individuals own parts of them and have rights to common land on them … and that there is a desire to divide and enclose them, with a specific share given to each owner" (p. 14). Porter's list included 3,867 such Acts, with the majority occurring during the decades of 1770-1780 and 1800-1820, similar to France.

13. In Switzerland we see a number of communes, ruined by wars, which have sold part of their lands, and now endeavour to buy them back.

13. In Switzerland, we see several communities that were devastated by wars and have sold parts of their land, and now they are trying to buy it back.

14. A. Buchenberger, "Agrarwesen und Agrarpolitik," in A. Wagner's Handbuch der politischen Oekonomie, 1892, Band i. pp. 280 seq.

14. A. Buchenberger, "Agriculture and Agricultural Policy," in A. Wagner's Handbook of Political Economy, 1892, Volume I, pp. 280 and following.

15. G.L. Gomme, "The Village Community, with special reference to its
Origin and Forms of Survival in Great Britain" (Contemporary Science
Series), London, 1890, pp. 141-143; also his Primitive Folkmoots
(London, 1880), pp. 98 seq.

15. G.L. Gomme, "The Village Community, with special attention to its
Origin and Forms of Survival in Great Britain" (Contemporary Science
Series), London, 1890, pp. 141-143; also his Primitive Folkmoots
(London, 1880), pp. 98 seq.

16. "In almost all parts of the country, in the Midland and Eastern counties particularly, but also in the west—in Wiltshire, for example—in the south, as in Surrey, in the north, as in Yorkshire,—there are extensive open and common fields. Out of 316 parishes of Northamptonshire 89 are in this condition; more than 100 in Oxfordshire; about 50,000 acres in Warwickshire; in Berkshire half the county; more than half of Wiltshire; in Huntingdonshire out of a total area of 240,000 acres 130,000 were commonable meadows, commons, and fields" (Marshall, quoted in Sir Henry Maine's Village Communities in the East and West, New York edition, 1876, pp. 88, 89). See also Dr. G. Slater's The English Peasantry and the Enclosure of Common Fields, London, 1907.

16. "In nearly all areas of the country, especially in the Midland and Eastern counties, but also in the west—in places like Wiltshire—in the south, such as Surrey, and in the north, like Yorkshire, there are large open and common fields. Out of 316 parishes in Northamptonshire, 89 are in this situation; more than 100 in Oxfordshire; around 50,000 acres in Warwickshire; in Berkshire, half the county; more than half of Wiltshire; in Huntingdonshire, out of a total area of 240,000 acres, 130,000 were commonable meadows, commons, and fields" (Marshall, quoted in Sir Henry Maine's Village Communities in the East and West, New York edition, 1876, pp. 88, 89). See also Dr. G. Slater's The English Peasantry and the Enclosure of Common Fields, London, 1907.

17. Ibid. p. 88; also Fifth Lecture.

17. Ibid. p. 88; also Fifth Lecture.

18. In quite a number of books dealing with English country life which I have consulted I have found charming descriptions of country scenery and the like, but almost nothing about the daily life and customs of the labourers.

18. In many books about English country life that I've looked at, I've found beautiful descriptions of the countryside and similar things, but almost nothing about the daily lives and customs of the laborers.

19. In Switzerland the peasants in the open land also fell under the dominion of lords, and large parts of their estates were appropriated by the lords in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. (cf. A. Miaskowski, in Schmoller's Forschungen, Bd. ii. 1879, pp. 12 seq.) But the peasant war in Switzerland did not end in such a crushing defeat of the peasants as it did in other countries, and a great deal of the communal rights and lands was retained. The self-government of the communes is, in fact, the very foundation of the Swiss liberties. (cf. K. Burtli, Der Ursprung der Eidgenossenschaft aus der Markgenossenschaft, Zurich, 1891.)

19. In Switzerland, the peasants in the open land were also under the control of lords, and during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, a significant portion of their estates was taken by these lords. (cf. A. Miaskowski, in Schmoller's Forschungen, Bd. ii. 1879, pp. 12 seq.) However, the peasant war in Switzerland didn’t result in such a devastating defeat for the peasants as it did in other countries, and they managed to keep a lot of their communal rights and lands. In fact, the self-governance of the communes is the very foundation of Swiss freedoms. (cf. K. Burtli, Der Ursprung der Eidgenossenschaft aus der Markgenossenschaft, Zurich, 1891.)

20. Dr. Reichesberg, Handworterbuch des Schweiz. Volkswirthschaft, Bern, 1903.

20. Dr. Reichesberg, Dictionary of Swiss Economics, Bern, 1903.

21. See on this subject a series of works, summed up in one of the excellent and suggestive chapters (not yet translated into English) which K. Bucher has added to the German translation of Laveleye's Primitive Ownership. Also Meitzen, "Das Agrar-und Forst-Wesen, die Allmenden und die Landgemeinden der Deutschen Schweiz," in Jahrbuch für Staatswissenschaft, 1880, iv. (analysis of Miaskowsky's works); O'Brien, "Notes in a Swiss village," in Macmillan's Magazine, October 1885.

21. For more on this topic, refer to a series of works summarized in one of the excellent and insightful chapters (not yet translated into English) that K. Bucher contributed to the German version of Laveleye's Primitive Ownership. Also, check out Meitzen's "Das Agrar-und Forst-Wesen, die Allmenden und die Landgemeinden der Deutschen Schweiz," in Jahrbuch für Staatswissenschaft, 1880, iv. (analysis of Miaskowsky's works); O'Brien's "Notes in a Swiss village," in Macmillan's Magazine, October 1885.

22. The wedding gifts, which often substantially contribute in this country to the comfort of the young households, are evidently a remainder of the communal habits.

22. The wedding gifts, which often provide significant support to the comfort of young households in this country, clearly reflect a leftover of communal traditions.

23. The communes own, 4,554,100 acres of woods out of 24,813,000 in the whole territory, and 6,936,300 acres of natural meadows out of 11,394,000 acres in France. The remaining 2,000,000 acres are fields, orchards, and so on.

23. The communities own 4,554,100 acres of forest out of 24,813,000 total acres in the entire territory, and 6,936,300 acres of natural meadows out of 11,394,000 acres in France. The remaining 2,000,000 acres consist of fields, orchards, and other areas.

24. In Caucasia they even do better among the Georgians. As the meal costs, and a poor man cannot afford to give it, a sheep is bought by those same neighbours who come to aid in the work.

24. In Caucasia, they even manage better with the Georgians. Since the meal costs a lot and a poor man cannot afford to provide it, a sheep is purchased by those same neighbors who come to help with the work.

25. Alfred Baudrillart, in H. Baudrillart's Les Populations Rurales de la France, 3rd series (Paris, 1893), p. 479.

25. Alfred Baudrillart, in H. Baudrillart's Les Populations Rurales de la France, 3rd series (Paris, 1893), p. 479.

26. The Journal des Economistes (August 1892, May and August 1893) has lately given some of the results of analyses made at the agricultural laboratories at Ghent and at Paris. The extent of falsification is simply incredible; so also the devices of the "honest traders." In certain seeds of grass there was 32 per cent. of gains of sand, coloured so as to Receive even an experienced eye; other samples contained from 52 to 22 per cent. only of pure seed, the remainder being weeds. Seeds of vetch contained 11 per cent. of a poisonous grass (nielle); a flour for cattle-fattening contained 36 per cent. of sulphates; and so on ad infinitum.

26. The Journal des Economistes (August 1892, May and August 1893) recently published some results from analyses conducted at the agricultural laboratories in Ghent and Paris. The level of falsification is truly shocking; the tactics of the "honest traders" are equally alarming. In some grass seed samples, there was 32 percent sand, dyed to deceive even the trained eye; other samples had only 22 to 52 percent pure seed, with the rest being weeds. Vetch seeds contained 11 percent of a poisonous grass (nielle); a cattle-fattening flour had 36 percent sulfates; and the list goes on endlessly.

27. A. Baudrillart, l.c. p. 309. Originally one grower would undertake to supply water, and several others would agee to make use of it. "What especially characterises such associations," A. Baudrillart remarks, "is that no sort of written agreement is concluded. All is arranged in words. There was, however, not one single case of difficulties having arisen between the parties."

27. A. Baudrillart, l.c. p. 309. Initially, one grower would take on the responsibility of providing water, and several others would agree to use it. "What particularly stands out about these associations," A. Baudrillart notes, "is that there is no written contract. Everything is arranged verbally. However, there was not a single instance of any disputes arising between the parties."

28. A. Baudrillart, l.c. pp. 300, 341, etc. M. Terssac, president of the St. Gironnais syndicate (Ariege), wrote to my friend in substance as follows:—"For the exhibition of Toulouse our association has grouped the owners of cattle which seemed to us worth exhibiting. The society undertook to pay one-half of the travelling and exhibition expenses; one-fourth was paid by each owner, and the remaining fourth by those exhibitors who had got prizes. The result was that many took part in the exhibition who never would have done it otherwise. Those who got the highest awards (350 francs) have contributed 10 per cent. of their prizes, while those who have got no prize have only spent 6 to 7 francs each."

28. A. Baudrillart, l.c. pp. 300, 341, etc. M. Terssac, the president of the St. Gironnais syndicate (Ariege), wrote to my friend, essentially saying:—"For the Toulouse exhibition, our association gathered the cattle owners whose animals we thought were worth showcasing. The organization covered half of the travel and exhibition costs; each owner contributed one-fourth, and the final fourth was covered by those exhibitors who won prizes. As a result, many participated in the exhibition who otherwise wouldn’t have. Those who received the top awards (350 francs) donated 10 percent of their prizes, while those who didn’t win anything only spent 6 to 7 francs each."

29. In Wurttemberg 1,629 communes out of 1,910 have communal property. They owned in 1863 over 1,000,000 acres of land. In Baden 1,256 communes out of 1,582 have communal land; in 1884-1888 they held 121,500 acres of fields in communal culture, and 675,000 acres of forests, i.e. 46 per cent. of the total area under woods. In Saxony 39 per cent. of the total area is in communal ownership (Schmoller's Jahrbuch, 1886, p. 359). In Hohenzollern nearly two-thirds of all meadow land, and in Hohenzollern-Hechingen 41 per cent. of all landed property, are owned by the village communities (Buchenberger, Agrarwesen, vol. i. p. 300).

29. In Wurttemberg, 1,629 out of 1,910 communes have communal property. They owned over 1,000,000 acres of land in 1863. In Baden, 1,256 out of 1,582 communes have communal land; between 1884 and 1888, they managed 121,500 acres of fields in communal cultivation and 675,000 acres of forests, which is 46 percent of the total forest area. In Saxony, 39 percent of the total area is in communal ownership (Schmoller's Jahrbuch, 1886, p. 359). In Hohenzollern, nearly two-thirds of all meadow land, and in Hohenzollern-Hechingen, 41 percent of all property is owned by the village communities (Buchenberger, Agrarwesen, vol. i. p. 300).

30. See K. Bucher, who, in a special chapter added to Laveleye's Ureigenthum, has collected all information relative to the village community in Germany.

30. See K. Bucher, who, in a special chapter added to Laveleye's Ureigenthum, has gathered all information related to the village community in Germany.

31. K. Bucher, ibid. pp. 89, 90.

31. K. Bucher, same source, pp. 89, 90.

32. For this legislation and the numerous obstacles which were put in the way, in the shape of red-tapeism and supervision, see Buchenberger's Agrarwesen und Agrarpolitik, Bd. ii. pp. 342-363, and p. 506, note.

32. For this legislation and the many obstacles that were created, in the form of bureaucracy and oversight, see Buchenberger's Agrarwesen und Agrarpolitik, Vol. II, pp. 342-363, and p. 506, note.

33. Buchenberger, l.c. Bd. ii. p. 510. The General Union of Agricultural Co-operation comprises an aggregate of 1,679 societies. In Silesia an aggregate of 32,000 acres of land has been lately drained by 73 associations; 454,800 acres in Prussia by 516 associations; in Bavaria there are 1,715 drainage and irrigation unions.

33. Buchenberger, l.c. Bd. ii. p. 510. The General Union of Agricultural Cooperation includes a total of 1,679 societies. Recently, 73 associations have drained an area of 32,000 acres of land in Silesia; 516 associations have drained 454,800 acres in Prussia; and in Bavaria, there are 1,715 drainage and irrigation unions.

34. For the Balkan peninsula see Laveleye's Propriete Primitive.

34. For the Balkan Peninsula, see Laveleye's Primitive Property.

35. The facts concerning the village community, contained in nearly a hundred volumes (out of 450) of these inquests, have been classified and summed up in an excellent Russian work by "V.V." The Peasant Community (Krestianskaya Obschina), St. Petersburg, 1892, which, apart from its theoretical value, is a rich compendium of data relative to this subject. The above inquests have also given origin to an immense literature, in which the modern village-community question for the first time emerges from the domain of generalities and is put on the solid basis of reliable and sufficiently detailed facts.

35. The information about the village community, found in nearly a hundred volumes (out of 450) of these inquests, has been organized and summarized in an excellent Russian work by "V.V." The Peasant Community (Krestianskaya Obschina), St. Petersburg, 1892, which, besides its theoretical importance, is a valuable collection of data on this topic. These inquests have also led to a vast amount of literature, in which the modern village-community issue emerges for the first time from broad generalizations and is established on a solid foundation of trustworthy and adequately detailed facts.

36. The redemption had to be paid by annuities for forty-nine years. As years went, and the greatest part of it was paid, it became easier and easier to redeem the smaller remaining part of it, and, as each allotment could be redeemed individually, advantage was taken of this disposition by traders, who bought land for half its value from the ruined peasants. A law was consequently passed to put a stop to such sales.

36. The redemption had to be paid through annuities for forty-nine years. As time went on and most of it was paid off, it became easier and easier to redeem the smaller remaining part, and since each portion could be redeemed individually, traders took advantage of this by buying land for half its value from the struggling peasants. A law was therefore passed to stop such sales.

37. Mr. V.V., in his Peasant Community, has grouped together all facts relative to this movement. About the rapid agricultural development of South Russia and the spread of machinery English readers will find information in the Consular Reports (Odessa, Taganrog).

37. Mr. V.V., in his Peasant Community, has compiled all the facts related to this movement. English readers can find information about the rapid agricultural development in South Russia and the use of machinery in the Consular Reports (Odessa, Taganrog).

38. In some instances they proceeded with great caution. In one village they began by putting together all meadow land, but only a small portion of the fields (about five acres per soul) was rendered communal; the remainder continued to be owned individually. Later on, in 1862-1864, the system was extended, but only in 1884 was communal possession introduced in full.—V.V.'s Peasant Community, pp. 1-14.

38. In some cases, they moved very carefully. In one village, they started by combining all the meadow land, but only a small part of the fields (about five acres per person) was made communal; the rest remained privately owned. Later, from 1862 to 1864, the system expanded, but it wasn't until 1884 that communal ownership was fully implemented.—V.V.'s Peasant Community, pp. 1-14.

39. On the Mennonite village community see A. Klaus, Our Colonies (Nashi Kolonii), St. Petersburg, 1869.

39. For information on the Mennonite village community, see A. Klaus, Our Colonies (Nashi Kolonii), St. Petersburg, 1869.

40. Such communal cultures are known to exist in 159 villages out of 195 in the Ostrogozhsk district; in 150 out of 187 in Slavyanoserbsk; in 107 village communities in Alexandrovsk, 93 in Nikolayevsk, 35 in Elisabethgrad. In a German colony the communal culture is made for repaying a communal debt. All join in the work, although the debt was contracted by 94 householders out of 155.

40. Such community cultures are known to exist in 159 out of 195 villages in the Ostrogozhsk district; in 150 out of 187 in Slavyanoserbsk; in 107 village communities in Alexandrovsk, 93 in Nikolayevsk, and 35 in Elisabethgrad. In a German colony, the community culture is set up to repay a communal debt. Everyone participates in the work, even though the debt was incurred by 94 households out of 155.

41. Lists of such works which came under the notice of the zemstvo statisticians will be found in V.V.'s Peasant Community, pp. 459-600.

41. You can find lists of these works that were noticed by the zemstvo statisticians in V.V.'s Peasant Community, pp. 459-600.

42. In the government of Moscow the experiment was usually made on the field which was reserved for the above-mentioned communal culture.

42. In the Moscow government, the experiment was typically conducted on the area set aside for the communal farming mentioned earlier.

43. Several instances of such and similar improvements were given in the Official Messenger, 1894, Nos. 256-258. Associations between "horseless" peasants begin to appear also in South Russia. Another extremely interesting fact is the sudden development in Southern West Siberia of very numerous co-operative creameries for making butter. Hundreds of them spread in Tobolsk and Tomsk, without any one knowing wherefrom the initiative of the movement came. It came from the Danish co-operators, who used to export their own butter of higher quality, and to buy butter of a lower quality for their own use in Siberia. After a several years' intercourse, they introduced creameries there. Now, a great export trade, carried on by a Union of the Creameries, has grown out of their endeavours and more than a thousand co-operative shops have been opened in the villages.

43. Several examples of similar improvements were reported in the Official Messenger, 1894, Nos. 256-258. Groups of "horseless" peasants are starting to appear in South Russia. Another really interesting development is the sudden rise of many co-operative creameries for butter production in Southern West Siberia. Hundreds of these creameries have spread in Tobolsk and Tomsk, with no one knowing where the idea for the movement originated. It came from Danish co-operators, who used to export their own higher quality butter and buy lower quality butter for personal use in Siberia. After several years of interaction, they introduced creameries there. Now, a large export trade, managed by a Union of the Creameries, has emerged from their efforts, and over a thousand co-operative shops have opened in the villages.

CHAPTER VIII

MUTUAL AID AMONGST OURSELVES (continued)

MUTUAL AID AMONG US (continued)

Labour-unions grown after the destruction of the guilds by the State. Their struggles. Mutual Aid in strikes. Co-operation. Free associations for various purposes. Self-sacrifice. Countless societies for combined action under all possible aspects. Mutual Aid in slum-life. Personal aid.

Labour unions grew after the State's destruction of the guilds. Their struggles, mutual aid during strikes, cooperation, and free associations for various purposes reflect the spirit of self-sacrifice. There are countless societies for collective action in every possible way, providing mutual aid in slum life and personal assistance.

When we examine the every-day life of the rural populations of Europe, we find that, notwithstanding all that has been done in modern States for the destruction of the village community, the life of the peasants remains honeycombed with habits and customs of mutual aid and support; that important vestiges of the communal possession of the soil are still retained; and that, as soon as the legal obstacles to rural association were lately removed, a network of free unions for all sorts of economical purposes rapidly spread among the peasants—the tendency of this young movement being to reconstitute some sort of union similar to the village community of old. Such being the conclusions arrived at in the preceding chapter, we have now to consider, what institutions for mutual support can be found at the present time amongst the industrial populations.

When we look at the everyday life of rural communities in Europe, we see that, despite everything that's been done in modern states to break down village life, the way peasants live is still deeply rooted in habits and customs of helping each other. Important remnants of shared land ownership still exist, and once the legal barriers to rural cooperation were lifted recently, a network of free unions for various economic purposes quickly emerged among the peasants—this new movement aims to recreate some form of union similar to the old village community. With this conclusion from the previous chapter in mind, we now need to examine what mutual support systems currently exist among industrial populations.

For the last three hundred years, the conditions for the growth of such institutions have been as unfavourable in the towns as they have been in the villages. It is well known, indeed, that when the medieval cities were subdued in the sixteenth century by growing military States, all institutions which kept the artisans, the masters, and the merchants together in the guilds and the cities were violently destroyed. The self-government and the self-jurisdiction of both, the guild and the city were abolished; the oath of allegiance between guild-brothers became an act of felony towards the State; the properties of the guilds were confiscated in the same way as the lands of the village communities; and the inner and technical organization of each trade was taken in hand by the State. Laws, gradually growing in severity, were passed to prevent artisans from combining in any way. For a time, some shadows of the old guilds were tolerated: merchants' guilds were allowed to exist under the condition of freely granting subsidies to the kings, and some artisan guilds were kept in existence as organs of administration. Some of them still drag on their meaningless existence. But what formerly was the vital force of medieval life and industry has long since disappeared under the crushing weight of the centralized State.

For the past three hundred years, the conditions for the growth of such institutions have been just as unfavorable in towns as they have been in villages. It's well known that when the medieval cities were conquered in the sixteenth century by rising military states, all institutions that brought together artisans, masters, and merchants in guilds and cities were violently dismantled. The self-governance and self-jurisdiction of both the guild and the city were eliminated; the oath of loyalty among guild members became a betrayal against the State; the properties of the guilds were seized just like the lands of village communities; and the internal and technical organization of each trade was taken over by the State. Laws, gradually becoming harsher, were enacted to stop artisans from joining together in any way. For a while, some remnants of the old guilds were tolerated: merchants' guilds were allowed to exist on the condition that they freely provided subsidies to the kings, and some artisan guilds were retained as administrative bodies. Some of them still linger in their pointless existence. But what used to be the driving force of medieval life and industry has long vanished under the heavy burden of the centralized State.

In Great Britain, which may be taken as the best illustration of the industrial policy of the modern States, we see the Parliament beginning the destruction of the guilds as early as the fifteenth century; but it was especially in the next century that decisive measures were taken. Henry the Eighth not only ruined the organization of the guilds, but also confiscated their properties, with even less excuse and manners, as Toulmin Smith wrote, than he had produced for confiscating the estates of the monasteries.(1) Edward the Sixth completed his work,(2) and already in the second part of the sixteenth century we find the Parliament settling all the disputes between craftsmen and merchants, which formerly were settled in each city separately. The Parliament and the king not only legislated in all such contests, but, keeping in view the interests of the Crown in the exports, they soon began to determine the number of apprentices in each trade and minutely to regulate the very technics of each fabrication—the weights of the stuffs, the number of threads in the yard of cloth, and the like. With little success, it must be said; because contests and technical difficulties which were arranged for centuries in succession by agreement between closely-interdependent guilds and federated cities lay entirely beyond the powers of the centralized State. The continual interference of its officials paralyzed the trades; bringing most of them to a complete decay; and the last century economists, when they rose against the State regulation of industries, only ventilated a widely-felt discontent. The abolition of that interference by the French Revolution was greeted as an act of liberation, and the example of France was soon followed elsewhere.

In Great Britain, which serves as the best example of the industrial policy of modern states, we see Parliament starting to dismantle the guilds as early as the fifteenth century; however, it was particularly in the next century that significant actions were taken. Henry the Eighth not only destroyed the organization of the guilds but also seized their properties with even less justification and decorum, as Toulmin Smith noted, than he had for confiscating the estates of the monasteries.(1) Edward the Sixth finished the job,(2) and by the second half of the sixteenth century, we find Parliament resolving all disputes between craftsmen and merchants, which used to be settled in each city separately. The Parliament and the king not only made decisions in these disputes, but also, considering the interests of the Crown in exports, they began to regulate the number of apprentices in each trade and precisely oversee the technical details of manufacturing—the weights of materials, the number of threads in a yard of cloth, and similar aspects. With little success, it must be noted; because the disputes and technical issues that had been resolved for centuries by agreements among interdependent guilds and federated cities were entirely beyond the capabilities of the centralized state. The constant interference from its officials crippled the trades, leading many to a complete decline; and the economists of the last century, when they opposed state regulation of industries, merely expressed a widely-held dissatisfaction. The removal of that interference by the French Revolution was welcomed as an act of liberation, and France's example was soon followed elsewhere.

With the regulation of wages the State had no better success. In the medieval cities, when the distinction between masters and apprentices or journeymen became more and more apparent in the fifteenth century, unions of apprentices (Gesellenverbande), occasionally assuming an international character, were opposed to the unions of masters and merchants. Now it was the State which undertook to settle their griefs, and under the Elizabethan Statute of 1563 the Justices of Peace had to settle the wages, so as to guarantee a "convenient" livelihood to journeymen and apprentices. The Justices, however, proved helpless to conciliate the conflicting interests, and still less to compel the masters to obey their decisions. The law gradually became a dead letter, and was repealed by the end of the eighteenth century. But while the State thus abandoned the function of regulating wages, it continued severely to prohibit all combinations which were entered upon by journeymen and workers in order to raise their wages, or to keep them at a certain level. All through the eighteenth century it legislated against the workers' unions, and in 1799 it finally prohibited all sorts of combinations, under the menace of severe punishments. In fact, the British Parliament only followed in this case the example of the French Revolutionary Convention, which had issued a draconic law against coalitions of workers-coalitions between a number of citizens being considered as attempts against the sovereignty of the State, which was supposed equally to protect all its subjects. The work of destruction of the medieval unions was thus completed. Both in the town and in the village the State reigned over loose aggregations of individuals, and was ready to prevent by the most stringent measures the reconstitution of any sort of separate unions among them. These were, then, the conditions under which the mutual-aid tendency had to make its way in the nineteenth century.

With wage regulation, the State had no better luck. In medieval cities, the divide between masters and apprentices or journeymen became increasingly clear in the fifteenth century, leading to unions of apprentices (Gesellenverbande) that sometimes took on an international aspect, which opposed the unions of masters and merchants. It was the State that tried to address their grievances, and under the Elizabethan Statute of 1563, the Justices of the Peace were tasked with setting wages to ensure a "fair" living for journeymen and apprentices. However, the Justices were unable to reconcile the conflicting interests and even less able to force the masters to comply with their decisions. The law gradually became ineffective and was repealed by the end of the eighteenth century. Yet, while the State relinquished wage regulation, it continued to strictly prohibit any combinations formed by journeymen and workers to increase their wages or maintain them at a certain level. Throughout the eighteenth century, it enacted laws against workers' unions, and in 1799, it finally banned all types of combinations, threatening severe punishments for violations. In fact, the British Parliament was merely following the lead of the French Revolutionary Convention, which had imposed harsh laws against workers' coalitions, viewing these coalitions as attempts against the sovereignty of the State, which was supposed to equally protect all its citizens. Thus, the dismantling of medieval unions was completed. In both towns and villages, the State ruled over loose groups of individuals and was prepared to prevent, through strict measures, the formation of any separate unions among them. These were the conditions in which the mutual-aid movement had to navigate in the nineteenth century.

Need it be said that no such measures could destroy that tendency? Throughout the eighteenth century, the workers' unions were continually reconstituted.(3) Nor were they stopped by the cruel prosecutions which took place under the laws of 1797 and 1799. Every flaw in supervision, every delay of the masters in denouncing the unions was taken advantage of. Under the cover of friendly societies, burial clubs, or secret brotherhoods, the unions spread in the textile industries, among the Sheffield cutlers, the miners, and vigorous federal organizations were formed to support the branches during strikes and prosecutions.(4) The repeal of the Combination Laws in 1825 gave a new impulse to the movement. Unions and national federations were formed in all trades.(5) and when Robert Owen started his Grand National Consolidated Trades' Union, it mustered half a million members in a few months. True that this period of relative liberty did not last long. Prosecution began anew in the thirties, and the well-known ferocious condemnations of 1832-1844 followed. The Grand National Union was disbanded, and all over the country, both the private employers and the Government in its own workshops began to compel the workers to resign all connection with unions, and to sign "the Document" to that effect. Unionists were prosecuted wholesale under the Master and Servant Act—workers being summarily arrested and condemned upon a mere complaint of misbehaviour lodged by the master.(6) Strikes were suppressed in an autocratic way, and the most astounding condemnations took place for merely having announced a strike or acted as a delegate in it—to say nothing of the military suppression of strike riots, nor of the condemnations which followed the frequent outbursts of acts of violence. To practise mutual support under such circumstances was anything but an easy task. And yet, notwithstanding all obstacles, of which our own generation hardly can have an idea, the revival of the unions began again in 1841, and the amalgamation of the workers has been steadily continued since. After a long fight, which lasted for over a hundred years, the right of combining together was conquered, and at the present time nearly one-fourth part of the regularly-employed workers, i.e. about 1,500,000, belong to trade unions.(7)

Need it be said that no measures could eliminate that tendency? Throughout the eighteenth century, workers' unions were consistently reformed. They weren’t deterred by the harsh prosecutions that occurred under the laws of 1797 and 1799. Every weakness in management, every delay by employers in reporting the unions, was exploited. Under the guise of friendly societies, burial clubs, or secret brotherhoods, the unions spread within the textile industries, among Sheffield cutlers, and miners, and strong federal organizations were established to support local branches during strikes and legal challenges. The repeal of the Combination Laws in 1825 gave new momentum to the movement. Unions and national federations formed in all trades, and when Robert Owen launched his Grand National Consolidated Trades' Union, it quickly gathered half a million members within a few months. However, this period of relative freedom didn’t last long. Prosecutions resumed in the 1830s, leading to the infamous harsh condemnations of 1832-1844. The Grand National Union was dissolved, and across the country, private employers and the Government in their own operations began forcing workers to cut ties with unions and to sign "the Document" to this effect. Union members faced mass prosecutions under the Master and Servant Act—workers were quickly arrested and convicted based on a simple complaint of misconduct made by their employer. Strikes were harshly suppressed, and there were shocking penalties for merely announcing a strike or acting as a delegate—let alone the military crackdown on strike riots and the punishments that followed frequent acts of violence. Practicing mutual support under these conditions was anything but easy. Still, despite all the challenges, of which our generation can hardly imagine, the revival of the unions began again in 1841, and the consolidation of workers has continued steadily since then. After a prolonged struggle lasting over a hundred years, the right to organize was achieved, and today about one-fourth of regularly employed workers, roughly 1,500,000, are part of trade unions.

As to the other European States, sufficient to say that up to a very recent date, all sorts of unions were prosecuted as conspiracies; and that nevertheless they exist everywhere, even though they must often take the form of secret societies; while the extension and the force of labour organizations, and especially of the Knights of Labour, in the United States and in Belgium, have been sufficiently illustrated by strikes in the nineties. It must, however, be borne in mind that, prosecution apart, the mere fact of belonging to a labour union implies considerable sacrifices in money, in time, and in unpaid work, and continually implies the risk of losing employment for the mere fact of being a unionist.(8) There is, moreover, the strike, which a unionist has continually to face; and the grim reality of a strike is, that the limited credit of a worker's family at the baker's and the pawnbroker's is soon exhausted, the strike-pay goes not far even for food, and hunger is soon written on the children's faces. For one who lives in close contact with workers, a protracted strike is the most heartrending sight; while what a strike meant forty years ago in this country, and still means in all but the wealthiest parts of the continent, can easily be conceived. Continually, even now, strikes will end with the total ruin and the forced emigration of whole populations, while the shooting down of strikers on the slightest provocation, or even without any provocation,(9) is quite habitual still on the continent.

As for the other European countries, it's enough to say that until very recently, all kinds of unions were treated as conspiracies; yet they still exist everywhere, even though they often have to operate as secret societies. Meanwhile, the growth and strength of labor organizations, especially the Knights of Labor in the United States and Belgium, have been clearly shown through strikes in the 1890s. However, it's important to remember that, aside from legal actions, simply being part of a labor union requires significant sacrifices in terms of money, time, and unpaid labor, and there’s always the risk of losing a job just for being a union member. Additionally, there's the threat of strikes that union members constantly face; the harsh reality of a strike is that a worker's family's limited credit at the bakery and the pawn shop gets exhausted quickly, strike pay doesn’t stretch far enough for even basic food, and soon hunger shows on the children's faces. For someone who closely interacts with workers, a lengthy strike is a deeply distressing sight. What a strike meant forty years ago in this country, and what it still means in most parts of the continent that aren’t wealthy, is easy to imagine. Even now, strikes can lead to the complete devastation and forced emigration of entire communities, while the shooting of strikers at the slightest provocation—or even without any provocation—is still quite common on the continent.

And yet, every year there are thousands of strikes and lock-outs in Europe and America—the most severe and protracted contests being, as a rule, the so-called "sympathy strikes," which are entered upon to support locked-out comrades or to maintain the rights of the unions. And while a portion of the Press is prone to explain strikes by "intimidation," those who have lived among strikers speak with admiration of the mutual aid and support which are constantly practised by them. Every one has heard of the colossal amount of work which was done by volunteer workers for organizing relief during the London dock-labourers' strike; of the miners who, after having themselves been idle for many weeks, paid a levy of four shillings a week to the strike fund when they resumed work; of the miner widow who, during the Yorkshire labour war of 1894, brought her husband's life-savings to the strike-fund; of the last loaf of bread being always shared with neighbours; of the Radstock miners, favoured with larger kitchen-gardens, who invited four hundred Bristol miners to take their share of cabbage and potatoes, and so on. All newspaper correspondents, during the great strike of miners in Yorkshire in 1894, knew heaps of such facts, although not all of them could report such "irrelevant" matters to their respective papers.(10)

And yet, every year thousands of strikes and lockouts happen in Europe and America—the most intense and long-lasting ones being the so-called "sympathy strikes," which are launched to support locked-out coworkers or to uphold union rights. While some in the media tend to explain strikes as driven by "intimidation," those who have spent time with strikers speak highly of the solidarity and support constantly shown among them. Everyone’s heard about the massive efforts put in by volunteers to provide relief during the London dockworkers' strike; about miners who, after being out of work for weeks, donated four shillings a week to the strike fund when they returned to work; about the widow of a miner who contributed her husband’s life savings to the strike fund during the Yorkshire labor conflict of 1894; about how the last loaf of bread was always shared with neighbors; about the Radstock miners, with their larger kitchen gardens, who invited four hundred miners from Bristol to come and take their share of cabbage and potatoes, and so on. All newspaper reporters covering the great miners' strike in Yorkshire in 1894 knew plenty of such stories, although not all of them could report on these "irrelevant" issues to their publications.(10)

Unionism is not, however, the only form in which the worker's need of mutual support finds its expression. There are, besides, the political associations, whose activity many workers consider as more conducive to general welfare than the trade-unions, limited as they are now in their purposes. Of course the mere fact of belonging to a political body cannot be taken as a manifestation of the mutual-aid tendency. We all know that politics are the field in which the purely egotistic elements of society enter into the most entangled combinations with altruistic aspirations. But every experienced politician knows that all great political movements were fought upon large and often distant issues, and that those of them were the strongest which provoked most disinterested enthusiasm. All great historical movements have had this character, and for our own generation Socialism stands in that case. "Paid agitators" is, no doubt, the favourite refrain of those who know nothing about it. The truth, however, is that—to speak only of what I know personally—if I had kept a diary for the last twenty-four years and inscribed in it all the devotion and self-sacrifice which I came across in the Socialist movement, the reader of such a diary would have had the word "heroism" constantly on his lips. But the men I would have spoken of were not heroes; they were average men, inspired by a grand idea. Every Socialist newspaper—and there are hundreds of them in Europe alone—has the same history of years of sacrifice without any hope of reward, and, in the overwhelming majority of cases, even without any personal ambition. I have seen families living without knowing what would be their food to-morrow, the husband boycotted all round in his little town for his part in the paper, and the wife supporting the family by sewing, and such a situation lasting for years, until the family would retire, without a word of reproach, simply saying: "Continue; we can hold on no more!" I have seen men, dying from consumption, and knowing it, and yet knocking about in snow and fog to prepare meetings, speaking at meetings within a few weeks from death, and only then retiring to the hospital with the words: "Now, friends, I am done; the doctors say I have but a few weeks to live. Tell the comrades that I shall be happy if they come to see me." I have seen facts which would be described as "idealization" if I told them in this place; and the very names of these men, hardly known outside a narrow circle of friends, will soon be forgotten when the friends, too, have passed away. In fact, I don't know myself which most to admire, the unbounded devotion of these few, or the sum total of petty acts of devotion of the great number. Every quire of a penny paper sold, every meeting, every hundred votes which are won at a Socialist election, represent an amount of energy and sacrifices of which no outsider has the faintest idea. And what is now done by Socialists has been done in every popular and advanced party, political and religious, in the past. All past progress has been promoted by like men and by a like devotion.

Unionism isn't the only way workers express their need for mutual support. There are also political groups that many workers see as more beneficial for the community than trade unions, which are now limited in their goals. Of course, just being part of a political organization doesn’t necessarily show a desire for mutual aid. We all know that politics often blend selfish interests with altruistic goals. But any seasoned politician understands that significant political movements have usually focused on broad and often distant issues, and the strongest ones are those that inspire the most selfless enthusiasm. All major historical movements have had this trait, and for our generation, Socialism is a prime example. "Paid agitators" is a common complaint from those who don't truly understand it. The reality is that—speaking from my own experience—if I had kept a diary over the last twenty-four years documenting the dedication and selflessness I encountered in the Socialist movement, the word "heroism" would constantly come to mind for anyone reading it. Yet the individuals I would describe weren't heroes; they were everyday people driven by a noble idea. Every Socialist newspaper—and there are hundreds in Europe alone—shares a history of years filled with sacrifices made without any expectation of reward, and, in most cases, without personal ambition. I've seen families uncertain about where their next meal would come from, the husband ostracized in his small town for his role in the paper, while the wife kept the family afloat through sewing; this situation lasted for years until the family would give up, quietly saying, "Keep going; we can't hold on any longer!" I've witnessed men, dying from tuberculosis and fully aware of it, who still trudged through snow and fog to organize meetings, spoke at those meetings just weeks from death, and only then went to the hospital saying, "Now, friends, I'm done; the doctors say I have just a few weeks left. Tell the comrades I'd be glad if they come to visit me." I've seen stories that would be called "idealization" if I shared them here, and the names of these men, scarcely known outside a small circle of friends, will soon fade into obscurity once their friends are gone too. Honestly, I can't decide which is more admirable—the unwavering commitment of these few or the collective minor acts of dedication from the many. Every penny paper sold, every meeting held, every hundred votes won in a Socialist election represents an amount of effort and sacrifice that outsiders can hardly comprehend. What Socialists are doing today has been reflected in every popular and progressive political and religious movement in the past. All historical progress has been driven by similar individuals and the same kind of devotion.

Co-operation, especially in Britain, is often described as "joint-stock individualism"; and such as it is now, it undoubtedly tends to breed a co-operative egotism, not only towards the community at large, but also among the co-operators themselves. It is, nevertheless, certain that at its origin the movement had an essentially mutual-aid character. Even now, its most ardent promoters are persuaded that co-operation leads mankind to a higher harmonic stage of economical relations, and it is not possible to stay in some of the strongholds of co-operation in the North without realizing that the great number of the rank and file hold the same opinion. Most of them would lose interest in the movement if that faith were gone; and it must be owned that within the last few years broader ideals of general welfare and of the producers' solidarity have begun to be current among the co-operators. There is undoubtedly now a tendency towards establishing better relations between the owners of the co-operative workshops and the workers.

Cooperation, especially in Britain, is often referred to as "joint-stock individualism." As it stands today, it certainly seems to promote a kind of cooperative egotism, not just towards the community but also among the cooperators themselves. However, it's clear that at its inception, the movement was fundamentally about mutual aid. Even now, its most passionate supporters believe that cooperation can elevate society to a better balance in economic relationships, and you can't visit some of the strongholds of cooperation in the North without noticing that a large number of the rank and file share this belief. Most of them would likely lose interest in the movement if that faith were lost; and it should be noted that in recent years, broader ideals of general welfare and solidarity among producers have started to gain traction among cooperators. There’s certainly a growing trend towards improving relationships between the owners of cooperative workshops and the workers.

The importance of co-operation in this country, in Holland and in Denmark is well known; while in Germany, and especially on the Rhine, the co-operative societies are already an important factor of industrial life.(11) It is, however, Russia which offers perhaps the best field for the study of cooperation under an infinite variety of aspects. In Russia, it is a natural growth, an inheritance from the middle ages; and while a formally established co-operative society would have to cope with many legal difficulties and official suspicion, the informal co-operation—the artel—makes the very substance of Russian peasant life. The history of "the making of Russia," and of the colonization of Siberia, is a history of the hunting and trading artels or guilds, followed by village communities, and at the present time we find the artel everywhere; among each group of ten to fifty peasants who come from the same village to work at a factory, in all the building trades, among fishermen and hunters, among convicts on their way to and in Siberia, among railway porters, Exchange messengers, Customs House labourers, everywhere in the village industries, which give occupation to 7,000,000 men—from top to bottom of the working world, permanent and temporary, for production and consumption under all possible aspects. Until now, many of the fishing-grounds on the tributaries of the Caspian Sea are held by immense artels, the Ural river belonging to the whole of the Ural Cossacks, who allot and re-allot the fishing-grounds—perhaps the richest in the world—among the villages, without any interference of the authorities. Fishing is always made by artels in the Ural, the Volga, and all the lakes of Northern Russia. Besides these permanent organizations, there are the simply countless temporary artels, constituted for each special purpose. When ten or twenty peasants come from some locality to a big town, to work as weavers, carpenters, masons, boat-builders, and so on, they always constitute an artel. They hire rooms, hire a cook (very often the wife of one of them acts in this capacity), elect an elder, and take their meals in common, each one paying his share for food and lodging to the artel. A party of convicts on its way to Siberia always does the same, and its elected elder is the officially-recognized intermediary between the convicts and the military chief of the party. In the hard-labour prisons they have the same organization. The railway porters, the messengers at the Exchange, the workers at the Custom House, the town messengers in the capitals, who are collectively responsible for each member, enjoy such a reputation that any amount of money or bank-notes is trusted to the artel-member by the merchants. In the building trades, artels of from 10 to 200 members are formed; and the serious builders and railway contractors always prefer to deal with an artel than with separately-hired workers. The last attempts of the Ministry of War to deal directly with productive artels, formed ad hoc in the domestic trades, and to give them orders for boots and all sorts of brass and iron goods, are described as most satisfactory; while the renting of a Crown iron work, (Votkinsk) to an artel of workers, which took place seven or eight years ago, has been a decided success.

The importance of cooperation in this country, in the Netherlands, and in Denmark is well recognized; while in Germany, especially along the Rhine, cooperative societies are already a significant part of industrial life. However, Russia may provide the best opportunity to study cooperation from countless perspectives. In Russia, it develops naturally, stemming from the Middle Ages; and while a formal cooperative society would face numerous legal hurdles and official skepticism, informal cooperation—the artel—forms the essence of Russian peasant life. The story of "the making of Russia," and the colonization of Siberia, is a tale of hunting and trading artels or guilds, followed by village communities. Today, we find artels everywhere; among each group of ten to fifty peasants from the same village working at a factory, across building trades, among fishermen and hunters, among convicts traveling to and in Siberia, among railway porters, exchange messengers, customs laborers, and throughout village industries that employ 7 million people—spanning the entire working world, permanent and temporary, for production and consumption in every conceivable form. To this day, many fishing grounds on the tributaries of the Caspian Sea are held by large artels, with the Ural River being shared by all the Ural Cossacks, who allocate and reallocate the fishing grounds—possibly the richest in the world—among the villages without any interference from authorities. Fishing is always conducted by artels in the Ural, the Volga, and all the lakes in the North of Russia. In addition to these permanent organizations, there are countless temporary artels formed for specific purposes. When ten or twenty peasants arrive from a locality to a large town to work as weavers, carpenters, masons, boat builders, and so on, they always form an artel. They rent rooms, hire a cook (often the wife of one of them fills this role), elect an elder, and share meals, with each person contributing their share for food and lodging to the artel. A group of convicts on their way to Siberia does the same, with their chosen elder serving as the officially recognized liaison between the convicts and the military leader of the group. In hard-labor prisons, the same structure exists. Railway porters, exchange messengers, customs workers, and town messengers in the capitals—who are collectively responsible for each member—have such a good reputation that merchants trust substantial sums of money or banknotes to the artel members. In construction trades, artels of 10 to 200 members are formed; serious builders and railway contractors prefer to work with an artel rather than with individually hired workers. Recent attempts by the Ministry of War to engage directly with productive artels, created specifically for domestic trades, and to place orders for boots and various brass and iron goods, are reported to be very satisfactory. Additionally, the lease of a Crown ironworks (Votkinsk) to a worker artel about seven or eight years ago has proven to be a clear success.

We can thus see in Russia how the old medieval institution, having not been interfered with by the State (in its informal manifestations), has fully survived until now, and takes the greatest variety of forms in accordance with the requirements of modern industry and commerce. As to the Balkan peninsula, the Turkish Empire and Caucasia, the old guilds are maintained there in full. The esnafs of Servia have fully preserved their medieval character; they include both masters and journeymen, regulate the trades, and are institutions for mutual support in labour and sickness;(12) while the amkari of Caucasia, and especially at Tiflis, add to these functions a considerable influence in municipal life.(13)

We can see in Russia how the old medieval institution, having not been interfered with by the State (in its informal forms), has fully survived until now and takes on many different shapes to meet the needs of modern industry and commerce. In the Balkan peninsula, the Turkish Empire, and the Caucasus, the old guilds are still fully intact. The esnafs of Serbia have completely retained their medieval character; they include both masters and workers, regulate trades, and serve as support systems for work and illness; while the amkari of the Caucasus, especially in Tiflis, add significant influence to municipal life.

In connection with co-operation, I ought perhaps to mention also the friendly societies, the unities of oddfellows, the village and town clubs organized for meeting the doctors' bills, the dress and burial clubs, the small clubs very common among factory girls, to which they contribute a few pence every week, and afterwards draw by lot the sum of one pound, which can at least be used for some substantial purchase, and many others. A not inconsiderable amount of sociable or jovial spirit is alive in all such societies and clubs, even though the "credit and debit" of each member are closely watched over. But there are so many associations based on the readiness to sacrifice time, health, and life if required, that we can produce numbers of illustrations of the best forms of mutual support.

In relation to cooperation, I should probably also mention the friendly societies, the Oddfellows unions, the village and town clubs set up to cover doctors' bills, the dress and burial clubs, and the small clubs that are quite common among factory workers, where they contribute a few pence each week and later draw lots for a sum of one pound, which can at least be used for something meaningful. There is a decent amount of social or friendly spirit present in all these societies and clubs, even though each member's "credit and debit" is monitored closely. However, there are so many associations focused on the willingness to give up time, health, and even life if necessary, that we can provide numerous examples of the best forms of mutual support.

The Lifeboat Association in this country, and similar institutions on the Continent, must be mentioned in the first place. The former has now over three hundred boats along the coasts of these isles, and it would have twice as many were it not for the poverty of the fisher men, who cannot afford to buy lifeboats. The crews consist, however, of volunteers, whose readiness to sacrifice their lives for the rescue of absolute strangers to them is put every year to a severe test; every winter the loss of several of the bravest among them stands on record. And if we ask these men what moves them to risk their lives, even when there is no reasonable chance of success, their answer is something on the following lines. A fearful snowstorm, blowing across the Channel, raged on the flat, sandy coast of a tiny village in Kent, and a small smack, laden with oranges, stranded on the sands near by. In these shallow waters only a flat-bottomed lifeboat of a simplified type can be kept, and to launch it during such a storm was to face an almost certain disaster. And yet the men went out, fought for hours against the wind, and the boat capsized twice. One man was drowned, the others were cast ashore. One of these last, a refined coastguard, was found next morning, badly bruised and half frozen in the snow. I asked him, how they came to make that desperate attempt? "I don't know myself," was his reply." There was the wreck; all the people from the village stood on the beach, and all said it would be foolish to go out; we never should work through the surf. We saw five or six men clinging to the mast, making desperate signals. We all felt that something must be done, but what could we do? One hour passed, two hours, and we all stood there. We all felt most uncomfortable. Then, all of a sudden, through the storm, it seemed to us as if we heard their cries—they had a boy with them. We could not stand that any longer. All at once we said, "We must go!" The women said so too; they would have treated us as cowards if we had not gone, although next day they said we had been fools to go. As one man, we rushed to the boat, and went. The boat capsized, but we took hold of it. The worst was to see poor drowning by the side of the boat, and we could do nothing to save him. Then came a fearful wave, the boat capsized again, and we were cast ashore. The men were still rescued by the D. boat, ours was caught miles away. I was found next morning in the snow."

The Lifeboat Association in this country, along with similar organizations on the Continent, deserves mention first. The former currently has over three hundred boats stationed along the coasts of these islands, and it would have twice as many if it weren't for the financial struggles of the fishermen, who can’t afford to buy lifeboats. The crews, however, are made up of volunteers, whose willingness to risk their lives to save complete strangers is put to the test every year; each winter, several of the bravest among them are lost. If you ask these men what drives them to take such risks, even when the chance of success is slim, their answer often goes something like this: A terrible snowstorm swept across the Channel, affecting a small, sandy village in Kent where a small fishing boat, loaded with oranges, got stuck on the beach nearby. In these shallow waters, only a flat-bottomed lifeboat of a simpler design can be used, and launching it in such a storm meant almost certain disaster. Yet the men went out, battled the wind for hours, and the boat flipped twice. One man drowned, while the others washed up on shore. One of those who made it back, a refined coastguard, was found the next morning, badly bruised and half-frozen in the snow. I asked him why they had made such a desperate attempt. "I don’t know," was his reply. "There was the wreck; everyone in the village was on the beach, and they all said it would be foolish to go out; we’d never make it through the surf. We saw five or six men clinging to the mast, signaling for help. We all felt that something had to be done, but what could we do? An hour passed, then two, and we were all just standing there, feeling uneasy. Suddenly, through the storm, it seemed we could hear their cries—they had a boy with them. We couldn’t take it anymore. All at once, we said, 'We have to go!' The women said the same; they would have called us cowards if we didn’t go, even though the next day they claimed we were foolish for doing so. As one, we rushed to the boat and set out. The boat flipped, but we held on to it. The hardest part was watching a poor soul drowning next to us, powerless to save him. Then a huge wave crashed over us, the boat flipped again, and we were thrown ashore. The others were rescued by the D. boat; we ended up miles away. I was found the next morning in the snow."

The same feeling moved also the miners of the Rhonda Valley, when they worked for the rescue of their comrades from the inundated mine. They had pierced through thirty-two yards of coal in order to reach their entombed comrades; but when only three yards more remained to be pierced, fire-damp enveloped them. The lamps went out, and the rescue-men retired. To work in such conditions was to risk being blown up at every moment. But the raps of the entombed miners were still heard, the men were still alive and appealed for help, and several miners volunteered to work at any risk; and as they went down the mine, their wives had only silent tears to follow them—not one word to stop them.

The same feeling moved the miners of the Rhonda Valley when they worked to rescue their trapped comrades from the flooded mine. They had tunneled through thirty-two yards of coal to reach their buried friends; but when only three more yards were left to dig, they were surrounded by fire-damp. The lamps went out, and the rescue team had to pull back. Working in those conditions meant risking an explosion at any moment. But they could still hear the knocks of the trapped miners; the men were alive and calling for help, and several miners volunteered to keep working despite the danger. As they descended into the mine, their wives could only watch with silent tears—there were no words to hold them back.

There is the gist of human psychology. Unless men are maddened in the battlefield, they "cannot stand it" to hear appeals for help, and not to respond to them. The hero goes; and what the hero does, all feel that they ought to have done as well. The sophisms of the brain cannot resist the mutual-aid feeling, because this feeling has been nurtured by thousands of years of human social life and hundreds of thousands of years of pre-human life in societies.

There’s the essence of human psychology. Unless people are driven crazy by the chaos of battle, they "can’t handle" hearing calls for help and not responding. The hero steps up, and everyone else feels they should have done the same. The tricks of the mind can’t overpower the instinct to help each other, because this instinct has been cultivated over thousands of years of human society and hundreds of thousands of years of pre-human social life.

"But what about those men who were drowned in the Serpentine in the presence of a crowd, out of which no one moved for their rescue?" it may be asked. "What about the child which fell into the Regent's Park Canal—also in the presence of a holiday crowd—and was only saved through the presence of mind of a maid who let out a Newfoundland dog to the rescue?" The answer is plain enough. Man is a result of both his inherited instincts and his education. Among the miners and the seamen, their common occupations and their every-day contact with one another create a feeling of solidarity, while the surrounding dangers maintain courage and pluck. In the cities, on the contrary, the absence of common interest nurtures indifference, while courage and pluck, which seldom find their opportunities, disappear, or take another direction. Moreover, the tradition of the hero of the mine and the sea lives in the miners' and fishermen's villages, adorned with a poetical halo. But what are the traditions of a motley London crowd? The only tradition they might have in common ought to be created by literature, but a literature which would correspond to the village epics hardly exists. The clergy are so anxious to prove that all that comes from human nature is sin, and that all good in man has a supernatural origin, that they mostly ignore the facts which cannot be produced as an example of higher inspiration or grace, coming from above. And as to the lay-writers, their attention is chiefly directed towards one sort of heroism, the heroism which promotes the idea of the State. Therefore, they admire the Roman hero, or the soldier in the battle, while they pass by the fisherman's heroism, hardly paying attention to it. The poet and the painter might, of course, be taken by the beauty of the human heart in itself; but both seldom know the life of the poorer classes, and while they can sing or paint the Roman or the military hero in conventional surroundings, they can neither sing nor paint impressively the hero who acts in those modest surroundings which they ignore. If they venture to do so, they produce a mere piece of rhetoric.(14)

"But what about those men who drowned in the Serpentine while a crowd watched without helping?" one might ask. "What about the child who fell into the Regent's Park Canal—also in front of a holiday crowd—and was only rescued because a maid thought quickly and sent out a Newfoundland dog to help?" The answer is straightforward. Humans are shaped by both their inherited instincts and their upbringing. Among miners and sailors, their shared work and daily interactions create a sense of community, while surrounding dangers nurture bravery and resilience. In cities, on the other hand, the lack of shared interests fosters indifference, and bravery, which rarely has a chance to manifest, fades away or shifts to something else. Furthermore, the heroic tradition of miners and fishermen thrives in their villages, surrounded by a poetic charm. But what traditions does a diverse London crowd share? The only common tradition they might have should be created by literature, but literature that mirrors village epics is almost nonexistent. The clergy are so eager to demonstrate that all human nature is sinful and that all goodness in people comes from a supernatural source that they often overlook real examples of inspiration or grace that arise from everyday life. As for secular writers, their focus is mainly on one type of heroism, the kind that supports the idea of the State. So, they admire the Roman hero or the soldier in battle while ignoring the heroism of fishermen, barely acknowledging it. Poets and painters could be inspired by the beauty of the human heart itself; however, they rarely know about the lives of the poorer classes. While they can create traditional works centered around Roman or military heroes, they struggle to capture the heroism of those who act within the modest settings they overlook. When they attempt this, they often produce nothing more than empty rhetoric.

The countless societies, clubs, and alliances, for the enjoyment of life, for study and research, for education, and so on, which have lately grown up in such numbers that it would require many years to simply tabulate them, are another manifestation of the same everworking tendency for association and mutual support. Some of them, like the broods of young birds of different species which come together in the autumn, are entirely given to share in common the joys of life. Every village in this country, in Switzerland, Germany, and so on, has its cricket, football, tennis, nine-pins, pigeon, musical or singing clubs. Other societies are much more numerous, and some of them, like the Cyclists' Alliance, have suddenly taken a formidable development. Although the members of this alliance have nothing in common but the love of cycling, there is already among them a sort of freemasonry for mutual help, especially in the remote nooks and corners which are not flooded by cyclists; they look upon the "C.A.C."—the Cyclists' Alliance Club—in a village as a sort of home; and at the yearly Cyclists' Camp many a standing friendship has been established. The Kegelbruder, the Brothers of the Nine Pins, in Germany, are a similar association; so also the Gymnasts' Societies (300,000 members in Germany), the informal brotherhood of paddlers in France, the yacht clubs, and so on. Such associations certainly do not alter the economical stratification of society, but, especially in the small towns, they contribute to smooth social distinctions, and as they all tend to join in large national and international federations, they certainly aid the growth of personal friendly intercourse between all sorts of men scattered in different parts of the globe.

The many societies, clubs, and groups that have recently popped up for enjoyment, study, research, education, and more have grown so numerous that it would take years to list them all. They represent a constant tendency for people to come together and support each other. Some of these groups, like young birds of different species gathering in the autumn, focus entirely on sharing the joys of life. Every village in this country, as well as in Switzerland, Germany, and elsewhere, has its cricket, soccer, tennis, bowling, pigeon, music, or singing clubs. Other societies are much more common, and some, like the Cyclists' Alliance, have rapidly grown in size. Although the members of this alliance only share a love of cycling, there's already a sense of camaraderie for mutual support, especially in remote areas that aren't overrun by cyclists; they view the "C.A.C."—the Cyclists' Alliance Club—in a village as a kind of home, and many lasting friendships have formed at the annual Cyclists' Camp. The Kegelbruder, or Brothers of the Nine Pins, in Germany, are a similar group, as are the Gymnasts' Societies (with 300,000 members in Germany), the informal paddlers' brotherhood in France, yacht clubs, and more. While these associations don't change the economic structure of society, especially in small towns, they help smooth over social distinctions, and as they often unite in large national and international federations, they promote personal friendships among all sorts of people spread across the globe.

The Alpine Clubs, the Jagdschutzverein in Germany, which has over 100,000 members—hunters, educated foresters, zoologists, and simple lovers of Nature—and the International Ornithological Society, which includes zoologists, breeders, and simple peasants in Germany, have the same character. Not only have they done in a few years a large amount of very useful work, which large associations alone could do properly (maps, refuge huts, mountain roads; studies of animal life, of noxious insects, of migrations of birds, and so on), but they create new bonds between men. Two Alpinists of different nationalities who meet in a refuge hut in the Caucasus, or the professor and the peasant ornithologist who stay in the same house, are no more strangers to each other; while the Uncle Toby's Society at Newcastle, which has already induced over 260,000 boys and girls never to destroy birds' nests and to be kind to all animals, has certainly done more for the development of human feelings and of taste in natural science than lots of moralists and most of our schools.

The Alpine Clubs, the Jagdschutzverein in Germany, which has over 100,000 members—hunters, educated foresters, zoologists, and just regular nature lovers—and the International Ornithological Society, which includes zoologists, breeders, and ordinary farmers in Germany, share the same spirit. Not only have they accomplished a significant amount of useful work in just a few years that only large organizations could typically handle (like maps, refuge huts, mountain roads; studies of wildlife, harmful insects, bird migrations, and more), but they also forge new connections between people. Two climbers from different countries who run into each other in a refuge hut in the Caucasus, or the professor and the local ornithologist sharing the same house, are no longer strangers. Meanwhile, the Uncle Toby's Society in Newcastle, which has motivated over 260,000 boys and girls to never destroy birds' nests and to be kind to all animals, has definitely contributed more to the development of human compassion and appreciation for natural science than many moralists and most of our schools.

We cannot omit, even in this rapid review, the thousands of scientific, literary, artistic, and educational societies. Up till now, the scientific bodies, closely controlled and often subsidized by the State, have generally moved in a very narrow circle, and they often came to be looked upon as mere openings for getting State appointments, while the very narrowness of their circles undoubtedly bred petty jealousies. Still it is a fact that the distinctions of birth, political parties and creeds are smoothed to some extent by such associations; while in the smaller and remote towns the scientific, geographical, or musical societies, especially those of them which appeal to a larger circle of amateurs, become small centres of intellectual life, a sort of link between the little spot and the wide world, and a place where men of very different conditions meet on a footing of equality. To fully appreciate the value of such centres, one ought to know them, say, in Siberia. As to the countless educational societies which only now begin to break down the State's and the Church's monopoly in education, they are sure to become before long the leading power in that branch. To the "Froebel Unions" we already owe the Kindergarten system; and to a number of formal and informal educational associations we owe the high standard of women's education in Russia, although all the time these societies and groups had to act in strong opposition to a powerful government.(15) As to the various pedagogical societies in Germany, it is well known that they have done the best part in the working out of the modern methods of teaching science in popular schools. In such associations the teacher finds also his best support. How miserable the overworked and under-paid village teacher would have been without their aid!(16)

We can't overlook, even in this brief overview, the thousands of scientific, literary, artistic, and educational organizations. So far, the scientific institutions, which are heavily regulated and often funded by the State, have mostly operated within a very limited scope, leading many to see them as just pathways to State jobs, and this narrowness certainly fostered petty rivalries. Still, it's true that the divisions of social class, political parties, and beliefs are somewhat diminished by these groups; in smaller and more isolated towns, scientific, geographic, or musical organizations, especially those that attract a broader audience of enthusiasts, become small hubs of intellectual life, connecting the local area to the wider world and providing a space where people from diverse backgrounds meet as equals. To truly understand the value of such centers, one should experience them, say, in Siberia. As for the numerous educational organizations that are just starting to break the State's and Church's hold on education, they'll soon become the dominant force in that field. We already owe the Kindergarten system to the "Froebel Unions," and various formal and informal educational groups have helped raise the standard of women's education in Russia, even while having to resist a powerful government. It's well known that the various educational societies in Germany have played a major role in developing modern teaching methods in public schools. In these organizations, teachers also find their best support. Just imagine how difficult it would have been for the overworked and underpaid village teacher without their help!

All these associations, societies, brotherhoods, alliances, institutes, and so on, which must now be counted by the ten thousand in Europe alone, and each of which represents an immense amount of voluntary, unambitious, and unpaid or underpaid work—what are they but so many manifestations, under an infinite variety of aspects, of the same ever-living tendency of man towards mutual aid and support? For nearly three centuries men were prevented from joining hands even for literary, artistic, and educational purposes. Societies could only be formed under the protection of the State, or the Church, or as secret brotherhoods, like free-masonry. But now that the resistance has been broken, they swarm in all directions, they extend over all multifarious branches of human activity, they become international, and they undoubtedly contribute, to an extent which cannot yet be fully appreciated, to break down the screens erected by States between different nationalities. Notwithstanding the jealousies which are bred by commercial competition, and the provocations to hatred which are sounded by the ghosts of a decaying past, there is a conscience of international solidarity which is growing both among the leading spirits of the world and the masses of the workers, since they also have conquered the right of international intercourse; and in the preventing of a European war during the last quarter of a century, this spirit has undoubtedly had its share.

All these groups, organizations, brotherhoods, alliances, and institutes, which number in the tens of thousands across Europe alone, each representing a huge amount of voluntary, unambitious, and often unpaid work—what are they if not countless expressions, in a variety of forms, of humanity’s ongoing drive for mutual aid and support? For nearly three centuries, people were restricted from coming together even for literary, artistic, and educational purposes. Societies could only be formed under the protection of the State, the Church, or as secret brotherhoods like Freemasonry. But now that these restrictions have been lifted, they are flourishing in all directions, spreading across countless areas of human activity, becoming international, and they undoubtedly contribute, in ways we still can’t fully measure, to breaking down the barriers set up by nations between different cultures. Despite the rivalries fueled by commercial competition and the hatred stirred up by the remnants of a fading past, there is a sense of international solidarity growing among both influential leaders and the working masses, as they too have gained the right to engage internationally. This spirit has undoubtedly played a role in preventing a European war over the last twenty-five years.

The religious charitable associations, which again represent a whole world, certainly must be mentioned in this place. There is not the slightest doubt that the great bulk of their members are moved by the same mutual-aid feelings which are common to all mankind. Unhappily the religious teachers of men prefer to ascribe to such feelings a supernatural origin. Many of them pretend that man does not consciously obey the mutual-aid inspiration so long as he has not been enlightened by the teachings of the special religion which they represent, and, with St. Augustin, most of them do not recognize such feelings in the "pagan savage." Moreover, while early Christianity, like all other religions, was an appeal to the broadly human feelings of mutual aid and sympathy, the Christian Church has aided the State in wrecking all standing institutions of mutual aid and support which were anterior to it, or developed outside of it; and, instead of the mutual aid which every savage considers as due to his kinsman, it has preached charity which bears a character of inspiration from above, and, accordingly, implies a certain superiority of the giver upon the receiver. With this limitation, and without any intention to give offence to those who consider themselves as a body elect when they accomplish acts simply humane, we certainly may consider the immense numbers of religious charitable associations as an outcome of the same mutual-aid tendency.

The religious charitable associations, which represent a whole world in their own right, certainly deserve a mention here. There’s no doubt that most of their members are driven by the same feelings of mutual aid that everyone shares. Unfortunately, religious leaders often attribute these feelings to a supernatural source. Many of them claim that a person doesn’t consciously feel the urge to help others unless they have been enlightened by the teachings of the specific religion they represent, and like St. Augustine, most do not recognize these feelings in the "pagan savage." Furthermore, while early Christianity, like all other religions, appealed to the universal human feelings of mutual aid and sympathy, the Christian Church has aided the State in dismantling all established institutions of mutual aid and support that existed before it or were developed outside of it. Instead of the mutual aid that every individual considered a basic obligation to their kin, it has promoted charity that carries an implication of inspiration from above, suggesting a certain superiority of the giver over the receiver. With this caveat, and without intending to offend those who see themselves as an elect group when performing simple humane acts, we can certainly regard the vast number of religious charitable associations as a product of the same mutual-aid tendency.

All these facts show that a reckless prosecution of personal interests, with no regard to other people's needs, is not the only characteristic of modern life. By the side of this current which so proudly claims leadership in human affairs, we perceive a hard struggle sustained by both the rural and industrial populations in order to reintroduce standing institutions of mutual aid and support; and we discover, in all classes of society, a widely-spread movement towards the establishment of an infinite variety of more or less permanent institutions for the same purpose. But when we pass from public life to the private life of the modern individual, we discover another extremely wide world of mutual aid and support, which only passes unnoticed by most sociologists because it is limited to the narrow circle of the family and personal friendship.(17)

All these facts show that a reckless pursuit of personal interests, with no concern for other people's needs, isn't the only feature of modern life. Alongside this trend that boldly claims to lead human affairs, we see a tough struggle by both rural and industrial populations to bring back established institutions of mutual aid and support. We also find a broad movement across all social classes toward creating a diverse range of more or less permanent institutions for the same purpose. However, when we shift from public life to the private life of the modern individual, we uncover another vast realm of mutual aid and support, which most sociologists overlook because it is confined to the close circle of family and personal friendships.(17)

Under the present social system, all bonds of union among the inhabitants of the same street or neighbourhood have been dissolved. In the richer parts of the large towns, people live without knowing who are their next-door neighbours. But in the crowded lanes people know each other perfectly, and are continually brought into mutual contact. Of course, petty quarrels go their course, in the lanes as elsewhere; but groupings in accordance with personal affinities grow up, and within their circle mutual aid is practised to an extent of which the richer classes have no idea. If we take, for instance, the children of a poor neighbourhood who play in a street or a churchyard, or on a green, we notice at once that a close union exists among them, notwithstanding the temporary fights, and that that union protects them from all sorts of misfortunes. As soon as a mite bends inquisitively over the opening of a drain—"Don't stop there," another mite shouts out, "fever sits in the hole!" "Don't climb over that wall, the train will kill you if you tumble down! Don't come near to the ditch! Don't eat those berries—poison! you will die." Such are the first teachings imparted to the urchin when he joins his mates out-doors. How many of the children whose play-grounds are the pavements around "model workers' dwellings," or the quays and bridges of the canals, would be crushed to death by the carts or drowned in the muddy waters, were it not for that sort of mutual support. And when a fair Jack has made a slip into the unprotected ditch at the back of the milkman's yard, or a cherry-cheeked Lizzie has, after all, tumbled down into the canal, the young brood raises such cries that all the neighbourhood is on the alert and rushes to the rescue.

Under the current social system, all connections among people living on the same street or in the same neighborhood have faded away. In wealthier areas of large cities, residents often don’t even know who their neighbors are. However, in the crowded backstreets, people know each other well and frequently interact with one another. Naturally, minor disputes happen, just like anywhere else; but friendships based on personal connections develop, and within their circle, they practice mutual support to a degree that wealthier individuals can’t even imagine. For example, if we look at the children in a poor neighborhood who play in the street, churchyard, or a green space, we can immediately see that they share a strong bond despite occasional squabbles, and this bond helps shield them from various troubles. The moment one child leans curiously over a drain, another yells, “Don’t stay there, fever’s lurking in that hole!” “Don’t climb over that wall, you’ll get hit by a train if you fall!” “Stay away from the ditch! Don’t eat those berries—they’re poisonous, you’ll die.” These are the first lessons taught to the little ones when they’re outdoors with their friends. How many children playing on the pavements around “model workers' housing” or by the canals would be crushed under carts or drown in muddy waters if it weren't for this kind of mutual support? And when a kid named Jack slips into the uncovered ditch behind the milkman’s yard or a rosy-cheeked Lizzie tumbles into the canal, the other kids cry out loud enough that the entire neighborhood is alerted and rushes to help.

Then comes in the alliance of the mothers. "You could not imagine" (a lady-doctor who lives in a poor neighbourhood told me lately) "how much they help each other. If a woman has prepared nothing, or could prepare nothing, for the baby which she expected—and how often that happens!—all the neighbours bring something for the new-comer. One of the neighbours always takes care of the children, and some other always drops in to take care of the household, so long as the mother is in bed." This habit is general. It is mentioned by all those who have lived among the poor. In a thousand small ways the mothers support each other and bestow their care upon children that are not their own. Some training—good or bad, let them decide it for themselves—is required in a lady of the richer classes to render her able to pass by a shivering and hungry child in the street without noticing it. But the mothers of the poorer classes have not that training. They cannot stand the sight of a hungry child; they must feed it, and so they do. "When the school children beg bread, they seldom or rather never meet with a refusal"—a lady-friend, who has worked several years in Whitechapel in connection with a workers' club, writes to me. But I may, perhaps, as well transcribe a few more passages from her letter:—

Then comes the bond among mothers. "You can't imagine" (a female doctor who lives in a low-income neighborhood told me recently) "how much they help each other. If a woman hasn’t prepared anything, or couldn’t prepare anything, for the baby she’s expecting—and that happens a lot!—all the neighbors bring something for the newcomer. One neighbor always looks after the kids, and another always stops by to help with the household while the mother is resting in bed." This practice is widespread. It’s noted by everyone who has lived among the poor. In countless small ways, mothers support each other and care for children that aren’t their own. Some training—good or bad, they can decide that for themselves—is needed for a woman from wealthier classes to be able to walk past a shivering and hungry child on the street without acknowledging it. But mothers from poorer backgrounds don’t have that training. They can’t bear to see a hungry child; they have to feed it, and so they do. "When school children ask for bread, they rarely or even never encounter a refusal," a female friend, who has worked several years in Whitechapel with a workers' club, wrote to me. But I might as well share a few more excerpts from her letter:—

"Nursing neighbours, in cases of illness, without any shade of remuneration, is quite general among the workers. Also, when a woman has little children, and goes out for work, another mother always takes care of them.

"Nursing neighbors during times of illness, without any expectation of payment, is very common among workers. Additionally, when a woman has small children and goes out to work, another mother always looks after them."

"If, in the working classes, they would not help each other, they could not exist. I know families which continually help each other—with money, with food, with fuel, for bringing up the little children, in cases of illness, in cases of death.

"If the working class didn't support one another, they wouldn't survive. I know families that consistently help each other—with money, food, fuel, taking care of young kids, during illness, and in times of death."

"'The mine' and 'thine' is much less sharply observed among the poor than among the rich. Shoes, dress, hats, and so on,—what may be wanted on the spot—are continually borrowed from each other, also all sorts of household things.

"'Mine' and 'yours' are not as strictly defined among the poor as they are among the rich. Shoes, clothes, hats, and so on—whatever is needed at the moment—are often borrowed from one another, along with all kinds of household items."

"Last winter the members of the United Radical Club had brought together some little money, and began after Christmas to distribute free soup and bread to the children going to school. Gradually they had 1,800 children to attend to. The money came from outsiders, but all the work was done by the members of the club. Some of them, who were out of work, came at four in the morning to wash and to peel the vegetables; five women came at nine or ten (after having done their own household work) for cooking, and stayed till six or seven to wash the dishes. And at meal time, between twelve and half-past one, twenty to thirty workers came in to aid in serving the soup, each one staying what he could spare of his meal time. This lasted for two months. No one was paid."

"Last winter, the members of the United Radical Club gathered some funds and started, after Christmas, to provide free soup and bread to the schoolchildren. Eventually, they served 1,800 children. The money came from external donations, but all the work was done by the club members. Some of them, who were unemployed, arrived at four in the morning to wash and peel vegetables; five women came at nine or ten (after taking care of their own housework) to cook and stayed until six or seven to wash the dishes. At mealtime, between twelve and twelve-thirty, twenty to thirty volunteers came in to help serve the soup, each staying as long as they could spare from their lunch break. This continued for two months. Nobody was paid."

My friend also mentions various individual cases, of which the following are typical:—

My friend also mentions several individual cases, of which the following are typical:—

"Annie W. was given by her mother to be boarded by an old person in Wilmot Street. When her mother died, the old woman, who herself was very poor, kept the child without being paid a penny for that. When the old lady died too, the child, who was five years old, was of course neglected during her illness, and was ragged; but she was taken at once by Mrs. S., the wife of a shoemaker, who herself has six children. Lately, when the husband was ill, they had not much to eat, all of them.

"Annie W. was given by her mother to stay with an elderly woman on Wilmot Street. After her mother passed away, the old lady, who was quite poor herself, took care of the child without receiving any payment. When the elderly woman also died, the five-year-old Annie was neglected during her illness and was in rags. However, she was quickly taken in by Mrs. S., the wife of a shoemaker, who had six children of her own. Recently, when her husband was sick, they all struggled to find enough food."

"The other day, Mrs. M., mother of six children, attended Mrs. M—g throughout her illness, and took to her own rooms the elder child…. But do you need such facts? They are quite general…. I know also Mrs. D. (Oval, Hackney Road), who has a sewing machine and continually sews for others, without ever accepting any remuneration, although she has herself five children and her husband to look after…. And so on."

"The other day, Mrs. M., the mother of six kids, took care of Mrs. M—g during her illness and brought her older child into her own rooms…. But do you really need to hear about this? It's pretty common…. I also know Mrs. D. (Oval, Hackney Road), who has a sewing machine and constantly sews for others without ever asking for payment, even though she has five kids and a husband to take care of…. And so on."

For every one who has any idea of the life of the labouring classes it is evident that without mutual aid being practised among them on a large scale they never could pull through all their difficulties. It is only by chance that a worker's family can live its lifetime without having to face such circumstances as the crisis described by the ribbon weaver, Joseph Gutteridge, in his autobiography.(18) And if all do not go to the ground in such cases, they owe it to mutual help. In Gutteridge's case it was an old nurse, miserably poor herself, who turned up at the moment when the family was slipping towards a final catastrophe, and brought in some bread, coal, and bedding, which she had obtained on credit. In other cases, it will be some one else, or the neighbours will take steps to save the family. But without some aid from other poor, how many more would be brought every year to irreparable ruin!(19)

For anyone who understands the lives of working-class people, it's clear that without widespread mutual support, they wouldn't be able to get through their challenges. It's mostly by chance that a worker's family can go through life without facing situations like the crisis described by the ribbon weaver, Joseph Gutteridge, in his autobiography.(18) If some families manage to stay afloat in these situations, it's thanks to mutual aid. In Gutteridge's case, it was an old nurse, who was living in poverty herself, that showed up just when his family was about to hit rock bottom, bringing bread, coal, and bedding she had gotten on credit. In other instances, it could be someone else, or neighbors stepping in to help save the family. But without support from other poor people, how many more would suffer irreparable ruin each year!(19)

Mr. Plimsoll, after he had lived for some time among the poor, on 7s. 6d. a week, was compelled to recognize that the kindly feelings he took with him when he began this life "changed into hearty respect and admiration" when he saw how the relations between the poor are permeated with mutual aid and support, and learned the simple ways in which that support is given. After a many years' experience, his conclusion was that "when you come to think of it, such as these men were, so were the vast majority of the working classes."(20) As to bringing up orphans, even by the poorest families, it is so widely-spread a habit, that it may be described as a general rule; thus among the miners it was found, after the two explosions at Warren Vale and at Lund Hill, that "nearly one-third of the men killed, as the respective committees can testify, were thus supporting relations other than wife and child." "Have you reflected," Mr. Plimsoll added, "what this is? Rich men, even comfortably-to-do men do this, I don't doubt. But consider the difference." Consider what a sum of one shilling, subscribed by each worker to help a comrade's widow, or 6d. to help a fellow-worker to defray the extra expense of a funeral, means for one who earns 16s. a week and has a wife, and in some cases five or six children to support.(21) But such subscriptions are a general practice among the workers all over the world, even in much more ordinary cases than a death in the family, while aid in work is the commonest thing in their lives.

Mr. Plimsoll, after living among the poor on a weekly budget of 7s. 6d. for some time, had to admit that the kind feelings he brought with him transformed into genuine respect and admiration when he witnessed how relationships among the poor are filled with mutual support and assistance. He learned about the simple ways that this help is given. After many years of experience, he concluded that "when you think about it, the men he encountered represent the vast majority of the working class." When it comes to raising orphans, even the poorest families tend to do this, and it's so common that it can be considered a general rule; for example, among the miners, it was found after the two explosions at Warren Vale and Lund Hill that "nearly one-third of the men killed, as the respective committees can testify, were supporting relatives other than their wife and children." "Have you thought about what this means?" Mr. Plimsoll added. "Wealthy men, even those who are comfortably off, do this, I'm sure. But think about the difference." Consider what a contribution of one shilling from each worker to support a colleague's widow, or 6d. to help a fellow worker with the costs of a funeral, means for someone earning 16s. a week who has a wife and, in some cases, five or six children to care for. But such contributions are a common practice among workers everywhere, even in more ordinary situations than a family death, while offering help at work is an everyday occurrence in their lives.

Nor do the same practices of mutual aid and support fail among the richer classes. Of course, when one thinks of the harshness which is often shown by the richer employers towards their employees, one feels inclined to take the most pessimist view of human nature. Many must remember the indignation which was aroused during the great Yorkshire strike of 1894, when old miners who had picked coal from an abandoned pit were prosecuted by the colliery owners. And, even if we leave aside the horrors of the periods of struggle and social war, such as the extermination of thousands of workers' prisoners after the fall of the Paris Commune—who can read, for instance, revelations of the labour inquest which was made here in the forties, or what Lord Shaftesbury wrote about "the frightful waste of human life in the factories, to which the children taken from the workhouses, or simply purchased all over this country to be sold as factory slaves, were consigned"(22)—who can read that without being vividly impressed by the baseness which is possible in man when his greediness is at stake? But it must also be said that all fault for such treatment must not be thrown entirely upon the criminality of human nature. Were not the teachings of men of science, and even of a notable portion of the clergy, up to a quite recent time, teachings of distrust, despite and almost hatred towards the poorer classes? Did not science teach that since serfdom has been abolished, no one need be poor unless for his own vices? And how few in the Church had the courage to blame the children-killers, while the great numbers taught that the sufferings of the poor, and even the slavery of the negroes, were part of the Divine Plan! Was not Nonconformism itself largely a popular protest against the harsh treatment of the poor at the hand of the established Church?

Nor do the same practices of mutual aid and support fail among the wealthier classes. Of course, when you think about the harshness often displayed by wealthy employers towards their employees, it’s easy to take a very pessimistic view of human nature. Many must remember the outrage that erupted during the great Yorkshire strike of 1894 when elderly miners who had taken coal from an abandoned pit were prosecuted by the mine owners. And even if we set aside the horrors of times of struggle and social conflict, like the execution of thousands of workers' prisoners after the fall of the Paris Commune—who can read, for instance, the findings from the labor inquest that took place here in the forties, or what Lord Shaftesbury wrote about "the frightful waste of human life in the factories, to which the children taken from the workhouses, or simply purchased all over this country to be sold as factory slaves, were consigned"(22)—who can read that without being profoundly struck by the depravity that humans can exhibit when their greed is involved? However, it should also be noted that not all blame for such treatment can be placed solely on the criminal nature of humanity. Wasn't the teaching of scientists, and even a significant portion of the clergy, until quite recently, filled with distrust, disdain, and almost hatred towards the poorer classes? Did science not suggest that since serfdom was abolished, no one needed to be poor unless due to their own failings? And how few in the Church had the courage to condemn those who harmed children, while many taught that the suffering of the poor, and even the enslavement of Black people, were part of the Divine Plan! Wasn't Nonconformity itself largely a popular reaction against the cruel treatment of the poor by the established Church?

With such spiritual leaders, the feelings of the richer classes necessarily became, as Mr. Pimsoll remarked, not so much blunted as "stratified." They seldom went downwards towards the poor, from whom the well-to-do-people are separated by their manner of life, and whom they do not know under their best aspects, in their every-day life. But among themselves—allowance being made for the effects of the wealth-accumulating passions and the futile expenses imposed by wealth itself—among themselves, in the circle of family and friends, the rich practise the same mutual aid and support as the poor. Dr. Ihering and L. Dargun are perfectly right in saying that if a statistical record could be taken of all the money which passes from hand to hand in the shape of friendly loans and aid, the sum total would be enormous, even in comparison with the commercial transactions of the world's trade. And if we could add to it, as we certainly ought to, what is spent in hospitality, petty mutual services, the management of other people's affairs, gifts and charities, we certainly should be struck by the importance of such transfers in national economy. Even in the world which is ruled by commercial egotism, the current expression, "We have been harshly treated by that firm," shows that there is also the friendly treatment, as opposed to the harsh, i.e. the legal treatment; while every commercial man knows how many firms are saved every year from failure by the friendly support of other firms.

With these spiritual leaders, the feelings of the wealthy classes became, as Mr. Pimsoll pointed out, not so much dulled as "stratified." They rarely interacted with the poor, who live very differently and whom they don’t see at their best in daily life. However, among themselves—considering the impact of wealth-driven desires and the pointless expenses that come with it—within their family and friend circles, the rich provide the same mutual aid and support as the poor do. Dr. Ihering and L. Dargun are absolutely correct in saying that if we could track all the money that circulates as friendly loans and assistance, the total would be massive, even compared to global commercial transactions. And if we could add, as we should, what’s spent on hospitality, small mutual favors, managing others' affairs, gifts, and charities, we would definitely recognize the significance of these financial transfers in the national economy. Even in a world dominated by commercial self-interest, the phrase, "We have been treated harshly by that firm," indicates that there’s also friendly treatment compared to the harsh, i.e., the legal treatment; while every business person knows how many companies are saved from failure each year by the support of other businesses.

As to the charities and the amounts of work for general well-being which are voluntarily done by so many well-to-do persons, as well as by workers, and especially by professional men, every one knows the part which is played by these two categories of benevolence in modern life. If the desire of acquiring notoriety, political power, or social distinction often spoils the true character of that sort of benevolence, there is no doubt possible as to the impulse coming in the majority of cases from the same mutual-aid feelings. Men who have acquired wealth very often do not find in it the expected satisfaction. Others begin to feel that, whatever economists may say about wealth being the reward of capacity, their own reward is exaggerated. The conscience of human solidarity begins to tell; and, although society life is so arranged as to stifle that feeling by thousands of artful means, it often gets the upper hand; and then they try to find an outcome for that deeply human need by giving their fortune, or their forces, to something which, in their opinion, will promote general welfare.

As for the charities and the amount of work done for the common good by many wealthy people, as well as by workers and especially by professionals, everyone recognizes the role these two groups of generosity play in modern life. While the desire for fame, political influence, or social standing can often overshadow the true nature of that generosity, there's no doubt that the drive often stems from the same mutual aid sentiments. Many wealthy individuals frequently find that their riches do not bring the fulfillment they expected. Others start to realize that, despite what economists might claim about wealth being a reward for ability, their own rewards feel inflated. The awareness of our shared humanity begins to emerge; and although society is structured to suppress that feeling through countless clever methods, it often prevails. Consequently, they seek to channel that fundamental human need by giving their wealth or efforts to causes they believe will benefit the public good.

In short, neither the crushing powers of the centralized State nor the teachings of mutual hatred and pitiless struggle which came, adorned with the attributes of science, from obliging philosophers and sociologists, could weed out the feeling of human solidarity, deeply lodged in men's understanding and heart, because it has been nurtured by all our preceding evolution. What was the outcome of evolution since its earliest stages cannot be overpowered by one of the aspects of that same evolution. And the need of mutual aid and support which had lately taken refuge in the narrow circle of the family, or the slum neighbours, in the village, or the secret union of workers, re-asserts itself again, even in our modern society, and claims its rights to be, as it always has been, the chief leader towards further progress. Such are the conclusions which we are necessarily brought to when we carefully ponder over each of the groups of facts briefly enumerated in the last two chapters.

In short, neither the overwhelming power of the centralized government nor the teachings of mutual hatred and ruthless competition, which were presented with a veneer of science by willing philosophers and sociologists, could eliminate the sense of human solidarity deeply rooted in people's minds and hearts, because it has been fostered by our entire evolution. What has emerged from evolution since its earliest stages cannot be overshadowed by one aspect of that same evolution. The need for mutual aid and support, which had recently found refuge in the close-knit family, among slum neighbors, in villages, or within secret unions of workers, reasserts itself once again, even in our modern society, and demands its rightful place as the main driving force for further progress. These are the conclusions we inevitably reach when we carefully reflect on each of the groups of facts briefly outlined in the last two chapters.

NOTES:

1. Toulmin Smith, English Guilds, London, 1870, Introd. p. xliii.

1. Toulmin Smith, English Guilds, London, 1870, Introd. p. xliii.

2. The Act of Edward the Sixth—the first of his reign—ordered to hand over to the Crown "all fraternities, brotherhoods, and guilds being within the realm of England and Wales and other of the king's dominions; and all manors, lands, tenements, and other hereditaments belonging to them or any of them" (English Guilds, Introd. p. xliii). See also Ockenkowski's Englands wirtschaftliche Entwickelung im Ausgange des Mittelalters, Jena, 1879, chaps. ii-v.

2. The Act of Edward the Sixth—the first of his reign—ordered the transfer to the Crown of "all fraternities, brotherhoods, and guilds within the realm of England and Wales and other areas under the king's rule; and all manors, lands, tenements, and other properties belonging to them or any of them" (English Guilds, Introd. p. xliii). See also Ockenkowski's Englands wirtschaftliche Entwickelung im Ausgange des Mittelalters, Jena, 1879, chaps. ii-v.

3. See Sidney and Beatrice Webb, History of Trade-Unionism, London, 1894, pp. 21-38.

3. See Sidney and Beatrice Webb, History of Trade-Unionism, London, 1894, pp. 21-38.

4. See in Sidney Webb's work the associations which existed at that time. The London artisans are supposed to have never been better organized than in 1810-20.

4. Look at Sidney Webb's work to see the connections that were present during that time. The London workers are believed to have been more organized than ever between 1810 and 1820.

5. The National Association for the Protection of Labour included about 150 separate unions, which paid high levies, and had a membership of about 100,000. The Builders' Union and the Miners' Unions also were big organizations (Webb, l.c. p. 107).

5. The National Association for the Protection of Labor had around 150 different unions that paid high fees and had a membership of about 100,000. The Builders' Union and the Miners' Union were also large organizations (Webb, l.c. p. 107).

6. I follow in this Mr. Webb's work, which is replete with documents to confirm his statements.

6. I follow Mr. Webb's work, which is full of documents to back up his claims.

7. Great changes have taken place since the forties in the attitude of the richer classes towards the unions. However, even in the sixties, the employers made a formidable concerted attempt to crush them by locking out whole populations. Up to 1869 the simple agreement to strike, and the announcement of a strike by placards, to say nothing of picketing, were often punished as intimidation. Only in 1875 the Master and Servant Act was repealed, peaceful picketing was permitted, and "violence and intimidation" during strikes fell into the domain of common law. Yet, even during the dock-labourers' strike in 1887, relief money had to be spent for fighting before the Courts for the right of picketing, while the prosecutions of the last few years menace once more to render the conquered rights illusory.

7. Since the 1940s, there have been significant changes in how the wealthy view unions. However, even in the 1960s, employers made a strong coordinated effort to eliminate them by locking out entire communities. Up until 1869, merely agreeing to strike and announcing a strike through posters, not to mention picketing, were frequently seen as forms of intimidation and punished. It wasn't until 1875 that the Master and Servant Act was repealed, allowing peaceful picketing, while "violence and intimidation" during strikes was classified under common law. Still, during the dockworkers’ strike in 1887, relief funds had to be used to fight in court for the right to picket, and recent prosecutions threaten to make the rights that were won feel meaningless once again.

8. A weekly contribution of 6d. out of an 18s. wage, or of 1s. out of 25s., means much more than 9l. out of a 300l. income: it is mostly taken upon food; and the levy is soon doubled when a strike is declared in a brother union. The graphic description of trade-union life, by a skilled craftsman, published by Mr. and Mrs. Webb (pp. 431 seq.), gives an excellent idea of the amount of work required from a unionist.

8. A weekly contribution of 6d. from an 18s. wage, or 1s. from 25s., means a lot more than 9l. from a 300l. income: it mostly comes out of food expenses; and the amount is quickly doubled when a strike is called in a related union. The detailed account of trade-union life, written by a skilled craftsman and published by Mr. and Mrs. Webb (pp. 431 seq.), provides a great sense of the work expected from a union member.

9. See the debates upon the strikes of Falkenau in Austria before the Austrian Reichstag on the 10th of May, 1894, in which debates the fact is fully recognized by the Ministry and the owner of the colliery. Also the English Press of that time.

9. See the discussions about the strikes in Falkenau, Austria, before the Austrian Reichstag on May 10, 1894, where the Ministry and the owner of the coal mine fully acknowledge the situation. The English press of that time also reported on it.

10. Many such facts will be found in the Daily Chronicle and partly the Daily News for October and November 1894.

10. Many such facts can be found in the Daily Chronicle and partly in the Daily News for October and November 1894.

11. The 31,473 productive and consumers' associations on the Middle Rhine showed, about 1890, a yearly expenditure of 18,437,500l.; 3,675,000l. were granted during the year in loans.

11. The 31,473 productive and consumer associations on the Middle Rhine showed, around 1890, an annual expenditure of £18,437,500; £3,675,000 were granted in loans during the year.

12. British Consular Report, April 1889.

12. British Consular Report, April 1889.

13. A capital research on this subject has been published in Russian in the Zapiski (Memoirs) of the Caucasian Geographical Society, vol. vi. 2, Tiflis, 1891, by C. Egiazaroff.

13. A comprehensive study on this topic has been published in Russian in the Zapiski (Memoirs) of the Caucasian Geographical Society, vol. vi. 2, Tiflis, 1891, by C. Egiazaroff.

14. Escape from a French prison is extremely difficult; nevertheless a prisoner escaped from one of the French prisons in 1884 or 1885. He even managed to conceal himself during the whole day, although the alarm was given and the peasants in the neighbourhood were on the look-out for him. Next morning found him concealed in a ditch, close by a small village. Perhaps he intended to steal some food, or some clothes in order to take off his prison uniform. As he was lying in the ditch a fire broke out in the village. He saw a woman running out of one of the burning houses, and heard her desperate appeals to rescue a child in the upper storey of the burning house. No one moved to do so. Then the escaped prisoner dashed out of his retreat, made his way through the fire, and, with a scalded face and burning clothes, brought the child safe out of the fire, and handed it to its mother. Of course he was arrested on the spot by the village gendarme, who now made his appearance. He was taken back to the prison. The fact was reported in all French papers, but none of them bestirred itself to obtain his release. If he had shielded a warder from a comrade's blow, he would have been made a hero of. But his act was simply humane, it did not promote the State's ideal; he himself did not attribute it to a sudden inspiration of divine grace; and that was enough to let the man fall into oblivion. Perhaps, six or twelve months were added to his sentence for having stolen—"the State's property"—the prison's dress.

14. Escaping from a French prison is incredibly tough; however, a prisoner did break out of one of the French prisons in 1884 or 1885. He managed to stay hidden all day, even though the alarm was raised and the local villagers were searching for him. The next morning, he was found hiding in a ditch near a small village. He might have planned to steal some food or clothes to change out of his prison uniform. While he was lying in the ditch, a fire broke out in the village. He saw a woman running out of one of the burning houses and heard her frantic cries for help to rescue a child trapped on the top floor. No one moved to help. Then the escaped prisoner ran out of his hiding place, made his way through the flames, and, with a burned face and scorched clothes, managed to bring the child out safely and handed it to its mother. Naturally, he was arrested immediately by the village gendarme, who showed up just then. He was taken back to prison. The incident was reported in all the French newspapers, but none took action to secure his release. If he had protected a guard from an attack by another prisoner, he would have been hailed a hero. But since his act was simply altruistic and didn’t align with the State’s ideals, and he didn’t claim it was a sudden moment of divine intervention, he faded into obscurity. It’s possible that six to twelve additional months were added to his sentence for "stealing"—the prison’s uniform, which was considered "the State’s property."

15. The medical Academy for Women (which has given to Russia a large portion of her 700 graduated lady doctors), the four Ladies' Universities (about 1000 pupils in 1887; closed that year, and reopened in 1895), and the High Commercial School for Women are entirely the work of such private societies. To the same societies we owe the high standard which the girls' gymnasia attained since they were opened in the sixties. The 100 gymnasia now scattered over the Empire (over 70,000 pupils), correspond to the High Schools for Girls in this country; all teachers are, however, graduates of the universities.

15. The Medical Academy for Women (which has produced a significant number of Russia's 700 female doctors), the four Ladies' Universities (around 1,000 students in 1887; closed that year and reopened in 1895), and the High Commercial School for Women are all the results of these private organizations. We also owe the high standards achieved by girls' gymnasiums since they began in the sixties to the same societies. The 100 gymnasiums now spread across the Empire (with over 70,000 students) are similar to the High Schools for Girls in this country; however, all teachers are graduates of the universities.

16. The Verein für Verbreitung gemeinnutslicher Kenntnisse, although it has only 5500 members, has already opened more than 1000 public and school libraries, organized thousands of lectures, and published most valuable books.

16. The Association for the Dissemination of Useful Knowledge, despite having only 5,500 members, has already opened over 1,000 public and school libraries, organized thousands of lectures, and published many valuable books.

17. Very few writers in sociology have paid attention to it. Dr. Ihering is one of them, and his case is very instructive. When the great German writer on law began his philosophical work, Der Zweck im Rechte ("Purpose in Law"), he intended to analyze "the active forces which call forth the advance of society and maintain it," and to thus give "the theory of the sociable man." He analyzed, first, the egotistic forces at work, including the present wage-system and coercion in its variety of political and social laws; and in a carefully worked-out scheme of his work he intended to give the last paragraph to the ethical forces—the sense of duty and mutual love—which contribute to the same aim. When he came, however, to discuss the social functions of these two factors, he had to write a second volume, twice as big as the first; and yet he treated only of the personal factors which will take in the following pages only a few lines. L. Dargun took up the same idea in Egoismus und Altruismus in der Nationalokonomie, Leipzig, 1885, adding some new facts. Buchner's Love, and the several paraphrases of it published here and in Germany, deal with the same subject.

17. Very few writers in sociology have focused on it. Dr. Ihering is one of them, and his case is quite enlightening. When the prominent German writer on law started his philosophical work, Der Zweck im Rechte ("Purpose in Law"), he aimed to analyze "the active forces that drive societal progress and sustain it," and to provide "the theory of the social man." He first examined the selfish forces at play, including the current wage system and various forms of coercion found in political and social laws. In a detailed outline of his work, he planned to dedicate the final section to the ethical forces—the sense of duty and mutual love—that contribute to the same goal. However, when he began to discuss the social roles of these two elements, he ended up writing a second volume that was twice the length of the first; still, he only briefly covered the personal factors that will be discussed in just a few lines in the following pages. L. Dargun explored the same idea in Egoismus und Altruismus in der Nationalokonomie, Leipzig, 1885, adding some new insights. Buchner's Love, along with several adaptations published here and in Germany, addresses the same topic.

18. Light and Shadows in the Life of an Artisan. Coventry, 1893.

18. Light and Shadows in the Life of an Artisan. Coventry, 1893.

19. Many rich people cannot understand how the very poor can help each other, because they do not realize upon what infinitesimal amounts of food or money often hangs the life of one of the poorest classes. Lord Shaftesbury had understood this terrible truth when he started his Flowers and Watercress Girls' Fund, out of which loans of one pound, and only occasionally two pounds, were granted, to enable the girls to buy a basket and flowers when the winter sets in and they are in dire distress. The loans were given to girls who had "not a sixpence," but never failed to find some other poor to go bail for them. "Of all the movements I have ever been connected with," Lord Shaftesbury wrote, "I look upon this Watercress Girls' movement as the most successful…. It was begun in 1872, and we have had out 800 to 1,000 loans, and have not lost 50l. during the whole period…. What has been lost—and it has been very little, under the circumstances—has been by reason of death or sickness, not by fraud" (The Life and Work of the Seventh Earl of Shaftesbury, by Edwin Hodder, vol. iii. p. 322. London, 1885-86). Several more facts in point in Ch. Booth's Life and Labour in London, vol. i; in Miss Beatrice Potter's "Pages from a Work Girl's Diary" (Nineteenth Century, September 1888, p. 310); and so on.

19. Many wealthy people struggle to understand how the very poor can support each other because they don’t realize how little food or money often determines the survival of those in the lowest classes. Lord Shaftesbury recognized this harsh reality when he established his Flowers and Watercress Girls' Fund, which provided loans of one pound, and sometimes two pounds, to help the girls buy a basket and flowers when winter arrives and they are in serious need. The loans were given to girls who had "not a sixpence," but who always managed to find another poor person to vouch for them. "Of all the movements I have ever been involved with," Lord Shaftesbury wrote, "I consider this Watercress Girls' movement to be the most successful…. It started in 1872, and we granted 800 to 1,000 loans, losing less than £50 throughout the entire period…. What has been lost—and it’s been very little, given the circumstances—has been due to death or illness, not fraud" (The Life and Work of the Seventh Earl of Shaftesbury, by Edwin Hodder, vol. iii. p. 322. London, 1885-86). Additional facts can be found in Ch. Booth's Life and Labour in London, vol. i; in Miss Beatrice Potter's "Pages from a Work Girl's Diary" (Nineteenth Century, September 1888, p. 310); and others.

20. Samuel Plimsoll, Our Seamen, cheap edition, London, 1870, p. 110.

20. Samuel Plimsoll, Our Seamen, budget edition, London, 1870, p. 110.

21. Our Seamen, u.s., p. 110. Mr. Plimsoll added: "I don't wish to disparage the rich, but I think it may be reasonably doubted whether these qualities are so fully developed in them; for, notwithstanding that not a few of them are not unacquainted with the claims, reasonable or unreasonable, of poor relatives, these qualities are not in such constant exercise. Riches seem in so many cases to smother the manliness of their possessors, and their sympathies become, not so much narrowed as—so to speak—stratified: they are reserved for the sufferings of their own class, and also the woes of those above them. They seldom tend downwards much, and they are far more likely to admire an act of courage … than to admire the constantly exercised fortitude and the tenderness which are the daily characteristics of a British workman's life"—and of the workmen all over the world as well.

21. Our Seamen, u.s., p. 110. Mr. Plimsoll added: "I don't want to put down the wealthy, but I think it's fair to question whether they develop these qualities to the same extent; because, even though some of them are aware of the reasonable or unreasonable demands of their less fortunate relatives, these qualities aren't consistently put to use. Wealth often seems to dull the sense of manliness in those who have it, and their empathy becomes, not so much limited as—let's say—layered: it's reserved for the struggles of their own class and also for those above them. They rarely extend their concern downwards, and they’re much more likely to admire a single act of bravery… than to appreciate the ongoing resilience and compassion that define the daily lives of a British worker"—and of workers everywhere.

22. Life of the Seventh Earl of Shaftesbury, by Edwin Hodder, vol. i. pp. 137-138.

22. Life of the Seventh Earl of Shaftesbury, by Edwin Hodder, vol. i. pp. 137-138.

CONCLUSION

If we take now the teachings which can be borrowed from the analysis of modern society, in connection with the body of evidence relative to the importance of mutual aid in the evolution of the animal world and of mankind, we may sum up our inquiry as follows.

If we consider the insights we can gain from analyzing modern society, along with the evidence highlighting the significance of mutual aid in the development of the animal kingdom and humanity, we can summarize our investigation like this.

In the animal world we have seen that the vast majority of species live in societies, and that they find in association the best arms for the struggle for life: understood, of course, in its wide Darwinian sense—not as a struggle for the sheer means of existence, but as a struggle against all natural conditions unfavourable to the species. The animal species, in which individual struggle has been reduced to its narrowest limits, and the practice of mutual aid has attained the greatest development, are invariably the most numerous, the most prosperous, and the most open to further progress. The mutual protection which is obtained in this case, the possibility of attaining old age and of accumulating experience, the higher intellectual development, and the further growth of sociable habits, secure the maintenance of the species, its extension, and its further progressive evolution. The unsociable species, on the contrary, are doomed to decay.

In the animal kingdom, we see that most species live in social groups, and they find that working together gives them the best tools for survival—understood, of course, in the broad Darwinian sense—not just as a fight for basic existence, but as a struggle against any natural conditions that are harmful to the species. The animal species where individual competition is minimized and cooperation is highly developed are consistently the most numerous, successful, and open to further advancement. The shared protection they experience, the chance to live longer and gain experience, the higher level of intellectual development, and the increased social behavior all ensure the survival of the species, its expansion, and its ongoing evolution. In contrast, unsocial species are destined to decline.

Going next over to man, we found him living in clans and tribes at the very dawn of the stone age; we saw a wide series of social institutions developed already in the lower savage stage, in the clan and the tribe; and we found that the earliest tribal customs and habits gave to mankind the embryo of all the institutions which made later on the leading aspects of further progress. Out of the savage tribe grew up the barbarian village community; and a new, still wider, circle of social customs, habits, and institutions, numbers of which are still alive among ourselves, was developed under the principles of common possession of a given territory and common defence of it, under the jurisdiction of the village folkmote, and in the federation of villages belonging, or supposed to belong, to one stem. And when new requirements induced men to make a new start, they made it in the city, which represented a double network of territorial units (village communities), connected with guilds these latter arising out of the common prosecution of a given art or craft, or for mutual support and defence.

Moving on to humans, we found them living in clans and tribes at the very start of the Stone Age. We observed a wide range of social structures already emerging in the early savage stage, within the clan and the tribe. We realized that the earliest tribal customs and practices formed the foundation for all the institutions that later became key elements of further progress. From the savage tribe came the barbarian village community, which developed a broader set of social customs, habits, and institutions—many of which are still present today—based on the shared ownership of land and joint defense under the village assembly and in the federation of villages that belonged, or were thought to belong, to a common lineage. When new needs prompted people to make a fresh start, they did so in the city, which represented a complex network of territorial units (village communities) linked with guilds that emerged from the collective pursuit of a specific trade or craft or for mutual aid and protection.

And finally, in the last two chapters facts were produced to show that although the growth of the State on the pattern of Imperial Rome had put a violent end to all medieval institutions for mutual support, this new aspect of civilization could not last. The State, based upon loose aggregations of individuals and undertaking to be their only bond of union, did not answer its purpose. The mutual-aid tendency finally broke down its iron rules; it reappeared and reasserted itself in an infinity of associations which now tend to embrace all aspects of life and to take possession of all that is required by man for life and for reproducing the waste occasioned by life.

And finally, in the last two chapters, evidence was presented to show that although the growth of the State, modeled after Imperial Rome, violently ended all medieval institutions that provided mutual support, this new phase of civilization couldn’t last. The State, which was built on loosely connected individuals and claimed to be their only source of unity, failed to fulfill its purpose. The tendency for mutual aid eventually broke through its strict controls; it reemerged and reasserted itself in countless associations that now aim to cover all aspects of life and to provide for everything needed by people to live and to replace the resources depleted by life.

It will probably be remarked that mutual aid, even though it may represent one of the factors of evolution, covers nevertheless one aspect only of human relations; that by the side of this current, powerful though it may be, there is, and always has been, the other current—the self-assertion of the individual, not only in its efforts to attain personal or caste superiority, economical, political, and spiritual, but also in its much more important although less evident function of breaking through the bonds, always prone to become crystallized, which the tribe, the village community, the city, and the State impose upon the individual. In other words, there is the self-assertion of the individual taken as a progressive element.

It might be noted that mutual aid, even though it can be one of the factors of evolution, only represents one side of human relationships. Alongside this strong current, there has always been another current—the individual’s self-assertion. This isn't just about striving for personal or social superiority, whether economic, political, or spiritual; it's also about its even more significant, though less visible, role in breaking free from the constraints that the tribe, village, city, and state place on individuals, which tend to harden over time. In other words, individual self-assertion acts as a progressive force.

It is evident that no review of evolution can be complete, unless these two dominant currents are analyzed. However, the self-assertion of the individual or of groups of individuals, their struggles for superiority, and the conflicts which resulted therefrom, have already been analyzed, described, and glorified from time immemorial. In fact, up to the present time, this current alone has received attention from the epical poet, the annalist, the historian, and the sociologist. History, such as it has hitherto been written, is almost entirely a description of the ways and means by which theocracy, military power, autocracy, and, later on, the richer classes' rule have been promoted, established, and maintained. The struggles between these forces make, in fact, the substance of history. We may thus take the knowledge of the individual factor in human history as granted—even though there is full room for a new study of the subject on the lines just alluded to; while, on the other side, the mutual-aid factor has been hitherto totally lost sight of; it was simply denied, or even scoffed at, by the writers of the present and past generation. It was therefore necessary to show, first of all, the immense part which this factor plays in the evolution of both the animal world and human societies. Only after this has been fully recognized will it be possible to proceed to a comparison between the two factors.

It’s clear that no review of evolution can be complete without analyzing these two dominant trends. However, the self-assertion of individuals or groups, their struggles for superiority, and the resulting conflicts have been analyzed, described, and celebrated throughout history. In fact, until now, this trend alone has captured the attention of epic poets, chroniclers, historians, and sociologists. History, as it has been written so far, is almost entirely a portrayal of how theocracy, military power, autocracy, and later, the dominance of wealth have been promoted, established, and maintained. The conflicts between these forces essentially define history. We can therefore assume a basic understanding of the individual factor in human history—even though there's still plenty of room for a new study on that. Meanwhile, the role of mutual aid has been completely overlooked; it has either been denied or ridiculed by writers of both this and past generations. It’s important to first demonstrate the significant role this factor plays in the evolution of both the animal kingdom and human societies. Only after this is fully acknowledged can we begin to compare the two factors.

To make even a rough estimate of their relative importance by any method more or less statistical, is evidently impossible. One single war—we all know—may be productive of more evil, immediate and subsequent, than hundreds of years of the unchecked action of the mutual-aid principle may be productive of good. But when we see that in the animal world, progressive development and mutual aid go hand in hand, while the inner struggle within the species is concomitant with retrogressive development; when we notice that with man, even success in struggle and war is proportionate to the development of mutual aid in each of the two conflicting nations, cities, parties, or tribes, and that in the process of evolution war itself (so far as it can go this way) has been made subservient to the ends of progress in mutual aid within the nation, the city or the clan—we already obtain a perception of the dominating influence of the mutual-aid factor as an element of progress. But we see also that the practice of mutual aid and its successive developments have created the very conditions of society life in which man was enabled to develop his arts, knowledge, and intelligence; and that the periods when institutions based on the mutual-aid tendency took their greatest development were also the periods of the greatest progress in arts, industry, and science. In fact, the study of the inner life of the medieval city and of the ancient Greek cities reveals the fact that the combination of mutual aid, as it was practised within the guild and the Greek clan, with a large initiative which was left to the individual and the group by means of the federative principle, gave to mankind the two greatest periods of its history—the ancient Greek city and the medieval city periods; while the ruin of the above institutions during the State periods of history, which followed, corresponded in both cases to a rapid decay.

To make even a rough estimate of their relative importance using any more or less statistical method is clearly impossible. One single war—we all know—can cause more immediate and long-term harm than hundreds of years of the unchecked mutual aid principle can create good. But when we see that in the animal kingdom, progressive development and mutual aid go hand in hand, while internal struggles within a species lead to backward development; when we notice that for humans, even success in conflict and war correlates with the level of mutual aid in each of the two competing nations, cities, parties, or tribes, and that throughout evolution, war itself (as far as it can progress in this way) has been subordinated to the goals of mutual aid within the nation, city, or clan—we start to see the dominant influence of mutual aid as a factor of progress. However, we also see that the practice of mutual aid and its developments have created the very conditions of social life that allowed humans to develop their arts, knowledge, and intelligence; and that the times when institutions based on mutual aid thrived were also the times of greatest advancement in the arts, industry, and science. In fact, examining the inner workings of medieval cities and ancient Greek cities shows that the combination of mutual aid, as practiced within guilds and Greek clans, along with considerable individual and group initiative granted by the federative principle, gave humanity its two greatest historical periods—the ancient Greek city and the medieval city periods; whereas the decline of these institutions during the subsequent State periods of history corresponded to a rapid deterioration.

As to the sudden industrial progress which has been achieved during our own century, and which is usually ascribed to the triumph of individualism and competition, it certainly has a much deeper origin than that. Once the great discoveries of the fifteenth century were made, especially that of the pressure of the atmosphere, supported by a series of advances in natural philosophy—and they were made under the medieval city organization,—once these discoveries were made, the invention of the steam-motor, and all the revolution which the conquest of a new power implied, had necessarily to follow. If the medieval cities had lived to bring their discoveries to that point, the ethical consequences of the revolution effected by steam might have been different; but the same revolution in technics and science would have inevitably taken place. It remains, indeed, an open question whether the general decay of industries which followed the ruin of the free cities, and was especially noticeable in the first part of the eighteenth century, did not considerably retard the appearance of the steam-engine as well as the consequent revolution in arts. When we consider the astounding rapidity of industrial progress from the twelfth to the fifteenth centuries—in weaving, working of metals, architecture and navigation, and ponder over the scientific discoveries which that industrial progress led to at the end of the fifteenth century—we must ask ourselves whether mankind was not delayed in its taking full advantage of these conquests when a general depression of arts and industries took place in Europe after the decay of medieval civilization. Surely it was not the disappearance of the artist-artisan, nor the ruin of large cities and the extinction of intercourse between them, which could favour the industrial revolution; and we know indeed that James Watt spent twenty or more years of his life in order to render his invention serviceable, because he could not find in the last century what he would have readily found in medieval Florence or Brugge, that is, the artisans capable of realizing his devices in metal, and of giving them the artistic finish and precision which the steam-engine requires.

Regarding the sudden industrial progress we've seen in our century, which is typically credited to the success of individualism and competition, its roots run much deeper than that. After the major discoveries of the fifteenth century, particularly the understanding of atmospheric pressure, and with advancements in natural philosophy—developed within the framework of medieval city life—there was a natural progression towards innovations like the steam engine. Had the medieval cities persisted long enough to advance their discoveries to that level, the ethical impacts of the steam revolution might have been different; however, the same technological and scientific revolution would have inevitably occurred. It's still debatable whether the decline of industries that followed the fall of the free cities, especially noticeable in the early eighteenth century, significantly delayed the emergence of the steam engine and the resulting changes in the arts. When we reflect on the remarkable speed of industrial advancement from the twelfth to the fifteenth centuries—in areas like weaving, metalworking, architecture, and navigation—and consider the scientific breakthroughs that resulted by the end of the fifteenth century, we must question whether humanity was held back from fully benefiting from these achievements during the widespread decline of arts and industries in Europe after the fall of medieval civilization. It surely wasn't the disappearance of the skilled artist or the downfall of major cities and the breakdown of their connections that could have favored the industrial revolution; indeed, we know that James Watt dedicated twenty years of his life to make his invention practical because he couldn't find in the last century what would have been readily available in medieval Florence or Bruges: artisans skilled enough to bring his designs to life in metal, providing the artistic detail and precision that the steam engine needed.

To attribute, therefore, the industrial progress of our century to the war of each against all which it has proclaimed, is to reason like the man who, knowing not the causes of rain, attributes it to the victim he has immolated before his clay idol. For industrial progress, as for each other conquest over nature, mutual aid and close intercourse certainly are, as they have been, much more advantageous than mutual struggle.

To attribute the industrial progress of our century to the constant competition it has created is like the man who, unaware of the reasons for rain, blames it on the sacrifice he made to his clay idol. Industrial progress, like any other victory over nature, is much more helped by cooperation and close connections than by competition.

However, it is especially in the domain of ethics that the dominating importance of the mutual-aid principle appears in full. That mutual aid is the real foundation of our ethical conceptions seems evident enough. But whatever the opinions as to the first origin of the mutual-aid feeling or instinct may be whether a biological or a supernatural cause is ascribed to it—we must trace its existence as far back as to the lowest stages of the animal world; and from these stages we can follow its uninterrupted evolution, in opposition to a number of contrary agencies, through all degrees of human development, up to the present times. Even the new religions which were born from time to time—always at epochs when the mutual-aid principle was falling into decay in the theocracies and despotic States of the East, or at the decline of the Roman Empire—even the new religions have only reaffirmed that same principle. They found their first supporters among the humble, in the lowest, downtrodden layers of society, where the mutual-aid principle is the necessary foundation of every-day life; and the new forms of union which were introduced in the earliest Buddhist and Christian communities, in the Moravian brotherhoods and so on, took the character of a return to the best aspects of mutual aid in early tribal life.

However, it is particularly in the area of ethics that the importance of the mutual-aid principle becomes clear. It seems obvious that mutual aid is the real foundation of our ethical beliefs. Regardless of the opinions on the original source of the mutual-aid feeling or instinct—whether a biological or supernatural cause is attributed to it—we can trace its existence back to the earliest stages of the animal world. From these early beginnings, we can track its continuous evolution, despite various opposing forces, through all levels of human development up to the present day. Even the new religions that emerged at different times—typically when the mutual-aid principle was weakening in the theocracies and despotic states of the East, or during the decline of the Roman Empire—have only reaffirmed that same principle. They found their first supporters among the humble and the oppressed in society, where mutual aid is the essential foundation of everyday life. The new forms of community that arose in the earliest Buddhist and Christian groups, in the Moravian brotherhoods, and similar movements, reflected a return to the best aspects of mutual aid seen in early tribal life.

Each time, however, that an attempt to return to this old principle was made, its fundamental idea itself was widened. From the clan it was extended to the stem, to the federation of stems, to the nation, and finally—in ideal, at least—to the whole of mankind. It was also refined at the same time. In primitive Buddhism, in primitive Christianity, in the writings of some of the Mussulman teachers, in the early movements of the Reform, and especially in the ethical and philosophical movements of the last century and of our own times, the total abandonment of the idea of revenge, or of "due reward"—of good for good and evil for evil—is affirmed more and more vigorously. The higher conception of "no revenge for wrongs," and of freely giving more than one expects to receive from his neighbours, is proclaimed as being the real principle of morality—a principle superior to mere equivalence, equity, or justice, and more conducive to happiness. And man is appealed to to be guided in his acts, not merely by love, which is always personal, or at the best tribal, but by the perception of his oneness with each human being. In the practice of mutual aid, which we can retrace to the earliest beginnings of evolution, we thus find the positive and undoubted origin of our ethical conceptions; and we can affirm that in the ethical progress of man, mutual support not mutual struggle—has had the leading part. In its wide extension, even at the present time, we also see the best guarantee of a still loftier evolution of our race.

Each time an attempt was made to return to this old principle, its fundamental idea was broadened. It expanded from the clan to the lineage, then to the federation of lineages, to the nation, and finally—at least in theory—to all of humanity. It was also refined in the process. In early Buddhism, early Christianity, in the works of some Muslim teachers, in the initial movements of the Reformation, and especially in the ethical and philosophical movements of the last century and our own times, the complete rejection of the idea of revenge, or of "just reward"—of good for good and evil for evil—is increasingly emphasized. The elevated notion of "no revenge for wrongs," and of willingly giving more than one expects to receive from others, is proclaimed as the true principle of morality—a principle that transcends mere equivalence, fairness, or justice, and is more supportive of happiness. People are urged to guide their actions not just by love, which is often personal and at best tribal, but by understanding their connection with every human being. In the practice of mutual aid, which we can trace back to the earliest stages of evolution, we find the undeniable origin of our ethical ideals; and we can assert that in the ethical development of humankind, mutual support—not mutual conflict—has played the primary role. Its broad application today also serves as the best assurance of an even higher evolution of our species.


Download ePUB

If you like this ebook, consider a donation!